View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve B an k of Chicago

Business
Conditions
1963 N ovem ber

Contents
Trends in banking and finance

2

Stock prices
and business prospects

6

Foreign trade— the United States
competitive position

11

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

in banking and finance

I^eliminary estimates indicate that the flow
of private short- and long-term United States
capital abroad abated sharply in the third
quarter of 1963 from the record levels of the
first and second quarters of the year. The de­
cline may be attributed in part to a series of
monetary and fiscal policy actions adopted
and proposed in recent months to help reduce
the continuing large deficit in the United
States balance of international payments.
In mid-July, the Federal Reserve Banks
raised their discount rates from 3 to 3.5 per
cent. In addition, the ceiling on interest rates
commercial banks are permitted to pay on
time money—other than passbook savings—
deposited for three to 12 months was raised
to 4 per cent, the same ceiling as was in force
on time deposits of one year and over. At the
same time, the President requested Congress
to impose a temporary “interest equalization”
tax on United States purchases of foreign
securities from nonresidents.1

The increases in the discount rate and in­
terest rate ceiling together with greater Fed­
eral Reserve emphasis on providing reserves
through the discount window exerted upward
pressure on domestic short-term interest
rates. However, the continuing high level of
domestic unemployment made it undesirable
to transmit the upward pressure fully to long­
term interest rates. Higher long-term rates
would tend to restrict investment in new
domestic facilities. Raising the interest rate
ceiling on time deposits contributed to
higher across-the-board short-term interest
rates by giving banks greater leeway in bid­
ding for three to 12 month deposits. On the
other hand, the increased inflow of time de­
posits encouraged the banks to seek addi­
tional longer-term investments, bidding up
the prices of long-term securities and tending
to at least partially offset upward pressures
on long-term rates.

Tor a review of the proposed interest equaliza­
tion tax see “Foreign Long-Term Borrowing in the
United States,” Business Conditions, September

Since the end of June, when anticipations
of an increase in the discount rate began to
exert a noticeable impact on short-term inter-

1963.

BUSINESS CONDITIONS

S h o rt-te rm ra te s rise

is published monthly by the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago. G eorg e G . Kaufman

was primarily responsible fo r the article “ Trend s in Banking and Finance" and G eorge W . C loos fo r “ Stock
Prices and Business Prospects.”
Subscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public w ithout charge. Fo r inform ation concerning bulk
mailings, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago, Chicago, Illinois 60690.
2

A rticles may be reprinted provided source is credited.




B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N ovem ber 1963

est rates, yields on three-month Treasury bills
have increased about .5 per cent to just under
3.5 per cent. At the same time the average
yield on long-term Government bonds rose
only slightly—from 4 per cent to 4.07 per
cent—despite the additional upward pressure
exerted by the recent acceleration in business
activity and a large-scale Treasury refunding.
The latter increased the volume of long-term
securities outstanding substantially, lengthen­
ing the average maturity of the marketable
public debt from 4 years 11 months to 5
years 3 months, the longest in seven years.
Banks have bid vigorously for time de­
posits. At mid-October, many large banks
were offering 3.75 per cent interest on three
to six month negotiable time certificates of
deposit, compared with the ceiling rate of 2.5
per cent three months earlier. Some banks
also offered 3% per cent on six to nine
month CDs, Vs per cent more than in midJuly. These higher rates attracted a consider­
able volume of funds. Large New York City
banks increased their volume of outstanding
CDs more than 400 million dollars, or almost
20 per cent, in the three months from midJuly to mid-October against an increase of
only 11 per cent in the comparable 1962
period.
The total increase in time deposits of indi­
viduals, partnerships and corporations—
other than passbook savings—at large banks
throughout the country was more than 750
million dollars in this period, over twice as
much as a year earlier. At the same time,
passbook savings, on which the interest rate
ceiling remained at 3.5 per cent for deposits
held less than one year and 4 per cent for
over one year deposits, rose less rapidly than
in the 1962 period.
Higher short-term rates appear to have
contributed to the slowdown in the outflow
of short-term capital in the third quarter. The



Sp re ad between short-term
interest rates in United States
and abroad narrows in recent months
yield

I9 6 0

1961

1962

1963

:;:Three-m onth treasury b ill rates.
fTh re e -m o n th rates on U. S. dollar deposits in London.

outflow is estimated to have declined to only
about half that of the second quarter when re­
corded short-term outflows totaled over 500
million dollars.
C a p ita l a ttra c te d to h ig h e st return

Short-term United States capital move­
ments abroad generally take the form of bank
loans, trade credit and investments in foreign
liquid assets. Bank loans and trade credit are
usually denominated in dollars—and must
be repaid in dollars—while investments may
be in either dollars or foreign currency.
American capital is transferred abroad when
net returns there are greater. Capital de­
nominated in dollars is generally transferred
in response to interest rate differentials. Capi­
tal denominated in foreign currency is influ­
enced not only by interest rate differentials
but also by the risk of unfavorable move­
ments in exchange rates that may occur be­
tween the time the funds are moved abroad
and the time they are reconverted into dol­
lars. Investors may hedge against this risk, if

