View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
November 1971

Contents
The coming upsurge
in employment
Gold-Part I:
An historical perspective

2

12

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The coming upsurge
in employment

2

Seventy-one million Americans were em­
ployed by nonagricultural establishments in
October—600,000 more than at the start of
1971 but a quarter of a million less than at
the employment peak reached in March
1970. Manufacturing employment, at 18.6
million in October, was no higher than at
the start of the year, and 1.6 million less
than at the peak set in 1969. In most of the
industrial areas of the Midwest, the employ­
ment picture in recent months has been less
favorable than for the nation.
Following two years of declining activity
or subnormal growth, a substantial rise in
spending, output, and employment is gener­
ally expected for next year. Currently, how­
ever, most job markets remain soft with few
companies recruiting actively on a large scale.
Some companies continue to retrench, and
layoffs are still occurring, particularly among
manufacturers of machinery and equipment.
In some industries that have increased pro­




duction, increases in output per man-hour
(productivity) and longer workweeks have
reduced the need for additional workers.
No sustained uptrend in payroll employ­
ment has occurred in the two years since a
cyclical peak in general business activity was
reached late in 1969. In the five-year period,
1965-69, employment rose at the very rapid
pace of 3.8 percent annually. Even in 1967,
a year of retarded growth in general activity,
employment averaged 3 percent more than in
1966. In most industrial areas of the Mid­
west, employment has remained below the
1969 level, reflecting cutbacks in locally im­
portant producer equipment industries.
While wage and salary employment has
been sluggish in 1971, the labor force has
continued to grow, although at a somewhat
slower pace than in past years. Despite slight
declines in September and October in na­
tional totals, unemployment is substantially
higher than it was two years ago in almost all

Business Conditions, November 1971

major labor markets. In addition, average
workweeks are below the levels of the late
1960s. Finally, many workers released by
employers, and many new entrants to the
labor force, now hold jobs that do not fully
utilize their experience and education.
This article describes recent developments
in employment and unemployment, with spe­
cial reference to the Midwest. It explores the
major causes of the current condition, and
looks ahead to the substantial growth in em­
ployment that appears probable.

The recent decline in nonfarm
payroll employment followed
several years of large gains
change in millions

The g ro w in g la b o r force

Total employment was estimated at more
than 82 million in October 1971. This total
includes, in addition to the 71 million non­
farm wage and salary workers, more than 5
million self-employed and unpaid family
workers, about 3.4 million agricultural work­
ers, and 2.7 million members of the armed
services. The unemployed — those without
jobs, but available for work and seeking
jobs—numbered about 5 million in October.
The total labor force, including the armed
services and the unemployed, was 87.5 mil­
lion in October. This number increased by
2.5 million in two years. Growth in the labor
force was faster in the late Sixties. From
1966 through 1969, the increase averaged
1.8 million annually.
Individuals are counted as part of the labor
force either if they have jobs or are actively
seeking work. Each year this number is aug­
mented, at least potentially, by growth in
the number of people of working age—de­
fined as those 16 through 65. Of course,
many of the people in the 16-25 age bracket,
choosing to devote full time to their educa­
tion, are not in the labor force. Others, in
all age groups, are too ill to work, or are con­
fined in institutions. Many women devote full
time to their families. People approaching 65



Ananu)(a a uring
_

rn

[1

M M 1 ______

■

*Ten m o n th s.

may take early retirement, an option increas­
ingly more available. On the other hand, mil­
lions of people continue to work past 65.
Many millions of potential workers—es­
pecially students, housewives, and retired
people— are not continuously in the labor
market, but take jobs or seek work periodi­
cally, depending on individual circumstances
and the availability of suitable job oppor­
tunities. In times of vigorous expansion, in­
creases in employment may reflect new en-

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

4

trants, or reentrants, to the labor force more
than reductions in unemployment. In times
of declining activity, workers who lose jobs
through layoffs do not necessarily remain in
the labor force as unemployed people seek­
ing work. In some cases, they “drop out” of
the labor force, assuming—rightly or wrongly
—that a job search is not worthwhile.
About 61 percent of the noninstitutionalized population 16 years and over are now in
the labor force. This proportion rose slightly
each year from 1964—when it was 59.6 per­
cent—through 1970. The string of increases
may have been broken in 1971. In the third
quarter, the labor force participation rate
was slightly less than a year earlier—prob­
ably because of slack demand.
The trend of labor force participation has
differed markedly for men and women since
World War II. For men, the rate has declined
from 87 percent in 1950 to less than 81 per­
cent now. For women, the participation rate
increased fairly steadily in this period—from
34 percent in 1950 to 43 percent now.
Various factors have produced diverse
trends in labor force participation rates for
men and women. Longer years of schooling
and earlier retirements have tended to reduce
labor force participation rates for both men
and women, but these trends have been more
important in the case of men. Offsetting de­
velopments have brought additional numbers
of women into the labor force. Labor saving
appliances, and fuller processing of foods,
have reduced the time women must spend at
household tasks, allowing them more free­
dom to take full- or part-time jobs. The stig­
ma once attached by some people to women,
especially married women, working for pay
has gradually eroded. Changes in the age mix
of the population, and the long business ex­
pansion of the 1960s, also have influenced
participation rates for men and women.




