View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
December 1970

Contents
New farm law—
a step toward the
marketplace

2

The Federal Reserve Systemvital and viable
in the Seventies

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

New farm law —
a step toward the marketplace

After two years of negotiations, the Agricul­
tural Act of 1970 was passed by Congress
and signed into law on November 30. Re­
placing the act of 1965, the new act will be the
basis for farm policy for the next three years.
The Secretary of Agriculture sought a bill
that would reflect the goals of the Adminis­
tration as well as those of the various factions
within the farm political bloc. But the new
law, like most legislation, may best be termed
a compromise rather than a consensus.
In formulating the new act, controversy
centered, as so often in the past, on the degree
of government support that should be pro­
vided for farmers. After 40 years of govern­
ment programs, some form of support for
agriculture is generally accepted. Periodic­
ally, however, there is a movement to make
agriculture more market-oriented. This is
equated with reducing government’s role and
giving farmers more freedom in production
decisions. This type of program is especially
appealing to government policy makers with
budget constraints in mind. It is less appeal­
ing to congressmen from farming states and
to their constituents who face the prospect of
lower farm prices.
The Agricultural Act of 1970, while mov­



ing in the direction of less government sup­
port and control, still provides farmers insula­
tion from the sometimes harsh vagaries of the
marketplace. The new farm act does not
depart significantly from the 1965 Food and
Agricultural Act that expires this year. As
under that act, farm production will be con­
trolled by idling cropland, and farmers’ in­
comes will be supplemented through direct
payments and price support loans.
Success o f d ire ct p a ym e n ts

Direct payments to farmers for idling
wheat, cotton, and feed grain acreage appear
to have worked fairly satisfactorily in pre­
venting a buildup of excess stocks of govern­
ment-owned commodities. Since 1961, when
direct payments to discourage production
were first initiated, government stocks of
wheat have been more than halved—declin­
ing from well over 1.3 billion bushels in
1961 to just over 600 million bushels in 1969.
Corn stocks controlled by the government
declined from 1.9 billion bushels to about
730 million bushels. Still, the direct payments
type of program has come under criticism
because of the rapid increase in payments to
farmers for not producing. Especially sharp

Business Conditions, December 1970

criticism springs from the extremely large
payments to a few individual producers. In
1969, five operators received payments of $1
million or more each. Furthermore, about 5
percent of the farmers received 38 percent of
all direct payments in 1969.
Direct payments to farmers rose from
$700 million in 1960 to approximately $3.8
billion in 1969—more than fivefold. The in­
crease in direct payments should not be
interpreted as a net increase in government
support of agriculture. Rather, the increase
reflects a change in the form of farm income
supplements. Prior to the 1960s, farmers’
incomes were bolstered indirectly through
relatively high price support loans. For ex­
ample, the support rate for corn ranged from
$1.40 to $1.62 per bushel in the 1954-57
period, compared to $1.00 to $1.05 per
bushel in the 1965-69 period. Support loan
rates for cotton and wheat declined similarly
following changes in these programs. With
the lowering of price supports on the major
commodities, income supplements to farmers
were maintained by boosting direct payments.
As for the matter of inequitable distribu­
tion of payments, government farm support
programs have always been commodityoriented with the largest producers receiving
the most benefits. But the direct payment
system makes the level of support to each
individual highly visible. Formerly, large
farmers received their benefits indirectly by
selling at artificially high prices in the market­
place or to the government.
A p r e c e d e n t is s e t

The controversy surrounding the matter of
large government payments to farmers re­
sulted in a compromise feature in the 1970
Agriculture Act that limits payments any one
recipient may receive to $55,000 per crop.
Theoretically, a grower of all three major



Most farmers receive less
than $5,000 in direct
government payments!
Percent
o f to tal

G o v e rn m e n t p a y m e n ts

R ecip ien ts

(d o lla rs)

(n u m b er)

Less th an 5 ,0 0 0

2 ,3 8 8 ,3 1 7

95

5 ,0 0 0 - 9 ,9 9 9

8 7 ,1 8 9

3

1 0 ,0 0 0 - 2 4 ,9 9 9

3 4,0 0 3

1

2 5 ,0 0 0 - 4 9 ,9 9 9

6 ,0 2 9

*

5 0 ,0 0 0 - 9 9 ,9 9 9

1 ,40 4

*

1 0 0 ,0 0 0 — 4 9 9 ,9 9 9

346

*

5 0 0 ,0 0 0 - 9 9 9 ,9 9 9

11

*

1 ,0 0 0 ,0 0 0 a n d o v e r

5

*

H e s s th a n 1 p erce n t.
|D a t a fo r 1969.

