View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Fe d era l Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
1953

N ovem ber

Contents
Debt, to most men and through all
ages, has been a "two-faced w o rri­
some thing." The problems and par­
adoxes posed by high and rising debt
are discussed in

Debt— Jekyll and Hyde

4

and the current debt developments
are reported in

The Trend of Business

2

r p n n

the
E v id e n c e

that

o v e r -a l l

b u s in e s s

a c t iv it y

is receding slowly from the record springtime
rate continues to accumulate. Preliminary esti­
mates indicate that the total dollar value of the
nation’s output of goods and services fell
slightly in the third quarter, despite somewhat
higher prices in many lines. Industrial produc­
tion, which had. declined in July largely for
seasonal reasons, failed by several per cent to
regain its earlier level in August and Septem­
ber. Moreover, both employment and average
weekly hours worked in manufacturing indus­
tries failed to show their usual late summer
advance, although unemployment remains near
the postwar low.
By far the most dramatic reversal of condi­
tions in recent months has taken place in the
credit field. Reflecting heavy demands for
credit and relatively limited availability of
funds, interest rates on both long- and short­
term obligations rose markedly in the spring.
Advances ranged from 14-% per cent, depend­
ing upon the type and maturity of security
offered.
Since the latter part o f June, however, inter­
est rates generally have been tending down­
ward, and in the past few weeks yields on
short- and intermediate-term securities have
dropped sharply. From the June peak to early
in October, for example, market rates dropped
2 /3 of 1 per cent on 3-5 year Government
securities and a full percentage point on 91 day
Treasury bills. At around 1.4 per cent, the
latter were at the lowest yield since 1950.
What accounts for the break in security
yields after the marked rise earlier in the year?
One major factor appears to have been a sub­
stantial increase in the supply of loanable funds.
2

Business Conditions, November 1953




of

business

Yields on shorter-term Government
securities turn sharply downward
per cent y ie ld

Saving by individuals in the form of time de­
posits, savings and loan shares, and life
insurance equities has continued at a peace­
time record rate through the summer, and re­
payments on mortgages and other investments
have been rising steadily. As a result, most
financial institutions are faced with a large and
growing volume of funds to invest.
More important to the abrupt change in
market conditions has been the release of sub­
stantial amounts of bank reserves by the
monetary authorities. A reduction in member
bank reserve requirements early in July freed
about 1.2 billion dollars in reserves. In addi­
tion, purchases of short-term Government
securities by the Federal Reserve since the end
of April have provided about 1.5 billion dol­
lars in new reserves to the banking system.
Lender attitudes also have contributed to the
sharp fluctuation in interest rates this year. As

yields were rising early in the spring, lenders
naturally were somewhat reluctant to commit
themselves on new loans and investments until
rates had stabilized at some higher level. When
yields turned down in the summer, however, it
was to the lenders’ advantage to invest as close
to the peak as possible, with the result that
credit requests have received more favorable
consideration. Certainly, the over-all demand
for credit has not yet shown weakness compa­
rable to that suggested by the decline in interest
rates, although some slackening in several
important areas has been in evidence recently.
Business and agricultural loans at weekly
reporting banks have advanced less than sea­
sonally so far this fall. From early July through
September, such loans had increased only 500
million dollars, as against an expansion of 1,100
million in the same period of 1952. Among
industry groups borrowing substantially less
since midyear than in 1952 have been food,
liquor, and tobacco firms, commodity dealers,
oil, chemical, and rubber producers, retail
stores, and sales finance companies.
In part, the smaller loan expansion so far
this fall in the food lines probably reflects the
higher proportion of current farm crops being
placed under Government loan, the funds for
which are usually supplied initially by outlying
banks. This dampening influence will be re­
versed in coming weeks, however, as large
banks purchase Commodity Credit Corporation
offerings of certificates of interest in farm price
support loans for addition to their portfolios.
Such purchases may raise bank loan totals by
around 1 billion dollars by year-end.

months. Judging by the experience of banks
and sales finance companies, monthly repay­
ments have been running about an eighth
larger than at this time last year. Moreover,
new credit extensions dropped slightly in July
and more in August, largely in response to a
moderate falling off in new car sales.
Mortgage lending on residential properties
has been in very large volume so far this year.
Mortgage recordings of $20,000 or less (mostly
on single-family homes) amounted to 13 billion
dollars in the first eight months of 1953— oneeighth more than in the same period last year.
Home mortgage debt is estimated to have in­
creased 3.3 billion dollars in the first half of
this year, as against 2.9 billion in 1952.
Although the dollar volume of mortgage
lending will continue high, the year-to-year dif­
ference is likely to narrow substantially in the
months ahead. Private housing starts, on a
seasonally adjusted basis, have dropped about
20 per cent from the early spring rate, and
since June have fallen below comparable 1952
levels. Consequently, since prices have changed
little, the dollar volume of completions probably
will be little or no larger than in the closing
months of last year.

