View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SEPTEMBER, 1946

jppar-

■

S




IN-ESS CON

A REVIEW BY THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

**,*r»^m

Control of Agricultural Prices Continued
But New Law Sets Special Limitations
The notion has become rather general in some quarters
that under the new price control extension act agricultural
commodities are largely exempt. While such commodities are
subjected to special treatment under the new law, it is
erroneous to infer that they are exempt.
Before going specifically into the provisions relating to
agricultural products some general considerations involved
in the new act are worth reviewing. The act directs that the
Office of Price Administration and other Governmental
agencies use their powers, including powers over prices and
subsidies, to “promote the earliest practical balance between
production and the demand therefore of commodities under
their control” and that price and subsidy controls he ter­
minated as quickly as possible consistent with this objective
“and in no event later than June 30, 1947.”
The act directs the President to recommend to Congress
as soon as practicable and before January 15, 1947, the
measures and policies which he deems necessary to supple­
ment existing controls of prices and wages with a view to
terminating all controls by June 30, 1947, without danger of
further inflation. He is further required to report to Con­
gress before next April 1 what commodities and services are
so critically short as to require continuances of price control
powers beyond next June 30.
On non-agricultural commodities the act requires the
termination by December 31, 1946, of price controls where
the commodity is not important in relation to business costs
or to the costs of living. The ceilings on any non-agricul­
tural commodity are directed to be removed whenever the
supply equals or exceeds demand, including proper allow­
ance for inventory requirements. Finally, if the supply of
a non-agricultural commodity falls below demand for a rea­
sonable period of time, the Administrator is required to rein­
state price control of the commodity with the advance
written consent of the three-man Price Decontrol Board
established by the act.
SECRETARY OF AGRICULTURE GIVEN POWERS

There has been much discussion of the special treatment
accorded agricultural commodities in the new act. Many
appear to have the impression that there were in effect no
controls written into the law covering farm commodities
and their products. However, the machinery for regulating
agricultural commodity prices is fairly elaborate and some­
what complicated. Most significant of the changes wrought
by the new law is the augmented authority given to the
Secretary of Agriculture over farm commodity prices.
On the first of each month the Secretary is required to
certify to the Price Administrator the agricultural com­
modities for which he believes that the supply is less than
demand. Each month the certified list is to be corrected.



The law forbids the application of maximum prices on any
agricultural commodity not so certified. In other words, the
dropping of a commodity from the Secretary’s certified list
is sufficient to end existing price ceilings for that item, and
conversely, the certification of a commodity as being in short
supply is necessary before its price can be again put under
a ceiling. But even on items certified as short in supply the
Secretary of Agriculture is empowered to recommend up­
ward adjustment in maximum prices if he finds that existing
ceilings are impeding production, and he is further author­
ized to recommend the price adjustments he finds necessary
to increase production. On all agricultural commodities
which the Secretary finds to be unimportant as business
costs or living costs, he is required to recommend the re­
moval of maximum prices. His determination with regard
to such products must be completed so that he can recom­
mend elimination of ceilings on all such commodities by
December 31, 1946.
Where maximum prices on an agricultural commodity
have been removed and subsequently there develops a situa­
tion of demand in excess of supply, provision is made for
reimposition of ceilings. When the Secretary of Agriculture
determines that the item is in short supply he is permitted,
with the consent of the Price Decontrol Board, to recommend
to the Price Administrator the re-establishment of maximum
prices if he believes such action is necessary to achieve the
purposes of economic stabilization and prevent inflation.
Following upon recommendations by the Secretary either
as to adjustments of maximum prices or the removal of
ceilings on items which he determines to be unimportant
as to business costs or living costs, the Office of Price Ad­
ministration is required to take the recommended steps.
Such action must be taken within ten days after receipt of
the recommendation.
DEFINITIONS RAISE PROBLEMS

For purposes of clarifying the intent of Congress the law
specifically defines certain terms. Two of these are of in­
terest here. The term "agricultural commodity” is defined
as “any agricultural commodity and any food or feed product”
manufactured or processed in whole or substantial part from
any agricultural commodity. Since the passage of the law
two rulings have been adopted further clarifying this defini­
tion. Fish and fish products have been ruled to be agri­
cultural commodities.
Congressional attempts to make the definition of an agri­
cultural commodity precise still left a gap that raised juris­
dictional questions for the Price Administrator, particularly
because of the power given the Secretary of Agriculture over
agricultural commodity prices. This question arose over how
(Continued on Page 5)

Two Postwar Booms Compared
Will 1919-21 Experience be Repeated?
Erosion and relaxation of price controls have drawn current
business and public attention almost magnetically to the
uncontrolled “hoom-and-bust” readjustment of 1919 21 which
followed the close of World War I. Wholesale prices, belying
deflationary forecasts made at and shortly after the Armistice,
soared from 197 per cent of the prewar figures in February
1919, to 272 in May 1920, and then collapsed to 138 in
January 1922 after 20 months of the sharpest price deflation
this country has ever known. Cost-of-living figures followed
the same pattern, as shown on the accompanying chart.
Output, income, employment, and wage rates fell as well,
once the peak was passed. Rents continued to rise; the
housing shortage remained acute until 1924.
Will prices continue to spiral upward? What month of
what year may correspond to May of 1920? Can a downturn
be avoided or at least minimized? These are key questions
confronting bankers and other business leaders in the present
situation. Some observers stress the similarities between the
two postwar periods. They consider 1946 as "1919 over
again,” and prophesy varying degrees of collapse in 1947 or
early 1948 at the latest. Other observers, usually more op­
timistic, stress the differences between 1946 and 1919. Some
of these see another “New Era” of prosperity extending for
at least four or five years and interrupted by nothing more
than mild hesitations.
SIMILARITIES IN THE PATTERNS

Most of the obvious surface elements in the economic
pattern of 1946 are strikingly similar to those of 27 years
ago, but as will be seen, there are many significant differ­
ences. A demobilization and a reconversion, each more than
twice the quantitative magnitude of its earlier counterpart,
have been accomplished more slowly but at least as smoothly
in 1945-46 as in 1918-19, except in a few fields (notably
automobiles) which did not convert fully to war production
in 1917-18. Reconversion was accompanied by crippling
strikes in both cases, even the industries affected being fre­
quently identical (coal, steel, and railroad transportation).
The preponderance of expert” opinion forecast serious
deflation and unemployment after the 1918 Armistice as
well as after V-J Day. The following prognosis, for example,
might have been written by a Government spokesman on the
eve of V-J Day. It actually was written in November 1918
by the economist for a large New York bank:
The belief that there will be a drastic drop in prices is based on
obvious conditions. With a vast volume of labor rapidly being dis­
charged from munition factories the world over to resume the pro­
duction of normal supplies; with steel, copper, coal, shipping and
other essentials released; with 50,000,000 soldiers returning to farms
and factories, there will be an immense increase in the volume of
goods available for civilian consumption. Prices should fall, even
before this actual transformation is carried far, because wholesale
markets commonly forecast impending changes.