crops—feed grains, wheat, and cotton—can
still collect up to $165,000 in direct pay­
ments. In 1969, however, only two producers
would have qualified.
The significance of the $55,000 payment
limitation may be in setting a precedent that
could portend more restrictive payment ceil­
ings in the future. The House of Representa­
tives passed legislation in 1968 and 1969 to
limit payments to $20,000 per producer, but
the Senate did not agree. In 1970, the Senate
passed a $20,000 limit but agreed to the
$55,000 limit in the House bill. The $20,000
limit may come to the fore again in 1973.
The current $55,000 limitation, one of the
most publicized features of the new act, will
affect very few farmers. Moreover, it will not
significantly reduce government outlays on
agriculture. Only 1,100 farmers received pay­
ments of more than $55,000 in 1969. Of
these, 950 were cotton growers in the South
and West. Within the Seventh District states,
only 18 farmers received government pay-

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Direct government payments . . .
billion dollars

ments in excess of $55,000. All
were in the leading feed grain
producing states of Illinois, Indi­
ana, and Iowa. If the $55,000 per
crop limitation had been in effect
in 1969, direct payments of ap­
proximately $3.8 billion would
have been reduced by $58 million,
less than 2 percent.
Lo o senin g g o v e rn m e n t re in s

. . . replace high price supports
dollars per bushel

4



Other provisions in the new
farm act are in the direction of
more freedom of choice for pro­
ducers, more flexible price sup­
ports, and less reliance on rigid
formulas.
The “set-aside” provision of
the 1970 act is a new twist to
the old scheme designed to take
wheat, feed grain, and cotton acres
out of production. Purportedly, it
will allow the farmer greater free­
dom to choose the crops he wishes
to grow after “setting aside” a
designated portion of his acreage.
Under the old program, feed
grain, wheat, and cotton acreages
on participating farms were lim­
ited to predetermined base acre­
age allotments (1959-60 average
wheat, cotton, and feed grain acre­
age on the farm) less the idled
acres. Thus, a farmer with a 100acre feed grain base, for example,
who chose to idle 20 percent of his
acreage could plant only 80 acres
of feed grains, even though he
might have 200 acres of cropland.
The new set-aside provision
will allow the farmer to plant
whatever crop he wishes on his
remaining acreas after idling the

Business Conditions, December 1970

required acreage. Thus, a farmer is not lim­
ited by his base acreage allotment and may
plant all his remaining crop acres to feed
grains or other crop he deems most profitable.
This relaxation of controls could result in
sharply higher grain production and lower
grain prices. There are provisions in the new
act, however, which allow the Secretary of
Agriculture to limit the number of feed grain
acres on participating farms through 1973 to
provide an orderly transition toward marketdirected plantings, should that be necessary.
The removal of marketing quotas and
acreage restrictions from the cotton program
was another step toward less government
intervention. Formerly, if in any year the
U. S. cotton supply exceeded the “normal”
supply, the Secretary of Agriculture pro­
claimed a marketing quota and established
necessary acreage restrictions to control pro­
duction the succeeding year. A referendum
was called in which two-thirds of the cotton
producers had to approve the quota in order
for it to be effective. Under the new act, an
annual production goal will be declared by
the Secretary of Agriculture as a guide for
producers, but mandatory quotas, penalties,
and acreage restrictions are suspended for the
next three years.
P a rity — less em phasis

The parity concept has been a key factor in
government farm programs since the 1930s.
Parity—as a policy guide—is based on the
premise that a bushel of corn, for example,
should have the same purchasing power to­
day as it did in agriculture’s supposed “golden
era,” 1910 to 1914. Parity carries the con­
notation of being fair. Farm prices are said
to be at parity when the relationship between
the prices of farm products and the prices of
goods and services farmers purchase is the
same as it was in the 1910-14 period.



Government stocks lower
than early 1960s
billion bushels

The original method of calculating parity
prices maintained a constant relationship be­
tween prices of individual farm commodities,
i.e., the relationship between the price of
corn in relation to the price of hogs was
frozen according to their relation in the
1910-14 base period. Several years ago this
was adapted to adjust for changes in the
supply and demand factors affecting indi­
vidual commodities. Individual farm product
prices are now determined by use of an ad­
justed base—a ten-year moving average of
prices for a particular commodity divided by
the average index of prices for all farm prod­
ucts. This adjusted base price is then multi­
plied by the index of prices paid by farmers,
which is still based on the 1910-14 period,
to arrive at the parity price.
Parity, with its emphasis on prices, does
not take into account the rapid advances
made in the technology of production. Mod­
ern technology has lowered unit costs of pro­
duction for many farm commodities, and it
has drastically increased quantities produced.
Department of Agriculture statistics indicate