About 97 percent of American men, aged
25 to 45, currently are in the labor force.
This proportion has not changed significantly
since World War II. For men 45 to 55, the
rate is 94 percent, down slightly in the past
15 years. Clearly, virtually all of the ablebodied men 25 to 55 are either working or
seeking work. Men in these age groups are
in their prime working years, usually have
completed their formal education, and, typi­
cally, support dependents.
The maximum labor force participation
for women is in the 20 to 25 year old
bracket, at 58 percent. The rate drops to 45
percent in the 25 to 35 bracket, and then
rises again in following years, reflecting the
easing of family responsibilities as children
grow older. In each of the age brackets, how­
ever, the proportion of women in the labor
force has increased steadily in the past 20
years. This is true even for those women

An increase in the proportion of
women in the labor force has off­
set a gradual decline for men
percent in labor fo rce

Business Conditions, November 1971

with children of preschool age. This trend is
likely to continue.
Commentaries on trends in unemployment
often emphasize the situation for married
men (now somewhat less than half of the
total labor force) who normally support de­
pendents. As a group, married men obviously
are more strongly attached to the labor force
than other groups. But needless to say, a
large share of the women and single men in
the labor force also must work to provide
necessities and comforts for themselves and
others. Even in cases where workers merely
supplement the income of the “bread win­
ner,” they contribute to the nation’s supply of
goods and services, and comprise a vital por­
tion of the nation’s labor resources.

Employment has continued to rise
in state and local government
and in the service industries
percent

change

(1969 averoge to October 1971)

8

4

-

0 + 4

8

Em p lo ym en t b y sector

During the past two years of widespread
economic adjustment, changes in employment
have varied substantially among industries,
and among regional labor markets. For the
most part, differences in regional trends in
employment reflect developments in the in­
dustries that are most important in the area.
The last year of relatively “full employ­
ment” was 1969. The following comparisons
relate employment in major industries in
October 1971, seasonally adjusted, to the
annual average for 1969.
In October, state and local government
employment showed the largest gain of any
sector, up almost 9 percent from the 1969
average. These governments now employ
more than 10 million people. States and
municipalities have been under strong pres­
sure to improve and expand their services—
including education, public health, welfare,
sanitation, and police protection. Recently,
the limited availability of funds caused by the
economic slowdown, and by voter reluctance
to approve bond issues and tax hikes, has



forced curtailment of desired programs. But
state and local government employment has
continued to rise, although at a slower rate
than in past years.
Federal government civilian employment
was 2.7 million in September, only about
one-fourth as large as state and local govern­
ment employment. Instead of expanding, fed­
eral employment in October was 3 percent
less than the 1969 average. Part of the decline
since 1969 reflects reductions in the Depart­
ment of Defense and in aerospace activities.
A further decline in total federal employment
is under way. In August, the President di­
rected federal departments to reduce employ­
ment by 5 percent by mid-1972, as part of
his economic stabilization program.
While federal civilian employment has de­
clined moderately in the past two years, the
armed forces have been cut sharply. In Sep­
tember 1969, the armed forces numbered

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

6

more than 3.5 million—near the Vietnam
War high. By October 1971, the number was
2.7 million, after declining for 25 consecu­
tive months. The decline apparently contin­
ues, but the great bulk of the planned reduc­
tion probably has been accomplished.
Among the stronger private employment
sectors are finance (including banking, in­
surance, and real estate) and services (a wide
variety of miscellaneous activities), each up
about 7 percent in October from the 1969
average. About 3.8 million people are em­
ployed in the financial sectors, and almost 12
million in service activities. Employment in
these sectors probably will continue to rise
because of increasing demands for the serv­
ices they render. Opportunities to increase
output per man-hour through automation in
these industries are limited.
Employment in wholesale and retail trade
totaled more than 15 million in October, up
4 percent from the 1969 average. Further in­
creases in employment in the trade sectors
are likely because of population growth, de­
spite increased emphasis on self-service in
many stores.
Total employment in the transportation
and public utility industries combined, now
about 4.4 million, has changed little in recent
years. Within the category some diverse
trends have developed. Transportation com­
panies, especially the airlines, have reduced
employment, while the utilities have con­
tinued to hire additional workers. A recent
step-up in air traffic has caused some airlines
to increase hirings again.
Contract construction employment, at 3.3
million in October, was 5 percent lower than
the 1969 average. Residential construction
has been very strong in 1971, but nonresidential construction has declined. Activity in
residential construction is expected to remain
near this year’s level in 1972, while non­




residential construction is expected to in­
crease somewhat.
Employment in agriculture (including the
self-employed) was less than 3.4 million in
September, compared to a 3.6 million aver­
age in 1969. Agriculture is the only major
sector in which employment has trended
downward for many years. Currently, agri­
cultural employment is only half as large as
20 years ago, and only one-third as large as
in the 1930s. Innovations in agricultural
equipment and techniques over the years
have resulted in increases in output per man­
hour at a much faster pace than in most non­
farm sectors. Because modern technology is
not yet applied universally, a substantial
further decline in agricultural employment is
probable in years to come.
Trends in m an u factu rin g

For all U. S. manufacturing industries,
payroll employment totaled 18.6 million in
October, seasonally adjusted, down 8 per­
cent from the 1969 average—the largest de­
cline for any major sector. Manufacturing
employment apparently is rising again, but
no early return to record levels is anticipated.
Even assuming a steady rise in manufactur­
ing output, probable increases in output per
man-hour and extensions of average work­
weeks will reduce the need for additional
employees.
In recent months, manufacturing employ­
ment in most Midwest centers has been fur­
ther below the 1969 level than has been the
case for the United States as a whole. The
difference largely reflects lower levels of out­
put in the machinery and equipment indus­
tries, and in the primary metal industries—
both steel and nonferrous. With less than 16
percent of the nation’s population, the states
of Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Michigan, and
Wisconsin produce almost one-third of its

Business Conditions, November 1971

Employment in durable goods
manufacturing has declined
more than employment
in nondurable goods
percent change
(1969 overage to October 1971)

