View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

a n e c o n o m ic re v ie w b y th e F e d e ra l R eserve B a n k o f C hicago




Interbank lending—
an essential function

Dwindling world
grain reserves
Banking developments

novem ber
1974




Interbank lending—
an essential function

3

Dwindling world grain reserves

8

Current analyses focus on the trend of
the federal funds rate as an indicator
o f the thrust o f m onetary policy. Too
little attention has been paid to some
im portant economic functions o f the
interbank loan m arket.

Longstanding trends in production
and consum ption have led to the
current tight conditions in world
grain reserves.
Banking developments

13

Subscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public free of charge. For
information concerning bulk mailings, address inquiries to Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, P. O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.
Articles may be reprinted provided source is credited. Please provide the bank’s
Research Department with a copy of any material in which an article is reprinted.

3

Business Conditions, November 1974

In te rb a n k lending
an essential function
The federal funds rate has become a closely
watched indicator o f changes in money
market pressures. This rate, as published,
is a weighted average o f the interest rate
paid on unsecured loans between banks for
one day at a time. It tends to be at the low
end o f the spectrum o f m oney market rates
in periods o f m onetary ease and at the high
end when authorities are trying to restrain
m onetary expansion. These swings over
the interest rate cycle reflect changes in the
w illingness o f the monetary authorities to
supply the banking system with sufficient
reserves to support the current pace o f
deposit growth. If deposits are growing
faster than desired, the Federal Reserve
slows down the rate at which it supplies
reserves through open market operations
so that the cost o f reserves (federal funds
rate) rises and discourages banks from ex­
panding deposits and their holdings of
assets (loans and investments).
With current analyses generally focus­
ing on the trend o f the federal funds rate as
an indicator o f the thrust o f monetary
policy, too little attention has been paid to
some important econom ic functions the in­
terbank loan market performs, whatever
the policy posture. First, it contributes
greatly to the efficiency o f the banking
system in serving both credit and deposit
customers. Second, it enhances the pre­
cision with which monetary policy is
implemented.
Every day several billion dollars are
sold (loaned) by some banks and purchas­
ed (borrowed) by other banks in the federal
funds market. Some transactions are
arranged directly between the buyer and
seller, but a large portion o f total activity is




arranged through brokers. The great bulk
o f the dollar volum e is in the form of
transfers between deposit balances, also
called “ reserves,” o f member banks at the
Federal Reserve. Such shifts are effected
for immediate credit to the borrower by a
telephone or wire order on the part o f the
lending bank. N onm em ber banks also par­
ticipate in the interbank loan market,
through the reserve balances o f their cor­
respondents who are members.
There is no measure o f the total
amount o f such interbank loans, but daily
reports from about 50 m ajor money market
banks alone often show transactions
aggregating more than $15 billion, equal to
nearly h a lf o f the total outstanding
member bank reserves. Individual trans­
actions range from less than $100 thou­
sand to more than $100 million. What ac­
counts for the demand and supply o f very
short-term funds on the part o f banks?

The role of reserves
Reserves held by member banks at the
Federal Reserve are working balances
through which m any transactions (such as
check clearings) are channeled. A bank
that has a greater value o f checks written
on its deposits than the value of checks
deposited with it written on other banks
pays the difference by drawing down its
reserve account. N orm al deposit flows
between depositors o f the thousands of
commercial banks in the United States
result in significant shifts in the distribu­
tion o f reserves am ong individual member
banks.
Besides the need to hold funds on

4

deposit with the Reserve banks to effect
such payments, the Federal Reserve re­
quires that member banks hold on average
for each weekly reporting period (Thurs­
day through W ednesday), an amount o f
reserves—“ required reserves” —equal to a
specified percentage o f deposits. By setting
the percentage o f deposits that must be
held as reserves (i.e., reserve requirements)
and controlling the overall level o f reserves
in the banking system, the monetary
authorities im pose a ceiling on the quanti­
ty o f deposits and credit that can be created
by member banks. A member bank whose
reserves just satisfy its reserve require­
ment is vulnerable to becom ing deficient in
reserves in the event o f an unanticipated
deposit outflow. This follow s since every
dollar o f net deposit outflow lowers
reserves by a dollar, while required
reserves fall by only a fraction o f a dollar.

