View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Monetary policy—
an experiment proposed

2

Bargaining power for farmers

7

Personal certificates—
a stabilizer?

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Monetary policy—
an experiment proposed
.an’s desire for precision in the behavior
tinuously and without undue upward pressure
M
and management of the economy is no less
on prices or strain on the balance of pay­
keen than it is in the realm of mechanical
phenomena. But the possibility of achieving
precision in economic affairs remains remote,
largely because economic data and the units
of economic performance arise out of the
activities of individuals whose behavioral
patterns are so widely varied as virtually to
defy precise and comprehensive measurement
and prediction. Indicative of the desire for
greater precision in economic policy is the
term “fine tuning” which has appeared re­
peatedly in writings and discussions in recent
years. The term connotes both precise fore­
casts, to serve as a basis for economic policy
formulation, and continuous adjustment of
policy—largely in relation to taxes, govern­
ment spending, and credit—in response to
changes in current and prospective develop­
ments.
Monetary policy, in some ways the most
flexible of economic policy tools, tends to
move to center stage when fine tuning of
economic policy is under discussion. But the
idea of fine tuning has critics as well as pro­
ponents, as indeed its feasibility remains to
be demonstrated.
Nearly everyone supports the goal of ad­
herence to a pace of sustainable economic
growth with relatively full (but not overfull)
and continuous utilization of the labor force
and other resources. This clearly implies a
finely tuned economy, with the capability of
adjusting continuously to the many changes
that must occur if growth and high-level out­
put and employment are to be achieved con­




ments. Which policy techniques hold the
greatest promise of facilitating the achieve­
ment of this desirable goal?
This question is a matter of continuing
interest and concern to the Joint Economic
Committee of Congress, among others. Cre­
ated by the Employment Act of 1946, the
committee reviews the President’s Annual
Economic Report and studies matters relating
to the health and performance of the econ­
omy. Composed of members from both the
House and Senate, the committee originates
no legislation of its own but investigates
economic conditions and reports its findings
and recommendations to the two houses.
Monetary policy, quite naturally, is of con­
tinuing interest as the committee searches for
ways to help obtain the benefits of a finely
tuned economy, whether achieved by finely
tuned economic policies or otherwise.
The committee recently has proposed that
“Congress should advise the Federal Reserve
System that . . . the rate of increase of the
money stock . . . ought . . . for the present
. . . to be within the limits of 2 to 6 percent
per annum, measured on a quarter-by-quarter
basis in a range that centers on the . . . longrun . . . sustainable real growth rate” of the
economy.
The proposal—clearly not in the vein of
“fine tuning”—is put forth as an experiment
in monetary policy, to be tested operationally
for several years and the results observed
with care. If found wanting by this test, the
guideline presumably would be revised. The

Business Conditions, October 1968

consequences of implementing such a plan
as this, or other similar proposals, of course,
cannot be determined in advance. Even after
being tested operationally, specific economic
policies are difficult to evaluate because of the
great complexity of the economy and the
great array of forces that always are affecting
it simultaneously.
If adopted, adhered to, and gradually re­
fined, the proposal would set the stage for
a number of changes in monetary policy.
Most important, it would place money supply
at the top of a list of policy guides. Histori­
cally, the Federal Reserve has given substan­
tial emphasis to moderating strong short-run
fluctuations in interest rates, exchange rates,
and credit availability. The rate of growth
of money supply, while given consideration
along with other pertinent factors, has not
been the only or dominant consideration in
determining the policies conducive to achieve­
ment of general economic objectives.
Although the committee’s current proposal
has not been cast in precise or rigid terms—
doubtless reflecting the variety of views pre­
sented by monetary experts at its hearings
—it is generally consistent in spirit with
previous JEC findings that Congress should
assume greater responsibility for the direction
of domestic economic policy and that an
experiment should be conducted to determine
whether less variation in money supply
growth would have desirable effects on eco­
nomic performance.
The committee’s report acknowledges that
the Federal Reserve has an abundance of
guidelines relating to its goals or objectives.
In addition to its responsibilities under the
Federal Reserve Act of 1913, the System
pursues the objectives of the Employment
Act of 1946, which, in the words of the com­
mittee, “involves maintenance of low rates
of unemployment, reasonable stability in the




purchasing power of the dollar, a high and
stable rate of economic growth, and a stable
exchange rate for the dollar.”
The committee also notes that the Federal
Reserve must often take into consideration
other important objectives of public policy
such as avoiding “significant changes in
money market conditions at times of new
Treasury issues,” avoiding “excessively high
interest rates,” and protecting “the flow of
funds to nonbank financial intermediaries,”
which are important suppliers of credit for
homebuilding.
G o a l p rio ritie s

Economic policy invariably has a number
of objectives. No single one of them can be
pursued without taking into consideration the
effects on others. Some weighing of the var­
ious objectives is inevitable.
The committee concluded that since mone­
tary policy has a variety of objectives, an
ordering of priorities must be made and that
this ordering should be done by Congress.
An important benefit the committee believes
might flow from such an expression of con­
gressional responsibility is better evaluation
of “the relative roles of monetary policies
and other policies, including various types of
fiscal policies, in promoting and reconciling
. . . economic objectives.”
The committee underscored the interrela­
tions between monetary and fiscal policies,
declaring that the federal government’s needs
for credit cannot be denied and that under
certain conditions “monetary action to ac­
commodate management of the federal debt”
would be required. It is noted that “the
Federal Reserve cannot stabilize both the
money stock and interest rates in this situa­
tion” and that Congress should adopt the
necessary fiscal policies to forestall potential
problems, such as those resulting from abrupt

