View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
October 1971

Contents
Checking account costs—
Trends and composition
among small banks, 1966-70
Farmers7off-farm incomes
exceed farm earnings

2

12

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Checking account costs—
Trends and composition among small banks, 1966-70
If you were a banker you would know:
• Demand deposits subject to transfer by
check (checking accounts) are the unique
feature of the commercial banking business.
• Checking accounts play the key role in
the nation’s payments mechanism—they are
used in about 90 percent of all transactions
by dollar volume.
• Approximately half of all personnel at
banks with deposits under $50 million are
employed in processing checking accounts.
• Checking account costs have a decisive
influence on the profitability of any bank.
Obviously, checking account costs are a
matter of prime concern to all bankers. This
article provides a brief account of recent
trends in these costs and traces their move­
ment and composition over the period 196670. An attempt is made in the article to isolate
some of the factors that have a systematic
influence on checking account costs. It is
hoped that the information contained herein
will be of value to Seventh District bankers
in assessing their own checking account costs
and, where necessary, bringing them under
better control.

The d ata

Most of the data in this article are derived
from the Functional Cost Analysis Program
initiated by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago in 1965. Eighty-three Seventh Dis­
trict member banks with average deposits
under $50 million participated in the pro­
gram continuously from 1966 to 1970. The
descriptions of recent trends in the demand
deposit function in the analysis that follows
are based on aggregates of these banks. Fig­
ures relating only to 1970 are based on re­
ports of 133 banks with deposits under $50
million participating in the program last year.
The Functional Cost Analysis (FCA) Pro­
gram is a bank-oriented, standardized cost
accounting system designed primarily for
small banks lacking the personnel and re­
sources to develop their own systems. The
basic approach of the FCA is to subdivide
the bank for accounting purposes into a
number of distinct “functions” and then to
determine the level and composition of the
costs and revenues associated with each func­
tion. An important byproduct of the FCA
Program is a wealth of detailed data on each
of the important bank functions.

Trends in checking account costs

2

Not surprisingly, costs relating to checking
accounts have increased steadily during the
past five years. This has been almost entirely
a matter of inflation, with each of the inputs
into the demand deposit function—labor,
capital, and materials—increasing sharply in




price. Between 1966 and 1970, the 83 FCA
banks’average annual cost of maintaining and
servicing a checking account increased 35
percent, rising from $32.23 to $43.48. This
increase was large even in relation to increases
in costs and prices in most other areas of the

Business Conditions, October 1971

Although costs per checking
account rose steadily from
1966 to 1970 for FCA banks . . .
dollars per account

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

economy. It has occasioned deliberate efforts
by bank managements to achieve greater
efficiency in order to offset continued in­
creases in the cost of funds and thereby to
maintain bank profits. These efforts fre-

checking account costs fell
relative to total bank costs . . .
percent of total cost




quently take the form of introducing more
capital-intensive technology.
For reasons largely unrelated to the de­
mand deposit function itself, checking ac­
count costs for the 83 smaller district FCA
banks declined relative to other bank operat­
ing costs between 1966 and 1970. For the
most part, this was a consequence of the de­
clining relative importance of demand de­
posits as a source of bank funds and the
recent emergence of interest on time deposits
as the largest single expense of commercial
banks. In 1966, time deposits at the typical
district member bank exceeded total demand
deposits for the first time in 30 years. The
trend has continued, and in 1970 time de­
posits constituted 57 percent of the total de­
posits of the typical district member bank. As
a proportion of the total available funds of the
83 FCA banks under discussion here, de­
posits in checking accounts decreased from
42 percent in 1966 to 37 percent in 1970.
Contributing to these trends has been the
sharp rise in interest rates paid on time and
savings deposits in recent years. The more
attractive return to depositors prompted a

as checking accounts declined
as a proportion of total
available bank funds
percent of available funds
5 0 f

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

rapid growth of time deposits and
at the same time gave depositors
an incentive to economize on de­
mand deposits. The increase in the
proportion of time to total de­
posits and the sharp rise in the
unit price of time deposits re­
sulted in an increase in the pro­
portion of interest on time de­
posits to total expenses from 42
percent in 1966 to 48 percent in
1970 at the 83 FCA banks. This
alone was almost sufficient to ac­
count for the decline in the rela­
tive importance of checking ac­
count costs.