Managing reserves
A member bank can meet a reserve
deficiency in a number o f ways. Normally,
a bank will use w hichever w ay it finds to be
least expensive. The bank can replenish
reserves by selling assets. While this ap­
proach will produce the necessary reserve
adjustment, it is inefficient, both for the in­
dividual bank and the system. It means a
great number o f transactions, with all the
costs involved in buying assets when
deposits and reserves flow into the bank
and selling assets when deposits and
reserves flow out. This is a cumbersome
w ay to make day-to-day adjustments, and
involves the risk o f loss due to changes in
market values.
Another alternative is to borrow
reserves from the Federal Reserve discount
window at the adm inistratively set dis­
count rate. But the borrow ing privilege is
not freely available on a regular basis. Its
purpose is to cover unusual and temporary
needs, and adm inistration o f the window
imposes an im plicit cost in the form o f sur­




Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

veillance o f member banks that use it over
extended periods o f time. Thus, today’s
borrowings tend to reduce the willingness
o f the Federal Reserve to accom m odate
future borrow ings by the bank.
A third approach for meeting potential
deposit outflows is for a bank to maintain
reserves at a higher level than required
reserves dictate. This involves a cost in
that the bank foregoes the return it could
have earned on the “ excess” reserves if
they were invested in assets.
The interbank loan market offers
banks yet another method o f adjusting to
deposit inflow s and outflows. These trans­
actions, usually referred to as “ federal
funds,” take advantage o f the fact that an
outflow o f deposits and reserves at one
bank is usually m atched by an equal in­
flow o f deposits and reserves at another
bank. Thus, a loan equal to the deposit flow
from the bank with the deposit inflow to
the b a n k w ith the deposit outflow
eliminates the disturbance to reserve
positions at both banks. Since the inter­
bank loan market serves as both a source
and outlet for reserves, it increases the ef­
ficiency o f reserve usage by permitting the
banking system to operate with lower
levels o f excess reserves. This greater ef­
ficiency, in turn, tends to increase the ear­
nings o f depositors (either in the form o f in­
terest or services) and to lower bank in­
terest charges to borrowers.

Market behavior
Since member banks must satisfy
their reserve requirements over a weekly
settlement period, the interbank loan
market exhibits a distinct weekly pattern.
Early in the settlement week (Thursday,
Friday, and M onday), the federal funds
rate tends to be fairly stable and slightly
above the weekly average. On these days,
the reserve positions o f individual banks
and the banking system as a w hole are still
relatively unclear and subject to change as

Business Conditions, November 1974

the week progresses, so that the interest
rate on interbank loans tends to hover near
the banking system ’s expected rate for the
week. This expected rate is likely to be
heavily influenced by the interbank loan
rates in recent weeks.
A n y deviation from the expected rate
would cause banks to vary the relative use
they make o f the interbank loan market
and the asset market and tend to eliminate
the deviation. With a rate above the ex­
pected rate, the interbank loan market
would attract sellers and discourage
buyers o f reserves. Conversely, an inter­
bank loan rate below the expected rate
would cause the asset markets to gain
sellers and lose buyers o f reserves. This is
especially so since the earlier in the week a
bank makes an asset adjustment, the
longer the holding period and the smaller
the volum e o f transactions necessary to
offset a given absolute loss o f reserves.
Since transaction costs rise with the size
and number o f the transactions, the earlier
in the week the adjustment is made, the
lower the transactions cost. These shifts
from interbank loans to asset adjustments
do tend to spread any upward or downward
pressures on the fed funds rate to other
short-term debt markets.

The federal funds rate tends to
be higher early in the week, de­
clining as the week progresses.
daily rate as percent of weekly average

T .0 2 4
•1

T.1.025

i

T

1.015

Parenthesis enclose one standard devia­
tion (a measure of dispersion) above and
below the mean Standard deviation is the
square root of the sum of squares of
deviations of observations from the mean
of the observations divided by one less
than the total number of observations.

T

J 1 .000

I

• 0 .9 36

i

J
____ I____ L
Thurs.

Fri.

Mon.

Tues. Wed.

