View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

an e c o n o m ic re v ie w b y th e F e d e ra l R eserve B a n k o f C hicago







The Farmers Home
Administration

3

Because o f the swiftness with which
the operations and program
emphasis o f this 40-year old federal
agency have changed, the rapid ex­
pansion o f its activities in recent
years has gone largely unnoticed.

How useful are export
promotion programs?

9

Over the years the U.S. Government
has established a number of agencies
to facilitate exports. Some o f these
agencies and their programs, and
their place in a rapidly changing
world, are discussed herein.

S ubscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public free of charge. For
inform ation concerning bulk mailings, address inquiries to Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, P. O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.
A rticles may be reprinted provided source is credited. Please provide the bank’s
Research Department with a copy of any material in which an article is reprinted.

3

Business Conditions, December 1975

le Farmers Fiome
Administration
The Farm ers Home Administration
capped its fortieth anniversary as a federal
credit agency by extending a record $5.5
billion in loans and grants to rural areas in
1975. The new mark reflects a number of
changes in the operations and the program
emphasis over the long and varied history
of the agency. Prior to the early sixties the
annual lending volume of the agency never
exceeded $400 million and the bulk of its
activity was directed at farmers unable to
obtain financing from other lenders.
The recent history of the Farmers
Home Administration (FmHA) has been
influenced mainly by services imple­
mented by Congressional concerns over
rural development. As a result, the annual
volume of funds extended by the FmHA
has soared, paced largely by ventures in
financing rural housing and community
development. Well over one-half of the $33
billion extended by the FmHA throughout
its history was extended in the past five
years. Nearly one-half of the funds extend­
ed by the FmHA are now channeled
through rural housing programs. Funds
distributed through the expanded com­
munity facility programs and the relative­
ly new business and industrial develop­
ment program absorb an additional onefifth, while the remaining one-third of the
funds are channeled through the various
programs available to farmers.
The surge in funds extended, as well as
the shift in program emphasis, has been
associated with significant changes in the
lending practices and funding operations
of the FmHA. Direct loans funded by Con­
gressional appropriations were long the




mainstay of the agency. But now, virtually
all the funds extended by the FmHA are
tied to insured or guaranteed loans which
are funded by private investors and
lenders. Moreover, the growing impor­
tance of guaranteed loans and the in­
creased emphasis on participating in loans
made by other lenders represent a marked
departure from the long-held view that the
FmHA was a secondary lender, serving
only those unable to obtain credit else­
where. In some programs the FmHA now
serves as a primary lender. Because of the
sw iftness w ith w hich fundamental
changes have occurred, the rapid expan­
sion of the FmHA has gone largely un­
noticed except by these closely associated
with the organization.

A brief history
The history o f the FmHA dates back to
the Resettlement Administration (RA) es­
tablished by President Franklin Roosevelt
in 1935. RA programs were designed to
resettle and rehabilitate a rural population
racked by drought and depression. Rela­
tive to its lineage with FmHA, the RA is
best known for instituting a supervised
credit program that provided short-term
loans and grants to low-income farmers—
the forerunner to the FmHA’s current farm
operating loan program. The unique
p hilosoph y of the supervised credit
program, and one that has served as the
backbone of most FmHA programs, was
that (1) funds were directed toward lowincome farmers unable to obtain credit
elsewhere and (2) borrowers were pro­

4

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

vid ed t e c h n ic a l an d su p erv isory
assistance to help convert marginal farms
into self-sufficient ones.
The success of the supervised credit
program was a major factor behind the
1937 enactment of the Bankhead-Jones
Farm Tenant Act. The act instituted a lowinterest, supervised, 40-year farm owner­
ship loan program, the precursor to the
farm ownership program operated by the
FmHA today.
T he n a m e o f the R esettlem ent A d ­

ministration was changed to the Farm
Security Administration (FSA) in 1937,
and in 1938 the FSA was placed under the
jurisdiction of the U.S. Department of
Agriculture. Few new programs were in­
stituted by the FSA as the fading of the
Depression and the advent of World War II
stimulated economic recovery. In 1942,
however, the FSA did assume full respon­
sibility for the farm water facilities
program, instituted in 1937 to provide
loans for farm water systems in states par-

The major loan and grant programs
Farmer programs
Farm ownership loans — Insured or
guaranteed loans for farmers lacking other
sources of credit to buy, improve, or enlarge
farms they operate. Statutory limits are $100,000 at 5 percent interest with up to 40 years for
repayment. The Fm H A will accept a second lien
on real estate securing loans of other lenders if
the total indebtedness against the real estate
does not exceed $225,000.
Farm operating loans— Insured or
guaranteed loans to assist farmers lacking
other sources of financing to purchase feed,
seed, fertilizer, livestock, machinery, or other
factors of production. The statutory limit is
$50,000 with up to seven years for repayment.
The interest rate is fixed annually in accor­
dance with rates paid on U.S. Treasury
obligations. The rate for fiscal 1976 is 8% per­
cent. Private lenders are encouraged to provide
as much of the financing as possible.
E m e r g e n c y l o a n s — In s u r e d or
guaranteed loans to sustain ongoing operations
and cover production losses inflicted by natural
disasters. Repayment terms range up to 20
years. Rates on loans covering actual losses are
established at 5 percent, while rates on loans to
sustain ongoing operations change periodically
in accordance with rates paid on Treasury
borrowings. A special emergency livestock loan
program that provides guaranteed loans to dis­




