View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve B a n k of Chicago

Business
Conditions
1957 M ay

C ontents
Our American economy:
strength of the Republic

4

Savings levels and turnover

7

Credit unions: mutual finance

9

The Trend of Business

2-3

OF
Q

S e v e r a l important measures of activity which
had coursed upward during most of 1956 have
maintained a remarkably level trend in recent
months. Factory and mine output, in total,
changed little from October through March.
Retail trade, seasonally adjusted, was main­
tained near the level reached in November.
Moreover, total spending represented by the
gross national product increased only slightly
in the first quarter.
Past patterns of economic trends provide
few illustrations of such plateaus. As the year
moves on, it is highly probable that the recent
leveling will appear to be either the “pause that
refreshes” before renewed real growth which
must be reasserted in time or the prelude to
some temporary slide in over-all activity.
Examination of recent trends can never pro­
duce sure-fire guides to the future. But the ap­
parent absence of physical gains, as opposed to
dollar increases, in late 1956 and early 1957
does not appear to provide as solid a basis for
pessimism as the trends which were evident a
year ago at this time.

BUSINESS

appliances and steel, however, industrial pro­
duction over-all in March was only one point
below the December peak. These declines were
largely offset by advances in the output of min­
erals, business equipment and ordnance.
The steel industry had been operating at 98
per cent of capacity in February. In succeeding
weeks the rate dropped to about 91 per cent
in late March. At this level of operations, it is
believed that output approximately balances
usage. However, certain firms are still operating
their facilities at virtual capacity. Industry ex­
perts continue to expect pourings of steel dur­
ing 1957 as a whole to approximate or exceed

B ro ad activity measures
repeat early 1956 slowdown
per cent change from previous quarter
seaso nally adjusted
+ 5 r

industrial production

+ 3

-

The c o n tra st w ith e a r ly ' 5 6

2

In the spring of last year voices were raised
to support the view that the American economy
was slipping back from the peaks registered at
the end of 1955. The industrial production
index dropped from 144 in December to 141
in March (1947-49=100) mainly because of
a sharp cutback in the automotive sector. Also
there was weakness in textiles and some other
lines.
This year auto sales are deemed to be some­
what disappointing, and vehicle output has
declined from earlier peaks almost as sharply
as a year ago. Despite cutbacks in autos, TV,


B usiness C o nditio ns, M a y


1957

0

-I
1955

1956

quarterly
3

2

1957

the 115 million ton total of 1956 which was
only a shade below record 1955.

Retail sa le s on new high plateau

H o u sin g, tr a d e a n d in v e n to rie s

The decline in housing starts was another
danger signal a year ago. In March of 1956, new
starts were off mare than 20 per cent, on an
annual rate basis, from the high of 1955. In
February and March 1957, the rate of private
housing starts dropped below one million for
the first time since 1951 and was about 20 per
cent below the high of last year. New home
building, then, in contrast to industrial produc­
tion is constituting a drag on total activity much
as it did last year.
Retail trade has been well maintained in the
early months of 1957 in contrast to a pro­
nounced sluggishness in the same months of
1956. Sales had remained stable in the final
quarter of 1955 and had actually dropped off
in the first quarter of last year despite rising
incomes. Retail trade during March of this year
was influenced adversely by the later date of
Easter, April 21 compared with April 1 in 1956.
Therefore, an adequate comparison requires
that March and April be combined. On this
basis, preliminary evidence suggests that retail
spending has been fairly well in line with the
6 per cent increase in personal income.
Gross national product apparently rose by
only 3 billion dollars, or less than 1 per cent,
during the first quarter of 1957, despite some
uptrend in prices of finished goods. This per­
formance contrasts with a rise of 10 billion dol­
lars in the previous three-month period. How­
ever, a similar slowing had been evident a year
ago. Between the fourth quarter of 1955 and
the first quarter of 1956, GNP rose only 1.5
billion dollars, a development which compared
unfavorably with the earlier rate of growth.
In January total business inventories, season­
ally adjusted, increased at a rate of 200 million
dollars per month. All of this growth occurred
at the manufacturing level. During these months
last year, inventories were rising by over 600
million dollars a month, or three times as fast.
Moreover, wholesale and retail firms were con­
tributing to the rise in early 1956. On the basis



of this comparison, it appears that the current
level of business activity owes comparatively
little to investment in inventory, an inherently
unstable source of demand for goods.
Securities vs. lo a n s

In early 1956, demand on the part of busi­
ness firms for both long- and short-term funds
was very strong. The increase in outstanding
securities and bank loans combined was far
greater than ever before. This year, some ob­
servers have been pointing to the much slower
increase in commercial bank loans as evidence
of a reduced tempo of business activity.
During the first quarter of 1957, commercial
and industrial loans at weekly reporting banks
rose only 150 million dollars compared with an
increase of about 1.2 billion in the same period
of 1956. However, corporate security issues for
new capital amounted to 3.3 billion dollars. This
was 1.2 billion or 60 per cent more than last
year’s record. Thus, the greater volume of funds
obtained by business from the capital markets
about balanced the much smaller increase in
loans. Lesser dependence upon short-term fi­
nancing, of course, suggests an amelioration in
the liquidity position of corporate business
which had deteriorated substantially during
1956.

