View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
1970 February

Contents
The trend of business

2

The EEC and U. S.
agriculture

6

Farm mortgages—
The impact of tight
credit

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

THE

2

T h e business expansion that began in the
spring of 1967 halted in the closing months of
last year. A convincing body of evidence
supporting this conclusion became available
early in 1970. Total activity apparently
leveled in the fourth quarter, and some sec­
tors declined—both in the nation and in the
Midwest. Sales and output of passenger cars
and other consumer durables declined sig­
nificantly. As yet unresolved is the question
of whether the economy has entered a period
of cyclical decline, the first since 1960.
Total employment increased only slightly
in the fourth quarter, and manufacturing
employment declined. Overtime hours were
reduced or eliminated at many factories,
and some short weeks were scheduled. Indus­
trial production declined 2 percent from July
to December, and new orders for durable
goods receded from the record level reached
in September. Many federal spending pro­
grams, especially on defense, were curtailed.
Construction activity, led by homebuilding,
was declining more than seasonally late in the
year. Total spending on goods and services
(the gross national product) rose at a much
slower pace in the fourth quarter, and this
rise merely reflected price increases.
The leveling in activity in late 1969 pri­
marily was the result of a series of restrictive
monetary and fiscal actions starting almost a
year and a half earlier. But strikes played
supporting roles. Most important was a work
stoppage beginning October 27, and lasting
through January, that involved more than




OF

BUSINESS

100,000 employees of the nation’s largest
producer of electrical goods. Upward stim­
ulus will result as these disputes are settled
and the pipelines restocked. But losses in
income and profits associated with long
strikes are not quickly recovered when pro­
duction is resumed, especially in a period of
slackened activity. Moreover, other far reach­
ing walkouts, notably in motor transport, may
lie ahead.
R ecessio n a h e a d ?

A period of slackened general economic
growth with declines in construction and
manufacturing does not automatically qualify
for the recession label. A consensus definition
characterizes a recession as a decline in total
spending, adjusted for price changes, that
extends for at least two consecutive quarters.
The definition sets no standards for the
amount of the decline in activity or the time
required for recovery of previous peak levels
after growth resumes. But it clearly excludes
temporary pauses in activity such as occurred
in 1962 and 1967.
The four “fully accredited” recessions of
the postwar period began in 1949, 1953,
1957, and 1960, respectively. Succeeding de­
clines in real gross national product from
peak to trough quarters were not large, rang­
ing from 1.4 percent (1960-61) to 3.9 per­
cent (1957-58). The worst of these recessions
was short and shallow compared to business
downtrends recorded before World War II.
Declines in industrial production were greater

Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

than declines in total activity, however, rang­
ing from 8 percent to almost 13 percent, and
even larger declines were recorded for the
durable goods industries. In the cyclical
troughs of 1958 and 1961, unemployment,
always a lagging indicator, exceeded 7 per­
cent of the labor force. The unemployment
rate averaged only 3.5 percent in 1969, the
lowest rate since the Korean War.
1 9 6 9 v s. 1 9 6 6

Comparisons of postwar pauses or reces­
sions, although interesting and useful, do not
provide sure clues to future developments.
Examination of these periods reveals many
similarities, but also striking differences.
Vast changes in the structure of the labor
market, in the financial system, and in politi­
cal philosophy, have altered relationships
among economic developments from those
existing ten or 20 years ago. The temptation
currently, therefore, is to find parallels with
the more recent developments of the 1966-67
experience.
Housing starts declined sharply from a

Industrial production
declined gradually from July
through December
percent, 1957-59=100




seasonally adjusted high early in the year in
both 1966 and 1969. Industrial production
continued to climb throughout 1966, whereas
a peak was reached in July 1969. Auto sales
and production started down in the second
quarter of 1966. A similar development did
not occur until the fourth quarter of 1969.
Employment continued to rise at a good
pace throughout 1966, in contrast to the
leveling trend in late 1969. The unemploy­
ment rate remained relatively low in both
years. Despite less vigor in employment and
output trends, the unemployment rate was
even lower in late 1969 than three years
earlier. Insured unemployment, reflecting the
status of experienced workers, was at the
same low rate in both periods. New claims
for unemployment compensation have in­
creased significantly since November. A sim­
ilar development occurred in late 1966.
S a le s a n d in v e n to rie s