3

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

they wish, by the simultaneous purchase of a
like amount of United States dollars for
future delivery. Such purchases are called
forward cover. Hedged movements respond
primarily to the net spread—commonly re­
ferred to as the net incentive—between inter­
est rate differentials and the cost of hedging
or purchase of forward cover.
The cost of forward cover is the difference
between the cost of United States dollars for
immediate delivery—the spot exchange rate
—and the cost for future delivery—the for­
ward exchange rate. When the forward ex­
change rate is below the spot rate, the for­
ward rate is said to be at a discount. When
the forward exchange rate is above the spot
rate, the forward rate is said to be at a pre­
mium.2
When the gross interest rate spread is equal
to the cost of forward cover, there is no moti­
vation to transfer hedged capital in response
to international interest rate differentials and
interest rate parity is said to exist.
Although Canada raised its discount rate
to 4 per cent from 3.5 per cent in August,
only one month after the United States dis­
count rate was raised to 3.5 per cent, Cana­
dian short-term interest rates rose somewhat
less in the three months since mid-July than
rates in this country. By mid-October, the
gross spread between rates on three-month

4

The 3-month forward discount or premium is
often shown as a percentage to permit ready com­
parisons with interest rate differentials. The per­
centage discount or premium is computed, at first
approximation, by dividing the difference between
the spot and the 3-month forward exchange rates by
the spot rate and multiplying by 4 to convert to an
annual interest rate basis. For example, if the spot
U. S. dollar-British pound sterling exchange rate
were $2.80 for £ 1 and the 3-month forward rate
$2.78 for £ 1 , the forward dollar would be selling
at a premium equal to (.02 -r- 2.80) x 4 or 2.86
per cent. Likewise, the forward pound would be
selling at a discount of 2.86 per cent.




Treasury bills in Canada and the United
States, which had favored Canada by about
.25 per cent, was reduced to only a few per­
centage points. Interest rates on three-month
British treasury bills remained relatively sta­
ble during this period and the gross spread
between American and British rates narrowed
from over .50 per cent in favor of British bills
to less than .25 per cent.
The changes are similar with respect to
the incentives for hedged transactions. In
mid-July the net incentive favored Canada by
about .20 per cent as a result of somewhat
higher Canadian short-term interest rates and
a slight discount in the price of the forward
Canadian dollar. Three months later, the net
incentive favored Canada by less than half as
much. The decline in the spread between
American and Canadian interest rates was in
part offset by a reduction in the discount on
the forward Canadian dollar. The discount
on forward British pound sterling changed
only slightly in this period, but as the spread
between American and British short-term
interest rates declined sharply, the net incen­
tive to transfer capital abroad on a covered
basis turned in favor of the United States.
Possibly more important than the effects
of interest rates on capital flows have been
the effects of the policy actions in increasing
confidence in the ability and willingness of
this country to defend the dollar. This has
served to diminish the incentive to transfer
funds abroad in anticipation of a depreciation
of the dollar relative to gold and other cur­
rencies. Sharply higher short-term interest
rates have been proposed as a solution to the
balance of payments problem, particularly
by foreigners.
T a x slo w s ca p ital o u tflo w

Although Congress has yet to take final
action on the proposed “interest equaliza­

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N ovem b er 1963

tion” tax, uncertainty surrounding its adop­
tion has affected long-term capital move­
ments. Foreign borrowers and domestic lend­
ers alike are hesitant about entering into
agreements without full knowledge of the tax
cost. As a consequence, scheduling of new
foreign securities has slowed almost to a
standstill. Nevertheless, because the proposed
tax exempts new securities registered but not
sold before July 18, third quarter figures on
long-term capital outflows from the United
States will still show a sizable outflow.
The almost complete cessation of new
foreign security sales in this country may be
attributed more to the uncertainty surround­
ing congressional approval of the tax than to
the penalties of the tax itself. It has been
estimated that once Congress acts on the tax
proposal, regardless of the outcome, the sales
of new foreign issues here will rise again al­
though probably not to the unusually high
levels of the first half of the year.
The proposed tax has also created a dual
market for outstanding foreign securities.
Securities sold by nonresidents frequently
sell at a somewhat lower price than the same
securities sold by residents. The difference in
price roughly reflects the buyer’s estimate of
the probability of the tax being adopted. Re­
cently, for example, a share of Royal Dutch
Petroleum (a Dutch concern) traded on the
New York Stock Exchange at $47% if the
seller was a resident and at $46% if the seller
was a nonresident. This difference in price is
less than the amount of the proposed tax,
reflecting the market’s doubts about its pas­
sage in the present form.
Monetary and fiscal actions have a fairly
prompt impact on capital movements. Effects
on other components of the balance of pay­
ments would take place more gradually. For
example, if higher short-term interest rates
discourage business firms from borrowing