Data fro m Federal Reserve Bank o f New York,
D a ily E ffe c tiv e Federal F unds Rate, S e p te m b e r
21, 1968-S eptem ber 11, 1971.




5

Later in the week (Tuesday and
Wednesday), the federal funds rate is more
volatile and tends on average to decline
from its level earlier in the week. The rate is
more volatile because the relationship
b etw een reserves held and required
reserves within the settlement week
becomes clearer and the possibility of a
reversal o f deposit flow s within the settle­
ment week has diminished. In addition, in­
dividual banks are more willing to accept a
federal funds rate that is sharply different
from the longer-run expected average
because the transactions cost o f adjusting
reserves through asset changes late in the
week is relatively high. The closer the end
o f the settlement week, the larger the
volume o f asset changes required to offset
a given reserve loss for that week.
Because the probabilities o f deposit
outflows decline as the end o f the settle­
ment week approaches, the need for a
cushion o f excess reserves declines and the
federal funds rate tends to m ove down.
Faced with accumulated excess reserves
that approach worthlessness at week’s
end, the bank is w illing to loan reserves at
a lower rate. A bank waiting until the end
of the settlement week to make up a reserve
deficiency will, on average, get funds at a
lower rate, but will be risking greater
variance from the longer-run average rate.

The market and credit allocation
The interbank loan market also
assists the banking system in achieving a
more efficient distribution o f credit. Banks
serve an intermediary role in the allocation
o f credit—acquiring funds when deposits
are made by the public, then using these
funds to extend credit through loans or the
purchase o f securities. However, deposits
are not likely to be distributed among
banks in such a w ay that the best credit
needs o f the econom y can be efficiently met
by each bank individually at the local
level, especially in a banking system with

6

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

many unit banks that operate in fairly
small market areas.
Some banks are unable to satisfy
relatively attractive credit requests out o f
their own deposits, while other banks have
surplus funds after satisfying relatively
less attractive credit requests. By enabling
individual banks to be continuous lenders
or borrowers o f funds over sustained
periods o f time, the interbank loan market
divorces the extension o f credit from the
ability o f individual banks to attract
deposits. A gain, this increases the efficien­
cy o f the credit market, raising the return
to deposit holders and lowering the cost of
bank credit to borrowers.
Data available on federal funds trans­
actions indicate that smaller banks in the
aggregate are net lenders and larger banks
are net borrowers, although the size and
com position o f these flow s vary greatly in
the short run in response to temporary
deposit shifts. Small banks usually par­
ticipate in the market through their larger
correspondents, which, in turn, offset any
undesired im pact on their own positions in
the national market.
B a n k s that are p ersisten t net
borrowers (buyers o f federal funds) are
financing part o f their assets through the
interbank loan market. Banks that are
Large banks tend to be net buyers of federal
funds, while small banks are net sellers

8 m oney m arket banks
45 other weekly
reporting banks
8 8 0 other district
member banks

Average daily
net purchases
of federal2
funds: 1973

(m illio n s)

Seventh Federal Reserve
District Banks

Average total
deposits:1
1973

(m illio n s)

3 5 3 9 .8 9

24 9 .1 5

4 3 3 .5 7

12 .86

The market and monetary policy

3 2 .2 6

-1.08

The Federal Reserve usually im­
plements monetary policy by buying or
selling governm ent securities in the open
market. This alters the level o f reserves in

1 Data from June 1973 and December 1 9 73 call reports.
2 Data from Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago fo r 1973.




continuous lenders (sellers o f federal
funds) are passing up the return on credits
they could extend to other customers in
favor o f the return on interbank loans.
This behavior is reasonable for both buyer
and seller if the rate on interbank loans is
below the rate o f return available to the
buying bank on its loans and investments,
but above the rate available to the selling
bank.
Lending or borrowing funds in the in­
terbank loan market over sustained
periods o f time involves an element o f in­
terest rate risk when effected through a
series o f one-day loans. The decision to use
the federal funds market as either a source
o f or outlet for funds over a sustained
period incorporates expectations about the
course o f interst rates, by both borrower
and lender. If the one-day loan rate rises
above the lender’s expected levels, then his
return increases; a fall below his expected
levels decreases his return. Conversely, a
rise above the borrower’s expected one-day
rate lowers his return, while a fall below in­
creases his return.
Reallocating funds to higher rates of
return within the banking system could be
a ccom p lish ed without subjecting the
banks involved to the risks o f interest rate
fluctuations by m atching the maturity of
the asset purchased, or foregone in the case
o f the lender, with an interbank loan of
equal maturity. In recent years, the
development o f the market in so-called
“ term federal funds” has this potential.
While involving transfers o f immediately
available reserves, these interbank loans
may have maturities o f as long as one year,
but the rate o f interest over the maturity o f
the loan is set at inception.