The pressure of postponed demand proved more powerful
than these deflationary forces after each war. After minor
downward readjustments, prices and wages rose, thus far at
slower rates in 1946 than in 1919. Some controls were taken
off in each case tyith great haste, and makeshift substitutes
had to be improvised subsequently; the decontrol process
has been considerably slower in 1945-46. Real estate and
securities have followed the same general upward pattern in
prices as in 1919. Consumer demand again appears strong
and tends to be concentrated in luxury lines, although no
single commodity is playing the role of the 1919 “silk shirt”
and although the current buying wave may not have reached
the recklessness indicated by this Boston report to the Federal
Reserve Bulletin for September 1919:
An interesting sidelight on the psychology of the current attitude
of the public toward the high cost of living is furnished by an in­
stance cited of a lot of shoes which were moving slowly being cleaned
up at once when the price was raised $1 ... So much of the call is
for the better grades of shoes that one manufacturer reports parts of
leather left over are being sold to Europe rather than being used in
cheap shoes which do not have a ready market.

As wages and prices pursue each other upward, they are
again accompanied by vociferous complaints of high labor
mobility and low labor productivity. Business Conditions,
referring to the Seventh District specifically, provided in
August 1919 what could pass for the opinion of some
business men today:
A very large part of the answers to our current questionnaire make
particular complaint about the decreased efficiency of workers, not
merely because of shorter hours, but because of the marked letting
down of interest in work and a growing desire to live for amusement,
self indulgence, and luxury. The matter is thus summarized by one
of the great mercantile leaders: "... I see no solution of the problem
except to increase production and decrease consumption. The workers
cannot get the goods they want if they do not make them in suffi­
cient quantities; and when they work for eight hours only, and
sometimes only five days a week, they cannot expect to find all the
goods they want in the retail stores when they go to make their
purchases . . . Interested people should urge upon the workers of
this country the necessity of working longer hours for the next six
months, in order to bring up production for the needs of the people
of this country and of the world. Nothing else will do it.” Another
says: "Many workers spend their time at the movies, and their minds
seem to be on airships and automobiles more than on their day’s
work. This causes lack of production and, following the natural law
of supply and demand, the prices of commodities move upward.”

High mobility of labor was a particular complaint in
agricultural regions because of the lower wages and longer
hours of farm labor. For the Seventh District, Business
Conditions warned in March 1920:
There is considerable apprehension over the farm labor supply in
all parts of the District. Advices are that it is impossible to hold an
unmarried man as a farmhand except on terms offered by city manu­
facturers, namely short hours and high hourly rates.

THIS MONTH’S COVER
Camegie-Illinois South Works at Chicago
0Courtesy of Camegie-Illinois Steel Corporation')

Page 1

Abundance of money and low interest rates were cited in
1919 as in 1946 as possible causes of inflation, though the
rates paid on Liberty Bonds (4Vi and 4U per cent) seem
extravagantly high at the present time. As early as April 1919,
the Federal Reserve Board called attention to the concen­
tration of the World War I debt in the banks and to its
inflationary consequences:
Complete restoration of prices to their eventual normal basis,
whatever that may he, cannot be expected to occur so long as the
war loan securities of all kinds continue to rest in any very consider­
able figure in the hands of the banks. It is therefore strongly to the
interest of the public that as rapidly as possible such war loan paper
should be eliminated from the banks.

The principal individual scarcities, both in 1919 and in
1946, have been sugar, textiles, shoes, automobiles, and
above all, housing. In the housing field, quotations from
1919-20 issues of Business Conditions for the Seventh Dis­
trict would appear current with the references to rent in­
creases replaced by notes on devices for evading rent controls.
The housing situation is looming up as a serious problem in
practically all the industrial centers of the Middle West . . . Con­
ditions in Chicago a year ago were such as to bring into use for
winter housing places built for summer use only . . . Apartments in
Chicago which for many years had been idle and almost ready for
condemnation are again pressed into service, and several families in
many instances are "doubling up.” The so-called middle class of
salaried people . . . also have found the scarcity of dwelling space
a serious factor in their living costs, with home seekers bidding up
rentals against each other to extreme figures. Rentals have advanced
from 20 to 75 per cent and even 100 per cent . . . The kind of
homes which appear to be chiefly in demand are the 4-, 5-, and
6-room apartments. The one and two room kitchenette apartments
are more frequently constructed because of the income they return
to the owner ... At the present rate, authorities estimate from four
to ten years will be required to overcome the housing deficiency.
(December 1919)
The scarcity of labor in some sections of the District is traceable
to a shortage of housing facilities. Plans in Chicago and other manu­
facturing centers to utilize portable houses made for the Government
in war times, promise some relief. CFebruary 1920)
The traditional irresistible demand for more houses and rentable
rooms continues to beat its head against the immutable difficulty of
building on the present levels of wages and structural material costs
. . . Masons, carpenters, plasterers, hod carriers, plumbers, and the
rest of the structural trade demand such compensation, and the cost
of lumber, mill work, cement, sand, stone, wire nails, and plumbing
supplies rules so high that it is an exceptional financier who can see
any profit in building houses for the necessitous. (August 1920)
SIGNIFICANT DIFFERENCES LISTED

