View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
1968 January

Contents
Pound sterling devalued

2

Seventh District developments

5

Fewer farmers,
and the average age rising

9

Recent time deposit growth

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Pound sterling devalued
M any small countries follow Britain’s lead
J 3 rita in announced November 18 that the
exchange rate of the pound sterling was being
reduced from $2.80 to $2.40.
The announcement had immediate impact
throughout the world. Within hours, govern­
ments of 13 countries announced reduction
in the exchange rates of their currencies rela­
tive to the U. S. dollar. Eleven other countries
announced reductions soon after.
In the days following, repercussions were
felt in markets for foreign exchange and gold
as individuals, businesses, and governments
responded to the new conditions. Interna­
tional markets for goods and commodities
will doubtlessly be adjusting for months as
patterns of trade gradually respond to the new
structures of exchange rates and associated
shifts in competitive positions of suppliers.
Directly or indirectly, the lives of millions of
people throughout the world will be affected
by the devaluation of the pound.
W h y B ritain d e v a lu e d

The fundamental reason for the British
action was a persistent balance of payments
deficit that had plagued the country for years.
The devaluation came as the most dramatic
in a long series of moves undertaken to
balance its international expenditures and
receipts.1
Previous measures, especially those last
year, had been aimed essentially at limiting
the growth of domestic demand for goods and

2

T or a summary description of previous measures
undertaken by the British government, see Business
Conditions, October 1966.




services. This had been done both to dampen
demand for imported goods and to free up
more domestically produced goods for export.
It was also expected that such measures
would help relax some of the structural rigid­
ities of the British economy and arrest the
wage-price spiral that had been undermining
the competitiveness of British goods in world
markets.
In the first months of 1967, the measures
seemed to produce the desired results. Un­
employment rose to 550,000—the highest
level in 20 years—and industrial production
and growth in consumer spending declined.
There seemed reason to believe that Britain
could not only balance her accounts but,
hopefully, also repay international credits
obtained over the previous two years.
But the improvement was short-lived.
Partly because of such external developments
as the crisis in the Middle East and the de­
cline in economic activity in a number of
other countries, which weakened demand for
British exports, and partly because of such
continued internal difficulties as strikes in
the shipping docks, a large deficit in British
trade accounts reappeared, causing renewed
concern that the pound might not be viable
at the current rate of exchange. This caused
speculation against the pound—that is, the
taking of positions by traders, investors, and
speculators to minimize losses or maximize
gains if the value of the pound were reduced.
Faced with rapidly diminishing international
reserves, the government chose to devalue
the pound as a means of stemming the specu-

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

lative outflow of funds in the short run and
balancing trade accounts in the long run.
W h a t is d e v a lu a tio n ?

The current international monetary system
is largely an outgrowth of the 1944 Bretton
Woods Conference, which laid the ground­
work for the establishment of the Interna­
tional Monetary Fund. Member countries of
the fund have defined the values of their cur­
rencies in terms of the U. S. dollar and are
expected to adopt domestic policies that will
allow them to keep the relative values fixed.
Only if a country suffers from a fundamental
imbalance in its international accounts can
it apply to the International Monetary Fund
for permission to change the value of its
currency relative to the dollar—to devalue.2
Devaluation, in effect, reduces the number
of dollars or other dollar-defined currencies
that can be bought with a given amount of do­
mestic currency. Viewed from the foreign
side, it increases the amount of domestic cur­
rency that can be bought with dollars or other
foreign currencies. It has no direct effect on
the domestic value of the currency as such.
The impact on domestic prices is indirect,
arising mainly from the effects of the devalua­
tion on imported goods and services.
H ow d o e s d e v a lu a tio n w o rk ?

The primary impact of currency devalua­
tions is on the prices of goods and services
exchanged between the devaluing country
and its trading partners. It reduces the prices
of domestically produced goods and services
to foreigners and increases the prices of for­
eign goods and services to residents of the
devaluing country.
On the morning after devaluation of the
T he charter provides that a member nation can
change the par value of its currency up to 10 per­
cent without seeking the fund’s approval.



