View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Business
Conditions
1962 February

Contents
The money in your pocket

5

International commodity
price problems

The Trend of Business

8

2-5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

OF

^ISusiness activity rose further in January
following a marked acceleration in the fourth
quarter of 1961. Steel continued to spearhead
the advance in both the nation and the Mid­
west, while auto production remained at a
high level. Output of industrial equipment
continued to improve moderately, and pro­
duction of farm equipment was increasing
again after cutbacks caused by excessive in­
ventories in the spring of last year. In addi­
tion, a number of Midwest centers reported
increases in defense work, particularly in
military vehicles and electronic equipment.

2

The business atmosphere in early 1962
contrasts sharply with the situation which
prevailed a year ago when aggregate activity
had been declining for several months. Most
businessmen are now confidently forecasting
increases in their sales and orders, and many
of them anticipate that favorable conditions
will prevail throughout the year. This opti­
mism is buttressed by evidence that retail
sales rose substantially in the final months of
1961 and that manufacturers’ order backlogs
continued to increase. In line with the faster
tempo of activity, business demand for bank
credit strengthened in December.
During the second half of 1961 inven­
tories of durable goods manufacturers, sea­
sonally adjusted, rose by about 300 million
dollars per month—over 3 billion on an an­
nual rate basis. Inventories probably are be­
ing increased at a faster rate currently, largely
because of attempts to build steel inventories
as a hedge against a possible strike. In Janu­




BUSINESS

ary steel output was at an annual rate of about
120 million tons compared with total produc­
tion of 100 million tons in all of 1961. Steel
output is expected to rise substantially fur­
ther in February and March. Industry fore­
casts, however, point to a maximum total
output of 115 million tons in 1962.
While the build-up of steel inventories is
adding impetus to the general business up­
swing at present, it is almost certain to be
followed by a cutback in production after
midyear whether or not a strike is called. Any
early indications that labor-management dif­
ficulties will be resolved without a long work
stoppage would tend to slow inventory buy­
ing and lessen prospects for substantial de­
cline in steel production later in the year.
Two factors which had clouded the eco­
nomic scene during much of 1961 became
more favorable in recent months. First, the
seasonally adjusted rate of unemployment
which had been “stuck” at just under 7 per
cent for almost a year dropped to 6.1 per
cent in November and remained at this re­
duced level in December. Second, retail sales
which had not responded fully to higher per­
sonal incomes from February through Sep­
tember, rose very sharply in the fourth
quarter.
The consum er com es th ro u g h

For the first quarter of 1961—the low point
for the 1960-61 recession—retail sales were
at an annual rate of 215 billion dollars. By
the third quarter the rate had increased to

Business Conditions, February 1962

217 billion dollars, about 1 per cent. But in
the fourth quarter sales rose 4.5 per cent to
227 billion.
The increase in retail sales in the fourth
quarter of 1961 marked the largest quarterto-quarter gain since the periods of “scare
buying” in the Korean war more than 10
years earlier. Consumers reduced the propor­
tion of current income saved and made great­
er use of instalment credit as they boosted
spending. Personal saving probably declined
to about 6 per cent of disposable income,
compared with an average of 7.4 per cent
for the past decade.
The upsurge in consumer outlays reflected
in part the failure of these expenditures to
increase more rapidly in earlier months de­
spite higher income. Consumer spending
usually rises rather slowly in the early stages
of a business recovery while employment is
increasing less rapidly than output. In addi­
tion, some individuals wish to rebuild savings
which were reduced during the period of un­
employment and shorter work weeks. More-

Rise in retail sales
in fourth quarter of 1961
was largest in recent years

1958




1959

I9 6 0

over, it takes time to create confidence that
the current rise in activity will continue for
some time.
In 1958-59 retail sales increased only 2.5
per cent in the first six months of the up­
swing and 5.5 per cent in the second six
months. It now appears that sluggishness of
retail sales in the face of rapid general eco­
nomic improvement was much more signifi­
cant throughout most of 1961 than in the
1958-59 recovery period.
Why did retail buying revive so slowly in
1961? There are a number of possible ex­
planations. One factor was that unemploy­
ment, although never so high as the peak rate
in 1958, was a problem in more areas and
was at a relatively high level for a longer time.
Limited availability of 1962 model cars,
as a result of strikes in September and Oc­
tober, coupled with small holdover invento­
ries of 1961 models, also held down sales in
the late summer and early fall. As output rose
the annual rate of sales, including imports,
averaged close to 7 million units in Novem­
ber and December,
compared with a total
of less than 6 million
for the year as a whole.
This development was
primarily responsible
for the 9 per cent gain
in sales at durable
goods stores, including
automobile dealers, in
the October-December
period. Sales at other
kinds of stores rose 2.4
per cent during this
period.
Another influence
on consumer buying
during 1961— inca­
pable of measurement