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

production of farm commodities increased
about 127 percent from the 1910-14 period
to the 1967-69 period. At the same time, the
amount of inputs required to produce this
output increased less than 30 percent. The
result: a 77 percent increase in productivity.
Most of this gain in productivity is attribu­
table to the mechanization of agricultural
production—that has sharply reduced the
amount of labor required—to the develop­
ment of hybrid seeds, and to the use of com­
mercial fertilizers. Thus, increased prices of
production items purchased by farmers have
been offset in varying degrees, depending on
the commodity, by substantial increases in
productivity.
An attempt to sever the ties between parity
and farm supports in the Administrationbacked House bill was strongly opposed by
members of the Senate. As a result, the con­
cept of parity remained alive, although di­
minished in importance, in the final version
of the farm bill hammered out by the HouseSenate conferees.

Increased efficiency boosts
agricultural output

6

‘ In clu d e s a ll item s used in a g ric u ltu ra l p ro d u ctio n .




In general, the new act gives more weight
to actual market price in determining the
level of price supports. In the case of feed
grains, cooperating farmers are guaranteed
a minimum price support payment of either
$1.35 per bushel for corn, or 70 percent of
parity, if higher, on half the production from
their feed grain base acreage. In 1973, how­
ever, if the 70 percent parity guarantee would
result in total payments exceeding those of
the previous year the amount of excess would
be nullified. The price support loan floor was
set at $ 1.00 per bushel for corn without refer­
ence to parity.
M ost fa rm e rs b e n e fit little

Approximately two-thirds of the individ­
uals counted as farmers by the Bureau of the
Census benefit little from current government
farm support policies. This is because they
control relatively few agricultural resources.
These farmers operate two-thirds of the
nearly three million Census-enumerated
farms,1 but receive only about a fifth of the
government payments. Payments per farm in
this group averaged about $440 in 1969.
Obviously the majority of places and per­
sons counted as farms and farm operators by
the Census already depend on sources other
than farming for their livelihood. Indeed, in­
come from off-farm sources accounted for
78 percent of the family incomes of these
“farmers” in 1969. Half of the operators in
this group received nearly 90 percent of their
income from off-farm sources. Many in this
group make up the rural poor. For others,
farming is a hobby or sideline.
The largest one million commercial farm­
ers—who operate about a third of the farms
in the nation and produce over 85 percent of*
*A farm is defined as a place of ten acres or more
with at least $50 in sales, or a place of less than ten
acres with at least $250 in sales.

Business Conditions, December 1970

the farm commodities
—have benefited most
from farm price and
income support pro­
grams. They are also
most dependent on
continuance of the
programs.
Large-scale com­
mercial farmers rely
on stable prices for a
dependable cash flow
to meet current oper­
ating expenses. Over
half the items used in
farm production are
purchased from non­
farm sources, usually
through the use of
credit. In the past,
when the average farm
was much smaller,
most of the inputs
originated on the farm
where used. Most im­
portant, family labor
accounted for a much
larger share of total
inputs. Under these
circumstances, small
farmers could survive
short-run price and in­
come fluctuations by
“belt-tightening,” in
effect accepting a
lower wage for their
labor.
Many large farm in­
vestments were made
on the assumption that
farm product prices
would continue to be
supported. Farmland



Direct government payments account
for increased proportion of farm income
R e a lize d net fa rm
incom e
1960

D irect g o ve rn m e n t
p a ym e n ts

1969

1960

(m illion d o lla rs)

1969

(m illio n d o lla rs)

P aym en ts as
p ercen t o f incom e
1960

1969

(p ercen t)

Illin o is

589

849

18

195

3

23

In d ia n a

337

590

17

132

5

22

Io w a

708

1 ,275

21

260

3

20

M ich ig an

255

276

18

73

7

27

W isco n sin
U nited S tate s

394

562

17

56

4

10

11,7 3 6

1 6,1 5 4

693

3 ,7 9 4

6

23

Majority of "farmers" rely on sources
other than farming for income
In co m e p er f a r m , 1969
A n n u a l fa rm
p ro d u ct sale s

N u m b er
o f fa rm s

(d o lla rs)

(th o u sa n d s)

Less th an 2 ,5 0 0

1,223

41

1 ,082

7,011

87

2 ,5 0 0 - 4 ,9 9 9

286

10

2 ,1 2 2

4 ,8 9 5

70

5 ,0 0 0 - 9 ,9 9 9

389

13

3 ,6 3 0

4 ,4 8 8

55

10,0 0 0 - 1 9,999

5 05

17

6,481

3,141

33

2 0 ,0 0 0 - 3 9 ,9 9 9

357

12

10,4 6 6

3,241

24

4 0 ,0 0 0 an d o ve r

211

7

2 7 ,5 0 3

5 ,4 6 4

17

Percen t o f
a ll fa rm s

Farm

O ff- fa r m
(d o lla rs)