-38

-12

-8

-4

0

machinery and equipment, and account for
about 28 percent of its primary metal indus­
tries. According to the Federal Reserve in­
dex of industrial production, output of busi­
ness equipment in October was more than
10 percent below its 1969 average, compared
with a decline of less than 5 percent for all
industrial production. (In recent months,
total output of business equipment has in­
creased slightly.) Primary metal industries
were also operating at relatively low levels
in October. Steel industry activity was down
almost one-third from 1969 as steel buyers
reduced strike-hedge inventories accumulated
prior to August 1, 1971.
Employment in almost all major categor­
ies of manufacturing, both in the nation and
in the Midwest, was down from the 1969
average in October, to a greater or lesser



degree. In two relatively stable industries,
printing and publishing and food processing,
the national decline was less than 2 percent.
For paper, apparel, and chemicals, the de­
cline was less than 5 percent. In the more
volatile machinery and equipment and pri­
mary metal industries, however, employ­
ment was down 12 percent in October.
By far the sharpest decline in manufac­
turing employment since 1969 has occurred
in aerospace — both aircraft and missiles.
From an 850,000 average in 1969, aero­
space employment declined almost 40 per­
cent to less than 500,000 recently. Cutbacks
in these industries have played a major role
in causing widespread unemployment in
some labor markets, especially in the state
of Washington, in southern California, and
in the Boston area. Aerospace is relatively
much less important in the Midwest.
The decline in employment in the ma­
chinery and equipment and aerospace indus­
tries probably may be giving way to modest
increases. But no substantial rise is prob­
able in the near future. A recent survey of
plant and equipment spending intentions for
1972 indicates a rise of only 2 percent in
physical volume for all industries. Steel out­
put, on the other hand, will rise significantly
as inventory reduction programs are com­
pleted. Some recalls of laid-off steel workers
were announced in October.
A lo o k a t u n em p lo ym en t

Unemployment was estimated at just un­
der 5 million for the nation in October, 5.8
percent of the civilian labor force. State esti­
mates for September indicate that the un­
employment rates for Illinois, Iowa, and
Wisconsin were less than 5 percent. The
Indiana rate matched the national average. In
Michigan, despite stepped-up auto output
(the state’s dominant industry) the unem-

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The total unemployment rate has
remained near the cyclical peak
for the past year
percent of labor force

8

ployment rate was almost 8 percent in Sep­
tember. The rates are seasonally adjusted.
The U. S. Department of Labor estimates
unemployment each month for many sub­
groups in the labor force—by age, sex, mari­
tal status, race, and previous employment.
Recently, special quarterly estimates have
been made for Vietnam War veterans and
for poverty-stricken sections of major cities.
Such detailed data are not estimated for
states or metropolitan areas.
In a free economy some “frictional” un­
employment always exists, as people “be­
tween jobs,” and new entrants to the labor
force, seek suitable positions. Unemploy­
ment compensation, welfare programs, home
ownership, the ability to draw on past sav­
ings, and help from friends or relatives reduce
pressure on individuals to take jobs that do
not suit their inclinations and capabilities.
These factors, probably more important than
in past decades, tend to raise the level of
frictional unemployment.
The overall unemployment rate for the




nation has hovered near the 6 percent level
since November 1970. In 1969, this rate
averaged only 3.5 percent, the lowest level
since the Korean War years 1951-53. Over­
all unemployment rates below 4 percent—
some would say 4 V2 percent—have been as­
sociated with large numbers of job vacancies,
high labor turnover, inefficiency, and rapid
price inflation. These conditions prevailed in
1968 and 1969 in the eyes of many.
Although much higher than in the late
1960s, the current 6 percent unemployment
rate is not a record for the postwar period.
The rate averaged 6.8 percent in the last half
of 1949, 7.5 percent in the worst months of
the 1958 recession, and 7.0 percent for a
four-month period in 1961. But the duration
of the high plateau in unemployment—a full
year—is without precedent since the 1930s.
Among the subgroups of the labor force,

The unemployment rate for
married men is well below
the rates for other groups
percent unemployed

men

women

population

Business Conditions, November 1971

the unemployment rate for married men (liv­
ing with their wives) receives close analysis.
The unemployment rate for married men
was 3.0 percent in October. This rate aver­
aged only 1.5 percent in 1969. As in the case
of the rate for the entire labor force, the un­
employment rate for married men in 1969
was the lowest since the Korean War. At no
time in the recent business adjustment has
the unemployment rate for married men ap­
proached the 5.1 percent average rate for
1958, or the 4.6 percent average for 1961.
There are no data on the number of mar­
ried men, or others, who have lost relatively
well-paid jobs, and who have accepted work
at lower compensation. Such cases have been
especially numerous in the aerospace field,
but parallels exist to some degree in many
other industries in which managements have
been under strong pressure to reduce costs
and improve profit margins, even when this
has required the release of employees with
many years of service. The frequency of such
situations in the past year or two probably
has not been equaled since the 1930s.
Unemployment rates almost always aver­
age lower for men than women, for teenagers
than adults, for whites than blacks, and for
white-collar workers than blue-collar work­
ers. The relative difference within these
groups has not been constant over the years.
For men 20 and over, the October unem­
ployment rate was 4.3 percent, compared to
5.5 percent for women 20 and over. For both
sexes aged 16-19, the September unemploy­
ment rate was 17 percent. Since late 1970,
the teenage unemployment rate has averaged
much higher than for any period of similar
length since World War II. Teenage unem­
ployment has been boosted in the past dec­
ade compared to the 1950s, mainly because
of the larger number of young people in the
work force, both absolutely and relatively.