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

but probably significant nonetheless—was the
Berlin crisis. Studies of consumer behavior
indicate that tension and uncertainty cause a
deferral of major purchases while further
developments are awaited. Moreover, during
the summer and fall some reservists and na­
tional guardsm en were called to active serv­
ice and draft calls were stepped up. Com­
monly, the shift from civilian to military life
means reduced family income. As apprehen­
sion over the outbreak of war tended to abate
in the final months of 1961, draft calls were
reduced and it was suggested that national
guard units might soon be deactivated. With
these developments, came a marked strength­
ening in retail trade.
C h ristm as sa le s fin ish e d stro n g

4

December is always the largest month for
retail sales because of Christmas gift buying.
This is particularly true of department stores
which sell about 15 per cent of their year’s
total volume in December—more than twice
as much as the average for the other 11
months of the year.
Until the final two weeks of the Christmas
season, department store sales had been dis­
appointing. Late shoppers, however, more
than made up for the earlier hesitancy. In the
four weeks ending December 30, department
store sales for the nation were 8 per cent
above the record level of 1960, while in the
Seventh District they were up 5 per cent.
Department store sales within the District
were strongest in the smaller cities which
serve rural areas. (Farm income had risen
substantially in 1961.) The sales gain for a
group of smaller centers in the Midwest was
9 per cent in the last four weeks of the year
compared with increases of 2 to 5 per cent
in the major metropolitan areas. For 1961
as a whole, department store sales in the
District were 1 per cent above 1960 as com­




pared with a 3 per cent rise for the nation.
Favorable sales results in the Christmas
season also were reported by apparel stores,
mail order houses and other establishments
which do a large holiday business. Because
the surge in sales came late in the year, inven­
tories were reduced more than usual at many
stores. As a result, markdown sales in January
were less prevalent than in recent years.
The o u tlo o k fo r h o gs

Hog farmers had a good year in 1961. As
a result of high pork prices, farmers’ receipts
from hogs increased 6 per cent to 2.9 billion
dollars and accounted for about 8 per cent
of total income from farm marketings last
year. In the Midwest, where hogs are the
major source of income for many farmers,
the results were even more favorable, and
the prospects for 1962 are good. This spring
farmers are planning to increase farrowings
of pigs by about 3 per cent. Since this follows
a 4 per cent increase in pigs farrowed last
fall, the per capita pork supply in 1962 will
be only slightly above last year.
This is a relatively slow rise in production
in view of the favorable prices. Last fall the
market value of 100 pounds of live hog was
equal to the value of about 16 bushels of
corn. In the past, hog-corn ratios as high as
this have generally been followed by an 8 to
10 per cent increase in the number of pigs
farrowed the following spring.
To a large extent, the small increase in
hog production reflects the effects of the Gov­
ernment’s 1961 feed grain program. Com
Belt farmers planted 18 per cent fewer acres
of corn last year and the Government raised
its price support on com from $1.06 to $1.20
a bushel. Many hog producers scaled their
hog production plans in accordance with the
reduction in acreage and the expected higher
prices for corn. By the end of 1961, when it

Business Conditions, February 1962

was apparent that even with less acreage the
corn crop would be the second largest in his­
tory and only 7 per cent below 1960’s record
crop, hog producers had already made their
plans for the 1962 spring pig crop. This as­
sures favorable hog prices during most of the
current year. But with the large 1961 corn

crop providing ample “raw materials” and
the unexpected low corn prices in recent
weeks (reflecting large Government sales of
“certificate” corn under the 1961 feed grain
program), Corn Belt farmers should have
ample incentive for expanding hog produc­
tion substantially next fall.

The money in your pocket
1 5 y the end of January the Christmas bulge
in currency in circulation had largely disap­
peared. Each year as the Christmas shopping
season unfurls the amount of “pocket money”
withdrawn from the nation’s commercial
banks rises sharply. Between the end of Oc­
tober and the second half of December 1961,
the public’s holdings of currency (including
coins) rose 900 million dollars. To accom­
modate this increased flow, commercial banks
boosted their holdings of vault cash by about
300 million dollars, bringing the total amount
of currency outside the Federal Reserve
Banks and the Treasury to a record 34 billion
at year-end.
But the Christmas bulge is short-lived.
Once the spurt in spending has passed, in­
dividuals, banks and other businesses quickly
reduce their holdings of currency. By the
latter part of January, with its mission ac­
complished, the bulk of the Christmas money
had been returned to the Federal Reserve
Banks. On the basis of past experience, the
amount in circulation is expected to continue
to decline into February to a seasonal low,
roughly 1.4 billion dollars below the seasonal
high in December.
Similar, though smaller, short-run changes



