View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve B an k of Chicago

Business
Conditions
1963 July

Contents
Trends in banking and finance

2

G reat Lakes ports broaden
Midwest links to w orld

5

The patterns of personal income

10

Defense of the dollar—
a Midwest view, a speech
by Charles J. Scanlon

15

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

in banking and finance

^ 3 a n k loans grew much more rapidly in the
past year than in the preceding twelve months
of the current business upswing. At member
banks in the Seventh Federal Reserve District
total loans have risen 25 per cent since the
low point of the recent recession in February
1961, with almost two-thirds of the gain
occurring in the past twelve months. The ac­
celerated growth in the later period was
especially marked in the major cities.
Detailed data available from the spring
condition reports indicate that this pattern
was general for all of the major loan categor­
ies. Real estate loans produced the biggest
dollar gains over the period as a whole, ac­
counting for about 30 per cent of total loan
growth in the two years ending last spring. At
the same time, a substantial amount of funds
was channeled into very liquid types of loans
—to security dealers and brokers and to other
banks and nonbank financial institutions.
The largest gains in real estate loans in the
1962-63 period were in Chicago and Detroit
and consisted mainly of Government-under­
written residential mortgages. Although Chi­
cago banks reported the largest percentage

BUSINESS CONDITIONS

increase in mortgages, their total holdings of
real estate loans were still slightly less than
10 per cent of their total loans. In Detroit, last
year’s acquisitions boosted mortgage loans
from 30 per cent to almost 33 per cent of
total loans.
While mortgages have always been con­
sidered an appropriate outlet for time money,
the recent move into mortgages by city banks
reflects the absence of strong demand for
business credit as well as the large growth in
time deposits during the past two years.
B o o st fro m a u to p a p e r

Consumers stepped up their bank borrow­
ing sharply in the 1962-63 period, with the
brisk pace of automobile purchases providing
a major stimulus. As total automobile instal­
ment paper outstanding in the United States
rose 13 per cent, such paper in the portfolios
of District banks increased about 20 per
cent. Strong gains were reported at banks in
four of the five major cities and at other
banks in all five of the District states.
Loan trends are typically more stable from
year to year in smaller communities than in

is published monthly by the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago. D orothy M . Nichols

was primarily responsible fo r the article "Tre n d s in Banking and Finance," W . Ernst Kuhn fo r "G re a t Lakes Ports
Broaden M idw est Links to W o r ld " and G eorge W . C loos fo r “The Patterns o f Personal Income."
Subscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public w ithout charge. Fo r inform ation concerning bulk
mailings, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago, Chicago 90, Illinois.
2

Articles may be reprinted provided source is credited.




B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

1963

market “firmed” on a broad front.
Virtually all short-term interest
rates— on Treasury bills, com­
mem ber banks
other
mercial paper, acceptances and
in 5 c i t ie s
m e m b e r banks
dealer loans—rose to the highest
p er cent change (sp rin g call dates)
-10
0
+10
+20 0
+10
+20
levels in three years. The supply
type of loan
of Federal funds—reserves which
are loaned by some member
com m ercial and in d u s tria l
banks to other banks on an over­
night basis—“dried up” at times
and rates stuck close to the dis­
fa rm
count rate of 3 per cent. Banks
generally will not pay other banks
more for reserves than the rate at
re a l e s ta te
which they can borrow from the
Federal Reserve Banks.
Excess reserves—the amount
by which the total reserves held
by all member banks exceed re­
lo a n s on s e c u ritie s and
quired reserves — declined, and
to fin a n c ia l in s titu tio n s
the amount of reserves borrowed
from the Federal Reserve Banks
rose. As a result, free reserves—
to ta l lo a n s
excess reserves less borrowed re­
serves—declined to a three-year
*P e r cent change n o t sh o w n due to sm a ll base.
low. The relationship of these re­
serve measures is shown below
the large cities. The cyclical variation in large
for comparable periods of the past three
cities reflects primarily the credit needs of
years.
large corporations. During the current busi­
First half of June
ness expansion, however, commercial and
1961
1962
1963
industrial loans rose faster in the smaller
(million dollars)
cities. The relatively slow demand for busi­
Total reserves . . . . 18,184* 18,976* 19,424
ness credit at banks in the major cities may
Less required
reserves .......... . .17,584*
18,523* 19,054
reflect both smaller over-all credit needs due
Equals excess
to the rise in internally generated funds (as
600
reserves .......... . .
453
374
measured by retained earnings plus deprecia­
Less borrowed
tion) and the fact that large businesses have
66
reserves ..........
51
232
access to other sources of credit, such as the
Equals
free
commercial paper and securities markets.

Loan gro w th accelerated in
second year of business expansion

Firm er m o n e y m a rk e t; ra te s rise

In late May and early June, the money



reserves .......... . .
534
402
*Adjusted to current requirements.

142

The rise in short-term rates was accompa-

3

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

the amount of borrowing is greater than ex­
cess reserves), it should be clear that free
reserves are not a measure of the amount of
reserves available as a base for credit expan­
sion. The amount of credit that can be ex­
tended in any given period depends not on
free reserves nor even on the amount of ex­
cess reserves existing at the start of that
period but rather on the reserves available
during the period. The latter can rise (or
decline) substantially with no effect on ex­
cess reserves if required reserves have
changed by a like amount.
The total amount of reserves in the bank­
ing system sets limits to the amount of de­
posits and, therefore, the amount of loans and
investments that banks can accommodate. A
rise in free reserves merely indicates that
banks are not using the available
supply of reserves as fully as in
Auto loans up sharply
the previous period. A fall in free
in most District areas
reserves, on the other hand, indi­
cates simply that unborrowed re­
serves were less than those needed
auto
commercial
real
to support deposits.
instalm ent
and in d u stria l
estate
per cent change Mar 1962-Mar. 1963
member banks in
The important point is that
0 10
20
0
10
20
30
major cities
----20
30
0
10
bank credit can rise rapidly in a
Chicago
period when free reserves decline
D e tro it
and even when free reserves are
M ilw aukee
a negative quantity. Conversely,
□
total bank credit can decline as
Ind ia na p olis
free reserves rise. This often hap­
no change
Des M oines
pens when business activity levels
off or declines with the accom­
other member
percent change Mar I962-M a r.l963
panying
easing of credit demands
banks
10
20
30
0
10
20
0
10
20
30
and
with
repayment of borrow­
Illin o is
ings from the Federal Reserve
M ichigan
Banks.
What, then, is the significance
W isc o n sin
of
free reserves? In periods of
Ind ia na
rapidly expanding business activ­
Iowa
ity and strong demands for credit,
the Federal Reserve may not pro-

nied by higher yields in all sectors of the
securities markets despite the continued rapid
accumulation of investment funds and moder­
ate volume of security issues. There is con­
siderable evidence that much of this acrossthe-board increase in yields was a reflection,
not of a basic change in supply-demand rela­
tionships for funds but of investors’ expecta­
tions that credit supplies would be curtailed
because free reserves had declined. The free
reserve statistic has been interpreted by nu­
merous observers in the press and elsewhere,
as a measure of the availability of credit, that
is, the ability of the banks to make loans and
purchase investments. That this view is
erroneous is illustrated by the experience of
the past two years.
Since free reserves can be negative (when




