View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

The trend of business—
inflationary forces still in check
Trends in agriculture
Regional economic integration

2
7
11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

THE

OF

BUSINESS

In fla tio n a ry forces s t ill in check

TJ_he view that in 1964 the nation will pro­
duce around 620 billion dollars of goods and
services—6 per cent more than in 1963—is
widely held. Some observers anticipate an 8
per cent gain, a projection that implies an
annual rate of 650 billion dollars or more by
the fourth quarter of the year. The possibility
of such a large rise in the dollar volume of
activity in so short a period of time is re­
garded with apprehension by some observers
who believe it probably would be accompa­
nied by rising prices, excessive inventory
building and an unsustainable increase in the
rate of business spending on capital goods
and consumer spending on durable goods.
Some concern exists that the economy al­
ready is developing such stresses and strains.
In part, opposition to the tax reduction bill,
enacted late in February, reflected fears that
the measure would excessively stimulate an
already buoyant economy. Doubtless, spend­
ing in January and February was boosted in
some degree by the conviction that the bill
would be approved. Does the weight of the

evidence suggest that excesses have developed
thus far in 1964?
Price tre n d s th e k e y

Clear evidence of the overheating of the
economy, when and if it occurs, will be found
in movements of the major price indexes. As
yet, these “thermometers” have shown little
evidence of any strong rise in temperature.
Average consumer prices have continued
to move up at a rate of between 1 and 2 per
cent a year in recent months—mainly be­
cause of increases in services— as they have
for the past five years. Wholesale prices in
February averaged V2 of 1 per cent above the
same month last year but were slightly below
the level in the same month of 1961 and
1962.
The Labor Department’s index of spot
commodity prices was 4 per cent above its
year-earlier level in mid-April as increases
for all major nonferrous metals and steel
scrap more than offset declines for agricul­
tural products. Nevertheless, spot commodity

BUSINESS C O N D IT IO N S'5 published monthly by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. George W . Cloos was primarily
responsible for the article "The Trend of Business," Roby L. Sloan for "Trends in agriculture" and W. Ernst Kuhn for
"Regional economic integration."
Subscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public without charge. For information concerning bulk mail­
ings, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.
2

Articles may be reprinted provided source is credited.




Business Conditions, M ay 1964

prices averaged appreciably below the April
level in 1961.
Price movements are of major importance
in analysis of business conditions not merely
because they reflect excessive demands upon
available resources, but also because they
tend to cause such developments to become
cumulative. Expectations of progressively
higher prices encourage businesses to antici­
pate future needs by increasing inventories
and advancing purchases of “big ticket” dura­
ble goods. Such developments usually are fol­
lowed by a reaction in the opposite direction.
Rising prices usually have been associated
with booming business conditions in the later
stages of an expansion. But there have been

important exceptions to this generalization.
Prior to the onset of the Great Depression of
1929-33, for example, the averages of both
consumer and wholesale prices had been de­
clining gradually for years. In the postwar
period, rather general price inflation preceded
the peaks of 1948, 1953 and 1957 but was
much less in evidence prior to the peak in
1960.
C a p ita l e x p e n d itu re s

Explanations of booms of the past often
center about the decisions of business firms
to purchase new plant and equipment. There
has been a tendency for these outlays to be
bunched, with enterprises competing with one

Consum er prices have continued their gradual climb in recent
months while wholesale prices have risen slightly