Revolutionary changes in the
technology of processing
checking account activity . . .
percent of F C A

1966

banks using indicated technology

1970

computer

The com position of costs

4

Bank costs can be classified in
a number of ways to make them
led to capital costs rising
more meaningful for purposes of
faster than labor costs
analysis. One of the more useful
between 1966 and 1970
distinctions that can be made is
labor costs as a percent of
capital costs as a percent of
that between direct and indirect
total direct costs
total direct costs
costs. Direct costs are those that
24
0 depositu size
. 0 20 40 60 80
are clearly assignable to a given
~I
I
I------- T
I
(million dollars)
banking function and usually vary
0
1
0
1970
in a fairly systematic manner with
the volume of activity in that func­
I0-20
tion. Indirect costs are incurred
for services essential to the opera­
20-30
tion of each and every function.
However, causal responsibility for
30-40
them is imbedded in the overall
operation of the bank, and can be
40-50
assigned only arbitrarily to any
particular function. The impor|—
all banks
tance of the distinction between
direct and indirect costs is that, as
a general rule, only direct costs
related to the demand deposit function, there­
are affected to any appreciable degree by
changes in the volume of activity or organiza­
fore, are the costs most germane to decisions
tion of any single function. The direct costs
affecting that function only. The significance




Business Conditions, October 1971

of any error in classifying particular costs as
direct or indirect is minimized by the fact
that indirect costs amounted to only about
20 percent of the total costs of the FCA
banks.
Direct costs consist primarily of labor and
material costs and those capital costs attrib­
utable to equipment and furniture used speci­
fically by the function in question. Like most
other service industries, banking has tradi­
tionally been labor-intensive in its tech­
nology. Of all the banking functions, how­
ever, the demand deposit function is the most
capital-intensive. While capital costs consti­
tute only 3 to 10 percent of the total costs
associated with other bank functions, they
have accounted for more than 15 percent of
the costs of the demand deposit function at
FCA banks in recent years.
Checking accounts alone—which in recent
years have accounted for between 93 and 95
percent of total demand deposits—grew
steadily more capital-intensive during the
period between 1966 and 1970. In 1966, the
83 FCA banks’ ratio of capital costs to total
direct costs of processing checking accounts
was 16 percent; by 1970 it had risen to 22
percent. Most of the change occurred in
banks with less than $30 million in deposits,
perhaps reflecting the lagged adoption by
smaller banks of technology in use at larger
banks for many years. This substitution of
capital was at the expense of both labor and
materials. Although each category of costs
grew in absolute terms, labor costs declined
from 69 to 65 percent find materials costs
from 15 percent to 13 percent of total costs.
Only in the case of banks with less than $10
million in deposits did capital costs increase
entirely at the expense of labor costs.
This marked increase in the capital in­
tensity of checking account processing was
associated with a virtual revolution in the



technology of the demand deposit function.
In the 1966-70 period, the percentage of the
83 FCA banks using computers rather than
conventional or electronic bookkeeping ma­
chines (“tronics” ) rose from 37 percent to
89 percent. Concurrently, a considerable
number of the banks already using the serv­
ices of off-premise computers, usually on a
time-sharing basis, leased or purchased com­
puters for on-premise use.
Occupancy costs—rent, taxes, and depre­
ciation and maintenance on the bank’s prem­
ises—were the largest component of the 83
FCA banks’ indirect costs, accounting for
nearly half the total in 1970. Advertising
costs, only a small portion of which are spe­
cific to individual banking functions, ac­
counted for roughly 18 percent. The re­
mainder consisted of: legal, audit, and
directors’ fees; insurance; and professional
association membership dues. Although in­
direct costs allocated to checking accounts
also increased over the five-year period, they
increased less rapidly than direct costs.
R e ve n u e s

The only important revenues directly asso­
ciated with the demand deposit function are
service charges and penalty charges on check­
ing accounts—often referred to together as
“activity income.” Although pricing practices
vary greatly, both between banks and be­
tween different categories of accounts within
banks, the common practice is to tie service
charges to account activity. Thus, there may
be a certain charge for each check written or
each deposit made. Some banks also levy a
small monthly charge that is independent of
activity and which is designed to cover the
bookkeeping and other costs of maintaining
the account.
While both activity income and costs per
checking account increased at smaller FCA