Recent trends in business inventories pro­
vide a marked contrast with the situation
three years ago. Inventories rose $ 15 billion,
about 12 percent in 1966, and the rate of
rise jumped to a record $20 billion in the
fourth quarter, as consumer purchases failed
to match expectations. The ratio of inven­
tories to sales rose substantially during the
year.
Inventories rose only $8 billion, about 5
percent, in 1969. No appreciable increase in
sales-inventory ratios occurred last year. The
reasons are several. The normal tendency to
keep inventories at the lowest level commen­
surate with efficient operations has been
reinforced by closely limited credit avail­
ability and the highest interest rates in mod­
ern times. Apprehension of a general business
letdown was present through most of the past
year, a concern not evident until 1966 was
well advanced. Manufacturers began to

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

cut output in 1969 when sales prospects ap­
peared unfavorable. Strikes, especially in the
motor vehicle and electrical goods industries,
that reduced output below desired levels in
some cases, also were factors reducing growth
in inventories last year. Finally, in contrast
to 1966, retail sales did not slow in the fourth
quarter of 1969 from the rate of earlier
months. Sales of nondurables, in fact, showed
relatively favorable gains in comparison with
increases in disposable personal income,
while sales of durables were lower than a year
earlier.
C a p ita l e x p e n d itu re s strong

Although most general measures of activity
showed the business adjustment to be further
advanced at the beginning of 1970 than three
years earlier, various evidence indicates that
capital expenditure prospects currently are
appreciably stronger than in early 1967. Sur­
veys of business investment plans indicate an
increase of more than 10 percent in plant and

Inventory growth in 1969
below 1966 rate
billion dollars

4



1966

1969

equipment expenditures in 1970 from 1969.
At the start of 1967, a rise of about 5 percent
was anticipated (trimmed to an actual in­
crease of about 2 percent).
Capital spending appropriations approved
by directors of large manufacturing compa­
nies, as tabulated by the National Industrial
Conference Board, reached a peak in the
second quarter of 1966, and then declined
sharply. In 1969, these appropriations rose
substantially in the third quarter, the latest
for which data are available.
Allowing for strike influences, orders for
most types of machinery and equipment were
well maintained in the final months of 1969.
Declining machine tool orders in the fourth
quarter were in opposition to the general
trend. The picture is especially strong for
utilities—gas, electric, and communications.
But demand from manufacturers and other
industries for many types of equipment—in­
cluding air conditioning, trucks, railroad
equipment, electrical apparatus, chemical
processing facilities, and office
equipment— remains vigorous.
Construction contracts for com­
mercial buildings have been very
large.
The sharp dichotomy of weak
demand for consumer durables
and strong demand for producers
durables is unique in the postwar
period. It reflects the confidence
of business in prospects for an
early resumption of growth, con­
tinued expectations of price in­
flation, and the desire to reduce
labor costs, in addition to needs
for more capacity and higher
quality products.
In time, a more normal rela­
tionship among developments in
these broad industry groups will

Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

be re-established. Lower profits and lower
than expected sales might cause some com­
panies to scale down capital expenditure
plans. But past patterns suggest this will
happen on a broad scale only if a recession
develops. An alternative possibility is a re­
surgence in consumer purchases of durables
from recently depressed levels. This could
occur if individuals’ spending and use of
credit resumed a more normal relationship
to income.
The co urse of policy

Contrasts in monetary and fiscal policy
actions in 1969 and 1966 are at least as
marked as differences in business develop­
ments. Fiscal policy played no positive role
in repressing the boom in 1966. Federal ex­
penditures continued to rise rapidly, while
tax rates remained unchanged. Last year, ex­
penditures increased but less rapidly, while
receipts rose, partly because of the higher
tax rates enacted in 1968.
Monetary policy was relatively restrictive
throughout 1966. Credit markets tightened
severely for a brief period in August. The
resulting scramble for funds was soon tagged
as a “credit crunch,” to describe the fear in
some financial circles (albeit unfounded)
that a liquidity squeeze of panic proportions
was developing.
The growth of credit, especially total bank




credit, was checked early in 1969. But at no
time did circumstances resemble those pre­
vailing during the crunch. Instead, commer­
cial banks, as well as most other lenders and
borrowers, developed new sources of funds to
moderate the impact of restrictive credit
policies.
The n e x t p h ase

Seldom before have the monetary and
fiscal authorities worked in such strong con­
cert to contain a rapid and long continued
wave of price inflation. Actions intended to
slow the rise in spending have been success­
ful. The rate of price increase, if not reduced,
probably is no longer accelerating. Hopefully,
the coming months will bring a moderation
in the uptrend.
Monetary policy, largely unaided, halted
the rise in spending in late 1966 and early
1967. Price inflation slowed substantially in
the first half of 1967. The momentum of the
inflation is much greater now than three years
ago. But margins of unused capacity are now
building in manufacturing facilities and in the
labor force. Businesses and governments con­
tinue their efforts to hold down inventory ac­
cumulations and new hirings. Consumers re­
main cautious. Taken together, these devel­
opments comprise the anti-inflation forces
that work to contain inflation in a free society.