3

Findings and Recommendations*
I
Congress should give serious consideration
to providing more specific guidelines relating
to the objectives o f monetary policy— guide­
lines relating to the weights to be attached to
the various objectives, among which are
maintenance o f continuously low rates of
unemployment, reasonable stability in the
purchasing power o f the dollar, a high and
stable rate of econom ic growth, and a stable
exchange rate for the dollar. Such an attempt
by Congress might yield two beneficial re­
sults: First, it might provide more specific
guidance to the Federal Reserve in terms of
goals or objectives. Second, the very process
would afford Congress an opportunity to
evaluate better the relative roles of monetary
policies and of other policies, including var­
ious types of fiscal policies, in promoting and
reconciling our econom ic objectives. Flowever, as noted earlier in the report, these
guidelines ought not to be interpreted as rigid
directives.

II
Just as Congress has the authority to fix

shifts of funds from savings institutions into
the securities markets, oppressive mortgage
interest rates, international capital flows, and
the like.
As an aid to Congress in arriving at opti­
mum judgments on fiscal policy, the Federal
Reserve authorities have been requested by
the committee to submit to the committee at
the beginning of each year their views on the
kind of monetary policy called for in light of
the expected state of the economy. The Fed­
eral Reserve Board has agreed to provide
annually projections prepared by its staff of
financial developments consistent with the
economic prospects envisaged in the Presi­
dent’s Economic Report. And in lieu of
quarterly reports on growth of the money
supply requested by the committee, the Board
has proposed the preparation for the com­




government expenditures and taxes, and thus
largely to determine the budget surplus or
deficit, Congress has the responsibility of
reckoning with the monetary consequences
of its action. While the monetary authority
granted to Congress by the Constitution has
been delegated to the Federal Reserve Sys­
tem, it behooves Congress to provide some
guidance to the Federal Reserve on how the
system should see to the support of the gov­
ernment’s credit and, in particular, to what
extent Congress regards the expansion of
Federal Reserve credit as an appropriate way
to finance any part of the deficit.

Ill
To provide a first approximation to an
economic posture that would manage to
maintain price stability while encouraging
maximum employment and rapid growth,
Congress should advise the Federal Reserve
System that variations in the rate of increase
of the money stock (currency plus demand
*U.S., Congress, Joint Economic Committee,
Standards for Guiding Monetary Action, 90th
Cong., 2nd Sess., 1968 pp. 19-20.

mittee of a broader analysis of significant
developments in financial markets following
each calendar quarter.
M o n ey su p p ly a s a guide

In proposing that the money supply be
made a primary guide to monetary policy,
the committee necessarily was obliged to de­
fine the term money and satisfy itself that the
Federal Reserve is in a position to control the
amount of money. The call for disciplined
control over growth in the money supply pre­
supposes that there is a close and dependable
relationship between the amount of money
and the behavior of the economy and that
goals other than those relating to the state of
the economy would not ordinarily become
over-riding in the determination of monetary
policy.

deposits adjusted) ought not to be too great
or too sharp. In normal times, for the pres­
ent, the desirable range of variation appears
to be within the limits of 2 to 6 percent per
annum, measured on a quarter-by-quarter
basis— a range that centers on the rate of
long-run increase in the potential gross na­
tional product in constant dollars, which is
our sustainable real growth rate.
On any occasion on which the Federal
Reserve System, deliberately or as a result
of external monetary developments, has not
maintained a money-stock growth rate within
the desired range, the committee requests
that the monetary authority report promptly
to it, or to another appropriate body of
Congress, on the reasons that the Federal
Reserve System would give for this diver­
gence. Periodic reports on the reasons for
action taken within the desired range should
also be made.
If, after several years’ experience with a
rule, refinements in the guidelines seem war­
ranted, they could, and should, of course, be
made.

On what is money, the committee took the
commonly accepted measure—currency and
private demand deposits (excluding deposits
of the U. S. government). These are the
financial assets that serve primarily as media
of exchange. But other financial assets—such
as savings deposits, savings and loan shares,
and U. S. savings bonds—while not serving
as media of exchange, are easily converted
into assets that do. Some people consider
these other assets to be so much like money
as to merit inclusion in any list of assets the
supply of which is to be controlled in the
interest of promoting general economic sta­
bility. The broader the range of financial
assets, of course, the more nearly the total
approximates total credit—which is also be­
lieved by some to be a factor whose varia­
bility should be constrained in order to help



IV
Finally, as a regular procedure, the Fed­
eral Reserve authorities should at the be­
ginning of each year, set forth publicly as
specifically as possible their notion of what
kind of monetary policy the expected state
of the economy calls for. This would supple­
ment in the monetary field the review of the
federal government’s econom ic programs
which the President is now required to set
forth in the Econom ic Report. Such a public
projection (which we understand is already
available internally) would present a picture
of what the financial world— money supply,
flows through financial intermediaries, the
appropriate course of interest rates— would
look like. This would also tie in with the gross
national product projection indicated in the
report of the Council of Econom ic Advisers.
It would certainly help Congress to adopt the
necessary fiscal policies and to foresee and
forestall potential problems such as those
resulting from disintermediation, oppressive
interest rates in the housing field, interna­
tional capital flows, and the like.