tressed livestock farmers is available until
December 1976.
Other farmer programs—Insured or
guaranteed loans to help farmers develop
recreational and other non-agricultural incomeproducing enterprises and for improvement of
soil and water resources; loans to nonprofit
associations for irrigation and drainage
systems and grazing ranges; loans to Indian
tribal organizations to purchase privately own­
ed land within reservation boundaries.
Statutory maximum terms for all of these
programs are 40 years for repayment at 5 per­
cent interest.

Housing Programs
Individual home ownership — Insured
loans to families with low or moderate income,
including senior citizens, living in rural com­
munities of up to 10,000 in population.* Repay­
ment terms range up to 33 years. The interest
rate, currently 9 percent, is adjusted periodi­
cally. Supplemental benefits, however, may
reduce the interest rate to as low as 1 percent for
low-income families. Direct loans of up to $5,000
for home repair are available to very lowincome families for 20 years at 1 percent
interest.
R en tal h ou sin g— Insured loans to
provide modernized rental housing for senior
citizens and younger families of low to

5

Business Conditions, December 1975

ticularly affected by drought. This was the
forerunner of the many water-related
programs administrated by the FmHA.
The Farmers Home Administration
Act of 1946 reorganized the Farm Security
Administration into the FmHA and
authorized an “insured” farm ownership
loan program. In the first three years of its
existence the FmHA concentrated on
providing supervised credit to farmers. In
1949 the Federal Housing Act authorized
the FmHA to make housing loans to

farmers and the Disaster Loan Act im­
plemented special emergency loans for
farmers that sustained losses from natural
disasters.
The FmHA’s array of services was ex­
panded markedly during the first half of
the sixties. The Consolidated Farmers
Home Administration Act of 1961, among
other things, raised loan limits for both the
farm ownership and the farm operating
loan programs and expanded coverage of
the water facilities program to rural com-

of the Farmers Home Administration
moderate income in rural communities with
populations of up to 10,000.* Repayments range
up to 50 years for senior citizen housing, 40
years for others. The interest rate is adjusted
periodically, with reduced rates for public, non­
profit and limited-profit developers of modern
units priced within the means of low-income
tenants.
Other housing programs —Two-year
loans to nonprofit developers of improved rural
homesite areas; loans and grants for develop­
ment of adequate farm labor housing; grants to
qualified organizations to help low-income
families accomplish “ self-help” homebuilding
projects by performing much of their own con­
struction.

Community Programs
Water and Waste Disposal System s—
Insured loans for organizations, nonprofit cor­
porations, and public agencies in rural com­
munities with populations of up to 10,000 that
lack financing for the development, treatment,
or distribution of water or the collection, treat­
ment, or disposal of waste. Terms range up to 40
years for repayment at 5 percent interest.
Grants can be added where necessary to pre­
vent the debt repayment load from imposing ex­
cessive service rates on users.
Community facilities—Insured loans for
any essential community facility or s e r v ic e -




including fire protection, community halls,
hospitals, nursing homes, medical clinics,
libraries, schools, and recreation centers—
provided by a public body or nonprofit
organization. Loans are made for up to 40 years
at 5 percent interest.

Business and Industry
Industrial development loans — Insured
or guaranteed loans to public, private, or
cooperative organizations and to individuals in
communities with populations of up to 50,000
for purposes o f fin a n cin g operations,
purchases, and development of business and in­
dustry. Repayment terms range up to 30 years.
Interest rates for guaranteed loans are deter­
mined by the lender and the borrower. Interest
rates for insured loans, currently 10% percent,
are adjusted periodically in accordance with the
cost of Treasury borrowings.
Rural development grants — Available
to public bodies to facilitate development of
private business enterprises, including the
development, construction or acquisition of
land, buildings, equipment, streets, and utility
extensions.

*The population limit was raised to 20,000 by
Congress in 1974 but has not yet been implemented by
the Fm HA.