in the volume of currency in circulation oc­
cur around other national holidays and even
over weekends. These have an important im­
pact on the nation’s banks. Most apparent,
of course, is the physical task of keeping the
public supplied with the kinds and amounts
of currency needed in each area and at all
times. In 1960, for example, the 12 Federal
Reserve Banks received and counted nearly
10 billion coins and close to 5 billion pieces
of paper currency sent in by the commercial
banks. The total value of this money handled
during the year was about equal to the aver­
age amount outstanding. An even greater
volume is handled by the commercial banks.
Rough estimates based upon short-run
changes in vault cash holdings of individual
banks indicate that, on the average, banks
pay out currency and coin to their customers
about three times for each time it is shipped
to a Federal Reserve Bank.
Shifts in the amount of currency in circu­
lation also affect bank reserves. While the
impact is less apparent to the users of money
than the job of filling the current demand, it
is important to the individual banks and the
monetary system over-all. A withdrawal of
deposits in the form of currency or coin re-

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

duces bank reserves and, in the absence of
offsetting new reserves, would produce a con­
traction of deposits and earning assets of
commercial banks several times the amount
of currency withdrawn. A deposit of currency
and coin, on the other hand, increases re­
serves and, again barring offsets, would per­
mit an expansion of deposits and earning
assets several times greater than the amount
of the currency deposited. Currency flows,
therefore, are important considerations to
banks in the management of their reserves
and to the Federal Reserve System in admin­
istering monetary policy.
P attern s in cash circulation

6

Of shortest duration is the “cash” drain
that banks generally experience at the end
of each week and the return inflow at the
beginning of the following week. Vault cash
holdings of all member banks, in an average
week, drop by roughly 15 per cent on Friday.
By the close of business on Monday, how­
ever, a net inflow typically restores vault cash
to its previous level.
There is also a fairly regular intramonthly
pattern in currency in circulation. Currency
in the hands of the public is higher in the first
half of most months than in the second half,
no doubt reflecting the payment of bills due
around the first of the month. The reverse is
true for banks’ holding of vault cash.
Superimposed on the weekly and monthly
patterns are the large increases in cash in the
hands of the public that occur at the time of
major holidays, such as Easter, Memorial
Day, the Fourth of July, Labor Day and
Christmas. Individuals obviously need extra
cash over the holidays when the banks are
closed and expenditures for travel, lodging
away from home and entertainment rise. As
noted above, the most pronounced seasonal
swing in currency occurs during the Christmas




shopping season. During this period, banks as
well as individuals and businesses add sub­
stantially to their cash positions.
The increase in aggregate holdings of cur­
rency during holiday periods does not affect
all bills and coins to the same degree. During
the Christmas season, for example, the de­
mand for all coins and bills up to and includ­
ing $100 rises, but demand for the smaller
bills increases more than for the larger ones.
This reflects the fact that consumer spending,
especially for lower-priced durable and non­
durable goods and the use of currency for
gifts, reaches a seasonal peak during the
weeks just before Christmas. These uses
chiefly involve currency in denominations of
$20 and less.
Individuals and businesses hold whatever
volume of currency they desire, limited only
by their ability to pay for it. Commercial
banks serve merely as agents through which
the choice of the public for a greater or lesser
amount of currency is expressed. Flows of
currency between the public and individual
banks depend primarily upon the kinds of
customers the banks have. Banks which serve
mainly customers who make the bulk of their
payments by check and hold little money in
the form of currency keep a different propor­
tion of their assets in the form of vault cash
than banks which serve customers who make
a large proportion of payments in currency.
The holdings of vault cash by member banks
in the Seventh Federal Reserve District range
from a low of less than 1 per cent of total
assets to a high of about 5 per cent.
Trends in currency circulation

Of greater interest perhaps than the shortrun shifts are the changes in the public’s
holdings of currency over a period of years,
particularly changes in relation to the total
money supply and total spending. While cur-

Business Conditions, February 1962

rency and coin are the only kinds of money
held by many people—those not having
checking accounts—this kind of money ac­
counts for only one-fifth of the total. About
four-fifths is held in the form of commercial
bank demand deposits. In 1961, for example,
demand deposits, other than those of the
U. S. Government and of individual banks
held in other banks, averaged 113 billion dol­
lars. The currency and coin in the hands of
the public was on the order of 29 billion
dollars. Moreover, over many years the pro­
portion of the money supply held as demand
deposits has tended to rise—from less than
75 per cent in the early postwar period to
80 per cent today.
While short-run changes in the volume of
currency in circulation appear to be linked
to changes in consumer spending, it would be
unrealistic to expect a close parallel between
the two over long periods of time. Factors
unrelated in any direct way to consumer
spending have been associated with changes
in currency holdings at various times. World
War II for example, brought a substantial
growth in the demand for currency, particu­
larly $10, $20, $50 and $100 bills.
During the postwar period, particularly in
the past decade, the volume of currency in
circulation has increased less rapidly than
consumer expenditures. This probably re­
flects a number of factors: the large wartime
rise in demand for currency, the postwar
growth of checkbook spending and the growth
of various types of credit instruments, includ­
ing charge accounts, revolving credit plans
and credit cards.
In the past decade or so, the use of credit
for small but regular purchases such as gaso­
line and lodging and meals away from home
has increased. Periodic settlement with the
creditor typically involves payment by check,
not currency. Then, too, more and more peo