O ff- fa rm
to to ta l
(p ercen t)

7

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

accounts for about two-thirds of total agri­
cultural assets. Farmland values are sup­
ported by government programs. If current
programs were eliminated, land values would
decline, thereby reducing the accumulated
equity of all farmers. The largest landowners
would lose the most.
While large operators control the bulk of
farm assets, they likewise hold a much greater
than proportionate share of the total farm
debt. A 1966 census indicated that farmers
with annual farm product sales of $20,000 or
more comprise only 12 percent of all farmers,
but account for nearly 50 percent of total
farm debt. These farmers rely on continued
maintenance of farm commodity price levels
to repay their debts.
N e w d irectio n s

The farm program that has been outlined
for the next three years does not differ sub­
stantially from its predecessor. Nevertheless,
national priorities are shifting. Problems of

8



environmental pollution, housing, labor, and
poverty are in the spotlight. These problems
usually are associated with urban centers.
However, they are also significant issues in
rural America and may well come to the fore
as less government funds are allocated for
farm commodity price support programs. The
1970 Agricultural Act asserts the need for
developing a “sound rural-urban balance”
and calls for reports on planning, technical,
and financial assistance to rural communities.
Greater reliance on marketplace allocation
of resources seems appropriate for the com­
mercial sector of agriculture. But, it should
be recognized that 40 years of government
support must be dismantled slowly to mini­
mize capital losses and human suffering.
New policies are needed to assist the re­
maining noncommercial farmers. Problems
of these families perhaps should be viewed
in the broad context of the need to provide
education and job opportunities for low in­
come persons, rural or urban.

Business Conditions, December 1970

The Federal Reserve System—
vital and viable in the Seventies
Remarks of Mr. Robert P. Mayo
President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
at the Bankers Club of Chicago on
December 2, 1970

We are all aware that in this day and age
the charge of irrelevancy has become almost
commonplace. Our institutions are viewed
by some as being outmoded, rigid, and mis­
directed. They are charged with being in­
capable of meeting the changing needs of our
present society. It is said they are hopelessly
inadequate as innovators. These charges do
not apply to the Federal Reserve System! At
least I don’t think so.
Although I won’t be able to cover com­
pletely tonight what I judge to be the Fed’s
vital and viable role in the Seventies, I hope,
at least, that we can start a dialogue that will
continue after this evening.
O b je c tiv e o f F e d e ra l R e s e rv e policy

The basic objective of the Federal Reserve
System is to facilitate the achievement of the
social and economic goals of our people and
our government through System contributions
to an appropriate economic environment.
These are not, obviously, the same words
that were used in the preamble to the Federal
Reserve Act or in the Employment Act. But
the words are meant to convey the same sense
of purpose. Hopefully, they also convey the



view that in this changing society we must
focus on a broad view of our functions if we
are to meet our responsibilities.
System officials, bankers, and the general
public alike must remember that the primary
function of the central bank is the promotion
of the public interest. But the public interest
is in a state of flux, affected continuously by
rapid change, innovations, and new dimen­
sions of sophistication. These “facts of life”
have and will vastly modify our interpretation
of our objective, and also how the System’s
functions relate to the whole fabric of society
—not just to the economic process or our
financial machinery.
My restatement of the System objective
does not, of course, modify the three areas
of specific System responsibility; namely
monetary control, a smoothly running pay­
ments mechanism, and banking supervision.
But, as I say, I feel that we should interpret
these specific goals in an environment where
needs are constantly changing. This means an
environment where effective action may be
blocked by relics of a bygone era in the form
of legislation, structural rigidities, or just
plain lethargy. What I’m saying is that the

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

10

goals are familiar but their implications for
today are far different from what they were
ten years ago. And, because today’s priorities
have shifted, we must constantly rethink
those priorities and the options open to us to
achieve them.
Each sector in the economy, of course, sees
these objectives in a different light. More­
over, it is easy to think of methods of achiev­
ing each separate objective that may look
promising, but yet may be mutually inconsis­
tent. Compromises have to be reached. The
trade-offs need to be clearly understood.
The paramount responsibility of the Fed­
eral Reserve, as the central bank of the
United States, is to provide the reserve base
that will allow the commercial banking sys­
tem to generate the appropriate total supply
of money and credit. I stress the “total supply
of credit” because, in this view of the central
bank’s responsibility, the task of allocating
the supply among would-be borrowers is left
to individual bankers and other suppliers of
credit interacting freely in the marketplace.
In recent years, the efficiency of the allocation
function has been called into question, and
some changes may be due.
There are two possible approaches. One is
for the Federal Reserve to take a more direct
role in guiding credit flows. The other is to
improve the market’s ability to achieve the
kind of credit and resource use that appears
to be most needed. In my view, the second
approach is greatly to be preferred. It de­
pends for its success on competition, knowl­
edge, and mobility of both money and people.
To the extent that it cannot be made to work
to the satisfaction of the majority of our peo­
ple, pressures will mount to steer funds in
the direction of socially-desired objectives,
whatever those may be at the moment. But
this approach entails serious problems of
possible errors in human judgment, of conflict