How e m p lo y m e n t estim ate s a r e m ad e

The U. S. Departm ent of Labor pub­
lishes two separate sets of employment data.
The household series is based on replies to
monthly interviews with individual house­
holds. The establishment series is based on
monthly reports made by employers to state
labor departments. Together with informa­
tion on unemployment compensation, the
household series and the establishment series
provide the m ajor sources of statistical in­
formation on labor m arket developments.
Data on the total labor force, total em­
ployment and unemployment with break­
downs by age, sex, race, and general cate­
gories of employment are derived from the
household series. The sample used was de­
signed by the Bureau of the Census (De­
partm ent of Com m erce), which collects and
tabulates data for the Bureau of Labor
Statistics (D epartm ent of Labor). It con­
sists of 52,500 households located in 449
areas, some in each state. Trained inter­
viewers contact these households each
m onth to obtain responses to standardized
questions. The sample is considered ade­
quate to provide accurate estimates of the
characteristics of the U. S. labor force. The
sample is not suitable for providing informa­
tion for regions or states.
Data on wage and salary employment,
payrolls, average workweeks, and labor
turnover by industry (including types of
manufacturing) are obtained from the es­
tablishment series. Reports are furnished
by employers to state labor departments,
which tabulate the data and forward re­
sults to the Bureau of Labor Statistics,
which develops national statistics. Compar­
able data are available for states, metropoli­
tan areas, and for many smaller cities.
Many state labor departments also make
estimates of total employment and unem­
ploym ent, using a variety of sources.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Classifications of labor markets
by U.S. Department of Labor
O cto b e r
1969

O cto b e r
1970

O cto b e r
1971

B

C

C

C
C
B

C
C
C

D
C
D

C
B
B
B
C
C

C
C
C
C
D
C

C
C
D
C
C
C

Illin o is
C h ic a g o
D aven p o rtRock Is la n d -M o lin e
P e o ria
R ockford

In d ia n a
E v a n s v ille
Fort W a y n e
G a ry -H a m m o n d
In d ia n a p o lis
South Bend
T e rre H au te

Io w a
C e d a r R a p id s
Des M oines

B
B

C
C

C
C

C
C
B
C
C
B
D
C

D
D
D
D
C
E
D

D
D
D
D
D
C
E
D

C
B
B
C

C
C
C
D

C
C
C
D

M ich ig an
B attle C re e k
D etro it
Flin t
G ra n d R a p id s
K a la m a z o o
La nsin g
M uskegon
S a g in a w

c

W isco n sin
K en o sh a
M ad iso n
M ilw a u k e e
R acin e

E x p la n a tio n o f la b o r m a rk e t c la s s ific a tio n s
C la ss
A
B
C
D
E
F

D e scrip tio n
O v e ra ll la b o r sh o rta g e
Low u n e m p lo ym e n t
M o d e ra te u n e m p lo ym e n t
S u b s ta n tia l u n e m p lo ym e n t
S u b s ta n tia l u n e m p lo ym e n t
S u b s ta n tia l u n e m p lo ym e n t

10




U n e m p lo ym e n t ra te
U n d e r 1 .5 p ercen t
1 .5 -3 .0
3 .0 -6 .0
6 .0 -9 .0
9 .0 -1 2 .0
O v e r 1 2 .0

The unemployment rate for all whites in
October was 5.3 percent, compared to 10.7
percent for non whites (90 percent of whom
are blacks). The unemployment rate for
blacks has been about twice the rate for
whites for many years.
In designated poverty neighborhoods, un­
employment rates are substantially higher
than the national average, both for the total
and for all subgroups—as might be expected.
For Vietnam veterans, 20-29, the unemploy­
ment rate was estimated at 8.3 percent in
the third quarter, compared to 6.9 percent
for nonveteran men in the same age bracket.
The differential between veterans and non­
veterans was much narrower a year earlier.
D ifferences in local la b o r m a rk e ts

In cooperation with state agencies, the
Department of Labor classifies 150 major
labor markets each month, assigning letter
grades indicating the relative strength of sup­
ply and demand for workers. Consideration
is given not only to current estimates of un­
employment, but also to qualitative judg­
ments of local experts as to the probable
persistence of current conditions.
The letter grade A (unemployment less
than 1.5 percent) has not been used to clas­
sify a labor market since 1957. Grades B and
C indicate low to moderate unemployment
(under 6 percent), while grades D, E, and F
indicate increasing severity of unemploy­
ment. These last three groups are designated
as areas of “substantial labor surplus.”
In October 1969, only five of 150 major
labor markets were in the substantial labor
surplus groups. Currently, 65 labor markets
are in these groups. Of 24 major labor mar­
kets in Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Michigan, and
Wisconsin, only one was in the substantial
labor surplus category in September 1969.
Currently, 11 are so classified. Two years

Business Conditions, November 1971

ago, 62 of the nation’s major labor markets
were in the B group (low unemployment,
under 3 percent), compared to only six to­
day. None of these are in the Midwest.
Substantial unemployment in major labor
markets of the Northeast, Midwest, and Far
West is related to conditions in the machin­
ery and equipment, steel, auto, and aero­
space industries. The low unemployment
centers, of which Washington, D. C., is by
far the largest, are all in the South.
W h y u n em p lo ym en t persists

In 1968 and 1969, the final years of the
nation’s longest economic uptrend, many
companies were unable to recruit all the
qualified workers they needed. A widely-held
view in late 1969 was that such conditions
would change as the ebullient economy was
dampened by restrictive monetary and fiscal
policy. Few analysts predicted, however,
either the rapidity of the shift from excess
demand for workers to underutilization of
the labor force, or the extended duration of
the changed conditions.
Continued high rates of unemployment, in
large part, reflect the fact that total output
(real GNP) is only slightly higher than it was
two years ago. The long-term growth trend is
about 4 percent annually. The fact that man­
ufacturing output is 5 percent below the peak
rates of two years ago is reflected in high un­
employment rates for industrial centers, par­
ticularly those specializing in durable goods.
Other factors have been at work. The
growth of imports relative to exports, deci­




sions to close marginal plants (which usually
have relatively high labor inputs), gains in
output per man-hour, and management deci­
sions to keep new hirings, and training pro­
grams, to a minimum until the economic sit­
uation is clarified—have all played a role. At
present, few private industries or public
agencies are expanding their staffs rapidly.
Moreover, new layoffs have been announced
recently by companies in the industrial equip­
ment, construction machinery, computer, and
aluminum industries — all characterized as
“growth” industries through much of the
decade of the 1960s.
Im p ro vem en t in 1972