Business loans at big city banks gain
less than last year so far this fall
m illio n d o lla rs
cumulative change

Consumer instalment credit has expanded
6.3 billion dollars, or about 45 per cent, since
the termination of Regulation W in May 1952.
Nearly 2Vi billion of this increase occurred in
the first eight months of the current year.
Recently, however, the growth in instalment
debt has diminished significantly. In August,
the increase amounted to only 200 million dol­
lars, as compared with gains averaging 400
million dollars in each of the five preceding




3

Debt—Jekyll and Hyde
While debt creates problems both for the borrower and for
the economy as a whole, it plays a vital role in transferring idle savings
to those seeking use of investment funds.
D e b t , in common with most everything else in
the economic world, involves many puzzling
and often unpleasant paradoxes. The big puz­
zler is this: high and rising indebtedness poses
obvious threats both to the individuals in debt
and to the over-all economy; yet, experience
over the years indicates that periods of great
prosperity are times in which debt is large and
climbing and that apparently the more rapidly
debt rises the more prosperous is the period.
Little wonder that in all ages and to most men,
debt has been a “two-faced worrisome thing.”
Solving the debt puzzle is partly a matter of
semantics. The emotional content of the word
“debt” is quite different from that associated
with the word “credit.” But the economic
transaction referred to is the same— to use
credit is to incur debt, and in prosperous times
increasing amounts of credit are not so seem­
ingly paradoxical.
Not all of the obstacles to solving the puzzle
can be dispelled, however, by changing over to
a word with a less foreboding connotation. The
real catch lies in understanding the function of
debt— we might better say credit at this point
— in a capitalistic economy. Answers to the
questions, “What is it?”, “Where is it?”, and
“Why does it exist?” are a prerequisite to in­
formed discussion of the influences which debt
wields in our changing society.

W h a t is debt?
Everyone knows what debt is when he owes
it, but many do not recognize the debts of
others when they own them. For example, few
depositors regard their credits at the bank as
bankers’ debts, though one may be sure that
bankers do. A catalog of debt will insure that
4

Business Conditions, November 1953




we recognize it in its unfamiliar as well as
familiar forms. Beyond this, listing kinds of
debts will suggest the relationships involved in
debt and some of its characteristics.
— to consumers
As individuals we are familiar with mort­
gages on our homes, with instalment debts for
the purchase of automobiles, refrigerators, and
other household goods, with charge accounts
owed to retail merchants, and with personal
loans to carry us over periods of unexpectedly
large expenditure. In this listing we see some
debt that extends over a very long period of

Total debt—who owes it?

time, sometimes over half of the active earning
period of a man’s lifetime. Other debt falls due
in so short a time that it may be little more than
an accounting convenience that we use credit
instead of cash. We could also note that credit
is not the only way in which consumers buy
houses, automobiles, and household goods.
They can first save and then buy, instead of
buying and then saving through debt repayment.
From whom do consumers borrow to meet
their needs? Only to a limited extent do they
depend directly on other individuals. Princi­
pally, they rely on financial institutions— banks,
savings and loan associations, and insurance
companies. Often short-term credits are ar­
ranged by retailers who, at least initially, may
provide credit to stimulate sales.

Total debt—who owns itP

— to business
Businessmen probably have a greater aware­
ness of debt than consumers because there are
few, if any, businesses that do not make
important use of credit in some form or other,
whereas there are a good many consumers who
manage their affairs so as to avoid the con­
scious use of credit altogether. Businesses, like
individuals, often go into debt to buy longlived goods. Some business assets, such as fac­
tories and various types of equipment, have an
earning potential that extends far beyond the
working span of a human life and are so costly
that a business would lose years of profits wait­
ing until it could “save” enough to buy them.
Businessmen also borrow a great deal of
money for short periods of time. Much of this
short-term credit fills time gaps between outlays
for production expenses and later receipts from
product sales. Thus, a farmer will borrow
money to buy feeder cattle, then repay the debt
months later when the finished livestock is
shipped to market. Some forms of temporary
debt even arise almost automatically, as when
a businessman defers wage payments until pay­
day, waits a few days before paying his supplier
for shipments, or waits until next year to pay
Federal taxes on this year’s income.