B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

Bank credit has continued to rise
while free reserves have declined
billion dollars

1961

1962

1963

vide the full amount of reserves needed to
support the continuation of rapid credit and

1963

deposit expansion. In such circumstances, the
relative scarcity of reserves causes some banks
to borrow at the discount window, thus reduc­
ing free reserves. Since such borrowing can be
only a temporary source of reserves for indi­
vidual banks, those that are borrowing feel
pressure to expand credit less rapidly or even
to reduce the amount of credit they have out­
standing. This tends to be accompanied by
rising interest rates.
That a falling level of free reserves does
not necessarily indicate a decline in “credit
availability” is illustrated by recent experi­
ence. The accompanying chart shows the
movements in free reserves and bank credit
over the past two years. Free reserves have
declined gradually since early 1962, yet bank
credit grew more rapidly after mid-1962 than
before. Reflecting the strength of credit de­
mands, loan growth was actually greatest in
those months when free reserves showed the
sharpest declines.

Great Lakes ports broaden
Midwest links to world
T h e 1963 Great Lakes shipping season
opened on a note of moderate optimism.
Both imports and exports had risen substan­
tially in 1962 as a wide variety of goods
flowed through the St. Lawrence Seaway to
and from a large number of countries. Sea­
way revenues, however, continued to lag be­
hind long-term expectations, and this pattern
seems certain to be maintained during 1963
despite expected further gains.
Some 877 million dollars worth of exports



to Canada and overseas countries left the
United States via Great Lakes ports in 1962,
an increase of 17 per cent over 1961. Imports
through these ports amounted to 540 million
dollars, or 19 per cent more than in the pre­
ceding year. Tonnages were up 15 per cent
for exports and 33 per cent for imports.
Almost half of the dollar value of Great
Lakes exports and two-thirds of the imports
move through Seventh Federal Reserve Dis­
trict ports. Measured by weight, the relative

5

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

Exports and im ports through Great Lakes ports located in the Seventh Federal
Reserve District during the 1962 shipping season*
Leading commodities

M ajor sources and destinations

(million dollars)

(million dollars)

Corn (41), machinery and parts (27), soybeans (26),

Canada (52), Germany (28), United

Great Lakes port

C h ica go
E x p o rts
Value—$221 million
W eight—4,202 million lbs.

railway locomotives and parts (21), machine tools

Kingdom

(12), hides and skins—raw (10), animal oils and

India (17), Italy (12), all other (66).

(27),

Netherlands

(19),

fa ts—edible (10), all other (74).
Im p o rts
Value—$169 million
W e ight— 1,999 million lbs.

and

Canada (39), W est Germany (30),

parts (18), distilled spirits, liquors and wines (17),

United Kingdom (28), Federation of

rolled-finished steel mill products (13), auto trucks

Malaya (10), Japan (10), all other

(11), all other (76).

(52).

Machinery and parts (15), machine tools (15), auto

Argentina

trucks and accessories (10), rolled-finished steel mill

(11), India (7), W e st Germany (7),

Standard

newsprint

paper

(34),

machinery

Detroit
E x p o rts
Value—$81 million
W e ig ht—888 million lbs.

Im p o rts
Value—$100 million
W e ig ht—5,029 million lbs.

(6),

(13),

United

Australia

products (9), auto trucks excluding parts (8), all

Italy

other (24).

(32).

Iron ore and concentrates (17), standard newsprint

Canada (44), United Kingdom (17),
(11),

W e st

(5),

Kingdom
all

Germany

other

paper (15), rolled-finished steel mill products (12),

Belgium

iron-steel semi-finished products (11), all other (45).

France (4), Japan (3), all other (16).

(5),

M ilw a u k e e
E x p o rts
Value—$52 million
W e ight—903 million lbs.

Machinery and parts (15), corn (8), dried milk (5),

Canada

wheat flo u r semolina (4), all other (20).

W e st Germany (5), Italy (3), Nether-

(8),

United

Kingdom

(5),

Im p o rts
Value—$33 million
W e ight—489 million lbs.

Standard newsprint paper (9), barley and rye (4),

Canada (15), United

rolled-finished steel mill products (3), all other (17).

Belgium (2), France (2), Netherlands

lands (3), all other (28).
Kingdom (3),

(2), W e st Germany (2), all other (7).

S a g in a w -B a y City, M ic h ig a n
E x p o rts
Value—$27 million
W e ight—458 million lbs.

Vegetables and preparations (7), synthetic resins

Netherlands (9), Canada (8), United

(3), wheat (3), chemical specialties (3), all other

Kingdom (6), all other (4).

Im p o rts
Value—$10 million
W e ight—367 million lbs.

Pig iron (9), all other (1).

Canada (9), all other (1).

E x p o rts
Value—$1 million
W e ight—67 million lbs.

Iron and steel scrap (0.4), all other (0.9).

Italy (0.4), Canada (0.3), all other

Im p o rts
Value—$17 million
W e ig ht—3,636 million lbs.

Iron ore and concentrates (16), all other (1).

( ID .

East C h icago , In d ia n a




(0.6).
Canada (15), all other (2).

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

Great Lakes port

________________ Leading commodities________________

M ajor sources and destinations

(million dollars)

(million dollars)

1963

G re e n B a y, W isco n sin
E x p o rts
Value—$7 million
W e ig h t— 106 million lbs.

W heat flo u r
other (1).

semolina

(3),

dried

milk

Im p o r ts
Value— $8 million
W e ig h t— 171 million lbs.

Wood pulp (6), sugar (1), all other (1).

(3),

all

Algeria (1), Morocco (1), India (1),
Egypt (1), Italy (1), all other (2).