pound, for example, an American in London
would have found he could buy a sweater
for which he paid, say £ 10 ($28.00) the
day before 14.3 percent cheaper—for only
$24.00 ( £ 10). But, an Englishman in
Chicago would have found that the steak for
which he paid, say, $2.80 ( £ 1) the day be­
fore now cost him 16.7 percent more— 1
pound, 3 shillings, and 24 pence ($2.80).
Similar price changes will be made in goods
and services the British import and export,
but there are several reasons why the prices
of internationally traded goods will show
smaller changes than these examples.
For one thing, retail prices of British goods
sold abroad contain, in addition to the cost of
the goods in Britain, such other charges as
transportation, insurance, duties, and profits
of the wholesalers and retailers abroad—all
costs largely unaffected by the devaluation of
the pound. Thus, a 14.3 percent reduction in
the dollar-price of British goods in Britain
would normally lead to a much smaller reduc­
tion in the price of those goods to customers
abroad, possibly only 6 to 7 percent.
For another, many goods produced in Bri­
tain contain raw materials imported from
abroad. As the prices of these materials to
British importers are increased by the devalu­
ation, British producers will have to increase
the pound-prices of the products.
For still another, in some cases, producers
may increase the pound-prices of their goods
to the full extent of the devaluation, par­
ticularly if they think the demand for their
goods abroad completely exhausts their
ability to supply it.
And finally, increases in the prices of
imported goods in Britain may create de­
mands for wage and salary increases that, if
granted, could increase the costs of produc­
tion and be reflected in higher prices.
While the final effect of the devaluation on

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

the price structure of traded goods is hard to
predict at this point, British prices are ex­
pected to change enough to stimulate exports
and retard imports—thus helping the country
balance its international accounts.
But there is an important assumption
underlying the expectation of such a favor­
able outcome. It is essential that the de­
crease in British prices to foreigners, and the
increase in foreign prices to Britons, does not
only increase foreign demand for British
goods (and decrease British demand for for­
eign goods) but also that the shift will be
sufficient in both cases to offset the initially
unfavorable impact of devaluation on the
country’s total international earnings and
expenditures.
The devaluation-induced reduction in the
dollar-prices of British exports, and increase
in the pound-prices of imports, reduce Bri­
tain’s total receipts in dollars on a given vol­
ume of trade by the same percentage as the
devaluation—and increase its total expendi­
tures in pounds by approximately the same
percentage. Thus, unless exports increase or
imports decrease at least as much as the
percentage change in international prices,
Britain’s trade balance would actually be
worsened by devaluation. The government
can aid such a development by rechanneling
productive resources into export industries
to accommodate increased demand abroad
and by restricting domestic demand to set the
stage for decreases in imports.
The e ffe ct on Britain

4

Devaluation in itself will not solve the
economic problems that have plagued Britain
for years. It can help restore the balance in
Britain’s international accounts and it can
help restructure the British economy so that
in the long run it can meet the requirements
placed on it by changing patterns of world




trade. But the fundamental adjustments still
have to be made internally. The economic
forces unleashed by devaluation will have to
be channeled toward such basic restructuring.
Otherwise, the initial advantage gained by
devaluation will be lost.
The British government, in announcing
the devaluation, made it clear that it intends
to do whatever is necessary to make sure that
the devaluation not only re-establishes bal­
ance in the country’s international accounts
but that it also allows the country to earn
enough surplus to repay the foreign credits
it received during months preceding the
devaluation. Additional restrictions have al­
ready been announced:
• To reduce domestic demand still further,
the government increased downpayment
requirements on instalment buying and
shortened the maximum repayment period.
It also proposed an increase in the tax on
corporate income from 40 to 42.5 percent.
• To ensure that credit expansion does not
provide support for inflationary pressures,
the government asked British banks to
restrict their lending, and the Bank of
England increased the discount rate from
6.5 percent to 8 percent.
• To reduce the demands on the economy
arising from government spending, the
Chancellor of the Exchequer proposed a
£ 400 million reduction in government
expenditures.
The period ahead will doubtlessly mean an
interruption in the rise in the standard of
living for Britons. As the rise in import prices
affects the cost of living, increases in wages
and salaries will have to be held back to pre­
vent cost-push inflation from boosting the
prices of export products. The general level
of demand will have to be held in check to
guard against demand-pull inflation. Employ­
ment policies will have to be aimed at weed-

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

ing out structural rigidities that have ham­
pered Britain’s progress, and that could mean
unemployment would have to remain uncom­
fortably high.
The response of the British people and the
British economy to current policies will
largely determine whether the once greatest
economic power in the world will successfully
resolve its balance of payments problem and
continue to play an important role in inter­
national trade and finance.
The e ffe c t on th e U. S.