3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

4

another to obtain the buildings or equipment
they desire as soon as possible. In such cir­
cumstances prices for these goods tend to
rise sharply as order backlogs of firms pro­
ducing capital goods increase. Such develop­
ments usually have led to sharp declines in
outlays later. This sequence of events oc­
curred, for example, in the capital spending
upsurge of the mid-Fifties and its subsequent
decline during the 1957-58 recession.
Between the first quarter of 1955 and the
third quarter of 1957, capital expenditures
rose 47 per cent, partly because of sharp price
increases for these goods, while the gross
national product increased 17 per cent. In the
following year there was a sharp drop in such
investments and a coincident decline in gen­
eral business activity.
From the second quarter of 1961 when the
current upswing in capital expenditures be­
gan through the first quarter of 1964, these
outlays rose 23 per cent—only slightly more
than the 19 per cent increase in the gross
national product during the same period.
Government tabulations of business capi­
tal spending plans for 1964 indicate a rise of
10 per cent from 1963. It is possible that an
even greater increase will occur, but these
estimates have been remarkably precise in
recent years except when recessions caused
cancellations or postponements of programs.
If the forecast for 1964 proves accurate, this
would mean a moderate acceleration of the
capital outlay uptrend. Capital outlays would
amount to 7.0 per cent of the expected gross
national product for the year compared with
6.7 per cent in the past three years. In 1956
and 1957 capital expenditures were 8.4 per
cent of gross national product.
Because the size and rapidity of the cur­
rent expansion in capital expenditures has
been moderate, there has been little tendency
for prices of capital goods to increase sharply




as evidenced in 1956 and 1957. As a result,
there has been only a moderate build-up in
the order backlogs of machinery and equip­
ment producers.
The current capital expenditure expansion
has another favorable aspect in comparison
with 1955-57. In the earlier period, the move­
ment was dominated by programs to expand
capacity in heavy industries producing basic
materials—especially steel, aluminum, glass
and cement. At present the rise in capital out­
lays, led by autos and steel, is more broadly
based and a larger share of the total is for
modernization and creation or expansion of
capacity to produce finished goods.
In v e n to rie s r e la t iv e ly low

At the end of February, the book value of
total business inventories was at a record high
of more than 103 billion dollars—up 3.6 per
cent from the level of a year earlier. But dur­
ing the same interval total business sales rose
almost 6 per cent. The ratio of inventories
to sales was 1.48 in February compared with
1.51 a year earlier, the lowest for any similar
month since the current series began.
Inventory fluctuations are especially im­
portant in the durable manufacturers cate­
gory which is heavily represented in the Mid­
west. In these industries the processing cycle
from raw materials to finished product typi­
cally is longer than in the case of soft goods.
Moreover, during the past decade more and
more of the burden of carrying durable goods
inventories has been shifted from the retail­
ers and distributors to the manufacturer, who
must be able to ship goods quickly upon re­
ceipt of customers’ orders. Consequently, in­
ventories of durable goods manufacturers
have increased relative to total business in­
ventories and a larger proportion of manu­
facturers’ inventories now consists of finished
goods as opposed to purchased materials and

Business Conditions, M ay 1964

O rd e rs and in v e n to rie s of durable goods producers
have remained low relative to shipments

goods-in-process. Because of these trends, the
stocks of durable goods manufacturers pro­
vide a focus for consideration of the entire
inventory situation.
There has been a slight decline in the in­
ventory-sales ratio for durable goods manu­
facturers since the beginning of the current
business expansion in February 1961 (see
chart). Nevertheless, this ratio has been
highly stable during these years when com­
pared with the record of the earlier postwar
period which was affected by steel strikes,
recessions, inflation and materials shortages.
As long as sales are rising as much or more
than inventories, there is no question of in­
ventories overall becoming burdensome, al­
though particular firms may encounter diffi­
culties. Nevertheless, a stable or declining
inventory-sales ratio does not necessarily



guard against a business downturn, as indi­
cated by the experience of 1948 and 1960.
In the postwar period durable goods inven­
tories have risen sharply relative to shipments
only when the latter were reduced by steel
strikes or recessions.
When business sales decline, inventories
usually continue to rise for a time before the
momentum of the inflow of goods from sup­
pliers can be slowed. For this reason the cur­
rent favorable business prospect is fortified
not only because inventories have been rising
less rapidly than sales but also by the fact
that they are low relative to past periods of
prosperity. Lower inventory sales ratios re­
flect accounting procedures that have re­
duced book values and improved inventory
control has reduced the “fat” in these hold­
ings substantially.