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

6

banks between 1966 and 1970, costs in­
creased considerably faster, with the result
that service charges covered a smaller pro­
portion of costs at the end of the period. The
$ 11.25 increase in costs per checking account
was more than ten times as large as the $1.03
increase in revenues. Thus, in 1970 the 83
FCA banks’ explicit revenues from checking
accounts covered only 26 percent of the cost
of maintaining them, as opposed to 32 per­
cent in 1966.
All of this adds up to what, at first glance,
appears to be irrational and damaging pric­
ing. Actually, it is the inevitable result of a
competitive pursuit of profit subject to reg­
ulatory constraints. Since 1933, banks have
been prohibited from paying interest on de­
mand deposits— in essence, and contrary to
the facts of the marketplace, Congress de­
clared such deposits to be a “free good.” As
long as banks have profitable outlets for
funds, they would find it remunerative to pay
a positive price for demand deposits rather
than forego them. They find it necessary be­
cause most deposit customers can employ
their funds in alternative ways that promise
higher returns. Consequently, banks have
taken to competing for demand deposits by
a variety of means that do not constitute the
“payment of interest” in a narrow legal sense.
The permissible alternatives have included
the provision of various services free to de­
positors and the reduction to minimal levels
of service charges on checking accounts.
Many banks, including some of the FCA
banks, have eliminated service charges on
accounts maintaining a specified minimum
monthly balance. Others have gone to the
limit permitted by law and completely elim­
inated charges on all regular checking ac­
counts, without regard for balances or
activity. Whatever the legal classification of
this absorption of the costs of account activity




Although costs per dollar of
checking accounts rose . . .
cents per dollar

3.0

total costs
net costs

1966

(total costs less activity income)

1967

1968

1969

1970

net earnings also increased
between 1966 and 1970
cents per dollar

* Portfolio income eq u als total revenue from the invest­
ment of checking account funds less the costs of lending
and investing these funds.
* *N e t earnings before taxes equ als portfolio income
from checking account funds less the net cost—total costs
less activity income—of processing checking accounts.

Business Conditions, October 1971

by banks, it is clear that in the economic
sense, it is tantamount to the payment of
interest.
What the waiver of service charges on
some classes of accounts indicates is that the
market rate of interest on demand deposits—
the rate that would prevail in the absence of
regulation—now exceeds by a considerable
margin the service charges that would prevail
under the same conditions. Presumably, these
charges would cover the full costs of servicing
the accounts. This interest rate, in turn, is
linked by market forces of supply and de­
mand to the prevailing rates on both bank
loans and other types of credit. The higher
the interest rates on loans, open market credit
instruments, and competing deposit-type
liabilities—including commercial bank time
deposits—the smaller the proportion of
checking account costs that explicit service
charges can be expected to cover. If one looks
at the annual net cost of available funds ac­
quired through deposits in checking accounts
—total costs less all activity income—per
dollar of such funds, it is clear that it in­

creased between 1966 and 1970 at the 83
small Seventh District FCA banks. In view of
the pronounced increase in market interest
rates over this period, this is what would be
expected.
In order to determine the profitability of
checking accounts in any meaningful sense,
it is, of course, necessary to calculate the
bank’s earnings net of all expenses, including
money costs on investments or loans made
possible by the funds derived from these ac­
counts. Judged by this criterion, and taking
the existing prohibition of interest on demand
deposits as given, the present structure of
service charges appears much more reason­
able than it does when only explicit activity
income is taken into account. Bankers have
been wont to complain that they are “giving
away” their services. This is simply not true.
Indeed, because changes in deposit rates tend
to lag behind changes in lending rates and be­
cause bank lending is relatively short-term,
the rate of earnings on funds derived from
checking accounts actually increased over the
past five years.