During the postwar period, coins in
circulation have risen more rapidly than
large bills or consumer spending
billion d o lla rs

billion dollars

pie have acquired checking accounts and are
using them more intensively.
The increasing use of substitutes for cur­
rency and coin has affected the various de­
nominations of currency quite differently. In
recent years, largely as a result of the wide­
spread use of coin-operated vending ma­
chines, the amount of coins in circulation has
risen at a faster pace than consumer spending
for nondurable goods (see chart). Trade
sources estimate that vending machines dis­
pense a sixth of the cigarettes sold, a fifth of
the candy bars and a quarter of the soft
drinks. In addition, coin-operated machines
are used for an increasing variety of services,

7

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

such as payments on toll roads, sales of pack­
aged meals and for laundry, dry cleaning and
other personal services.
Since 1951, the volume of $1 bills, on the
other hand, has risen at the same rate as
consumer spending for nondurables, while
$5, $10 and $20 bills have grown at no­
ticeably slower rates. The number of bills of
$500 and higher denominations in circulation
has declined even though personal income
and spending have risen. This may indicate
a continuing decline in large currency hoards
accumulated by some individuals during
World War II.
Of greater economic significance than just
the amount of currency and coin is the use
made of it. Unfortunately, very little is known

about this. The number of times demand de­
posits are spent in a given month or year can
be determined quite readily. In 1961, for
example, aggregate demand deposits at all
commercial banks were spent or “turned
over” about 30 times. On the other hand, the
number of times currency and coin “changes
hands” cannot be readily determined as there
is little information available on transactions
of this type. It appears, however, that the
turnover of currency is considerably less than
that of demand deposits. Also, the turnover
of currency and coin probably is less sensitive
to changes in business activity than is that of
demand deposits, but there is little specific
evidence available to support these general
impressions.

International commodity
price problems

8

j \ d a n y commodities traded in large volume
in international markets have long been sub­
ject to rather abrupt and wide price fluctua­
tions. For industrial raw materials this in­
stability has largely reflected changes in de­
mand over the course of the business cycle in
major industrial countries, while for agricul­
tural foodstuffs, it has more closely reflect­
ed changes in supply owing to the vagaries of
weather, crop diseases or other natural events.
If these price fluctuations occurred within
a generally rising trend, the consequences for
economic and political stability in raw material producing countries might not be great,




but most leading international commodity
price indexes have reflected a downward price
trend from the abnormal highs reached during
the Korean emergency over a decade ago.
Currently, many important international
commodities are described as being in “dis­
tress.” In January of this year the spot (cash)
price of sugar in the world “free market”
dropped below 2.1 cents a pound—the lowest
since 1941—following collapse of the Geneva
International Sugar Conference over failure
to agree on export quotas for 1962 and 1963.
New York spot prices for key grades of cocoa
and coffee are down 48 and 31 per cent,

Business Conditions, February 1962

respectively, from average prices in 1958.
Softness also has dominated international
markets for industrial materials. The spot
price of crude rubber in New York is cur­
rently about 25 per cent below the average
in 1960. Lead prices have been under pres­
sure owing to overproduction and high in­
ventories. In November 1961 the spot price
of lead in the London market dipped below
8 cents a pound—the lowest in 15 years. Tin,
the major exception, is up about 20 per cent
in price since the end of 1960.
To many observers, the absence of any ap­
preciable price strength in international com­
modity markets has been puzzling, especially

in view of the continued high level of business
activity in Europe and Japan, the vigorous
recovery of the United States economy since
the early part of 1961 and the increased inter­
national tension associated with Berlin and
fighting in the Congo.
The K o re a n e xperien ce

Following the outbreak of the Korean War
in June 1950, basic commodity prices ad­
vanced sharply. This tended to confirm the
belief, on the part of some observers, that the
world was headed for a prolonged shortage of
many primary commodities. In January 1951
the President appointed a special committee
(known as the Paley Commission)
“to study the materials problem of
the United States and its relation
Since 1953 primary commodity price indexes
to the free and friendly nations of
have drifted downward despite continued
the world.” The commission re­
growth in Western industrial countries
port, submitted in June 1952,
warned: “There is no blinking the
per cent, 1953 =100
fact that the United States and the
free nations face a more difficult
supply situation in the future than
in the past.”
The United States and British
governments accelerated their
stockpiling programs to assure
adequate domestic supplies of
“strategic and critical” raw mate­
rials. Purchase obligations issued
by the United States stockpile
agency rose from 253 million dol­
lars in fiscal 1948 to a peak of 2.1
billion in fiscal 1951. These pur­
chase contracts and the sharp price
advances to which they contribut­
ed encouraged the expansion of
existing raw materials supply
sources as well as the development
of new ones throughout the West­
ern world.



Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

But primary commodity prices quickly re­
treated from their Korean peaks. Reuter’s
index of primary commodity prices quoted on
British markets and weighted according to
their relative importance in international trade
(1953= 100) declined from a high of 126 in
April 1951 to 104 by the end of 1952. By
mid-195 3 Reuter’s index had receded to 100
—the level prevailing at the start of the Ko­
rean War. In the United States, by this time
the Bureau of Labor Statistics index of spot
commodity prices also had returned to its
pre-Korean level.
Since mid-195 3 most major international
primary commodity indexes, while fluctuat­
ing considerably, have continued to drift
downward. This has occurred against a back­
ground of recurring international crises in­
volving Suez, Lebanon, Cuba, Laos and, more
recently, Berlin and the Congo and continued
vigorous economic growth in Western indus­
trial countries.
From sh o rta g e to su rplu s

10

The above has essentially reflected a grad­
ual shift in the world’s supply picture from
one of shortage to abundance.
On the demand side, stockpiling of strate­
gic raw materials by the United States and
Great Britain has dropped off dramatically.
Purchase obligations issued by the United
States stockpiling agency averaged less than
30 million dollars annually during fiscal years
1959-61, compared with an average of about
1.1 billion a year during the Korean emer­
gency. This country in recent years has begun
to make large net sales of crude rubber, cop­
per and nickel from its strategic stockpile.
The impact on prices, of course, is the reverse
of that when the stockpile was being built up.
Changes in patterns of industrial activity
and improvements in technology also have
tended to reduce Western dependence upon




many primary commodities. In the United
States, Western Europe and even Japan, post­
war industrial growth has been most pro­
nounced in the highly complex chemical, elec­
tronic and metal products industries which
have required substantially greater inputs of
capital and skilled labor in relation to inputs
of primary raw materials. Technological ad­
vance also has facilitated greater economies
in the use of raw materials and has led to
increased substitution of new or “processed”
materials for traditional ones normally sup­
plied by the primary producing countries.
World supplies of many basic commodities
continued to rise with advances in agricultural
productivity in both temperate and tropical
zone countries, improvements in mining tech­
nology and the emergence of new areas of
production. In many instances the develop­
ment of new supply sources was an integral
part of the long-range economic development
programs of the newly emerging nations in
Africa and Asia.
Som e k e y c om m o d itie s

Although world production and consump-

Rubber
thousand long tons

cents per lb.

Business Conditions, February 1962

tion of rubber (both crude and synthetic)
have remained approximately in balance in
recent years, the New York spot price of
crude rubber has declined from an average
of about 37 cents a pound in both 1959 and
1960 to about 28 cents in recent months.
Rapid gains in production and improvement
in the quality of synthetic rubber in Western
industrial countries have exercised a dampen­
ing effect on crude rubber prices.
Output of synthetic rubber in the United
States has risen nearly 220 per cent from the
average of 1948-50 and now accounts for
over 70 per cent of all new rubber consump­
tion in this country, compared with about
42 per cent in the early postwar period. Large
net sales of rubber from the United States
and British strategic stockpiles also have
tended to depress crude rubber prices. The
U. S. Government has launched a long-range
program to dispose of about 500,000 tons of
crude rubber. Under a recent revision, rub­
ber sales will be suspended for one month
whenever the average market price for the
preceding month was below 28 cents a pound.
World cocoa production reached a record
1.2 million long tons in the 1960-61 crop
year reflecting exceptionally favorable grow­
ing conditions in Ghana and Nigeria. This
was the second consecutive year in which
world cocoa output exceeded 1 million tons
and represented an increase of roughly 29 per
cent over the 1958-59 crop.
Consumption of cocoa also has expanded
vigorously but not as fast as production. In
1961 cocoa consumption equaled an esti­
mated 1 million long tons, representing an in­
crease of about 18 per cent since 1958. This
has resulted in steadily increasing surpluses
—totaling 50,000 long tons in 1959, 100,000
in 1960 and about 200,000 in 1961. The cost
of carrying these surpluses has largely fallen
upon producing countries where national co­



coa marketing boards have attempted to sup­
port prices by withholding production from
marketing channels.
Under the impact of heavy crop carry-overs
and aggressive selling by leading African pro­
ducers, the New York spot price of Accra
cocoa slid from an average of 36 cents a
pound in 1959 to just under 20 cents in Sep­
tember 1961—the lowest in 11 years. By
December, however, the price had recovered

Cocoa
thousand long tons

cents per lb.