By and large, businessmen go to different
sources for their long- and short-term needs.
Corporations and farmers sell their bonds and
mortgages chiefly to insurance companies and
individual investors. Some of this debt also
goes to banks, although business turns to banks
primarily for short-term loans. The biggest
“two-way” lenders to business are other busi­
nesses, which hold large amounts of corporate
obligations and extend substantial trade credits
to their customers.
The profit motive is a critical element in
business borrowing. A businessman will add to
his liabilities willingly only if he expects that the
extra profit he can earn with the use of the
borrowed funds will exceed the debt costs.
Whether the borrowing is to finance a specific
expenditure or merely for working capital, the
deciding factor is the prospect for increased
income.
— to governm ents
With governmental bodies— Federal, state,

5

and local— borrowing is a different proposition.
They can largely determine their own income
via the taxes they impose and set their expendi­
tures, not to gain profits or personal satisfac­
tion, but to further general public welfare.
The overwhelming bulk of the Federal Gov­
ernment’s borrowing has always been to bridge
gaps between its tax collections and its ex­
penditures, rather than to buy particular public
services or projects or to increase the Govern­
ment’s future income. State and local govern­
ment agencies, on the other hand, borrow
mainly for specific capital outlay projects—
highways, schools, and other public structures.
The chief vehicle for governmental borrow­
ing is the sale of securities, of both short and
distant maturities. There are the familiar U. S.
savings bonds, which make up a sizable chunk
of the total Federal debt. Other government
securities come in assorted combinations of
“payable on demand,” “payable at maturity, or
when called,” “payable only to owner of rec­
ord,” and “payable to holder” whoever that
might be. The typically high standing and at­
tractive combinations of terms for these securi­
ties have found them many homes— in portfolios
of corporations, financial institutions, pension
and trust funds, as well as in the safety deposit
boxes of individuals and small businesses.
— to financial in s titu tio n s
The one remaining large group of debtors is
the nation’s collection of specialized financial
institutions. This may come as a bit of a sur­
prise, for they have just been referred to as
important lenders to borrowing consumers,
businesses, and governments. But the fact re­
mains that our financial institutions flout
Polonius’ advice, “Neither a borrower nor a
lender be,” for they are both, in equal degree.
Their role is that of middleman, accepting the
savings and in turn lending out these funds to
others seeking money to build plants, buy con­
sumer goods, or otherwise acquire desired assets.
Various savings institutions receive funds
from a customer under a promise to return

6

Business Conditions, November 1953




them, upon request and subject to various con­
ditions. Banks, insurance companies, and, in
effect, savings and loan associations are there­
fore in debt to their account and policy holders.
In effect, they have “borrowed” the deposits of
account owners and the funds used to accumu­
late insurance policy reserves.
The “borrowing” which financial institutions
do is unusual in several respects. For one thing,
almost all the debt incurred has no fixed
maturity, but is repaid in practice upon demand.
Few other debtors would be willing to under­
take such an awesome obligation. For another,
financial institutions “go in debt” more or less
involuntarily, whenever and for whatever
amounts their account and policy holders may
offer. Moreover, many times an institution will
both borrow and lend to the same individual,
as happens when a bank makes a loan to one
of its depositors. Finally, financial institutions
pay for their borrowing privilege in different
ways— sometimes with interest or dividends, but
often with special types of service and protec­
tion. The attractiveness to creditors of financial
institution debt is apparent, for such inter­
mediaries are popular recipients of “loans” from
individuals and organizations the country over.
Debts are assets
Double-entry bookkeeping is at the root of
the simplest of the paradoxes inherently asso­
ciated with debt— the fact that while debt is a
claim on the assets and earning capacity of
those in debt, it is simultaneously a part of
their creditors’ worldly goods. For every buyer
there must be a seller, and similarly for every
liability entered on someone’s balance sheet,
whether that balance sheet actually exists on
paper or only in a figurative sense, someone
else has an asset of equal value.
For example, such debts as a U. S. savings
bond, or a bank account, or a corporate bond
are as much assets to their owners as is cur­
rency or tangible property. In the case of
commercial banks and most other financial
institutions, almost all assets consist of pieces

Long-term debt makes up over 40 per cent of total debt
S h o r t- t e r m

I
200

0
L o n g -te rm

deb t

co n sum ers
b u sin e sse s

g o ve rn m e n ts

400

600

_ i_

800

b illio n d o lla rs

in clu d e s

such

b o rro w in g s

in clu d e s

such

b o rro w in g s

os:

co n sum ers

instalment credit; personal
loans; policy loans; charge
accounts

b u sin e sse s

bank loans; accounts pay­
able

g o ve rn m e n ts

Treasury bills, certificates,
and notes; state and local
government warrants; U. S.
savings bonds ( if cashed be­
fo re m a tu rity ); accounts
payable

fin a n c ia l
in stitu tio n s

borrowings from Federal
Reserve Banks and from
Federal Home Loan Banks

a s:

residential mortgages
railroad, public utility, and
industrial bonds and notes;
mortgages on rental hous­
ing and farm real estate
Federal, state, and local
government bonds; U. S.
savings bo7ids (when held
to maturity)

