View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

Business
Conditions
1 9 6 4 October

Contents
The trend of business

2

International developments
and monetary policy
Downturn in homebuilding?

5
13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

OF
TJ_he business uptrend gained momentum in
the summer and early fall, both in the nation
and the Midwest. Production, employment
and income rose at a quickened pace and
order backlogs of durable goods producers
continued to mount.
Major labor-management negotiations
were being resolved without widespread work
stoppages, although with more generous
package settlements than had been generally
anticipated. Increases of 4 to 5 per cent in
total hourly compensation in some industries
exceed average annual productivity gains of
slightly over 3 per cent for the economy and,
therefore, have long-run inflationary implica­
tions. In the near-term future, the avoidance
of strikes would help to maintain expanding
production and favorable supply conditions.
The index of wholesale prices, after six
and one-half years of relative stability, ap­
parently has been nudged slightly upward,
mainly by increases for metals and livestock.
Some factors behind these price increases are
transitory—for example, strikes and political
unrest abroad for copper, and the “farmers’
strike” for beef cattle and hogs. But any up­

BUSINESS

ward movement in the general price level
bears close watching. Price indexes provide
the thermometers that reflect the “overheat­
ing” of the economy that occurs when de­
mand for goods and services presses too
closely upon total productive capacity.
Is c a p a c ity cra m p e d ?

Since 1957, margins of unused manpower
and productive facilities have served as bar­
riers to the resumption of a general rise in
commodity prices. In recent months there
have been signs that these margins have nar­
rowed. While the total supply of workers re­
mains ample, there are widespread reports of
shortages of workers having the needed ex­
perience and skills. A similar situation pre­
vails in the case of plant and equipment. Total
capacity is not being taxed, but facilities that
produce some goods are being utilized fully.
Satisfactory measurements of capacity—
whether for individual plants, whole indus­
tries or the entire economy—are elusive.
Ceiling output in particular plants may be de­
termined at any given time by the number of
work shifts, the quality of labor force, man-

BUSINESS CONDITIONS js published monthly by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. George W . Cloos was
primarily responsible for the article, "The trend of business."
Subscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public without charge. For information concerning
bulk mailings, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, Illinois 60690.

2

Articles may be reprinted provided source is credited.




Business Conditions, October 1964

agement and equipment, the standards of in­
spection applied to finished products, the
product mix, the availability of supplies and
many other factors. Nevertheless, there are
a number of clues that give indications of
increases in demand relative to the ability of
producers to increase output. Among these
are changes in backlogs and delivery sched­
ules, as well as prices.
Unfilled orders for all types of durable
goods, which have been rising since last De­
cember, reached 51.6 billion dollars at the
end of August— an increase of 10 per cent
from the year-earlier period. Even larger in­
creases in order backlogs have been reported
for metals and most capital goods including
machine tools, freight cars and construction
machinery.
Typical delivery schedules for some types
of steel that are in strong demand such as
sheets and plates have stretched out substan­
tially in recent months, and producers of
some capital goods have been forced to
lengthen promised delivery times. In August,
22 per cent of the purchasing agents of Chi­
cago, representing many different businesses,
as compared with 10 per cent a year earlier,
reported that they were ordering supplies 60
days or more in advance of delivery.
But rising backlogs and lengthened deliv­
ery times must be viewed in perspective.
Despite the rise in unfilled orders of durable
goods producers, backlogs at the end of July
were only 2.7 times monthly shipments, com­
pared with 2.6 times a year earlier. Moreover,
this ratio remained near the postwar low.
Although most capital goods producers
have had large increases in orders this year,
many Midwest producers of equipment used
in agriculture, construction and industry indi­
cate that they could accommodate an even
larger volume of business without strain on
available capacity.



Building materials such as cement, lumber
and wallboard remain in ample supply. De­
livery schedules for most nondurable goods
including chemicals, paper products and pe­
troleum products have been well maintained
despite strong demand. Prices of some basic
chemicals have strengthened in recent months
after being under downward pressure for sev­
eral years, but there has been little general
tendency for prices of soft goods to rise.
Steel demand continues to mount as pro­
duction of goods containing steel rises further
and as moves to increase inventories are im­
plemented. In late September steel ingot pro­
duction reached an annual rate of 130 million
tons, far more than the 117 million tons the
industry turned out in record 1955. The pro­
duction rate is expected to move higher but
not approach closely the 165 million ton rate
that the industry is believed capable of reach­
ing under full draft.
The supply of basic steel is not likely to
constitute a bottleneck as it did as recently
as in 1955 and some earlier years; however,
capacity to produce plates and sheets of the
quality and dimensions desired by users al­
ready is being strained. If major steel users
should undertake to build inventories above
normal requirements, as has been reported in
the press, the supply situation could tighten
further. At present, the signs associated with
periods of peak steel demand in the past—
lowering of quality standards, sharp increases
in imports and “gray markets” in which steel
is resold at premium prices—have not been
apparent.
There have been reports of shortages of
freight cars, particularly gondolas used to
move steel products. Various substitutes have
been employed, including flat cars and high­
way haulers. In addition, railroads have been
renovating substantial numbers of freight
cars that had been scheduled for scrappage