among experts as to the proper course of
action, of mushrooming government controls
to make initial controls work, and of plugging
loopholes that tend to render the original
rules inequitable or ineffective.
In what ways, then, can the Fed be ex­
pected to provide the environment within
which banks can meet the needs of agricul­
ture, housing, urban areas, state and local
governments, the federal government, and the
international payments mechanism? The Sys­
tem must affect the environment through its
influence on banking structure, bank per­
formance, and the availability of credit.
I’m not going to talk about inflation
specifically tonight. But I’m sure you’ll all
agree that better control of inflation than we
had in the 1965-68 era is absolutely essential
to the achievement of our goal of a healthy
environment for the 1970s. Nor should the
absence of any comments tonight on the
respective roles of commercial banks and
other financial institutions be interpreted as
indicating any lack of concern as to the future
of banking in America. Suffice it to say that
each of you has as vital a role in the future
of America as you ever have had.
I certainly don’t come to you tonight with
a series of neat solutions to any one of the
issues of the 1970s—much less solutions to
all of them. The best anyone can do, as he
looks into the future, is to search a wide range
of possible problem areas—challenges, as I
prefer to call them—and to identify the ones
that are most likely to produce difficult
choices in the future. There are several I
would like to examine in some detail.
Banking structure

Among the problems faced by the Federal
Reserve few are more difficult or of greater
potential importance to the economy than
those having to do with banking structure.

Business Conditions, December 1970

Together with the Comptroller of the Cur­
rency, the Federal Deposit Insurance Cor­
poration, and the 50 state banking depart­
ments, the Federal Reserve is responsible for
assuring that developments in banking struc­
ture—a term encompassing the number and
size-distribution of commercial banks, their
pattern of branching, and the types of activiities they conduct—are compatible with the
broad goals of depositor safety, technological
efficiency in banking, efficient allocation of
financial resources throughout the economy,
and the prevention of excessive concentra­
tions of economic power.
The System’s specific responsibilities with
respect to banking structure are spelled out
in federal banking laws. In particular, I refer,
of course, to the Federal Reserve Act, the
Bank Holding Company Act of 1956, the
Bank Merger Act of 1960, and their amend­
ments. Among many others, System respon­
sibilities include ruling on applications for
mergers and acquisitions of banks by holding
companies; administration of the Regulation
Q ceilings on interest rates on time deposits;
the determination of whether proposed new
activities of banks are “so closely related to
the business of banking or of managing or
controlling banks as to be a proper incident
thereto . . . .”
Especially since the early 1950s, a major
purpose of the Federal Reserve has been to
encourage vigorous competition among banks
within limits consistent with the safety of the
banking system. Competition has been pro­
moted as the guarantor of good performance,
assuring protection against arbitrary and un­
fair decisions in allocating credit among
competing borrowers. The basic presumption
has been that competition is best served by
maintaining an adequate number of inde­
pendent sources of banking services in each
local market. The System has bulwarked



competition by preventing mergers and ac­
quisitions that contribute even marginally to
the share of resources controlled by the larg­
est banking associations in markets where
concentration is already high. I foresee no
change in the general emphasis of the present
policy in the coming decade.
One major obstacle to the achievement of
these goals has been the existence of state
laws that restrict the Federal Reserve’s range
of discretion in merger and holding company
cases by foreclosing competitively preferable
alternatives. For example, geographic re­
strictions on branching can result in the ap­
proval of a merger that is not in the best
interests of competition. Under other circum­
stances, this type of merger might be denied
in the hope that the bank to be acquired some­
how might be purchased by a bank not now
competing in the same market. Similarly,
home-office protection clauses in state
branching laws often result in the denial of
mergers promising substantial improvement
in efficiency because there is no possibility of
potential entry by a competing bank to offset
the loss of an independent source of banking
services. Although federal law has long de­
ferred to state law in the matter of branching,
the question should be raised as to whether or
not such deference precludes the attainment
of anything approaching an optimal structure
of banking.
For the immediate future, and for some
time to come, the Federal Reserve’s greatest
challenges in the area of banking structure
and competition will be found in its adminis­
tration of the new Bank Holding Company
Act—expected to be enacted before Con­
gress adjourns its current session.1 Since
1967, banks have been forming one-bank*
’Mr. Mayo’s remarks were made prior to final
Congressional action on the One-Bank Holding
Company Act.