of paper which are evidence that someone has
borrowed from them on a short- or a long-term
basis— notes, bonds, mortgages.
Our dynamic expanding economy is based
on the continuous production of more and
new kinds of goods and services. This process
requires a high rate of investment and, in turn,
large savings— savings that are promptly chan­
neled into productive and profitable uses.
Sometimes the saver and investor are one
and the same— as, for example, when an indi­
vidual uses his savings to pay for the construc­
tion of a house, or a business finances its plant
and equipment expenditures with its retained
earnings. This procedure was typical of the days
when most Americans were farmers or small
businessmen, reinvesting in their farms and
businesses any earnings over and above those




debt

D e p o s it -t y p e

debt in clu d e s such “ b o rro w in g s”

f in a n c ia l
in stitu tio n s

T a x - lia b ilit ie s
b u sin e sse s

as:

bank deposits; savings and
loan association shares; cash
value of life insurance pol­
icies; dividends left with
life insurance companies
in clu d e

such

"b o rro w in g s ”

a s:

acci’ued corporate income tax

needed to support their families.
Today, however, most of us are employees,
not proprietors, and much, though by no means
all, investment is made by individuals and firms
without enough ready cash to finance expan­
sion of their production facilities. Thus, the
accumulation of personal savings and the ex­
penditure of these funds for investment pur­
poses are frequently separate and distinct
processes, performed by separate and distinct
persons or groups. Thus, it is essential to have
convenient, well-established ways of transferring
unspent funds of savers to businesses, govern­
ments, or individuals seeking the use of funds.
The tra n s fe r function o f debt
In this country, savings can be put to work
in a number of ways. Savings in the form of

7

cash balances in checking accounts may be
exchanged for stock (equity shares) in business
concerns. In this way savers become part own­
ers of the business and share in its earnings
and losses after prior claims have been met. Or
they may directly lend their accumulated funds
to others, in return for interest and the borrow­
er’s promise to repay the debt sometime in the
future. That is, savers exchange their cash or
bank deposits for a less liquid debt asset that
yields an income, but must ordinarily be re­
converted into cash or a checking account bal­
ance before it can be spent or reinvested.
Most often, savings indirectly find their way
into investors’ hands, with banks and other
financial institutions acting as middlemen be­
tween the savers and users of investment funds.
All of these methods of putting savings to work,
aside from the purchase of stock, involve the
creation of debt and are vital branches of the
economy’s “transport system” for savings.

guard for the funds entrusted to them, although
it is supported by a number of additional pro­
tective arrangements, such as the spreading of
funds over a wide number of undertakings,
the maintenance of an equity cushion to absorb
debt defaults, governmental supervision of
operations, and governmental insurance and
guarantees of some loans held by institutions as
well as a large share of their deposit liabilities.
Thus, both individual savers and the finan­
cial middlemen to whom they may entrust a
portion of their savings are desirous of keep­
ing much of their funds under the protective
cover which debt affords. In these circum­
stances, users of funds, who may have to seek
out money wherever it can be found, will nat­
urally be inclined to accommodate such desires
by offering debt rather than equities. Those
who need outside funds often find it easier and
cheaper to obtain them through channels of
debt, either directly from savers or indirectly
through financial intermediaries.

Less ris k
In a system such as ours today, it is inevitable
that debt totals be relatively substantial. To the
average saver, debt is in many respects a more
attractive repository for his funds than are
riskier, though possibly more rewarding, equi­
ties. The majority of savers place a high
premium on keeping their savings safe, liquid,
and conveniently available. Only the debts of
others can have these attributes in high degree,
and only certain forms of debt at that.
A number of debt vehicles tailored to these
saver desires have been developed over the
years. The most common are the host of
financial institutions which dot our economic
landscape. They specialize in making promises
to repay funds left with them, in exact dollar
amount, immediately upon request. To insure
their ability to deliver on such promises, they
in turn must invest funds received in assets
readily disposable at or near par value, which
for the most part means high-grade debt obli­
gations of businesses, governments, and indi­
viduals. Such prudence is their prime safe­

8

Business Conditions, November 1953




Debt and money
Debt can do more than simply transport idle
funds to places where they are desired. It is
also the means by which entirely new funds are
created, funds that may be required for a pros­
perous, expanding economy.
The banking system is the mechanism that
accomplishes this “money creation.” Today,
most purchases are paid for by checks drawn on
bank demand deposits. Practically, therefore,
demand deposits have become accepted as
money. But they are also bank debts, liabilities
of a bank to its depositors. How do these bank
deposit liabilities arise? Usually they are in­
curred when a depositor brings in cash or a
check on another bank which the recipient bank
can collect in cash. The deposit of the cus­
tomer at the recipient bank is upped, but the
public’s total holdings of cash and deposits in
other banks are reduced by a like amount. The
nation’s total money supply remains unchanged.
When a bank makes a loan or buys a secu­
rity, however, it is a different story. The bank