3

Our American economy:
strength of the Republic*

4

X n inviting me to address this golden anniversary meeting of the Economic Club of New
York, you are according an honor to the great
American institution I am privileged to serve.
It is deeply appreciated. Unless the Federal Re­
serve System has the interest and understanding
of organizations such as yours, it cannot hope
to fulfill its mission.
In seeking understanding I am not asking
approval. It is not idle flattery to say that this
is a highly enlightened audience, one unusually
well-informed in economic affairs. Yet, I dare
say, you are by no means unanimous in your
feelings about that misnomer, so-called “tight
money.” If it gets any tighter, as one commenta­
tor has amusingly said, it may be just as hard
to get into debt as it is to get out.
I shall touch on that subject later, but an oc­
casion such as this invites a broad look at our
economic heritage in order that we may take
some bearings on the course we are pursuing.
One of the determinants of that course over
the sweep of American history has been the
position we as a nation have taken, through our
democratic processes, on the role and respon­
sibilities of the Government in economic affairs.
Fifty years ago the United States was just
completing its transition from a predominantly
agricultural country to the leading manufac­
turing and industrial nation of the world.
Jefferson’s belief that Government is best
when it governs least was little by little encrpached upon. Yet the system we developed,
with its main emphasis on the dignity of man’s
own initiative and enterprise, spurred the trans­
formation of this country from a wilderness to
the world’s foremost industrial nation at a speed
unprecedented in history.
The system worked. That was proved by the
mighty surges of expansion. But progress was

n d itio n s, M a y
Busin ess C o


1957

not smooth or painless. Prosperity came only
in fits and starts. Exhilarating bursts of expan­
sion produced in their wake depressing spells
of contraction. Men began to question whether
the merriment was worth the misery, especially
when the misery was worst among millions who
had never gotten in on the merry-making.
Early in the Twentieth Century an event oc­
curred to convert the public’s increasingly ques­
tioning attitude into a conviction that the Gov­
ernment had a responsibility — a duty — to do
something to protect people from economic
disasters that were beyond individual control.
That event was the Money Panic of 1907. It
was into that crisis that the Economic Club of
New York was born and out of it that the Fed­
eral Reserve System emerged as an institutional
response to public demand for the protection
I cited.
Diagnosing the panic of 1907 is easy for us
now. With the perfect vision of those who look
backward in time, we can now readily perceive
the panic’s approach. We know now that the
wave of speculative activity that preceded and
provoked it was, in fact, unhealthy.
If the vision of the time was blurred, the
reason lay, in part, in the widespread belief that
a panic like that of 1893 or 1873 could never
again occur. How could it, asked a magazine of
the day, in view of the “phenomenal increase
of our economic strength, the coordination of
American industry since 1899, the establishment
of the gold standard of currency and, more
particularly, the great and concentrated re­
sources of our banks?”
Certainly most people were caught by sur­
prise when the panic struck. That is evident in
* Address of W illiam McC. Martin, Jr., Chairman, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Eco­
nomic Club of New York, March 12, 1957.

a picture of the time, sketched by Senator Nel­
son W. Aldrich in a speech to members of this
club two years later. Senator Aldrich, who
headed the National Monetary Commission
that was established to study the causes of the
financial crisis of 1907, told the members of
your club, on November 29, 1909, that “to the
great majority of the people of the country the
blow came without warning.” Most of the
economic crises in our history have similarly
come — which should teach us to beware of
smugness or complacency.
By the time Woodrow Wilson took office as
President in 1913, financial reform had become
a matter of urgent priority. “It is absolutely
imperative,” the new President said in a special
message he delivered before the Congress of
June 23, 1913, “that we should give the busi­
nessmen of this country a banking and currency
system by means of which they can make use of
freedom of enterprise and of individual initia­
tive. . . .”
Six months later, Congress responded by
passing the Act creating the Federal Reserve
System, entrusting to it responsibility for man­
aging the money supply of the country. This
was a revolutionary step, signifying an end to
the historic refusal of the American people to
accept the very real hazards of a managed
currency.
It was a careful step, too. In framing the Fed­
eral Reserve Act, great care was taken to safe­
guard this money management from improper
interference by either private or political in­
terests. That is the importance of maintaining
the System’s independence. Hence, we have a
system of regional banks headed by a coordinat­
ing board in Washington intended to have only
that degree of centralized authority required to
discharge a national policy effectively. This
constitutes, as you know, a blending of public
and private interests so uniquely American in
character.
Since the Federal Reserve System came into
being, the country has not suffered from in­
elasticity of currency and credit, from immobil­
ity of bank reserves or from the money panics
that haunted the past. However, we learned



from the inflationary bubble following World
War I, and the speculative collapse of the late
Twenties and early Thirties, that elimination
of these factors of instability did not prevent
drastic depression. The over-all problem of
stability also involves fiscal, budgetary and debt
management policies as well as prudent deci­
sions on the part of the business and financial
community.
In the sphere of business and economics, the
great challenge of our times is to prevent the
recurrence of the boom and crash sequence
that has imperiled us in the past, and could
destroy us in the future. It is a continuing chal­
lenge. Meeting it requires constant vigilance.
Over the last hundred years the American
economy has experienced some 24 full turns
of the business cycle, an average of one com­
plete rise-and-fall each four years. As a general
rule, the immediate impetus to expansion of the
Government’s role in economic affairs has come
from one of these periodic disasters. But some­
times, it appears, we can be driven as hard by
fear of disaster as by disaster itself. To find an
example, we need go back little more than a
decade, to the enactment of the Employment
Act of 1946.
In that instance, so great were the psycholog­
ical scars of the 1930’s that the fear that mass
unemployment would develop in the wake of
World War II was sufficient — though the fear
proved groundless — to bring about the Em­
ployment Act of 1946, pledging the Federal
Government to do its utmost to keep employ­
ment, production and purchasing power at con­
sistently high levels.
In 1945, as all of us will recall, there was
great apprehension that the problem we were
going to- face, when the war was over and when
millions of men took off their uniforms, would
be unemployment on a huge scale, and on all
sides, because private business would be un­
equal to providing jobs for these men.
The same apprehension pervaded Con­
gressional debate on the Employment Act in
1946. The Act was adopted almost unanimously
amidst a virtual unity of opinion that it would
be necessary for the Government to act to