!I

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

holding companies to organize or purchase
subsidiaries, some of which are engaged in
activities that banks, themselves, are pre­
cluded from by banking laws. While acknowl­
edging the desirability of broadening existing
restrictions on bank activities, neither the
Congress nor the federal banking agencies are
willing to see the line between banking and
commerce obliterated. Not only does the
common control of purveyors and users of
credit raise serious conflict-of-interest possi­
bilities, but the very size of the banks in­
volved, to say nothing of the scope of their
planned activities, appears to some to threaten
too great a concentration of economic power.
Unless the law that finally emerges from
the Congress is much different than expected,
the Federal Reserve will be called upon to
decide whether existing or proposed activities
of companies owned by one-bank holding
companies “are so closely related to banking
or managing or controlling banks as to be a
proper incident thereto.”2 It is difficult to
exaggerate the importance of the Federal
Reserve’s responsibilities under the proposed
legislation. The Board will have to issue rul­
ings defining activities that are closely related
to banking. Almost certainly, lengthy hear­
ings will precede initial rulings. Moreover, it
will be necessary for the System to process
individual applications for acquisitions of
nonbanking subsidiaries. It is expected that
the casework load of the Board of Governors
and the Reserve banks might be doubled or
tripled, requiring an impressive amount of
recruiting and training of personnel.
Whatever the actual dimensions of the task
turn out to be, it is clear that the Federal
Reserve will play a crucial role in determining
the future evolution of the financial system.

12

2Quoted from the Bank Holding Company bill
reported out of the House-Senate conference committee.




I can assure you that we in the System will
take a sober view of our far-reaching re­
sponsibilities in implementing the legislation.
In te rn a tio n a l resp o n sib ilities

Another area of significant interest and
importance to the System, and to me person­
ally, is the role of the Federal Reserve in the
sphere of international finance. Over the past
decade, the Federal Reserve System has be­
come increasingly involved in international
financial relations, reflecting a growing con­
cern about the impact of our country’s
balance-of-payments deficit on the viability
of an international monetary system in which
the dollar has long been the focal point.
The United States has run a deficit in its
balance of payments almost continuously
over the past 20 years. For almost a decade
hardly anybody was concerned about it. In­
deed, the deficit in the 1950s was viewed
rather with satisfaction both by the world at
large and by the U. S. Government.
To the individual nations abroad, our de­
ficit represented the means by which they
could replenish their war-depleted reserves
with a currency accepted throughout the
world as a means of payments and a store of
value. Our deficit enabled many foreign
countries to move away from severe restric­
tions on their foreign trade which, in turn,
permitted them to flourish economically—
often beyond their fondest expectations.
To the United States, the deficits of the
Fifties were a source of satisfaction in that
they enabled the government to carry out its
plans for economic and military aid. In those
years, the United States gave over $60 billion
to other countries to lessen economic de­
privation and to encourage the free world to
defend itself against potential subjugation by
international Communism.
Throughout the Fifties, the monetary pol-

Business Conditions, December 1970

icy makers did not worry about the balanceof-payments problem. Formulation of mone­
tary policy was governed almost exclusive­
ly by domestic considerations—employment,
prices, and growth. In the late Fifties and
early Sixties, however, the situation changed
drastically. With restoration of currency con­
vertibility the restraint on foreign investment
was removed. The U. S. investor no longer
had to be concerned about his ability to
repatriate the proceeds of these investments.
Thus, he felt free to take advantage of profit
opportunities promised by the establishment
of the European Common Market. As a re­
sult, the private capital outflow accelerated
tremendously. On the other hand, the rapid
growth of income in Europe, along with the
reduction of trade barriers throughout the
free world, enabled producers abroad to
move toward large scale production and to
compete more effectively against U. S. pro­
ducers, both in the United States and abroad.
The U. S. balance-of-payments deficits
increased and led to a rapid rise in the ratio
of our foreign liquid liabilities to our gold
reserves. Our short-term liabilities surpassed
our gold stock in dollar volume in 1961.
Ever since, our liabilities have been increas­
ing and our gold stock has been declining.
These developments gave rise to concern
about the ability and willingness of the United
States to maintain its convertibility commit­
ment. The concern culminated in the 1960
“gold rush.” As you will recall, this specula­
tive purchasing in the London gold market
was in anticipation of a U. S. revaluation of
gold as a means of easing the burden of the
convertibility commitment.
The speculative attack was beaten back.
But it became clear that U. S. national eco­
nomic policies had to become more intimately
concerned with the country’s balance of pay­
ments. One result was that U. S. monetary