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

4

and have boosted orders for new
Busine ss p la n t and equipment
equipment.
expenditures continue strong uptrend
In recent weeks various firms,
billion dollars
particularly producers of steel and
50
aluminum, have reopened facili­
Matonally odjutted annual rotat
ties that had been idle for years
and were slated for dismantling.
These occurrences dramatize the
vigor of the current expansion,
especially in the hard goods.
Activation of unused, obsolete
plants necessarily incurs substan­
tial start-up costs resulting from
the need to renovate equipment
and train additional personnel.
Also, operating expenses are
higher than for modern facilities.
On the bright side, the ability of
manufacturers to bring idle plants
into production testifies to the
flexibility of American industry
quarterly
1957
1958
1959
I9 6 0
1961
1962
1963
1964
when demand rises and consti­
Note: Third and fourth quarters 1964 estimated.
tutes a safety valve against infla­
in capital outlays was foreseen.
tionary pressures.
At the indicated level, this year’s capital
In short, pressure upon capacity appears to
expenditures are likely to slightly exceed 7
be concentrated in particular areas of demand
per cent of total spending on goods and serv­
and has not become nearly so general as in
ices—up from 6.7 per cent in the 1961-63
the mid-Fifties when inflationary pressures
period but well below the 8.4 per cent ratio
gained dominance. Stringencies are being re­
reached in 1956-57. The current level of
solved in some instances by steps to increase
capital spending, therefore, is not of boom
output through more extensive use of existing
proportions relative to total output nor is it
equipment. In addition, new facilities will be
expected to reach that stage in the months
completed in the months ahead in larger vol­
immediately ahead.
ume than in recent years.
Early evidence shows capital spending
C a p ita l e x p e n d itu re s risin g fu rth e r
plans for 1965 to be well advanced. Many
orders for large capital goods placed recently
In 1964 United States businesses expect to
contemplate deliveries six to nine months
spend 44.2 billion dollars on new plant and
hence. Construction contracts for manufac­
equipment, 13 per cent more than last year’s
turing buildings reported by F. W. Dodge in
record total. The current estimate, released
the January-July period were 16 per cent
by the Department of Commerce in Septem­
above last year in the nation and 29 per cent
ber, represents a moderate upward revision
from last March when a 10 per cent increase
higher in the Midwest. In addition, Iron Age




Business Conditions, October 1964

reports that new capital spending projects
approved by metalworking producers—in­
cluding primary metals, fabricated metal
products, machinery and transportation
equipment—in the second quarter were far
ahead of any previous quarter in the six-year
history of its survey. Approvals of new plans
by the steel industry were especially large.
Capital expenditure programs now under
way and in prospect, of course, are concen­
trated in facilities to produce those goods for
which demand is strongest. Cramped supply
situations that appear to be developing at
present, therefore, will be alleviated in time.
In the past, notably during the Korean War
and in the mid-Fifties, surges in capital
spending were so abrupt as to tighten bottle­

necks for some time and were followed by
sharp reductions in total outlays once the peak
had been passed. Such cutbacks in capital ex­
penditures typically have been associated
with general business recessions. It remains
to be seen whether the present movement will
continue to be kept within the limits that can
be accommodated by producers of capital
goods without sharp increases in backlogs
and prices that would have widespread effects
throughout the economy. If a capital expen­
diture boom is developing, it may be damp­
ened or offset by a leveling or decline in de­
mand for some consumer durables, housing
and military hardware. These segments of
demand combined substantially exceed total
spending on business plant and equipment.

International developments
and monetary policy
J. Herbert Furth, Adviser
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System*
jS ^ o n e ta ry policy and international devel­
opments are mutually interrelated.
Monetary policy affects international trans­
actions in four ways. Through the impact on
domestic price and wage movements, it influ­
ences the competitive position of domestic
industry and thereby the exports and imports
of goods and services. Through the impact on
cost and availability of domestic credit, it in*A paper presented at a Seminar on Central
Banking for college teachers of money and banking
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, September
10, 1964. The paper reflects the author’s personal
views and should not be interpreted as representing
the opinion of the Board of Governors.




fluences interest rate differentials and thereby
international flows of interest sensitive longand short-term capital. Through the impact
on profits and profit expectations, it influ­
ences international flows of equity capital, in­
cluding direct and portfolio investments. And
through the combined impact on all these
items in the balance of payments, monetary
policy influences expectations regarding ex­
change rate fluctuations and thereby interna­
tional flows of short-term funds for purposes
of speculation or hedging.
Developments abroad, in turn, affect mon­
etary policy through their impact on inter-