6

munities with populations of up to 2,500. In
addition, the rural housing loan program
was broadened to cover non-farm rural
residents and low-rent apartment projects
for senior citizens.
During the latter part of the sixties,
Congressional actions expanding the
agency’s services concentrated on rural
h o u s in g and com m unity facilities
programs. The water facilities program
was broadened to cover both water and
waste disposal systems in communities
with populations of up to 5,500. For rural
housing the practice of direct loans was
largely replaced by insured loans;
coverage was expanded (in 1971) to com­
munities with populations of up to 10,000;
and a subsidized loan program permitting
rates as low as 1 percent was instituted for
some low -incom e fam ilies and for
developers of low-priced rental housing.
Two important revisions in the farm
ownership program occurred in the early
seventies. The individual loan ceiling was
raised from $60,000 to $100,000. In addi­
tion, the agency expanded cooperative ef­
forts with other lenders by consenting to
take a second lien on security mortgaged
both for the FmHA and other lenders’
loans. The latter action marked a more
liberal interpretation of the restriction that
limits FmHA loans to farmers unable to
obtain credit from other lenders.
A major expansion in FmHA services
was mandated by the Rural Development
Act of 1972, an act that vested primary
responsibility for all federal activities in­
volving rural development in the Depart­
ment of Agriculture. Among other things
the act authorized the FmHA to guarantee
loans made by commercial lenders and es­
tablished a new program for financing
business and industry in rural cities with
populations of up to 50,000. The act also
markedly expanded community facilities
programs by abolishing some lending
ceilings, raising grant authorizations, and
broadening the types of community




Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

facilities eligible for FmHA financing. In
the area of farmer programs the Rural
Development Act raised the individual
farm operating loan limit from $35,000 to
$50,000 and authorized insured (as op­
posed to direct) farm operating loans.
Widespread damage caused by floods
and hurricanes in 1972 induced Congress
to liberalize the emergency disaster loan
program. Interest rates were reduced to 1
percent and a “ forgiveness clause” was at­
tached to the first $5,000 borrowed to cover
actual losses. The cost of the disaster loan
program soared, however, and the
liberalized features were suspended the
following year. In 1974 widespread losses
among livestock producers encouraged
Congress to pass a special Emergency
Livestock Credit Act which, as amended in
1975, authorized the FmHA to guarantee
up to $1.5 billion in loans to livestock
producers. The program is scheduled to
end in December 1976. In 1974 Congress
expanded the housing programs by permit­
ting loans in rural communities with pop­
ulations of up to 20,000 and authorizing
loans on m obile hom es and con­
dominiums.

Structure and organization
The rapid expansion of the Farmers
Home Administration into new program
areas in recent years in part reflects its
vast structure, which stretches from
Washington D.C. to virtually every county
in the United States. The implementation
of Congressional programs for rural
development has been markedly simplified
by reliance on this established, decen­
tralized network of FmHA offices.
The national office of the FmHA in
Washington, D.C. is headed by a Presidentially appointed administrator who
operates under the jurisdiction of the U.S.
Department of Agriculture. The respon­
sibilities of the national office revolve
around the formulation and administra-

7

Business Conditions, December 1975

FmHA loans and grants extended in district states in fiscal 1975
III.

Ind.

Iowa

Mich.

Wis.

United
States

( m illio n d o lla r s )

All farmer programs*
Operating loans
Ownership loans
Emergency disaster loans
Emergency livestock loans

88
13
12
59
4

36
10
10
13
2

109
18
15
44
31

50
12
7
28
2

121
19
15
84
4

2,009
551
352
735
353

All rural housing programs*
Individual owners
Rental housing

65
53
12

73
63
10

61
44
17

91
71
19

44
31
13

2,245
1,931
292

All community programs*
Water and waste systems
Loans
Grants
Facilities

27

31

17

28

12

869

13
4
10

15
4
7

10
4
2

14
5
8

5
4
3

470
177
200

All business and industrial*
Loars

13
13

3
3

7
7

7
7

9
9

364
350

194

143

194

176

187

5,486

Grand total

’ Totals include small amounts not listed separately.

tion of policies and procedures to imple­
ment federal statutes. In addition, ad­
ministrators of the FmHA frequently ad­
vise Congress regarding the status of ex­
isting programs and the value of proposed
programs.
The national office also provides a
tem porary allocation of the annual
program ceilings among the various state
offices. (The program ceilings, which are
normally established as part of the Con­
gressional appropriations bill, set upper
limits on all loans and grants to be extend­
ed in a fiscal year.) Toward the end of a
fiscal year, unutilized allocations are
pooled so states that face particularly
heavy loan demands have access to a
greater volume of allocations.
The Secretary of Agriculture appoints
state directors who are responsible for im­
plementing the policies and procedures es­
tablished at the national office. There are
presently 42 such directors handling
FmHA matters in the United States and its
territories. Several district directors within
each state are part of the state director’s
staff and serve as liasons between the state
office and the county offices.
The FmHA maintains 1,780 county of­
fices representing 3,066 rural counties. For
most programs the county office serves as




the main contact between the federal agen­
cy and borrowers. The county offices are
responsible for determining the eligibility
of borrowers as well as servicing and
documenting loans. The county office is
also responsible for approving loans for
most of the farm programs and the rural
housing programs. Large loan requests,
more typical in the business and industrial
development program or one of the various
community facilities programs, are nor­
mally approved at the state level.