enough to create upward price pressures on
commodities, this would have a longer-term
favorable effect on the trade balance. Slower
increases in the prices of domestic products
in comparison with foreign prices, would
help to increase exports. (For a more detailed
analysis of recent price trends see “Foreign
Trade—the United States Competitive Posi­
tion” on page 11 of this issue.) It has long
been noted that a country can better achieve
a lasting equilibrium in its balance of inter­
national payments by increasing exports than
by restricting capital outflows.
District b u sin e ss lo a n s stre n g th e n

Business loans outstanding at major banks
in Seventh District leading cities rose 165
million dollars in the third quarter of 1963,
well over twice as much as in the same
quarter of 1962. At the same time business
loans at large banks throughout the country
rose less than in 1962. At the end of Septem­
ber, District business loans were almost 12
per cent above year-earlier levels. This rate
of expansion was almost twice as fast as for
the larger banks in all United States leading
cities and compares with an increase of less
than 8 per cent in the previous 12 month
period when District loans expanded at about
the national average.
The recent strengthening in District busi­
ness loan demand is evident for almost all
industry groups except retail outlets and mis­
cellaneous durable goods. Loans to petro­
leum firms, commodity dealers and chemical
and rubber concerns showed particular
strength, increasing 38, 30 and 19 million
dollars, respectively, more than in the third
quarter of 1962. Bank loans to finance com­
panies, which are not included in business
loans, also expanded sharply, ending the
quarter 50 million dollars above the year-ago
level.

5

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

Stock prices
and business prospects
jA -fter a dull performance in the early sum­
mer, common stock prices surged upward and
in September the most widely used indexes
broke through the previous record highs
reached in December 1961. This develop­
ment was taken as a favorable omen not only
for a further rise in the market but also for
general business prospects.
Stock market trends long have been ac­
corded an almost mystical significance. Some
believe changes in stock prices directly meas­
ure the level of business activity. Others
solemnly repeat the adage, “the stock market
discounts everything six months in advance.”
Observers strain at personification: “What is
the market trying to tell us? I think the mar­
ket is saying. . . .” In late summer the mes­
sage that the business outlook was excellent
seemed to be coming through loud and clear.
But a leveling of the stock indexes in October
gave rise to doubts. Do market trends foretell
business prospects in a useful manner? Let’s
look at the record.
W h y should the m a rk e t te n d to le a d ?

Stock price changes were more generally
accepted as a forecasting aid in the Twenties
than in recent years. This was partly because
the entire statistical framework for analyzing
business conditions was relatively undevel­
oped at that time.
A 1927 book, Forecasting Business Condi­
tions, by Hardy and Cox, observed that,
6

Perhaps the most widely accepted principle
in relation to the subject of our study is the
doctrine that changes in the stock market




forecast similar changes in the volume and
direction of business activity.

The authors went on to voice considerable
skepticism toward the market’s dependability
as a short-run indicator. Their doubts were
validated by subsequent developments. Busi­
ness activity began to decline a month or two
before the market crash in 1929 and abortive
stock price revivals in 1930 and 1931 raised
false hopes of an early end to the business
depression.
In recent years most writers on business
forecasting have concluded that changes in
stock price indexes tend to lead changes in
business activity but that the relationship is
not stable. Nevertheless, when attempts have
been made to draw up lists of statistical indi­
cators which customarily move in advance of
general business activity an index of stock
market price almost invariably is included.
The rationale behind the use of stock price
indexes as an indicator of future business
prospects is clear enough. The major stock
exchanges are among the most perfectly com­
petitive markets in the entire economy with
many well-informed buyers and sellers.
Prices of shares are determined by the deci­
sions that millions of individuals and institu­
tions throughout the world communicate to
traders in the organized stock exchanges.
Although some investors buy or sell on the
basis of formulas, “systems” or hunches,
most decisions are based upon evaluations of
a vast array of detailed information on the
economy and on individual business firms.
Rising prices indicate that optimistic senti-