to 28 cents a pound, reflecting estimates of
a lower cocoa crop for 1962 and a growing
belief that leading cocoa producing and con­
suming nations would sign an international
cocoa agreement. As drafted by the U. N.
Cocoa Study Group, the agreement would
attempt to stabilize cocoa prices by applying
export quotas on cocoa beans, cocoa butter
and other cocoa derivatives. Since the first
of the year, cocoa prices have weakened no­
ticeably with the New York spot price declin­
ing to about 22 cents a pound in response to
upward revisions of the 1962 crop forecast.
The problem for coffee is essentially simi-

]]

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

12

lar to that of cocoa. In recent years, bumper
crops and aggressive selling by new African
producers have kept coffee prices under pres­
sure. The New York spot price for a key
grade of Brazilian coffee (Santos No. 4) de­
clined from an average of 57 cents a pound
in 1957 to about 37 cents in both 1959 and
1960. During 1961 the price declined slightly
from an average of 37 cents a pound in the
first part of the year to 34 cents by the end of
the year.
World exportable production of coffee rose
rapidly from an average 31 million bags (132
pounds each) a year in the early Fifties to a
peak of 66 million in the 1959-60 crop year.
Production for the 1961-62 season is esti­
mated at 61 million bags— or roughly double
the average level of production a decade ear­
lier. During this period, however, world cof­
fee imports, which provide a rough indication
of demand, increased from an average 33
million bags a year to an estimated 45 million
in the current year, or 36 per cent.
As a result, surplus coffee stocks in pro­
ducing countries have risen from virtually nil
a decade ago to a record 64 million bags as
of June 30, 1961, with an addition to the
carry-over of roughly 16 million bags indi­
cated for the current crop year. In Brazil,
which has accounted for the bulk of the stock­
piling, and Colombia surplus coffee stocks
are tightly controlled by government agencies
but in other producing regions this is done
largely by individual growers and merchants.
In some of these countries, producers are now
experiencing major difficulties in financing
their coffee inventories.
One may be puzzled by the relative sta­
bility of spot coffee prices since mid-1959.
To a large extent, it reflects the effects of the
International Coffee Agreement signed in
September 1959 to supersede the Latin American Coffee Agreement. The agreement,




whose members account for over 90 per cent
of the world’s production of coffee, attempts
to stabilize the market by assigning export
quotas among members in relation to expect­
ed demand in traditional foreign markets.

Coffee

In spite of these efforts, coffee prices have
declined about 11 per cent since the first part
of 1961 and the current price structure re­
mains highly precarious in view of the enor­
mous world coffee surplus. A sharp price drop
would doubtless occur if Brazil curtailed
stockpiling and decided to push exports more
vigorously, especially in the United States, to
regain exports lost to the new African pro­
ducers.
Against this background of uncertainty,
coffee growers have tried to develop ways for
strengthening the present international agree­
ment and have enlisted the support of key
consumer countries—notably the United
States. In December 1961 a committee of the
U. N. Coffee Study Group, representing 44
producer and consumer nations, submitted a
draft of a five-year support plan which would

Business Conditions, February 1962

replace the present international pact due to
expire this year. In addition to providing for
export quotas geared closely to world imports,
closer policing of surplus coffee stocks and
penalties for selling “below the established
minimum prices,” the plan would provide for
an import control system under which con­
sumer countries would be obligated to main­
tain import restrictions against shipments
from nonmember countries or from member
producer countries who had violated their
export quotas.
The price of tin “went through the roof”
in June 1961 when the buffer stock manager
of the International Tin Council, which man­
ages the International Tin Agreement, an­
nounced in London that he had exhausted his
stocks of tin through sales aimed at keeping
the price from rising above the IT A ceiling
price of £,880 a long ton ($1.10 a pound).
The IT A floor price for tin was £ 7 3 0 a long
ton ($.91 a pound). The buffer stock man­
ager has authority to buy tin when demand is
weak and sell when demand is strong so as
to smooth out price fluctuations. Purchases
are made with funds advanced by IT A pro­
ducer members.1
By August the New York spot price of tin
reached a high of $1.25 a pound under con­
tinued heavy buying. In subsequent months
the price has retreated to the current level of
about $1.20 a pound, which is still 20 cents
above the price prevailing at the end of 1960.
All this may seem strange since production
or supplies were free to rise owing to the fact
that during the second half of 1960 the Tin
1In January of this year the International Tin
Council voted to extend the ITA on a provisional
basis until the end of June and to raise both the
ceiling and floor prices which govern operations of
the buffer stock manager. The ceiling price was in­
creased to £.965 a long ton ($1.21 a pound) and
the floor price to £ 7 9 0 a long ton ($.99 a pound).
Ratification by member countries is required.