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business firms have a strong incentive to
hold inventory growth in check: carrying in­
ventory is costly in terms of interest, space,
insurance and handling. These costs are esti­
mated to total 10-15 per cent on an annual
rate basis. In addition, inventories may lose
value because of changes in technology, style
or customer preference.
Potential delays in deliveries and prospec­
tive price increases, therefore, must be fairly
certain and important to cause firms to in­
crease inventory holdings beyond current
needs. On the other hand, expectations of
immediate substantial price increases or ap­
preciable stretchouts in the time period re­
quired to obtain goods from suppliers can
quickly overcome such caution. Avoidance of
excessive inventory building, therefore, re­
quires that comfortable margins of capacity
be maintained in most industries.
O rd e r b ack lo g s low

6

The stable and slightly declining trend of
the ratio of order backlogs to sales or ship­
ments by durable goods manufacturers during
the past three years contrasts even more
strikingly with the earlier postwar period than
does the trend of the inventory-sales ratio.
From December to April, new orders of
durable goods producers rose more than ship­
ments with the result that order backlogs in­
creased. Nevertheless, backlogs represented
only 2.5 months’ sales compared with a ratio
of 2.6 a year earlier. In the early months of
1964, order backlogs of durable goods pro­
ducers were the lowest relative to sales since
the current series began in 1947.
Relatively small order backlogs held by
durable goods producers provide an eloquent
commentary on the ability of industry to
manufacture goods as rapidly as required by
customers, despite the long-sustained rise in
demand. This phenomenon is closely tied to




the fact that there has been little incentive to
build inventories in this expansion resulting
from fears of higher prices or of delays in
deliveries.
If order backlogs begin to rise appreciably
relative to sales, the movement doubtless will
be accompanied by a lengthening of order
lead times and a rash of price increases. That
such trends might cumulate is obvious. The
inflationary periods of 1950-51 and 1955-56
were characterized by such developments.
Thus far in 1964, order lead times have
shown little tendency to stretch out except in
some types of steel and construction ma­
chinery. In March only 17 per cent of the
Purchasing Agents of Chicago reported that
they were ordering supplies and materials 60
days or more ahead of requirements, com­
pared with 18 per cent a year earlier. When
the wholesale price index began to increase
in mid-1955, this proportion was 39 per cent.
Relatively low order backlogs are viewed
with disfavor by business managers who pre­
fer to have sufficient orders on hand to keep
their plants operating at a high level for many
months to come, partly because economies
result when longer runs of particular prod­
ucts can be scheduled. But a comfortable
backlog for a producer represents an uncom­
fortable delay for the customer, who may be
tempted to place duplicate orders elsewhere
to make certain that the goods he requires are
obtained on time. Obviously, large order
backlogs in past periods compared with those
of the present provide no assurance that a
recession is not imminent as shown by the
experience of 1953 and 1957. Orders can be
canceled or set back, particularly when they
represent defense work or duplications.
Lab o r supplies a d e q u a te

Equal in importance to adequate supplies
of productive facilities in an expanding econ­

Business Conditions, M a y 1964

omy is an ample supply of manpower. Some
observers have speculated that excessive
pressure upon the supply of labor played as
important a role in early postwar price infla­
tion as shortages of materials. Today, expan­
sion is hampered by an unfulfilled demand
for certain types of workers with special skills
or scientific training, but there can be no
immediate question of an overall shortage of
labor.
Unemployment, seasonally adjusted, aver­
aged 5.5 per cent of the labor force in the
first quarter— down from 5.8 per cent a year
earlier and the lowest quarterly average since
mid-1960. Nevertheless, the recent rate was
far above the quarterly lows for the postwar
period, for example, 3.5 per cent in the
fourth quarter of 1947 and 2.6 per cent in
the second quarter of 1953.
Aside from the extent of unemployment,
the labor market may be kept relatively slack
in the period ahead because of the growing
number of young people who will be seeking

work. In the past five years an average of 2.7
million persons reached the age of 18 each
year, and almost exactly this number will
reach 18 in the 12-month period ending July
1, 1964. During the period from mid-1964
to mid-1965, this number will jump almost
40 per cent to about 3.7 million, reflecting
the sharp increase in the birth rate following
the end of World War II. The number of per­
sons reaching 18 each year will remain at
about 3.5 million throughout the remainder
of the decade before moving even higher.
In the first quarter of this year an average
of 58.1 million persons were employed in
nonfarm jobs, 1.6 million more than a year
earlier and 4.5 million more than at the low
point in the first quarter of 1961. This is an
excellent record, but because of the probable
expansion of the labor force, the number of
job opportunities will have to increase even
more rapidly in the future to prevent a rapid
growth in unemployment.
— continued on page 16