and fiscal policy makers began to take into
account balance-of-payments considerations
along with the more traditionally domestic
goals set forth in the Employment Act of
1946—high levels of employment, stable
growth, and implicitly, stable prices.
Thus, since early 1960 the Federal Reserve
entered—or rather re-entered—the interna­
tional arena. Its activities, and the develop­
ment of its policies, evolved along two distinct
paths:
1) the use of traditional monetary policy
tools for purposes of influencing the
balance of payments;
2) the development of new tools to deal
with the problems arising from the
balance-of-payments deficit.
As I have already suggested, balance-ofpayments objectives were added to the al­
ready established goals of monetary policy.
This merely increased the possibility of mu­
tually inconsistent and unattainable objec­
tives. What the task finally boiled down to
was an attempt to find a satisfactory middle
ground between the opposing forces of do­
mestic considerations and balance-of-payments considerations. With a sluggish do­
mestic economy in the early Sixties, the scale
in this trade-off inevitably tipped in favor of
domestic considerations. But because of
balance-of-payments considerations, expan­
sionary policies were pursued with sufficient
moderation to result in the maintenance of
a relatively stable price level through the
early 1960s. This paid dividends. Stability of
our price level relative to that of our foreign
competitors enabled us to maintain our com­
petitive position in the world markets. This
alone contributed to improvements in the
trade account. In addition, through “opera­
tion twist,” the Fed tried to discourage inter­
national short-term capital outflows believed
to be sensitive to short-term interest rate dif-

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

14

ferentials, and to encourage domestic invest­
ment by selling bills and purchasing bonds
presumed to depend upon the long-term
interest rate level.
By late 1965, the domestic economy began
to show signs of overheating and monetary
policy gradually swung to tightness. We
moved into a period where the domestic and
international objectives were in obvious har­
mony, but also a period where the success
of continuing policies to contain inflationary
trends were still in doubt.
In my book, fiscal policy failure in that
period far outdistanced the shortcomings of
monetary policy. The fact remains, however,
that the severe inflationary pressures we ex­
perienced had an adverse influence on our
balance of payments, specifically the trade
account. Our trade surplus, which rose
steadily between 1960-64, virtually disap­
peared, largely as a result of sharp increases
in imports prompted by our overheated
economy.
We have seen some improvements this
year. But the problem of finding a healthy
balance between the domestic and interna­
tional objectives of national policy will re­
main a challenge for us at the Fed. We know
that the U. S. economy cannot prosper with­
out a viable trade and financial relationship
with the outside world. Similarly, for years to
come, the outside world must depend heavily
on a healthy dollar—backed by a viable U. S.
economy—for its continued growth and
prosperity.
The Federal Reserve has made important
contributions in dealing with the strains con­
fronting the international monetary system.
The development, and imaginative use, of a
network of mutual credit lines between cen­
tral banks—the so-called swaps—have been
one of the major defenses we have developed
to deal with speculative pressures on the




monetary system. These and other arrange­
ments are an outgrowth of intensive partici­
pation by the Federal Reserve in international
consultations with other central banks. Out
of these consultations have emerged such
concrete measures of international coopera­
tion as the Gold Pool Arrangements in the
early Sixties, the General Agreement to Bor­
row that strengthened the facilities of the
IMF, and last year’s IMF special drawing
rights that hold promise of a better function­
ing international monetary system.
We have a long way to go in solving the
problems encountered in the monetary rela­
tionship among nations. In the years to come,
the continuously changing kaleidoscope of
challenges presented by the problems will
require imaginative building upon the base of
mutual cooperation among monetary authori­
ties. I expect to participate actively within the
framework of the Federal Open Market Com­
mittee in the search for solutions acceptable
to independent nations in our interdependent
world.
The international challenges that we at the
Chicago Fed shall be facing in the next
decade arise from our position as a leading
regional bank. Our Seventh Federal Reserve
District leads the nation in the export of
manufactured and agricultural goods. We
have corporations that have been real trailblazers in the development of multinational
business—one of the most significant de­
velopments on the international scene during
the past decade.
With this increasing international orienta­
tion of Midwest industry has come a pro­
found transformation of banking in our
district. Our banks have responded with gusto
to the growing international banking needs of
their customers. While in the early Sixties,
international banking facilities were offered
at only a few Midwest banks— and in many