D ebt in the consumer balance sheet
Assets

Liabilities and Net Worth
Consumers' debt

Debt of others

due to
3 other consumers

due from :
other consumers

J businesses

businesses
c o rp o ra te b o nd s and
m o rtg a g e s

Federal Government
(FNMA

governments

m o rtg a g e s)

F e d e ra l

financial in stitu tio n s

s ta te - lo c a l

<—

com m ercial banks
m u tu a l sa v in g s banks

financial institu tio n s

*—

and sa v in g s and loan
a sso c ia tio n s

co m m e rc ia l bank d ep osits

instalment
credit and
residential
mortgages

lif e in su ra n c e com panies
m u tu a l sa v in g s d e p o sits
and sa ving s and loan
s h a re s

c a sh value o f
life in su ra n c e p o lic ie s

Total debt assets
+
cash, business equities, tangible personal
property, and real estate

Total Consumers' assets
accepts its customer’s note or security and in
exchange gives him an equivalent increase in
his deposit account. Nobody else loses a de­
posit. Consequently, the total of cash and
deposits— the money supply— is increased.
Money has been created.
If this were all there was to the process, of
course, everybody would be getting into the
banking business. Actually, the operations of
our far-flung hanking system siphon away the




$ 9 0 billion

Total liabilities
+

consum ers' net worth

Total Consumers' liabilities
and net worth
fruits of money creation from any individual
bank. Few people borrow money to keep it
idle. Usually a borrower will quickly write
checks on his new deposit to make some in­
tended payments. In the normal course of
events, the persons he pays will redeposit these
checks in their own banks. This sort of transfer
is even more rapid when the bank buys a
security, for the seller typically requests imme­
diate transfer of the funds to his own bank. In

9

either case, the newly created deposit has not
disappeared, but it has shifted from the orig­
inal bank to others. When this happens, the
original bank must be able to lay its hands on
cash or its equivalent to pay out to the other
banks. As a practical matter, therefore, any
one bank cannot afford to add to its loans and
investments (creating new deposits in the
process) by an amount greater than its excess
holdings of cash reserves.

D ebt

What cash is “excess” depends upon a num­
ber of factors. Generally speaking, a bank need
keep cash equal to only a moderate fraction of
the deposits made by customers with cash or
checks on other banks for usually, as one such
deposit is drawn down, some other customer
is bringing in additional funds for deposit. Thus,
if a bank receives a big bulge of cash and
checks for deposit, it may safely regard a sizable
portion of the funds so received as “excess”

in the business balance sheet
Liabilities and Net Worth

Assets

Businesses' debt

Debt of others
due from :

due to :

consumers

consumers
c o rp o ra te bonds and m o rtg a g e s

other businesses

other businesses

Federal Government

Federal Government
accrued corpora te ta x lia b ilit ie s

financial institu tio n s

financial in stitu tio n s

'c o m m e rc ia l

deposits
at

c o m m e rc ia l b a n k s

banks
m utua l s a v in g s banks
m u tu a l s a v in g s
life in su ra n c e com panies

banks

Total debt assets

$ 180 billion

+
business plant and equipment, farm land and equip­
ment, inventories, and equity in other businesses

Total Business (and farm)
assets
10

Business Conditions, November 1953




$ 2 5 0 billion

business
. toons,
mortgages,
and
bonds

Total liabilities
+

business and farm net worth

Total Business (and farm)
liabilities and net worth

and make loans and create new deposits in a
comparable amount. Once those created de­
posits shift to other banks and the lending bank
transfers its excess cash resources in payment,
its ability to create new money is exhausted.
But this is not true for those banks receiving
that transferred cash and deposit. They simi­
larly need keep as cash reserves only a fraction
of the funds placed with them, and they too
can lend the remainder, creating new deposits in
the process. As this chain of action grows and
spreads through the entire banking system,
more and more “new” deposits are “created.”
The maximum amount of this deposit expan­
sion is determined by the portion of deposited
funds which is kept as cash reserves. At pres­
ent, national and state authorities require banks
to maintain reserves equal to about one-fifth
of their demand deposits. Mathematically this
permits the banking system as a whole, in meet­
ing borrowers’ demands for credit, to create
about 4 dollars more of deposit money for each
dollar of cash reserves. That the overwhelming
bulk of our money supply consists of bank
deposits rather than hard cash or paper cur­
rency attests to the importance of this process.
The volume of money in the economy and
the speed with which it changes hands has an
obvious influence on the tempo of economic
activity. A money supply which is constricted
by scarcity of the reserves which the banking
system needs to create deposits may make it
impossible to finance some projects. An easily
expansible money supply, on the other hand,
can encourage a larger volume of business,
higher prices for the same volume, or both.
Dangers — re a l . . .
While moderate injections of new money are
helpful lubricants for an expanding economy,
it is easy to flood the economic mechanism and
bring about an inflationary situation. Bank
deposit creation can proceed as long as banks
have more than enough cash reserves to meet
legal requirements and have opportunities to
add to their loans and investments. Such addi­