Business Conditions, November 1974

the banking system and thereby the quan­
tity o f bank deposits, bank credit, and the
level o f interest rates. The Federal Reserve
pays for the securities it buys with a check
drawn on itself. When the check is
deposited by the seller o f the securities, it
increases reserves and generates an ex­
pansion in bank deposits, an increase in
bank credit, and a lowering o f interest
rates. Similarly, a sale o f government
securities by the Federal Reserve is paid for
by a check drawn on reserve balances so
that bank reserves fall, lowering deposits
and bank credit, and raising interest rates.
Because policy action has its first im ­
pact on bank reserves, because the federal
funds market reflects the relationship of
the supply and demand for these reserves,
and because banks have choices between
interbank loans and other money market
instruments, this market tends to serve as
a conduit through w hich the effects o f
policy are spread throughout the credit
markets. The holding o f excess reserves—
reserves which are not used to full poten­
tial in supporting deposits—constitutes a
slippage in the process o f implementing
policy. Unexpected fluctuations in the
percentage o f total reserves held as excess
reserves ham per m onetary policy by in­
ducing fluctuations in the level o f bank
deposits, the quantity o f bank credit ex­
tended, and the level o f interest rates. By
permitting banks to offset flow s o f funds
within the banking system, the interbank
loan market reduces fluctuations in excess
reserves and thereby increases the preci­
sion o f m onetary policy.
T h e fe d e ra l fu n d s market also
provides valuable inform ation for the
short-run implementation o f monetary
policy. The m onetary authorities face a
number o f problems in determining what
daily open market actions are appropriate
to the achievem ent o f money, credit, and




7

interest rate targets. Deposit changes, for
example, are not known accurately for a
week or two. A n d despite elaborate projec­
tions, the volum e o f reserves is not known
precisely until the follow ing day.
These uncertainties are important
because open market operations are not
the only factor causing changes in the
reserves o f the banking system. There are
three principal sources o f uncertainty in
reserve fluctuations: (1) drains or inflow s
due to exchanges by the banks o f vault
cash for reserves at the Federal Reserve;
(2) changes in the amount by w hich credits
made to payee member bank reserve ac­
counts in the check clearing process exceed
funds not yet collected from paying banks
( k n o w n as F ed era l R eserv e float);
(3) changes in the rate at which the
Treasury’s balance at Federal Reserve
banks are disbursed to commercial banks.
These outside factors, which often affect
reserves by several hundred million
dollars in a single day, produce changes in
deposits and interest rates in precisely the
same way as Federal Reserve operations.
In attempting to achieve desired
monetary effects in its day-to-day actions,
the Federal Reserve estimates the inter­
bank loan rate that is consistent in the
short run with the desired level o f deposits
and supporting reserves. Movements o f the
actual rate outside the targeted range
provide clues that reserves are either insuf­
ficient or excessive, and consequently
point to the need for policy actions.
Thus the rate on interbank loans per­
form s as a two-directional transmitter. It
signals temporary im balances in the
market that trigger day-to-day open
market action. But over weeks or months,
the trend o f this rate reflects the monetary
authorities’ response to the strength o f
credit demands and monetary growth.