Funding and lending practices
For many years direct loans and
grants were the avenues used to channel
FmHA funds into rural areas, and both re­
quired annual appropriations of govern­
ment funds. Although direct loans and
grants are still utilized by the agency—
particularly in rural housing and com­
munity facilities programs—their relative
importance has diminished considerably.
Today, the bulk of FmHA lending is
handled through “insured loans” and
“ guaranteed loans.” In general, insured
loans are those made, funded, and serviced
by the FmHA. Guaranteed loans are ones
made, funded, and serviced by private
lenders with an FmHA guarantee that the

8

lender will not lose a stated percentage of
the loan, usually 90 percent. Terms on in­
sured loans are defined by statutory
guidelines, while terms on guaranteed
loans are generally negotiated between the
borrower and the private lender.
Three revolving funds support FmHA
insured and direct loans, as well as its
liabilities stemming from the guarantees
of other lenders’ loans. The Agricultural
Credit Insurance Fund, established in the
m id-forties, is the oldest and serves all
farmer programs as well as some minor
areas of the community facilities pro­
grams. The Rural Housing Insurance
Fund was established in 1965 in conjunc­
tion with the inauguration of insured rural
housing loans. The Rural Development In­
surance Fund was established in 1972 to
cover lending activities related to the com­
munity facilities programs and the busi­
ness and industrial development program.
The three revolving funds are based on
government capital. But for ongoing
operations, annual government appro­
priations are limited largely to the
amounts necessary to cover losses in the
revolving funds. The bulk of the funds used
to finance ongoing operations are derived
from principle and interest payments on
loans held by the FmHA and from the sale
of obligations to investors, such as in­
dividuals, banks, trust and pension funds.
Since the development of the Federal
Financing Bank in 1974, all investor
obligations of the FmHA have been sold to
the Federal Financing Bank, which uses
these and other agency obligations as
security for its own obligations which it, in
turn, sells to investors.

Opportunities for banks
The operating guidelines of the
Farmers Home Administration still state
that farm ownership and farm operating
loans are available only to farmers unable
to secure credit elsewhere. But since the




Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

early seventies the FmHA has actively
promoted its willingness to accept second
liens on real estate mortgages and to
supplement farm operating loans provided
by other lenders. In fiscal 1975 banks and
other lenders provided $371 million in
loans to farmers under such participation
arrangements, down somewhat from the
fiscal 1974 total.
Guaranteed loans are perhaps the
most promising area for joint oppor­
tunities between the FmHA and other
lenders. Currently, the FmHA offers loan
guarantees on farm ownership loans, farm
operating loans, emergency disaster loans,
emergency livestock loans, and business
and industrial development loans. In
general, loans guaranteed by the FmHA
must be fully secured and, with the excep­
tion of business and industrial loans, are
available only to borrowers who cannot ob­
tain the needed financing without the
guarantee. The lender is charged a fee for
the FmHA’s guarantee, which covers
losses of up to 90 percent of the loan. In­
terest rates are either negotiated between
the borrower and the lender or established
by statutory provisions. Where statutory
provisions hold rates below the lender’s
normal charge, however, the FmHA pro­
vides an interest subsidy.
Guaranteed loans were first author­
ized by the Rural Development Act of 1972,
but were not implemented until fiscal 1974.
Despite the recent innovation, the volume
of guaranteed loans accounted for 14 per­
cent of all loans and grants extended by
the agency last year. Of the $763 million in
guaranteed loans extended in fiscal 1975,
nearly one-half was channeled through the
business and industrial loan program, ac­
counting for virtually all of the loans ex­
tended under this program . Other
guaranteed loans were distributed through
farmer programs with most going through
the emergency livestock credit program.
Gary L. Benjamin

9

Business Conditions, December 1975

ow useful are export
promotion programs?
In international trade as in domestic trade
the provision of credit is an important fac­
tor in facilitating transactions. Depending
on the nature of the transaction and the
type of goods being traded, such credit in
the international sphere typically takes
the form o f open account credit provided by
exporting firms or some form of short-term
credit such as bank-issued letters of credit
or bankers’ acceptances. In the case of
goods where the return is realized over a
longer period o f time (as, for example,
capital goods), the credit usually takes the
form of intermediate- or long-term loans.
Most trade-financing credits in the
free world economies are provided by the
private sector, either directly by the seller
of the goods or indirectly by financial in­
stitutions specializing in the provision of
credit—primarily banks and insurance
companies. However, a portion of the ex­
ports of virtually all countries is financed
by credit provided by governments, usual­
ly through special agencies established for
that purpose. The United States is no ex­
ception. Over the years the U.S. Govern­
ment has established or supported several
institutions designed to facilitate U.S. ex­
port trade by direct or indirect credit
assistance. This article surveys some of
these programs and evaluates their con­
tribution to the national welfare.