Interbank differences
The preceding discussion of trends for the
83 smaller FCA banks as a group did little
more than hint at the differences that exist in
the level and nature of checking account costs
among these banks. These differences, which
are extremely large, are partly under the con­
trol of bank managements and partly beyond
their control. An understanding of why they
exist is a prerequisite to any effective program
for reducing costs.
Probably the figure of most interest to the
banker viewing his checking account costs is
the cost of obtaining and retaining a dollar
of checking accounts. The cost per account



is a subsidiary consideration which, though
obviously related, is one step removed from
a bank’s cost of funds as such. Data for 133
FCA banks for 1970 reveal an extremely
broad range of costs per dollar of demand
deposits.
B an k size a n d costs

The data also indicate the existence of a
pronounced inverse relationship between
costs per dollar of checking accounts and de­
posit size of bank. This might be taken as
evidence that larger banks are somewhat
more efficient in processing checking ac-

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

counts. To be sure, it is a presumption of long­
standing that there are economies of scale in
banking. However, the data as presented re­
flect more than the inherent efficiencies of
larger size. They also reflect such factors as
average size of account, composition of
deposit accounts between regular and special
checking accounts, and—perhaps most im­
portant of all—the amount of activity per
account.
Size of account is a crucial factor because
most costs associated with the administration
of a checking account are independent of the
account balance. Hence, the larger the aver­
age size of account held by a bank, the lower
its costs per dollar of checking accounts will
appear to be. But the fact that a bank deals
with large customers keeping large deposit
balances is no indication, in and of itself, of
the bank’s efficiency. The widely acknowl­
edged fact that large customers tend to pa-

Interbank variation in costs per
dollar of checking accounts . . .
number of banks

40r

8

1.0- 1.5- 2.0- 2.5* 3.0- 35- 4.0- 4.5- 5.0- 5.51.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 5.5 6.0
cost

per

dollar of




checking

accounts in cents

appeared to be closely related
to deposit size of bank in 1970
cents per dollar

0-10

10-20

20-30

30-40

40 -5 0

deposit size (million dollars)

tronize large banks makes somewhat spurious
the observed relationship between costs per
dollar of deposits and size of bank.
Another factor often cited as having an
important influence on checking account
costs is the mix of accounts between regular
and special checking accounts. Special check­
ing accounts are typically low average bal­
ance, low activity accounts that are offered
to individuals unable to qualify for regular
checking accounts. They normally carry a
fairly substantial charge for each check writ­
ten but either no monthly maintenance charge
or a small one, depending on the minimum
balance in the acount. That regular checking
accounts normally have somewhat higher per
account costs than special checking accounts
is probably due more to their greater average
level of activity than to any difference be­
tween the two types of accounts in the cost
of processing a given amount of activity. In
1970, the average cost per account of regu­
lar checking accounts for FCA banks was

Business Conditions, October 1971

$47; for special checking accounts it was
only $25.
For the 133 FCA banks under considera­
tion here, average dollar balance per checking
account increased more rapidly with size of
bank than did activity per account. This was
true despite the fact that the larger banks had
a larger proportion of special checking ac­
counts, as measured by either dollar volume
or number of accounts. The upshot is that,
although certain systematic relationships be­
tween costs, size of account, composition of
accounts, and activity can readily be ob­
served, the relationships so far considered do
not provide a firm basis for judgments regard­
ing the relative efficiency of banks of different
size in processing checking accounts.
M easu rin g efficien cy

It is only a small step from recognition of
this problem to the conclusion that the proper
measure of efficiency in administering check­
ing accounts is one that relates checking ac­
count costs to the total activity generated by
such accounts. In a very real sense, this
activity—the processing of home debits, de­
posits, and transit checks and the book­
keeping expenses associated with preparing
monthly statements—can be considered the
“output” produced by the checking account
function of the bank. It would, therefore, ap­
pear entirely reasonable to use costs per unit
of activity as a measure of efficiency. A
problem that must be overcome before this
is done, however, is that activity is not a
homogeneous category. For example, it re­
quires more separate operations to process a
home debit or deposit than a transit check,
and still more for a monthly statement.
In an unregulated and fully competitive
banking system, banks would impose a
charge per unit of each activity that would
reflect customers’ evaluations of the utility of



the activity. These charges could then be used
to weight the units of various types of activity
to obtain an overall dollars-and-cents mea­
sure of the “output” of the checking account
function. Lacking an explicit market valua­
tion of the various types of activity, weights
reflecting the relative handling costs per item
relative to the cost of handling a transit check
have been used. These weightings, which
have been in use in the FCA program for
several years, are based on time studies car­
ried out by the National Association for Bank
Audit, Control, and Operations (now the
Bank Administration Institute). They are as
follows:
Activity
Home debit
Deposit
Regular checking account
maintenance
Special checking account
maintenance
Transit check