Trends in agriculture
P ro d u c tio n of agricultural commodities has
continued to increase fairly steadily, rising
nearly one-fourth since 1950. But because of
improvements in technology, there has been
little change in the total amount of resources
used by farmers. There have been large shifts,
however, in the amounts of individual re­
sources used, reflecting changes in relative
prices and productivity.
Rising wage rates and the greater ease of
managing mechanical equipment as com­
pared with hired workers have spurred con­
tinued efforts to mechanize operations where




possible, and farm use of fertilizer and lime
has risen substantially.
In contrast, land used for crops has de­
clined sharply. Land values have risen mark­
edly but the impact of the higher prices on
total farm costs has been softened somewhat
by greater use of fertilizers, pesticides, herbi­
cides, improved seeds and other develop­
ments which have greatly increased produc­
tion per acre. The result, overall, has been a
sizable gain in production per unit of re­
sources used.
Innovations such as electrically timed auto-

Business Conditions, M ay 1964

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

matic feeding equipment, bulk tanks and her­
ringbone milking parlors for the handling of
milk, multiple row tilling and harvesting ma­
chines and a host of such new developments
as improved hybrid seeds, herbicides and
pesticides— and more efficient management
practices— also have made this possible.
Crop production per acre, for example, has
risen nearly 40 per cent since 1950. Rela­
tively high price supports coupled with acre­
age restriction on some crops provided farm­
ers with a strong incentive to boost yields.
Production per livestock breeding unit has
shown equally impressive gains. In the last
few years, the number of milk cows has been
at a low level and the number of chickens for
egg production has dropped far below the
average of the early Fifties, yet total produc­
tion of milk and of eggs has been at or near
record highs. Producers of broilers have
greatly increased the efficiency with which
feed is converted into chicken meat and cat­

tlemen have boosted the liveweight produc­
tion of cattle and calves without a commen­
surate increase in breeding stock.
Big ger farm s

In an effort to increase their incomes, indi­
vidual farmers have rapidly adopted improve­
ments in technology and have been acquiring
additional land with the result that many
smaller farms have been absorbed or merged
to provide larger units.
While the total number of farms declined
about 27 per cent from 1950 to 1959 (based
upon the 1954 Census definition of farms),
the number of farms with gross sales of farm
products above 20,000 dollars more than
doubled and those with sales of 10,000 to
20,000 dollars increased nearly 50 per cent.
Conversely, the number of commercial farms
with gross sales between 2,500 and 5,000
dollars dropped nearly a third and there were
43 per cent fewer farms with less than 2,500

dollars gross sales in 1959 than in 1950.

inventories and farmers’ deposits in banks)
were also substantially increased—up 118
and 56 per cent, respectively. The value of
assets per farm worker is now in excess of
25,000 dollars; there is an average of about
two workers per farm.

Farm a sse ts rise

With the evolution of the commercial farm
into an increasingly technical and more
highly mechanized enterprise, the amount of
capital invested per farm and per worker has
continued to rise sharply. Total value of pro­
duction assets in agriculture rose to 198 bil­
lion dollars in 1963 from 116 billion, or
nearly three-fourths, during the past 14 years.
With the decrease in the number of farms,
the value of production assets per farm
increased nearly 200 per cent from 1950
to 1963. The value of real estate more than
tripled and that of machinery and equipment
more than doubled. Livestock inventories
and other assets per farm (primarily crop