create jobs and to see that the transition from
military to civilian employment would not be
attended by unemployment on the scale suf­
fered in the depression.
Actually, the history of the period since the
war has made clear that the problem has not
been one of creating jobs. The ingredients for
growth, the technological advances, the op­
portunities for development in the entire West­
ern world, in the period since the war, have
been limitless — and in my judgment still are.
The real problem has been sustaining jobs and
holding back inflation that would endanger
those jobs by undermining stability.
Nearly everyone subscribes to the objectives
of the Employment Act, but it does seem that
we need to give more attention to certain re­
lated questions: What is the means of attaining
high levels of employment? What is the means
of sustaining jobs and leading us to a per­
manently higher standard of living?
In public discussion in connection with the
Employment Act, you find many references to
money as a medium of exchange, but almost
none with respect to money as a standard of
value. The reason is that almost all attention
was focused on the problem of deflation, and
almost none on inflation.
In my judgment, the objectives of the Em­
ployment Act of 1946, under present condi­
tions, can be attained only by understanding
inflation and resisting it. The fight against de­
flation begins with the fight against inflation.
If inflation is allowed to pursue its course, it
feeds upon itself in such a way that, when the
inevitable correction finally comes, unemploy­
ment will be that much worse.
It should not be difficult to see how inflation
leads to unemployment. The danger becomes
manifest when, as costs go up, it becomes in­
creasingly hard to pass those costs along to the
customer in the form of price increases and it
becomes increasingly easy to misjudge or mis­
calculate the market. Then, the first time volume
dips there is a price-profit squeeze and, at some
point, the profit squeeze leads to a cutback in
investment, income and production. The cut­
 itio ns, M a y
B usiness C o nd


1957

back in production leads to a cutback in em­
ployment.
That’s the cycle. It is what follows when
people try to spend more than they have to
obtain more goods and services than are cur­
rently available. The situation can’t be cured by
additions to the money supply. More money
only pushes up prices and speeds the cyclical
effect.
I have less faith in the magic of money and
credit than some people, and more faith in the
economy than those same people when it comes
to recognizing the economy’s capacity for
adjustment. In the last ten years we have con­
sistently tended to underestimate the vitality
and strength of our economy.
Not long ago an economic historian, Robert
Heilbroner, declared that man has found, over
the centuries, only three ways of insuring the
execution of the thousands of intertwined tasks
— the disagreeable ones as well as the pleasant
ones — that must be done each day to keep
human society from breaking down.
One way has been to organize society around
the forces of tradition, by handing down the
varied and necessary tasks from generation to
generation according to custom and usage; son
follows father, and a pattern is preserved. Thus,
in India, until recently, certain occupations were
traditionally assigned by caste.
The second way, also in use for countless
centuries, has been to use the lash of central
authoritarian rule to see that the necessary tasks
get done. That was the system used to build the
pyramids of ancient Egypt. It is the system the
Soviet government uses today to get its Five
Year Plans carried out.
The third solution to the problem of eco­
nomic survival is the market system. It achieved
general acceptance only a couple of centuries
ago, and yet it revolutionized civilization in the
Western world.
A market provides a means of exchanging
goods, but a market system does considerably
more. It provides a mechanism for sustaining
and maintaining an entire society. It constitutes
a way of life that affords freedom that cannot
— c o n tin u e d o n p a g e 1 4

Savings levels and turnover
C

Leavings deposits at Midwest banks are moving
back into the limelight. By year-end 1956, sav­
ings balances at commercial banks in the Dis­
trict’s 32 major cities had grown to nearly 6 V2
billion dollars, for a gain of 3 per cent from
the previous year. But activity in these accounts
also has been on the rise, adding to the volume
of bank operations in the current period of
rising costs. Hence, attention is being focused
more and more on the step-up in activity and
the factors behind it.
A ccoun t size a n d activity

The total of savings deposits at any bank is
made up of accounts of all shapes and sizes.
When rates of inflow and withdrawal are to be
compared, the particular distribution of account
sizes within a bank or for all banks within a
city becomes more pertinent than the actual
dollar volume of balances. For account size
varies a good deal from bank to bank and com­
munity to community, and it is associated rather
closely with the behavior of savings deposits.
A look at average balances among Chicago
banks illustrates the extent to which size of
savings account typically varies among the
faster-growing and the older, more established
sections of a large metropolitan area. In a con­
tinuing study of deposit trends in Midwest cities,
the figures for the Chicago area, because of its
large size and diversity, have been divided into
15 sub-areas. The primary basis for defining
these sub-areas has been to group together
banks which tend to serve approximately the
same kinds of depositors.
The average size of savings account in Loop
banks was more than twice that of banks in
some suburban areas. Among the various com­
munities outside the city, variations in average
account size were almost as striking. Banks in
the North Shore section showed average bal­
ances IV2 times the size of those in Du Page
and southern Cook Counties. Average size of



savings deposit in each of these sections as of
January 31 is listed below:
C h ica go :
Loop ..................................................... $1,499
N orth S i d e ............................................