stabilize the economy.
The Board of Governors has expressed the
belief that broader measures than money in
the narrow sense of currency and demand de­
posits are most meaningful for economic
analysis and policy purposes, and the chair­
man of the Joint Economic Committee has
indicated his willingness to consider alterna­
tive concepts within the framework of the
committee’s broad objectives.
The committee concluded that the Federal
Reserve could normally reach a target level
of money supply “with reasonable accuracy.”
However, this may not be a simple under­
taking, especially if the target were quite
precise and the time period in which it was
to be achieved were short. The amount of
money available at any one time depends
both on actions of the public and actions of

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

the Federal Reserve and the banking system
as a whole. Since money does not include all
financial assets, the public can shift back and
forth between assets—between, say, demand
deposits and time deposits—in response to
changes in the amount of money it wishes
to hold.
The amount of money the public seeks to
hold tends to rise with increases in income but
to decline when interest rates rise. The first
effect is a reflection of the higher spending
associated with greater income and the latter
a matter of economizing on cash when yields
on liquid, nonmonetary assets are high.
Actions of commercial banks affect the
amount of deposits, and demand deposits are
the major component of the money supply.
Many banks hold reserves in excess of legal
requirements. When the amount of these ex­
cess reserves changes, total loans and in­
vestments and, consequently, deposits also
change. Because excess reserves produce no
income, banks normally try to hold them to
a minimum. The amount of excess reserves
that banks are content to hold tends to be
smaller when interest rates are high than
when they are low.
A given amount of total reserves, there­
fore, does not always result in a given supply
of money. To control the supply of money
within any fairly narrow confines, the Federal
Reserve would have to predict future be­
havior of banks and the public, which is hard
to do. However, the range of growth rates
proposed by the committee is relatively wide
and the time period within which the average
growth rate would be determined is fairly
long.
M o n ey a n d incom e

6

Testimony before the committee regard­
ing the relation between money and economic
activity was largely contradictory. Unless the




velocity of money held stable, total expendi­
tures and, therefore, economic activity would
not be stabilized by exercising control over
growth in the supply of money. Some wit­
nesses saw no consistent relationship between
money supply and economic activity. Others
saw a strong relationship. Still other wit­
nesses testified that, while the relationship
might not always be close, abrupt changes in
the amount of money are closely related with
succeeding abrupt changes in economic activ­
ity. The committee concluded that “a steadily
growing economy with stable prices (is) likely
to be best assisted by a comparable steady
growth of money supply.”
While recognizing that the primary objec­
tive of monetary policy is to affect aggregate
levels of economic activity, the committee
also recognized that other goals must some­
times become overriding. “The monetary
authority cannot be indifferent if its policy
threatens to create such stringency that the
mortgage and municipal bond market verge
on collapse. Nor can it ignore the deteriora­
tion of monetary contracts in any important
market.”
The committee noted that conditions might
sometimes require that the Federal Reserve
System operate outside the proposed 2 to 6
percent rate of growth in money supply. But
the inference is strong that the committee is
searching for a simple, precise, quantitative
guide to monetary policy that could be sub­
stituted at least in part for the present judg­
mental process which takes into considera­
tion a very comprehensive range of economic
information. Governor George Mitchell, of
the Federal Reserve Board, suggested in his
testimony that such a search is almost certain
to be fruitless.
The lim its of te stin g

Adherence to the proposed guide would

Business Conditions, October 1968

have resulted in somewhat different monetary
policy in recent years. Quarter-to-quarter
changes in the money supply have been out­
side the 2 to 6 -percent range a number of
times since 1958. In recent quarters, annual
rates of growth in excess of 6 percent have
been frequent. Slower rates of monetary
growth during those times probably would
have resulted in higher interest rates and
intensified pressures on money, capital, and
mortgage markets. Presumably, higher inter­
est rates, after a time, would have helped
restrain demand and relieve inflationary pres­
sures with rates then receding. But unfortu­
nately current economic knowledge permits
no unequivocal statement of the precise ef­
fects of alternative policies.
The Joint Economic Committee would
have the Federal Reserve System test the eco­
nomic effects of a fairly stable growth in
money supply. Because of the complexity of
the economy, there can be no guarantee that
the results of such a test can be measured
accurately. Nevertheless, the search for better

Annual rates of change
in money supply, quarterly
percent

1958

fcestimote

I960

1962

1964

1966

1968

understanding and better economic policies
will continue—for our stake in stability,
growth, and maximum output and income is
great.

Bargaining power for farmers
merican farmers have long held the belief that their bargaining position is weak,
relative both to their suppliers and to the
processors that buy their products. Recently,
proposals have again been made for strength­
ening the position of farmers in the sale of
their products.
The President, in his State of the Union
Message, called for programs to “help the
farmer bargain more effectively for fair
prices.” The Secretary of Agriculture has



also suggested that more bargaining power
may be needed for farmers to secure a more
equitable income. And farm organizations
and the agricultural press, while divided on
the means of gaining and using bargaining
power, tend to agree that it is what farmers
need.
B a rg a in in g p o w e r fo r w h a t?