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

national commercial and financial transac­
tions. These transactions influence domestic
price and income levels, interest rates, profit
expectations and spot and forward exchange
rates; and the resulting changes in interna­
tional flows of funds affect the liquidity of the
banking system and of the economy as a
whole. Hence, developments abroad influ­
ence, at least marginally, all the variables
which the monetary authorities have to take
into account in deciding upon their policy
actions.
International considerations are particu­
larly important for monetary policy whenever
the monetary authorities feel under obligation
to influence a country’s balance of interna­
tional payments. Modest deficits or surpluses
may be disregarded, especially if they alter­
nate in reasonable periods so that they do not
produce a large and persistent inflow or out­
flow of monetary reserves. But if deficits or
surpluses show signs of becoming large and
persistent, the monetary authorities may feel
compelled to review their policies so as to
correct, or at the very least not to perpetuate
or aggravate, that imbalance.
M easu rin g th e d eficit

6

Sometimes it is difficult to decide whether
or not a country’s international payments are
in balance. In the year ending June 30, 1964,
for instance, the United States payments defi­
cit amounted to 1.8 billion dollars according
to the conventional calculation. This assumes
that debt prepayments received by the U. S.
Government are not to be considered regular
receipts—although the lending operations
that generate such debt are considered regu­
lar expenditures. If this peculiar assumption
is abandoned, the deficit is reduced to 1.0
billion dollars. The conventional calculation
also assumes that investments of foreign private short-term funds in the United States in




the form of bank deposits or money market
paper are not considered receipts either—al­
though again similar investments of United
States funds abroad are considered expendi­
tures. If this asymmetry is likewise removed,
the deficit is further reduced to 0.7 billion
dollars. Finally, one might take the position
—which I would not recommend but which
would conform to the practice of many for­
eign countries—that an increase in mediumterm debts of the Government such as the
issue of intermediate-term Treasury bonds
(commonly referred to as “Roosa bonds” )
to foreign monetary authorities and drawings
on the International Monetary Fund should
be considered as actions reducing rather than
financing the payments deficit. Under this
assumption, the United States deficit for the
year ending June 30, 1964, would be reduced
to the negligible amount of 0.2 billion dollars.
This problem of alternative methods of
computing the payments balance arises only
under our present international payments
system. Under the textbook version of the
gold standard, the balance was fully reflected
in changes in gold reserves and, through the
resulting adjustment in the country’s supply
of money and credit, eventually in movements
of the domestic price and income level.
Similarly, if we were to adopt the proposals
of some economists and permit all exchange
rates to fluctuate freely without central bank
intervention, changes in a country’s payments
balance would be automatically reflected in
fluctuations in its currency’s exchange rate,
and through the impact of these fluctuations
on import and export prices eventually re­
flected again in movements of the domestic
price and cost level.
This comparison illustrates the basic dif­
ference between the present international
payments system—which I like to call the
reserve currency system for reasons which

Business Conditions, October 1964

will soon become apparent—and the other
systems that have either been tried in the his­
tory of modern capitalism or have been pro­
posed by reform minded economists and poli­
ticians. Only under the present system do
monetary authorities enjoy— or suffer from—
a large though not unlimited degree of free­
dom from restraints imposed by changes in a
country’s payments balance.
In contrast to a system of freely fluctuating
exchange rates, the present system gives the
monetary authorities not only the right but
the duty of using their reserves or credit facili­
ties to avert rate fluctuations outside the nar­
row limit permitted under the Articles of
Agreement of the International Monetary
Fund—unless they shift to a new par value
for their currency.
In contrast to the gold standard, the pres­
ent system permits the monetary authorities
to offset the domestic effects of reserve
changes so as to keep the supply of money
and credit adjusted to domestic requirements.
Hence, changes in the payments balance are
not necessarily, and certainly not automati­
cally, reflected in changes in domestic prices
and incomes.
Obviously, the economic transactions mak­
ing for a payments imbalance (for example,
an export surplus) have some direct effect on
the domestic economy, regardless of the
ability of the monetary authorities to avoid an
impact on the resulting reserve changes on
the supply of domestic money and credit. But
given the appropriate use of the tools of mon­
etary policy, the authorities will be able to
deal with those effects in the same way as
with purely domestic disturbances.
Credit facilities for purposes of financing a
payments deficit were, needless to say, avail­
able to monetary authorities also under the
gold standard. But the volume of such credits
was strictly limited by considerations of their




effect on gold movements. United States mon­
etary history records several instances in
which the authorities found it difficult to bor­
row gold in case of need either from foreign
or from private domestic holders.
Under the present system, international
transactions are settled not only among pri­
vate bankers, businessmen or investors but
also among governments and central banks
primarily, if not exclusively, by means of a
few internationally acceptable currencies,
among which the dollar plays the most im­
portant role. Virtually, all central banks use
the dollar as the exclusive vehicle for their
foreign-exchange operations and therefore
must hold larger or smaller proportions of
their reserves in the form of dollars. Hence,
the present system is in effect based on a
reserve currency standard.
R e s e rv e c u rre n cie s “ e la s tic ”

