View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

an e c o n o m ic re v ie w b y th e F e d e ra l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ica g o




Long-term economic
strategies needed
Export controls and
U.S. agriculture
Banking developments
Index for the year 1973

december
1973




Long-term economic
strategies needed

3

Shortages serve to constrain
our achievable economic goals,
at least in the short run, and
the public m ust be aware o f
those constraints if the public
is to give realistic direction
to policy efforts.

Export controls and
U.S. agriculture

6

When a major supplier, like the
United States, unilaterally re­
sorts to export controls, it places
inordinate pressures on alterna\ tive suppliers and on importers
relying on a stable supply source.

S u b scr ip tio n s to

Banking developments

12

Index for the year 1973

15

Business Conditions are

a v a ila b le t o t h e p u b lic free o f c h a r g e.

For

in f o r m a t io n c o n c e r n i n g b u lk m a ilin g s, a d d re ss in q u ir ie s t o R e s e a r c h D e p a r t m e n t ,
F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h i c a g o , P. O . B o x 8 3 4 , C h i c a g o , I l l i n o i s 6 0 6 9 0 .
A r t i c l e s m a y b e r e p r i n t e d p r o v i d e d s o u r c e is c r e d i t e d .

P l e a s e p r o v i d e t h e b a n k ’s

R e s e a r c h D e p a r t m e n t w i t h a c o p y o f a n y m a t e r i a l in w h i c h an a r t i c l e is r e p r i n t e d .

Business Conditions, December 1973

3

Long-term economic strategies needed
Excerpts from “Economic Policy Strategies for the 1970s,”
an address by Robert P. Mayo, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
before the Greater Des Moines Committee
Des Moines, Iowa
November 29,1973
The prospects of gasless Sundays, slower
highway speeds, reduced airline service,
lower temperatures in homes and factories,
and a less glittering Christmas have made
everyone keenly aware of the “energy
crisis.” Seldom has public interest and con­
cern with an economic issue developed so
rapidly and so intensely.
The implications of relative scarcities
or shortages for economic stabilization
policies—and here I mean the use of both
monetary and fiscal policies to achieve and
maintain stable prices and relatively full
em ploym ent—are not simply abstract, theo­
retical exercises of concern to economists
and the armchair policymaker. It seems
clear to me that shortages of supply serve
to constrain our achievable economic goals,
at least in the short run, and the public
must be aware of those constraints if the
public is to give realistic direction to policy
efforts, to have realistic expectations of the
results that can be achieved, and to make
realistic assessments of economic policies
and economic policymakers.
Unfortunately, public expectations of
the performance of economic policies, even
in the absence of scarcities, have been
greater than those policies could be reason­
ably expected to achieve, attributable I am
afraid to policymakers and economists who
promised more than they could deliver.
Since the 1930s, the intent of government
policy has been to foster actively economic
well-being, economic stability, and eco­




nomic growth. Implicit in these actions has
been the belief th at national policies could
solve many of our economic problems. In
practice, over this period the results have
been mixed, but generally successful.
The basic emphasis of fiscal and mon­
etary policy over the past few decades has
been on the management of the demand
for goods and services. Nevertheless, supply
considerations have n o t been ignored. We
have, for example, affected supply through
agricultural support programs and mini­
mum wage legislation, even though supply
effects may n o t have been the primary or
sole objective of these programs. We have
also taken the existing limits of capacity
growth into account in our planning. But
the basic thrust and emphasis have been on
influencing and affecting private and public
demands for goods and services.
The reasons for our lack of complete
success in following this demand-oriented
scenario highlight some of the difficulties
that economic policy faces in a changed en­
vironment where supply constraints may
exist to a serious degree. Clearly, there have
been a number of periods in our history in
which we were unwilling or unable to re­
strain demands on our productive potential
and inflation resulted. You will recall that
in the early 1960s the economy was charac­
terized by stable prices,but an unemploy­
ment rate of about 5V& percent. Demand
was stimulated. The demands of the Viet­
nam War, with heavy pressures on man­

4

power and other productive resources, plus
the initiation of vast new government social
programs—demands not covered by com­
mensurate tax increases—reduced the un­
employment rate to 3V2 percent by 1969.
At the same time, however, inflationary
pressures mounted. These expansionary
policies sowed the seeds of an inflationary
cycle from which we have not by any
means fully extricated ourselves. During
this period, we simply asked too much
from this economy in terms of both public
and private goods. Total supply could not
adjust as rapidly as demands increased and
price pressures resulted. This is another
way of saying th at public expectations for
the economy exceeded the econom y’s abil­
ity to deliver. And public expectations for
economic policy have exceeded the capa­
city of policy to deliver.
Obviously, if we are rapidly moving
toward an environment in which our popu­
lation growth and per capita resource de­
mands exceed availability, we end up with
the apocalyptic conclusion of “Dooms­
day.” This I reject completely. Exhaustive
studies have shown that there is no foresee­
able limitation on supplies of basic natural
resources. Extreme pessimism is also un­
warranted because it attaches insufficient
weight to the impressive array of adaptive
mechanisms through which a market econ­
omy such as ours responds to shifting pat­
terns of resource scarcity. Technological
change and changes in relative prices are
powerful mechanisms.
I do not mean to play down the
short-run adjustment problem we face. But
even in the short run the price mechanism
can and does work. With limited supplies,
price signals will activate the adjustment
mechanism. And, it is within our current
capabilities to provide relief and assistance
to any groups in the society th at would
otherwise bear a disproportionate share of
the adjustments such price signals might
bring about.
Even if we were confident that we




Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
could adjust to supply constraints we still
haven’t eliminated the difficulties for eco­
nomic policy, and we must have realistic
expectations of what these policies can de­
liver. First, the adjustment takes time. In
the presence of shortages, policies designed
to expand total output, and perhaps in­
crease employment through demand man­
agement, may work more slowly than they
would w ithout supply constraints. Second,
the process of adjusting supplies upward
will, in a market economy, require in­
creases in prices for some period at least. It
is the price mechanism th at communicates
the demands for increased capacity, raw
materials, or new technologies.
Even with improvements in the speed
of adjustment, it will, I fear, be difficult to
achieve both of our goals of full employ­
ment and price stability simultaneously. It
may even be impossible if we insist on de­
fining our short-run goals too restrictively—say 4 percent unem ploym ent and 2
percent inflation. In the presence of shortrun nonhuman resource limitations, we
may n o t always be able to achieve full em­
ploym ent before generating price pressures
on our other resources. Adaptation may
simply not be that rapid.
The process of achieving the goal of
minimum unem ployment could put us in a
future position where not only is the goal
of price stability outside its range of toler­
ance but also where it is impossible to con­
tinue to achieve acceptable rates of unem­
p lo y m en t. The objective of economic
policy controls cannot be simply to get us
from where we are to where we would like
to be. The optimal policy is one that brings
the economy to a desired point in the “best
way.” Policy actions set in motion a whole
train of events that if not carefully watched
can bring us to a state beyond the targeted
point that is untenable.
All this means simply th at our policies
must be conceived within a broader time
frame than in the past. Our short-run suc­
cesses of economic policy may not look as

Business Conditions, December 1973
good as they have in the past, but over a
longer time span perhaps they will be closer
to what we really want.
What then are the appropriate policy
considerations for the remainder of this de­
cade? What are the alternative strategies in
a changing environment? I do not pretend
to have the policy answers completely and
clearly identified. Most of these views will
require further evaluation.
Of greatest concern to me is the point
I made earlier, that is, the tendency for
public expectations to outrun realities in
the economic sphere. This isn’t a new prob­
lem, but with shortages—even though cor­
rectable or adjustable over time—it takes on
added seriousness for economic policy. If
we fail to recognize th at available economic
resources form a constraint upon national
abilities to achieve our goals, the gap be­
tween expectations and realities will widen.
It isn’t necessary to write a whole scenario
before it becomes clear th at the wider the
gap, the greater the public concern, the
greater the demands for action, and the
greater the likelihood of ineffectual or in­
a p p ro p ria te short-run economic policy
actions.
This does not mean th at any of us are
opposed to an improved quality of life or
t h a t we m u s t a d o p t an “ anti-environ­
m entalist” stance. But it does mean the
realization th at decisions to produce public
benefits impose costs. We need to weigh
these costs and benefits not only for the
particular program or policy action under
consideration but also against all of the
other programs with benefits and real re­
source costs. In terms of public policy, this




5
suggests the need for congressional budget­
ary reform, especially in putting an end to
fragmented consideration of expenditures
and by relating expenditures to prospective
revenues and the nation’s broader needs
and desires. It is essential that congressional
resp o n sib ility for resource allocation be
performed with the same emphasis on the
total outcome th at is given to the prepara­
tion of the budget by the Executive branch.
The old goal choice or trade-off be­
tween unem ployment and price stability
still exists, but in a world of even short-run
shortages, new difficulties are added. We
will have to look more carefully beyond
the short-run effects that we can achieve to
the longer-run conditions we may create.
More flexible fiscal policies may be a part
of the answer, as would appear to be poli­
cies and programs to smooth out or shorten
the time necessary to make adjustments.
But I would be misleading you and con­
tr ib u tin g to excessive expectations of
policymakers’ abilities if I suggested that
we have all—or even most of—the answers.
Our knowledge of control procedures for
this type of environment is still limited but
it is growing.
The current and short-run prospects
of our economy are a m atter of concern
but not of alarm. The economy can and
will adjust to the developing environment
of relative shortages. It was in the process
of doing so before the recent burst of pub­
lic awareness. And based on my earlier ex­
periences in fiscal policy and my current ex­
periences in monetary policy, I know that
although it will be a difficult challenge we
have the capability of meeting it.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