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The EEC and U. S. agriculture
t w e l v e years have passed since six Euro­
pean nations banded together to promote
trade among themselves. In 1958, Belgium,
France, Italy, Luxemburg, Netherlands, and
West Germany created the European Eco­
nomic Community (EEC), often called the
Common Market. One objective of the organ­
ization was the gradual elimination of tariff
barriers among the members and the estab­
lishment of common tariffs for trade with
other nations.
Early last December, after 12 years of
operation, the member nations met to discuss
the future of the organization. Discussions
and negotiations still in progress are con­
cerned with possible expansion of the mem­
bership, problems of economic and political
integration, and possible changes in the
group’s common agricultural policy (CAP).
Because the EEC is a major importer of
United States agricultural products, the out­
come of these negotiations will be of special
interest to American farmers.
Farm pro blem s in Europe

Agricultural policy formulation has been
one of the most difficult tasks encountered by
the Common Market since its founding. Indi­
cations are that it will be no less vexing in the
future.
High price supports have promoted in­
creased agricultural output within the group,

6

and burdensome surpluses of some products
have accumulated. If agricultural prices
within the Common Market are maintained
at the present high levels, potential new mem­
bers with lower agricultural prices would
experience some problems in negotiations for
membership in the EEC. British consumers,
for example, would not welcome the high
food prices of the Common Market, nor
would the British government willingly accept
the high costs incurred by the EEC in main­
taining support prices and export subsidies.
Prices and production in the Common
Market are protected by various restrictions
on imports, and some exports are promoted
by export subsidies. Import restrictions on
food, feed grains, and livestock have limited
shipments from the United States, Canada,
Argentina, and Australia. Furthermore, ex­
ports of many less developed countries have
been held down by preferential trade agree­
ments of the EEC with former French col­
onies in Africa. South American exports have
been especially hard hit by these agreements.
A m ajor U. S. m a rk e t

The Common Market is the largest export
market for U. S. agricultural commodities
under a single jurisdiction, accounting for 22
percent of the total in 1968. That year, 15
percent went to Japan, and 10 percent each
to Canada and to the countries associated

NOTE: Major sources for this article include:
Berntson, B. L., et al., The European Community’s Common Agricultural Policy—Implications
for U. S. Trade, U. S. Department of Agriculture, October 1969.
Sorenson, Vernon L., and Hathaway, Dale E., The Grain-Livestock Economy and Trade Patterns
of the European Economic Community, Michigan State University, 1968.




Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

in the European Free Trade As­
Soybeans and corn, major U. S.
sociation (EFTA ).1 Feed grains
agricultural exports to Common M arket
and oilseeds and oilseed products
Percent
(primarily soybeans) are the most
1968
ch an g e
I9 6 0
A m o u n t Percen t A m o u n t Percent 1960-68
important EEC imports from the
(m illio n d o lla rs)
United States, accounting for
S o y b e a n s an d so yb e an
three-fifths of the total.
p roducts
139
13
4 40
32
+217
C o rn
83
8
23
313
+ 276
Changes in the common agri­
W h e a t an d flo u r
54
5
84
6
+ 57
cultural policy arising from nego­
O ilse e d s an d oilseed
tiations among the EEC members
pro du cts o th er th an
so yb e an s
and prospective new members
59
5
49
4
— 17
Feed g ra in s o th er
could be of considerable signifi­
th a n corn
114
10
23
2
— 80
cance to American farmers. At
A ll o th er
59
6 50
458
33
— 44
present, the common agricultural
T o tal
1 ,099
100
1 ,3 6 7
100
+ 24
policy is highly protectionist. Any
substantial easing in the restric­
(1) “Target” or internal support prices
tions on imports would benefit the United
set by the EEC yearly;
States and other exporters of agricultural
(2) “Variable levies” on certain imported
products. A less restrictive posture would also
agricultural products equal to the difference
facilitate British entry into the Common
between the world price of the commodity
Market. Conversely, if Britain were to adopt a
and the “threshold” price, the lowest price at
more restrictive posture toward agricultural
which particular imported commodities may
enter the market (Support prices and thresh­
imports in order to join the EEC, both Amer­
old prices are virtually identical.);
ican farmers and British consumers would be
(3) Export subsidies enabling certain
affected adversely.
EEC commodities to compete on the world
market;
O rig in s of th e policy
(4) A European Guidance and Guarantee
The first steps toward establishing the com­
Fund financed by import levies and member
mon agricultural policy were taken in 1962.
assessments that supports both internal EEC
A common level of agricultural prices was
“target” prices and the EEC export subsidies.
The CAP programs for high level price
to be achieved by the end of 1969, a goal
supports, the levies on selected imports, and
realized in July 1968.
the export subsidies are of particular concern
Common Market agricultural policies are
to U. S. agriculture. The levy fluctuates with
administered through a complex framework
the world prices for the products. Among
of interrelated regulations, which vary among
commodities. Basic features include:
commodities subject to the variable levy are
feed and food grains, beef and veal, pork,
food lard, dairy products, and poultry prod­
’The eight EFTA countries are: Austria, Den­
ucts. Commodities subject to the variable levy
mark, Finland, Norway, Portugal, Sweden, Switzer­
land, and the United Kingdom. Iceland has been
accounted for 27 percent of U. S. agricultural
accepted for membership and will officially become
exports to the EEC in 1960 and 37 percent
a part of EFTA during 1970. EFTA members have
eliminated tariffs among themselves, but the organi­
in 1968.
zation does not impose common restrictions against
Prior to the EEC, member countries did
nonmembers.



Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

not produce enough feed grains, high protein
wheat, meats, and poultry to meet domestic
needs. Higher production stimulated by CAP
programs has reduced the deficit in some
commodities, but member nations still import
large quantities of feed grains and lesser
amounts of hard red wheat, durum wheat,
and meats.
Substantial surpluses of some commodities
have accumulated within the EEC. Export
subsidies—principally for grains, dairy prod­
ucts, sugar, meat, and poultry—have been
used extensively in order to move these sup­
plies into world markets.
Sizable surpluses of dairy products have
accumulated in the Common Market in
recent years. Most European cattle are dual
purpose, beef-milk breeds. Improved feeding
has been emphasized to increase beef and veal
output. But existing price support levels do
not adequately encourage meat production
over milk production. The result has been a

Common M arket levies
substantially raise prices
of imported grains
dollars per bushel
300

price to-*
buyers

i?* v $2.97
T

2 .5 0 -

$2 32
added

by

2 00- va,riable
levy

1.5 0

LO O -

5 0

0

-

im port
price

.

barley

corn

S O U R C E : U. S. D e p a rtm e n t o f A g ric u ltu re .
D a ta a re an a v e r a g e fo r y e a r en ded J u ly 1968.




percent
io o

imo fro
p rts m
w r—

" h

I9 6 0

1968

e p rts to
xo
—

—

I9 6 0

—

1968

* E u ro p e a n Free T ra d e A sso cia tio n .
S O U R C E : U. S. D e p a rtm e n t o f A g ric u ltu re .

chronic surplus of milk and milk products.
In the fiscal year ended June 30, 1969, the
EEC spent more than $600 million for dairy
price supports and export subsidies alone.
All expenditures on price supports and
subsidies under CAP programs cost $2.4
billion in fiscal 1969—a sixfold increase from
1963 and a third more than in 1968. Ex­
penditures have been projected as high as
$3.4 billion yearly by 1975.
If the agricultural budgets of the six nations
are added to the costs of the Guidance and
Guarantee Fund, it has been estimated that
total agricultural policy costs in the Common
Market countries exceeded $8 billion in the
year ended in June 1969. The U. S. agri­
cultural budget cost about $6 billion in the
same period.
U. S. s h a re d e clin e s

wheat

8

Larger share of agricultural
trade in Common M arket
is among members

The United States has been an important
supplier of agricultural products to Common
Market countries for many years. Trade pat­
terns, however, have changed since the estab-

Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

lishment of the EEC in 1958. A principal
reason for the removal of trade barriers
within the Common Market was to increase
trade among the members and reduce their
trade with nonmembers. These intentions
have been realized to a marked degree.
From 1960 to 1968, agricultural trade
within the EEC nearly tripled, while imports
from both the United States and the EFTA
countries increased by only about one-third,
and trade with the rest of the world increased
only one-fifth. Exports from the Common
Market to nonmembers during this period
grew much faster than imports—77 percent
to the United States and 48 percent to EFTA
countries.
Changes in market shares also reflect the
shift in trade patterns. From 1960 to 1968,
the share of total imports from other members
within the Common Market rose from 18 per­
cent to 32 percent, while imports from the
United States declined slightly. The pattern
for exports was similar. Intra-EEC exports
expanded from 45 percent to 60 percent,
while the share of exports to the United States
and EFTA declined.
C h a n g e s in com position