Reserve currencies, in contrast to gold,
can be created by decision of the reserve cen­
ter’s monetary authority. Any United States
importer or investor can settle his foreign
obligations by paying dollars and can get
these dollars (through the intermediary of his
bank) from the Federal Reserve—as long as
the Federal Reserve is willing to make them
available. Any foreigner can do the same: he
can get the dollars either from his own central
bank—not only to the extent that that bank
holds dollar reserves, but beyond this point
as long as the Federal Reserve is willing to
make dollars available to that central bank—
or like a United States resident through a
domestic bank, again as long as that bank
can get them in turn from the Federal Re­
serve.
In this way, international liquidity can be
made as elastic as the monetary authorities of
the reserve centers decide. Insofar as periph­
eral, nonreserve countries can count on as-

7

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

sistance from those authorities, the freedom
of domestic monetary policies from balance
of payments constraints is enjoyed by the
peripheral countries as well as by the reserve
centers.
This freedom is further enhanced by the
emergence of an international lender of last
resort, the International Monetary Fund. At
any given time the resources of the fund are
limited to a specified amount. But this
amount can be increased by vote of its mem­
bers: in 1959 the limit was raised by one-half
and is widely expected to be raised further
next year. Here again, the limits depend on
the decision of the monetary authorities rather
than on the physical availability of gold.
Clearly, however, the possibilities of in­
creasing the supply of reserve currencies are
not unlimited. If the supply of dollars to for­
eigners became excessive, the universal ac­
ceptability would be threatened. The accepta­
bility of the dollar of an international means
of payments is more vulnerable than that of
domestic money. Domestically, money has
legal tender status. But in international trans­
actions, the use of any given means of pay­
ment is completely voluntary, and any de­
velopment that undermines confidence in its
stable value can put an end to its international
circulation.
For these reasons, any system based on the
use of a fiduciary asset such as a reserve cur­
rency as means of international payments
must necessarily and continuously be walking
a tightrope, trying to avoid the abyss of
liquidity shortage on the one hand and that of
excess liquidity on the other.
Risks an d o p p o rtu n itie s

8

Fortunately, the reserve currency system
has a built-in mechanism that keeps the sys­
tem approximately in balance. If the United
States suffers from a large and persistent pay­




ments deficit and as a result puts too many
dollars into international circulation, the dol­
lars tend to flow from foreign businessmen,
investors and commercial banks to their cen­
tral banks. These central banks in turn will
present their excess dollars to the United
States for redemption in gold or, under the
IMF articles, into their own currency. There­
by, they can force the United States to deplete
its gold reserves, or to draw the currencies of
surplus countries from the fund or to use its
credit, say, in the form of Roosa bonds. All
these steps put pressure on the United States
to correct its payments imbalance and thereby
to eliminate the source of dollar redundancy
abroad.
Conversely, if the international availability
of dollars is insufficient, foreign countries will
increase their pressure for assistance both
directly from the United States and from in­
ternational agencies. During the past 20
years, such pressures induced the United
States to help finance such agencies as the
International Monetary Fund and to institute
bilateral currency swaps. Moreover, the free­
dom from the constraints of the gold standard
permitted the United States to extend aid
through such schemes as the European Re­
covery Program, President Truman’s “Point
Four” program, the World Bank and its affili­
ates, the Inter-American Development Bank
and the Alliance for Progress.
To sum up, the freedom of domestic poli­
cies from payments constraints presents risks
as well as opportunities. This freedom has
enabled the Federal Reserve to offset com­
pletely the domestic effects of the outflow of
gold resulting from the United States pay­
ments deficit, and thus to generate the funds
that were needed to finance our economic ex­
pansion. Such policy, however, tends to im­
pede the equilibrating mechanism that was
generated under the so-called classical gold

Business Conditions, October 1964

standard. Since an outflow of gold no longer
necessarily results in a tightening of monetary
policy, with a resulting downward pressure
on prices and incomes and upward pressure
on interest rates, it no longer necessarily re­
duces imports or attracts foreign capital.
In other words, while the new system has
freed the world from the periodically recur­
ring danger of virtually automatic monetary
contraction, with its depressive effect on eco­
nomic activity, it has made possible larger
and more persistent payments imbalances.
A ch ie v in g b a la n ce