Robert D. Laurent

8

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

D w in d lin g
w o rld
I
grain

■

reserves
World grain consum ption has expanded
sharply in the Seventies in response to
both population growth and rising world
a f f lu en c e. D u rin g the same period,
however, adverse weather conditions have
slowed the rate o f increase in world grain
production. A s a result, world grain
r e s e r v e s — a s m easu red by e n d i n g
carryover stocks—are likely to fall below
87 m illion metric tons* by mid-1975. This
level would be 54 percent below the record
h ig h level o f the late Sixties, and
equivalent to about 9 percent o f the w orld’s
annual grain consumption.
The current tight grain reserve situa­
tion w as a m ajor reason for holding the re­
cent W orld Food Conference in Rome.
Although a number o f issues were in­
volved, the basic concerns o f the con ­
ference centered on the necessity to
stimulate world food production, the need
for m aintaining adequate food reserves,
and the provision o f food to areas where
starvation conditions exist. The issues and
the recom m endations o f the World Food
Conference will likely be topical for a long
time. T his article is intended to provide a
better understanding o f the trends in
production and consumption that led to the
tight condition in world grain reserves.
*S ta tis tic a l measures in th is a rtic le are based on
the m e tric system. The fo llo w in g equations can be
used to co n ve rt m e tric figu res in to U .S . eq uivale nts.
1 hectare = 2.471 acres
1 q u in ta l = 220.4622 pounds
1 q u in ta l/h e c ta re = 89.293 po un ds/acre
1 k ilo g ra m = 2.2046 pounds
1 m e tric to n = 2,204.622 pounds




Business Conditions, November 1974

9

Less left over
World grain reserves have experienced two
periods o f significant tightening since the
beginning o f the Sixties. Total grain
r e s e r v e s — a s m easu red b y e n d i n g
carryover stocks—amounted to 174 million
metric tons in mid-1961, equivalent to
about 27 percent o f annual consumption.
The level declined to a low o f 113 million
metric tons, or 15 percent o f world con­
sumption, by mid-1966, after two years o f
particularly sharp gains in consumption.
With the aid o f good weather and new seed
varieties, production outpaced rising con­
sumption during the latter part o f the Six­
ties, boosting ending carryover grain
stocks to a high o f 187 m illion metric tons
by mid-1969, equal to 24 percent o f annual

world consumption. T he subsequent trend,
however, has been decidedly downward as
consumption has accelerated, while in­
creases in production have been somewhat
slowed by adverse weather conditions.
The continuing depletion o f coarse
grain (com , sorghum, barley, oats, and
rye) stocks and the absence o f a significant
recovery in wheat stocks h ave led to the re­
cent tightness in world grain reserves.
Current estim ates indicate mid-1975
carryover stocks o f coarse grains will be
equivalent to less than 7 percent o f annual
world consumption. Wheat stocks will
likely be equivalent to 14 percent o f world
consumption.
The reduction in grain reserves has

U.S. and world wheat reserves, by volume
and as a percent of consumption

U.S. and world coarse grain reserves, by
volume and as a percent of consumption
million metric tons

been particularly evident in the United
States. In the early Sixties, U.S. carryover
stocks o f wheat consistently exceeded an­
nual utilization (consum ption plus ex­
ports) and were equivalent to roughly oneh a lf o f world stocks. Similarly, U.S.
carryover stocks o f coarse grain were
equivalent to about one-half o f annual
utilization and around three-fourths o f
world reserves. The willingness and the
ability o f the United States to export
grains during the “ feed the w orld” cam ­
paigns o f the mid-Sixties and early Seven­
ties led to com paratively large declines in
dom estic grain stocks with respect to world
stocks and to utilization from dom estic
supplies.

percent of consumption

million m etric tons
140

percent of consumption
140
— -------United States

World

120

----------- World

100
-

80

80

60

40

20
J

20

0

0

■
60/61

62/63

*USDA estimate.

64/65

66/67

68/69

70/71

72/73

J
74/75*

0

10

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Production expands irregularly
World grain production is expected to total
916 million metric tons in fiscal 1975, down
nearly 6 percent from last year but 43 per­
cent above the levels o f the early Sixties.
(Alm ost all o f the U.S. grain harvest occurs
in the first six m onths o f a fiscal year.)
Since the start o f the Sixties, annual fluc­
tuations in world grain production have
ranged from an increase o f nearly 11 per­
cent (1971/72) to a decline o f nearly 6 per­
cent (1974/75). Year-to-year fluctuations in
the Sixties resulted largely from consistent
ups and dow ns in wheat production. More
recently, production o f both coarse grains
and wheat h as exhibited large swings.
Despite the ups and dow ns in world
grain production, the overall trend has