A substantial shift in the composition of
U. S. agricultural exports to the EEC has
occurred since 1960. Although feed grains
are subject to high internal EEC price sup­
ports and imports are subject to the variable
levy, U. S. corn exports to EEC nations
nearly quadrupled between 1960 and 1968.
The gain reflects the EEC’s increasing need
for foreign feed grains to promote meat
production.
United States exports of beef, veal, and
other meat products to the EEC have risen
rapidly since 1960 because of the EEC’s con­
tinued difficulty in increasing beef and veal
output. The upward trend in U. S. beef ex


Growth in agricultural
trade of Common Market
largest among members
percent change, 1960-68
0
30
60
90
120

150

180

from other
members
all agricultural
imports
United States
EFTA *

rest of world

e p rts
xo
to other
members
all agricultural
exports
United States
EFTA*
rest of world
* E u ro p e a n Free T ra d e A sso cia tio n .
S O U R C E : U. S. D e p a rtm e n t o f A g ric u ltu re .

ports to the EEC will probably continue. It
should also be noted, however, that the Euro­
peans prefer leaner meat to the high degree
of marbling favored and produced in the
United States.
Much of the increased importation of feed
grains in Europe is fed to poultry and swine.
EEC policies have effectively closed the Com­
mon Market to U. S. poultry exports. High
threshold prices for imports and the variable
levy provide protection for European pro­
ducers. The EEC also subsidizes poultry ex­
ports, thereby cutting into U. S. sales to nonEEC European countries. In 1968, the
United States retaliated by providing an ex­
port subsidy on poultry to match EEC sub­
sidized export prices.

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The most important category of U. S. agri­
cultural exports to the EEC is the oilseed and
oilseed products group, mainly soybeans
from the Midwest. But this is a relatively new
development. As recently as 1960, oilseeds
and oilseed products made up 18 percent of
the value of U. S. agricultural exports to the
EEC—tied with feed grains behind raw cot­
ton. By 1968, oilseeds and oilseed products
accounted for 36 percent of the total, far
ahead of second-place feed grains. Soybeans
and soybean products—important in Euro­
pean diets, but not grown there in quantity—
are exempt from the variable import levy. A
tax on oilseeds and oilseed products, intern­
ally produced as well as imported, is now
under consideration. The purpose is to raise
the price of margarine, thereby encouraging
consumers to eat surplus butter.
A tax is also proposed on oilcake which is
fed to cattle as a protein supplement. Higher
resulting feed costs would reduce oilcake
utilization and imports and reduce milk pro­
duction and surpluses, but would also reduce
meat supplies—a result not desired. Further­
more, consumption of high protein feed
grains could be substituted for oilcake, de­
feating the purpose of the tax. United States
policy vigorously opposes this tax proposal,
and retaliatory measures aimed, perhaps, at
EEC industrial products are a possibility.
Fu tu re d e v e lo p m e n t s

10

Expansion of the Common Market mem­
bership is possible in the next few years. The
most likely candidates for inclusion are Den­
mark, Ireland, Norway, and the United King­
dom. The conditions of their entry will be
of particular interest to U. S. agriculture.
Britain, which in 1968 took 6 percent of U. S.
agricultural exports, imports foods at prices
well below those prevailing in the EEC. Although some adjustments in the EEC’s agri­




cultural policy would be required before
Britain would join, it is probable, neverthe­
less, that British membership in the EEC will
result in further restrictions on imports of
U. S. agricultural products.
In large part, increases in agricultural ex­
ports to the EEC since 1960 were in soy­
beans, which do not face significant restric­
tions. But feed grain exports to the EEC,
especially corn, also grew substantially, in
spite of heavy import restrictions. This
growth is attributed to the feed grain deficit
of the EEC associated with emphasis on in­
creased meat and poultry production. In part,
increased U. S. feed grain exports replaced
poultry exports to the EEC, which have al­
most ceased.
The future of U. S. agricultural exports to
the EEC is uncertain at this time. Since 1966,
these exports have declined. Shipments of
products that are subject to the EEC’s vari­
able levy have dropped much more than those
not under the levy. Exports of soybeans and
soybean products continued to increase after
1966—though at a much slower rate than
during the early 1960s.
Principal uncertainties concerning restruc­
turing of the EEC common agricultural policy
may be resolved within the next 18 to 24
months. Changes may involve expansion of
membership and measures to halt the rapid
rise in agricultural outlays.
Agricultural policies, both within the ex­
isting Common Market and in potential
member nations, are influenced by strong and
volatile political forces. Policies that would
substantially lower farm prices will meet de­
termined opposition. Leaders in these nations
will be exploring plans to lower internal agri­
cultural program costs, dispose of surpluses,
and expand production of certain products.
Little hope exists that the Common Market
will soon relax its protectionist policies.

Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

Farm mortgages
The impact of tight credit
T o t a l farm debt more than doubled in
the 1960s. The increase was divided about
equally between loans secured by farm real
estate and other farm credit. Farm mortgage
debt, now totaling about $29 billion, has in­
creased about $2 billion annually since 1965.
About two-fifths of farm mortgage debt
outstanding is held by individuals. Federal
Land Banks and life insurance companies
each have a fifth of the total and commercial
banks have about 15 percent. These four
groups of investors hold more than 95 percent
of farm mortgage debt. The remainder is held
by the Farmers’ Home Administration, sav­
ings and loan associations, mutual savings
banks, and other lenders.
The relative importance of the major
groups investing in farm mortgages changed
substantially in the 1960s, and the shift has
accelerated in the past two years of tight
money and sharply higher interest rates. Most
notably, individuals and the Federal Land
Banks have increased their participation in
new farm mortgage loans in recent years,
while the role played by life insurance com­
panies has diminished.
In d iv id u a ls le n d m o re

By far the largest share of farm mortgage
debt has always been held by individuals. In
most cases, these loans result from sales of
farms rather than through investment of
cash. Last year, individual lenders probably
acquired more than half of the increase in
farm mortgage debt—up from 40 percent as
recently as 1965. Individuals now grant al


most twice as much new farm mortgage credit
as the next largest class of lenders, and the
margin is widening.
The growth of the individual sector in farm
mortgage finance in recent years is partly a
result of the attractive alternative investments
available to institutional lenders. But it also
reflects the desire of many farmers contem­
plating retirement to retain an investment
interest in their former properties or in other
farm real estate, rather than experiment with
less familiar alternatives.
More than half of farmland sales are sellerfinanced and, of these, about 80 percent are
sold under land contracts. The land contract
is a flexible instrument adaptable to individ­
ual circumstances. Because the sale is con­
ditional, title typically does not pass until
the contract is fulfilled. Repossession of the
property, therefore, is facilitated in case of
default.
The use of land contracts has been growing
in recent years for a number of reasons.
Lower downpayments may permit sales at
higher prices to a larger number of buyers,
often friends or relatives. Another advantage
to sellers is that, providing downpayments are
less than 30 percent, capital gains income
may be spread over several years and tax
liabilities reduced. When sellers of farmland
have large equities, frequently the case in
recent years, seller-financing under land con­
tracts may be preferred, even when other
sources of credit are available. Existing
owners often are willing to grant credit on
more favorable terms with interest rates as

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

much as a half percentage point lower than
rates charged by institutional lenders.
All of these factors are still present. Sellers
of farms therefore may assume a still larger
role in financing these properties in the years
ahead.
Land B an ks e x p a n d lo an s

Federal Land Banks have financed more
than a fourth of the increase in farm mort­
gage debt in recent years. In 1964, these
banks accounted for a fifth of the rise in farm
mortgages.
Lending activity of the 12 Federal Land
Banks is restricted to farm real estate. They
raise funds through sales of bonds on the
open market at relatively favorable rates.
The Federal Land Banks are farmer-owned
cooperatives and pay smaller income taxes
than other corporations. Also, their loans are
exempt from state usury statutes, an impor­
tant factor in the past year or two. Thus, the
Federal Land Banks have an advantage over

Farm debt more than
doubled in the Sixties*
b illio n

d o lla r s

60
real estate debt

r-

B

no n -rea l estate debt

40

I960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

*A m o u n t o u tsta n d in g in 48 s ta te s , J a n u a r y 1. E xclu d e s
co m m o dity cre d it co rp o ra tio n lo a n s.




other institutional lenders in their field of
specialty. All of these factors have helped
them to play a larger part in the farm real
estate credit picture in recent years.
The Administration in late 1966 requested
various federal agencies, including the Federal
Land Banks, to restrict new securities issues
to refundings of maturing obligations. This
resulted in reduced commitments to make
new farm loans in 1967 and may have been
responsible for slower growth in lending in
1968. The restrictive lending policy was then
relaxed, however, and a resurgence in mort­
gage loans by the Federal Land Banks oc­
curred in 1969. This trend appears to be
continuing in 1970.
In s u ra n c e c o m p a n ie s cut b a c k