Bargaining power—the ability to influence
the terms of exchange, whether in price or

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

8

such matters as grade and amount of the
product, delivery dates, and terms of payment
—can take several forms. Under some condi­
tions, a party to the exchange can force con­
cessions by threatening to inflict loss on the
other unless he accepts the terms offered.
Under other conditions, there may be a com­
munity of interests that allows each party to
benefit from concessions to the other. And
there are conditions under which the two
parties can gain at the expense of a third—
usually consumers, other businesses, or “the
public.” A combination of these conditions
is present in most bargaining.
Farmers’ renewed drive for greater bar­
gaining power comes at a time when govern­
ment programs insulate them, to a great
extent, from the influence of market forces.
It is pointed out that these programs cover
only a few “basic” commodities—that 60
percent of farm income comes from products
not covered by government programs. But it
is also pointed out that while many commodi­
ties are not supported directly, government
programs provide considerable indirect sup­
port—for example, that the feed-grain pro­
gram limits the available supply of feed and
raises the prices of all grain, which in turn
reduces the number of livestock raised and
increases livestock prices.
Agriculture is assisted by a number of
federal programs, including price supports,
restrictions on production, export subsidies,
and restrictions on imports. The government
distributed $3.1 billion to farmers in direct
payments last year. This accounted for more
than 20 percent of the net farm income. Siz­
able expenditures were also made on other
programs to boost farm income.
The Department of Agriculture and several
land-grant colleges have tried to estimate
what the level of farm income would have
been in recent years if government programs




had not been in effect. Their estimates vary
but generally suggest incomes about a third
lower. Many farmers, nevertheless, feel they
would receive higher incomes if they had
more bargaining power and could directly
influence the prices at which they sell their
products.
Prices of agricultural products have tra­
ditionally been established by competition
between processors or shippers for the avail­
able supply. But the marketing channels for
many products have changed through the
years, with reliance on terminal markets as
points of active competition and price deter­
mination becoming less important as more
and more products are moved through other
channels.
Rapid strides have been made in vertical
integration, contract growing, and direct buy­
ing. Along with other changes in marketing,
these developments tend to emphasize differ­
ences in the bargaining power of farmers and
the purchasers of their products.
With the shift in marketing channels, many
farm leaders have concluded that increased
bargaining power would provide a means for
gaining higher prices, broader markets, more
favorable terms of sales, and greater man­
agerial independence. Some of these aims,
however, are mutually exclusive. Higher
prices, for example, tend to restrict markets,
not broaden them. And contract commit­
ments are more likely to reduce farmers’ in­
dependence and managerial flexibility than
increase them. To achieve one goal, farmers
may have to give ground on another.
P o ten tial fo r b a rg a in in g p o w e r

One requirement for successful bargaining
is formation of a cohesive bargaining organi­
zation. Recognition that an organization can
speak for the group provides considerable
power in itself. But members must recognize

Business Conditions, October 1968

that effective group action requires that they
give up the freedom to make some production
and marketing decisions. For a bargaining
organization to be viable, members must be
willing to make individual sacrifices.
Experience seems to indicate that the pos­
sibilities of achieving effective group action
are greater in cases where a commodity is
produced primarily in a small geographical
area and by relatively few producers. It is
also helpful if producers are highly special­
ized in the commodity and, therefore, keenly
interested in its marketing. The producers of
cling-stone peaches, grown largely in Cali­
fornia, can work together much easier than
producers of beef cattle, which are grown
nationwide by a large number of producers
operating under a variety of conditions.
M a rk e t m an a g e m e n t

Higher prices, a goal of most farmers, are
not achieved by demanding them. Prices re­
spond to supply and demand.
A seller can influence the market, and
therefore prices, by changing supply condi­
tions or demand conditions, or, of course, by
changing both. Most nonagricultural busi­
nesses use advertising and other forms of
promotion in efforts to improve demand con­
ditions for their products, either by enlarging
the market or by increasing their share of it.
They can also schedule output to the sales
expected at the price asked.
Such efforts to manage the market are
easier to plan, however, than to carry out.
Typically, such efforts must be continuously
adjusted—but with less adjustment in price
than is usual in agriculture, the adjustment
being more in production, promotion, and
product design.
Agriculture closely approximates a theo­
retically pure competitive situation, albeit
with government intervention. With millions




of producers selling essentially homogenous
products, individual producers usually can­
not benefit noticeably from advertising. Sim­
ilarly, because the demand for food in the
U. S. is tied mainly to population growth,
gains from advertising are limited for agricul­
ture as a whole.
The supply side of the market might seem
the more likely area of manipulation for
farmers, but the highly competitive structure
of agriculture tends to deter any lasting group
effort to restrict supply. As individuals,
farmers face a completely “elastic” demand
for their production. Market conditions gen­
erally allow them to sell any amount they can
produce at the price being paid at the time
with each farmer’s output too small to have
any appreciable influence on the price. The
price is influenced primarily by total supply.
If producers increase the supply, prices must
decline to induce consumers to buy more and
speculators to hold larger inventories. While
it may be to the individual farmer’s advantage
to restrict supply in concert with other farm­
ers, not knowing what others may do, he
tends to produce at a fairly steady pace taking
into consideration his costs and expected
selling prices.
Only by government intervention have
large numbers of farmers been persuaded to
limit production, and reliance has been pri­
marily on payments to farmers to obtain
their cooperation. Yet, even with government
controls, most farmers have been able, at
least partially, to neutralize the restraints by
using more fertilizer and other resources to
boost acreage yields.
Con tro l of supply

Programs to control supply can be directed
toward the control of either production or
utilization. Production control has the great­
est potential for raising prices, but it is also