1,330

N orthw est S i d e ....................................

1,235

South S i d e ............................................

1,005

Sou thw est

Side

...................................

1,140

W est Sid e

............................................

1,211

O u tsid e the city:
N orth Shore

.........................................
O ther N orth a n d N o r t h w e s t .................
Sou theast (In d ia n a )

.............................
Southern C o o k C o u n ty ........................

Far Southw est
Cicero-Berw yn

1,105
808
803
685

..................................... 1,068
.....................................
952

O ther W estern C o o k C o u n ty .................
Du P a g e C o u n t y ...................................
Fox River V a lle y .................................

947
720
876

O v e r-all a re a a v e r a g e .............................

1,195

Size differences in savings balances tend to
be reflected in measures of activity. In general,
larger accounts turn over more slowly than
smaller accounts. In the present comparison of
Chicago banks, those banks with a high per­
centage of large accounts and hence a higher
average size of account tended to show a less
rapid turnover than those with a smaller average
size. Loop banks, for example, had an annual
withdrawal rate of $35 per $100 of beginningof-month balances, or less than half that of
banks in some outlying communities.
A g e a fac to r

Size of account, of course, is not the only
factor involved in explaining differences in rates
of savings turnover among banks. While quanti­
tative information is not available to measure
precisely the possible influence of age of ac­
count on withdrawal activity, there is some
evidence that this factor also may be important.
The high rate of turnover characteristic of new­
ly opened accounts is all too familiar to most

C o m m u n itie s with the greatest sav-

ings deposit growth tend to have high
withdrawal rates

Chicago area

other north
and northwest

per cent increase in savings deposits
in commercial banks
dec. 31,1952~dec.3l, 1956

$74

I

I less than 10

■

2 1 -3 0
3 1 -4 0
41 and over

Figures within each area are
withdrawals per $100 of deposit
balances in 1956.

Du Page County
$ 74

other western
Cook County
$6 6

west side
$51

loop
$35

CiceroBerwyn
$ 60

r

southwest

Fox River valley
$ 53

side

south side

southern Cook County
$69

far southwest
$49

8


B usiness C o nditio ns, M a y


1957

southeast (ind.)
$58

bankers. Confirming this tendency, sections of
the Chicago area which have had the greatest
relative growth in population and apparently
in savings deposits as well have shown relatively
high withdrawal rates in savings deposits.
Among these sub-areas, high inflow rates almost
invariably were associated with high withdrawal
rates during both 1955 and 1956. This second
factor of age of accounts, although closely re­
lated to account size, may explain some dif­
ferences not accountable on the basis of size
alone. Thus, banks in older, more established
places like Gary, Indiana, and other southeast
communities show less withdrawal activity than
banks in faster-growing regions northwest of
the city, where average size of accounts was
about the same.
At best, a substantial part of intercommunity
and interbank differences remain unexplained.
The kind of community, its income level, al­

ternative outlets for savings funds, prevailing
rates paid on savings deposits and other factors
which defy precise measurement, all have a
bearing upon the behavior of savings depositors
in a given area.
Among the individual banks, the attention
directed toward the depositor who uses his sav­
ings account as a sugar bowl varies a great deal.
In some banks, too frequent withdrawals by
holders of savings accounts are likely to bring
an invitation to shift to a checking account ar­
rangement. Another device to limit withdrawals
is the practice of omitting interest payments
during a period when excessive withdrawals
are made. Finally, some banks make activity
charges based upon the number of withdrawals.
The course of action of each bank varies as the
rising costs associated with turnover of accounts
are weighed with considerations of maintaining
good customer relations.

Credit unions: mutual finance
A s the number of consumers who use credit
for durables has increased and experience of
lenders with credit-worthy characteristics of in­
dividuals has expanded, the use of credit for a
variety of personal exigencies and outsized
purchases has grown tremendously. Lending to
consumers has become a big business with its
own “know-how” and peculiar problems.
In the typical American fashion, this oppor­
tunity for the rewarding use of funds has en­
couraged a variety of financial institutions to
enter the field of consumer lending. Commercial
banks have always taken care of a portion of
this market, but in relatively recent times some
banks have sharply expanded their holdings of
consumer paper by opening consumer loan de­
partments or purchasing consumer paper gen­
erated by retail sellers of durables.
An additional major share of consumer credit



has come to be extended by sales finance and
personal finance companies, specializing in of­
fering loan contracts tailored to particular types
of consumer expenditure.
Other institutions have developed which both
lend to and borrow from consumers, providing
an outlet for personal savings as well as a source
for certain types of personal financing. In this
category are mutual savings banks, savings and
loan associations and, to a lesser extent, life
insurance companies, which direct all or an
important part of the savings they receive into
the financing of the most durable of consumer
purchases, housing. Also included in this group
are the most numerous and fastest growing of
all savings institutions, the credit unions. The
aggregate savings lodged in credit unions are
but a tiny fraction of the total invested in the
other financial institutions mentioned. Credit

union assets are less than one-tenth of the total
for mutual savings banks or savings and loan
associations; they make less than 7 per cent of
total consumer instalment credit; and even in
the field of their specialty, the instalment cash
loan, credit unions hold only 17 per cent of the
national aggregate. But the current strength of
their appeal may be illustrated by the fact that,
in the last year alone, 1,500 new credit unions
were formed and total credit union assets grew
by 11 per cent.
S a v in g s a p p e a l

Several factors account for the recent gains in
credit union assets. One reason is that many
credit unions have paid dividends on members’
savings of between 3 and 5 per cent per annum,
which compares favorably with the return from
bank time deposits and savings and loan shares.
The typically convenient location of the credit
union office has invited savings. The weekly de­
posit of a few dollars has been encouraged in
some industrial plants by having the credit
union office next to the paymaster’s window.