Of the significant differences between the economy of
1946 and the economy of 1919, some induce optimism and
some do not. While some of the differences are less immedi­
ately apparent than the similarities, they nevertheless present
an imposing list, including these:
1. There is a considerable difference in degree, although
similarity in pattern, between the World War II and World
War I rise in circulating money (including demand deposits
in commercial banks). The total nearly tripled in World
War II, as against a doubling in World War I. As for Gov­
ernment debt, the World War II rise of 225 billion dollars
is close to ten times that of World War I. Despite these
monetary factors, prices have thus far risen much less rapidly
than during and after the earlier war. The more comprehen­
sive price, rationing, and other controls of World War II
Page 2




channelled a greater proportion of the increased money in­
comes into liquid funds whose volume is now estimated at
over 225 billion dollars, or more than three times their
1919 level.
2. On the other hand, peacetime productive capacity in
1946 also far exceeds the capacity of 1919, both hy reason
of the advances made during the interwar period and because
of the greater volume of convertible war plants built during
World War II. In per capita terms and related to the standard
of living, however, this difference is less significant.
3. The price-wage race of 1919-20 was won by prices, by
a wide margin. Many of the major strikes were labor defeats.
The breaking of the 1919 steel strike in particular may have
postponed mass unionism for 18 years. The major strikes of
1945-46 have all been union victories, partial or complete,
although they have not prevented some decline in real hourly
and weekly earnings from their wartime peaks as prices have
risen and hours declined.
Greater economic power of organized labor makes the
danger of early collapse from prices outrunning purchasing
power less than it was in 1919—although the majority of
workers participate indirectly, if at all, in the gains of the
organized minority. The danger of further inflation via wage
increases leading to eventual disaster is, however, greater
and likewise the danger of delayed production through suc­
cessive waves of strikes.
4. The price increases of 1919-20 were concentrated in
clothing and in rent. Food prices had turned downward at
wholesale, although not at retail, within a year after the
close of hostilities in Europe. In 1945-46, with rents under
relatively strict control, and the world food situation far more
unsatisfactory than in 1919, the price increase has been
concentrated in food and clothing. The higher level of farm
prices for foodstuffs and textile raw materials in 1946, com­
bined with a lower level of rents, is an additional factor
tending to support purchasing power to a greater extent than
the 1919-20 pattern of relative prices, since the proceeds go
to lower income groups. According to ex-President Hoover,
however, the world food crisis should pass its peak during
the autumn of 1946. If this forecast is correct, the relative
price pattern may be expected to shift in 1947 somewhat
closer to that which prevailed in 1920.
5. The United States is far more removed from the direct
influences of foreign business conditions at the present time
than in 1919. The American export balance in 1919 exceeded
4 billion dollars and caused a sharp fall in the foreign
exchange rates of the leading customers as dollars became
scarce abroad. This fall led to a decline in exports early in
1920—perhaps the initial indicator of the general downturn
which came in the late spring and early summer. The cur­
rent demand for American exports is rising, but the export
balance still comprises a noticeably smaller percentage of the
national product. While some foreign exchange rates have
fallen, others have been pegged, and a few have been in­
creased as protection against further American inflation.
On the import side, American accumulation of inven­
tories of foreign products (particularly Japanese silk) sup­
ported great booms abroad. These booms collapsed when
American imports dropped back to the level of current con­

sumption. The foreign crashes which began in Japan led in
turn to the forced devaluation and liquidation of inventories
held by American industry, particularly textiles and sugar,
which featured the summer and fall of 1920. Accumulation
of foreign raw materials by American industry has not yet
taken on the scale of 1919-20, principally because of the
lower productive capacity of the potential suppliers and the
development of synthetics in this country.
Crises in other booming nations heralded the collapse in
America in 1920, whereas at the present time the United
States is unlikely to feel any serious immediate repercussions
from a slump abroad.
6. Doctrinaire opposition to peacetime economic controls
is less stern and uncompromising than it was in 1919.
Such passages as the following (Commercial and Financial
Chronicle, November and December 1919) are still common
in business publications, but carry less conviction:

applied by the Wilson and Harding administrations. Once
prices had started to slip in 1920, the ruling psychology of
“normalcy” involved allowing them to fall—to the prewar
“normal” if necessary. As for the unemployment that ac­
companied the price fall, the United States Employment
Service’s activities in placing returning servicemen had
ceased March 4, 1919, with expiration of the agency’s funds,
and no Federal agency was available for assistance. Although
by no means precluding some downward movement, current
expectations are against tolerance of any repetition of the
1920-21 price fall or the accompanying unemployment, let
alone its acceleration by the “tight money” policy of the
same period. Agricultural prices in particular led the 1920
downturn; the political pressure of farm groups may well
prevent their falling so fast or so far again. Support programs
are established and under way which, if effective, will mini­
mize any second postwar collapse, at least in the short run.
We shall in peace soonest return to our former state if we ad­
7. Inventories still appear low relative to sales, although
minister this temporarily continuing control with the sole view of it is difficult to measure them adequately in their present
getting rid of it as fast as possible, in order that new and larger
unbalanced condition. A slight fall of demand, moreover,
expansion may ensue under the natural laws that exist, always pulling
and always powerful, laws that we will not, cannot abrogate, though
may cause inventories to rise with tremendous rapidity under
we may seemingly defy them and interrupt them, laws ordained in
the constitution of things, made for men’s benefit and working for conditions of capacity production. Inventory controls con­
his good when, and only when, he obeys their divine edicts.
tinue to exert a stabilizing influence, and to the extent of
The first lesson we should learn is that mighty forces are resuming
their effectiveness, constitute a limiting force upon manufac­
of themselves their control of human destiny and in accordance with
turers, wholesalers, and retailers not present in 1919-20.
the beneficence of creation—and that therefore we have nothing
really to fear, if only we live in the light of mutual benefits that lie
Fragmentary inventory statistics for 1919-20 indicate only
in mutual interests.
a moderate rise in physical volume until the latter year.
When and if deflation comes, Governmental supports Deterioration of railroad equipment combined with a suc­
already available will accordingly he stronger than those cession of railroad strikes to delay deliveries after production
of basic raw materials had been resumed. A continued and
intensified box-car shortage during the fall and winter of
1946-47 might well have a similar effect. Acceleration of
COST OF LIVING — WORLD WARS I AND H
deliveries in the winter and spring of 1919-20 rendered
inventories suddenly excessive, particularly in the East,
though widespread complaints of shortages had been reported
as late as April in the Chicago, San Francisco, and Dallas
Federal Reserve Districts. At the same time, reduced avail­
ability of credit and rises in money rates, which had been
delayed in order to assist the Treasury in floating the Victory
Liberty Loan and in stabilizing the bond market, forced
inventory liquidation at price sacrifices, and the slump was
under way. Frequently mentioned as an opening event,
analogous to the stock market crash in October 1929, was
160
WORLD WAR I
a
20 per cent slash of prices “across the board” by a leading
JULY 1914 * 100
New
York department store early in May.
cc 150
150 5
8. There is more general awareness of the dangers in­
herent in the current situation than there was after World
War I. More and better economic guides are also available
for the interested. The memory of 1920-21, moreover, is
still tangible to the middle-aged and elderly population in
all economic classes. This now prompts hesitancies and mis­
WORLD WAR TL A
AUGUST 1939 * 100 )
givings which were confined after World War I to a vague,
uncomprehending "This can’t last,” compounded primarily
of emotional and moralistic factors. This psychological differ­
ence cannot be measured, but its operation can be suspected
as a factor reinforcing remaining controls, promoting buyers’
939 1940
1944
strikes, inciting consumers and others to endure scarcities
SOURCE- UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS
while waiting out the boom, and otherwise retarding and
diminishing the postwar inflationary peak.