Devaluation of currencies abroad has af­
fected the United States in two ways—by
changing its competitive position in world
trade and by influencing the position of the
dollar in world finance. As dollar-prices of
imports from the United States increase in
countries that devalued their currencies, U. S.
exports of goods to those areas can be ex­
pected to taper off. Also as dollar-prices of
U. S. imports from devaluing countries drop,

imports of goods from those areas can be ex­
pected to increase. The interplay of these
two forces—one tending to decrease U. S.
exports, the other tending to increase U. S.
imports—will act to reduce the U. S. surplus
in international trade accounts. But the im­
pact will probably be small. Only about 11
percent of U. S. exports and 13 percent of
U. S. imports will be affected—and these by
relatively small price changes.
With the devaluation of the pound, addi­
tional attention is focused on the position of
the dollar in its role as a reserve currency.
The Secretary of the Treasury has observed
that the dollar now stands in “the front line”
against possible future speculation. To main­
tain confidence in the dollar as a viable re­
serve currency and thereby enable it to con­
tinue serving effectively in helping finance
a growing volume of the world’s trade and
investment, the United States must intensify
efforts to reduce the outflow of dollars—to
balance its own international accounts.

Seventh District developments
^3usiness in the Seventh Federal Reserve
District was in a strong upswing at year-end.
With the settlement of labor disputes in im­
portant Midwest industries, manufacturing
production rose sharply and employment was
on the rise. Preliminary reports indicate that
the sluggishness in retail sales earlier in 1967
had been overcome. Orders for steel had
strengthened, and moderate increases in
orders for machinery, equipment, and com­
ponents were reported. Construction con­
tracts, at record levels in the second and third



quarters, continued strong in the fourth.
While earlier predictions of a vigorous rise in
business activity in the fall failed to mate­
rialize, the rise underway at year-end gives
indication of continuing and even strengthen­
ing further in the early months of 1968.
Em ploym ent rising

Total nonfarm employment in states of the
Seventh District— Illinois, Indiana, Iowa,
Michigan, and Wisconsin—has risen every
year since 1961, but the increase has not kept

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

pace with the growth of employment na­
tionally. While the district’s average annual
rate of growth was 3 percent between 1961
and 1967, the average rise nationwide was a
little higher—3.3 percent. Indiana and Iowa
led the advance in the district, and Wisconsin
matched the U. S. average gain. The district’s
slower rate of increase is partly explained by
its population growing slower than the nation.
The smaller district gain in nonfarm
employment also reflected a leveling off
in Midwest manufacturing employment be­
tween 1966 and 1967. Although year-end
employment in district manufacturing was
apparently about the same as at the end of
1966, average monthly employment in manu­
facturing through the third quarter of 1967
was below the 1966 average in all district

Growth in District
manufacturing employment slows
m illio n employees

m illio n employees

a ve ra g e s

I960

1961

1962

* F i r s t nine months.




1963

1964

1965

1966

1967*

states except Iowa. Production in many areas
was curtailed by the generally slow growth of
the economy in the first half of 1967, un­
usually severe weather last winter, and strikes
in a number of manufacturing industries in
the summer and fall. But with these disrup­
tive influences largely out of the way, expan­
sion was widespread at year-end.
P e rso n a l incom e la g s

Personal income in the first half of the year
also rose less in the district than the nation.
Between the fourth quarter of 1966 and the
second quarter of 1967, the rise for the dis­
trict was less than 1 percent, compared with
1.3 percent for the nation. Preliminary data
for the third quarter indicate a continuation
of this difference—personal income for the
district rising 4.3 percent over the same
period a year before, compared with 6.5 per­
cent for the nation. Seventh District states,
which have large proportions of personal
income derived from manufacturing, were
affected more than other states.
Personal income actually declined between
the first and second quarters in Indiana, Illi­
nois, and Wisconsin. But preliminary infor­
mation indicates that solid gains were made
between the second and third quarters in all
states of the district but Iowa, where the
change was negligible.
In Indiana, a production slowdown in the
electronic industry and a rash of strikes in
the trucking, electrical machinery, and furni­
ture industries accounted for much of the
decline between the first and second quarters.
In Wisconsin, a decline in the average work­
week and in weekly earnings, offset the in­
crease associated with rising employment.
And in Illinois, the trucking strike, which
severely curtailed production in some indus­
tries, was largely responsible for a small (less
than 1-percent) decline. A gain in Michigan

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

was due largely to increases in automobile
production schedules and a spring surge in
nonmanufacturing, especially retailing.
Although district growth in personal in­
come lagged in the first half of 1967, the
increase in per capita income since 1961 has
exceeded that for the nation. Illinois, with a
35-percent increase, almost matched the na­
tional advance of 36 percent over this period.
All other district states surpassed the U. S.
increase. Iowa’s growth in per capita income
was fastest—more than 50 percent.
Production slo w d o w n e a r ly in 1 9 6 7

Manufacturing activity in Chicago slipped
in 1967. Buffeted by a decline in demand, a
severe winter, and strikes, manufacturing in
the district’s largest metropolitan area drop­
ped slightly more than 5 percent from the
second half of 1966 to the first half of 1967.
However, measured by an index based on the
electric power used in various industries, two-