This situation does not pose any great dif­
ficulty if a country’s international surplus co­
incides with domestic underemployment or
its international deficit with domestic over­
employment. Expansionary monetary and
fiscal policies can remedy both ills in the first
case; restrictive policies can do the same in
the second.
A peripheral country is not faced with a
serious problem even in the two cases of what
is called in the fund articles “fundamental
disequilibrium”— that is, the coincidence of
domestic underemployment with a payments
deficit and of domestic overemployment with
a payments surplus. Currency depreciation or
appreciation again can correct both the un­
derlying domestic and the international costprice imbalance.
But if a country has an internationally im­
portant capital market, a change in its cur­
rency’s par value may well result in disruptive
international capital movements, as in the
German and the Netherlands revaluations in
March 1961. If the country is a reserve cen­
ter, a change in the par value of its currency
would destroy that currency’s function as an
international means of payments and as a
reserve asset. We know what happened to the
pound sterling, and in consequence to the net­



work of international trade and finance, when
sterling was devalued in September 1931.
Even in the case of a reserve center in
fundamental disequilibrium, the question of
eliminating a payments surplus presents no
insoluble policy problem. Any country can
presumably correct a payments surplus by
unilateral reduction in tariffs and other im­
port barriers. Such action would have the
same effects on imports as a revaluation of
the currency; but these effects would not ex­
tend to capital movements. Hence only the
problem of a large and persistent payments
deficit of a reserve center suffering from large
and persistent domestic underemployment is
really bothersome.
How do these considerations apply to the
present United States situation and to our
present problems of monetary policy?
The United States has suffered from the
one case of international imbalance for which
there is no fully satisfactory traditional rem­
edy. It has experienced, for the past seven
years, both considerable domestic under­
employment and a large payments deficit. Let
us see how this situation affects monetary
policy in regard to its main points of impact:
1 ) price-cost relations; 2 ) differences in
credit cost and availability; 3) profits and
profit expectations, and 4) exchange-rate ex­
pectations.
In three out of these four points, there is
no conflict between the domestic and inter­
national purposes of monetary policy. Do­
mestically as well as internationally, we must
preserve reasonable stability of costs and
prices—domestically, as the basis of sustain­
able and orderly growth; internationally, as
the basis of our trade surplus.
Domestically and internationally, we must
strive for an economic climate of continuous
growth and expansion permitting a reason­
able level of present and expected future

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

profits—domestically, in order to stimulate
investment; internationally, in order to stem
the outflow (and perhaps induce an inflow)
of equity capital.
Domestically and internationally, we must
maintain a stable exchange value of the dol­
lar—domestically, on grounds of equity and
in order to encourage saving, but especially
in order to permit rational long-range plan­
ning and accounting; internationally, in order
to avert disruptive speculative capital move­
ments.
In te re st ra te s

]o

There is only one point in which there
might be at times a divergence of domestic
and international considerations: the cost
and availability of domestic credit—in short,
the level of United States interest rates.
Domestically, we need a level as low as com­
patible with the avoidance of an inflationary
boom, in order to encourage enterprise and
investment. Internationally, we need a level
high enough to discourage outflows of inter­
est sensitive arbitrage funds.
Some observers believe that this goal can
be reached by keeping short-term rates high
and long-term rates low. They believe—
rightly—that domestic investment demand
depends more on the rates for long-term than
on those for short-term capital; and they be­
lieve—more questionably—that international
capital flows depend more on short-term than
long-term rates. Hence, they advocate what
has been called “operation twist”—concen­
tration of restrictive measures on short-term
rates, such as the discount rate, the Treasury
bill rate and bank deposit rates, and avoid­
ance of restrictive measures affecting long­
term rates. This operation means that a rela­
tively larger part of the public debt is financed
through short-term issues, and that Federal
Reserve open market transactions involve at




times the sale of bills and the purchase of
bonds.
But twist operations have obvious limits.
Successful debt management requires a bal­
ance between short- and long-term debt that
proves acceptable to the market and cannot
therefore be based exclusively on twist con­
sideration; and in fact, recent debt manage­
ment operations have on balance lengthened
rather than shortened the maturity of the pub­
lic debt.
Moreover, at least in the longer run, arbi­
trage between various maturities necessarily
tends to restore a market equilibrium be­
tween short- and long-term rates that may be
impervious to moderate twist operations of
debt management and monetary policy. Al­
though recent actions of the monetary au­
thorities have been concentrated on the short­
term sector, several long-term rates have
advanced in sympathy with short-term rates,
although, as usual, much less so.
And finally, the international effectiveness
of moderate unilateral changes in short-term
rates on the United States payments balance
is questionable. Immediately after the rise in
the Fed discount rate in July 1963, bank re­
ported outflows of short-term funds dropped
from 400 million dollars in the second quar­
ter to 100 million dollars in the third. But in
each of the following three quarters they rose
again to amounts larger than the record vol­
ume preceding the rate increase.
Three reasons may be advanced for this
disappointing result.
First, not all flows of short-term funds are
interest sensitive; quite a few of them depend
on such factors as, say, the volume of foreign
trade.
Second, insofar as these funds are interest
sensitive, they are primarily determined by
rate differentials rather than rate levels. If the
major foreign money market centers follow a