The widely accepted “standard forecast”
for the economy for 1972 projects a rise of
about 6 percent in total output of goods and
services. Following two years of sluggish
activity, growth of such magnitude can be
expected to be associated with a strong rise
in employment and reduced rates of un­
employment nationally.
Consumer expenditures have accelerated
in recent months, especially for autos and
other durable goods. Business firms, how­
ever, continue cautious in making capital in­
vestments and additions to inventory. Con­
tinuance of the improvement in consumer
spending can be expected, in time, to encour­
age increases in business investments. Never­
theless, even economic growth of the magni­
tude foreseen in the most optimistic projec­
tions is not expected to reduce unemployment
to the levels prevailing in the late Sixties.

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Part 1: An historical perspective

12

On August 15, the President of the United
States announced suspension of the convert­
ibility of the dollar into gold. With that one
action an international arrangement that
had been one of the mainstays of the inter­
national monetary system for the past quarter
century came to an end. The gold exchange
international monetary standard—as the ar­
rangement was known—ceased to exist.
Negotiations among the trading nations
of the world for new monetary arrangements
started almost immediately after the Presi­
dent’s announcement. As yet no concrete re­
sults have emerged from these negotiations.
The foreign exchange markets quickly recov­
ered from the initial shock of August 15,
and trading in foreign currencies soon re­
sumed. But arrangements underpinning these
operations are viewed by responsible officials
as temporary and of a contingency nature at
best. Negotiations for more permanent ar­
rangements are continuing. Clearly, more
time is needed for negotiators to arrive at an




agreement. Many complex issues, glossed
over for several years in the cooperative ef­
fort of the participating nations to make the
system work, surfaced in the wake of the
U. S. action. Resolution of these issues will re­
quire extended negotiations and compromises
on questions of vital interest to individual
sovereign nations.
One of these issues centers on gold, its
price and its future role in international
monetary arrangements. The controversial
nature of this issue stems largely from the
peculiar mixture of myths, emotions, and
sound economic principles that surround
gold. Over the centuries, when gold played
an important role both in international
monetary arrangements and in the monetary
systems of individual countries, this mixture
became an integral part of public folklore—
and political realities. While sound principles
of modern monetary management had long
argued for a diminution of the role of gold
in monetary arrangements, the widespread

Business Conditions, November 1971

popular mystique of gold has tended to make
such a step politically unpalatable. The re­
cent suspension of dollar convertibility set
the stage for a fundamental reappraisal of
the entire international monetary system,
including the role of gold. This article pro­
vides an historical perspective on the role of
gold in monetary arrangements in the way of
background for such a reappraisal. An article
to appear in the next issue of Business Con­
ditions, will focus on recent developments.
G o ld a s n a tio n a l m o ney

The world hardly would have progressed
beyond primitive stages of economic devel­
opment if it were not for the emergence of
a medium of exchange—money. Money fa­
cilitated the specialization of production that
transformed countless simple barter societies
into an international market economy.
The wide acceptance of gold as a medium
of exchange contributed to this process. Be­
cause of its durability and scarcity, gold
served this function well. Use of gold as
money goes back to early recorded history.
Some scholars trace the initial use of gold
as a medium of exchange to the Egypt of
4300 B.C. As a result of Greek and Roman
conquests, the use of gold coins spread
throughout Europe by the fourth century
B.C. Contrary to popular belief, however,
the role of gold in the development of money
as a medium of exchange is not rooted in
the dawn of civilization. Clay, porpoise
teeth, and slave girls—to name only a few
commodities—served as money long before
gold. And even after gold was adopted as a
metal for coinage in ancient times, gold
coins remained rather scarce. Silver, be­
cause of its relatively greater abundance, was
far more widely used. It was only as fresh
supplies of gold reached Europe from the



newly discovered American continents in
the sixteenth century that gold joined silver
as a widely used metal for coinage.
The emergence of gold as a focal point
of the monetary system is even more recent.
It was only in 1816 that England established
the gold sovereign as its primary monetary
unit, with silver given only a limited role as
legal tender. More than fifty years passed
before Germany-(in 1871) and the United
States (in 1873) followed.1 Only at the turn
of the century did a monetary standard
based on gold become prevalent in major
countries of the world.
Another popular misconception exists con­
cerning the ability of gold—or of any metal­
lic monetary standard—to assure “proper”
monetary management of a country. Evi­
dence shows that as early as the fifteenth and
sixteenth centuries, European economies
were buffeted alternately by shortages, fol­
lowed by oversupplies, of the precious metals.
In the early fifteenth century, Europe ex­
perienced a deep economic depression as a
result of an increasingly severe shortage of
gold and silver. The situation was somewhat
relieved by the discovery of new silver mines
lOn the North American continent, the silver
and gold money that circulated in the early period
of colonization was brought in by immigrants
from England, Spain, France, and the Netherlands.
An independent monetary system in the United
States was established by the Coinage Act of 1792.
The act established the dollar as the basic mone­
tary unit, and defined it as equal to 24% grains of
pure gold, or to 371% grains of pure silver.
The bimetallic standard continued in the United
States until Congress passed the Coinage Act of
1873. This act demonetized silver and placed the
dollar on the gold standard. Effective converti­
bility of dollars into gold was not achieved until
1879, however. Initially, the gold value of the
dollar was based on the world price of gold—
$19.39 per troy ounce. The price was changed in
1834 to $20.69 and again in 1837 to $20.67, where
it remained until 1933.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