tional debt assets may arise from new bor­
rowing requests or they can be drawn from the
existing pool of loans and investments held by
non-bank investors. These processes, and par­
ticularly the latter, are commonly called
“monetizing” debt— that is, selling it to banks
in exchange for new bank deposits, thus in­
creasing the money supply. Obviously, the pos­
sibilities for debt monetization are greater, the
larger the stock of debt which the economy
accumulates. The problem of Federal debt
monetization has been particularly acute since
the end of World War II, because of the huge
increase in Federal obligations necessary to
finance the war. Only in the past few years has
it been brought under control— partly because
other developments eased active inflationary
pressures and partly because the Federal Re­
serve System became free to use its various
powers to limit the reserves available to banks.
But the threat of inflation is not the only
dilemma raised by a large and rising debt in a
prosperous period. Another is the fact that
under these conditions a substantial share of
business— many house, auto, and appliance
sales and much of the inventory build-up— is
facilitated by the fact that it is easy to borrow
money to finance these purchases. The issue is,
can we sustain prosperity without constantly
increasing dosages of credit, which threaten
inflationary outbursts? Then, too, what if the
boom fades? Since people do not find it easy
or sound to borrow in bad times, sales on credit
may slump badly. Meanwhile, existence of old
debts will make a recession a period of net debt
repayment, narrowing the spendable remainder
of incomes. To what levels will spending on cur­
rent production drop under these influences?
Part of the answer to these crucial questions
depends upon how well debtors and creditors
can manage their present debt positions in ad­
versity, part on how well agencies responsible
for maintaining stability can do their jobs.
. . . o r fanciful
The fact that debt is so necessary to our

D ebt in the government balance sheet
(Federal, s ta te , and l o c a l )
Assets

Liabilities

Debt of others

Governments' debt

due fro m :

securities held by

consumers
FN M A

consumers
m o rtg a g e s

businesses
c o rp o ra te in c om e ta x
lia b ilitie s

businesses
state-local holdings
of Federal securities

Federal Government
financial in stitu tio n s

financial institu tio n s

comm ercial bank d e p o sits

----- c o m m e rc ia l b a n k s

■“

m u tu a l s a v in g s b a n k s and
sa v in g s and loan a s so c ia tio n s
life

in su ra n c e c o m p a n ie s

Federal Reserve Banks

Total debt assets

$ 5 0 billion

$ 2 5 0 billion

Total liabilities

+
public property including military hard goods

+
invested to preserve "the American way of life"

Total Government assets = Total Government liabilities
economic life, but seems so loaded with
ominous threats, casts it in the role of a paradox
to many people. Sometimes, however, this
paradox draws force, not from any real threats,
but from people’s deep-seated moral attitudes
about the “wrongness” of being in debt. For
individuals, thrift has always been a virtue and
thriftlessness— often represented by going into
debt— a vice. These attitudes frequently are a
product of confusing what can be done by

12

Business Conditions, November 1953




individuals and businesses on their own hook
and what all consumers or all businesses or even
the whole economy can do in the aggregate.
As individual consumers we know that, if our
income exceeds our spending, we grow in
financial strength whereas, if our spending ex­
ceeds our income, we face an eventual day of
reckoning. This is so since we must repay or
refinance these debts, and it is not always wise
or even possible to refinance individual debts

at the discretion of the debtor.
In the aggregate, however, there is no par­
allel necessity to reduce total outstanding debt,
and reduction of aggregate debt is frequently
not desirable. We have already seen that, inas­
much as the saver usually is not the actual
user of the funds, a large share of total invest­
ment must be accompanied by debt transac­
tions. Too, we have seen that all debts are
assets as well as liabilities, that repayment of
bank-created debt reduces total assets as well
as liabilities, and that a reduced money supply
can be an unsettling influence on the economy.
And as we know from our own experience
as consumers and businessmen, going into debt
does not always mean prodigality. Often there
is a choice as to whether to pay for a given
expenditure by reducing purchases of other
items, by cutting savings, or by borrowing, and
often there are distinct advantages to borrowing.
For example, when we borrow to purchase a
home or to develop a business, we receive in
the present the returns which the money used
to service the debt might have secured for us
only in years to come. Far from indicating
thriftlessness, borrowing to buy a residence
often results in the home-owner’s saving far
more, via repaying the debt and increasing his
equity in the house, than he would save in any
other way. Furthermore, many a profitable
business venture and much investment in new
products and processes would not have been
possible were not the necessary credit available.
As we approach the trillion-dollar mark in in­
debtedness, we can feel with some degree of con­
fidence that this does not brand us as a nation
of spendthrifts. Rather, it mirrors more than
anything else our large accumulation of savings
and high levels of investment, the present-day
separation of savers and users of money, and
the preferences for sheltered abodes for sav­
ings. The role that debt plays is not a simple
one, for the distribution— and creation— of
funds have many ramifications within modern
economics. By-products of debt changes can
be the aggravation of inflations and recessions.