been decidedly upward. Based on a twoyear m oving average (a technique that
smoothes large annual changes and more
accurately reflects the trend), increases
have ranged from a low o f 0.1 percent
(1970/71) to a high o f 5.7 percent (1967/68)
and averaged 3.0 percent since the early
Sixties. Since 1969, the average increase in
world grain production has slowed frac­
tionally to 2.8 percent as two years o f sharp
declines offset much o f the increases
recorded in two bumper crop years.
The overall uptrend in world grain
production has been achieved largely
through increased yields rather than in
area harvested. The w orld’s annual grain
production came from an average o f 473

World grain production
percent, fiscal 4961-62=100

percent, fiscal 1961-62=100
160
150

140

130

120

110

100

*USDA estimate




11

Business Conditions, November 1974

m illion hectares in the first half o f the Six­
ties. The harvested area expanded slightly
during the latter h a lf o f the Sixties then
dipped in the early Seventies. However,
significant increases occurred in both
fiscal 1974 and 1975 when, according to
current estimates, the area harvested
m ight average 504 million hectares. O f
this, the coarse grain harvest should ac­
count for 284 m illion hectares and the
wheat harvest for 220 million hectares.
Yields per harvested hectare have
registered significant increases since the
early Sixties. During the past three fiscal
years, world wheat yields have averaged
16.4 quintals per hectare, up from 11.8 in
the early Sixties. Similarly, coarse grain

yields have averaged 20.9 quintals per hec­
tare, up from 15.5 in the early Sixties.
Wheat yields in the United States have
averaged 22 quintals per hectare, and
coarse grain yields have averaged 45.5
quintals per hectare in the past three fiscal
years.
High yields are the m ajor reason why
the United States ranks number one in
world grain production and exports. The
United States typically accounts for about
one-fourth o f the w orld’s grain production
and for around one-half o f world trade in
grain. Interestingly, o f the w orld’s top six
grain-producing areas, only the United
States has been a consistent net exporter
during the past two years.

Grain production and trade balances for the world’s major producing
areas: average for fiscal years 1973 and 1974
Wheat

_________ Coarse grains______
Trade
balance*

Production

Trade
balance*

Production

(m illion m etric tons)
United States
USSR
Western Europe
Eastern Europe
PRC
India
Canada
Argentina
Australia
South Africa
Other

34.7

+31.4
-7 .5
-0 .5
-3 .8
- 5.6
- 2.3
+ 13.6
+ 2.1
+ 5.4
+ 0.2

44.3
97.8
51.0
31.1
28.0
25.6
15.5
6.7
9.2
8.1

World total

352.0

*A " + " indicates net exports while




f
l

184.4
83.5
81.4
54.8
31.4
15.9
18.6
16.5
4.2
8.2

+18.1
-5 1 .1

79.2

70.8f

578.1

' ' indicates net imports. tTotal world trade.

+40.0
- 5.0
-1 9 .2
- 2.6
- 1.4
-0 .8
+ 2.5
+ 6.4
+ 1.8
+ 1.8
f
l

+18.2
-4 1 .7
70.7 f

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

12

Consumption exceeds population gains
World grain consum ption will decline in
fiscal 1975—primarily through grain fed to
livestock—as the result o f a reduced
harvest and low reserves. The decline will
be in sharp contrast to the trend that has
seen world grain consum ption rise, or hold
virtually unchanged, annually since the
start o f the Sixties. During this period, the
annual rise in world grain consumption
has averaged 3.2 percent, well above the 2
percent annual growth rate in world pop­
ulation. Moreover, the annual increase in
consumption has surged to 4.1 percent dur­
ing the past five-year period, due m ainly to
a rising affluence that permitted higher
living standards throughout the world.
This accelerated rate o f increase is the
most significant factor contributing to the
tightening in world grain reserves.

World grain consumption
percent, fiscal 1961-62=100

*USDA estimate.




Per capita grain consumption
percent, fiscal 1961-62=100

tC e n tr a lly p la n n e d c o u n trie s in c lu d e
USSR, Eastern E urope, PRC, N o rth Korea,
N o rth V ietnam , and M o n g o lia .
*U S D A e stim ate.