Also through payroll deduction plans, many in­
dustrial credit unions have regularized mem­
bers’ savings and have made loan repayments a
routine procedure. Paradoxically, the lending
facilities themselves may also encourage saving,
because of the acquaintanceship with credit
union operation which a borrower gains.
Credit unions, in addition, perform a number
of other services for members, such as cashing
payroll checks and furnishing advice on family
budgeting. The low-cost life insurance which
most credit unions provide in an amount gen­
erally equivalent to members’ shareholdings
and loan balances induces older members,
especially, to borrow rather than liquidate their
savings when in temporary need of cash. And,
of course, the general prosperity of the nation
and the high rate of saving have also contributed
to the expansion of credit union assets.
The credit union movement was introduced in
America about fifty years ago, largely in re­
sponse to the belief that the low-income pop­
ulace could improve on the financial facilities
available to them by pooling their savings and

Credit union assets have steadily increased . . . and now are 16 times the prewar
figure
Millions




tim e s 1939 a s s e t s

lending to each other. Such lending was expect­
ed ordinarily to be in modest amounts and for
necessitous purposes. In order to have a com­
munity in which members would know other
members and lending could be done largely on
the basis of character, membership in each
credit union was restricted to persons having a
well-defined mutual bond, such as work or wor­
ship or residence in a common place.
While in the early years, credit unions were
envisioned as appealing equally to neighbor­
hood, church, fraternal and employee groups,
today three out of four credit unions serve oc­
cupational groups. This is so partly because
plant managers who want to avoid the problems
and clerical expense involved in processing sal­
ary advances and wage garnishments have en­
couraged workers who need cash to borrow
from “company” credit unions.
Credit unions are most numerous, therefore,
in industrial states. Of the nation’s 17,500 credit
unions at the end of 1956, Illinois leads with
1,466, followed by California with 1,439 and
New York with 1,010. Assets are even more
concentrated. Five states — California, Illinois,
Michigan, Ohio and Massachusetts — account
for about half the assets of all credit unions.
Four of the five Seventh District states are
among the nation’s first 15 in credit union
assets. Illinois is second; Michigan ranks third;
Wisconsin, ninth; and Indiana, eleventh. The
rapidity of credit union growth is especially
outstanding in Michigan, where aggregate credit
union assets have grown in ten years from 21
million to 224 million dollars.
Credit unions operate either under state or
Federal charter. Since 1909, when the Massa­
chusetts law was passed, 44 states and the Disstrict of Columbia have enacted enabling legis­
lation. Credit unions may be chartered in any
state or territory under the Federal Credit
Union Act of 1934. While state credit unions
are under the supervision of state authorities,
Federal credit unions are examined by em­
ployees of the Bureau of Federal Credit Unions,
an agency which is at present part of the De­
partment of Health, Education and Welfare.
Members purchase shares which are recorded,



along with any repayments, in pass books. In
some states deposits are also accepted. The ac­
cumulated saving of members thus forms the
credit union’s capital. Similar to savings and
loan shares, members receive dividends from
net earnings rather than interest. And in prac­
tice, shares, unless pledged as security for a
loan, can be redeemed, or deposits withdrawn,
on demand. Credit unions, like savings banks
and savings and loan associations, may require
a 60-day, usually written, notice of withdrawal.
Thereafter, if withdrawal requests cannot be
honored, business is suspended. If the credit
union cannot work out the situation, there is
finally a general scale-down of share values or
liquidation.
L o w cost lo o n s

The laws regulating credit unions vary some­
what, but differences have lessened over the
years and are now for the most part confined to
the amount of money that can be loaned under
various conditions. The Federal Credit Union
Act, under whose provisions about one-half of
all credit unions operate, specifies that all loans
in excess of 400 dollars must be secured. Fur­
thermore, secured loans may not exceed 10 per
cent of the credit union’s unimpaired capital
and surplus. The maturity on any loan may not
be more than three years, though contracts are
often renewed or extended prior to maturity.
The interest rate charged may not exceed 1 per
cent per month on the unpaid balance of the
loan, including servicing charges. This rate of
interest approximates bank charges, and it is
considerably less than the rate on many finance
company loans. In some cases, the effective rate
is even lower, since if earnings are good, the
credit union, following the cooperative principle
of serving both saver and borrower, may refund
a portion of the interest paid by the borrower.
For much of the history of the movement,
the focal point of credit union operations and
literature has been the small, emergency-type
loan. In line with the national trend toward in­
creased instalment buying, however, a growing
proportion of the loan activity of credit unions
has involved the financing of purchases of dura­

ble goods. Information from 1950 Regulation
W reports indicated that, of outstanding credit
union loans, 63 per cent were for personal uses,
while 26 per cent were for automobile pur­
chases, 6 per cent to finance other retail pur­
chases, and 5 per cent to meet repair and mod­
ernization costs. Five years later, in 1955, the
share of credit union loans for personal pur­
poses was down to 59 per cent. With the grow­
ing concentration of credit union assets in larger
credit unions, which do a substantial amount of
automobile financing, instalment loans to fi­
nance retail purchases appear likely to continue
to be a rising share of total loans.
M a jo rity rule