Recent rise in electric power
consumption indicates recovery
from first-half slowdown
percent, 1957-59=100




thirds of the decline had been recovered by
the third quarter, and preliminary reports
indicate further recovery to year-end.
A first-half decline in manufacturing in
Detroit was moderated in June by a spurt in
automobile production. As a result, manu­
facturing activity in the district’s second
largest metropolitan area declined less than
2 percent in the first half. With output in
automobile and related plants limited first by
downtime for model changeovers and then by
work stoppages, the performance of Detroit
manufacturing continued sluggish into the
second half but rose sharply at year-end.
Sp e n d in g g a in s m o d e ra te

Retail sales for the district in 1966 ran
about 8 percent above levels for the year
before—slightly more than the year-to-year
increase for the nation. But the rate of in­
crease slackened in the first half of 1967,
and retail sales in the district slipped below
year-ago levels in three of the first six months.
Sales weakened more for the district than for
the nation, reflecting the severe weather in
the spring. While gains in retail sales in the
Midwest have largely paralleled those of the
nation since midyear, they are still small com­
pared with the rise in personal income.
Bank debits, a measure of local spending,
showed less evidence of a district decline in
the first half and sluggishness in the second
than did other measures. While district debits
dipped in January, the 1966 level was ex­
ceeded by April and a new high was set in
August. Debits in district centers tend to
fluctuate more widely than those for the na­
tion, but short-term changes have been
similar for the district and the nation.
Co nstructio n stro n g

Construction contracts were at record
highs in the second and third quarters. Con-

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

tract awards for residential, commercial, and
public construction have been large, espe­
cially for apartment buildings.
Rates on new mortgages have increased to
the highs seen in the fall of 1966—6.5 to 7
percent. Money remains available, with sav­
ings inflows to savings and loan associations
continuing large. With the associations having
heavy mortgage commitments to builders,

Consumer prices in Chicago
accelerate, while increases
in Detroit are moderate
percent, 1957-59*100

District retail sales slipped
below year-ago levels in three
of the first six months
percent change from year-ago month

expansion of residential construction is likely
to continue.
Price p re ssu re s continue

8




Price pressures were stronger in Chicago
than in the United States as a whole. The
consumer price index showed only moderate
increases in Chicago in the first quarter as
prices of food and housing remained stable,
tending to restrain the overall rise. But the
index rose 2.5 percent between April and
September—or at an annual rate close to
6 percent. The increase reflected sharp rises
in nearly all categories of consumer goods
and services—food, housing, transportation,
and health care.
The consumer price index for Detroit has
shown more moderate increases. Although

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

there was a sharp rise between February and
April, the increase through September was
less rapid than for the nation.
N e a r-te rm p ro sp ects

Business in the district is expected to con­
tinue improving. Some production increases
will accrue from efforts to regain time lost to
strikes, and if the predicted general ebullience
of the U. S. economy materializes in the first
half of 1968, the picture in the Midwest will
be even better.
State and local spending appears to be

rising in the district undeterred by the costs
of financing. Steel orders are improving,
and inventories of steel in the hands of manu­
facturers, now generally low, will probably
increase as manufacturing activity gains mo­
mentum and, in view of a possible strike in
the fall, companies undertake protective in­
ventory buildups. Although production of
defense materials is not generally important
in this district, increased demand for other
products stimulated by continued defense
spending will add strength to measures of
district activity.

Fewer farmers,
and their average age rising
T h e average age of farmers is rising. This
has paused some concern for the future of
agriculture. But the trend, which is of long
standing, has had no significant adverse ef­
fects thus far. Nor are there any in the offing,
even though the trend is almost certain to
continue for many years to come.
The average age of the nation’s farmers in
1964, the year of the most recent Census of
Agriculture, was 49. That was an increase of
4 years in the average age since 1950.
Workers in manufacturing average 39 years
— 10 years less than farm operators. Nearly
two-fifths of the farmers in the Seventh Fedaral Reserve District are over age 55. This
is up from one-third in 1950.
The tendency for older groups to account
for an increasing proportion of farmers
reflects the rapidly rising productivity of
American agriculture and the accompanying




decline in the number of farmers needed to
supply the nation with farm commodities. As
total requirements increase or decrease, in
any occupational group, it is the younger
elements that make most of the adjustment.
In agriculture, production per manhour has
increased rapidly as farmers have found new
technologies (such as larger machines, im­
proved seeds and fertilizers, new chemicals,
and even computers) profitable and put them
increasingly to use. As a result, the number
of people participating directly in the produc­
tion of agricultural commodities has declined
for more than 30 years. And since new
technology is most effective on fairly large
farms, the number of farms—and, therefore,
farmers—has declined.
The efficiencies obtained through enlarging
farm size are only one aspect of the migration
from farms to urban centers and the increased