Business Conditions, October 1964

rise in United States rates— as they fre­
quently if not invariably tend to do— the
United States move cannot change the differ­
ential.
Third, in many if not most cases, move­
ments of short-term funds are covered against
exchange risks by forward exchange transac­
tions. In these instances, the determining dif­
ferential is based on gross interest rate’s dif­
ferences plus or minus a forward premium or
discount on the currency into which funds are
moved in relation to the currency out of
which they are moved and into which they
are expected to be repatriated. If a rise in the
discount rate is interpreted as a sign of weak­
ness in the country’s international payments
position, the forward rates for the currency
in question will deteriorate, and this deteri­
oration may fully, or even more than fully,
offset the advantage gained by the rise in the
gross interest rate differential.
As mentioned earlier, it seems doubtful
whether all movements of short-term funds
should be considered as affecting the pay­
ments balance. If Canadian banks offer
higher deposit rates than American banks,
and a United States corporation deposits its
funds with the New York agency of a Cana­
dian bank—has the net liquidity position of
the United States been damaged by that act?
After all, the increase in liquid dollar hold­
ings of the Canadian bank has been exactly
offset by the increase in liquid claims of
United States residents on the Canadian
bank. If this position is sound, most—though
by no means all—flows of short-term funds
become neutral from the point of view of pay­
ments analysis, and there is no sense in letting
monetary policy deviate from its domestic
interest rate standards for the sake of achiev­
ing an economically meaningless “statistical”
improvement in the payments balance.
This reasoning does not apply to long-term



flows—which, incidentally, in the case of the
United States are often larger than short­
term flows. The granting of a long-term
credit, in the form of bank loans or bond
issues, by a United States investor to a foreign
borrower means indeed a deterioration in the
short-run United States international liquidity
position—though not necessarily in the longrun position and obviously not in the United
States international net asset position. But
long-term flows cannot be affected by meas­
ures designed merely to raise short-term inter­
est rates. They can be affected only by meas­
ures tightening credit availability (or domes­
tic liquidity in general) and raising long-term
rate levels. In fact, since for obvious reasons
long-term rates in the relatively capital poor
foreign countries are and must remain, with
few exceptions much higher (even after ad­
justment for risk factors) than in the rela­
tively capital rich United States, only a seri­
ous tightening and a resulting large increase
in long-term rates could hope to influence
long-term flows of American capital.
Fiscal v e rsu s m o n e ta ry policy

For this reason, changes in long-term dif­
ferentials may be proper goals of fiscal rather
than monetary policy. The recently enacted
Interest Equalization Tax (IET) means for
some specified types of financing the creation
of an artificial 1 per cent differential between
long-term rates in the United States and in
developed countries outside the Western
Hemisphere. It therefore takes the place of a
monetary policy that would have had to be so
restrictive as to raise long-term rates by 1
per cent. Under existing conditions of under­
employment, such a restrictive policy would
presumably have done great harm to domestic
real investment and hence to output, employ­
ment and economic growth.
It is too early to tell whether this pioneer-

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

12

ing experiment in the use of fiscal rather than
monetary measures for the purpose of affect­
ing interest rate differentials will turn out to
be successful. If it does, it may open the way
to a completely new consideration of pay­
ments adjustments. Until recently, virtually
all adjustments were made or attempted pri­
marily if not exclusively by means of influ­
encing price-cost differentials in merchandise
trade; fiscal measures of the type of the IET
could lead to adjustments primarily or exclu­
sively through creation or elimination of
price-cost differentials in credit and capital
flows. Such adjustments should have fewer
adverse repercussions on money incomes and
thus on real economic activity in both the
deficit and the surplus countries since they
would be free of deflationary or inflationary
implications.
But this would not mean that monetary
policy would be relegated to a minor role.
Simultaneously with the first exploration of
these new means of fiscal policy, the Federal
Reserve has experimented with new tools of
international monetary policy, that is, mu­
tual holdings of major currencies. At present,
only the first steps in this direction have been
taken. The Fed has concluded “swap” ar­
rangements with 12 foreign central banks,
involving a potential total of 2 billion dol­
lars. These arrangements permit the partici­
pants to draw funds for periods of three
months, renewable for a maximum total
period of one year, under full exchange value
guarantee. They are designed to avoid dis­
orderly exchange markets or disruptive tem­
porary and reversible flows of short-term
funds. They are not designed to correct or
even finance a more basic payments dis­
equilibrium.
If, however, mutual currency holdings be­
come a matter of routine, it would be possible to free such holdings from the restrictions