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N o ve m b e r 1 9 6 3

ment is predominant and that buyers are tak­
ing the initiative. In a falling market the
opposite conditions prevail—selling pressure
is relatively strong because of the growth of
pessimistic attitudes.
Changes in the level of stock prices tend
to have a direct impact on business condi­
tions. First, since stock prices are widely
accepted as a leading indicator, increases or
decreases in the indexes may cause businesses
and consumers to become more aggressive or
show greater caution in spending and in mak­
ing investment commitments. Second, indi­
viduals who hold stocks find that their wealth
and borrowing power—using stocks as col­
lateral—fluctuate with stock prices and their
spending may be influenced by market move­
ments even though they have not realized
gains or losses through sales of their holdings.
Third, businesses that contemplate selling
stock to finance expansion and perhaps pro­
vide a base for additional debt may activate
or postpone such plans depending upon
whether stock prices rise or fall.
The level of the stock market as measured
by common stock price indexes has strong
appeal as an economic barometer for a num­
ber of reasons. First, changes in prices re­
flect changes in investors’ evaluations of
future corporate profit trends, with the aggre­
gate value of all common stocks thus pre­
sumably measuring the going concern value
of all corporate business. Second, in contrast
with most other economic measures, which
become available a month or more after the
period covered, stock price indexes are calcu­
lated every hour of the trading day. Third, the
latest stock price indexes are readily available
to all interested parties because they are re­
ported regularly over the “ticker,” on the
radio and in virtually all major newspapers.
Fourth, millions of individuals follow the
market because they have a personal interest




in stock price indexes as owners or potential
owners of stock.
Substantial changes in stock prices often
have a highly speculative basis—for example,
the sharp drop in September 1955 following
President Eisenhower’s heart attack. But
most stockholders presumably buy and sell
on the basis of changes in the prospects for
corporate profits (after taxes) available for
dividends or reinvestment.
Emphasis on profits does not invalidate the
market as a barometer of business activity.
For obvious reasons corporate profits tend to
rise and decline with the level of business.
In the early stages of a business upturn or
downturn, changes in business sales bring
even greater relative changes in profits be­
cause a substantial proportion of business
costs are fixed or relatively fixed during short
periods of time. After an upswing has been
under way for a year or more, rising costs
usually begin to catch up with or surpass the
rise in sales. As a result, total corporate prof­
its and especially profits as a per cent of sales
have tended to decline or rise before general
business activity. For this reason corporate
profits after taxes, along with common stock
prices, appear to be a measure that often
changes direction before business activity.
Does the market forecast changes in cor­
porate profits accurately? If so, the market
averages would move fairly smoothly some
distance ahead of profits. But this has not
been the case as the chart on pages 8-9 shows.
There is also the matter of relative changes
in magnitude over time. In 1962 corporate
profits after taxes were nearly the same as in
1959 while industrial production was 12 per
cent higher and stock prices averaged 9 per
cent higher. In a longer-term comparison
1962 corporate profits were 20 per cent
greater than in 1948 while industrial produc­
tion was up 73 per cent and the index of

7

Fed era l Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N ove m b e r 1963

H av e ch ange s in stock prices "called business turns"?

The postwar record shows many erratic movements.

corporate profits after tax-billion dollars
stock prices-standard 8 p o o rs - 1 9 4 1 - 4 3 = 1 0 0
s tria ) p ro d u c tio n -p e r cent, I 9 5 7 " 5 9 = 1 0 0

100
90

“ !3 0

80

“ 120

70

“ 110 2 8

70

12

60

8

- J - ju - i 5 0

4

-

10

„,i. i i i i i i i i i i,

1946

1948

1949

common stock prices had increased fourfold.
The p o stw a r reco rd

8

Anyone who has observed the continuing
fluctuations in stock prices realizes that it is
not easy to determine when a genuine “turn”
occurred in the market prior to a peak or
trough in the business cycle even if the event
is long past. The financial press carries highs
and lows in the averages for each trading day.




1950

1951

1952

1953

Often trends are established for several days,
even weeks and months, only to be reversed
several times before a peak or trough in the
business cycle occurs.
Some who follow the market try to inter­
pret the highly erratic day-to-day movements.
Business cycle analysts normally employ
monthly averages which smooth out some
random movements. Standard and Poor’s
composite index of 500 industrial, rail and

1954 * *

-

■*> 1955

1957

1958

utility stocks is most commonly employed for
analytical purposes. How has this measure
performed in relation to general business
activity during the postwar period?
The S & P composite index averaged 49
per cent higher in September 1963 than five
years earlier. In the 60 months between these
dates the index rose 36 times and declined
24 times. The longest “run” in one direction
was seven months and the second longest was

I9 6 0

1962

four months. Between the start of the current
business expansion in February 1961 and
September 1963 the index rose 17 per cent.
During the period there were 19 increases
and 12 declines. The longest consecutive run
in one direction was only four months and
the index changed direction from one month
to another no less than 14 times out of a
possible 31!
There have been eight business cycle turns