6

xport controls and U.S. agriculture
Agricultural exports from the United States
surged to an unprecedented $12.9 billion
during fiscal 1973, 60 percent higher than
the previous record in 1972, and the De­
partm ent of Agriculture has forecast that
the value of agricultural exports will con­
tinue at a strong pace into 1974. In some
respects, the performance of U. S. farm
products in world markets in 1973 came as
a welcome boost to what had been gener­
ally sagging exports. But this development
has had some undesirable repercussions.
Strong worldwide demand for agri­
cultural commodities in conjunction with
poor crops in numerous major production
areas created a domestic shortage of basic
commodities and led to controversy over
public policy toward agriculture. For de­
cades, U. S. policy has been aimed at pro­
moting agricultural exports. Elements of
this policy have included subsidizing export
shipments through concessional sales for
nonconvertible foreign currency, barter
arrangements, and direct dollar subsidies to
exporters. In recent years, public policy has
been directed toward reducing government
assistance and promoting commercial dollar
sales in traditional and new markets. In
1973, as strong domestic and foreign de­
mand collided with limited domestic sup­
plies to push prices of agricultural raw
materials and retail foods to record-high
levels, this policy of export promotion and
limited export subsidies came under wide­
spread attack. The U. S. Government re­
sponded to the apparent shortages by im­
posing temporary export quotas on selec­
ted agricultural commodities.

The economics of export controls
The rules and guidelines of the Gen­




eral Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), with which the major world trad­
ing nations generally comply, contain lim­
ited provisions permitting a country to
impose quantitative restrictions, such as
quotas, on exports w ithout the spector of
sanctions being initiated by countries in­
jured by the action. The conditions under
which GATT permits the imposition of ex­
port quotas require a justification based
on the national security of the exporting
nation or to prevent or relieve critical
shortages of foodstuffs or other essential
products, provided th at all contracting
countries are assured equitable shares of
the international supply (GATT articles
XI-2, XX-j, and XXI).
Export controls take various forms.
They include tariffs (not allowed in the
United States),1 quotas (legislated or
“voluntary”), and such subtle restrictions
as differential availability of export finance
credit and currency exchange controls. Ex­
port tariffs are often imposed by the gov­
ernments of developing countries as a
means of obtaining revenue. Export tariffs
regulate quantity by restricting the number
of units sold through the rationing process
of a higher price. Export quotas, on the
other hand, directly control the quantity
that can be exported because once the
quota level is reached exports are halted—
regardless of price.
1There is a constitutional question as to
whether an export tax can be imposed by the U. S.
Government. Article I, Section 9, of the Constitu­
tion reads in part “No Tax or Duty shall be laid on
Articles exported from any State.” The general in­
terpretation has been that direct export taxes are
prohibited. This provision was apparently included
in the Constitution in response to Britain’s taxa­
tion of the Colonies’ exports and as an assurance
to the states that the new federal government
could not tax their exports—such taxes were a key
motivating factor in the American Revolution.

Business Conditions, December 1973
Export quotas Eire a routine procedure
for groups th at desire to affect world price
levels. Viable multinational commodity
ag ree m en ts, such as the International
Coffee Agreement, or the Organization of
Petroleum Exporting Countries may use
export quotas to regulate the quantity
(scarcity or abundance) of a product on the
world market, and consequently the price
of the product. Such multilateral quota
agreements usually have the intent of sta­
bilizing a world price within some agreedupon range (occasionally they take on
monopoly cartel characteristics). This is
typically accomplished through the alloca­
tion of quotas among exporting countries
—and often among importing countries as
well.
The unilateral imposition of export
quotas such as the United States imposed
on oilseeds in the summer of 1973 is
usually done in order to assure adequate
domestic supplies at lower prices than
those prevailing in world markets. Export
quotas of another form have come into
play since around 1960. These are the socalled “voluntary” quotas imposed by par­
ticular industries or by the government of
an exporting country in order to avoid
having an importing country impose im port
quotas. For example, in 1969, under strong
pressure from the U. S. Government, “vol­
u n ta ry ” quotas were imposed by the
Japanese and Common Market steel indus­
tries on exports to the United States. In
1971, under similar circumstances, Hong
Kong, Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan
accepted voluntary quotas on synthetic and
wool textile exports to the United States.