Weight
2.73
3.82
722.00
60.16
1.00

The use of weight units of activity as a
measure of output associated with the check­
ing account function suggests that it may also
be the appropriate measure of bank size for
the purpose of measuring the relationship be­
tween size and efficiency within the check­
ing account function. One would, of course,
expect to find a fairly high correlation be­
tween a bank’s size as measured by total de­
posits and its total checking account activity.
The data indicate that the per unit costs
of checking account activity do, in fact, vary
inversely with total checking account activity.
To be sure, the influence of all factors other
than the amount of activity that might pro­
duce this relationship has not been accounted
for, and any conclusions must, therefore, be
tentative. Nevertheless, the regularity of the
decline in unit costs from one activity level

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Costs per unit of activity in
1970 varied inversely with
the level of activity . . .
cents per unit of activity

0 -5

5-10
million

units of

10-15
activity

suggesting that efficient use
of computers requires high
levels of account activity
percent of banks

10

million units of activity




15-20

class to the next suggests that there may, in
fact, be economies of size in the administra­
tion of checking accounts.
To say that unit costs vary inversely with
the level of activity does not explain why
this should be so. In general, economies of
scale result from the fact that some means of
production—e.g., certain machines or pro­
cesses—are indivisible and can be used
economically only when total output exceeds
some minimum level. Thus, the decline in
checking account unit costs as activity ex­
pands may reflect the progressive adoption of
successively more efficient types of demand
deposit accounting technology. As has al­
ready been seen, this is reflected in the higher
ratio of capital costs to the total costs of pro­
cessing checking accounts in large banks than
in smaller ones. It is shown more directly in
the greater proportion of large banks that
utilize on- or off-premise computers for de­
mand deposit bookkeeping, as opposed to
electronic or conventional bookkeeping ma­
chines.
Greater activity also enables the bank to
utilize personnel more efficiently. Not only
can there be greater specialization of tasks
when output is greater, but the proportion of
the time that tellers and other personnel can
be expected to be idle during the day varies
inversely with the number of customers and
transactions.
Despite its importance, the level of activity
is only one of many factors that help to ac­
count for interbank differences in checking
account costs. Another is the organizational
structure of the banking firm—whether it is
a branch or unit bank. Although it would be
reasonable to expect branch banks to have
higher occupancy costs and, because of the
distribution of personnel among two or more
locations and consequent limited specializa­
tion, higher labor costs, the independent in-

Business Conditions, October 1971

W age levels had an important
influence on checking account
costs in 1970
cents per unit of activity

may have an important influence on costs.
Finally, the large, if declining, proportion
of labor costs to total costs of processing
checking accounts suggests that inter-area
differences in wages may explain an impor­
tant part of the differences in costs. The local
areas in which the FCA banks were located
were classified into low and high wage areas,
and the costs per account of banks of similar
size in the two types of areas compared. The
results support the thesis that banks in high
wage areas experienced higher costs than
banks in low wage areas.
Conclusion

0 -5

5-10

10-15

15-20

million units of activity

fluence of branching is hard to discern from
data on the 133 FCA banks. In the aggregate,
the cost per checking account in 1970 was
4.8 percent higher for banks with branche
than for unit banks. The erratic behavior of
the differences in the costs of unit and branch
banks in the same deposit-size classes may be
due to the failure to account for major varia­
tions in the number of branches. In addition,
branches vary greatly in the scope of their
operations, some functioning simply as pay­
ing and receiving stations, others being
operated virtually as individual unit banks.
Because of these weaknesses in the data, the
relatively insignificant differences found here
do not preclude the possibility that branching




Despite attempts to explain interbank dif­
ferences in checking account costs by relating
them to a number of factors commonly be­
lieved to affect costs, the remaining variation
is still quite large. The level of activity was
found to account for a large proportion of
the variation in cost per account between
banks, while differences in the average bal­
ance per account explained much of the dif­
ference between costs per dollar of deposits
and costs per account. The seemingly un­
systematic character of the remaining varia­
tion in costs suggests that it may be the result
of major differences in the quality and costconsciousness of individual bank manage­
ments. To the extent that this is true, there
is considerable scope for cost reduction by
deliberate measures under the control of bank
management that are independent of such
given and fixed conditions as the size and
location of the bank.