The proportion of new farm mortgage debt
taken by life insurance companies has de­
clined each year since 1964, when they ac­
counted for almost a fourth of the rise in
outstandings. By 1968, the life insurance
company share of new farm mortgages was
down to 10 percent, and last year, the pro­
portion was only about 5 percent.
Life insurance companies can purchase a
variety of debt and equity investments. They
have wide latitude to shift available funds to
the highest earning assets. In 1969, highgrade corporate bonds were sold to yield as
much as 9 percent annually. Even higher
rates were available on commercial and in­
dustrial mortgages. In addition, many bond
issues and loans have had a claim against
equity in some form—“a piece of the action.”
Not only are such provisions seldom included
in farm or home mortgages but, in addition,
farm loans typically are subject to usury
ceilings. Another factor causing life insurance
companies to reduce new long-term invest­
ments of all classes has been the sharp in­
crease in their policy loans starting in 1966.

Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

Im p a ct in t h e C o rn b e lt

The decline in farm mortgage lending by
insurance companies has probably been felt
most strongly in the Cornbelt, which includes
the Seventh District states of Illinois, Iowa,
and Indiana, where these companies have tra­
ditionally been more important as suppliers
of farm real estate credit than in other regions.
A review of farm mortgages recorded by life
insurance companies through 1968 reveals a
sharp downtrend in each of these states.
Recordings by insurance companies in
both Illinois and Iowa reached peak dollar
levels in 1965. Three years later recordings
had declined by almost a half in Illinois and
by a third in Iowa. In this period, the propor­
tion of all farm mortgage recordings ac­
counted for by life insurance companies
dropped from a third to a fifth. In Indiana,
insurance companies’ share of farm mort­
gage recordings averaged close to a fifth of all
recordings in 1965, but in 1968, only a tenth.
Insurance companies’ farm mortgage lend-

Individuals' share of farm
m ortgage loans rises as insurance
companies' share declines
p e rce n t o f a n n u a l
6 0

in c r e a s e

individuals
Federal Land B an ks

50-

life insurance companies
com m ercial

banks

40-

1964

1965

1966

1967

S O U R C E : Flow of Funds, F e d e ra l R e se rve B o a rd .




1968

ing historically has been comparatively small
in Wisconsin and Michigan. Even so, as in the
other district states, their role has declined.
Farm mortgage recordings by insurance
companies in Wisconsin were 10 percent of
the total in 1965, and in 1968, only 4 percent.
In Michigan, the decline was from 5 percent
to 2 percent. As in the rest of the nation, the
decline in farm real estate lending by insur­
ance companies has been about offset by in­
creases for individuals and Federal Land
Banks.
B a n k s ’ r o le s t a b le

Throughout most of the 1964-69 period
the proportion of the annual increase in farm
mortgage debt held by commercial banks
remained at about 15 percent. Farm real
estate lending by rural commercial banks is
influenced more by trends in deposits locally
than by conditions in the national credit
markets. Despite attractive yields on money
market investments, most country bankers
look to their market areas for
long-term growth in both deposits
and in loans.
In most farm communities, a
few large bank depositors have
shifted their funds to other invest­
ments in response to the higher
rates available. But this develop­
ment appears to have had only a
small influence on the growth of
deposits at most rural banks.
Farm real estate mortgages are
not the primary credit extended
by commercial banks. Normally,
banks prefer to accommodate
short- and intermediate-term
credit demands before committing
funds to long-term loans. There­
fore, their holdings of farm mort­
1969
gage loans usually depend on the

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

local credit situation. Nationally, farm real
estate loans are about 15 percent of all bank
loans to farmers, but in the Seventh District,
the ratio exceeds 17 percent. Some of these
loans are temporary accommodations, pend­
ing the arrangement of long-term permanent
financing with another lender. Some are mort­
gage loans because farm real estate was taken
as collateral on loans extended for other pur­
poses and did not arise out of a land transfer.
Commercial banks are unlikely to increase,
and may reduce, the rate of growth of their
farm real estate loans. In recent years, bank
loans have been increasing much faster than
deposits. From 1961 to 1968, total deposits
of “agricultural banks” in the Seventh Federal
Reserve District—banks at which farm loans
are at least 30 percent of the loan portfolio—
increased about 52 percent. Farm loans at
these banks increased 70 percent in the same
period. One result, of course, has been a rise
in loan-to-deposit ratios.
Fewer than half of the agricultural banks
in the Seventh District had loan-to-deposit
ratios of 50 percent or more at mid-1961.
But, by mid-1968, about two-thirds reported
ratios of at least 50 percent. As loan ratios
have increased, some bankers have become
more cautious on new commitments, espe­
cially for long-term real estate loans.
F u tu re t r e n d s