Page 3

MYTH OF THE BUYERS’ STRIKE

The mythology of the 1920-22 depression features a
‘‘buyers’ strike,” in which the consuming public suddenly
revolted without benefit of organization, came to work in
barrels and overalls in protest against clothing prices, and
reversed four years of inflationary trends. The facts support
this view only in part. Of the existence of “buyers’ strikes”
in 1919-20 there is no doubt. Their effectiveness is dubious
until prices had already passed their peak, when postpone­
ment of purchases had obvious economic advantages in addi­
tion to resentment against “profiteering.” The 1946 “buyers’
strike” movement, however, has organizational advantages
over its predecessor, manifested particularly in closer rela­
tions with the labor movement.
Mention of sporadic instances of “buyers’ strikes” can be
found in economic periodicals as early as August of 1919.
They were small-sized, local, short-lived, and confined to
a few commodities and stores. Business Conditions for Janu­
ary 1920—five months before the turn—summarized their
effect in the Seventh District:
On one side there are forays against high prices. Society women
engineering film propaganda and quasi-boycotts against this or that
commodity at the prevailing price; or else pledging themselves to
refrain from buying until concessions are made. On the other side
there is the obstinate fact that demand for commodities outruns any
possibility of providing a supply . . . “The wish is father to the
thought,” apparently, when it is asserted that “prices are on the
point of breaking.” Occasionally, it is true, there appear advertise­
ments announcing “big cuts” in prices; and these are heralded as the
beginning of the era of forced liquidation and of declines in the cost
of living. Investigation fails to show that these “leaders” represent
the facts of the general market.

At least one “buyers’ strike” in the spring of 1920 appears
to have backfired, as the following account indicates:
In April 1920, a movement began in the South, which soon spread
to other parts of the country, to induce men to wear overalls. This
movement was intended as a protest against the high price of men’s
clothing, and it was argued that a decrease in the demand for
ordinary suits of clothes would effect a reduction in the price. An
immediate effect was to increase materially the price of denims, of
which material overalls are made.

The "buyers’ strike” movement in its cumulative aspects
certainly added to the severity of the crash and deflation of
the latter half of 1920, and therein lies its importance. There
is no evidence that it caused the downturn or even affected
its timing materially. Statistics on department store sales
indicate a downturn only in July, lagging behind the peak
in the cost of living. This timing is difficult to reconcile with
the “buyers’ strike” myth.
SUMMARIZING THE OUTLOOK

Unless the parallels between 1947 and 1920 prove to be
closer than those between 1946 and 1919, it will be dangerous
to rest estimates of the future course of business exclusively
or even primarily on this historical analogy. A substantial
number of business analysts in private and Government
service nevertheless have become or remain frankly pessi­
mistic as regards business prospects for 1947-48. Their
tentative conclusions pose a dilemma: whether production
rises further or remains at or below its present level, a down­
turn seems in the offing.
Page 4




If wage-price-profit controversies lead to further waves of
successive strikes, the American economy faces a period of
inflation with output definitely below capacity, which would
probably end in an early collapse when the savings of un­
organized consumers are exhausted and their current incomes
prove insufficient to support the going price levels. On the
other hand, early resumption of full production would re­
lease productive capacities which may be too great for the
market to absorb even at pre-June 30 OPA prices, and sub­
stantial deflations will be necessary in most industries.
There is basis for greater optimism, however. The probable
consequences of continued strikes and inflation cannot be
questioned. With regard to possible overproduction defla­
tions, it is possible for price declines to come gradually, with
a few industries at a time encountering apparent overpro­
duction of final products while such key items as housing
and automobiles remain scarce. If the gluts come gradually,
the downward adjustments will be primarily in prices while
productive services shift easily to other employment. Any
general recession could be short and not very severe as
regards total income and employment. If, on the other hand,
substantial segments of the economy are faced with simul­
taneous overproduction, there is little hope of avoiding at
least a temporary over-all setback.
DANGER SIGNALS

Points of difference between 1946 and 1919-20 appear to
dominate the postwar business picture at the present time.
Danger signals lie primarily in reversions to the 1919-20
pattern, reversions which are not inconceivable in the near
future.
In addition to the usual business indicators (e.g. prices,
production, income payments), inventory statistics should
be subject to special attention. In many cases it may be
desirable to supplement published over-all inventory statistics
with estimates on individual items at all manufacturing and
distribution levels, which may lead the official figures in any
dangerous rises.
At least three other barometers of domestic trade will bear
careful scrutiny: (1) indications of financial stringency re­
quiring business firms to demand additional credit from
commercial banks, (2) cancellations of business programs for
plant and equipment expansion as wages and other costs
rise, and (3) further indications of large-scale multiple or­
dering at any level, which may result in epidemic cancella­
tions once heavy deliveries begin to be made.
Other pertinent figures relate to American international
trade, and specifically to the export volume. A sharp rise in
exports which cannot be maintained would be a danger
signal here, since high and rising prices in this country may
force American products out of world markets as soon as the
normal scale of foreign production is resumed. The fouryear British-Canadian wheat contract may be a symptom of
things to come. If this nation becomes acclimated to a high
export volume at high prices before foreign production is
resumed, a fall may bring a severe shock, particularly if it
should coincide with any important decline in demand in
this country.