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Farmers’ off-farm incomes
exceed farm earnings
Two out of three American farmers receive
over half their annual income from off-farm
sources. Most operators of small farms rely
almost entirely on off-farm earnings to pro­
vide their livelihood. And even those who
operate the nation’s largest farms receive a
significant proportion of their total incomes
from off-farm sources.
Record o f th e S ix tie s

The off-farm income of farm operators
doubled over the decade—rising from $8.5
billion in 1960 to $17 billion in 1970, when it
exceeded total net farm income for the first

Off-farm income outstrips
income from farming
billion dollars

12

SO U R C E: U. S. Departm ent o f Agriculture. See July
1971 Farm Income Situation.




time. Operators’ income received from farm­
ing increased only 44 percent during the same
period, from $11.7 billion to $15.9 billion.
The strong gain in off-farm earnings is
traceable in large part to the rapid growth in
the nation’s nonfarm economy, which pro­
vided an abundance of good-paying jobs dur­
ing the period. Nonagricultural wage and
salary employment grew by about 16 million
persons during the 1960s, and the unemploy­
ment rate fell from a high of 6.7 percent in
1961 to a low of 3.5 percent in 1969.
Nonfarm wages and prices spiraled upward
during the decade. Average weekly earnings
of factory workers rose 47 percent, and the
consumer price index advanced 26 percent.
More farm operators and their wives probably
felt the need to supplement their farm in­
comes, which were growing much slower than
the incomes of the nonfarm population, in
order to maintain a desired standard of living.
But the foundation of the trend itself can be
found in the mechanization and technological
breakthroughs that cut deeply into the time
required to operate a farm efficiently. Reflect­
ing this, the proportion of the farm population
in the labor force working in nonagricultural
jobs rose from 33 percent in 1960 to 44 per­
cent in 1970. In both years, three-fifths of the
farm population over 14 years old were par­
ticipating in the total labor force—but more
were engaged in nonfarming activity.
Farm women, like their urban counter­
parts, became more active in the labor force.
About 38 percent of all farm women were

Business Conditions, October 1971

Percent of farmers working off
the farm 100 days or more by
counties in 1969




13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

More Seventh District farmers
find off-farm employment
percent*

Illinois

Iowa

Indiana

Michigan

Wisconsin

* O p e ra to rs w o rk in g o f f the fa rm

TOO d a y s o r m ore.

either working or seeking work in 1970, com­
pared to 30 percent in 1960. By contrast, the
proportion of farm men in the labor force
dropped from 85 percent to 80 percent be­
tween 1960 and 1970. The decline in male
participation, in part, reflects the rising pro­
portion of farm men reaching retirement age
during the period.
The S e v e n th District

14

The rapid increase in off-farm employment
of farm operators in the states of the Seventh
District is indicated by data collected in the
1969 Census of Agriculture and only recently
published. Farm operators in district states
working 100 days or more off the farm rose
from just over 25 percent of all farmers to
nearly 38 percent between 1959 and 1969.
In the highly industrialized state of Michi­
gan, the proportion of farmers working off
the farm rose from 42 percent to 52 percent.
In Iowa, whose economy relies most heavily
on agriculture, the proportion of farmers




working off farms over 100 days rose most
rapidly—increasing from 14 percent in 1959
to 23 percent in 1969.
The proportion of farmers working in offfarm jobs tended to be highest near urban
areas and in areas where farm income was
lowest. For example, 44 percent of the
farmers located in standard metropolitan
statistical areas (SMSAs) worked off the
farm 100 days or more in 1969. Similarly, 44
percent of the farmers in the low farm income
areas of southern Illinois and Indiana and
northern Wisconsin and Michigan worked off
the farm 100 days or more. These proportions
compare to an average of 38 percent for the
entire district.
A problem of definition