H ig her incom e p e r farm

Total net income from farming declined
from about 14 billion in 1950 to less than 13
billion in 1963. However, net income per
farm from farming has trended upward from
about 2,400 dollars in 1950 to 3,580 last
year. Also more farm families have increased
the amount of off-farm work. As a result, in­
come per farm from nonfarm sources has
nearly doubled in the last 14 years and now
accounts for about one-third of total net in-

per cent,1950 =100

Amounts of selected

Prices of selected

Total

production items

production items

farm assets

farm
real estate

land

160

total
140

farm

machinery
120
crops 8

100
Note! The v e rtic a l scale on th ese ch a rts
is one-half th ot of the ch arts on the
preceding page

1950

8



|

'52
|

|

'54
I

I

'56
I

I

'58
I

I

livestock

'60
I

|

'62
I

I

1950
I

I

'52
I

I

'54
I

I

'56
I

I

'58
I

I

‘60
I

I

'62
l

I

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

come of the farm population from all sources.
C re d it n e e d s e x p a n d

The amount of credit used by farmers has
continued to increase sharply in the past few
years. As farm real estate values have risen,
more of the transfers of farmland have re­
quired the use of credit; farmers also have
increased their use of credit to meet rising
cash operating costs and to purchase ma­
chinery and other production items. Total
farm credit outstanding has nearly doubled
since 1950.
Despite substantial increases in farm debt,
the ratio of agricultural assets to total farm
debt is not as high as in many past years. Cur­
rently, the average ratio of farm debt out­
standing to the value of agricultural assets is

N et income per farm rises, with gains
from both farm and nonfarm sources
dollars

Farm debt rises sharply
billion dollars

per cent




about 1 to 7. While the ratio of debt to assets
has been creeping steadily higher during the
past decade, it is still considerably below the
ratios in the early Forties. Farm debt amount­
ed to about 1 dollar for every 5 of agricul­
tural assets in 1940.
The nation’s farmers will undoubtedly find
it necessary to continue to make extensive
adjustments in their farming operations.
Many of the causative factors underlying past
changes are still present. Therefore, farmers
will probably continue to enlarge their farms
and substitute mechanical equipment and
other capital items for manpower, and credit
requirements likely will grow further as the
changes are being effected. Net income from
farming will probably continue to trend
downward as higher production cost cuts into
gross return but net income per farm is likely
to continue to move to higher levels reflecting
fewer but more efficient farms.

Business Conditions, M ay 1964

Regional economic integration
TJLrade between nations has grown spectacu­
larly since the end of the second World War.
There are many reasons for this, including
the virtual collapse of international economic
intercourse during the Great Depression and
the severe disruptions of the economic fabric
caused by the war.
An outstanding feature of the postwar
growth of international trade has been the
emergence and proliferation of trading blocs,
whose major features are summarized in the
accompanying table. Reflected here are both
the economic and the political forces of a
world undergoing rapid change. Each devel­
opment reflects in its own way new aware­
ness of the benefits to be gained by tearing
down walls impeding the most efficient pro­
duction and exchange of goods and services
among nations that are endowed differently
with material and human resources. Chang­
ing technologies of mass production may have
made the expansion of markets for materials,
capital and finished goods even more impera­
tive than heretofore.
The Marshall Plan inaugurated by the
United States in 1948 laid the groundwork
for renewed cooperation among Western
European nations, both former allies and
former enemies. Out of it grew the European
Payments Union, the European Monetary
Agreement, and the Organization for Eco­
nomic Cooperation and Development of
which Canada and the United States are
members. But more important, it helped
spark the first large-scale peacetime experi­
ment in regional integration in Western Eur­
ope: the European Coal and Steel Com­
munity (ECSC). Fathered by the late French



premier Robert Schumann, the ECSC set
France, Germany, Italy and the Benelux
countries (which previously had already
formed an economic union) on the road to
economic unification.
When it became clear that the results of
this pooling effort had surpassed the boldest
expectations—the idea of a limited supra­
national governmental arrangement having
now been accepted in fact as well as in prin­
ciple—the six ECSC countries joined forces
on a considerably more ambitious project of
economic cooperation, the Common Market
or European Economic Community (EEC)
—sometimes referred to as the “Inner Six”
—which envisages the eventual political uni­
fication of Western Europe. It rests on a
comprehensive legal document, the Treaty of
Rome, and has been a going concern in a
number of activities since early in 1958.
Early efforts to enlarge the Common Mar­
ket’s geographical scope failed, however. This
set off a movement toward an independent
association of European countries that were
likewise pledged to the dismantling of tariffs
and quantitative restrictions on trade: the
European Free Trade Association (EFTA)
or “Outer Seven.” Subsequent attempts to
merge the two groups were unsuccessful, but
the door to such a development in the future
is still ajar.
Both groups continue to develop working
arrangements with additional countries. An
agreement creating an association between
the EFTA and Finland became effective in
1961. Under it, Finland has assumed sub­
stantially the same obligations as those of full
— continued on page 14