The Export-Import Bank
The Export-Import Bank of the United
States, or the “ Eximbank” as it is usually
called, was established in 1934 by ex­
ecutive order. It was continued as an agen­
cy of the U.S. Government by Acts of Con­




gress in 1935,1937,1939, and 1940 and was
made an independent agency of the
government by the Export-Import Act of
1945. This act has been amended on seven
occasions since 1945, each extending the
bank’s authorization. The most recent
amendment extends the bank’s authoriza­
tion through June 30, 1978.
Until 1971 the operation of the bank
was funded through the federal budget.
The Export Expansion Finance Act of 1971
not only removed the bank’s receipts and
disbursements from the purview of the
federal budget but also substantially in­
creased the bank’s lending authority. The
purpose of the bank as authorized by Con­
gress is “ to provide guarantees, insurance,
and extensions of credit at rates and on
terms and other conditions which are com­
petitive with the government-supported
rates and terms and other conditions
available for the financing of exports from
the principal countries whose exporters
compete with United States exporters.” 1
According to the enabling act, the Ex­
imbank is directed to supplement private
financing of exports but to refrain from
competing with private capital sources
and to assist in financing export transac­
tions for which financing otherwise would
not be available but which, in the bank’s
judgment, hold a reasonable promise of
repayment. The bank is authorized to ex­
tend aid through medium- to long-term
loans, the purchase or discount of existing
export loans, export loan guarantees, and
insurance against loan default.
'U .S . Congress, Public Law 93-646 Section 3
(6)(L)(A) Amendments to the Export-Import Act of
i945, 93rd Congress H.R. 15977, January 4, 1975.

10

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The Direct Loan Program—Trans­
actions qualifying for this program
usually involve multimillion dollar con­
tracts requiring medium- to long-term
financing. For a loan to warrant Eximbank direct loan participation, it must be
established to the bank’s satisfaction that
alternate credit institutions (domestic or
foreign) are unable or unwilling to assume
the full financing risk or that U.S. finan­
cial institutions cannot compete with
foreign financing arrangements covering
a non-U.S. product. In practice, a U.S.
financial institution applies for Eximbank
“ participation” in the export loan. If par­
ticipation is deemed appropriate, the Ex­
imbank determines the extent of its in­
volvement, which over the past several
years has ranged from 30 to 55 percent of
the contract value. Typically, with such an
arrangement the foreign buyer provides a
10 percent downpayment, and U.S. finan­
cial institutions provide the balance.
As of early December 1975 the Exim­
bank interest rate on participations
ranged from 8.25 percent for loans with
maturities of under six years to 9.5 percent
for loans of more than 14 years duration.
(Maturities are calculated from the date of
authorization.) Under unusual conditions
lower interest rates may be charged to meet
foreign interest rate competition. The com­
mercial market rate and the lower Exim­
bank rate taken together result in a
“blend” rate that is lower than commercial
bank rates, thus providing the U.S. ex­
porter with a relatively strong bargaining
position with respect to foreign competi­
tion. Under current Eximbank policy the
lowest “ blend” rate that will be supported
to meet foreign competition is 7.5 percent—
a floor rate on which major industrial
countries reached tentative agreement.2
The Loan Guarantee Program—
Under this program the full amount of the
export loan is provided by a commercial
bank, and the commercial bank, in turn,
applies to the Eximbank to guarantee the




loan against loss due to political or credit
risks. Currently, the Eximbank will
guarantee as much as 85 percent of the
loan, but the range of guarantee coverage
varies from time to time. Typically, to
assure guarantee coverage, the Eximbank
requires: that the importer supply a 10 per­
cent cash downpayment, that the U.S. ex­
porter carry a portion of the credit risk, and
that the U.S. bank carry some prescribed
share of the risk during the early portion of
the loan.
The Discount Loan Facility—This
facility came into being in 1966 and was
restructured in 1969 and again in 1971. Its
purpose is to encourage U.S. banks to
provide financing for exports during
periods of tight money. Banks also may ob­
tain advance commitments from the Exim­
bank for loans to be discounted over the
year, thus assuring that the loans will not
impinge on the commercial bank’s liquidi­
ty position. Banks that utilize this facility
are usually medium-sized regional in­
stitutions that find it an effective way to
serve customers in the export business
w ith o u t t y in g up th eir liquidity
position.

The C o o p era tiv e Financing
Facility—Aimed at small- to medium­
sized export transactions—in essence,
those purchases and loans most easily
evaluated by local foreign financial
institutions—this facility assists foreign
banks that are financing purchases of U.S.
exports. The Cooperative Financing
Facility (CFF) will lend up to 50 percent of
the value of the loan, and the foreign bank,
in turn, lends the full amount to the import­
ing firm. The individual foreign in­
2In November 1975 the major industrial countries
agreed to a system of “information sharing” on in­
terest rates charged for subsidized export credits. The
shared information applies to interest rates the eximbanks of various nations propose to offer on specific
export deals under negotiation. It is reasoned that
this information will allow competing countries to
offer similar rates and thereby reduce competition
based on export credit subsidies— assum ing com­
petitive interest rate reductions do not take place.