Most credit unions are managed by a board
of directors, a credit committee which approves
loan applications and a supervisory committee
which examines the books. All such officials
are elected by the members at an annual meet­
ing. Each member has one vote, irrespective of
the size of his investment in the credit union.
In contrast to savings and loan associations, no
proxy voting is allowed.
At the annual meeting, the members also
authorize the dividend rate and the interest re­
fund. In 1955, 13 per cent of Federal credit
unions, paid no dividends, while 63 per cent
paid dividends on shares of between 3 and 5
per cent.
With the exception of the treasurer, credit
union officers-must serve without pay. Volun­
teer managerial help, and in some cases also
volunteer clerical help, negligible advertising
costs and office space often donated by the

Num ber, shareholdings and member­
ship of credit unions have increased

Num ber

A v e ra g e
shares
per member
(dollars)

1949

9,897

171

1952
1955

12,249

222

16,050

292

1956

17,500

315

Digitized B usiness C o nditio ns, M a y
for FRASER


19 5 7

A v e rag e
m em bership
per credit union
413
481
508
509

sponsoring organization keep expenditures low.
This, in turn, helps to make possible the low
interest charges on loans. Also, since credit
unions are nonprofit organizations, they do not
pay Federal income taxes, only local property
and some state taxes, and social security.
The democratic organization of credit unions
in some respects contributes to, and in other
respects curtails, growth. Since the credit union
charter specifies the field of membership, each
credit union has a limited number of potential
members. Equality in voting, undoubtedly, at­
tracts some. But as growing credit unions have
lost the neighborly intimacy of the small group,
it has been increasingly difficult to enlist as
officers capable persons who are willing to give,
without salary, the time, energy and dedication
which administering a large credit union re­
quires. Moreover, since officers are elected as
much on the basis of personal popularity as
competence, mistakes occur. Recent Congres­
sional hearings have been concerned with em­
bezzlement and mismanagement, which is not
serious now, but which looms in the back­
ground as individual credit unions accumulate
large sums. In recognition of the responsibilities
involved, the training of personnel for man­
agerial positions has become an important part
of the program of individual state credit union
leagues and the Credit Union National Asso­
ciation.
P o rtfo lio c o n sid e ra tio n s

At the end of 1956,'loans represented 72 per
cent of total credit union assets. This figure has
been climbing gradually in the postwar period,
and now is within the range of ratios of loans
to assets which was common before the war. Aside from loans, most credit unions can legally
invest only in U. S. Government securities,
savings and loan shares and, in small restricted
amounts, in shares of other credit unions. For
big credit unions having more funds than are
currently demanded, savings and loan shares
have become the most popular residual earning
asset. Federal credit unions’ holdings of savings
and loan shares at the end of 1955 (the latest
year for which full statistics are available) were

The typical asso ciatio n is now much
larger than in 1935
per cent

total assets,

assets. During 1956, credit union borrowings
probably increased further, in repetition of the
1955 pattern. Such trends have helped to stimu­
late a great deal of discussion, both pro and
con, regarding the need for rediscount agencies
where member credit unions could borrow in
periods of financial stress.
S a v in g s n o t in su re d

twice their U. S. Government securities hold­
ings.
Portfolio composition, of course, varies
among individual credit unions. Size and age,
especially, have a decisive influence on asset
distribution. Young and small credit unions
tend to have more loans and fewer U.S. Gov­
ernment securities.
Credit union members are constantly pur­
chasing shares and making loan repayments.
But credit union receipts may sometimes fall
short of disbursements for a period. For exam­
ple, in emergency situations such as a strike,
numerous members may default in their loan
payments or may make heavy withdrawals.
Hence credit unions must have sufficient cash,
credit lines and short-term securities which can
readily be converted into cash to provide a safe
margin for operating expenses and withdrawals.
Among individual credit unions there is wide
variation in the ratio of cash and U.S. Govern­
ment securities to share capital, but for all
credit unions together this ratiQ stands now at
about 20 per cent. Credit unions may, of course,
meet heavy cash drains by borrowing from
banks or other credit unions. At the end of
1955, notes payable of Federal credit unions
amounted to 29 million dollars, 2.3 per cent of



Another point of controversy in credit union
circles has been the question of share insurance.
Shareholdings in Federal or state credit unions
are not now insured by any government agency,
although President Eisenhower in both his 1955
and 1956 Economic Report recommended to
Congress that they “consider the merits of
share-account insurance and other measures
for protecting savings in credit unions.” In Illi­
nois the legislature has enacted a law which
permits a private corporation to guarantee
shares of credit union depositors up to $10,000.
Twenty per cent of credit unions in Illinois now
have guaranty coverage. Some other states have
voluntary insurance plans administered by state
credit union leagues. Opponents of share in­
surance cite the record that credit union losses
on bad loans have amounted to less than Yx of
1 per cent of money loaned and that losses are
covered by reserves which each credit union is
required to maintain. Moreover, in liquidation,
they add, most credit unions have been able to
pay their members 100 per cent or more of their
shareholdings.
Other than in wartime, reasons for liquida­
tion of individual credit unions have included
plant shutdowns, company mergers, insufficient
membership, lack of competent management
and company hostility. Support for insurance
has come mainly from large credit unions that
fear the “runs” which can result from defalca­
tions and lay-offs and the costs and delays in
loan collection when a plant has closed and
workers have dispersed.
The c o n strain ts o f g r o w th