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

average age of farmers. Equally important
are the other, often more attractive, oppor­
tunities available to young workers in other
employment. As young men growing up on
farms survey the alternatives open to them,
more and more have been attracted to other
work. Many that started farming have lacked
the necessary capital or management skill to
expand their operations into efficient sizes
and, therefore, have seen little prospect for
satisfactory incomes as farmers. With em­
ployment available in urban areas, many have
turned to nonfarming employment.
Older workers, on the other hand, are more
likely to be established in their occupation
and are generally more reluctant, or less able,
to shift to other types of work. This is espe­
cially important in farming, which requires
large amounts of capital that typically must
be provided primarily by the farmer. Older
established farmers are in a strong position to
compete for land and resources. Thus, the
average age rises as fewer young men become
farmers and older men remain.

Young farm ers decline
as proportion of total . . .
percent change in number




proportion of

Many observers have suggested that, if this
trend continues, there will not be enough
farmers to provide adequate supplies of farm
commodities. But such concern does not
seem warranted. Although the number of
young men entering agriculture has declined,
those taking it up appear to be operating gen­
erally larger and more efficient farms than
older farmers and to be expanding their
operations faster.
In the Seventh Federal Reserve District,
the number of farmers under age 34 declined
more than 21 percent between 1959 and
1964. The decline, however, was confined to
those operators of relatively small farms. The
number of farmers in that age group operat­
ing farms with product sales of $20,000 or
more increased nearly 26 percent. Moreover,
a recent study by the Department of Agricul­
ture states, “One-third of the new entrants
into the $10,000 or over gross sales class
during recent years were under 36 years of
age.” Yet, in the five states of the Seventh
District, this age group accounted for only
about 15 percent of all operators
in 1964.
W ith m odern technology,
farmers have greatly increased
their production efficiency by
merging small farms into larger
ones. Although the number of
farms in the Seventh District de­
clined about 13 percent between
1959 and 1964, farms with prod­
uct sales totaling $20,00 or more
increased about 53 percent. Sim­
ilarly, the number of farms of
more than 260 acres rose about
12 percent between census years,
while those with fewer than 260
acres declined about 19 percent.
As indicated above, younger
farmers, although a small and de­

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

dining proportion of all farmers, played an
important role in these shifts.
Although the amount of resources devoted
to agriculture has remained fairly stable over
the past several years, production has risen
nearly 16 percent since 1959. Production per
acre in the Corn Belt has increased about 26
percent since then, and output per manhour
has increased about 64 percent.
The increases in production were prob­
ably even greater on farms making the
greatest investment in new technology. And
younger operators may well have adopted
improved methods faster than older farmers,
especially young farmers with access to addi­
tional capital. Studies of the characteristics
of farmers readly adopting new technology
indicate that innovators are venturesome,
more willing to take risks, and more edu­
cated than late adopters. Older age tends to

. . . and produce
greater quantities of
agricultural commodities

be associated with m ore conservative atti­

tudes, stable or declining production, and a
greater emphasis on stability and security.
. . . but operate larger acreages . . .

percent of farm operators
with 2 6 0 acres or more




Older farmers also have less formal education
than young farmers. These studies generally
found the average age of late adopters older
than that of innovators.
Younger farmers are probably more will­
ing to risk investments in new production
methods and technology—if only because
they can expect to realize more return over
their working years. New technology often
requires increased investment, and often the
use of borrowed capital, especially for young
farmers. According to the Federal Reserve
System’s 1966 farm loan survey and data
from the Census of Agriculture, young farm­
ers in the Seventh District used more bank
credit than their proportion in the number of
all farmers. Moreover, the average outstand­
ing amount of bank loans was largest for

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

borrowers 35 to 44 years of age—more than
$6,500 per borrower— and the average bank
debt outstanding to that age group increased
faster in 1956-66 than to any other group.
Other studies also indicate that young bor­
rowers are more likely to be indebted to more
than one lender, further increasing the total
debt to young farmers.
Census data reveal further evidence of
other characteristics associated with young
farmers. More than half the younger farmers
(those under 45) operated farms with gross
sales of $10,000 or more in 1964, while
only a third of the older farmers (those 55
to 64) reached that level. A fourth of the
younger farmers operated farms with gross
sales of $20,000 or more, compared with a
mere eighth of the older farmers. Similarly,
about a third of the younger farmers operated
260 acres or more, compared with a fifth of
the older farmers between 55 and 64. In
Illinois, the Seventh District state with the
largest average farm size, farmers from 35
to 44 operated farms averaging 268 acres,
while farmers 55 to 64 operated farms aver­
aging 204 acres.
Even though the number of young farmers
is relatively small, they produce a large pro­
portion of total farm commodities. Farmers
less than 45 years old made up only 36 per­
cent of the farmers in the district in 1964,
but they produced 45 percent of the farm
commodities. They also operated more than
half of the farms in the district with gross
sales of $20,000 or more. By contrast,
farmers at least 45 years old operated more
than two-thirds of the farms with sales be­
tween $5,000 and $9,999 and nearly threefourths of those with sales under $5,000.