The Department of Agriculture’s definition
of a “farmer” bears little relation, in the ma­
jority of cases, to how that person earns a
living. A farmer, as defined by the Depart­
ment, is any person who operates a farm. But
a “farm” is defined as a place of ten acres or
more with at least $50 in product sales, or a
place of less than ten acres with at least $250
in sales.
Forty percent of the 2.8 million “farms”
enumerated by the Department of Agriculture
have annual farm product sales of less than
$2,500, and they account for less than 3 per­
cent of total farm cash receipts. It is not too
surprising that the operators of these farms
receive nearly 90 percent of their income
from off-farm sources. But larger farmers,
too, rely on off-farm earnings to supplement
their farm incomes.
There are approximately 1.1 million
farmers with over $10,000 in annual farm
product sales, and together they account for
90 percent of all cash receipts from farming.
Nearly half of the farmers in this “commer-

Business Conditions, October 1971

Off-farm earnings increasingly
important to all farmers
S ize o f f a r m 1

N u m b er
o f fa rm s
1960

1970

(th o u sa n d s)

Pro p o rtio n o f
a ll fa rm s
1960

1970

F arm
inco m e2
1960

O ff- fa r m
inco m e

1970

(percen t)

1960

T o ta l
incom e

1970

1960

1970

(p e r farm in d o lla rs)

O ff- fa rm /
/T o ta l
1960

1970

(p ercen t)

1 ,84 8

1 ,184

47

40

850

1 ,05 9

2,731

7 ,9 5 4

3,581

9 ,0 1 3

76

88

$ 2 ,5 0 0 — $ 4 ,9 9 9

6 17

260

15

9

1,961

2 ,0 4 9

1 ,849

5 ,4 6 5

3 ,8 1 0

7 ,5 1 4

49

73
59

Less th a n $ 2 ,5 0 0

$ 5 ,0 0 0 —$ 9 ,9 9 9

6 60

370

17

13

3 ,3 0 5

3 ,49 2

1 ,573

4 ,9 8 4

4 ,8 7 8

8 ,4 7 6

32

$ 1 0 ,0 0 0 —$ 1 9 ,9 9 9

497

513

12

17

5 ,3 6 8

6 ,2 0 8

1,258

3 ,4 5 2

6 ,6 2 6

9 ,6 6 0

19

36

$ 2 0 ,0 0 0 —$ 3 9 ,9 9 9

2 27

374

6

13

8 ,65 2

9 ,9 6 2

1 ,678

3 ,5 0 3

10,3 3 0

13,4 6 5

16

26

$ 4 0 ,0 0 0 a n d o v e r

113

223

3

8

18,9 9 5

2 5 ,6 6 4

2 ,1 7 7

5 ,8 0 3

2 1 ,1 3 2

3 1 ,4 6 7

10

18

S O U R C E : U. S . D e p a rtm e n t o f A g ric u ltu re .
'M e a s u re d in term s o f a n n u a l fa rm p ro d u ct sale s.
2R e a lize d net incom e e xclu d e s in v e n to ry ch an g e an d in clu d e s g o ve rn m e n t p a y m e n ts.

cial-size” group had average family incomes
of $9,660 in 1970, and off-farm earnings
accounted for over one-third of the total. The
next larger-sized farmers had family incomes
of $13,465 in 1970, and off-farm earnings
equaled more than one-fourth of their total
incomes.
Although the relative importance of offfarm income decreases as the size of the farm­
ing operation increases, such earnings still
comprise a significant portion of the total in­
come of the very largest operators. About
one-fifth of the 1.1 million large, commercial
farmers in the United States averaged nearly
$ 125,000 in farm product sales in 1970. They
had average family incomes of more than
$31,400, with almost one-fifth derived from
off-farm sources. Undoubtedly, these very
large farmers receive most of their off-farm
earnings from nonfarm business enterprises
or investments, such as stocks and bonds,
rather than from wages and salaries. It should
be pointed out, too, that an increasing pro­
portion of farmers reach retirement age each
year, and as a result an ever increasing pro­
portion of “off-farm” income is accounted