Business Conditions, December 1975

stitutions accept full credit risk. The CFF
was established in 1970 and its importance
has increased steadily. In 1974 CFF funds
went to 350 banks in 56 countries.

Other supportive organizations—
In addition to the efforts to promote ex­
ports through direct involvement in the
provision of trade credit, the U.S. Govern­
ment has been involved in indirect support
through its participation in essentially
private institutional arrangements aimed
at supplying export credits.
The Private Export Funding Corpora­
tion (PEFCO) was established in 1971 as a
private institution jointly owned by 55
commercial banks, seven industrial com­
panies, and an investment banking firm.
All export loans financed by PEFCO are
unconditionally guaranteed by the Eximbank. In addition, the Exim bank
guarantees PEFCO’s debt obligations.
These guarantees, plus the equity capital
in PEFCO and the lines of credit provided
by the associated commercial banks and
the Eximbank, form the base for PEFCO’s
ability to borrow in the money markets at
comparatively low interest rates and to
make short- to medium-term low-rate
loans.
The Foreign Export Credit Insurance
Association (FCIA) is an association of in­
surance companies that provides credit in­
surance for small- and medium-sized firms.
Situations insured by FCIA include credit
risk due to default or insolvency on the part
of the importer. Political risks (actions
taken by the importer’s government that
prevent paym ent for the shipment)
associated with FCIA credit insurance are
covered by the Eximbank.

The Commodity Credit Corporation
The Commodity Credit Corporation
(CCC) was established in 1933 and
operated in close affiliation with the
Reconstruction Finance Corporation. It
was made a permanently chartered agency




11

of the U.S. Government in 1948. Since its
inception its nominal purpose has been to
stabilize and support agricultural com­
modity prices and farm incomes. But dur­
ing the years of its existence the CCC has
been used extensively as a tool of export
promotion. The assistance it lends in
promoting U.S. agricultural exports is
d e s ig n e d to com plem ent dom estic
agricultural policy objectives. Over a sub­
stantial portion of the life of the CCC
domestic agricultural production greatly
exceeded the domestic capacity to utilize
the products at prices considered by
policymakers to provide an adequate
return to farmers. The CCC stood ready to
purchase selected agricultural products
based on a schedule of minimum prices to
support domestic farm prices. In the
process the CCC accumulated stocks of
farm commodities, and foreign markets
provided an ideal outlet. The Commodity
Credit Corporation’s involvement in extens io n s o f e x p o r t c r e d it prom otes
agricultural exports in two ways: advan­
tageous interest rates and, probably more
importantly, credit terms that exceed the
expected life of the product. In practice the
export-promoting functions of the Com­
modity Credit Corporation have been
traditionally executed through three main
programs, two of which have an export­
financing component.

T h e E x p o r t C r e d i t Sales
Program—This program provides finan­
cing for commercial sales of agricultural
exports. The credits typically are mediumterm loans of up to three years in duration.
Interest rates are tied to U.S. Treasury
borrowing costs but also take into account
the level of the commercial bank’s prime
rate and the Federal Reserve discount rate,
as well as the lending rates of major
foreign competitors.
Grants-in-aid—The CCC provides
funds to foreign governments and selected
foreign private traders to purchase
agricultural commodities under Title I of

12

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Public Law 480 (the Agricultural Trade,
Development, and Assistance Act of 1954,
as amended). Unlike exports financed un­
der other CCC programs, these exports
typically fall into the economic aid
category. The funds supplied by the CCC
are reimbursed by Congressional ap­
propriations rather than borrowed from
the Treasury or the money markets.
Repayments of some portion of these funds
may be made in foreign currency.
The
Com m odity
Export
P ro g ra m —Under this program the CCC
provides direct subsidy payments or
“payments in kind” to exporters o f certain
agricultural commodities shipped from
stockpiles. The CCC also has been
authorized to sell commodities from stocks
acquired in dom estic price support
operations to private U.S. exporting firms.
This program was particularly active dur­
ing the period when domestic agricultural
prices were generally higher than world
prices. The Commodity Export Program
subsidies provided the differential between
the world market price and the U.S. price.
Since the termination of “ export differen­
tials” for wheat in 1973 the program has
not covered a large volume of commodities.

E v alu atin g governm ent
promotion programs

export

In assessing the efficacy of govern­
ment credit programs to promote exports
and to place the issues in focus, it is
perhaps best to consider the programs in
the framework of a “ cost-benefit” type
analysis. It must be understood that all of
the programs discussed have one thing in
common: they employ forms o f subsidies
that imply a cost to the nation.
In some programs, such as the Com­
modity Export Program of the CCC, the
cost is direct and obvious: the government
uses public funds to make up the difference
between the purchase price and the selling
price of particular commodities. In other




programs the subsidy (and its costs to the
taxpayer) may be more subtle. For exam­
ple, when the government finances an ex­
port loan at an interest rate lower than the
market rate, two things occur: one, the
market price of the commodity (to the ex­
tent that the credit terms for which the
goods are sold are an integral part of the
“total price” of the purchase) is reduced
from what it would have been under a
market-determined solution, and two, the
cost inflicted on the taxpayers and society
in general can be either direct (as a result of
the government borrowing at higher in­
terest rates than those realized when it
lends) or indirect (as when government
borrowing siphons off funds from other
uses causing the cost of credit to increase to
all other borrowers). The costs inflicted
upon society can be justified if, on balance,
the benefits of government intervention in­
crease the well-being and welfare of society
as a whole.