12




A large proportion of farmers are found
on small, noncommercial farms. Many are
semi-retired or hold part-time jobs. Income
from such nonfarm jobs to farmers with less
than $5,000 in sales of agricultural commodi­
ties average about $3,400 per farm in 1966.
About a fourth of the farms of that size were
operated by farmers at least 65 years old.
Some of these older farmers may have
transferred parts of their farm businesses to
younger men. That would partly explain their
lower production and sales. A retiring farmer
might, for example, rent some of his land to a
son but continue to live on the farm and
operate part of it to supplement his retire­
ment income.
The kinds of structural changes in agri­
culture that have been associated with the
decline in the number of farms and farmers
can be expected to continue. By 1980, further
improvements in technology and additional
investment in agriculture are likely to reduce
labor requirements still further—probably by
as much as a third. About half the men farm­
ing in 1968 will have reached retirement age
by 1980, but the number of younger farmers
needed to provide ever increasing amounts of
agricultural commodities for both domestic
consumption and exports to other nations will
be considerably smaller than the number
reaching retirement age.
While farm population can be expected to
decline further and in turn result in a further
increase in the average age of farm operators,
the flow of income to those remaining in
agriculture is nevertheless likely to rise. The
farmers will be larger operators, producing a
substantially larger volume of agricultural
commodities, and a larger income per farm.

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

Recent time deposit growth
Xnflows of savings to thrift institutions rose
sharply in the first three quarters of 1967.
Personal savings-type deposits at commercial
and mutual savings banks were up substan­
tially from last year. And additions to share
accounts at savings and loan associations
were more than six times as great as in the
same period in 1966 when funds were flowing
largely to other uses.
The question of where this money came
from takes on special significance in view of
the instability in time deposits and share
accounts in 1966 and fears that a new round
of turbulence might develop if market interest
rates were to continue to rise.
Inflows into time accounts at banks and
share accounts at S&Ls may come from a
variety of sources—savings from current in­
come, sales of physical assets, shifts of funds
from checking accounts or other financial
institutions, and sales of securities. How
much comes from each is, of course, un­
known. But some indication can be had from
looking at recent changes in the time-deposit
mix, recognizing that inflows into one type
of account are apt to be more related to one
source than another.
Liq u id ity p re fe r re d b y som e

Savings accounts at commercial banks
yield less return than can usually be had else­
where. Federal regulations allow banks to pay
no more than 4 percent on savings accounts,
compared with 5 percent on time certificates
under $100,000 and 5.5 percent on larger
certificates. The latter are of little practical
importance as a savings medium for individ­
uals, however, because the minimum denom­



ination is far too large for most people.
Unlike funds held in certificate form, sav­
ings accounts can usually be converted to
cash immediately. Because time certificates
have specified maturities, holders must usu­
ally wait until the maturity date to convert
their certificates into cash.
The prevalence of savings deposits over
certificates probably reflects the immediate
availability they offer depositors and the size
of most savings balances, which are typically
too small to make transfers to certificates
worthwhile. About half the banks require at
least $500 for investment in a certificate.
Because savings accounts provide a safe,
convenient means of holding assets in liquid
form, they are among the first types of savings
to show the effects of changes in income and
spending. Most funds deposited in bank sav­
ings accounts come directly from customers’
current income or transfers from their check­
ing accounts. Some banks provide a service
of transferring funds from checking accounts
to savings accounts at regular intervals. Sav­
ings deposits at commercial banks tend to
increase rapidly when aggregate personal
saving is rising relative to income, as it was
last spring and summer.
Banks in more than half the metropolitan
areas of the Seventh Federal Reserve District
reported net inflows into savings accounts in
the first three quarters of 1967. This was in
sharp contrast to the net outflow common in
the same period in 1966.
The sharp increase in inflows can be at­
tributed largely to sustained high levels of
personal income, coupled with strong motiva­
tions to build up liquidity. The emphasis on