]i

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

A checklist o f economic alliances and associations

Origin, membership, area,
population and gross
national product1

Organizational structure

Objectives

EUROPEAN COMMUNITY:
European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC)
Assembly

To pool the member countries' resources

effect since 1952. Belgium,

(142 members, elected by and from national

of coal, steel, iron and scrap in a single

France, Germany, Italy, Lux­

parliaments)

market

Treaty

of

Paris,

embourg and

1951,

in

Netherlands.

449,000 square miles;

178

million; $235 billion

Legislative:

European

Parliamentary

Executive: Council of Ministers (6 members, each
representing

a

national

government).

High

Authority (9 members, independent of national
governments)
Judiciary: Court of Justice (7 independent judges
forming supreme court of appeal on all Com­
munity matters)

European Economic Community (EEC)—Common Market
Treaty

of Rome,

1957, in

effect since 1958. Same as
ECSC

Legislative: Same as ECSC

To pool the members' economic resources

Executive: Council of Ministers (6 members)—basic

over a 12-15 year transition period in a

policy decisions, EEC Commission (9 members)

customs union within which goods, per­

—day-to-day administration

sons, services and capital will move freely,

Judiciary: Same as ECSC

to set up a common external tariff, and to
coordinate policies in other fields

European Atomic Energy Community (Euratom)
Treaty

of

Rome,

1957, in

effect since 1958. Same as
ECSC and EEC

Legislative: Same as ECSC and EEC
Executive:

Council

of

Ministers

Through coordination of research and pro­
(6

members),

Euratom Commission (5 members)
Judiciary: Same as ECSC and EEC

jects to give the Community a powerful
nuclear industry pledged to the peaceful
uses of atomic energy

OTHER ASSOCIATIONS:
European Free Trade Association (EFTA)
Treaty of Stockholm, 1959,

Legislative: None (Stockholm Convention)

To abolish—in stages—tariffs and quan­

in effect since 1960. Austria,

Executive: Council composed of representatives of

titative restrictions between member coun­

Denmark, Norway, Portugal,

member states (one vote each), meets at both

tries, with a view to promoting sustained

Sweden, Switzerland, United

official (delegate) and ministerial levels, office

economic expansion, full employment and

Kingdom.

square

of chairman rotating among member states.

higher standards of living (in contrast to

$130

Permanent secretariat (Geneva) in charge of

EEC, no common external tariff is en­

day-to-day business

visaged)

miles;

92

767,000
m illion;

billion

Judiciary: None
*1963 data, partly estimated.




Business Conditions, M ay 1964

Progress to date

Growth in trade

Problems

From 1953-58 ECSC established a common

ECSC intracommunity trade

Closing down of uneconomic coal mines delayed;

market for coal, steel, and related prod­

in coal, steel, etc., rose some

some overexpansion of steel production capacity

ucts. Has helped to double steel production

200 per cent from 1952 to

from 1953 to 1963; has reorganized the

1960 (as com pared with

coal industry and harmonized discrimina­

growth in output of these

tory transport rates

products of 35 per cent)

With

acceleration of timetable, by July

From 1958 to 1963 EEC in­

Despite basic agreement, integration of EEC agri­

1963 internal tariff duties cut to 40 per

tracom m unity

cent of their 1957 level (20 per cent lower

creased 130 per cent while

culture remains more phantom than substance;
implementation of basic principles of agricultural

than

some adjustments

trade with the rest of the

policy lagging

made in external tariffs. Import quotas on

world rose about 44 per cent

scheduled)

and

tra d e

in ­

industrial products eliminated in 1961

Euratom has established a common market
for nuclear materials and set up a joint
nuclear research center