AGRICULTURAL PRICES
(Continued from Inside Front Cover)

to define precisely what Congress meant by “manufactured
or processed in substantial part from any agricultural com­
modity.” Conceivably questions of jurisdiction could be
raised by misunderstandings as to what proportion of a
product was an agricultural commodity. OPA has, tem­
porarily at least, avoided difficulties on this score by arbi­
trarily ruling that any product containing 20 per cent or
more by volume of an agricultural commodity is “an agri­
cultural commodity” as defined by the law and therefore
subject to the authority of the Secretary of Agriculture.
The other definition of interest relates to the meaning
of the term “in short supply.” In a way this is one of the
crucial concepts in the law, for it is one of the most im­
portant criteria set up by the act as standards to determine
whether a given commodity is permitted or required to be
controlled. The law says simply that “an agricultural com­
modity shall be deemed to be in short supply unless the
supply of such commodity equals or exceeds the require­
ments for such commodity for the current marketing season.”
Without further clarification such restriction is useless as
a guide almost to the point of being a joker. For any given
commodity the requirement for the current marketing season
is not some one absolute quantity. The market will demand
a fairly wide range of quantities at various prices. Since
the price to be paid is the whole matter at issue, the way
in which "requirements” are to be calculated for purposes
of estimating the adequacy of supply would conceivably
leave the matter largely in administrative hands, to be
arbitrarily determined.
In a sense this is a good illustration of the problems in­
creasingly faced by administrators and legislators in attempt­
ing to achieve common policy objectives. There doubtless
will be some commodities for which it will be easy to agree
that they are “in short supply,” but there will be probably
others on which there will be controversy as to eligibility for
price control because of differences of opinion as to what are
the “requirements for the current marketing season.”
The act specifically states that as to these price powers
the Secretary of Agriculture is not subject to the direction
of any other appointive officer or agency of the executive
branch of the Government. He can at any time withdraw
his approval of actions requiring his approval under the
act, and such withdrawal makes rescinding of the action
mandatory on the Price Administrator. No maximum price,
regulation, or order can be applied to an agricultural com­
modity, or a service rendered in connection with an agri­
cultural commodity, that had not been subject to such con­
trol prior to April 1, 1946.
COMMODITIES GIVEN DIFFERENTIAL TREATMENTS

The important agricultural commodities are singled out
by the act for different kinds of treatment. On poultry and
eggs, and leaf tobacco, and their products no ceilings can
be imposed at all unless the Secretary of Agriculture finds
that the price is unreasonably above the June 30, 1946



ceiling plus subsidy paid at that time, that the commodity
is in short supply and price regulation is practicable and
enforceable, and that the public interest will be served by
the regulation. All three conditions must be met.
Ceiling prices were forbidden until August 21 on live­
stock, milk, and food and feed products derived from them;
cottonseed and soybeans and their products; and grains.
The Price Decontrol Board was charged with holding hear­
ings and determining before August 21 which of these
products are to be free from regulation. It may not restore
price control unless prices are unreasonably above June 30
ceilings plus subsidies in effect at that time, unless the
commodity is “in short supply” and the regulation practicable
and enforceable, and unless the public interest will be served
by the regulation.
Thus these products differ from poultry and eggs and leaf
tobacco chiefly in that the latter are exempted from price
control except by subsequent determination of the Secre­
tary, while the former group (livestock, milk, grains, etc.)
are subject to direct determination by the Price Decontrol
Board.
Use of subsidies as a price control device is circumscribed
in the act. The Price Decontrol Board is given power to
determine whether or not and how much of the subsidies
in effect June 30 on agricultural commodities may be rein­
stituted on commodities which it may put under price con­
trol. Those subsidies applying to agricultural commodities
and petroleum are limited to 869 million dollars; such out­
lays must be progressively reduced and must be terminated
on April 1, 1947. Furthermore, expenditures for these sub­
sidies must be limited to 629 millions during the last half
of 1946.
The Price Decontrol Board in its order of August 20
restored price control on livestock and meats, and on soy­
bean and cottonseed products. Beef, pork, and veal were
to be put under ceilings at approximately the June 30 level.
Livestock subsidies in effect on that date were restored, but
are required to be cut in half before January 10. The Board
said it found that the prices of livestock, meat, soybeans,
and cottonseed had risen unreasonably, that they are in
short supply, and that therefore recontrol is required by
the law.
Most grains and milk and milk products were continued
exempt from control, chiefly because the Board found that
prices of these items had not as yet risen unreasonably, but
it warned that milk and milk products prices will be watched
closely and controls restored in the event of unreasonable
price rises.
It is probable that milk and milk products will rise as the
coming season advances. It should not be taken as a certainty
that these items are to continue indefinitely for several months
without recontrol of their prices.
Soybeans, cottonseed, and their products were recontrolled
because not only are they in short supply, but their prices
have, said the Board, “advanced unreasonably.” Most of the
grains were, on the other hand, exempted because with pres­
ent crop prospects it appears that very shortly the grains will
be in plentiful supply.
Page 5

Wisconsin State Finance — I
Seventy Million Dollars Earmarked for Highways, Veterans, and Public Works
The green years that characterize the finances of the
states, beginning with 1940 and continuing through nearly
a full fiscal year after the end of World War II, are reflected
in the financial condition of the Wisconsin State Govern­
ment by a tenfold increase in the cash and investment bal­
ance of the State’s operating funds, a spectacular growth in
tax receipts to these funds, and a relatively stable level of
State expenditures exclusive of aids to local government.
On the revenue side, the apparent financial vigor is occa­
sioned by the enormously enhanced yield from the corpora­
tion income tax and by a less spectacular but substantial in­
crease from personal income taxes despite the discontinuance
of the emergency surtax which was in effect for the income
years 1935-42, inclusive. On the expenditure side, the de­
ferment of maintenance and capital outlays for highways
and state institutions and the lag in price-level salary adjust­
ments and pension aids are the significant considerations.
It may reasonably be anticipated that the resumption of
an accelerated maintenance and replacement program for
public facilities, together with the construction of new high­
ways and public buildings, will at present cost levels make
heavy inroads on the accumulation of liquid assets the State
now holds. Moreover, the perpetuation of present price
levels or a continuation of the upward trend will require
substantial increases in operating disbursements and aver­
age aids to the aged and other pensioners. These factors,
together with the prospective demands for the further ex­
pansion of State activities in veterans’ assistance and re­
habilitation, for example, even if unaggravated by a slump
in the level of general economic activity and the consequent
effects upon tax yields, will require a careful husbanding
of the State’s fiscal resources and favorable cash position.
The ability of the Wisconsin State Government to meet
annual expenditure requirements is measured by the current
productivity of its revenue system and whatever balance
remains from the prior year’s operation. Constitutional limi­
tations on incurring short-term debt, as set forth in Article
VIII, section 6, of the Wisconsin Constitution, are such as
to preclude the use of temporary loans in an amount to
exceed 100 thousand dollars. Section 6 states:

immediate legislative action, either to impose new taxes, to
borrow from trust or earmarked funds, or to effect an off­
setting retrenchment in State expenditures or aids to local
governments.
OPERATING FUNDS