of the present swap arrangements and to
finance longer payments swings by changes
in the mutual balances. Such use of mutual
currency holdings would be an even more
important supplement to present sources of
international liquidity, without interfering
with the basic functions of the existing pay­
ments system.
But these technical experiments should not
blind us to the more basic problems of inter­
national monetary policy. The theory and
practice of monetary policy in general, and
of international monetary policy in particu­
lar, have all too long resembled the state of
medicine painted by Moliere, when doctors
allegedly discussed only whether every illness
should be treated by bleeding or by purging.
Our European brethren and some of their
domestic followers tell us that all ills could be
cured by monetary restriction; and some of
our domestic critics, economists as well as
politicians, tell us that they could be cured by
monetary expansion, perhaps facilitated by a
preordained rate of rise in the money supply,
by flexible exchange rates or by an interna­
tional supercentral bank.
The two examples of new financial instru­
ments just mentioned may suggest that there
is more to international monetary policy than
simple expansion or contraction. But before
we can hope to discover further instruments,
or even to use the existing ones to full capa­
city, we must learn far more about the actual
working of the international monetary sys­
tem. All too many economists have spent the
last few years in explaining why the system
does not work perfectly: few if any have
bothered to try to explain why and how it
works at all. As teachers of international
monetary theory and policy, you will be
able to lead your students into virgin land
that is waiting for fresh minds to explore
its wonders.

Business Conditions, October 1964

Downturn in homebuilding?
^R esidential construction, as measured by
private nonfarm housing starts, has moved
erratically downward since late 1963. In
August of this year, starts were at an annual
rate of slightly less than 1.4 million units.
This was well under the rate of more than 1.6
million in the closing months of 1963 and
the first quarter of this year and somewhat
below the level in the second quarter.
Until recently in the current business ex­
pansion, which began in early 1961, homebuilding had been growing at a faster rate
than overall activity. Compared with yearearlier levels, private nonfarm housing starts

P riv a te nonfarm housing starts
have been declining recently
million units




were up 4 per cent in 1961, 12 per cent in
1962 and 8 per cent in 1963; by contrast,
year-to-year gains in gross national product
(in constant dollars) during the same periods
were only about half as great.
There have been three major postwar
cycles in residential construction. The first of
these topped out in 1950, the second in 1955
and the third in 1959. Concern has been ex­
pressed recently that the latest expansion in
homebuilding may be similarly topping out
this year, if indeed it has not already done so.
Contributing to the impression that hous­
ing construction may be past its fourth post­
war peak is a decline in permit activity. Since
the issuance of permits usually precedes ini­
tiation of construction, movements in permit
volume give an indication of the forthcoming
trend in starts. In the second quarter of 1964,
the annual permit rate (seasonally adjusted)
averaged 7 per cent below the first quarter. A
further small decline occurred in the average
July-August rate.
Indications of a downturn in residential
construction have appeared against a back­
ground of stable vacancy rates and rising
rents and construction costs, the latter attrib­
utable largely to rising wages in the building
trade.
C o n tra ct a w a rd s at high le v e l

Although the number of starts has been
drifting downward, the volume of construc­
tion contract awards during the first seven
months of 1964 suggests that the pace of
homebuildings should continue at a high, if
declining, level through at least the remainder
of the year. Residential contracts, reported by

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

•

the F. W. Dodge Corporation, totaled 11.9
billion dollars from January to July this year
—up 6 per cent from the comparable months
of 1963. The margin over a year ago, however, has been narrowing somewhat since the
early months of 1964.
Similarly, commitments by savings and
loan associations and life insurance compa­
nies to finance future housing construction
increased over this period. During the first
half of 1964, outstanding mortgage commit­
ments of savings and loan associations were
an estimated 8 per cent above last year’s level
while those of life insurance companies were
up almost as much.

Vacancy ra te s remain stable
per cent

9

'

M ulti-unit housing p a ce sla c k e n s

14

In recent years the fastest growing segment
of the housing market has been the multi­
unit structure. Nationally, such units ac­
counted for 38 per cent of private nonfarm
starts in 1963 as compared with 26 per cent
in 1960.
Amid continued reports of “overbuilding,”
the number of apartment permits authorized
on a seasonally adjusted basis has been
trending downward since the beginning of
1964. Nevertheless, several factors indicate
that apartments and other multi-family units
will continue to constitute an important seg­
ment of housing construction and may be
relatively stronger than the single-unit cate­
gory. Among the more important of these are
the changing age composition of a continually
growing population and the increasing dis­
tances and costs of local transportation in
large metropolitan areas.
The course of multi-unit construction is re­
lated to the increasing proportions of the
young and the old in the total population.
Young married couples tend to live in apart­
ments while accumulating savings for downpayments on houses; older persons often re-




turn to apartments from single-family homes
in order to enjoy the economy and easier
maintenance of smaller quarters. In the past
two or three years, townhouses and condo­
minium apartments and comprehensively
planned residential communities, especially
tailored to appeal to older couples, have ac­
counted for a growing share of the multi­
unit housing market.
M idw est building w e ll up from 1 9 6 3

During the first seven months of 1964, per­
centage gains from the corresponding yearearlier period in the number of permits to
build residential units in several important
District areas have been much larger than for
the nation.
Demand for housing in the Detroit area has
been stimulated by increased employment
and income associated with the high level of
auto production. Permits were up 27 per cent
over 1963 in the initial seven months of 1964,
following a 14 per cent increase in 1963 and
a 23 per cent gain the previous year. His­
torically, residential construction in Detroit
has been concentrated in single-family dwell-