Distorting pressures can develop, too, from
more devious influences not weighed here, such
as the “burden” of debt on various borrowers
and the pyramiding of indebtedness from repet­
itive transfers of existing assets. There is need
for discussion and analysis of these widespreading effects, from which to draw guidance for
actions which may minimize the hurts and
maximize the benefits that debt can produce.
But one basic fact stands forth: debt exists and
will continue to do so, and it performs useful
economic functions in its existence. What is
required is not its abolition, but rather its
intelligent supervision.

The debt picture today
In a society as complex as ours, the ability
and willingness to borrow or to lend differ
widely among individuals and organizations.
As a result, while the total of liabilities must be
equal to the sum of all debt assets for the econ­
omy as a whole, this need not be true for any
individual or group. For some consumers and
businesses, the debts they owe exceed the debts
owed them; for others, their debt assets surpass
their liabilities.
In the accompanying charts, the debt of five
conventional economic groups or interests in
our society is cross-classified on the basis of
who owns it and who owes it. In four of the
five groups— for consumers, businesses, finan­
cial institutions, and governments— the figures
are totals of the debt assets and liabilities of
many individual units. The fifth category— the
Federal Reserve System— although including
the operations of the twelve regional Reserve
Banks, is a single unit.
While the charts exclude intra-organization
debt— for example, Federal securities owned by
Government trust funds or bonds of a cor­
porate subsidiary held by the parent company
— they do include debt owed to wholly separate
economic units within each group. For exam­
ple, the data contain items such as residential
mortgages held by consumers, corporate-owned

13

bonds of other corporations, state and local
governments’ holdings of Federal securities, as
well as bank deposits of life insurance com­
panies and savings and loan associations. Of
these intra-group debts, those of businesses are
by far the most important, yet they are small
relative to the total debt of the sector.
Consumers la rg e st c re d ito r group
Consumers are the nation’s big creditor
group— either in the amount of their gross
holdings of debt assets or in terms of their net
holdings after deduction of their own debts.
Debts owed to individuals totaled 340 billion
dollars at the end of 1952, about 40 per cent
of all outstanding obligations. Almost 80 per
cent of all consumer held debt assets are of a
very liquid type, that is, assets held at financial
institutions— bank deposits and life insurance
policy reserves— and government bonds.
Debts owed by consumers amounted to
nearly 90 billion, but this was only one-fourth
the size of their total claims. In contrast to
their debt assets which, in the main, can be
converted into cash at will, about 60 per cent of
their obligations are of a fixed long-term nature.
Tw o groups net d ebtors
Businesses and government— Federal, state,
and local— are the large net debtors in the
economy, balancing the over-all creditor posi­
tion of consumers. Although the obligations
of business and government groups total close
to 250 billion each, governments are net debtors
to a much greater extent than are businesses.
The Federal debt, of course, dwarfs that of
all state and local bodies. The debt held by the
public— that is, outside of government agencies
and trust funds— amounted to 222 billion at
the end of 1952, the biggest share being held
by consumers and commercial banks. The Fed­
eral Government’s relatively modest claims on
other sectors consist primarily of business tax
liabilities, CCC loans, FNMA mortgages, as
well as loans to states and local governments.
Business owes its biggest debt to financial

14

Business Conditions, November 1953




institutions— 85 billion dollars, or over onethird of all business liabilities. The debts of
businesses are divided almost evenly between
long- and short-term obligations. Their debt
assets are predominantly short-term claims on
consumers and other businesses and deposits
at financial institutions.
For business, as for other sectors, debts are
not the only assets and liabilities that appear
on the balance sheet. Debt owned by corpora­
tions is over two-fifths of their total assets, and
their debt obligation about 60 per cent of their
total liabilities and net worth. The bulk of their
assets and liabilities are not claims payable in
money under terms of a contract. They are,
on the asset side, tangible assets, such as plant,
equipment, and inventory, and ownership of
other firms and of patents, good will, and the
like, and on the liability side, their capital or
net worth— the owners’ interest in the business.
Similarly, consumers have nondebt assets—
homes, durable and nondurable goods, and in­
tangibles such as job tenure and security— and
nondebt liabilities— their net worth positions.
Only in the case of the Federal Government,
where the bulk of the debt was incurred to
finance war and purchase war materials, does
debt overwhelm the balance sheet unless, of
course, we are prepared to place a money value
on preservation of the nation.
Financial in s titu tio n s in balance
Since financial institutions function as mid­
dlemen between savers and users of funds, a
financial institution usually acquires a debt asset
to match each additional debt liability, leaving
its claims and obligations approximately in bal­
ance. Thus, banks and savings and loan asso­
ciations attempt to employ the funds which they
acquire or can create to the fullest extent possi­
ble, within the limits set by law and traditional
banking practices. Life insurance companies,
as receivers of individuals’ savings in the
form of premium payments, also attempt to
invest their funds in earning assets to the
fullest possible extent.