The theory...
In a market economy the exchange of
goods and services is carried on in
response to various incentives present in
the market. On the demand side the incen­
tives include the purchasing power o f the
buyer, the buyer’s set o f preferences among
various available alternatives, and the
price of the contemplated purchase relative
to complementary or substitute alter­
natives. On the supply side the various
costs incurred in the process of production
determine what the producer is willing to
produce at various prices. Through the
“ give and take” of the marketplace, de­
mand and supply are brought into an
“ equilibrium” characterized by maximum
satisfaction of the consumers under given
constraints and by “ optimal” allocation of
resources among various uses in the
productive processes (optimal in the sense
that consumer preferences are met). It is
these preferences that function as the ul­

Business Conditions, December 1975

timate arbiters of what shall be produced.
Under most circumstances when a
subsidy in whatever form is introduced,
the “ optimality” of the market solution is
disturbed. A subsidy lowers the price of a
product and leads to a rearrangement of
priorities. Consumers respond by demand­
ing more o f that good and producers res­
pond by increasing production. More
resources are devoted to the production of
exported goods and less to the production
of other goods. To the extent that the sub­
sidized commodity is sold exclusively
abroad, the lower price benefits only
foreigners. Consumers in the exporting
country suffer because, in the aggregate,
lesser amounts of other commodities are
available to them.
A national policy of export promotion
may have a net positive effect, as when
resources lie idle and when, in effect, a sub­
sidy makes it possible for producers to
lower prices thereby increasing demand
and making it possible to employ these
resources. Under such circumstances
availability of goods domestically is not
reduced by export production, and the add­
ed employment may be viewed as a net in­
crease in society’s welfare. However, in
principle, such policies amount to the “ ex­
port of unemployment” as the country’s
production displaces production abroad.
Typically, such policies have been resisted
by other countries who usually retaliate by
adopting similar policies negating, in
effect, the net benefits gained by the
initiator.
Under the system of floating exchange
rates now widely used, an additional and
commonly overlooked complication is in­
troduced that makes governmental efforts
to increase exports through subsidies selfdefeating. As exports increase, with other
things equal, the supply of the exporting
country’s currency on world exchange
markets is reduced since more of that coun­
try’s currency is needed to pay for its ex­
ports. This inevitably forces up the price of




13

that currency in terms o f other currencies.
As the price of the currency rises, the prices
for all goods exported by that country rise
apace (in terms of foreign currencies) and
demand declines. The result: exports, par­
ticularly of nonsubsidized commodities,
are reduced, leaving the exporting country
in essentially the same position in respect
to its trade balance and employment as
before—but poorer by the amount it has ex­
pended on the subsidy.
In summary, the preponderance of
evidence gleaned from basic precepts of
economic theory suggests that an export
subsidy, while in some instances beneficial
to a particular segment of a country’s
economy, is, on balance, detrimental to
society as a whole.

...and the practice
In recent years the U.S. export promo­
tion programs have attracted much atten­
tion. The praise typically focuses on the
contributions these programs have made
in expanding the country’s exports; the
criticism essentially derives from the alleg­
ed distortions in the markets that they
cause. In analyzing and evaluating the
performance of the programs discussed in
this article against the backdrop of
theoretical precepts, it may be useful to dis­
tinguish among various phases of their
existence.
Most of the programs date to the
Depression of the thirties. Given the great
u n d eru tiliza tion o f resources that
characterized that period, it appeared to
make eminent sense for the government to
use its resouces in efforts to revive the
economy by providing stimulation to
domestic production through stimulation
of exports. The facts, however, suggest
that rather than contributing to the
recovery, such measures contributed to
deepening the Depression by precipitating
worldwide retaliation, which led ultimate­
ly to a severe retraction of world trade.