Following accelerated timetable, by end

From

1960 to 1962 intra-

Administration of system of "national origins" to

of 1963 intra-EFTA tariffs had been re­

EFTA trade rose 16 per cent

prevent foreign goods imported into low-tariff

duced to 40 per cent of 1960 levels (to

while trade with other coun­

member countries from being re-exported to high-

keep in step with EEC)

tries increased about 7 per

tariff member countries




cent

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

A checklist o f economic alliances and associations (continued)

Origin, membership, area,
population and gross
national product1

Organizational structure

Objectives

Treaty of Montevideo, 1960,

Legislative: Conference of the Contracting Parties

To expand and diversify trade and pro­

in effect since 1961. Argen­
tina, Brazil, Chile, Colom­

composed of representatives of member coun­

mote progressive complementarity of mem­

Latin American Free Trade Association (LAFTA)

b ia 2,

Ecu ado r2,

Paraguay,

Peru,

M exico,
Uruguay.

6,676,000 square miles; 181

tries

ber economies; over a 12-year period and

Executive: Standing Executive Committee, Secre­
tariat of Standing Executive Committee

through tariff reductions of not less than
8 per cent a year to bring area free trade

Judiciary: None

into full operation

million; $71 billion3

Central American Common Market (CACOM)
Treaty of Managua, 1960, in

Legislative: Central American Economic Council

To achieve free trade, freedom of capital

effect since 1960. Costa

composed of finance ministers of signatories

movement and a common external tariff

Rica4, El Salvador, Guate­

Executive: Executive Council, Secretariat of the

by 1966; establishment of monetary union

mala, Honduras, Nicaragua.

General

170,000 square miles; 11.8

gration

Treaty

for

Central

American

Inte­

and harmonization of policies in various
fields envisaged

Judiciary: None

million; $2.6 billion3

Council fo r Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON)
Established

under So viet

Legislative: None

At first to promote economic self-suffi­

leadership in 1949 in answer

Executive:

to the Marshall

representatives of all COMECON members
Judiciary: None

bania’,

Bulgaria,

slo va k ia ,

Plan.

A l­

Czecho­

Executive

Committee

composed

of

Union.

to specialize in lines of production for
which they are particularly well fitted, to
tie their economies more closely together

East G erm a n y,

Hungary, Outer Mongolia3,
Poland,

ciency; later to encourage member states

and to create an integrated market

Rum ania, So viet
9,635,000

square

miles; 326 million; G N P un­
known
-Joined in 1961.

14

“Gross domestic product.

4Joined in 1963.

continued from page 11
members of the organization in relation to
most of its trade with EFTA countries.
In 1962 the EEC concluded an association
agreement with Greece that provides for the
gradual establishment of a full customs union,
with special measures to protect and develop
the largely agricultural Greek economy. An




“Inactive.

“Joined in 1962.

association agreement with Turkey was
signed in 1963, but this will become effective
only after ratification by the parliaments of
the EEC member states and Turkey. Fur­
thermore, the former African colonies of
EEC member countries are linked to the
Common Market by special agreements
assuring privileged access to European mar-

Business Conditions, M ay 1964

Progress to date

Growth in trade

Problems

Three tariff-reducing sessions of the Con­

Zonal exports in 1962 rose

Trade among members has remained a small

ference of Contracting

about 20 per cent over 1961

portion (about 7 per cent) of their total trade

overall cuts of about 25, 15 and 10 per

(but

since 1960; industrialization still heavily depend­

cent, respectively

with 1950)

Parties achieved

not at all

compared

ent on outside imports; lack of coordination of
member economic policies and customs systems;
inability to speak with one voice in trade negotia­
tions with outside world; zonal payments system
undeveloped

customs

Intra-CACOM trade in 1962

Inadequate network of transportation; shortage

union nearly complete (tariffs unified on

rose about 37 per cent over

of risk capital to finance new industries

Free trade

largely

established,

more than 95 per cent of customs list

1961 (but still accounted for

items); C. A. Clearinghouse in operation,

only

treaty signed establishing C. A. Monetary
Union with view to adoption of single

trade)