The remarkable rate of growth of credit
unions is undeniable evidence of their appeal
as a savings institution and of their expanding

role in financing consumers. Yet there are lim­
its to the growth of individual credit unions
in their conventional form. They are set on the
savings side by the size of the group served,
and they may be inferred on the lending side
from the relatively slow national growth of
instalment cash loans from all sources com­
bined.
In practical operation, these limits may be
stretched by measures such as paying higher
dividends and diversifying loan services into
areas of relatively expanding credit use. But
such practices lead away from the initial aims

of the credit union movement, and the results
they produce can tend to dilute the intimate
credit union member relationship.
In the climate generated by these changes, it
becomes harder to nurture a reformist zeal for
ministering at low cost to the necessitous re­
quests of workers of modest means. One grati­
fying economic implication should not be over­
looked : that the financially underprivileged
worker of yesteryear is being succeeded by a
more knowledgeable and resourceful genera­
tion with a significantly wider horizon of finan­
cial opportunities in view.

O u r e c o n o m y c o n tin u e d fr o m p a g e 6

serfdom that once bound the mass of men for
life to their native plot of soil and their native
status in society were broken when payment in
produce was supplanted by payment in cash.
Money gave men freedom of movement and
leisure. It gave them the ability to change the
nature and locality of their possessions and
earnings at will. It gave them freedom to do as
they please with the product of their labors —
to eat it or drink it, to give it to a church or
charity, or spend it for learning something, to
save its value against some unforeseen event,
to use it to lift living standards for themselves
and their families or to put it aside to fortify
their independence when they wish to assert it.
In short, money can be an instrument of free­
dom — if only we permit it to function in that
role. But the power over money can also be
an instrument of tyranny — witness the coin
clipping by kings, a form of tyranny known at
first hand by many of those who settled early
in America. That is one of the reasons why
there has been so much concern over monetary
policy and monetary actions throughout our
history.
When the first Bank of the United States was
established under Government charter, great
effort was put into preventing the Government,
or political authority, from having any say over
the bank and thus having a chance to indulge in
coin clipping.

exist in a society run by tradition or the rule
of authority. For, in the market system, the
lure of gain, not the pull of tradition nor the
whip of authority, steers each man to his task.
And yet, although each may go wherever he
thinks fortune beckons, the interplay of one
man in competition with another results in the
necessary tasks of society getting done.
Now we know from our experience that the
functioning of markets is not always good. Mar­
kets can, in fact, function very badly, partic­
ularly when they are dominated by monopoly,
by speculative excesses or by inflationary forces.
Those of us who are truly concerned with utiliz­
ing the resources of the market must devote
our energies to the promotion of competition,
the restraint of speculative excess and the main­
tenance of the stability of the dollar.
It seems obvious that the market system
could not function without money, for money is
at the heart and center of a flexible society. No
modern country can have stability and progress
without some basis of sound currency. That is
why all modern countries have central banks.
That is why the United States has the Federal
Reserve System.
Money performs a great many services for
mankind, but none more important than in
providing a degree of freedom that man could
not attain if money did not exist. The bonds of
Digitized B usiness C o nd itio ns, M a y
for FRASER


1957

Gradually, as time went on, apprehension
arose about too much private control over
money. When the Second Bank of the United
States was formed, there was some recognition
that the public interest should be represented
in the bank’s setup. So, the Congress made pro­
vision for public representation when it granted
the bank’s charter.
But to Andrew Jackson, and many others
as well, it seemed that the public representation
permitted was not enough. It was not that Jackson opposed the idea of any central bank, for
he said in his veto message that such an institu­
tion “is in many respects convenient for the
Government and useful to the people.” What he
objected to was that this particular bank, as it
was set up, provided private interests with what
was, in the words of his veto message, “a
monopoly — an exclusive privilege of banking
. . . granted at the expense of the public.” In
consequence, Jackson destroyed the bank.
The enactment of the Federal Reserve Act,
as part of Woodrow Wilson’s “New Freedom,”
marked the beginning of what we might call
modern times with respect to the role of Gov­
ernment in monetary affairs. Jackson’s com­
plaint had been answered: there would not be
private domination of money — nor political
domination either.
Let us not, however, be misled into thinking
that the entrustment of money management to
the Federal Reserve represents a change in
fundamentals or an unawareness of the eco­
nomic facts of life or a denial of the ability and
courage of individuals as an essential part of
the mechanics by which a higher standard of
living is to be achieved.
At the center of our way of life always re­
mains the market place, tying together individ­
ual freedom and material progress. While con­
cepts may be modified, and should be from
time to time, our basic thinking continues to
recognize private property, free competitive
enterprise and the wage and profit motive, op­
erating in the open market through the price
mechanism, as the most effective means of
developing and sustaining our march toward