Council had removed all export quota re­
strictions imposed upon producer members.
Nonetheless, world mine production in 1961
is estimated to be unchanged from the pre­
vious year’s output or just under 180,000
long tons. Meanwhile, the demand for tin has
been rising. In 1960 world tin consumption
reached a record 181,000 long tons—up 10
per cent over 1959—with a further increase
of 5 per cent estimated for 1961.
The failure of tin output to respond to
demand and price increases is traceable to a
number of factors. Production flexibility has
been severely impaired by nationalization of
mines in Bolivia and Indonesia and political
turmoil in the Congo. In other important tin
producing countries, notably Malaya, Nigeria
and Thailand, a broadening range of attrac­
tive investment alternatives compete against

Tin
thousond long tons

cents per lb.

tin for scarce capital resources. Finally, un­
certainty regarding the outlook for tin prices
has been stressed as a further deterrent to in­
creased output in these countries. According
to trade sources, tin prices would nrobably

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

stage a hasty retreat from present levels if
Bolivia, Indonesia and the Congo entered the
market with increased offerings or the United
States began to sell tin from its substantial
stockpile. In September 1961, Government
officials asked Congress for permission to re­
lease 50,000 long tons of tin from the stock­
pile. Although Congress adjourned without
taking action, it is expected to give further
consideration to this proposal during the cur­
rent session.
Effects on d e v e lo p m e n t a n d tra d e

14

The pattern of ebbing prices for many of
the world’s important primary commodities
stands in sharp contrast with the firmness of
prices of manufactured goods sold by West­
ern industrial nations. With few exceptions,
primary producing countries are getting less
for their exports and are paying more for their
imports, while at the same time their longrange economic development programs have
become increasingly more ambitious. Hence,
the problem of how to carry out the develop­
ment programs which were largely predicated
on the expectation that the pattern of rising
export earnings of the early 1950’s would
continue. Financing has been met in part by
increased loans from the various international
lending agencies, grants and credits extended
by major Western governments, plus a high
level of private foreign investment. The pri­
mary producing countries have furnished the
balance by drawing down their foreign ex­
change reserves.
A number of countries, however, have been
compelled to defer or curtail planned devel­
opment projects as well as adopt rigorous im­
port and foreign exchange controls to protect
badly depleted foreign exchange reserves and
contain internal inflationary pressures result­
ing from deficit financing.
For major Western industrial countries




lower primary commodity prices had a two­
fold effect. On the one hand, it improved their
terms of trade—they had to sell less to pur­
chase a given quantity of raw materials—and
thus helped to offset the impact of large capi­
tal outflows on their over-all balance of pay­
ments positions. On the other hand, growth
in exports of manufactured goods was slowed
as some primary producing countries cut back
imports to conserve foreign exchange reserves.
The burden of these cutbacks largely fell
upon capital goods manufacturers, particular­
ly in the United States, creating additional
problems for industries that had large excess
capacity.
Further complicating the situation was the
risk that the Soviet bloc might offer more
“trade and aid” deals to hard-pressed primary
producing nations. Many of these countries
not only produce a number of important items
in short supply in the Soviet bloc—citrus
fruits, rubber, cotton, sugar, cocoa—but also
offer a convenient market for Soviet ma­
chinery, petroleum and technical assistance.
Substantial long-term barter transactions al­
ready have been conducted with Egypt (cot­
ton) and Cuba (sugar), and possible deals
with African cocoa producers have been ru­
mored in European trade circles.
S tro n ge r price p ro p s?

During the last twelve months, world-wide
concern for the economic problems of pri­
mary producing countries has sharpened
considerably and renewed efforts have been
directed toward finding ways for improving
the effectiveness of existing commodity price
stabilization agreements and adopting sup­
port schemes for commodities not presently
covered by international agreements. As not­
ed above, United Nations study groups have
drawn up drafts of an international cocoa
agreement and a stronger international coffee

Business Conditions, February 1962

agreement for approval by member consum­
ing and producing countries. Leading oil pro­
ducing nations in Latin America and the Mid­
dle East are vitally interested in adopting a
strong pact to stabilize crude oil prices in the
international market.
Another noteworthy development has been
the marked shift in the U. S. Government’s
attitude toward organized intervention in in­
ternational commodity markets. In the past
this country had generally confined its sup­
port to international stabilization schemes
covering commodities which it produced or
exported in large amounts—it is a member
of the international sugar and wheat agree­
ments. But in May 1961 the Administration
informed the U. N. Commission on Inter­
national Commodity Trade that it was will­
ing to consider “any reasonable proposal”
for attacking the problems of international
commodity markets. Three months later, at
the Inter-American Economic Conference in
Uruguay, the United States agreed to partici­
pate in a “workable international coffee agree­
ment” and to use its good offices to urge “par­
ticipation by other coffee consuming coun­
tries.” It also promised to consider partici­
pation in the International Tin Agreement
and examine the problems of other commodi­
ties important to the export earnings of Latin
American countries.
The Administration has followed this up
by attempting to link the objective of greater
stability for international commodity markets
with its over-all foreign aid program. In De­
cember the Secretary of State said: “There
is no sense whatever in taxing Americans for
foreign aid if we meanwhile pursue trade
policies which undermine the prospects for
economic development. It should be remem­
bered that a drop of a few cents in world
commodity prices could wipe out any con­
tribution we might make through our aid in



helping the underdeveloped country con­
cerned.”
Q u e stio n s a n d p ro b le m s