This balance is clearly illustrated in the
chart below. Financial institutions’ debt assets
— loans and investments plus commercial bank
deposits at the Federal Reserve Banks— totaled
270 billion dollars, as compared with obliga­
tions of 260 billion dollars. Commercial banks
account for 60 per cent of the totals, and life
insurance companies another 24 per cent, with

the mutual savings institutions holding the
remainder.
Paper currency occupies a unique place in
our present system. The 29 billion dollars in
circulation at the close of 1952 were liabilities
of the Treasury and the Federal Reserve System
to the bearers of the currency and, similarly,
debt assets to those holding it. In practice,

D ebt in the financial institution balance sheet
Assets

Liabilities and Net Worth
Financial Institutions' debt

Debt of others
due fro m :
consumers
—
instalment commercial banks
credit and m utual savings banks and
residential, savings and loan associations
mortgages life insura nc e companies
held by

due to :
consum ers
c o m m e rc ia l bank d e p o sits

—

m u tu a l sa ving s bank deposits and
savings and loan a sso cia tio n shares

cash value o f life insurance policies

businesses

________

c o m m e rc ia l banks

business
loans,
m utual sa v in g s banks and
mortgages,\ savings and loan associations
and bonds
owned by life insura nc e c om p anies

businesses
c o m m e rc ia l banks
m u tu a l s a v in g s b a n k s

deposits
at

governments

governments

bank d e p o sits
to com m ercial banks

— >

to m utual savings banks and
savings and loan associations,
to life insurance companies

other financial institutions

other financial institutions
Federal Reserve Banks
re s e rv e

d e p o s its

Total debt assets

$ 2 7 0 billion

$ 2 6 0 billion Total liabilities
+

currency, p la nt, and real estate

Total Financial Institution assets




financial in stitu tio n s' net worth

Total Financial Institution
liabilities and net worth
15

How economic groups share in the 860 billion
dollar total U. S. debt
Distribution among economic groups
N et debt
position

Gross debt
position

Consumers

Business

Government

Financial
institutions

Federal
Reserve
System

Consumers

+260

own 345
owe 85

10
10

65
15

85

185
60

0
0

Business

— 80

own 170
owe 250

15
65

75
75

25
25

55
85

0
0

Government

-1 9 5

own 50
owe 245

•
85

25
25

10
10

15
100

25

Financial institutions

+

10

own 270
owe 260

60
185

85
55

100
15

5
5

20
0

Federal Reserve System

+

5

0
0

0
0

25

0
20

0
0

own
owe

25
20

•

•Less than 2.5 b illio n dollars.
Figures in b illio n d ollars, as of December 31, 1952.

A ll figures rounded to the nearest 5 b illio n.

Note: Data presented in the table are partly estimated, and based on the follow ing concepts and definitions: businesses include corporations,
unincorporated enterprises, and farms; nonprofit associations and pension and trust funds are included w ith consumers; a ll debts are taken at
their par or face values; data fo r demand deposits are based on bank records and therefore include bank check flo a t; likew ise, business debt
is based on business records and therefore includes trade float.

however, currency, of which seven-eighths is
Federal Reserve notes, is considered by the
bearer not as a debt asset that will be redeemed
by the borrower at some specified time, but
rather as a very special type of tangible asset.
Paper currency now plays the role in our econ­
omy that gold played when it was free to
circulate.

market and discount policies and its powers to
set requirements for bank reserves, the Federal
Reserve System can influence the amount of
new debts incurred and the transfer of existing
debt. By continually adapting its policies, the
System aims to guide the nation’s debt flows in
accordance with the changing needs of a grow­
ing and prospering economy.

Role o f the Federal Reserve
Economic growth demands a continuing flow
of savings into investment uses. A large part
of the stream of accumulated and bank-created
funds must pass through debt channels to reach
those in a position to employ the funds. Some
of these channels are simple and direct, others
constitute an intricate network of transactions.
The Federal Reserve System can to some extent
alter the direction and dimension of these chan­
nels through its ability to influence credit ex­
pansion or contraction. Through its open

16

Business Conditions, November 1953




Business Conditions is published monthly by

the f e d e r a l r e s e r v e b a n k o f Ch ic a g o . Sub­
scriptions are available to the public without
charge. For information concerning bulk mail­
ings to banks, business organizations, and edu­
cational institutions, write: Research Depart­
ment, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Box
834, Chicago 90, Illinois. Articles may be re­
printed provided source is credited.