The rising standard o f living has been
most evident in developed countries and in
centrally planned countries. But less
developed countries also have experienced
increasing per capita consum ption of
grain. During the past three years, per
c a p ita g ra in co n su m p tio n in less
d e v e lo p e d cou n tries a v e ra g e d 103
kilograms, about 14 percent above the level
o f the early Sixties. In centrally planned
countries, per capita grain consumption
averaged 290 kilogram s annually during
the past three years, up 26 percent from the
early Sixties. In developed countries, per
capita grain consumption averaged 550
kilograms in recent years, a gain o f 20 per­
cent from the early Sixties. The higher
level o f consumption in centrally planned
countries and in developed countries large­
ly reflects a great per capita consumption
o f coarse grains.
Gary L. Benjamin

Business Conditions, November 1974

13

B anking d evelo pm en ts
Capital accounts include preferred
and common stock, surplus, undivided
Problems encountered by a few financial profits, and certain contingency reserves.
institutions in recent months have in­ Besides equity capital, long-term in­
creased the concern of the public, the debtedness in the form of subordinated
regulators, and bank management about notes and debentures is often included in
the ability of individual banks to remain capital accounts. In addition, to the extent
viable in the face of unusual losses or li­ a capital ratio is used as an indication of
quidity strains. This concern has been the thickness of the loss cushion, reserves
manifested in increased attention to bank specifically designated to absorb losses on
capital.
loans and declines in the value of securities
Bank capital is often viewed as a should be counted as capital funds.
cushion against losses and represents a
Regardless of how inclusive a defini­
hard core internal source of bank funds. It tion of capital is used and regardless of
can be measured in relation to deposits, to whether the capital is related to total
total assets, to so-called risk assets, or to a assets, risk assets, or deposits, aggregate
number of other variables. Which ratio is capital ratios of commercial banks have
most relevant depends largely on whether declined over the past decade. This
the observer is a depositor, some other shrinkage occurred despite the fact that
creditor, or a stockholder.
the dollar value of capital accounts has
more than doubled because assets
and deposits rose even faster.
Capital ratios in downtrend
While capital-to-risk-asset
ratios attempt to relate the capital
percent
cushion to broad classes of assets
20
that are most likely to entail losses,
equity capital and
reserves/“risk” assets
they are, at best, a very rough
15 - ' ______
^
guide. Usually they are calculated
on the basis of assets other than
those considered to be riskless,
equity cap ital/“risk” assets ' ' _____
such as cash and U.S. securities.
10
The gradual liquidation of the huge
quantities of U.S. securities ac­
equity capital and
quired during World War II has
reserves/total assets
resulted in a decline in these ratios
all Seventh District commercial banks
throughout the postwar era except
-1 . 1 1 1 1 . Li 1.1 1 1 , 1 1 1 1 1 .1 J—L_J when overall growth slowed tem1953 55 ’57 ’59 ’61 ’63 ’65 ’67 ’69 ’71 ’73 porarily.
At the end of last year, equity
Note: “ Risk” assets, as calculated for use in
capital plus loss reserves of district
this chart, are total assets less: cash assets, U.S.
obligations, and federal funds sold and securities
com m ercial b an ks, in the
bought under resale agreements. Data are not
aggregate, amounted to 10 percent
completely comparable over time due to
of domestic assets other than cash,
changes in available information.
Bank capital ratios

-




14

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Treasury and federal agency securities,
and short-term federal funds sales and
security resale agreements—down from 15
percent ten years ago. (See chart.) Loss
reserves alone have amounted to a fairly
constant 1.5 to 2 percent o f these assets.
Because o f bank-to-bank variations in
quality and liquidity within loan and in­
vestment portfolios, however, such ratios
are not very accurate representations o f
the capital cushion relative to actual
risk, and can be especially m isleading if
used by themselves to com pare individual
banks.
A more general capital relationship
measures the proportion o f assets financed
with internal funds—those supplied by
owners o f the bank in contrast to
depositors and creditors. This ratio in­
volves equity capital plus all reserves as a
percent o f total assets. Changes in the ratio
indicate whether the capital base o f a bank
is keeping pace with its overall growth. A
given ratio m ay or m ay not be “ adequate”
depending on the quality o f the assets and
of managem ent generally.