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

quick accessibility of savings was probably
fostered by uncertainties regarding future
income, and especially by spring and summer
forecasts of strong possibilities of layoffs re­
sulting from strikes in the automobile and
other industries. Increases in savings balances
during January-September were most com­
mon in areas of the Seventh District where
workers in manufacturing make up a large
part of the work force.
Five of the district’s 33 metropolitan areas
—Rockford, Muskegon, Kenosha, Milwau-

Savings have varied more
in district centers where
manufacturing is important
First nin e m onths
C e n te rs b y p ercen t

b a la n c e s co m p are d

B a la n c e ,

w ith y e a r e a r lie r

Se p tem b e r

o f e m p lo ym e n t in

1965

m a n u fa ctu rin g

1966

1967

1967
(m illio n s)

(p e rcen t ch an g e )

Commercial banks
S a v in g s d ep o sits
15 cen ters w ith
m ore th an 4 0%

14

— 11

2

$ 5 ,3 6 5

18 cen ters w ith
8

less th an 4 0%
1

T o ta l, 33 centers

— 6
0

—

1

7 ,5 8 6
12,951

— 7

T o tal sa v in g s-ty p e d e p o s its !

B an k s v e rsu s S&Ls

15 centers w ith
14

4

9

less th an 4 0%

9

2

10

1 0,179

T o ta l, 33 centers

11

3

9

17,6 1 4

m ore th an 4 0%

$ 7 ,4 3 5

18 centers w ith

Insured savings and loan associations
S h a re b a la n c e s
15 cen ters w ith
m ore th an 4 0%

5

—

1

9

$ 5 ,01 3

18 centers w ith
less th an 4 0%

4

2

6

1 0,592

T o ta l, 33 centers

4

2

7

15,6 0 5

*Less th an ±

14

0 .5 p erce n t.

flncludes, in addition to savings deposits, individuals'
holdings of time certificates of deposit.




kee, and Racine—had greater growth in sav­
ings deposits in 1967 than in 1965 or 1966.
All five areas have high concentrations of
workers in manufacturing.
There were large inflows into savings ac­
counts in some areas where the rate paid on
such deposits was relatively low. Banks in the
Gary-Hammond area, for example, had siz­
able increases in savings deposits in 1967,
even though some paid only 2 percent. Be­
cause of state regulations, no Indiana bank
could pay more than 3.5 percent on savings
accounts. Yet, gains in savings deposits in
Indiana were as large as those of other areas;
people seldom go outside their own communi­
ties to obtain savings deposit service.
For banks in most areas, certificates of
deposit were a more important source of
funds than savings deposits. In about a third
of the areas, savings deposits decreased in the
first three-quarters of 1967, but this was
offset by a rise in certificates. In other areas,
savings deposits rose, but the gains were
smaller than gains in certificates. Insofar as
the increase in certificates represented funds
diverted from savings accounts, the composi­
tion of deposits in commercial banks changed,
but with no net inflow of funds from outside
the banking system.

Since 1966, savings and loan associations
have had a regulated differential rate advan­
tage over commercial banks. In most of the
country, most S&Ls can pay as much as 4.75
percent on regular passbook share accounts,
compared with a maximum of 4 percent on
savings deposits at banks. Savings and loan
associations can usually pay as much as 5.25
percent on certificates, compared with 5 per­
cent at banks.
Many banks pay the maximum authorized
rates. Figures for July 31 (the latest avail-

Business Conditions, Ja n u a ry 1968

able) show nearly nine-tenths of all banks in
the United States with total deposits of $100
million or more, and almost two-thirds of the
smaller banks, paying 4 percent on savings
deposits. On certificates of less than $100,000
—those issued predominately to individuals
— about half the banks—those accounting for
four-fifths of the small-denomination certifi­
cate deposits outstanding—paid the 5 per­
cent ceiling.
Information available on S&Ls indicates
that in January 1967 about four-fifths of all
share accounts were of the regular passbook
type. A third of the associations, holding
nearly half the share capital, paid the maxi­
mum authorized dividend—4.75 percent in
most states but 5 percent in the Far West and
certain eastern states. Nearly all paid more
than the 4 percent maximum authorized for
banks. By contrast, a third of the associations
had paid only 4 percent on regular share
accounts in December 1965 and another third
4.25 percent. Very few had paid more than
4.5 percent.
The differential between savings and loan
dividend rates and bank interest rates on
passbook savings had therefore widened
noticeably by early 1967. Rate ceilings kept
most banks from following the lead of S&Ls
in increasing rates on savings. The result was
a growing attractiveness of passbook accounts
at S&Ls for savers wanting their funds to be
readily available. The widening gap appar­
ently slowed bank gains in savings deposits.
Information for the Seventh District pro­
vides an indication of the extent of the impact.
In the first nine months of 1967, banks in
three-fifths of the centers reported greater
growth in personal savings-type deposits
(savings deposits and certificates) than was
registered in share accounts at local S&Ls.
This was a smaller proportion of areas than
in 1965 and 1966 when banks in nearly all



areas improved their relative positions.
Thrift in stitutio n s v e rsu s th e m a rk e t