9

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

10

in the period from 1946 to date. Peaks were
reached in 1948, 1953, 1957 and 1960 and
troughs occurred in 1949, 1954, 1958 and
1961. In each case the change for better or
worse was preceded by at least one similar
movement in stock prices. But in some peri­
ods, particularly before the peaks of 1957
and 1960, a market decline was reversed in
the months immediately before the turn in
business. On several occasions, most noticea­
bly in 1946 and 1962, there were relatively
sharp changes in the market that were not
followed by comparable changes in business
activity. Assuming a change of 5 per cent
or more to be a “swing” in the monthly
average of the Standard and Poor’s composite
index, there have been 11 declines in the
market and 13 rallies since 1946 as compared
with only four business cycle troughs and
four peaks.
In retrospect the sharp drop in the market
in 1962—21 per cent from March to June
with no appreciable recovery until Novem­
ber—presents one of the most noteworthy
false signals provided by the stock price in­
dexes. Forecasts of a decline in general busi­
ness activity became widespread in October
1962 just at the time that a renewed upswing
was about to begin.
Only one other postwar decline in stock
prices— as measured by changes in monthly
averages—was as severe as that of 1962. Be­
tween May and November 1946 the compos­
ite index dropped 21 per cent. This develop­
ment, however, was followed by two years of
vigorous expansion in business activity dur­
ing which time the index never approached
its 1946 high.
A different sort of false signal was offered
by the stock market in 1957 when the Stand­
ard and Poor’s index rose 12 per cent be­
tween February and July. The latter month
afterwards was accepted widely as the peak




of the business expansion. The same story
was retold, although less emphatically, in
1960 when the market rose 4 per cent be­
tween March and June although May 1960
later was accepted as a business peak.
R e a d in g the m a r k e t’s m e ssa g e

Historical comparisons of trends in com­
mon stock prices and business activity reveal
no clear or dependable pattern. Since the
early postwar period, stock prices have risen
far more than most broad measures of activ­
ity and many zigs and zags in the market have
not had counterparts in business fluctuations.
In short, if the market is “trying to tell us
something” about short-term business pros­
pects, we have not yet learned its language.
In the long run, on the other hand, stock
market prices measure public confidence in
the future of American prosperity. Market
appraisals of the worth of business firms, in­
dividually and collectively, comprise a vital
part of our economic intelligence.

The Two Faces o f Debt
A new booklet e n title d The Tw o Faces

of Debt has recently been p u b lish e d by
the Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago.
It presents a d e sc rip tio n o f the role o f
debt in o ur economy and the d is trib u ­
tio n o f debt am ong m a jo r g ro u p s o f
debtors and c re d ito rs. Copies o f th is
booklet, as w e ll as M odern Money
Mechanics—a w o rk b o o k on deposits,
currency and bank re se rve s, a re a v a il­
able to banks, b u sin e ss o rg a n iza tio n s
and educational in s titu tio n s fro m the
Research D e p a rtm e nt, Fe d e ra l Reserve
Bank o f Chicago, Box 8 3 4 , Chicago,
Illin o is 6 0 6 9 0 .

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N ovem b er 1963

Foreign trade— the United States
competitive position
(_>un United States exports be increased
enough to eliminate the deficit in its balance
of international payments? This possible
remedy is given high priority in American
international economic policy. Businessmen
are urged to seek out additional export
opportunities and Congress has authorized
expansion and improvement of insurance and
financing facilities that aid private exports.
But many persons call attention to the fact
that this country now exports nearly 5 billion
dollars more of goods each year than it im­
ports and many observers express doubts
that this surplus can be boosted substantially.
Others not only believe that boosting exports
is the most desirable attack on the balance of
payments problem but also that this approach
has good prospects of succeeding.
One view — reiterated recently by the
Brookings Institution, a privately endowed
research organization — is that European
wages and prices will continue to rise fairly
rapidly and that this will go a long way
toward ending, possibly in five years, the
deficit in the United States balance of pay­
ments.1 The Brookings study also assumes a
faster rate of economic growth in the United
States, both relative to its own record in re­
cent years and relative to the growth rate in
Western Europe in the years ahead. While
there are plausible reasons for making these
'Such deficits, which have occurred almost every
year since 1950, result from the fact that the United
States spends, lends, invests and gives away abroad
more than foreigners spend, lend and invest in this
country.




assumptions, placing major emphasis on
continued inflation abroad to provide a solu­
tion to our balance of payments problem
leaves us in the awkward position of relying
on the failures of others in order to solve our
own problems. Whether these assumptions,
and the conclusions based upon them, prove
to be correct will be determined largely by
the answer to a more basic question: is the
competitive position of the United States
strengthening relative to that of its major
world trading competitors?
Prices a n d w a g e s risin g

Prices and wages have advanced during the
last few years in both the United States and
Europe. But in the United States, consumer
prices rose less rapidly than in France, Ger­
many, Italy and Britain. This has been true
even if allowance is made for changes in offi-

Prices and wages, 1962
Consumer
prices

Hourly
W holesale
earnings in
prices manufacturing

(1958 =

100)

United States. . .

105

100

France..................

119

113

133

Germ any.............

109

103

140

Ita ly ......................

109

101

132

United Kingdom.

110

107

127

SO URC E: OECD, Genera Statistics
Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, July 1963.