for by monthly Social Security payments.
An Illinois study

An insight into the role off-farm income
plays in the Corn Belt region of the Seventh
District is provided by a recent University of
Illinois study. The study included about 300
commercial farm operators in central Illinois,
a highly productive farming region. Off-farm
income accounted for nearly half the earnings
of farmers with total annual incomes of
$6,000 or less. Those with just over $9,000
in family earnings, which included two-thirds
of the families studied, obtained about onefourth of their annual incomes from off-farm
sources. Those with over $18,000 in family
income earned only 4 percent of the total
from off-farm sources.
Wages and salaries were by far the most
important source of off-farm income, ac­
counting for over 60 percent of the total. The
farmer’s wife, holding a job outside the home,
was a major contributor to earnings, account­
ing, on the average, for 44 percent of the
family’s off-farm income. One-fourth of the
farm wives surveyed in the Illinois study

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

worked off the farm. These women usually
were employed full-time at jobs requiring
special skills (secretarial work) or advanced
education (teaching and nursing).
Som e im plications

The importance of off-farm income to farm
families has implications for farm manage­
ment, for farm lenders, and for farm policy­
makers. It is important to farm managers be­
cause it affects the way farm enterprises are
organized. For the small farmer—the one
who lacks the financial resources, the man­
agerial ability, or the inclination to adapt to
modern, large-scale farming—off-farm em­
ployment for himself and his family provides
the means of maintaining a satisfactory
standard of living while he continues to farm.
In most instances, this means labor-intensive
enterprises, such as livestock raising, will be
eliminated from the operation of small farms.
Moreover, machinery larger than might
otherwise be necessary may be required to
enable the operator to complete his farm
work on schedule while maintaining off-farm
employment.
The implication of off-farm income for
farm lenders is that the repayment capacity
of farm borrowers is increased by off-farm
earnings. Medium-sized farms ($10,000 to
$20,000 in farm sales) are significant both in
numbers and in the amount of farm credit
used. Operators in this size group make up
more than one-third of the farm borrowers at
Seventh District banks, and they account for

over one-third of the farm production credit
outstanding. Since off-farm earnings are a
major source of income to farmers in this size
category, information concerning the educa­
tion and nonfarm employment status of the
farmer and his wife—and local off-farm job
opportunities—is as important as knowledge
about the prospective borrower’s farm opera­
tion in assessing credit worthiness.
Farm policymakers may infer from the im­
portance of off-farm earnings that increasing
the availability of jobs in rural areas is more
pertinent to aiding the majority of farm
families than boosting the level of farm in­
come through price supports or direct subsi­
dies. Since present agricultural support pro­
grams are based on acres controlled and
bushels or pounds produced, the few very
large farmers receive the greatest benefits.
For example, in 1970, farms with less than
$10,000 in cash receipts comprised over
three-fifths of the Census-enumerated farms
but collected just slightly over one-fifth of the
total direct government payments. On the
other hand, farms with $20,000 or more in
cash receipts comprised only one-fifth of all
farms but received three-fifths of the total
payments.
It would appear that the “farm policy”
that would bear the richest harvest for the
majority of farmers is not one based on com­
modities or acres of land, but a national
policy designed to foster overall economic
growth and provide educational and job op­
portunities for low income rural families.

B U SIN ESS C O N D IT IO N S is p u b lish e d m o nth ly b y the F e d e ra l R ese rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o .
L a rry R. M ote a n d D a v id E. U p d e g ra ff w e re p rim a rily resp o n sib le fo r the a rtic le "C h e c k in g
acco u nt costs—T re n d s a n d co m p ositio n am o n g s m a ll b a n k s, 1 9 6 6 -7 0 " a n d D enn is B. S h a rp e
fo r " F a rm e rs ' o ff- fa rm incom es e xce ed fa rm e a rn in g s ."
16

A rtic le s m a y be re p rin te d p ro v id e d source is c re d ite d . P le ase p ro v id e the b a n k 's R esearch
D e p artm e n t w ith a co p y o f a n y m a te ria l in w h ic h a n a rtic le is re p rin te d .