14

A somewhat slower increase in farm real
estate debt is probable in the 1970s. The
increase in farm mortgages in the 1960s was
associated with a strong uptrend in land
prices, a rise in the percentage of farmland
transfers that were credit-financed, and a rise
in the ratio of mortgage debt to purchase
price. Each of these factors may be less
significant in the future.
Farmland prices rose faster than the general price level during the 1960s, reflecting




Farm mortgage
interest rates rise
percent

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

* R a te s ch a rg e d b y m a jo rity o f a sso c ia tio n s e ffe c tiv e
th ird q u a rte r each y e a r .
f A v e r a g e ra te ch a rg e d b y m a jo r life in su ra n c e co m ­
p a n ie s on n e w lo a n s S e p tem b e r 30.

the impact of government programs, labor
saving technology, improved crop yields, the
drive toward farm enlargement, and the en­
croachment of urban developments on rural
areas. Early in 1969, farmland values were
60 percent higher than in 1960. By compari­
son, a measure of all prices of goods and
services (the gross national product “de­
flator”) rose 22 percent in the same period.
The softening in farmland prices in the past
year suggests this relationship has changed,
but this may be partly a reflection of reduced
credit availability and high interest rates. It
remains to be seen whether any future ad­
vance in land prices will be more in line with
changes in agricultural commodity prices
and the general price level.
Credit-financed sales of farmland rose
from 67 percent of all sales in 1960 to 80
percent in 1969. It is unlikely that the propor­
tion of credit-financed sales will continue to
rise significantly, because some transfers will

Business Conditions, Feb ruary 1970

always be for cash. Similarly, the rise in the
ratio of debt to purchase price on credit sales
of farmland from 65 percent in 1960 to 74
percent in 1969 leaves less margin for a
further increase. Also, unless interest rates
decline significantly, refinancings will be less
common, and refinancings have helped to
push debt ratios to present levels.
When credit demands are strong relative to
the supply, credit tends to flow to those bor­
rowers willing and able to pay the higher
interest rates. It appears that purchasers of
farm real estate are more sensitive to strongly
rising interest rates than most other borrowers
and, therefore, compete less vigorously for
borrowed funds when rates are high. In some
cases, demand has been limited by legal
interest rate ceilings.
Easing of usury ceilings that prevent
lenders from charging market rates of interest
to individuals would facilitate some farm
transfers through broadening the market for
farm debt. Three states of the Seventh District
—Illinois, Iowa, and Michigan—had usury
ceilings on real estate loans to individuals of
7 percent through part of 1969. In April
1969, the Iowa ceiling was raised to 9 per­




cent, and in July, the Illinois ceiling was
raised to 8 percent. Even so, these new higher
ceilings continue to restrict credit availability.
The statute was suspended for one year in
mid-1969 in Michigan for home mortgages
and land contracts but, apparently, not for
farm real estate loans.
The virtual withdrawal of life insurance
companies from farm real estate finance may
be only temporary, as in the past. Farm loans
of these companies declined in the late 1950s,
but rose again when credit conditions eased
in the early 1960s. However, the trend of
interest rates has been generally upward since
World War II, and there is no clear evidence
that interest rate levels will decline substan­
tially in the years ahead.
In summary, farm real estate debt will
probably rise substantially further in the
1970s, but at a slower rate than in the 1960s.
The shifts that have occurred among farm
mortgage lenders in recent years are likely to
continue. Shares of farm mortgages held by
individuals and the Federal Land Banks will
probably rise still further, while life insurance
companies are likely to continue to deemphasize these investments.

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Truth-in-Lending. A new, 15-ininute, customer-oriented filmstrip on the Truth-in Lend­

ing law, administered under Regulation Z of the Board of Governors of the Federal Re­
serve System, is now available. A filmstrip made available earlier is intended for lenders.
Copies of the film may be borrowed from the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago free
of charge. When submitting requests for the filmstrip, please indicate the dates desired,
with alternates, and the approximate size of the expected audience. Copies of an infor­
mation booklet for consumers will accompany the filmstrip.

is published monthly by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
George W . Cloos w a s p rim a rily responsible for the article "The trend of business," Ja c k L.
Hervey fo r "The EEC and U. S. ag ricu ltu re ," and Dennis B. Sharpe fo r "Farm m ortgages—The
im pact of tight credit."

BUSINESS CO N D ITIO N S

Subscriptions to Business Conditions are a v a ila b le to the public without charge. For in fo rm a­
tion concerning bulk m ailin g s, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.
16

Articles m ay be reprinted provided source is credited.