Canada

(4),

Sweden

(1),

Finland

(1), all other (2).

R acin e -K e n o sh a, W isco n sin
E x p o rt s
Value—$8 million
W e ig h t— 104 million lbs.

Auto trucks excluding parts (3), wheat flo u r semo­

United

lina

Netherlands (1), all other (4).

Im p o r ts
Value—$4 million
W e ig h t—22 million lbs.

Auto trucks (3), all other (1).

W est Germany (3), all other (1).

Wood pulp

Canada

E x p o rts
Value $3 million
W e ig h t— 108 million lbs.

Iron and steel scrap (1), canned fru its except juices
(1), a|| other (1).

Netherlands (0.5), all other (1.2).

Im p o r ts
V a lu e - $ 4 million
W e ig h t—53 million lbs.

Standard newsprint paper (0.7), auto truck (0.6),
wood pu|p (Q.5), a|| other (1 9)

Canada

Iron ore and concentrates

Canada

(2),

animal

oils

and

fats—edible

(1),

all

Kingdom

(2),

Belgium

(1),

other (2).

M arin e tte , W isco n sin
I m p o r ts
Value—$10 million
W e ig h t— 172 million lbs.

M u sk e g o n , M ic h ig a n
Italy

(0.9),

W e st

(1),

Germany

United

Kingdom

(0.6),

(1),

W e st Germany (1), all other (1).

P resque Isle, M ic h ig a n
E x p o rts
Value— $6 million
W e ig h t— 1,060 million lbs.

P ort H uron, M ic h ig a n
E x p o rts
Value— $3 million
W e ig h t—38 million lbs.

Vegetables and preparations (2), all other (1).

I m p o r ts

Wood pulp (0.5), auto truck (0.3), all other (0.2)

France (0.4), United Kingdom (0.4)
Algeria (0.3), all other (1.5).

Value— $1 million
W e ig h t—68 million lbs.

Sweden (0.3), W e st Germany (0.3),
all other (0.4).

South H a ve n , M ic h ig a n
Im p o r ts
Value— $3 million
W e ig h t—7 0 million lbs.

Wood pulp

Canada (1), Sweden (1), all other
( 1).

*A p ril to November.
SO U RC E: Based on data prepared by U. S. Bureau of the Census, as compiled by Chicago Association of
Commerce and Industry.




7

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

8

importance of District foreign trade via the
Great Lakes is considerably less than it is by
value, although the difference is not as pro­
nounced for imports as for exports.
In the table on pages 6-7, 1962 exports
and imports are listed for the District ports
which dispatched or received commodities
valued in excess of 1 million dollars. These
comprise the great bulk of all foreign trade
movements through District ports. For each
port the total value and tonnage of shipments
are noted as well as the leading commodities.
In addition, the main buyers of exports and
the principal sources of imports are shown.
Three cities—Chicago, Detroit and Mil­
waukee—accounted for 87 per cent of ex­
ports and 84 per cent of imports at District
ports. The port of Chicago alone handled
well over half of exports and nearly half of
imports. While Chicago and Milwaukee were
net exporters, Detroit had a net import
balance.
Generally, the more foreign trade cargo
handled by a port, the greater the variety in
the composition of the trade. For example,
Chicago’s largest export commodity, com,
contributed less than one-fifth to the total
value of its exports, but more than nine-tenths
of Port Huron’s exports consisted of one
class of goods—vegetables and preparations.
On the import side, the varying degree of
commodity diversification may be illustrated
by Detroit and Green Bay: iron ore and con­
centrates, the motor car city’s leading import,
was less than one-fifth of the total; but wood
pulp, the Wisconsin city’s foremost import,
accounted for more than three-fourths of the
total. Extremes of specialization are illus­
trated by one-commodity ports: Presque
Isle, Michigan, exporting iron ore and con­
centrates only, and Marinette, Wisconsin,
importing wood pulp exclusively.
With regard to geographic orientation,




exceptional is the port which ships to or re­
ceives from one country only; much more
common is a wide variety of destinations and
origins. Canada, the leading customer and
supplier of the United States in over-all trade,
was also prominent in both outbound and
inbound waterborne District shipments.
Canada ranked first in the imports received
at almost all District ports and in the exports
from two of the major ports—Chicago and
Milwaukee. The United Kingdom occupied
second or third place in shipments from the
five largest and to the three largest ports.
Several other European countries ranked
high on both sides of the trade ledger.
“Big th r e e ” p la y m ajor role

Chicago has two developed areas 13 miles
apart that form its port. Navy Pier and dock­
ing facilities in the mouth of the Chicago
River are adjacent to the downtown business
district (Loop) while Calumet harbor, Lake
Calumet and the river joining them are in the
southeast heavy industry area. Both com­
plexes are connected to the Illinois Waterway
and Mississippi River system.
During 1962 a total of 192 ships arrived
at Navy Pier from overseas and 370 ships in
the Calumet area. While the downtown fa­
cilities handle general cargo almost exclu­
sively, facilities at Lake Calumet and along
Calumet River accommodate most of the
bulk cargo as well as a large portion of the
general cargo. Bulk cargo accounts for 95
per cent of Chicago’s total tonnage.
More than 100 million dollars in public
and private money has been invested in new
port facilities in Chicago since the beginning
of construction of the St. Lawrence Seaway
in 1955. If the necessary additional funds are
appropriated, the U. S. Army Corps of Engi­
neers over a four-year period will deepen the
Calumet River and Lake Calumet to 27 feet

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

throughout. More than 4 million dollars has
been expended in clearing the outer ap­
proaches to Calumet River.
In addition to its 41 regular-service over­
seas steamship companies, Chicago is pres­
ently served by 21 trunkline railroads and 20
scheduled airlines. Seven companies offer
direct international service. Chicago is also
the center of the greatest concentration of
truck transportation in the world.
At the port of Detroit, a channel-deepen­
ing project by the Army Corps of Engineers
was virtually completed at the end of 1962
but, unfortunately, a dispute over private
versus public port development has slowed
the addition of new port facilities. Detroit has
42 steamship lines providing regularly sched­
uled service to ports in 61 countries and is
served by 11 railroads and 15 airlines.
Milwaukee is the only “big three” port
whose export traffic declined in 1962. The
drop-off from 1961 is attributed almost en­
tirely to the contraction of industrial scrap
shipments. These fell to about 5 per cent of
total export tonnage from 43 per cent in 1961
as such large buyers as Belgium, Italy and
France began to meet their requirements
from scrap produced in Europe. During
1961 Milwaukee completed a six-year, 14
million dollar port expansion program; it
hopes to gain increased shipment of heavy
commodities such as ferroalloys and lumber
products. The city is served by 33 steamship
lines, three railroads and seven airlines.
F in an cin g p ro b le m s