in Germany and Bohemia in 1450. It was
not until the New World exploits of the
Spanish and Portuguese augmented the
“money supply” that the stage was set for
the economic and commercial expansion of
Europe. But the influx of precious metals
soon proved to be economically damaging.
The money supply rose too rapidly, and by
1550 Europe found itself in the throes of
severe inflation.
Gradual development of bank notes, is­
sued by individual banks and fully convert­
ible into gold, eventually relieved the prob­
lem of shortages of supply, but introduced
a new element of instability. Economic cycles
in many countries tended to be exacerbated
by virtually unregulated expansions of money
during upswings, and massive contractions
(often accompanied by wholesale conversion
of paper currencies into gold) during down­
swings. It was only after individual countries
established strong central banking systems
charged with the responsibility to regulate the
money supply that monetary disturbances of
this nature were brought under control.
G o ld a s in te rn a tio n a l m o n ey

14

Historically, the international payments
system evolved from the domestic payments
systems of individual trading countries. As
the currencies of all major countries con­
sisted of, or were freely convertible into,
gold, international transactions were settled
by shipping gold. Besides simplifying inter­
national transactions, such shipments were
supposed to provide an automatic mechanism
for the elimination of deficits and surpluses
in a country’s balance of payments.
In a country where individual international
transactions undertaken by its nationals in­
volved payments to foreigners in excess of
receipts from foreigners—i.e., in a country
experiencing a deficit in its balance of pay­




ments—the money supply was reduced auto­
matically as gold flowed out. Scarcity of
money in the deficit country was supposed
to lead to a reduction in economic activity
and to a fall in prices, making the country’s
goods cheaper to foreigners. This, in turn, was
expected to stimulate foreign demand for the
country’s goods and help eliminate the coun­
try’s balance-of-payments deficit. A set of
forces tending in the opposite direction would
be at work in a surplus country: inflows of
gold would increase the money supply, push
up prices, and thus inhibit exports. This was
supposed to reduce the country’s balance-ofpayments surpluses.
Unfortunately, however, the international
gold standard never really functioned as was
intended. The price structure in many coun­
tries—particularly in those with advancing
industrialization and unionization—was too
rigid to respond smoothly to changes in the
money supply. Reductions in the money sup­
ply due to the outflow of gold did not always
lead to export-stimulating reductions in price

Free world’s production of gold...
billion dollars

Business Conditions, November 1971

. . . is largely absorbed by
industrial uses and
private hoarding
billion dollars

private hoarding
industrial uses
changes in monetary gold
stocks
n n

n

1. 61-

.8

-

1.6

-

2.4

i
1958

i

i
'60

i

i
'62

i

i
'64

i___ I___ I___ I___ I__ I
'66
'68
'70

protect themselves from worsening economic
depression.2
A few countries clung stubbornly to gold.
At the London Monetary Conference in July
1933, France, Switzerland, Belgium, the
Netherlands, Italy, and Poland signed a
pledge to retain the gold standard, forming
the so-called “gold bloc.” By 1936, long
after the rest of the world embarked upon
the road to recovery, even the gold-bloc
countries abandoned gold amidst deepening
depression, rising unemployment, and the
resulting social and political turmoil. With
that, the gold standard came to an end.
Having experienced the stifling influence
of the gold standard, no country (except the
United States in the post-World War II in­
ternational monetary arrangements) permit­
ted its currency to be convertible into gold
again.
G o ld — p o stw a r

levels. Rather than cutting prices, producers
cut back production and employment. Pro­
longed balance-of-payments deficits led to
rising unemployment.
The impact of gold movements on the eco­
nomic conditions in individual countries be­
came a great concern to governments, in­
creasingly committed to maintaining the
social and economic welfare of their people.
It ultimately led to the demise of the gold
standard during the worldwide depression in
the early Thirties, but only after the govern­
ments’ prolonged adherence to the “rules” of
the gold standard had extracted its toll in
terms of spreading unemployment and human
misery. Large speculative flows of gold—
combined with large-scale conversion of pa­
per currencies into gold—contributed signifi­
cantly to the spread of the Depression in the
early 1930s. By 1933, some 40 countries
had abandoned gold in a desperate effort to



In the postwar international monetary sys­
tem, the role of gold was reduced substan2The United States suspended its commitment
to the gold standard in 1933. In January 1934,
President Roosevelt, acting under the authority
of the Thomas Amendment enacted in Congress
in 1933, set the gold content of the dollar at
13.71 grains, increasing the dollar price of a troy
ounce of gold to $35.00. The Gold Reserve
Act of 1934 terminated circulation of gold coins
and free convertibility of paper currency into gold
for U. S. residents. It also prohibited U. S. citizens
in the United States from holding gold—a prohi­
bition that in the 1950s was extended to holding
gold abroad. The only domestic tie between the
dollar and gold that remained—largely as a
carry-over from the earlier days—was a require­
ment that the Federal Reserve maintain gold re­
serves against its notes and other liabilities. Ini­
tially, the requirement set these reserves at 40
percent against notes and 35 percent against other
liabilities. In 1945, the reserve requirement was
reduced to 25 percent on both notes and liabilities.
In 1965, the reserve requirement against liabilities
was abolished. In 1968, the 25 percent gold reserve
requirement against Federal Reserve notes in cir­
culation was dropped by an act of Congress.