9 per

cent of total

currency at par with U.S. dollar

First multilateral trading agreement be­

Betw een

1961

In the absence of agreed-on criteria for comparing

tween COMECON countries signed in 1957,

trade

C O M EC O N

costs as a guide to specialization, how to substi­

but

re­

countries increased 3-4 times

tute a multilateral trading system for the bilateral

Socialist

as fast as industrial produc­

agreements now in force between member states;

for

tion; COMECON trade with

delay in modernization of trading price structure

debts,

non-Communist countries in

(to bring it into line with changing world prices);

began operations in January 1964; some

recent years increased faster

opposition within the bloc to greater integration,

progress toward a common energy policy

than intrabloc trade

system of

tained;

bilateral

International

Countries,
multilateral

providing
settlement

settlements

Bank
a

of

mechanism
of

trade

1950 and

among

achieved

kets for their products and committing the
EEC to help in financing their development
projects.
Cohesion among the “Inner Six” was seri­
ously jeopardized early last year when the
negotiations with Britain, which had been
widely expected to lead to Common Market
admission of EFTA’s leading member, broke




especially when interpreted to mean a Sovietdictated program of specialization

down. Both EEC and EFTA have since con­
tinued to implement the accelerated time­
tables for tariff reductions previously agreed
upon.
Meanwhile, five Central American and
nine Latin American nations had made some
progress toward achievement of similar goals.
The Central American Common Market

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

(CACOM) is basically modeled after the
EEC, while the Latin American Free Trade
Association (LAFTA) follows, with some
variations, the pattern set by the EFT A.
Intracommunity trade among members of
the integrating groups in the Western Hemi­
sphere, however, is quantitatively much
smaller than that of the Western European
trading groups.
The same is probably also true of the
Council for Mutual Economic Assistance
(COMECON), an organization tying to­
gether the Communist-dominated countries
of Eastern Europe. COMECON, which oper­
ates under different ground rules, has re­
cently undergone some major changes whose
importance is not yet evident.
While the benefits of regional associations
are many, some danger exists that these trad­
ing blocs will substitute for the obsolete
national trade barriers of their members

regional obstacles of a similar kind. There
is some evidence, for example, that in the
agricultural sector the Common Market will
maintain high levels of protection against out­
side competition. Political boundaries, how­
ever, whether they encompass one country or
several, bear no consistent relationship to the
distribution of the world’s productive re­
sources and thus to geographic advantages
and disadvantages in the production of goods
and services. Consequently, it is important
that barriers to trade between blocs as well
as those between individual countries be pro­
gressively lowered. Some test of how much
—if any—progress can be achieved along
these lines will be furnished by the impend­
ing “Kennedy round” of trade negotiations
under the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade (GATT) in which the United States,
the EEC and members of the EFTA will each
play a leading role.

Business continued from page 7

“recession” and “expansion,” suggesting a
more mature economy and a more sophisti­
cated population.
The extent to which individuals and busi­
ness firms have avoided the more serious ex­
tremes of emotional reactions to changes in
business conditions is shown in many of the
economic data that describe economic de­
velopments of the past decade. In part, this
reflects growing confidence that the business
cycle can be moderated if not eliminated en­
tirely through wise private and public poli­
cies. This confidence will be fortified further
if stable growth can be achieved in 1964 for
the fourth successive year without the ex­
cesses that lead to a general rise in prices. At
the present time the prospects are easily
“fair” and probably “good” that this favora­
ble condition will be realized.

The importance of psychological elements
in business fluctuations has been recognized
since these phenomena first came under sys­
tematic scrutiny. When a business upsurge is
in process, expectations— and therefore spec­
ulations—are apt to outrun the real potential
of the movement, and, similarly, a downturn
is likely to cause the emotional pendulum to
swing too far toward the extreme of despair.
At one time, the literature of business
cycles gave great weight to the effects of
changes in psychology. The “normal” condi­
tion of the economy was thought to be sta­
bility or moderate growth interrupted only
occasionally by “panics” and “booms” with
extreme cases of the latter labeled “bubbles”
certain to be deflated. This characterization
16 of the economy has long since given way to