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

10

the most objectionable to farmers because it
impinges directly on their freedom as man­
agers. While farmers may agree generally
that the production of a commodity should be
curtailed to raise its price, the means of de­
vising and enforcing individual quotas or
allotments have not been adequate.
Efforts to boost prices by controlling utili­
zation rely on the diversion of part of the
supply to other than usual uses. Where this
form of control is applicable, it allows farmers
freer rein to produce as they choose. This
form of control is limited, however, to prod­
ucts with more than one use and different
demand characteristics in different markets.
Milk, for example, is consumed as fluid milk
and as manufactured products, such as
butter, cheese, ice cream, and dried and con­
densed milk. Dairymen can raise their in­
comes by splitting the market for fluid milk
from the market for processed milk and limit­
ing the amount of milk going into the fluid
milk market. Because the demand for fluid
milk is not as responsive to price changes as
the demand for other dairy products, the
supply diverted to the market for processed
milk depresses prices less there than it would
in the fluid milk market.
Another form of disposal control is “ex­
port dumping.” The amount of a product sold
on the domestic market is restricted to in­
crease the price, and the excess is then sold
on the export market at a lower price. The
ability to export surpluses is often limited,
however, by “antidumping” laws enacted by
other countries to protect their producers.
Either form of disposal control tends to
increase the supply in response to the increase
in average price. As the supply increases,
more of the total must be diverted into a
secondary market. Prices then decline in that
market, partly offsetting effects of the higher
prices in the primary market.




Production control, if effective, allows
producers to raise prices and maximize in­
come. But for a price to be raised significantly
for long, the commodity must have no close
substitutes and consumers must have a strong
preference for it. Also, acceptable procedures
must be provided for sharing the market be­
tween producers, and the total output must be
effectively controlled.
Production quotas would appear to be the
most effective means of control, but they are
the least attractive to farmers. Farmers prefer
acreage allotments for crops and number-ofhead allotments for livestock because these
types of controls allow them to exercise their
ingenuity as producers and seek to increase
their share of the total supply by more inten­
sive cultivation of crops and heavier feeding
of livestock. It is also necessary to control the
entrance of new producers attracted by the
higher prices.
Neither form of supply control is easy to
achieve for agricultural products, even— as
experience has shown—with the intervention
of federal and state governments. Even the
associations of fruit growers in California
and other groups dealing in specialized com­
modities grown in fairly small areas owe
much of their success to state and federal
marketing orders.
It does not appear that farmers can make
significant price gains without control of sup­
ply, and because of the structure of agricul­
ture, voluntary supply controls do not seem
likely to develop.
Another alternative is government control
of supply. This approach is repugnant to
many farmers, however, and may not be
politically feasible in the years ahead. In the
final analysis, consumers—and increasingly
urban consumers—have to pay the cost of
higher agricultural prices. Though farmers
have had the support of Congress in the past,

Business Conditions, October 1968

with the rise in urban population and the
growing interest in the problems of poverty,
hunger, and inflation, programs to boost farm
prices may attract less and less support.
Com m unity of in te re sts

If farmers cannot gain effective control of
supply, voluntarily or through government
intervention, agriculture may be able to in­
crease its bargaining power only through
greater use of the community-of-interest
principle. Most successful bargaining coop­
eratives have been operated under this prin­
ciple—that all parties to a bargain give some­
thing in return for a gain. In negotiating hog
contracts with packers, for example, bargain­
ing associations have agreed to deliver a
specified number of hogs to the packing plant
at specified times, to provide animals of speci­
fied quality and weight, and to absorb some
of the losses incurred as a result of damaged

carcasses. In return, packers have agreed to
pay a base price for hogs plus a premium for
quality carcasses. Such agreements reduce
the packer’s procurement and labor costs,
allow better scheduling of operations, and
ensure a steady flow of high-quality hogs. The
farmer receives a premium for producing
better hogs and is assured of a known market
for a specified number and quality of hogs.
The bargaining power of farmers may be­
come increasingly important as changes are
made in agricultural production, marketing,
and legislation. But bargaining power alone
will not solve the condition commonly known
as “the farm problem.” This problem springs
essentially from an overcommitment of re­
sources—primarily human resources—as is
evidenced by the continued decline in the
agricultural labor force and the chronic tend­
ency to produce more than can be sold at
prices “generally acceptable” to farmers.

Personal certificates— a stabilizer?
^ ^ . a n y banks have expanded their timedeposit services in recent years to include—
in addition to regular savings accounts—time
certificates or open-account deposits. Even in
certificates, many banks offer various sizes
and maturities or forms that emphasize
growth, income, or some other feature. By
offering an assortment of accounts, even
though the interest earnings are about the
same, banks can appeal to a variety of custom­
ers according to their preferences and needs.
Instruments differ from bank to bank—in
the method and frequency of computation
and payment of interest, in the minimum
balance required for interest, in the time



period for which funds must be committed,
in the amount that can be deposited or with­
drawn at any one time and in a variety of
other ways as well. One bank may offer, for
example, 3-, 6 - and 12-month 5-percent
certificates for a minimum of $ 1 ,0 0 0 , com­
pounding the interest quarterly, while another
offers 5-year certificates at the same rate, but
with interest compounded daily and requir­
ing a minimum investment of only $ 100 .
Despite such differences, however, users of
time deposit services are grouped the same at
all banks in at least one important respect.
The regulation authorized by the Banking
Act of 1935 defines three types of time de-

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

posit—savings accounts, certificates of de­
posit, and open accounts. Savings deposits
are usually held by people interested mainly
in the availability of their funds for immediate
withdrawal on request. Holders of certificates
and open accounts must be willing to wait at
least 30, and often 90, days or more for
instruments to mature or for the expiration of
notices to withdraw. While holders of both
certificates and open accounts must be willing
to commit their funds for specified periods,
open accounts are more flexible than certi­
ficates and, therefore, sometimes preferred
by depositors. Open accounts, which include
the so-called “golden passbook” accounts,
allow interim additions and withdrawals dur­
ing the term of the instrument thereby making
them closely resemble savings accounts.
W h y c e rtific a te s?