Thrift institutions have also attracted a
good deal of money that is held for invest­
ment purposes. These funds tend to be mainly
in certificate form at commercial banks but
in regular share accounts at S&Ls. A survey
conducted by the U. S. Savings and Loan
League at the end of 1965 indicates that sav­
ings and loan accounts contain a sizable
amount of “investment-type” money. The
survey showed that 31 percent of all savings
at associations was in accounts with balances
of more than $10,000. At commercial banks,
around 35 percent of all savings deposits
were in accounts exceeding $10,000. Holders
of these funds included individuals and non­
profit organizations such as pension funds,
churches, and credit unions. The large sums
involved suggest that such accounts are sensi­
tive to developments in the security markets.
There are indications that the funds ac­
quired by banks and S&Ls in the first three
quarters of 1967 resulted partly from a de­
cline in direct investment in marketable
securities. Data on flows of funds indicate a
decline in direct financial investment by
individuals in the first three quarters at a
seasonally adjusted annual rate of $8.7 bil­
lion. This contrasts with the $10.8 billion
average increase in 1966. Net gains at the
thrift institutions averaged a $36.4 billion
annual rate in the first three quarters of 1967
—far more than the 1966 gain of only $18.9
billion.
The shift of funds to thrift institutions was
related to the fall in interest rates on govern­
ment bonds and high-grade corporate securi­
ties from the 5.5 to 6 percent range in the
summer of 1966, when a substantial amount
of money was attracted to such instruments.
Although yields available in the long-term

15

Fe d e ra l R ese rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o

bond market remained generally higher than
maximum rates at thrift institutions in the
first nine months of 1967, the smaller yield
differential was apparently enough to curtail
investment in marketable securities. The
average size of savings and loan shares, which
had been $2,770 in December 1965, dropped
to a low of $2,670 in October 1966, but had
climbed to $2,800 by September 1967.
The ro le of c o rp o ra te d ep o sits

Negotiable time certificates of deposit in
denominations of $ 100,000 and more—
certificates held primarily by businesses—
rose about $1 billion in the first half of 1967
and accounted for about 13 percent of the
rise in aggregate time deposits of individuals
and businesses. Moreover, growth in certifi­
cates of large denominations was widespread,
with banks in almost all parts of the country
reporting increases.
The sharp rise in these deposits resulted
largely from a buildup in corporate liquidity
and, at least in early 1967, from the increased
attractiveness of bank interest rates compared
with rates on Treasury bills and other moneymarket instruments. Corporations, even more
than individuals, responded to the change in
the rate structure. Yields on short-term
government securities—which, to corpora­
tions and other large holders of liquid assets,

are the closest investment alternatives to time
certificates issued by banks—were consider­
ably lower in early 1967 than in 1966. In
September 1966, for example, the market
yield on six-month Treasury bills was 5.8
percent, compared with 3.8 percent in May
1967. With the fall in yields, banks—operat­
ing under a regulatory maximum of 5.5 per­
cent for certificates of deposit of $ 100,000 or
more—were able to attract larger amounts of
such deposits.
While corporations sometimes place funds
in savings and loan shares, their interest in
these establishments is small. Commercial
banks, with their greater liquidity and greater
flexibility in the kinds of time deposits and
loan services they can offer, are the primary
outlet for deposits of business. Reflecting the
buildup of time deposits of corporations,
total time and savings deposits at commercial
banks grew faster in the first three quarters
of 1967 than at other financial institutions.
The source of the recent gains in time de­
posits, therefore, appears largely to have been
current income and reduced flows of funds
into market securities, not transfers of funds
from other financial institutions. However,
this probably provides no substantial assur­
ance that flows of funds would not shift
again in favor of market securities if interest
rates make such a shift attractive to investors.

BUSINESS CO N DITIO N S is published m onthly by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Joseph G . K vasnicka w a s p rim a rily responsible for the article "Pound sterling d e va lu e d ,"
Charles E. Tuck fo r "Seventh District developm ents," Roby L. Sloan and D avid W . M aaske
fo r "Fe w e r fa rm e rs, and the a v e ra g e ag e risin g ," and Charlotte H. Scott fo r "Recent
time deposit g ro w th ."
Subscriptions to Business Conditions are a v a ila b le to the public without charge. For in fo rm a­
tion concerning bulk m ailin g s, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Chicago, Illinois 60690.
16

Articles m ay be reprinted provided source is credited.