Basis for export quotas
The imposition of export quotas may
increase the earnings of an exporting coun­
try if the export demand for the commodity
is little affected by an increase in price—and
if alternative foreign sources of supply are
not available. Both conditions appear to




7
apply to agricultural commodities, at least
in the short run. Imposition of quotas,
however, carries a political cost for the
exporting country vis-a-vis the foreign
countries cut off from the supply. This cost
might be felt in a loss of goodwill and
possible retaliatory trade moves by trading
partners, and loss of status as a reliable
source of supply. In addition, by artificially
re d u c in g demand—and thereby forcing
down the domestic price—the exporting
country runs the risk of discouraging ex­
pansion in domestic production of the
commodity in short supply. Such a short­
fall could exacerbate the worldwide supply
situation in the longer term , and make it all
the more difficult to rescind the export
quota w ithout stimulating a price rise, the
avoidance of which prompted the imposi­
tion of the quota in the first place.
Another hazard is the snowballing
effect of the unilateral imposition of ex­
p o rt controls. As traditional importers
attem pt to obtain needed supplies from
alternative suppliers, the alternate suppliers
may be forced to restrict exports in order
to assure adequate domestic supplies at
politically acceptable prices. Such condi­
tions obviously would seriously disrupt
market conditions, to say nothing of the
potential damage to political goodwill.

The summer of ’73
U. S. authorities imposed export con­
trols in an attem pt to insure adequate
domestic supplies. In mid-June 1973, the
Commerce D epartm ent began to require
exporters to report their export commit­
ments of oilseeds and grains. By late June,
when the first data were in, it appeared
that outstanding export commitments of
oilseeds exceeded the level of supplies avail­
able for export prior to the new crop har­
vest. The tightness of the supply-demand
relationship at that point had already
forced domestic prices up sharply as mar­
ket forces reacted to allocate the short-run

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

8

supply. Faced with these developments,
brought 39 other oilseeds, oilseed products,
and with the sharp advances in domestic
and protein supplements under licensing
food prices in general, the government’s
req u irem en ts. On September 8, export
position, as reflected in the President’s
licenses were perm itted at 100 percent of
contracted amounts, and on October 1, the
speech of June 13, was that U. S. con­
export licensing system was revoked.
sumers should not be forced to compete
The imposition of controls on U. S.
with foreign consumers for U. S.-produced
exports of agricultural commodities was
commodities solely on a price basis. The
preceded by a number of interrelated
simplest means of rearranging the alloca­
developments that accentuated the tight­
tion of the available supply, it appeared,
ness of such supplies in world markets and
was by temporarily cutting off a major
put unusual pressures on U. S. agricultural
portion of the m arket—that is, the export
market.
markets. These included:
1. The devaluation of the dollar
On June 28, 1973, the Administra­
vis-a-vis other major currencies.
tion, acting under provisions of the Export
2.
Poor crops in many major grainAdministration Act of 1969, imposed an
producing countries during 1972 (and
embargo on the exportation of soybeans
the winter and spring of 1972-73 in
and cottonseed, and on their meal and oil
products. On July 2, the
embargo was lifted in
favor of licensing con­
Devaluation reduced the impact of
trols on soybeans, cot­
U.S. price in cre a se s
in major foreign m arkets"
to n seed , and most of
their derivative products.
N o . 2 U . S , w h e a t,
U . S . s o y b e a n m e a l,
(Oils were freed from
U . K . m a r k e t s __________________
_______________________ R o t t e r d a m
license requirements on
U . S.
Ja p an ese
G e rm a n
U .S .
Jap an ese
G e rm a n
d o l la r s
yen
m a rk s
d o l la r s
yen
m a rk s
th is date.) All export
$ /b u sh e l
Y /b u s h e l
D M /b u sh e l
$ /m t. to n
Y /m t. to n
D M /m t. to n
contracts in force as of
1971
June 13 were reduced by
J u ly
2 .0 4
729
7 .0 6
1 0 6 .0 7
3 7 ,9 0 9
3 6 7 .0 0
50 percent of the un­
O c to b e r
1 .9 0
1 0 1 .3 4
626
6 .3 5
3 3 ,3 7 1
3 3 8 .4 8
shipped soybeans and 40
percent of the unshipped
1972
s o y b e a n me a l . New
Ja n u a ry
1 .8 2
5 .8 4
565
1 0 5 .4 2
3 3 8 .4 0
3 3 ,7 3 3
A p r il
1 .7 9
5 .6 9
546
3 5 ,3 7 2
1 1 6 .0 5
3 6 9 .0 4
licenses, good until Sep­
J u ly
1 .7 9
539
5 .6 7
1 2 4 .8 8
3 7 ,6 0 1
3 9 5 .8 7
tember 15 for soybeans
O c to b e r
2 .5 8
111
8 .2 6
1 3 8 .6 2
4 1 ,7 3 8
4 4 3 .5 8
and October 15 for meal
1973
and cake, were issued for
Ja n u a ry
3 .0 4
916
8 .6 3
2 1 9 .5 0
6 6 ,1 1 3
6 2 3 .3 8
the reduced quantities.2
A p r il
2 .8 7
762
8 .1 5
2 4 3 .2 5
6 4 ,5 8 3
6 9 0 .8 3
J u ly
4 .2 6
1 ,1 1 8
9 .8 8
5 8 0 .0 0
1 5 2 ,2 5 0
1 ,3 4 5 .6 0
O n J u l y 5, t he
Office of Export Control
Percent change
reimposed export license
J u ly 1971J u ly 19 7 2
-12
-2 6
-20
18
-1
8
requirements on soybean
and cottonseed oil, and
J u ly 19722 The June 13 date appar­
ently was used because the
President made the first pub­
lic reference to the possibility
of agricultural export controls
on that date.