Of all the State funds, the General Fund is the principal
indicator of the State’s financial condition. Into it are de­
posited receipts from personal and corporation income taxes,
public utility taxes, excises, insurance taxes, and death and
gift levies. A large part of these taxes is returned to localities
according to statutory distribution formulae; the remainder
is disbursed for State activities in education, welfare, and
miscellaneous functions of the several departments, boards,
and commissions. The General Fund also receives all Fed­
eral aid (except that portion devoted to highway purposes),
certain interest earnings, institutional receipts, and miscel­
laneous fees. Prior to 1945, when the legislature created the
State Highway Fund, highway-user taxes were paid into
the General Fund. Before 1931 the various school income
funds were maintained as separate accounts; subsequently,
state-supported institutions of higher learning, educational
aids to localities, and other activities in the field of education
have been financed through the General Fund. Other sig­
nificant operating funds—World War I bonus funds, Con­
servation Fund, Postwar Rehabilitation Fund, and Postwar
Construction and Improvement Fund—are financed largely
by special, earmarked taxes or by General Fund transfers.
The record of State financial operations, as reflected by
the funds discussed above, is shown in the accompanying
chart and table for the period 1920-46. These data indicate
that in most of the years covered, a close relationship between
annual expenditures and revenues was maintained. Sub­
stantial Federal aid for unemployment relief bolstered State
finances in the early depression years of the 1930’s, but a
comparatively large operating balance was the measure of
financial security on which the State relied during the decade
of the 1920’s. In these years the balance at the end of the
fiscal year was between 25 and 40 per cent of annual re­
ceipts or disbursements. Throughout the 1930’s operating
For the purpose of defraying extraordinary expenditures the state
may contract public debts (but such debts shall never in the aggre­ balances were at much lower levels, averaging approximately
gate exceed $100,000). Every such debt shall be authorized by law,
15 per cent of receipts and dropping as low as 8 per cent in
for some purpose or purposes to be distinctly specified therein and
two
years. Since 1940 the balance on hand has increased
the vote of a majority of all the members elected to each house, to
be taken by yeas and nays, shall be necessary to the passage of such
steadily; it is now at a record level of 100 million dollars, or
law; and every such law shall provide for levying an annual tax
over 60 per cent of 1946 receipts.
sufficient to pay the annual interest of such debt and the principal
The fiscal year-end balances do not fully portray signifi­
within five years from the passage of such law and shall specifically
appropriate the proceeds of such taxes to the payment of such prin­ cant fluctuations in the daily cash position of the State’s
cipal and interest and the appropriation shall not be repealed nor the
funds. Since their income is not a regular day-to-day flow
taxes be postponed or diminished, until the principal and interest of
such debt shall have been wholly paid.
but is concentrated around annual, quarterly, or monthly
A precipitous decline in State tax revenues, for example, tax-due dates, and since many disbursements, particularly
with a nominal cash balance on hand, would thus require the payments to local units of shared taxes or aids, occur in
Page 6




certain specified periods, the balance varies widely through­
out the year. Some indication of the importance of these
fluctuations may be obtained from the supplementary tabu­
lation on quarterly balances for selected State operating
funds in the accompanying table. It should be noted that
there is more stability in the quarterly balances during the
1930 s and 1940’s than in the 1920’s when a greater part of
the revenues depended upon single annual tax payments.
Until 1945, when the legislature segregated highway
funds from the General Fund, Wisconsin adhered rather
closely in the management of State funds to the policy of
non-segregation. Tax receipts, Federal aid, and the earnings
of State institutions and agencies, with minor exceptions,
were deposited in the State’s General Fund. Disbursements
for not only the regular activities of the State Government
but also the aid and tax sharing of local units were met by
withdrawals from that fund. There were numerous minor
exceptions to this rule (see footnote 1 to table for a list of
such funds), but segregation was largely confined to the
World War I bonus funds, the Conservation Fund, the
Unemployment Compensation Trust Fund, and various
trust funds.
World War I bonus funds consisted of the Educational
Bonus Fund supported by surtaxes on net incomes for 1918
to 1922, the Service Recognition Fund which was credited
with a one mill levy on general property, and a surtax on
net incomes of 1918. In 1923, balances in these funds were
transferred to the Soldiers’ Rehabilitation Fund and were
made available for medical care to veterans with service-

connected disabilities and for educational assistance to vet­
erans and children of veterans who were killed in action
or died as a result of injuries received during World War I.
The two major sources of revenue of the Conservation
Fund are two-tenths of one mill levy on general property
and all monies accruing from the various permits, license
fees, and enforcement of the conservation laws. The Com­
mission is required by law to spend the hunting and fishing
license fees for the administration of the fish and game laws.
Other disbursements are for supervision of forestry, park
police force, maintenance of fish hatcheries, forest crop aid
to counties, and other activities related to conservation.
POSTWAR FUNDS

Following is a summary in millions of dollars of the cash
and investment balances of the operating funds at the close
of fiscal year 1946:
General purposes ........................................
28.0
Other operating:
Postwar Rehabilitation .......................... 7.2
Postwar Construction and Improvement. 23.7
All other operating (Unemployment Ad­
ministration, Soldiers’ Rehabilitation,
State Office Building, and Reforesta­
tion funds) .......................................... 1.1
Total other operating.....................
32.0
Highway......................................................
39 4
Conservation................................................
2.7
Total .....................................
“102.1

RECEIPTS, DISBURSEMENTS, AND BALANCES
STATE OF WISCONSIN OPERATING FUNDS
FISCAL YEARS ENDING JUNE 30, 1920-46
MILLIONS

of

dollars

MILLIONS

160----------------------RECEIPTS IN EXCESS OF DISBURSEMENTS
(SURPLUS)

.....I
TOTAL

RECEIPTS

TOTAL

DISBURSEMENTS

OF

DOLLARS

160

DISBURSEMENTS FROM RECEIPTS
DISBURSEMENTS IN EXCESS OF RECEIPTS
(DEFICIT)

BALANCES
END OF FISCAL YEAR

1940

Note

composition of the 102 million dollar balance in 1946




shown above; all except 28 million dollars is earmarked for specific purposes.