Business Conditions, December 1970

instances in name only—at the beginning of
the Seventies, we have 24 banks with signifi­
cant loans abroad. Our banks have estab­
lished 20 overseas branches. Ten Edge Act
subsidiaries have been set up for purposes of
undertaking equity investment abroad. Nu­
merous other arrangements—such as repre­
sentative offices, ownership participation in
foreign banks, and an enlarged network of
correspondent relations with foreign banks—
have firmly established Midwest bankers as
a progressive group.
These developments have entailed new
challenges in virtually all functions at the
Chicago Fed. Our examination, discount, re­
serve analysis, and research departments all
have had to respond to the broadening hori­
zons of our banks. But our mission is broader
than just accepting the challenges. We envi­
sion our job to be more aggressive than that.
We must provide leadership and encourage­
ment to bank and industry alike in this area
of endeavor. Recognizing the vital role that
efficient international banking plays in healthy
growth, we plan to encourage expansion of
international banking in our district to the
limits of our ability.
As a first step in this direction we intend
to begin publication of a weekly international
letter. We know that Midwest banks, busi­
nesses, and the public have a pressing need
for timely and accurate information on inter­




national economic developments. We have
developed a number of sources of informa­
tion both here and abroad, and in our inter­
national letter we hope to share with you the
information available to us.
We want to participate with our banks in
finding solutions to problems they encounter
in their effort to grow to full-service interna­
tional operations. We are fully cognizant of
the importance of these international relation­
ships to the Midwest and to the nation—in­
deed, to the world at large.
Obviously, I have only scratched the sur­
face on issues and areas for our concern. I’ll
end here, nonetheless, with the hope that I
can continue this dialogue with each of you.
Any attempt to cover a topic of such breadth
in a single speech is foolhardy. But I do hope
that you leave with the view that the System
is very much alive, kicking, and relevant. As
for myself, I intend to do everything possible
to see that we accept the challenge provided
by the changing environment. A fundamental
reappraisal of many of our current policies
and regulations is definitely in order. As you
look back over this decade from the vantage
point of 1980, I am confident you will find
that the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
has played a vigorous role in meeting the
greater responsibilities arising from our tran­
sition into what may be called our post­
industrial economy.

15

B U SIN ESS

C O N D IT IO N S

is p u b lish e d

m o n th ly b y the F e d e ra l R ese rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o .

D ennis B. S h a rp e w a s p r im a rly resp o n sib le fo r the a rtic le " N e w fa rm la w —a step to w a rd the
m a rk e tp la c e ."

S u b scrip tio n s to Business Conditions a r e a v a ila b le to the p u b lic w ith o u t c h a rg e . For in fo r­
m atio n co ncern ing b u lk m a ilin g s , a d d re s s in q u irie s to the R esearch D e p a rtm e n t, F e d e ra l
R ese rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o , B o x 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , Illin o is 6 0 6 9 0 .

A rtic le s m a y be re p rin te d p ro v id e d source is c re d ite d . P le ase p ro v id e the b a n k 's R esearch

16

D e p artm e n t w ith a co p y o f a n y m a te ria l in w h ic h a n a rtic le is re p rin te d .




¥

Vi.

K,‘Siness
Conditions
j i

a review by the
Federal Reserve B ank of Chicago

Index for the year 1970
Month

Pages

January
June
March

10-16
2-4
12-16

February
October

11-15
7-11

A g ricu ltu re an d fa rm fin a n ce

Agriculture—Strong in 1969,
excess capacity continued......................................
Farm equipment prospects..........................................
Farm finance in a period of high interest rates...........
Farm mortgages
The impact of tight credit......................................
Food prices level off..................................................
New farm law
A step toward the marketplace..............................

December

2-8

October

2-6

B a n k in g , cre d it, an d m o n e ta ry policy

Bankers liberation
Equal opportunity in the money market...............
The Federal Reserve System
Vital and viable in the Seventies...........................
Housing, production, and finance.............................
Needed, adaptable home mortgages...........................
The one-bank holding company
History, issues, and pending legislation...............
Tight credit and the banks
1966 and 1969 compared......................................



December
March
April

9-15
5-11
13-16

July

2-16

May

4-11

Month

Pages

August
November
August
January
October
November
February
March

2-7
9-15
7-12
2-10
12-15
2-8
2-5
2-5

Econom ic conditions/ g e n e ra l

Consumption trails rising incomes.............................
Models as economic tools............................................
More working wives, fewer children.........................
The 1960s—lessons for the 1970s.............................
Paying for pollution control........................................
Recovery in corporate profits....................................
The trend of business..................................................
The trend of business..................................................
The trend of business
Continued strength in capital goods.....................
The trend of business
Impact of the truck strikes......................................
The trend of business
Inventory growth ahead..........................................

April

2-9

May

2-3

September

2-7

February
April
June
June
September

6-10
10-13
10-16
5-10
7-12

In te rn a tio n a l econom ic d evelo p m e n ts

The EEC and U. S. agriculture....................................
Foreign trade—the uneasy surplus...........................
Measuring the U. S. Balance of Payments.................
Perspective on the Seaway..........................................
U. S. trade—pressures for restriction.........................