The United States and Canada together
have invested more than 460 million dollars
in the seaway—the United States invested
130 million dollars—and additional hun­
dreds of millions in improved port facilities.
The initial debt had been scheduled to be
paid off in 50 years, that is, by 2008. To



1963

meet the interest and amortization payments,
ships using the seaway are assessed tolls for
the use of the St. Lawrence River section.
In its four years of operation, the seaway
has failed to produce anticipated revenues.
At the close of 1962, the St. Lawrence Sea­
way Development Corporation (SLSDC)—
the United States seaway authority—reported
a net “deficit”, relative to accumulated inter­
est obligation, of more than 8 million dollars.
The deficit probably will increase further in
1963.
A committee to review the seaway toll
structure, appointed by the U. S. Secretary of
Commerce, is to submit a report to the Secre­
tary of Commerce by July 1, 1964, dealing
with traffic forecasts, a reevaluation of devel­
oping potential markets and producing areas
and other factors which may make overhaul­
ing the rate structure advisable.
A similar Canadian committee is working
independently on the key questions pertain­
ing to the successful operation of the seaway.
Many Canadians are arguing for a reduction
in toll rates. Canada is much more dependent
on the seaway for getting her raw materials
into the world markets than is the United
States with its many alternative means of
transportation.
The administration of the SLSDC regards
refunding its debt as preferable to higher
tolls. As a result, the governments of the two
countries sharing the seaway may later be
asked to refund their seaway debts at lower
interest rates and to extend the maturities of
the principal. If the United States and Canada
should become deadlocked over the toll ques­
tion, Canada could quite easily develop her
own seaway by building an additional lock
in the Great Lakes.
The o u tlo o k

Undoubtedly, the seaway will continue to

9

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

be beset by important problems. It has failed
to attract as much traffic in high-value goods
as had been expected. Bulk shipments of
grain also have not met early expectations.
However, the great variety of products
passing through the seaway and the large

number of countries to which Midwest ex­
ports are moved and from which imports
originate indicate that the seaway will play an
increasingly important role in linking the
Midwest even closer to markets throughout
the world.

The patterns of personal income
T . postwar rise in personal income pro­
vides striking evidence of the continued ex­
pansion of the American economy. It has
made possible the stable growth in consumer
purchases that has played a large role in pre­
venting downturns in activity from develop­
ing into full-scale depressions.
At the present time personal income is at
an annual rate of about 460 billion dollars

W h a t is personal income?
Personal income, estimated monthly by the
Department of Commerce, is the income
received currently by individuals, unincor­
porated businesses and nonprofit institutions
(including pension, trust and welfare funds).
It consists of wages and salaries; other labor
income (mainly employer contributions to
pension, health and welfare funds); profits
of unincorporated businesses and farms;
dividends; interest and rents and transfer
payments from government or business for
which no service is rendered currently
(mainly social insurance benefits, military
pensions and relief). Personal income is the
total of these components less individual con­
10




compared with 189 billion in 1947. Through­
out the period income grew at a compounded
annual rate of almost 6 per cent. Of course,
part of the increase reflected higher prices
and part rising population. After adjustment
for these factors, it appears that per capita
personal income rose almost 2 per cent a year
during the postwar period.
Personal income in the United States dur-

tributions to social insurance funds.
About 95 per cent of personal income is
received in money; the remainder is imputed.
The principal imputations consist of the
rental value of owner-occupied dwellings net
of depreciation, taxes and maintenance; pay­
ments “in kind,” such as employer-furnished
meals, clothing and lodging; food and fuel
raised and consumed on farms and “free”
services furnished by financial institutions.
Neither capital gains nor transfers from one
person to another— such as gifts, insurance
payouts and private pensions— are included
in personal income. The theory is that such
payments increase the total resources of in­
dividuals but not of the whole population.

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

ing 1962 is estimated at $5,024 per full-time
employee. Since many families contain more
than one individual with an income, average
income per family was $7,140. On a per
capita basis, personal income has set a new
record each year since 1954 and averaged
$2,357 in 1962.
New highs also were reached last year in
each of the states of the Seventh Federal
Reserve District. During the 16-year period
1947-62, total personal income more than
doubled in the District. However, the per­
centage gain was somewhat less than in the
nation. Partly, this is because population
growth was slower in most of the District
states.
In the table on page 13 changes in income
and population in this area are compared
with the United States for three segments of
the postwar period. Each time period selected
begins and ends with a year of relatively high
business activity. Also, 1947 was the first
year of fairly “normal” production after
World War II; 1953 marked the high tide of
the Korean upswing, and 1957 saw the cul­
mination of the capital spending boom of the
mid-Fifties.

1963

M id w e st share of personal income
has declined since 1953

Rocky Mountains

In co m e shifts

During the postwar period all states and
regions of the United States have had sub­
stantial and more or less continuous increases
in personal income. But the relative rates of
growth of income have shifted appreciably.
In general, the states of the Southeast,
Southwest, Rocky Mountains and West Coast
have obtained larger shares of total income
while the shares of the rest of the nation, in­
cluding the Midwest, have declined. Two
principal, interrelated factors—the rate of
population growth and the rate at which pri­
marily agricultural states have been indus­
trialized—have been at work leading to ac


celerated gains in personal income.
The basic pattern of the geographical shift
in income outlined above was apparent in
most regions for many years prior to the post­
war period. For example, the Far West, led
by California, accounted for about 9 per cent
of total personal income in 1929. By 1947
this share had increased to 12 per cent and it
rose to more than 14 per cent in 1962. At the
other extreme, the mideastem states, includ­
ing New York and Pennsylvania, accounted
for 32 per cent of total personal income in