1

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

16

tially. Although the values of the currencies
of individual countries were defined in terms
of gold, the fixed exchange rates among cur­
rencies—the main feature of the postwar
system—were no longer maintained by ship­
ments of gold. Instead, monetary authorities
in individual countries agreed to maintain
a fixed rate of exchange of their currency in
terms of the dollar by buying and selling
dollars in their respective exchange markets
in response to supply and demand conditions.
The United States, in turn, undertook to buy
and sell gold to and from foreign official
institutions at a fixed price of $35 per ounce.
Individual currencies were thus tied to gold
only indirectly, through the gold-convertibil­
ity of the dollar.
Commitment to intervene in the exchange
markets to maintain fixed exchange rates
implied that countries must hold reserves.
Drawing on these reserves permitted any
particular country to offset the temporary
imbalance in foreign accounts that occurred
when the demand of nationals for foreign
currencies to purchase goods abroad created
a demand that was greater than current earn­
ings on the country’s sales of goods abroad.
Without sufficient reserves, the governments
had to impose restrictions on foreign pur­
chases to equate the supply and demand of
foreign currencies.
Given the shortage of supply of gold, and
given the role of the dollar as the “inter­
vention” currency, countries began to hold
dollars as part of their official reserves. But
even the dollar was in short supply abroad
in the years immediately following World
War II. To aid reconstruction of war-de­
stroyed economies, the United States em­
barked upon a massive program of foreign
aid. As a result, more dollars flowed abroad
than were being received from abroad. Large
portions of these were retained by official in-




Importance of gold in w orld’s
m onetary reserves continues
to decline
billion dollars

stitutions abroad as reserves. The resulting
growth of reserves made it possible for foreign
countries to liberalize trade and foreign ex­
change policies. This, in turn, fostered growth
of international trade and, with it, of the
world’s prosperity. But in the process of sup­
plying dollars, the United States ran massive
balance-of-payments deficits.
Eventually, the consequences of the de­
ficits had to be faced. The U. S. gold
stock dwindled as foreign governments ex­
ercised their right to convert into gold dol­
lars accruing to them through the deficits.
At the same time, claims on the diminishing
supply of gold that were held by those gov­
ernments that chose to retain dollars in
liquid form mounted rapidly. Those devel­
opments gradually began to undermine the
confidence of the world in the U. S. ability
to maintain its commitment to convert foreign-held dollars into gold at a fixed price.

Business Conditions, November 1971

Many began to suspect that the United States
might substantially increase the price of gold
in terms of the dollar in order to increase the
dollar value of its gold stock and thus place
itself in the position to maintain its commit­
ment. These suspicions began to generate de­
mand for gold by private speculators who
hoped to profit by such a move.
The first such speculative attack came in
1960. The price of gold on the London gold
market rose well above the official price of
$35 as speculators bought large quantities
of gold in anticipation of an imminent re­
valuation. To allay the speculative atmos-

After ye a rs of officially
maintained stability, price
of gold fluctuates in response
to private supply and demand
U .S. dollar equivalent per fine ounce

1968

1969

1970

1971

‘ M arket supported by G o ld Pool up to M arch 15, 1968
an d closed M arch 15-April 1, 1968.




phere, monetary authorities entered into
arrangements designed to stabilize the price
of gold on the free market, thereby demon­
strating their determination to maintain a
fixed price. The United States, in coopera­
tion with seven major European countries
formed a so-called “Gold Pool,” which un­
dertook the sale of gold from official re­
serves to the private market whenever the
demand for gold tended to increase the price
above the official $35 per ounce.
The success of this arrangement to stem
future disruptive speculation in the gold
market was clearly predicated upon the elimi­
nation of the fundamental, underlying causes
of the speculation—the U. S. balance-ofpayments deficit. As long as the deficit would
continue to pour increasingly unwanted
dollars abroad, the suspicion that the re­
valuation of gold may take place would
persist.
The international monetary system was at
an impasse. To accommodate a growing
volume of world trade and capital move­
ments, the system needed a growing volume
of reserves in the hands of the official insti­
tutions charged with maintaining fixed ex­
change rates to smooth out ever-larger tem­
porary shortfalls of flows of funds. Gold and
the dollar had been the primary sources of
reserves. But world gold production was in­
sufficient to fill the growing need. The flow
of U. S. dollars abroad through U. S. balanceof-payments deficits supplied the needed re­
serves but at the same time led to confidencedestroying imbalance between the amounts of
dollars held abroad and the amount of gold
in U. S. reserves that were “backing” these
dollars. This, in turn, generated speculation
on the revaluation of gold, increasing the pri­
vate demand for gold, thereby further reduc­
ing the supply available to monetary authori­
ties. At the same time, had the United States

17

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

succeeded in eliminating the source of the
instability—the flow of dollars abroad—the
world would have had to face the possibility
of an inadequate supply of reserves.
Recognizing the impasse, in the early
Sixties, monetary authorities of major coun­
tries initiated studies and negotiations aimed
at developing an international reserve asset
that could be relied on to supplement, and
eventually to supplant, the existing assets.
This process culminated in 1967 when “Spe­
cial Drawing Rights” (SDRs) were accepted
at the meeting of the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) in Rio de Janerio as an inter­
national asset to be issued to individual
countries. It was not until 1970, however,
that the first issue of the SDRs took their

World reserves continue to
decline relative to the
volume of world trade
billion dollars

18

C .I.F.: Includes cost, insurance, an d freight.