J u ly 1 9 7 3

138

107

74

364

305

240

'I n August 1971, the United States declared the dollar inconvertible into gold, and major world currencies
began "floating " vis-a-vis the dollar. In December 1971, agreement was reached whereby the dollar was devalued and
major foreign currencies were revalued. In February 1973, the dollar was again devalued and major foreign currencies
again began to "flo a t.” From Ju ly 1971 to Ju ly 1973, the value of the yen and mark increased, relative to the dollar,
by about 36 and 49 percent, respectively.

Business Conditions, December 1973
the southern hemisphere).
3.
A continued upgrading of diets
in markets traditionally supplied by
U. S. agricultural exports.
4.
Expanding trade between the
United States and the USSR and
China, with the emphasis on U. S.
agricultural exports.
5.
Mounting worldwide demand for
high protein foods—especially meats
an d anim al feed—coupled with a
worldwide shortage of high protein
fish meal.
6.
Reduced stockpiles of U. S. Gov­
ernment-owned grains.

Impact of export controls
The brief duration of the U. S. export
quotas (June 28 through September 8) pre­
vented the full impact of these actions
from being felt on critical raw materials in
world markets. Nevertheless, some of the
impact stemming from the controls was
clearly apparent. Domestic soybean prices

Soybean prices e rratic under
conditions of short supply
dollars per bushel

Jun.

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

Nov.

Dec.

‘ Price quotations for Rotterdam are for
Tuesdays; for Illinois, Thursdays (1973 data).




9
declined dramatically immediately after
quotas were imposed, although prices in­
creased again in late July and early August.
A sustained decline in prices occurred only
after a record 1973 soybean crop appeared
certain, and eventually stabilized at a level
far below early summer. Foreign soybean
prices advanced irregularly until a down­
turn in mid-August, also reflecting the re­
cord crop prospects.
The most obvious of the short-run
consequences was the contagious nature of
agricultural export controls. Shortly after
the U. S. oilseed quotas were in place,
Canada imposed quotas on selected oilseeds
and protein products. Argentina, Brazil,
Greece, India, Israel, Pakistan, and Spain
also imposed export restrictions on oilseeds
or high protein crops. Had the U. S. Gov­
ernm ent succumbed to pressures to place
export quotas on wheat and corn, the
breadth of reciprocal foreign protective ex­
port restrictions, considering current pro­
duction and stock levels, would no doubt
have been even greater.
As it is, the European Economic Com­
munity (EC) embargoed exports of hard
wheat (durum) and wheat products, and
Argentina installed wheat quotas. Australia
and Canada, both of which funnel wheat
ex p o rts through government marketing
boards, markedly slowed exports. A nation­
wide rail strike in Canada also slowed ex­
ports. Widespread restrictions, however,
naturally increased demand pressures on
the unrestricted, but limited, U. S. wheat
supply earlier this year. Record wheat
crops in Canada and the USSR have since
relieved some of that pressure.
The short-run scars from the 1973
bout with export controls apparently are
not serious. One fact is quite clear, how­
ever: when a major supply source, like the
United States, unilaterally resorts to export
controls on a critical commodity, it places
inordinate pressures on alternative supply
sources and on importers relying on a
stable supply source. With U. S. quotas

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

10

G rains led the export surge
in fiscal 19 73
Grains
Feed
grains
Wheat
unmilled
and flour

Oilseeds

Soybeans

Other
oilseeds and
oilseed products

Other
agricultural
commodities

Total
agricultural
exports

(billion dollars)
1970

1971

1972
1973P

N o te :

1.0
(27)

0.9
(6)

1.1
(37)

0.6
(34)

3.1
(10)

6.7
(17)

1.1

1.2
(28)

1.3
(19)

0.8
(32)

3.4

(11)

(9)

7.8
(16)

1.1
(2)

1.1
(-1 3 )

1.4
(9)

0.8
(6)

3.7
(8)

8.1
(4)

2.3
(107)

2.3
(123)

2.3
(65)

1.2
(44)

4.7
(30)

12.9
(60)

F ig u re in p a re n th eses rep rese nts p e rce n t ch ang e fro m p re v io u s y e a r.