better living standards and the elimination of
poverty.
Nothing in the background or history of the
Federal Reserve Act indicates any misunder­
standing of the law of supply and demand, or
any belief that a Federal Reserve System could
control or successfully manipulate, for long,
supply and demand forces. Certainly the history
of the past 40 years indicates the wisdom of this
approach and demonstrates again that you can
change the nature of demand and alter the com­
position of supply, but you can no more abolish
the law of supply and demand than you can
abolish the law of gravity. It must be reckoned
with always, sooner or later, and, whenever
we ignore the working of the market, we do it
at our peril and ultimately must pay the piper.
Six years ago a decision to unpeg the Gov­
ernment securities market was in process of
being carried into effect. For a number of years,
efforts had been made to adjust the supply-de­
mand relationships in Government securities
without resorting to the price mechanism.
It had become quite popular in that period
to assume that neither interest rates nor ex­
change rates made any difference, and that no­
tions that they did matter were the fetishes of
outmoded classical economists whose views
were completely out of tune with the modern,
postwar world. Then we saw reality creep up
on us, a seller’s market change to a buyer’s
market, and rates could no longer be pegged
at artificial levels. The devaluations of the 1949
period, brought to head in September by the
readjustment of the British pound sterling, were
casting their shadows before and indicating that
it might not be long before the supply-demand
relationship in our Government securities mar­
ket would have to be faced squarely unless we
were willing to accept the alternative of drastic
depreciation of the dollar.
Essentially, the Treasury-Federal Reserve
accord returned to the market some of the in­
fluence which had been denied it by conscious
Government policy for a period of more than
10 years. Once Government securities ceased
to be interest-bearing money, and supply-de-

mand relationships began to be equalized by
adjustment in interest rates, the credit mechan­
ism once again began to operate through the
market place.
The Federal Reserve System ceased to be an
engine of inflation. It would still be that if it
were to pour out money in the endless stream
that would be necessary to supply reserves in
sufficient volume to meet every demand for
credit without an increase in interest rates, the
price of money.
No one should expect the Federal Reserve to
do that, for to do so would be an abandonment
of the System’s duty to keep the flow of credit
in line with the resources of the economy so
that we may continue in the path of stability
and growth. Neither should anyone fear that
credit will become “unavailable at any price.”
Fundamentally, the so-called “tight money” sit­
uation that has evoked so much comment has
not been brought about by a reduction in the
money supply. The money supply has not in
fact been reduced. Actually, the money supply
has increased, and so has its velocity or turn­
over. Credit has not been tightened by an in­
sufficiency of money; rather, the tightening
effect has been produced by the magnitude and
intensity of demands for credit from practically
all quarters. All of the demands could have been
satisfied only by creation of more bank credit
— creation of more money — and that, of
course, would be inflationary.
But the problem of achieving a balance is not
insoluble. In an economy as strong as ours, it
can be solved in large measure by a reduction
in spending and an increase in saving brought
about by market forces.
The rediscovery of monetary policy in this
country and throughout the free world dramat­
ically illustrates the traditionally American
recognition of the superiority of judgments
arrived at in the market place to those made by
individuals, or groups of individuals, within
either Government or private business. It is my
conviction that, by and large and excepting
periods of war, you will get more impersonal,
fairer distribution of our economic production
through the process of the market than you will
DigitizedBusin ess C o n d itio n s, M a y
for FRASER


1957

by leaving the distribution to any group of
men, whether in the Federal Reserve or else­
where. Furthermore, the workings of the mar­
ket will create a greater end product to dis­
tribute than any other system as yet devised.
The background of the American Revolu­
tion is so well known that every school-boy
understands, in an emotional sense if no other,
the guarantees of the First Amendment to our
Consitution. Freedom of religion, freedom of
speech, freedom of the press, freedom of the
right to assemble and petition — all of them
strike answering chords in the hearts of most
Americans. Yet it has also seemed to me that
the inter-weaving of these concepts in the fabric
of our society, in terms of livelihood, is not so
well understood. That is why I have spent so
much time — perhaps too much — in reviewing
our economic heritage.
We are a Republic, a constitutional democ­
racy in which the general welfare is expressed
in political procedures, forms and institutions.
At the base of our structure lie certain prin­
ciples and concepts, such as the market system,
which are themselves the product of an evolu­
tionary process.
In discussing these matters with you, I have
been motivated by conviction that the problems
we are dealing with today, and the road we hope
to travel tomorrow, must be related to these
principles and concepts if we are to have useful
guideposts by which to keep our course steady
in the murk and fog that from time to time sur­
round us.
I have a deep and an abiding faith that the
foundation on which our American economy
rests is firm and sure. Our American economy
is, indeed, the strength of our Republic.
B u sine ss C o n d itio n s is p u b lis h e d m o n th ly b y
th e f e d e r a l r e s e r v e b a n k o f C h i c a g o . S u b ­
sc r ip tio n s a re a v a ila b le to th e p u b lic w ith o u t
ch a rg e. F o r in fo r m a tio n c o n c e r n in g b u lk m a il­
in g s to b a n k s, b u sin e ss o r g a n iz a tio n s a n d e d u ­
c a tio n a l in stitu tio n s, w rite : R e s e a r c h D e p a r t­
m e n t, F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ic a g o , B o x
8 3 4 , C h ic a g o 9 0 , Illin o is. A r tic le s m a y b e r e ­
p r in te d p r o v id e d s o u r c e is c r e d ite d .