113

and U. N.,

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

12

cial values of currencies. France’s prices
volume changes in many different commodi­
probably rose somewhat more than they
ties. Nevertheless, based upon available in­
would have in the absence of the 17 per cent
formation, it appears that export prices, in
devaluation of the French franc in December
terms of dollars, rose in the United States,
1958, and Germany’s prices may have been
Germany and Britain, and fell in France and
held down somewhat by the upward revalua­
Italy from 1958 to 1962. Import prices de­
tion of the German mark in March 1961.
clined in each of the five countries. Both
export volume and import volume in 1962
Wholesale prices were stable here but ad­
vanced in the Old World—though only
were larger for each country than in 1958.
nominally in Italy.
There is no consistent pattern between
price changes and volume changes. For ex­
The relative price stability in the United
ample, although prices (unit values) of ex­
States must be attributed in large part to the
ported goods rose somewhat more steeply in
ample capacity in major industries and a
Germany than in the United States, Germany
measure of restraint in wage settlements and
was able to boost its exports substantially
fringe benefits. These settlements, of course,
more. And although German import prices
are related to the over-all job market and
have been influenced by the relatively high
fell less than those in the United States, Ger­
level of unemployment.
many’s imports rose at a faster rate. On the
It does not necessarily follow from the
other hand, Italy, whose prices declined most
on both sides of the trade ledger, ranked first
above, however, that the United States ex­
port position has improved in proportion.
in gains in both exports and imports.
In all the countries, export prices rose
For export and import prices, which are
important factors affecting the
quantities of American goods de­
manded by foreigners and the
quantities of foreign goods de­
Export-im port prices and volume, 1962
manded by Americans, do not
Export
Export
Import
Import
necessarily move in step with the
prices® volume prices'* volume
broad gauge price indexes. This is
(1958 = 100)
especially true for a country like
117
United States.............. . . 103
96
127
the United States whose exports
96
95
144
150
France..........................
and imports are a much smaller
Germany...................... . . 104
144
97
171
fraction (8 per cent) of gross na­
211
93
198
90
Ita ly................................
tional product than is the foreign
122
United Kingdom......... . . 103
116
97
trade of most other industrial
159
Common M a rke t. . . . . . 100
147
95
nations (30 to 40 per cent).
European Free
Unfortunately, the available
97
125
136
Trade A re a ............ . . 102
evidence that pertains more di­
“Expressed in United States dollars in order to reflect revalua­
rectly to exports and imports also
tions of national currencies against the dollar. Index figures not
is less than adequate, largely be­
strictly comparable because o f varying procedures used by countries
in compiling indexes.
cause of difficulties in represent­
SO URC E: IMF, International Financial Statistics and U. N ., Monthly
ing in one or a few numbers
Bulletin of Statistics, July 1963.
the composite effects of price and




B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N ovem ber 1963

relative to import prices and the rise in im­
port volume generally outpaced the advance
in export volume. The only exception to this
is France, where export and import prices
moved nearly in step but import volume was
up less than export volume.
A convenient way to measure the relative
strengths of exports and imports is to let the
ratio of import volume to export volume of
each country be equal to one for the base
year (1958).
Import-export ratios, 1962
(1958 = 1.00)
F r a n c e ....................................... 0.96
United K in g d o m .....................1.05
Italy ..........................................1.07
United States ......................... 1.09
G e r m a n y ...................................1.19

Of the five countries compared, France was
the only one whose export volume rose faster
than import volume from 1958 to 1962.
The foregoing data suggest a few conclu­
sions. First, relatively small percentage in­
creases in the fairly comprehensive measures
of domestic wages and prices do not assure a
country a favorable standing in the prices
and the volume of goods exported. This is
partly because the commodity composition of
total exports differs from that in the whole­
sale and consumer price indexes. Prices and
wages rose considerably more in France than
in the United States, but it was able to boost
its export volume by about three times as
much due partly to its currency devaluation
in December 1958. The fact that France’s
import volume advanced only a little less,
despite higher franc prices of its imports
after devaluation, may be largely attributable
to the new trading opportunities which arose
as the members of the Common Market be­
gan to reduce their tariff barriers on January
1, 1959. In contrast, Germany’s export ex­
pansion was slowed and its import growth



boosted by the upward revaluation of the
mark in March 1961.
Second, a fall in import prices relative to
export prices tends to favor growth in im­
ports relative to exports. In the case of the
industrial countries considered here, the rela­
tive growth of imports reflects an improve­
ment in their terms of trade vis-a-vis the
countries whose major exports are raw ma­
terials. In other words, prices of their exports
tended to rise relative to prices of their im­
ports. The shifts in these price ratios, 195862, for the main regions of the world were:
United States and C a n a d a ..............106
Common M a r k e t.............................. 105
European Free Trade A r e a ......... 105
Latin A m e r ic a ................................. 96
Africa ................................................. 90
Middle E a s t ...................................... 89
SOURCE:
o f Statistics,

U.N., M on th ly
July 1963.