11

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

12

1929, 27 per cent in 1947 and less than 25
per cent in 1962.
The share of personal income accounted
for by some regions has not followed a steady
path. For New England, the proportion of the
nation’s income, after declining for many
years, has been quite stable since 1957. At
about the same time, in the Southwest, where
Texas is the largest state, a long rise in the
proportion of income was halted, at least
temporarily.
Increases in total personal income have not
always been accompanied by increases in
average income per capita. In the fastest
growing region, the Far West, per capita in­
come remains considerably higher than the
national average, but the margin is lower now
than in the early postwar period. On the other
hand, per capita income has risen substan­
tially in the Southeast relative to that of the
nation, although it remains well below the
average, as the area has industrialized.
At present, Illinois is the only Seventh
District state with per capita personal incomes
well above the national average. In 1962 it
was $2,830 or 20 per cent above the average.
This is because the Chicago area, like other
large cities, includes a heavy proportion of
relatively high-paid executives, professional
people and skilled factory workers.
In Michigan, incomes were substantially
above the national average from the end of
World War II to the mid-Fifties. Since then,
there has been a relative decline in incomes
largely as a result of changes in the automo­
tive industry in volume of output, degree of
automation and location of new facilities. In
1962 per capita income in Michigan was
$2,353, 2 per cent above the nation.
Iowa, the District state most influenced by
agricultural income, has seen sharp fluctua­
tions in its share of total personal income.
Peaks were reached in the high farm income




years of 1948 and 1954 but per capita in­
come was 7 per cent below the national aver­
age in 1962. In Indiana and Wisconsin the
share of total personal income has been fairly
stable in recent years at a level slightly below
the nation.
The regions shown in the accompanying
charts were selected by the Department of
Commerce for analytical purposes. Illinois,
Indiana, Michigan and Wisconsin are in­
cluded in the “Great Lakes” region along
with Ohio. Iowa is included in the “Plains”
Per capita income
in the Great Lakes area remains
above national average
30

20

per cent
U .S.
-1 0
average

per cent
+10

20

— I---------- '---------- 1---------- -----------1---------- ----------- 1---------- '----------1—

New England

Mideast

Great Lakes

Plains

c=
Southeast

Southwest
U .S . average

Rocky Mountains

Far West

=

1947—
1953—
1957—
1962—

$

1,316
1,788
2,048
2,357

B u sin e ss C o nd itio ns, J u ly

ries and employers’
contributions to pri­
vate pension funds
and similar fringe pay­
1957-62
1947-62
1953-57
1947-53
ments.
By 1947 this
(per
cent
change)
Personal income
proportion
was about
+ 132
+ 26
United States. .
+ 50
+ 23
65 per cent and in re­
+ no
+ 20
+ 44
+ 22
Illin o is.................
cent years about 70
+ 125
+ 20
Indiana...............
+ 15
per cent.
+ 105
+ 20
Iow a...................
+ 38
Within the wage
and salary component
+ 117
M ichiga n..........
+ 17
+ 13
of personal income,
+ 122
+ 24
+ 49
+ 20
W isc o n sin .........
the most significant
Population
change has been in the
+ 29
United S ta te s ..
+ 9
government category,
+ 8
+ 11
including civilians and
+ 22
Illin o is.................
+ 7
+ 6
+ 7
the
armed forces. The
+ 25
Indiana...............
+ 4
proportion of govern­
Iow a...................
+ 4
+ 11
+ 5
+ 1
ment wages and sala­
+ 32
M ichigan..........
+ 6
ries to all wages and
+ 26
W isc o n sin .........
+ 8
+ 8
salaries rose from less
than 6 per cent in
Per capita personal income
1929 to 13 per cent in
+ 15
+ 15
+ 36
United States. .
+ 79
1947 and increased
+ 34
+ 13
+
73
Illin o is.................
+ 14
further to 19 per cent
+ 81
Indiana...............
+
6
in 1962.
Income from pay­
+ 85
+ 31
Iow a...................
ments such as social
+
65
M ichigan..........
+ 7
+ 5
security, welfare and
W isc o n sin .........
+
76
+ 10
unemployment com­
pensation — transfer
paym ents— was less
than 2 per cent of the total in 1929 but rose
region where farm income is relatively larger
to 6 per cent in 1947 and 8 per cent in 1962.
than in the states east of the Mississippi.
The relative rise in wages and salaries and
So u rce s o f p e rs o n a l incom e
transfer payments has been accompanied by
a decline in the share of income accounted
The postwar period has brought changes
for by the net earnings of farms and unin­
in the proportion of personal income derived
corporated, businesses and property income
from various sources. For the most part these
from rents, dividends and interest. But trends
shifts represent a continuance of trends in
in these segments have not been steady. The
evidence since the late Twenties.
proportion accounted for by property income
In 1929 only 60 per cent of all personal
dropped from 22 per cent in 1929 to 11 per
income was accounted for by wages and sala­

1963

M id w e st states gain less ra|pidly
than the nation since the war




13

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

14

cent in 1947 but by 1962 recov­
Factory e arn in gs largest source
ered to 13 per cent.
of personal income in all District
Proprietors’ income for both
states except Iowa
farmers and other unincorporated
proportion of personal income in 1 9 6 2
per cent
businesses was a somewhat higher
proportion of total personal in­
come in 1947 than in 1929. In
fact, farm proprietors’ net income
was at a peak both absolutely and
relatively in 1948 when it was 8
per cent of the total. By 1962 this
proportion had declined to 3 per
cent. Other proprietors’ share
dropped from 11 per cent to 8 per
cent during the same period.
When the decline in proprie­
tors’ income and property income
is considered, it should be re­
membered that capital gains are
not included in these estimates.
Many owners of farms, small busi­
nesses, stocks and real estate have
benefited from substantial in­
wages and salaries compared with about onecreases in wealth resulting from the rise in the
fifth for the nation as a whole.
prices of these assets. Whether or not gains
have been realized in cash, they are not
1963 and beyond
counted as personal income.
Developments thus far in 1963 suggest that
Sources of income in Iowa differ most
personal income will be about 5 per cent
among the District states from the national
higher than last year. After adjustments for
pattern. Only a little over half of Iowa per­
population growth and higher prices, the rise
sonal income comes from wages and salaries.
in per capita “real” income probably will be
Income from farms and unincorporated busi­
about 2 per cent or slightly above the national
nesses is more than twice as large relatively
average for the postwar period. In the Mid­
in Iowa as in the nation.
west the current trend in income is about in
Within the wages and salaries component
line with the national picture.
of personal income, District states have a
What of the future? Available evidence
somewhat smaller proportion accounted for
points to a continuance of the steady up­
by government wages and salaries than the
rest of the nation. Manufacturing wages and
trend in personal income in the years ahead.
In fact, many analysts foresee an improve­
salaries are relatively more important in all
ment in the economic growth rate during the
District states except Iowa than in the nation.
next five or ten years. Increases in activity
In Indiana and Michigan one-third of all
are not likely to be hampered by material or
personal income is obtained from factory




B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

manpower bottlenecks, and vast opportuni­
ties exist in the exploitation of recent scien­
tific and technological advances in the pro­
duction of goods and services.
There seems to be no reason to expect
appreciable changes in the proportion of in­
come received from various sources in 1963
or subsequent years. If the pattern of income
distribution since World War II has contrib­
uted to stability and growth, it can be expected
to continue to do so in the future.