12

Banks pay more for certificate and openaccount funds than for savings accounts
partly because, with interest costs a large
part of total operating costs, the squeeze on
earnings can be reduced by limiting the
higher interest rate to only part of the ac­
counts they hold. This consideration becomes
less important, however, as more deposits
drift into higher yielding accounts.
Certificate promotion may also lower han­
dling costs by discouraging deposit transac­
tions. Unlike a saving account, a certificate
does not allow “activity” before the funds
are withdrawn. In addition, a range of ac­
counts differing more in their particular terms
than in their yield can discourage “compari­
son shopping” by savers and investors, and,
in turn, abate rivalry between competitors
over market shares.
For many banks, however, the clear ad­
vantage of certificate promotion is in port­
folio spacing. Because of the specified maturities of certificates, banks can better




predict when their liabilities will come due.
Such predictions are, in turn, helpful in fore­
casting liquidity requirements and in schedul­
ing asset maturities.
Role of ra te ceiling s

The vigor with which banks have pursued
the advantages of diversification in time in­
struments has depended, however, on the
intensity of the pressures they faced to find
loanable funds and the differentiations they
were allowed to make in interest rates. Until
1965, essentially the same ceiling applied to
all three types of time deposits.1 Conse­
quently, although use of rate differentials was
adopted sporadically by banks in Detroit and
a few other financial centers, differentials
were confined largely to banks serving
smaller communities, where competition for
funds was less intense and savings inflow
sufficient to take care of loan demand.
Faced with rising demand for credit and
growing need for funds, banks that had been
promoting alternative time instruments, espe­
cially the biggest banks in larger centers,
pushed their rates on savings accounts to the
limit in such years as 1961 and 1964— just
before new rate ceilings were set. Having
thereby eliminated a rate premium for certi­
ficate funds, they stopped promoting certifi­
cates. The result was a massive transfer of
funds into the more liquid savings accounts
within the banks.2
JA slight differential was introduced in late 1964
when the ceiling rate on certificates and openaccount deposits of 90 days or more was increased.
It was moved up only a half-point, however, over
the 4-percent ceiling on savings deposits.
Smaller banks may give greater consideration to
the advantage gained from knowing the maturity
of time liabilities than large city banks, since they
have fewer alternatives for coping with deposit
drains.
Likewise, the most important reason many banks,
especially larger ones, give for using a variety of
instruments and rates now is the 4-percent limit on

Business Conditions, October 1968

In December 1965, The Federal Reserve
and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corpora­
tion raised to 5.5 percent the ceiling on inter­
est rates commercial banks could pay on
certificates and open accounts. The hike,
from 4.5 percent on certificates and open ac­
counts with maturities of 90 days or more
and 4 percent on those for shorter periods,
widened the possible differential on various
types of instruments at a time when the high­
est rate banks were allowed to pay on savings
accounts was the same, as, or less than, the
dividend rates nonbank competitors paid on
similar accounts.
Returns on market securities were rising,
as were bank demands for loanable funds.
The new rate ceilings combined with market
pressures, therefore, encouraged banks to
innovate with new types of accounts paying
more than 4 percent designed to attract and
hold personal savings.
In September 1966, to restrict “unsound”
competition for personal savings and help
increase the availability of home mortgage
funds, regulatory agencies lowered to 5 per­
cent the top rate that could be paid by banks
on certificate and open-account deposits in
denominations of less than $ 100 ,0 0 0 , mainly
held by individuals. The only exception was
the ceiling on single-maturity time deposits
of $100,000 or more, which was left at 5.5
percent. Since then, the difference in rate
ceilings between regular savings accounts and
other time deposits under $ 100,000 has re­
mained fixed at 1 percent.
Effect on w ith d ra w a l a ctiv ity

An increase in time-account options to in­
clude higher rate certificates can increase
deposit totals but it also raises the troublesavings-account interest, the need to avoid sizable
deposit declines, and the possibility of attracting
additional deposit inflow by offering accounts at
higher rates.




some question of the effect of aggressive
bidding for funds on deposit withdrawal
activity overall. Because of fairly low and
generally predictable withdrawal rates, time
deposits (mostly savings deposits) have tra­
ditionally been thought of as funds available
for investment in mortgages and other long­
term assets. An increase in interest-sensitive
funds held in time accounts is thought to
expose banks to the risk of sizable with­
drawals if their interest rates fall behind those
offered by competitors or available from
security markets. If shifts can be expected,
then, growth in the proportion of time de­
posits in certificate form would imply the
need for greater liquidity and more short­
term marketable securities in bank portfolios.
Savings-account withdrawal activity in the
district increased sharply in early 1966 and
has remained high ever since. Amounts with­
drawn at banks in 51 urban areas in the first
six months of 1968, for example averaged
$5.90 a month for every $100 of average
balances. That is against $4.88 per $100 in
the first half of 1965—an increase of 20
percent.
Practices banks adopted to make savings
accounts more attractive—such as payment
of interest from day of deposit to the day of
withdrawal and the disbursement of funds
directly through money order and bank drafts
—may have induced shifts from checking
accounts to savings accounts, thereby increas­
ing the withdrawal activity. But at the same
time, by making savings accounts more at­
tractive, these practices also held more sav­
ings deposits, helping moderate withdrawal
volume.
The chief factor responsible for the in­
crease in savings-account withdrawals was
undoubtedly the diversion of funds to ac­
counts at savings and loan associations, credit
unions, and other investment media yielding