^ P re lim in a ry .

now removed, presumably the restrictions
imposed by other governments gradually
will be withdrawn—Canada’s oilseed restric­
tions are a case in point.
But the brush with export controls is
likely to make the future more difficult, if
not directly for U. S. agriculture then for
U. S. delegates at the new round of inter­
national trade negotiations which began
September 12, 1973.

Trade relations
Foreign reaction to the U. S. imposi­
tion of export controls was sharply critical.
During the early stages of the controls,
Japan, the largest single im porter of U. S.
oilseeds and a country highly dependent
upon a steady supply of soybeans for
human consumption and for conversion
into animal feed, sent a delegation to
Washington with the hope of obtaining
assurance of continued regular supplies.
Officials of the European Economic Com­
munity and of individual EC countries,
especially France, were particularly acrid in
their reactions. The EC views the U. S.
imposition of export quotas on agricultural
products as a curious turn, given the longheld U. S. position that the EC’s common
agricultural policy severely restricts U. S.




e x p o r t s to that area,
(U. S. export quotas were
imposed on commodities
not subject to severe EC
im port restrictions.)
A bas i c question
raised by the use of export quotas—that is, restricting access to supply
—is one th at needs to be
dealt with in the current
r o u n d of international
trade negotiations. The
question is, is open access
to markets, as a goal, to
apply to exports, as it has
to im port trade in the

postwar world?
A separate problem is of equally long­
term significance. In spite of the temporary
imposition of export quotas on oilseeds
and protein products, the United States
will continue to push for long-term ex­
pansion in farm commodity exports. Even
at historically high prices during 1973,
U. S. farm products remained highly com­
petitive in foreign markets because of the
dollar devaluations and the high rates of
inflation abroad. But an element of uncer­
tainty has entered the picture, and a key
question now is, what action, if any, will
foreign governments take to reduce their
dependency upon the United States in
order to assure a regular, stable, and expand­
ing supply of agricultural commodities?
The fact that the United States could
actually find itself in a situation where sup­
plies of farm commodities were so tight
that quotas were imposed must have been
as disturbing to foreigners as it was to
many domestic consumers. It is reasonable
to expect foreign buyers to be searching
for, and encouraging, the development of
alternative sources of supply. Brazil, for
example, is rapidly increasing its stilllimited production of soybeans. Britain and
Japan are reported to be moving quickly
toward the commercial production of a

Business Conditions, December 1973

11

high protein animal feed supple­
Oilseed and protein meal exports*
m e n t d e riv e d from petroleum
are increasing in major exporting
(another resource with availability
countries more rapidly than production
problems). Of course, alternative
Production
Exports
s u p p ly s o u rc e s w ill n o t be
U. S.
Foreign
Total
Foreign
U. S.
T otal
developed overnight. The United
( m illio n m e tr ic to n s )
States remains in the best position
45.7
24.7
1967
8.4
10.8
18.0
20.9
among world agricultural producers
24.7
24.8
49.6
9.9
10.8
20.8
1969
to expand production, and in 1974
25.2
53.4
13.4
24.7
1971
11.3
28.1
an expansion is anticipated.
28.7
56.9
12.3
27.3
28.3
15.1
1973e
In 1974, U. S. wheat produc­
Percent change
tion is expected to increase to 47
42.7
37.0
14.2
24.6
1967-73
80.0
13.8
million metric tons, 11 percent
above the 1973 level, and feed
* I n c lu d e s s o y b e a n s , f i s h m e a l , p e a n u t , s u n f l o w e r , c o t t o n , f l a x , r a p e s e e d ,
grains are projected to increase to
c o p r a , a n d p a lm k e r n e l ( t o n n a g e in t e r m s o f s o y b e a n m e a l e q u i v a l e n t a t 4 4 p e r ­
ce n t c ru d e p r o te in ).
191 million metric tons, 6 percent
e E s t im a t e . F o r e ig n fig u r e s a s s u m e d r e s u m p t io n o f P e r u v ia n a n c h o v y f i s h ­
above 1973. U. S. wheat exports as
in g in M a r c h 1 9 7 3 w h i c h d i d n o t o c c u r .
a percent of production are project­
1973, it became apparent that open access
ed to decline from about 76 percent to 66
had another face, that is, the freedom of an
percent. The export share of feed grains is
importing country to purchase goods (criti­
projected to remain at about 19 percent of
cal or noncritical) from an exporter with­
production. Foreign production of feed
grains and wheat in 1974 is expected to
o u t u n d u e e x p o r t restrictions being
imposed. Fortunately, across-the-board re­
increase about 6.5 percent from the 1973
strictions on exports of selected U. S. agri­
level. In spite of the production increases,
cultural commodities were short-lived. In
however, stocks of grain that will be avail­
October, the selective access to petroleum
able at midyear 1974 in major exporting
supplies by ten Middle Eastern nations pro­
countries are expected to be lower than at
v id e d an a b ru p t and more stringent
midyear 1973, indicating another year with
example of the vital importance of open
a potentially tight supply situation.
access to supplies.
What’s in store?
The conflict boils down to political
expedience as opposed to economic ratio­
nale. The rule book of international trade,
Based on the experience of export
the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade,
controls imposed during 1973, a central
question concerning international trade is
has only limited provisions concerning re­
now beginning to be raised. In an in­
stricted access to supply in international
trade. It is of considerable importance that
creasingly interdependent world, what in­
ternational provisions can be established
the “Tokyo R ound” of trade negotiations,
now in the preliminary stages, consider
that guarantee open access to markets?
rules of trade aimed at achieving and en­
Until the summer of 1973, the term
forcing open access of supply.
“open access” was generally interpreted as
freedom of exporting countries to ship
g o o d s to importing countries w ithout
Jack L. Heruey
undue im port restrictions. In June-July




Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

12

anking developments
Business loans lose steam
Bank loans to commercial and industrial
borrowers declined during the first six
weeks of the fourth quarter following
record-breaking expansion for the first
three quarters of 1973. Normally, business
credit demands are heaviest in the fall when
funds are needed to finance the processing
of agricultural products and a build-up in
inventories for the holiday season.
The recent weakness in bank loan de­
mand reflects both the slowing pace of the
business expansion and the elimination of
an abnormal rate structure that made bank
loans attractive relative to other short-term
sources of credit throughout the first nine
months of the year. About 40 percent of
net funds raised by corporate business in
the financial markets was in the form of
bank loans in the first nine months, com ­
pared with just over 25 percent in 1972
and 30 percent in 1969. At the large week­




ly reporting banks, the nine-month rise in
commercial and industrial loans (including
those transferred to affiliates) was 20 per­
cent nationally and 30 percent in the
Seventh District. This huge expansion in
bank loans to businesses has dwarfed the
1969 experience, and despite the contrac­
tion early in the fourth quarter, it appears
that the relative gain for the year probably
will exceed any year since 1950.

Rate spread a factor
The atypical behavior of business
loans at commercial banks thus far in 1973
is clearly related to the relationships be­
tween the interest rate on bank loans,
which is set by the lending bank, and the
rate that must be paid in order to sell
short-term promissory notes (commercial
paper) to investors, a rate that must be
competitive with other returns available in
the money market. Many large, well-known
corporations can choose between these two
routes in satisfying their short-term financ­
ing needs, and the choice is largely deter­
mined by relative costs. These costs include
more than just the nominal interest rate
payable on the obligation—for example, the
compensating balance required by a bank
and the costs of issuing and servicing
commercial paper.
Historically, the spreads between the
prime loan rate—the basic rate a bank
charges its most creditworthy customers—
and rates on various categories of com ­
mercial paper tend to vary within a fairly
narrow range over time except when banks
wish either to attract or repel loan business
or when commercial banks as a group are
under pressure from public policy to lag
behind rising market rates.

Business Conditions, December 1973
A longer-term comparison of the
prime loan rate prevailing at the nation’s
major banks and the average rate quoted by
dealers on four- to six-month commercial
paper shows that the prime generally has
been above the paper rate except in tight
money periods. This spread was modestly
negative for brief periods in 1969-70 but,
on a monthly basis, fluctuated within a
positive range of 5 to 140 basis points from
the spring of 1970 to February 1973. The
development of a negative spread of more
than 60 basis points late last winter reflect­
ed efforts by the Committee on Interest
and Dividends, in connection with the Ad­
m inistration’s price control policies, to re­
strain the price of credit, especially to small
businesses. This gap between bank loan
charges and the cost of borrowing in the
market led to a more than $9 billion in­
crease in business loans of big banks in the
first quarter, a period when there is nor­
mally little or no net gain. This was ac­
companied by a $3 billion decline in o ut­
standing dealer-placed commercial paper.
In April, many large banks adopted a
“tw o-tier” prime that enabled them to
gradually adjust the “large borrower rate”
to the m arket rate. Prime rate adjust­
ments became more frequent and the
spread narrowed but remained negative.
A bout the same time, many banks adopted
more restrictive lending policies and tight­
ened nonprice lending terms to stem the
flood of business loan demand rooted in
strongly expanding economic activity. For
the second and third quarters together,
business loans at the large banks expanded
by another $9 billion, while commercial
paper remained level. Only in late Septem­
ber, after the prime reached 10 percent, did
the sharp decline in market rates, generated
in part by expectations of a weaker econo­
my, restore the positive spread. The rever­
sal was so abrupt, in fact, that it imposed a
greater-than-normal penalty on bank loans.
Many borrowers switched back to the
paper market, and in October, dealer paper