Business Conditions, October 1964

ings and during the first half of 1964 permits
for such structures accounted for 67 per cent
of the total issued. The multi-family compo­
nent has been growing, however, as single­
family permits had represented 72 per cent of
the total in 1963 and 90 per cent in 1961.
The Chicago metropolitan area, with a
population approaching 7 million, is the larg­
est housing market in the Midwest. Permits
for the first seven months of 1964 were up 1
per cent from a year earlier. This upturn fol­
lowed year-to-year declines of 7 per cent in
1963 and 8 per cent in 1962. Apartment ac­
tivity continues to be important in the Chi­
cago area with permits amounting to 51 per
cent of the total as compared with 44 per cent
for the nation.
Milwaukee has experienced a large in­
crease in homebuilding activity this year. For

the first seven months, permit volume was
up 15 per cent from the comparable 1963
period. This follows a year-to-year increase of
17 per cent in 1963 and decline of 16 per
cent in 1962. Milwaukee’s proportion of per­
mits issued for multi-family units is slightly
above the nation’s.
Of the major District cities, only Indian­
apolis has had a decrease in permits in 1964.
During the first seven months of the year,
permits were 5 per cent below 1963. This
compares with a 1962-63 rise of 3 per cent
and a year-earlier gain of 7 per cent. About
half of the Indianapolis permits issued this
year, as well as last, have been for multi­
family construction. This is sharply above the
multi-family proportions of 28 per cent in
1962 and 14 per cent in 1961.
M o rtg ag e c re d it e x p a n sio n continues

H o using permit activity
has been stronger in the District
than in the nation this year

7 months




The 1961-63 upswing in housing construc­
tion in the United States has been accompa­
nied by a large increase in mortgage debt.
From December 1960 to December 1963,
mortgage debt on one-to-four family nonfarm
homes rose 41 billion dollars, an increase of
29 per cent.
Since 1960, savings and loan associations
have expanded their mortgage holdings by
approximately 13 per cent each year, a rate
exceeding any other major group of mortgage
lending institutions. With loans increasing an
additional 2 per cent in the first quarter of
1964, the associations’ share of total mort­
gage loans outstanding reached 44 per cent,
compared with 39 per cent in 1960.
In contrast, the share of total home mort­
gages held by life insurance companies
dropped from 18 to 15 per cent during the
same period, as acquisitions by these firms
grew less rapidly than the total supply of
mortgages. Mutual savings banks recorded a
small increase in their share of home mort-

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

gage outstandings, moving up from 13 per
cent in 1960 to 14 per cent in the first quar­
ter of this year.
The proportion of total home mortgages
held by commercial banks did not change
between 1960 and the first quarter of 1964,
remaining at 14 per cent. Banks increased
their mortgage holdings slightly in 1961, and
then, as time deposits increased rapidly, they
expanded their acquisitions at a pace faster
than the average for all mortgage investors in
1962 and 1963.
A gradual decline in mortgage interest
rates has paralleled the large increase in mort­
gage debt. Nationally, the Federal Housing
Administration reported that the average in­
terest rate for conventional mortgages on new
homes peaked at 6.30 per cent in mid-1960
and then decreased to 5.95 per cent in June
1961, 5.90 per cent in December 1962, 5.80
per cent in May 1963 and has remained un­
changed since. Rates for mortgages on used
homes have followed a similar pattern.
In contrast, yields on long-term govern­
ment bonds have been trending upward since
1961. They averaged 3.90 per cent in 1961,
3.95 per cent in 1962, 4.00 per cent in 1963
and reached 4.14 per cent in August of this
year.
More inclusive information on conven­
tional contract mortgage interest rates and
other loan terms has been available from the
Federal Home Loan Bank Board since De­
cember 1962. These data also indicate a
drop in mortgage interest rates in the second
half of last year. Furthermore, they indicate a
slight further easing of rates in 1964 as, for
example, a slight decline from 5.80 per cent

16




M ortg a g e te rm s on new homes
have eased since last winter
per cent

6.0 '

i 22
in te r e s t r a t e

ss.
58 "

---------

1963

„
___

1964

in December 1963 to 5.76 per cent in July
1964 for new home mortgages. The pattern
was similar for mortgages on used homes.
While mortgage rates have declined, other
mortgage terms also have eased. In particu­
lar, maturities have lengthened and the aver­
age size of loans relative to the value of
the property has increased. For example, na­
tional average maturities on new home mort­
gages increased gradually from 23.3 years in
December 1962 to 24.5 years in July 1964.
Maturities for used home mortgages followed
a similar pattern. National average loan-tovalue ratios on new home mortgages rose
from 72.0 per cent in December 1962 to 74.8
per cent in February 1964 and then declined
to 73.9 per cent in July.