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

higher returns. In June 1968, the prevailing
rate on savings deposits in 42 of the 51 urban
areas of the district was 4 percent—the ceil­
ing rate. Against this, many savings and loan
associations paid 4.5 and 4.75 percent on
accounts that could be withdrawn on de­
mand. Over one-quarter of the district’s
credit unions paid 5 percent or more and
another one-quarter paid between 4.5 and
5.0 percent on regular share accounts. The
return on Series E savings bonds was 4.15
percent when held seven years, and Freedom
Shares were yielding 4.74 percent with four
and a half-year maturities.3
Competitive pressures on personal certifi­
cates were less. As with savings accounts,
rates on time certificates were at the ceiling.
Banks in all 51 areas paid 5 percent in June,
compared with a rate of 5 or 5.25 percent
paid by savings and loan associations. Then
too, bank certificates and open-account de­
posits offer some advantages over savings
and loan certificates. Some bank certificates
mature in less than the six months required
by savings and loan associations, and some
are offered in denominations of $100 or less.4
The “golden passbook” time accounts of­
fered by banks usually require only a 90-day
period before savings can be withdrawn.
Also, the yield spread of, say, 9- to 12month U. S. government issues over 1-year,
5-percent time certificates, after reaching a
high of 80 basis points in September 1966,
narrowed through mid-1967, and though ris­
ing, did not exceed the 1966 record until
May 1968, when the threat of “disintermedia­
tion” was again posed by deposit outflows to
the security market. The certificate with­
drawal rate for May was, nevertheless, only
$3.41 per $100, and $3.48 for the full first

14

Effective June 1, 1968 the rate on Series E bonds
was raised to 4.25 percent and on Freedom Shares
to 5 percent.




six months of this year. Even in some of the
district’s largest centers where depositor
sensitivity to yield might be greatest, certifi­
cate withdrawal rates were little higher than
in smaller places. Thus, in the district’s four
major areas (Chicago, Detroit, Milwaukee,
and Indianapolis), the certificate withdrawal
rate averaged $4.17 per $100 for the first
half of 1968—only 69 cents more per $100
than the average for the district.
Associated with higher savings-account
withdrawals in 1968 than in 1965 was a
lower level of certificate withdrawals. As a
result, the rise in withdrawals from all per­
4The Federal Home Loan Bank System has dis­
couraged large shifts of funds to certificates at sav­
ings and loan associations by establishing a 50percent limit on the proportion of an association’s
share capital that can be in the form of certificates
with a maturity of less than three years. The mini­
mum amount on certificates is $1,000. Associations’
efforts to stay within the 50-percent limit have fre­
quently contributed to savings and loan certificates
being issued in denominations of $5,000 or more.
Also, because most associations can pay no more
than 4.75 percent on regular savings and 5.25 per­
cent on certificates, the differential is only a half
percent, compared with a full 1 percent for com­
mercial banks. Another regulation working against
savings and loan certificates is the requirement that
certificates must be held at least six months to earn
a dividend rate above the associations’ rate on regu­
lar share accounts.
To assist associations close to the 50-percent
limit, the Federal Home Loan Bank relaxed its
rules, effective October 1, to permit an association
to issue certificates as long as the weighted average
of dividends on all its accounts does not exceed 5
percent.
Few mutual savings banks issue certificates. The
largest ones did not do so until April 1, 1968, when
the New York law was revised to enable banking
authorities to limit the ratio of certificates to total
deposits to within a 15- to 40-percent range. More­
over, the flat 5-percent maximum that mutual sav­
ings banks can pay on any account under Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation regulations restrains
offerings of certificates.
These regulatory restraints stem from public
supervisors’ concern over institutions’ vulnerability
to deposit and share decline from too much de­
pendence on interest-sensitive funds.

Level
sonal savings deposits
was only about half
the rise in the savingsaccount component.
Further evidence
that certificates have
helped hold down
withdrawal activity so
far this year comes
from a comparison of
areas in the district.
By 1968, the larger an
area’s proportion of
total personal savings
deposits represented
by c e rtific a te s, the
lower the rate of with­
drawals.
Effect on v a ria b ility

Withdrawals as a
percent of average bal­
ances has varied much
more from month to
month for personal
certificates than for
savings accounts, un­
doubtedly reflecting
the larger amounts in­
volved per certificate
and the greater sensi­
tivity of these balances
to yields. The variabil­
ity in the monthly cer­
tificate withdrawal
rates over the period
January 1966 to June
1968 were about 2.5
times as great as in
savings account with­
drawals.
Nevertheless, there
have been no system-




a n d v a r i a b i l i t y in w i t h d r a w a l a c t i v i t y r e l a t e d t o

p r o p o r t io n o f p e r s o n a l a c c o u n t s h e ld a s c e r t if ic a t e s
C e rtific a te s as p ercen t of
total p erso n al b a la n c e s , Ju n e 30, 1968
0-29

30-39

40-49

50 an d
over

A ll
are a s

$5.11

$ 5.2 6

$ 5.46

$5.57

$5.36

1.20

1.85

1.58

1.82

1.62

24

38

30

33

31

$ 3.80

$ 3.86

$ 2.74

$ 1.72

$2.99

2 .90

3.4 0

2 .10

1.02

2 .32

74

93

72

60

75

$ 4.8 5

$4.61

$4.37

$3.47

$4.32

1.17

1.68

1.37

1.16

1.34

24

43

32

33

33

M onthly w ith d ra w a l ra te s
(p e r $ 1 0 0 of a v e ra g e b a la n c e s) ’
J a n u a ry 1 9 6 6 to Ju n e 1968