1963

The Seventh District now accounts for a
somewhat smaller proportion of total per­
sonal income than in earlier postwar years
when backlogs of demand for durable goods
were being filled. But such trends are not
irreversible. The advantages of location and
availability of materials and skilled man­
power that enabled the Midwest to grow
more rapidly than the nation in some periods
of the past continue to be vital factors in any
evaluation of prospects for the region.

Defense of the dollar —
a Midwest view
A s p e e c h b y C h a rle s J. S ca n lo n , P re sid e n t, F e d e ra l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ic a g o , b e fo r e the
a n n u a l m e e tin g o f th e In d ia n a B a n k e rs A s s o c ia tio n , F re n c h L ic k , In d ia n a , Ju n e 1 3 , 1 9 6 3 .

X

n 1962, for the fifth year in a row, the United
States had a sizable deficit in its balance of
international payments. So what! Here in the
Midwest, and close to the population center of
the nation, is it of any real concern that last year
Americans spent, invested, loaned and gave
away abroad more than other countries spent,
invested or loaned in the United States?
One’s natural instinct may be to say: “N o,
the problem is far removed from us.” But we
all know that is unrealistic.
In the early postwar years, while the United
States was engaged in a massive foreign aid pro­
gram to help get Europe and Japan back onto
their feet economically, it was reasonable that
we operate with a deficit in our balance of inter­
national payments. This helped to rebuild the
reserves of European countries and, along with
the recovery of their productive potential, ena­
bled the industrial nations of the free world to
move more rapidly toward freer trade and con­
vertible currencies.




But as the United States has continued to run
deficits in its balance o f payments with the rest
of the world, we have, in a sense, acquired a
large “demand” liability.
Deficit cau se s g o ld loss
The amount of the deficit, as measured in our
system of accounting, is the rise in foreign
liquid dollar claims plus our net sales of gold to
foreign countries. (A small offset occurs in the
form of any increase in our holdings of foreign
convertible currencies.) Last year, this deficit
amounted to 2.2 billion dollars and in the past
five years a total o f nearly 16 billion. Of this
amount, nearly 7 billion is reflected in the de­
cline in United States holdings of monetary
gold and about 9 billion in a rise in foreign
liquid dollar claims.
When foreign firms and individuals acquire
more dollars than they desire to hold, the excess
is converted into other currencies. In this pro­
cess the dollars gravitate to foreign central

15

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

banks and treasuries which can use the dollars
to purchase gold from the U. S. Treasury if they
desire to do so. As their holdings of dollars rise,
foreign central banks tend to convert more of
them into gold. Also, at any time the confidence
in the future value of the dollar is shaken, the
demand for gold rises.
In each of the past two years the United
States gold stock declined by roughly 1 billion
dollars. Our total monetary gold stock is now
somewhat less than 16 billion dollars. Of this
amount, roughly 12 billion is held as reserve
for the deposit and note liabilities of the Federal
Reserve Banks.

It may be recalled that in October 1960 the
dollar was sold heavily and there was a surge
of gold buying on the London market at prices
far above the United States price of approxi­
mately $35 an ounce. This brought the problem
into clear focus. Greater effort had to be di­
rected toward resolving the balance of payments
deficit.
Before discussing the actions that have been
taken to help deal with this problem, it will be
helpful to review briefly the structure o f the
U nited States in tern ation al p aym ents and
receipts.

This reserve requirement can be suspended
by action of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, or reduced or elim­
inated by action of the Congress. One or more
of these actions presumably would be taken, if
needed. But this would not provide any lasting
solution for the payments deficit. At best, it
would provide additional time to bring our cur­
rent international transactions into balance.

The United States exports substantially more
goods than it buys abroad. The net balance in
our favor on commercial merchandise trade in
1962 was about 2 billion dollars— with exports
of 18.3 billion and imports o f 16.2 billion. In
addition, we had 2.3 billion of Governmentfinanced merchandise exports for a total balance
on trade of about 4.4 billion dollars.
We also had a net balance in our favor in
another broad category of transactions which
are lumped together under the general heading,
services. This includes, for example, shipping,
insurance, tourist expenditures, and the like.
Included also are two items which merit specific
mention. One is the income from private foreign
investments— 3.7 billion dollars. The other is
the outgo in the form of military expenditures
abroad— about 3 billion dollars.
Over-all, “services” showed a small net
balance in favor of the United States. On trade
and services combined, then, the United States
had a net balance o f about 4.8 billion dollars.
Another important group of transactions in­
cludes the grants and capital flows.
Government grants and loans provided a net
capital outflow of about 3 billion dollars.
Private capital transactions also resulted in a
net outflow o f about 3 billion dollars, of which
1.4 billion was net direct private investment
abroad, largely in industrial and commercial
facilities. A somewhat smaller amount was for
long-term portfolio investment. Included in this

The necessity for a shift in posture with
respect to our balance of payments began to be
recognized in 1959. In 1958, after a small sur­
plus in 1957— attributable largely to the surge
in exports as a result o f the Suez crisis— the
United States ran a deficit of 3.5 billion dollars
in its international payments. Our gold reserves
declined more than 2 billion dollars. In 1959
and 1960 the deficits were somewhat larger than
in 1958 but the outflow of gold was smaller.

16

By the latter part of 1959 it was clear that
additional steps were required to curb the deficit
in our international payments and stem the
build-up of foreign liquid dollar claims. The
postwar shortage of dollars as a reserve currency
had been largely filled, at least for the time
being. European currencies were now convert­
ible and, as confidence in these currencies rose,
the dollar weakened in some exchange markets.
Occasionally the dollar declined to levels requir­
ing intervention by foreign central banks in
order to hold their currencies within the range
prescribed by the International Monetary Fund.