The determination to seek stronger props
for basic commodity prices raises some inter­
esting questions. Does it reflect concern over
“instability” or simply “low” prices? Under­
standably, primary producing countries would
like to see prices restored to the high levels
prevailing roughly a decade ago but these
prices were abnormally high, reflecting the
shortages of the early postwar period as well
as the “scare” buying of the Korean emer­
gency. Are consumer interests to be ade­
quately safeguarded or represented in the new
price propping arrangements? Finally, what
is to guide capital investment if production
and marketing of primary commodities are
subject to strict controls?
Commodity price stabilization has been
comparatively successful where production
or distribution is concentrated in a few pow­
erful hands, e.g., nickel and diamonds, or
where the price propping agency has access
to virtually unlimited financial resources, e.g.,
the U. S. Commodity Credit Corporation. But
when production is widely dispersed, as in the
case of sugar, tin, cocoa and coffee, the for­
mulation of closely knit price stabilization
schemes is a much more difficult undertaking.
To be effective, such schemes would have
to have the power to regulate production in
all important producing areas and control ex­
ports and imports through strict quotas.
The task has been complicated, however,
by the emergence of many new producing
areas during the postwar period. It is worth
noting that certain African cocoa and coffee
producers have been reluctant to join stabili­
zation schemes championed by the long-es­
tablished producing areas in Latin America.
Any price increases resulting from support

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

16

operations would doubtless intensify the
search for substitutes, e.g., plastics and alu­
minum for tin, as well as encourage the devel­
opment of new sources of production. These
factors might ultimately necessitate further re­
striction of output in established supply areas
participating in the agreement. In addition,
there would have to be complete cooperation
on the part of consuming countries to embar­
go imports from nonmember supply areas as
well as producing members who had violated
their export quotas. Primary producing na­
tions feel that consumer nations should accept
this responsibility. Yet, the temptation to buy
at the “best” price is hard to resist.
Formation of the European Common Mar­
ket has introduced an additional element of
uncertainty into the price stabilization pic­
ture. As the Common Market external tariff
comes into effect, African countries, which
were the former overseas territories of the
European “Six,” will have a decided advan­
tage over Latin American nations. Many
African nonferrous metals and tropical agri­
cultural products will enter the Common
Market duty free or at low rates while those
from Latin America will be subject to the
higher common tariff as well as quota restric­
tions. Both Latin America and the United
States continue to “petition” the Common
Market to amend the situation but the Latin
American nations are becoming impatient
and have suggested that the United States
impose trade curbs on European goods as a
retaliatory measure.
The foregoing does not appear to be con­
sistent with the desired goal of freer inter­
national trade which the Western countries
continue to support as general policy. It would
be unfortunate if the move toward stronger
commodity price stabilization arrangements
produced nothing more than increased hostility among all nations. It also would be un­




fortunate if these schemes maintained a price
umbrella over inefficient producers.
Western industrial nations are actively con­
sidering a program of increased economic aid
to offset declines in foreign exchange earn­
ings experienced by primary producing coun­
tries and the adoption of freer trade policies
with respect to agricultural products and in­
dustrial raw materials. This seems to offer a
more practical approach for solving the prob­
lems posed by declining international com­
modity prices. But balance of payments dif­
ficulties confronting Britain and the United
States severely limit the amount of additional
assistance that may be forthcoming from these
two countries. In the circumstances, other
European creditor nations are being urged to
assume a larger role in foreign aid and invest­
ment.
The achievement of lasting benefits, how­
ever, will require the adoption of appropriate
domestic measures in the primary producing
countries. These would include curbs on
inflation so that rising costs do not price
exports out of world markets, removal of
restrictions on foreign private investment,
greater diversification of export earning ac­
tivities and tailoring development programs
more closely to current prospective levels of
foreign exchange earnings.

Business C o n d itio n s is p u b l i s h e d m o n t h l y b y
th e

f e d e r a l

r e s e r v e

b a n k

o f

Ch

ic a g o

.

Sub­

s c r ip tio n s a r e a v a ila b le to th e p u b lic w ith o u t
c h a r g e . F o r in f o r m a t io n c o n c e r n i n g b u l k m a i l ­
in g s to b a n k s , b u s i n e s s o r g a n i z a t i o n s a n d e d u ­
c a ti o n a l i n s t i t u t i o n s , w r i t e : R e s e a r c h D e p a r t ­
m e n t, F e d e r a l R e s e r v e R a n k o f C h ic a g o , B o x
8 3 4 , C h ic a g o 9 0 , I llin o is . A r t i c l e s m a y b e r e ­
p r i n t e d p r o v i d e d s o u r c e is c r e d i t e d .