Bulletin

Third, the greater relative increase in the
foreign trade of Germany, Italy and France,
despite greater percentage increases in wages
and prices, reflects the high rate of growth of
trade within the Common Market. The
smaller relative increase in foreign trade of
the United States reflects the slower rise of
demand in Latin America and Canada, which
are important United States markets.
Another possibility for gauging a country’s
“exporting strength” is to express its export
(import) surplus as a per cent of its total
merchandise trade during a given period. For
the five countries considered, the results are
given in the table on page 14.
The two countries with an export surplus
in 1958 (United States and Germany) were
still net exporters in 1962, though by a some­
what smaller margin. Countries with an im­
port surplus in 1958 (France, Italy, United
Kingdom) were still net importers in 1962—

13

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

in 1958; in the United States the rise was
about one-eighth. But because of their low
starting point, representative European
wages in 1962 were on the whole still only
W a g e s , ou tpu t a n d prices
from one-fifth to two-fifths of the comparable
American average, and in absolute (rather
The most basic ingredient of international
than relative) terms the gap widened from
competition, of course, is comparative pro­
duction costs. While relative movements of
1958 to 1962.
Fringe costs, which are not included in the
production costs are affected by many things,
wage data, are often a sizable share of total
possibly wages loom largest. But while better
labor costs, and the relative importance var­
information is available for wages than for
ies widely from country to country. In Italy,
most other industrial costs, the implications
fringe benefits are almost equal to “regular”
of wage trends for shifts in competitive
strength are not easily appraised. Hourly
earnings. In France they account for about
two-thirds and in Germany for about half,
earnings in manufacturing do not reveal
but in the United Kingdom fringe benefits
whether or not the cost gap between United
are only about one-seventh of regular earn­
States and European goods that are interna­
ings. The comparable ratio in the United
tionally traded narrowed in relative terms
States is about one-fifth.
between 1958 and 1962. A rising wage trend
Combined hourly and fringe payments in
might be reinforced, or offset, by movements
major Western European countries range
of fringe costs, changes in output per man­
from approximately one-fourth (Italy) to
hour and other factors.
one-third (Germany) of the comparable
On an hourly basis, manufacturing work­
United States total. Including fringe benefits
ers in major European countries in 1962
has the effect, therefore, of narrowing the
earned on average about one-third more than
range of differences in
total hourly wage costs
in Europe while at the
Total trade flo w s and trade surpluses
same time bringing the
average E u ro p ean
Export
Ratio of surplus to
Value of
(import-) surplus
value of foreign trade
foreign trade
hourly wage costs
J958
J962
1958
1962
1958
1962
closer to the United
(millions)
Iper cent)
States figure. Such a
United States
broad,
multi-country
4,533
5,173
38,115
14.5
13.6
(d ol.)............. 31,307
average,
of course,
— 4.5 — 1.0
France (fr.). . . . 45,070“ 73,450“ — 2,050“ — 750
conceals
large
differ­
7.5
3.8
Germany (m.). . 68,810“ 102,040“
3,860
5,150“
ences.
This
is
also
true
— 11.0 — 13.0
Italy (L.)............ 3,621 b
6,701b — 399 b — 869
of
country
averages,
United Kingdom
which gloss over dif­
— 6.1 — 6.4
8,441
— 430 — 543
(stg.).............. 7,066
ferences among re­
“ Figures given in billions, with two decimal places only. In converting to millions, a
gions, industries and
ze ro has been added.
firms.
Nevertheless,
b Billions.
SO URCE: IMF, International Financial Statistics, July 1963.
wage d i f f e r e n c e s

by an even larger margin—except France
which had nearly eliminated her import sur­
plus.