S a v in g s a c c o u n ts
A v e ra g e
D e via tio n a ro u n d a v e ra g e
Rela tive

d e v ia t io n

(p e rc e n t)

P e rso n al c e rtific a te s
A v e ra g e
D e via tio n a ro u n d a v e r a g e
Rela tive d e v ia t io n

(p e rc e n t)

T o ta l
A v e ra g e
D e via tio n a ro u n d a v e ra g e
Rela tive d e v ia t io n

(p e rc e n t)

J u ly 19 63 to D ecem ber 1965

T o ta l
A v e ra g e

$3.99

$ 4.1 5

$3.81

$3.41

$3.84

D e via tio n a ro u n d a v e r a g e

.86

1.27

1.15

1.27

1.14

Re la tive d e v ia t io n

22

31

30

36

30

ll

12

16

12

51

(p e r c e n t )

N um ber of a r e a s
1 A v e ra g e , d e v ia tio n

arou n d a v e ra g e . an d re lat ve d e v ia tio n com puted fo r each
a re a an d a v e ra g e d fo r a ll a re a s w ith in s p e c ifie d g ro u p. D e viatio n of w ith d ra w a l
ra te s, a lte rn a te ly re fe rre d to as the sta n d a rd d e v ia tio n , d iv i ded by the a v e ra g e gives
the re la tiv e d e v ia tio n .
N o te: C o m m e rcial b an ks in the fo llo w in g a re a s are in clu d e d in the ta b lu a tio n :

C ertifica te s as proportion of to tal p erso n al b a lan c e s, Ju n e 3 0 , 1 9 6 8
Illin ois

Io w a

Bloom ington

16

Bu rling ton

C h a m p a ig n
C h icag o

33
22

C e d a r R ap id s
C lin ton

D a n v ille
D ecatur

34
44

C o u n cil B lu ffs
Des M oines

P e o ria

28

D ubuque

Q u a d C itie s
Rockford

53

M arsh allto w n

20

M ason C ity

S p rin g fie ld

40

M u scatin e
O ttum w a
S io u x C ity

In d ian a

W a te rlo o

G ra n d R apid s

35

67
42
34

Jack so n
K a la m a zo o
Lansin g

26
46
33

71
59
46

M uskegon
Port Huron

29
38

S a g in a w

22

47
62
57
77
37
60

An d erso n

42

Fort W a y n e
G ary-H am m o n d

42

M ichigan

40

A d ria n

31

In d ia n a p o lis

A nn A rb o r
Battle C re e k

22

La faye tte

48
69

M uncie

53

B a y C ity

South Bend

38

Detroit

18
35

T e rre H aute

47

Flin t

20

33

W isco nsin
A p p leto n
G re e n

B ay

49
55

K en o sha

40

M ad iso n

57

M anito w o c

38

M ilw a u ke e

29

O sh kosh
R acin e

45
49

S h e b o yg an

46

Seven th D istrict,
51 a r e a s

30

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

atic differences in the district in the size of
fluctuations in withdrawals rising out of
larger proportions of certificates. The average
variation in the 12 areas where certificates
accounted for at least half the deposits was
the same as the average for the district. This
similarity arises in part from offsetting
changes in the extent of variation in savings
and certificates accompanying the growth in
certificates.
Furthermore, a comparison of withdrawal
rates in the deposit total before and after the
1965 change in regulation—that is, for the
two periods, the 30 months from July 1963
to December 1965 and the 30 months from
January 1966 to June 1968, shows that,
while variability in withdrawal activity has
increased with more of personal savings in
the form of certificates, the increase was
small.
While the growth of balances in the form
of certificates worked towards the lower
overall withdrawal rate, the use of certificates
appears to have influenced variability very
little. This, no doubt, has been because the
rate ceiling on certificates of small denomina­
tions has generally been high enough for
banks to attract and hold individuals’ savings.
A fairly wide differential in the maximum
rates at a time when the demand for loanable
funds was increasing encouraged banks to
establish savings and investment programs
appealing to different types of customers.

W ithdraw als from savings
accounts in upward trend
since early 1967
withdrawals as percent of average balances
seasonally adjusted annual rate

Segmentation of depositors, however, did
not greatly change the basic nature of the
funds attracted and held by banks. Banks
were merely tapping a familiar source of
funds in a different way.
From experience in the Seventh District,
it appears that the risk of unanticipated with­
drawals large enough to disrupt the liquidity
provisions banks have made may well be
less, and certainly no greater, than when
banks confined their time offerings to conven­
tional savings accounts.

B U S IN E S S C O N D IT IO N S is p u b lish e d m o n th ly b y th e F e d e ra l R e se rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o . D en n is B. S h a rp e w a s p rim a rily
resp o n sib le f o r the a rtic le " B a r g a in in g p o w e r f o r f a r m e r s " a n d C h a rlo tte H. Scott fo r " P e rs o n a l c e rtific a te s —a s t a b iliz e r ? "
S u b scrip tio n s to B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s a r e a v a ila b le to th e p u b lic w ith o u t ch a rg e . For in fo rm a tio n co n cerning b u lk m a il­
in g s, a d d re ss in q u irie s to th e F e d e ra l R e se rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o , B o x 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , Illin o is 6 0 6 9 0 .
16

A r t ic le s m a y b e r e p r i n t e d




p r o v id e d s o u r c e is c r e d it e d .