Page 7

purpose of the expenditure or the character of revenues for
a state like Wisconsin, lies in the effect upon the size of the
State cash and investment balance. Without provision for
temporary loans or interfund borrowing, the more extensive
the use of segregation, the larger is the aggregate balance re­
quired for operations if the State is to meet all of its obliga­
tions promptly and in full. This consequence was no doubt
felt to be of slight importance relative to the desire to insure
the use of highway-user taxes for maintenance and con­
struction of highway and road facilities. The principle of
fixing the level of expenditure for streets and highways by
reference to the productivity of the taxes levied on highway
users is widely endorsed as a general long-run policy, but
it does not necessarily follow that the objective can only be
attained by the segregation of highway revenues from other
State funds. It can also be accomplished by planning the
State’s long-range program of expenditure with a view to
attaining this equivalence. With consideration to the varia­
tions in yield of different elements in the State tax system,
the revenues from non-highway sources can be made to meet
the program of non-highway expenditure without continual
withdrawals from highway earnings. The record in Wis­
consin indicates that there have been substantial diversions
to general expenditures of highway revenue; other needs
were regarded as having a higher priority at the time such
diversions took place.
The actual amount of diversion may be estimated as fol­
lows: on July 1, 1931, the balance of funds to the credit of
the Highway Commission was 17.9 million dollars. This
balance was reduced by 8.5 million dollars in the fiscal years
1932 and 1933, i.e., in those two years expenditures for high­
ways exceeded revenue from the motor vehicle licenses, the
fuel tax, Federal aid, and miscellaneous earnings. In the
years 1934-43, the balance to the highway account increased
from 1 to 6 million dollars annually, i.e., in this period high­
way revenues consistently exceeded highway expenditure, in
the aggregate by 41.0 million dollars. The trend reversed
in the fiscal years 1944 and 1945, and the balance was reduced
by 8.6 million dollars. With the creation of the Highway
Fund, 17.8 million dollars was transferred to it and 23.9
million dollars to the General Fund. Taking into account the
lapsing of 2.0 million dollars to the General Fund in 1933-35,
the net diversion of highway revenue during the 14-year
period was 8.0 million dollars. This computation ignores the
balance at the opening of the period (July 1, 1931). If the
same method is extended back through the 1920’s and prop­
erty taxes for highways are deducted, the additional diversion
from July 1, 1917, is 6.1 million dollars.
The equivalence of highway-user taxes and highway ex­
penditures, if it is to be obtained, can be most easily effected
not for each and every year but over a period of several
years, depending upon the character of economic conditions
and the State’s tax system. All during the war years, for
example, there were three unavoidable consequences of
military requirements and priorities: the substantial post­
ponement of outlays for highways, the sharp reduction in
highway-user taxes, and the larger maintenance require­
FUND SEGREGATION
ments. The equivalence of expenditure and revenue in any
One consequence of fund segregation, according to the single year was impracticable.

It will be noted that of the total balance shown above,
70 per cent is in the three postwar funds reserved for delayed
construction and improvement of State highways and public
buildings and for assistance to returning veterans; the re­
mainder consists of working balances in funds used for
normal State purposes.
Revenues earmarked for the Highway Fund are receipts
from motor fuel taxes, motor vehicle license and registration
fees, all other taxes or fees on motor vehicles or their opera­
tors, all Federal aid designated for highway purposes, any
balance in the State Trunk Highway Fund (a fund to be
used exclusively for the retirement of county highway bonds
issued and for new trunk highway construction), and any
other receipts for highway purposes. The Highway Com­
mission can authorize expenditures from the fund not in
excess of 36 million dollars in one year. During the fiscal
year just ended 30.5 million dollars was spent for highway
purposes. This is 6 million dollars more than was spent for
highways in 1944 and 2 million dollars more than was spent
in 1943, but is below the 34.0 million dollar average high­
way expenditure during 1937-42.
The Postwar Construction and Improvement Fund is to
be used for additions to and improvements of State institu­
tions. The total appropriation of 24.2 million dollars to this
fund has been allocated to specific projects. This money will
be put into use upon consent of the Governor, who may
secure the advice of the Executive Advisory Committee, fol­
lowing a written statement from the department head con­
cerned that materials and labor are available. Approximately
12.0 millions, or 50 per cent of the total, has been designated
for construction and equipment at the University of Wiscon­
sin, the general hospital in connection with the university,
the teachers’ colleges, and Stout Institute. Of the remaining
half, 7.7 millions is for State hospitals and training schools,
.5 million dollars is for Board of Health use, and 4.0 million
dollars for other needed improvements in the State institu­
tions. Expenditures from this fund to date have been approxi­
mately .5 million dollars, largely for plans and site acquisi­
tions.
The Postwar Rehabilitation Fund is to defray the cost of
the State’s veteran program and is administered by the newly
created Office of Veteran Affairs. So far, the office is charged
with coordinating the activities of the several State agencies
concerned with veteran affairs, assisting veterans having
claims against the United States, providing treatment for
any service-connected disabilities, extending any emergency
aids, and granting loans not to exceed 750 dollars at not
more than 2 per cent interest per annum for rehabilitation,
education, or aid in purchase of a business. It is estimated
from the Monthly Report of the State Treasurer that ap­
proximately 1.2 million dollars has been expended on vet­
erans’ rehabilitation during fiscal years 1945 and 1946. Since
no breakdown is available of the type of expenditure made,
it cannot be ascertained what portion of the amount spent
will be returned in principal of loans during future years.

Page 8




State government and government in general has assumed
tremendously increased responsibilities in the past two and
a half decades. These responsibilities involve commitments
to thousands of the State’s citizens for public aids, business
management of one of the country’s largest enterprises—the
furnishing of highway transportation facilities-and the tra­
ditional activities of government in the fields of education
and public safety. Careful planning and awareness of the
immediate and eventual cost of governmental services in
relationship to the tax and other revenues available to pay
for them can, at best, in view of economic uncertainties,
supply only an approximate annual balancing of revenues

and expenditures. The problems and difficulties of the ex­
ecutive in planning and executing the State budget are
seriously aggravated by undue segregation when the alter­
natives of short-term borrowing are denied. The net effect
of the segregation of highway funds may be both larger cash
balances than otherwise necessary and, in times of financial
stress, additional "temporary” taxes to finance threatened de­
ficiencies in the General Fund. The corporation income tax,
presently a substantial contributor to that fund, fluctuates
widely with changes in economic conditions. Pooling these
stable highway taxes with this revenue will avert some
exposure to temporary financial strain.