For district com m ercial banks, the
ratio o f equity capital and reserves to total
assets (based on dom estic offices only) was
about 7.5 percent at the end o f last year—
down from the near 9 percent level o f the
early Sixties but well above that prevailing
in the early postwar years. The rise and fall
o f this ratio over the past two decades
reflects two stages in the banking system ’s
m eth od s o f financing the needs of
b u s in e s s e s , h o u s e h o ld s , and lo ca l
governments. Throughout the Fifties, a
substantial portion o f loanable funds were
obtained through liquidating the G overn­
ments acquired during World War II. As
this source was largely exhausted in
the late Fifties, banks began to compete
more aggressively for new deposits and
oth er lia b ilitie s — so -ca lle d “ liability
m anagem ent” —to support further loan ex­
pansion, greatly accelerating total asset
growth in the process. But with the vast
changes in the com position o f assets,
today’s capital ratio appears thinner,
relative to potential needs, than a lower
ratio was 20 years ago.

Individual bank ratios cover wide range around the district average
Equity capital and
reserves as percent
of total domestic
assets

5.00 and under
5.01-6.00
6.01-7.00
7.01-8.00
8.01-9.00
9.01-10.00
10.01-11.00
11.01-12.00
12.01-13.00
13.01-14.00
14.01-15.00
15.01-20.00
Over 20.00




of total assets [m illion dollars)
5.0 &
under

5.110.0

10.1
15.0

15.125.0

4
7
25
46
61
56
46
27
18
14
11
13
33

4
14
68
141
152
111
52
29
16
14
5
7
1

9
19
72
113
88
48
21
8
7
1
1
1
1

6
44
116
146
103
52
24
7
4

25.150.150.0
150.0
(number o f banks)

—

19
41
88
101
75
34
11
6
5
1
1
1
1

150.1250.0

Over
250.0

16
42
77
82
48
23
11
6

7
4
8
14
6
5
2
2

2
9
15
13
8

-

-

-

3
-

1

2
—

1
-

—

-

1
-

-

-

—

—

Total

67
180
469
656
541
329
169
85
50
35
18
23
36

15

Business Conditions, November 1974

Range of ratios
Condition report data as o f mid-1974
showed that equity capital and reserves in
relation to total assets decreased as bank
size increased. Differences between groups
o f banks with total assets over $10 million
were relatively small, with little variation
am ong district states. However, the inclu­
sion o f foreign assets would produce
significantly lower ratios for some banks
in the largest size group. Individual bank
ratios show a substantial dispersion
which, in turn, was greater within the
smaller size groups. More than one-half of
the district’s 2,600 banks have assets o f
less than $15 million. O f these, almost 25
percent report equity capital and reserves
equal to 10 percent or more o f those assets.
However, these smallest categories include
a number o f fairly new banks whose ratios




The ratios of equity capital and
reserves to total assets decline as bank
size increases
Am ount o f
bank assets

A ll Seventh D istrict com m ercial banks,1
______________as of June 3 0 , 1 974_____________

on June 3 0 ,
1974

III,

In d,

Iow a

M ich.

Wis.

District
total

(e q u ity capital and reserves as p erc en t
o f total d o m e stic assets)

12.9
5 and under
8.7
5 .1 - 1 0 . 0
1 0 . 1 - 1 5 .0
7.9
1 5 . 1 - 2 5 .0
7.3
2 5 . 1 - 5 0 .0
7.2
5 0 . 1 - 2 5 0 .0
7.4
250.1 and over
6 .9

13.2
8 .7
7.8
7.5
7.8
7.0
6 .6

9 .4
8 .7
8 .2
8.1
8 .3
8.1
7.8

2 3.2
10.2
9 .0
7.8
7.6
7.2
7.0

10.3
8.5
7.7
7.8
7.6
7.6
6.3

11.4
8.8
8 .0
7.7
7.6
7.4
6 .9

^Com m ercial banks excluding nondeposit trust companies.

m ight be expected to be abnorm ally high.
At about one-fourth o f all district banks,
this capital and reserves-to-assets ratio
was between 7 and 8 percent, and at nearly
30 percent it w as less.
■