Structure o f th e b a la n c e o f p a y m e n ts

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

is the purchase by Americans of bond issues
floated by foreign firms and governments in
the United States capital markets as well as
purchase o f stocks and bonds on foreign ex­
changes and the making of long-term loans
abroad. (It may be of interest to note that the
inflow of foreign long-term capital for invest­
ment in this country totaled about 1 billion
dollars and the outflow of dollars for remit­
tances and pensions abroad was on the order of
900 m illion.)
Over-all, the grants and capital category
accounted for a net outflow of nearly 6 billion
dollars.
In addition, there was a net outflow of nearly
a billion dollars in other transactions, about
which very little is known.
The over-all deficit, therefore, as noted at the
beginning of my remarks, was about 2.2 billion
dollars.
Furthermore, and this is important, in the
absence of some special transactions, including
prepayment of debt by France, Sweden and
Italy, borrowing of foreign currencies against
non-negotiable bonds by the U. S. Treasury,
Germany’s allocation of funds for military
purchases in the United States, and United
States subscriptions to international financial
institutions, the deficit in the United States
balance of international payments would have
been around 3.7 billion dollars, or somewhat
greater than in 1961.
Although we had a sizable surplus on trade
and sizable deficits on grants, capital and un­
recorded transactions, it is not possible to pin­
point the specific sources or causes of the bal­
ance of payments deficit. Both the receipts and
the payments include a multitude of transactions
and the deficit is the net result of all trans­
actions, not just one or a few in isolation.
B a la n c in g th e account
The export surplus on goods and services has
not been great enough to cover the net outflow
of private capital and Government expenditures
on foreign military and economic aid programs.
But this does not lead to the conclusion that




1963

reducing our foreign military expenditures by,
say, a billion dollars would reduce our deficit by
the same amount. Presumably most of the
dollars acquired abroad under such programs
are used to pay for United States exports. There­
fore, our surplus on exports would be expected
to decline, although probably by less than a
billion dollars, hence, leaving some net improve­
ment in the payments balance.
Successive administrations and congresses
have reviewed our foreign military and aid ex­
penditures and concluded that for the present
at least these programs are necessary. Individ­
uals may agree or disagree with these findings.
But in the absence of a larger cut-back in U. S.
Government spending abroad, it has been con­
cluded that balance should be achieved, if pos­
sible, by boosting exports.
Another possibility is to restrict the freedom
of Americans to invest and travel abroad or the
freedom of other countries to borrow from our
banks or issue securities for sale in our capital
markets. But private investment abroad in­
creases future earnings of foreign exchange
and any move to provide arbitrary restrictions
on capital flows would be inconsistent with the
role o f the United States dollar as a key reserve
currency and with our basic international ob­
jective of encouraging relatively free trade.
Such action by us probably would cause some
foreign holders of dollar assets to lose confi­
dence in the dollar as a freely convertible re­
serve currency with resulting increase in the
outflow o f gold. Likewise, it probably would
cause some Americans to place more funds
abroad, anticipating that such restrictions on
transfers of capital might be tightened in the
future.
Our Government’s policy, therefore, includes
the promotion of exports by United States
business, efforts to get restrictions against im­
ports of American goods removed abroad, and
encouragement of further development and
freeing-up of capital markets outside the United
States. These moves are consistent with our
basic international economic policy. But since

17

Federal Reserve Ba nk o f Chicago

they require time to become effective, even if
implemented successfully, a number of interim
measures have been taken to help safeguard the
dollar internationally while these basic shifts
are accomplished.
Beginning in 1959 foreign aid provided
through the Development Loan Fund was
“tied”, that is, the dollars had to be spent on
goods purchased in the United States. In the
summer of the same year the Secretary of
the Treasury and Undersecretary of State (for
Economic Affairs) visited Europe and urged
such countries as Germany, France and Italy
to assume part of the cost of extending aid to
underdeveloped areas and to step-up their pro­
curement of military hardware from the United
States. United States officials have also urged
countries that restrict access to their capital
markets by foreign borrowers, especially those
countries that have acquired large reserves of
foreign exchange, to remove such restrictions.
Negotiations to reduce restrictions against im­
ports of American goods are being continued.
Meanwhile, domestic policies have been
shaped to help moderate the pressures on the
dollar. The Federal Reserve System has adapted
its monetary policies in response to the pay­
ments deficit. While providing ample reserves to
commercial banks to encourage and support
expansion in domestic business activity, short­
term interest rates have been supported so as
to minimize large flows of funds abroad in
search of higher interest rates.
Undoubtedly, some of the liquidity provided
to encourage domestic economic expansion has
spilled abroad and worsened our payments sit­
uation. Also, an even easier monetary policy
might have provided some additional stimulus
to domestic business, although possibly at the
cost of unsound speculative activity in securi­
ties and real estate markets. The problem has
been to achieve proper balance.

18

That credit has been, and is, readily available
is seen in the near-record rise— 19 billion dol­
lars— in the total bank credit last year and the
slow downward drift of interest rates on mort­




gages and some other long-term credits.
Short-term interest rates, as indicated by
yields on 90-day Treasury bills, have been held
within the relatively narrow range of about 2.6
to 3 per cent (slightly higher in recent w eeks).
This was accomplished by a large amount of
Treasury borrowing in the short end of the
market, Federal Reserve open market purchases
of securities of intermediate and long maturities,
reduction of reserve requirements applicable to
member bank deposits, raising the maximum
permissible interest rates on time deposits and
suspension for three years o f the interest rate
ceiling on time deposits of foreign official insti­
tutions. These actions helped to limit short-term
flows of funds abroad.
But with large foreign holdings of liquid
dollar claims, it is possible for the dollar to
come under severe pressure at any time and for
large and erratic demands for gold to develop.
Sta b iliz in g th e e x c h a n g e m a rk e t
The U. S. Treasury had begun limited opera­
tions in foreign exchange in March 1961, fol­
lowing the flight from sterling after revaluation
of the German Mark and Dutch Guilder.
In February 1962 the Open Market Com­
mittee of the Federal Reserve System authorized
transactions in foreign currencies, utilizing re­
sources of the Federal Reserve System. These
operations are undertaken to prevent disorderly
movements in the rates at which the dollar is
traded for other currencies and to cushion spec­
ulative flows of volatile capital which might
cause gold losses that would tend to undermine
confidence in the dollar.
The foreign currencies operations of the
Treasury and the Federal Reserve are closely
coordinated. All the transactions are conducted
by the New York Reserve Bank as agent for
the Treasury and the Open Market Committee
of the Federal Reserve System.
One difficulty in initiating the operations was
the absence of any significant inventory of
foreign currencies, since the United States, un­
like most other countries, had held its reserves
entirely in gold. Initially, the Federal Reserve