WISCONSIN OPERATING FUNDS
RECEIPTS, DISBURSEMENTS, AND BALANCES
FISCAL YEARS 1920-46
(In millions of dollars)
Year
Ending
June 30

Total

1920
1921
1922
1923
1924

45.5
35.8
38.8
35.8
40.1

1925
1926
1927
1928
1929

40.8
44.3
50.3
52.6
60.7

1930
1931
1932
1933
1934

71.2
74.9
75.1
71.2
87.4

1935
1936
1937
1938
1939

115.2
95.4
101.1
110.0
104.6

1940
1941
1942
1943
1944

112.7
121.4
138.8
140.6
149.7

1945;
1946

152.2
156.0

All Operating Funds
Receipts2 *
Disbursements2
State
Aid to
Earn­
Federal
Taxes8
Total Expendi- Localiings4 *
Aid
tures
ties*
38.0
6.1
1.4
38.6
30.6
8.0
24.6
7.8
3.4
35.6
26.3
9.3
26.3
7.5
5.0
38.5
28.6
9.9
25.5
7.4
2.9
35.6
24.5
11.1
29.1
7.9
3.1
37.4
25.1
12.3
29.8
8.9
2.1
39.4
26.7
12.7
33.5
8.2
2.6
44.5
29.5
15.0
37.1
9.8
3.4
51.2
32.9
18.3
37.6
9.8
5.2
54.3
36.4
17.9
45.1
10.3
5.3
61.5
36.1
25.4
52.9
10.8
7.5
65.7
38.3
27.4
53.3
11.5
10.1
73.1
47.4
25.7
54.5
11.3
9.3
86.1
51.8
34.3
53.2
9.6
8.4
78.0
44.5
33.5
55.2
9.4
22.8
78.9
30.2
48.7
58.4
10.6
46.2
112.4
31.5
80.9
67.1
10.4
17.9
96.1
37.2
58.9
76.6
12.4
12.1
100.0
45.5
54.5
79.5
13.9
16.6
109.7
51.3
58.4
71.8
17.4
15.4
110.3
52.4
57.9
80.0
16.6
16.1
114.4
47.8
66.6
89.4
16.0
16.0
111.2
42.8
68.4
103.2
16.8
18.8
124.7
50.7
74.0
105.9
16.5
18.2
128.0
46.9
81.1
116.0
17.0
16.7
127.5
45.6
81.9
117.1
21.1
14.0
134.2
48.4
85.8
120.0
22.8
13.2
140.1
*
*

'Consists of the General Fund, several school funds maintained as sepa­
rate accounts through 1931, the Conservation Fund, the postwar and
state highway funds, and minor operating funds. Specifically the fol1i0^l.n8o,aireTnClxTded: ,t^euGef1?fal Fund' the University Fund Income
(1920-31), the Normal School Fund Income (1920-31), the Agricultural
College Fund Income (1920-31), the Public School Fund Income (1929-301
the School Fund Income, Reforestation Fund, Drainage Fund the Serv-i
ice Recognition Fund (1920-23), Educational Bonus Fund (1920-23)
Soldiers' Rehabilitation Fund (1924-46), the State Depository Fund
(1926-36), Security Regulation Fund (1920-31), Milk Control Fund
(1936-37), State Office Building Fund (1940-46), Unemployment Ad­
ministration Fund (1935-46), Postwar Rehabilitation Fund'(1944-46)
Postwar Construction and Improvement Fund (1944-46), the Conserva­
tion Fund (1925-46), the State Trunk Highway Fund (1944), and the
State Highway Fund (1945-46).
-Inter-operating fund transfers and investment operations are eliminated
includes state taxes on motor fuel, motor vehicles, malt beverage, and
tobacco; state and local shares of state-collected public utility, insurance
liquor, and income taxes; state share only of locally-collected property’
income (prior to 1933), inheritance, and miscellaneous taxes. Excludes
unemployment compensation payroll taxes, teachers’ insurance and
retirement surtax on net income sufficient to meet actuarial require­
ments of the trust fund or an amount from general revenues to satisfy




Selected Operating Funds8
Quarterly Balances

Balance
End of
Year6

March
31

June
30

Sept.
30

Dec.
31

13.8
14.0
14.3
14.5
17.2

7.2
9.1
9.4
10.0
10.0

10.0
11.8
12.2
12.6
15.4

5.6
8.6
10.0
9.3
12.1

3.8
2.7
5.9
5.8
8.5

18.6
18.4
17.5
15.8
15.0

13.1
9.4
8.3
13.7
14.4

16.8
16.8
16.4
15.0
14.1

13.6
14.2
12.2
14.7
13.2

10.8
9.9
10.1
11.4
12.3

20.5
22.3
11.3
4.5
13.0

16.6
17.4
16.5
6.3
6.2

19.6
21.5
10.5
3.8
12.3

18.4
24.6
8.7
7.7
10.7

16.3
24.3
7.5
8.3
11.0

15.8
15.1
16.2
16.5
10.8

10.0
12.4
14.3
15.2
11.1

15.2
14.7
15.8
16.0
10.3

16.8
14.3
14.0
14.1
5.4

13.4
12.5
13.3
7.3
5.3

9.1
19.3
33.4
46.0
68.2

9.3
13.2
30.7
45.4
72.0

8.7
19.0
33.0
45.4
67.6

9.0
19.4
31.4
43.2
67.7

9.4
19.8
30.7
53.7
69.4

86.2
102.1

77.5
98.1

85.9
101.6

85.8

88.6

such requirements ; also excludes amount sufficient to meet interest re­
quirements of school fund and normal school fund. Tax receipts have
been reduced by the amount of tax refunds.
'Includes interest earnings, tuition receipts, reimbursements for oper­
ation of charitable and penal institutions (except amounts received for
intercounty payments), and miscellaneous license fees.
■Includes the local units’ share of state-collected taxes (see footnote 3
above) and grants made for specific purposes, principally education,
highways, relief, and welfare.
^Includes investments in the General Fund (1919-20, 1943-46) the Sol­
diers Rehabilitation Fund (1926-46), the State Depository Fund (1929c-1 ’
P?s£war Construction and Improvement Fund (1944-46) the
StAte*iJrT?k Highway Fund (1944), the State Highway Fund (1945-46)
and the Unemployment Administration Fund (1944-46).
■Figures for 1945 and 1946 have been estimated from the Monthly Report
of the State Treasurer and are partially incomplete
™nC^d™rallT°Ferating funds excePt the State Office Building Fund and
World War I bonus funds.
*Not available.
SOURCES: State of Wisconsin, Report of the State Treasurer• Bien­
nial Report of the Secretary of State of the State of Wisconsin; Wis­
consin Budget Bureau.




SEVENTH FEDERAL

IOWA

RESERVE DISTRICT