13

Bank prime lagged market
ra te s until autumn
percent

I 1.0

4 - 6 mo.
commerciol paper

Commercial paper/prime
rate" spread widens
basis points

100

-

I O O 11 11 I I I I I I I i l l 111 I I I i I I I 11111111II1111 1111111 I I I I I I I I 11 V i 111

1969

1970

1971

1972

1973

‘ Monthly average rates. The predominate
large-business prime rate charged by major banks
was weighted by business days in the month.

e x p an d e d by nearly $3 billion—about
double the contraction in business loans.
Subsequent downward adjustment in
the prime rate and a partial rebound of
market rates restored a more normal spread
by early November, and this condition is
likely to minimize shifts between these two
sources. If it persists, bank loan trends in
the months ahead will be more reflective of
the overall demand for short-term business
credit. The outlook for bank loan demand
is clouded by prospective energy shortages,
and by the degree to which corporations
will go to the capital markets both to fund
o u tsta n d in g short-term obligations and
planned increases in capital expenditures.
Corporate bond issues have been mod­
erate in 1973, as increased earnings added
to liquidity and many corporate treasurers
stayed short in the hope that funding could

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

14

Pattern of loan growth was similar for
most major industrial groups
Percent change in co m m e rcia l and in d u s tria l
loans o f large d is tric t banks w ith o rig in a l m a tu ritie s o f
1 year o r less
Jan.-Sept.
M a n u fa ctu rin g
M etal and m a ch in e ry
F ood, liq u o r, tob acco
O th e r m a n u fa c tu rin g & m in in g

+57
+ 28
+ 64

O ver 1 year

O ct.

Jan.-Sept.

O ct.

-1 0
-1 3
-1 0

+ 18
+ 47
+ 39

+ 2
- 1
- 1

Trade

+23

+ 1

+ 29

+ 2

U tilitie s

+66

-1 0

+

-

C o n stru ctio n

+33

-

5

+ 64

Services

+ 13

+ 3

+ 14

+ 3

Foreign

+ 16

-

+ 42

+ 26

Acceptances

-7 1

+ 3

A ll o th e r

+25

-

8

+271

+ 4

+32

- 6

+ 31

+ 2

Total

4

9

-

1

-1 3

-

Note: Based on reports of 18 large Seventh District banks. Excludes loans sold to affiliates.

be done later at lower cost. Issues of bonds
and equities together accounted for less
than one-fourth of total external corporate
financing in the first three quarters. When
short-term rates declined in early 1970,
long-term corporate bond yields softened
initially but, under pressures generated by a
huge volume of new issues, rose to their
peak levels in that cycle almost six months
later, while business loans declined. If capi­
tal expenditures planned for next year are
not cut back significantly, heavier reliance
on the bond market can be expected. But
because credit, though costly, has remained
available to business in 1973, unlike the
1969 experience, the necessity for busi­
nesses to issue long-term obligations ap­
pears less urgent in 1974 than it was in 1970.

Some district dimensions
The nine-month rise and subsequent
weakness in business loans were relatively
more pronounced in this district than na­




tionally. Reports by the largest district
banks on loans classified by borrower cate­
gories show a similar profile for all the ma­
jor industrial groups, with strong increases
through late summer followed by a level­
ing-off or decline thereafter. But as of midNovember, net dollar gains were substan­
tially above the year-ago period in all ex­
cept the construction and service groups.
The contraseasonal decline in loans to food
processors since mid-August reflects paydowns on the large increases placed on the
books three to six months earlier, partly in
connection with last summer’s surge in
commodity prices, that have more than off­
set borrowing to cover normal fall credit
needs.
The recent declines at district banks
were concentrated in short-term loans, ex­
cept in the construction sector. While total
loans of the largest banks declined almost
$350 million during October, term loans—
outstanding loans with original maturities
longer than a year—rose $100 million.

15

Business Conditions, December 1973

Index for the year 1973
Month

Pages

Banking and credit
Banking developments*
Small bank portfolio b e h a v io r...........
Bank holding companies: an overview
ABCs of figuring interest ...................

March
August
September

3-10
3-13
3-11

January
April
May
July
October
November
December

3-31
3-12
3-12
3-10
3-15
3-13
3-5

Economic conditions, general
Review and outlook—1972-73 ................
Economic growth strains capacity . . . .
Motor vehicles lead the u p s u rg e ..............
Agriculture—midyear review and outlook
I n f la tio n ......................................................
More on inflation ......................................
Long-term economic strategies needed. .

International economic trends
The expanded Common Market . . .
Export controls and U. S. agriculture

March
December

11-16
6-11

Government finance
Growth of government spending
Paying for government spending

February
June

*Banking developments is a regular feature of Business Conditions.




6-15
3-12