percent

place in the official reserves of nations.
In the meantime, the gold exchange stan­
dard was rapidly approaching its final
agonies. In 1966, the private, largely specu­
lative, demand for gold exceeded the
world’s gold production of $1,440 million,
and officially-held, international monetary
reserves of gold actually declined by $45
million. In 1967, the decline in the world’s
gold reserves amounted to $1.6 billion. The
drain peaked in early 1968, as speculation
on revaluation reached a fever pitch. In
March of 1968, monetary authorities aban­
doned efforts to stabilize the private gold
market and determined henceforth neither
to buy newly-mined gold, nor sell gold to
private sources.3 The two-tier gold market
emerged as a result. One tier was open to
the public, and here the price of gold was
permitted to fluctuate daily in response to
supply and demand conditions. On the other
tier, sales and purchases of the existing stock
of monetary gold were limited to monetary
authorities of individual countries. On this
tier, the authorities agreed to maintain the
price of gold at $35 per ounce.
The establishment of the two-tier gold
market and the decision by monetary author­
ities to stop buying newly-mined gold were
important steps in the modem evolution of
the role of gold. These arrangements, in ef­
fect, drew a sharp line separating two distinct
characteristics of gold—one as a useful
commodity for industrial use, the other as
a monetary metal. A freely fluctuating price
in the private market provided an efficient
mechanism by which supply and demand
could become self-regulating. It provided
a framework within which human and capi3The agreement not to buy gold was later
modified to permit purchases of newly-mined
gold by the IMF under certain circumstances.

Business Conditions, November 1971

tal resources could be devoted to the labo­
rious process of extracting gold from the
depths of the earth in response to the needs
of industry—or to the decisions of private
holders who wished to hold gold as an asset
—as reflected in their willingness to pay the
necessary price. On the other hand, the
fixed price of gold within the international
payments system preserved the role of gold
as a point of reference for determining the
relative values of individual currencies. At
the same time, the decision not to purchase
additional newly-mined gold for official
monetary purposes formally acknowledged
the diminished importance of gold as a
source of reserves in the face of the develop­
ment of the new reserve asset—the SDR—
shortly to be put to use.
The March 1968 agreement laid the foun­
dation for a new era in international mone­
tary relations. But before these foundations
could be built upon, the problem of the
chronic surpluses and deficits in individual
countries’ international accounts still had to
be met. The difficulties involved here were
not diminished by the “solution-in-principle”
of the monetary reserve-creating problem.
Even though, technically, the U. S. deficit
no longer needed to be relied upon to pro­
vide growth in reserves in the form of dollars
flowing abroad (the SDRs were to assume
that role), “turning off” the flow of dollars
continued to be as difficult as before—if
not more so. The inflationary pressures that
developed in the U. S. economy in the latter
half of the Sixties led to sharp diminution
of the U. S. trade surplus—traditionally the
strongest point in the U. S. international
accounts. In 1969, the U. S. balance-ofpayments situation improved briefly as a
result of a tight monetary policy instituted
for purposes of combating domestic infla­
tion. As U. S. interest rates rose and at­



tracted foreign-held dollars into the United
States, the United States recorded a surplus
in its balance of payments on the official
transaction basis.
But the improvement was short-lived. As
monetary conditions in the United States
began to ease in late 1970, the flow of funds
abroad resumed. In early 1971, the flows
were superimposed on the deteriorated U. S.
trade position. The combined result was an
unprecedented deficit in the U. S. balance
of payments and large surpluses in several
major European countries and Japan. With
the gold issue largely out of the picture, specu­
lators turned their attention to the exchange
markets as a possible source of quick profit.
Speculation developed that changes in the
par values of world currencies would be the
means of eliminating the imbalances. By
taking a position in currencies to be revalued,
speculators stood to make good profit when
selling these currencies after their revalua­
tion. The inflow of dollars into official in­
stitutions in countries whose currencies were
rumored to be likely candidates for revalua­
tion reached staggering dimensions. In re­
cent years, foreign official institutions had
refrained from demanding U. S. gold for the
“excess” dollars they held in their reserves.
But by mid-1971, there was increasing dan­
ger that the deluge of dollars into their re­
serves might force these institutions to cash
in large quantities of dollars for U. S. gold.
At the end of July, foreign official institu­
tions held almost $33 billion of liquid claims
—against which the United States held $10.4
billion in gold. A “run on the bank” under
these circumstances could have brought the
entire monetary system tumbling down in
an atmosphere of panic. It was to preclude
this eventuality that the President of the
United States suspended the gold convert­
ibility of the dollar on August 15.

19

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

International Letter presents a weekly re­
cap of significant events relating to banking,
business, and governmental economic policies
on the world scene, together with brief ana­
lytical backgrounds. The letter also contains
charts showing interest rates in the world’s
money and capital markets and exchange
rates of major world currencies. Prepared by
a team of research economists on the staff of
the Chicago Fed, International Letter is the
latest addition to a series of newsletters pub­
lished by the Chicago bank.
Subscriptions free on request. Write: Re­
search Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago, Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.

BUSINESS CONDITIONS is p u b lish e d m o n th ly b y the F e d e ra l R eserve B a n k o f C h ic a g o . G e o rg e
W . Cloos w a s p r im a rily re sp o n sib le fo r the a rtic le "T h e com ing u p su rg e in e m p lo y m e n t" an d
Jo sep h G . K v a s n ic k a fo r " G o ld —P art I: A n h isto rica l p e rsp e c tiv e ."
Su b scrip tio n s to Business Conditions a re a v a ila b le to the p u b lic w ith o u t c h a rg e . For in fo r­
m atio n co n cern in g b u lk m a ilin g s , a d d re ss in q u irie s to the R esearch D e p a rtm e n t, F e d e ra l
R eserve B a n k o f C h ic a g o , B o x 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , Illin o is 6 0 6 9 0 .
A rtic le s m a y be re p rin te d p ro v id e d so urce is cred ite d . P le ase p ro v id e the b a n k 's R esearch
20

D e p artm e n t w ith a co p y o f a n y m a te ria l in w h ic h a n a rtic le is re p rin te d .