14




B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, N ovem ber 1963

Since the extent to which an in­
crease in production per man­
hour offsets the increase in wages
Other nations
Difference
as per cent
Hourly earnings
varies, changes in wage cost per
in manufacturing
from U. S.
of U. S.
unit of output also differ between
1962
1958
1962
1958
1962
1958
countries. For example, in the in­
$2.39
United S ta te s... $2.11
dustrial sector (mining, construc­
.50
$1.73 $1.89
18
21
.38
France.................
tion and manufacturing) gains in
26
34
.54
.81
1.57
1.58
Germany............
output per hour in France and
1.9916
17“
.35
.40a
1.76
Ita ly.....................
Germany between 1954 and 1961
37
41
.99b
1.33
1.40
.78a
United Kingdom
offset roughly half the increase in
a 1961 (1962 figures not available).
wage cost per hour, hence unit
b Males.
wage cost rose by somewhat more
N o te : Figures are dollar equivalents o f payments received by (all) wage
than one-third. In the United
earners in their national currencies. Conversion into dollars at end-of-year
exchange rates.
States and Italy, on the other
SO URC E: U. N., Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, July 1963.
hand, output per hour advanced
at nearly the same rate as wages,
among leading European industries are far
resulting in only a very small rise in labor
less pronounced than the gap between these
cost per unit of output in these countries. In
industries and their United States counter­
the United Kingdom unit cost rose at a rate
almost equal to Germany’s, although the two
parts. In 1960, for example, average hourly
components of unit cost advanced much less
earnings and fringe benefits in the chemicals
rapidly.
and machine tool industries in European
It is of great consequence to industry on
countries tended to cluster around the equiva­
both sides of the Atlantic how the major
lent of $1; for workers in the United States
employed in these industries, the average was
determinants of unit labor costs will move in
the principal trading nations. If wage costs in
more than $3 an hour.
Europe increase on average 8 per cent per
Any meaningful appraisal of relative unit
year while output per man-hour advances
costs must take into account production per
only 4 per cent, and if at the same time Amer­
hour as well as wages. Although reliable data
ican wage costs increase 4 per cent per year
are scarce and problems of interpretation are
while output per man-hour increases 3 per
numerous, there can be no doubt that wide
cent, Europe’s competitive position will
differences exist, both in absolute levels of
worsen on balance.
output per man-hour and in the trend of
Any estimate of future changes in com­
changes in these levels, both among the Euro­
pean countries and between them and the
parative output per man-hour among various
countries—if anything more than an exten­
United States. For example, it is estimated
sion of recent trends—must take into account
that gross production per man-hour in manu­
many things. Commercially useful inventions,
facturing increased from 1954 to 1960 by
for example, may increase production per
well over 30 per cent in Germany, nearly 30
man-hour faster in one area than another.
per cent in France, but slightly less than 20
per cent in Italy, the United Kingdom and the
The economic integration of the European
Economic Community (EEC) and of the
United States.
C o m p arative w age earnings
in manufacturing




15

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

European Free Trade Association (EFTA)
—not to mention similar efforts in the less
developed countries of Latin America and
Africa—might possibly help Western Europe
to keep unit wage costs in check. But com­
petitive improvements on this score could be
offset by the effects of the new United States
tax incentives (accelerated depreciation and
tax credit provisions recently enacted) de­
signed to spur a higher rate of capital invest­
ment in this country. The currently proposed
reduction of corporate income tax rates
would tend to have similar effects.
Inflationary pressures in Europe are still
another uncertainty. They have lately gener­
ated increased interest in public policies on
wages and prices and resulted in adoption of
programs to restrain these pressures.
C on clusion s a n d o u tlo o k

16

On the basis of presently available infor­
mation, it is difficult to evaluate the competi­
tive position of the United States in interna­
tional trade. There is some indication that
the United States competitive position vis-avis other major trading nations declined
somewhat from 1958 to 1962, despite the
stability of wholesale prices in this country.
In recent months, however, several coun­
tries—especially France and Italy—have ex­
perienced a rapidly rising trend in hourly
labor costs. If it continues, it may well lead
to a strengthening of the competitive position
of the United States, but statistics on exports
and imports in 1963 hardly suggest that such
an improvement has already occurred.
Labor remains in relatively short supply in
Europe, while it is relatively abundant in the
United States. This should help to maintain
stable prices here. In years past, as the econ­
omy has moved close to full employment, an
accelerated rise of wage rates and prices has
followed. It may be necessary, therefore, to




develop wage-making arrangements which
permit the country to approach full employ­
ment without incurring cost-inflating wage
increases. The United States as well as Eur­
ope has shortages of particular skills, as edu­
cation and training have lagged behind
changing technological requirements and
changing consumer demands.
The growth trends in the labor force in
Europe and the United States will diverge
during the remainder of this decade. It has
been estimated that by 1970 the European
Economic Community’s labor force will be
only 5 per cent larger than it is now, while
the working population will be 17 per cent
greater in the United States and 7.5 per cent
larger in the United Kingdom.
Even if the rate of population increase in
Europe should rise above its 1 per cent
annual average of recent years and approach
the 1.7 per cent annual increase in the United
States, it would be many years before the
effects of the accelerated trend showed up in
the labor force. In the meantime Europe, like
the United States, may expect some addition
to the industrial labor supply resulting from
the shift of manpower “from farms to fac­
tories.” Whether the momentum of this
movement, already significant in the late
Fifties, can be maintained in the Sixties will
depend in part on how the area’s hard foughtout agricultural policy is finally implemented.
In the broadest view, some facets of pro­
spective developments in other industrial
countries will tend to favor a net gain in the
United States competitive position in world
markets in the Sixties. But the evidence is not
clear enough to assure that this will be the
outcome, and it is unlikely that the sizable
deficit in the balance of international pay­
ments of the United States can be resolved
by attention to exports alone, important as
that is.