B u sin e ss C o n d itio n s, J u ly

purchased small amounts of some currencies
from the Stabilization Fund of the Treasury and
opened, or reactivated, accounts with the foreign
central banks responsible for these currencies.
Later the System entered into swap arrange­
ments with foreign central banks and the Bank
for International Settlements. Under these ar­
rangements a central bank agrees to exchange
on request its own currency for the currency of
another country up to some predetermined
amount over a specified period of time.
The general outline of such arrangements
may be described as follows, although the de­
tails of individual agreements vary somewhat.
1. A swap constitutes a reciprocal “line of
credit” under which a central bank agrees to
exchange on request its own currency for the
currency of the other party up to a maximum
amount over a limited period of time, such as
three months or six months.
2. If such a standby swap between the
Federal Reserve and the Bank of England, for
example, were to be drawn upon by the Federal
Reserve, the Federal Reserve would credit the
dollar account of the Bank of England with
50 million dollars at a rate of, say, $2.80 to the
pound while obtaining in exchange a credit on
the books of the Bank of England of about 18
million pounds. Both parties would agree to
reverse the transaction on a specified date, say,
within three months, at the same rate of ex­
change, thus providing each with forward cover
against the remote risk of a devaluation of either
currency.
3. The foreign currency obtained by each
party as a result of such cross credits to each
other’s accounts would, unless disbursed in ex­
change operations, be invested in a time deposit
or other investment instrument, earning an
identical rate of interest of, say, 2 per cent and
subject to call on two days’ notice.
4. After consultation with the other, each
party would be free to draw upon the foreign
currency acquired under the swap to conduct
spot transactions or meet forward exchange
obligations.




1963

5.
Swap arrangements are renewable upon
agreement of both parties.
By the end of last year swap arrangements
had been entered into with the central banks of
eight major European countries, with the Bank
for International Settlements in Basle, Switzer­
land, and with the Bank of Canada, for a total
of 900 million dollars. Since then, the swap net­
work has been further enlarged to cover an
additional European central bank and a total
amount of 1,500 million dollars.
At present, actual use of the reciprocal credit
lines either by the Federal Reserve or the other
countries amounts to only a minor fraction of
the total facilities available. The Federal Re­
serve’s net debtor position was 61 million dollars
as of the end of April.
It would be erroneous, therefore, to assume
that the United States has been building up a
staggering debt position vis-a-vis the foreign
central banks. But it has established a network
o f arrangements which enable the various
countries to utilize currencies of other countries
on a moment’s notice to support existing official
rates of exchange.
In the meantime the Treasury has widened
the scope of its foreign exchange operations
through a series of short- and medium-term
borrowings. These began before the end of
1962, but did not assume substantial dimensions
until January of this year. During that month
over 300 million dollars in special nonmarketable Treasury securities were sold to Germany,
Switzerland, Canada and Italy. The securities
are redeemable in the currencies of the respec­
tive countries. Interest rates have been around
3 per cent and maturities between one and two
years.
By June 1 the Treasury had borrowed some­
thing over 600 million dollars in this way. These
Treasury issues provide foreign countries with
an advantageous investment for balance-ofpayments surpluses which might otherwise raise
their dollar reserves above traditional or legal
limits and hence be sold to the U. S. Treasury
for gold.

19

Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

20

The funds acquired through these new ar­
rangements have been used in System and
Treasury operations to minimize disturbing
fluctuations in both spot and forward exchange
markets and to reduce the flow o f dollars into
foreign official reserves. By mopping up tempo­
rary pools of dollars, large short-term drains on
the gold stock o f the United States are mini­
mized— drains which might initiate large specu­
lative runs on the dollar.
Another facet of the current international
monetary arrangements is the almost continuous
consultation that takes place in the regular meet­
ings of the Bank for International Settlements
and the Organization for Economic Coopera­
tion and Development. There are contacts at
both the technical and official levels. These as­
sure that each country is aware of possible re­
percussions of any actions it may take.
One result of this type o f international co­
operation is the development of a “gold pool,”
which came into being early in 1961. Managed
by the Bank of England, it operates in the
London gold market, absorbing or releasing
gold when the price tends to fall below or rise
above certain levels. The participating central
banks share in these transactions on a pro rata
basis. In dampening speculation in gold, the
“pool” hopefully serves as a shock absorber
and helps to stabilize currencies. If wide fluc­
tuations in gold prices can be prevented, the
prestige of convertible currencies is enhanced.
Supporting these first lines of defense of the
convertible international currencies are the
borrowing arrangements provided for member
countries of the International Monetary Fund.
These arrangements were supplemented last fall
by a special agreement between 10 major indus­
trial countries which made available to the fund
up to 6 billion dollars of additional reserves in
case of need. The United States share in these
standby facilities amounts to 2 billion dollars.
If the dollar were to come under serious and
sustained pressure, threatening the entire inter­
national monetary system, the United States
could draw on a substantial amount of convertible currency reserves from this source as well.




Conclusion
It must be emphasized that— valuable though
they may be, especially in emergencies— none of
the dollar defense arrangements discussed here
go to the root of the problem of how to bring
our foreign receipts and payments into balance.
N o Federal Reserve or Treasury official con­
cerned with these defensive arrangements has
any illusions on this point. These arrangements
are no substitute for actions to correct basic
imbalances in the international payments o f the
various countries. But it is equally recognized
that such defenses against speculation and other
short-term flows can, and do, provide a margin
of time during which appropriate policy solu­
tions can be developed and carried out in an
orderly manner.
In the final analysis, we must be sufficiently
competitive in world markets so that we earn
abroad enough to finance our foreign expendi­
tures, investments and grants. Our goods and
services must compete effectively with those
offered by foreign producers— in our domestic
market, in the home markets o f producers
abroad and in third countries where the prod­
ucts of United States and foreign firms meet on
“neutral” ground. This requires that our fac­
tories, farms, transportation and financing be
highly efficient. Wage and price policies are
especially important. Featherbedding, whether
by labor, management, farmers, government
workers, school teachers or others, must be
tossed overboard. Any benefits of higher wages
or prices are temporary and illusory if the result
is lost markets, reduced profits or rising unem­
ployment. Our goal must be efficient as well as
full use o f resources. Herein lies the long-run
answer to the United States balance of inter­
national payments as well as many other eco­
nomic problems. Monetary and fiscal policies
can facilitate the making of the necessary ad­
justments but alone they cannot solve the prob­
lem. This we, as responsible citizens, must bear
in mind as we participate in the making of
domestic monetary, fiscal, wage and price pol­
icies, in both the private and public sectors.