14

Thus, the contributions o f these programs
to the national welfare over that period
remain doubtful.
In the postwar period the programs
were used effectively to carry out the grand
design of foreign aid to the war-devastated
world. The humanitarian and political ob­
jectives achieved by these programs
provided, at least in principle, a conceptual
offset to their “ costs.”
With the rebuilding of the world
economy largely completed by the late fif­
ties, and with foreign aid largely phased
out, the programs tended to lose their
usefulness. However, by the mid-sixties a
new, conceptually persuasive argument
favoring their continuance began to
emerge. At that time the trading world
functioned on the basis of a system of fixed
e x c h a n g e rates that, w ith m inor
modifications, were established in the late
forties. The profound changes that had ac­
tually taken place in the relative economic
strengths and positions of individual coun­
tries had failed to be reflected in the
relative exchange rate structure of
national currencies. For various reasons
governments were reluctant to adjust the
exchange rates to reflect the new realities.
By the middle sixties the U.S. dollar had
become increasingly overvalued relative to
currencies of such rapidly expanding
economies as the European Common
Market and Japan. The ultimate results of
the dollar overvaluation were a rapid ero­
sion of the competitiveness of U.S. goods
on the world markets and a rapid shrink­
ing of the U.S. trade balance.
Given the key position of the U.S.
dollar in the post-World War II monetary
system, it was felt that the overvaluation
(and the growing imbalance) could not be
corrected by a unilateral U.S. devaluation
that would bring the exchange rate of the
dollar into better alignment with the
currencies of U.S. trading partners. Under
these circumstances export credit sub­
sidies provided a means for a partial ad­




Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

justment by reducing the effective price of
U.S. exports. The implicit “ cost” of sub­
sidies in this particular context may be
viewed as representing a “ payment”
against what amounted to the United
States living “beyond its means” due to the
misalignment of the exchange rates. The
“ distortions” implicit in the programs
were not, under these circumstances, dis­
tortions of an optimal situation but rather
corrections (however imperfect) of the dis­
tortions and misallocations that existed in
the world economy as a result of the ex­
change rate disequilibrium.
Obviously, the programs were inade­
quate to correct the growing disparity. The
disequilibrium deepened until, in August
1971, the conditions became ripe for a more
fundamental and efficient adjustment—
the devaluation of the dollar. The devalua­
tion, and later the adoption of floating ex­
change rates among major currencies in
1973, provided a means of adjusting to
d i v e r g e n c i e s be t w ee n i n d i v i d u a l
economies—and greatly undermined the
major rationale for continuing the export
promotion programs that existed under a
regime of misaligned, fixed exchange
rates. Thus, in the present setting the
broad contribution of the export promotion
programs to the national welfare is
questionable.
Even apart from the broad principles
involved, there are some obvious incon­
sistencies within the government’s export
credit programs that appear to warrant a
reevaluation. For example, the Eximbank
charter makes the bank responsible for
providing credit at below-market rates to
encourage and promote exports and at the
same time directs the bank not to compete
with commercial banks.
Another area that calls for close
scrutiny is the Eximbank practice of mak­
ing loans to finance U.S. exports for which
there is no effective foreign-made sub­
stitute product and no shortage of finan­
cing. A prime example is the longstanding

Business Conditions, December 1975

practice of financing commercial aircraft
purchases by foreign government-owned
airlines. Given the lack of substitutes, most
likely the aircraft would be sold, Eximbank
or not. The question then is where should
the financing originate?—in the United
States or in some foreign country? The
current interpretation of the Eximbank
charter apparently is to assist U.S. finan­
cial institutions to compete with foreign
financial institutions for the extension of
these credits—certainly a step beyond
what could be considered simply the

15

promotion of U.S. exports.
It would be grossly unfair to say that
all export subsidy programs should be
abolished. Rather, the “ passing away” of a
major rationale for programs as they
presently exist suggests that the govern­
ment can no longer accept the proposition
that the programs are unequivocally
beneficial. The governm ent should
scrutinize and evaluate the programs on
their merits to determine how they match
the realities of a changing world.
Jack L. Hervey

IN D E X FO R 1 9 7 5
Month

Pages

Agriculture and farm finance
Foods of the future..........................................................................................
Fertilizer outlook..............................................................................................
The food stamp program ..............................................................................
The Farmers Home Administration ........................................................

March
May
July
December

3-9
8-15
3-12
3-8

February
April
June
July
August
September
October
November

11-15
3-12
3-9
13-15
13-19
10-14
3-9
3-11

February
April

3-10
13-15

June
October

10-15
10-15

January
March
August
November

3-30
10-15
3-12
12-15

May
September
December

3-7
3-9
9-15

Banking and credit
1974 disintermediation—district impact..................................................
The prime ra te ..................................................................................................
Liabilities that banks m anage....................................................................
Bank profits in 1974 ................................................................................................... •
Credit allocation and commercial b a n k s................................................
Advertising for demand deposits..............................................................
The federal debt and commercial b a n k s ................................................
Is there a future for variable rate mortgages?......................................

Bank holding companies
Bank holding company review: 1 9 7 3 /7 4 — Part I ............................ .
Bank holding companies— Part I I ............................................................
Bank holding companies— concentration levels
in three district states................................................................................
Holding company developments in M ich igan ......................................

Economic conditions, general
Review and outlook— 1974-75 ......................................................................
The seventh business cycle..........................................................................
Corporate securities sales soar—record volume boosts liquidity. . .
Capital spending lags the upsw ing..........................................................

International trends
The Port of Chicago........................................................................................
International banking ..................................................................................
How useful are export promotion program s?........................................