View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Understanding
Urban Decline

ABOUT THE COVER
The burned-out mansion on the
cover was built in 1885 for lumber
baron Lucien Moore in Brush Park,
Detroit’s wealthiest neighborhood at
the time. Brush Park declined rapidly
in the 1930s and 1940s, becoming one
of the city’s most blighted areas by
1960. But in recent years, developers
have begun to renovate some of the
neighborhood’s grand old homes. The
Lucien Moore mansion, for example,
was rebuilt in 2006 and retrofitted
for apartments in 2012. Economists
may debate the merits of various
approaches to urban revitalization,
but one way or another, the cycle of
development and redevelopment
usually runs its course.

Cover Photo: Camilo José Vergara
Adjacent Photo: Michael G. Smith
Illustration: The Calvert Lith. Co., Library of Congress

ABOUT THE RICHMOND FED
MISSION: As a regional Reserve Bank, we serve the public by fostering the stability,
integrity, and efficiency of our nation’s monetary, financial, and payments systems.
VISION: To be an innovative policy and services leader for America’s economy.
KEY FUNCTIONS: We contribute to the formulation of monetary policy. We supervise
and regulate banks and financial holding companies headquartered in the Fifth Federal
Reserve District. We process currency and electronic payments for banks and provide
financial services to the U.S. Treasury. We also work with a wide variety of partners to
strengthen communities in the Fifth District.

Contents
Message from the Interim President.........................................................................2
FEATURE ESSAY
Understanding Urban Decline..................................................................................4
Fifth District Economic Report. . .............................................................................. 21
Boards, Councils, Officers, and Senior Professionals.....................................................................26
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Board.............................................................................................27
Baltimore Branch Board.........................................................................................................................28
Charlotte Branch Board..........................................................................................................................29
Community Depository Institutions Advisory Council............................................................................30
Community Investment Council.............................................................................................................30
Payments Advisory Council....................................................................................................................31
Management Committee.......................................................................................................................32
Officers and Senior Professionals...........................................................................................................33
Federal Reserve Information Technology (FRIT) Management Council.................................................34
FRIT Officers and Senior Professionals...................................................................................................35
Financial Statements...............................................................................................................................36

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

1

MESSAGE FROM THE INTERIM PRESIDENT

Why the Richmond Fed Studies Urban Issues

A

s a regional Reserve Bank, an important part of the Richmond Fed’s job is studying
what contributes to—or impedes—economic vitality in our region. Metropolitan
areas, which are home to the majority of our population and economic activity, are
an especially important part of the equation, as Santiago Pinto and Tim Sablik discuss in this
year’s Annual Report essay, “Understanding Urban Decline.” Here in the Fifth District, we have
some of the nation’s most culturally and economically vibrant cities, but we also have cities suffering persistent decline. And even within areas experiencing rapid growth, there are
pockets of deeply entrenched poverty.
Learning about the forces that shape urban areas has been of interest to the Richmond
Fed for many years. We recently have focused those efforts, with our Research, Outreach,
and Community Development functions joining together to study not just why cities grow,
but also why they decline. We’re working to measure the consequences of various policy
responses and to identify strategies that might help ameliorate urban decline, particularly
with respect to housing, income, and transportation. We also are studying the constraints
and incentives faced by the low- and moderate-income residents of our District to gain
insight into economic mobility and the persistence of poverty. To do so, we’re convening
academic and policy experts, conducting original research, and engaging with community
and business leaders from throughout the region.
Of course, our job is more than studying—it’s also sharing what we learn with the people
who live and work in our District. That’s the goal of this year’s essay, in which Santiago and
Tim explain the underlying economics of city formation and decline and distill the existing
research on urban revitalization efforts. I’ll leave the details to the authors, but I would like to
highlight some key takeaways.
First, as they note, a city’s decline wouldn’t necessarily be a cause for concern if the
people who lived there were able to easily move to another city with better amenities or
employment opportunities. Some people might want to stay in a declining city, for example,
to remain close to family or friends, but often there are factors preventing people who would
like to move from doing so.

2

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Second, in response to urban decline, community leaders may consider two general
types of approaches: place-based policies and people-based policies. Place-based policies
focus on revitalizing the city itself, for example, by providing tax credits and grants to potential employers and developers. A number of these programs have been tried in the United
States, and in the Fifth District, but the evidence of how well they work—and whether they
actually benefit the people they’re intended to—is mixed.
People-based policies include helping people move to areas with better economic prospects or enabling them to invest more in their education so they can put their skills to use in
a new industry or city. Research has found that moving can have long-term positive effects,
especially on young children, and the benefits of education are likely to extend well beyond
the individual. But as with place-based policies, people-based policies can have unforeseen
consequences—and there’s no guarantee that what works in one city will work in another.
The challenge is that all cities are different—just head up from Charleston, South Carolina,
to Charleston, West Virginia, by way of Charlotte, North Carolina, to see what I mean. Every
city in our District has its own character, its own challenges, and its own successes. Here at the
Richmond Fed, we’re excited and honored to have the opportunity to learn from those challenges and successes and to provide community leaders with information and connections
that will help them design the most effective programs for their unique places and people.
Just as cities undergo changes, so do institutions. The Richmond Fed is preparing for
an important change right now. At the time of this writing, our Board of Directors is in the
midst of its search for our next president and chief executive officer. During this period, I can
confidently report that the entire Richmond Fed team remains focused and committed to
delivering effectively on our policy, banking supervision, payments, and community development responsibilities.

Mark L. Mullinix
Interim President and Chief Operating Officer

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

3

In 1881, Detroit’s Brush Park neighborhood was called “Little Paris,” a nickname
that faded long before this streetscape was photographed again in 2011. The
cover of this annual report shows the same neighborhood in the foreground
but not the same house that appears below.

Photos: top ©Burton Historical Collection, Detroit Public Library; bottom ©Michael G. Smith

4

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Understanding
Urban Decline
By Santiago Pinto and Tim Sablik

O

ver the past two centuries, the population of the United States has become increasingly concentrated in cities. In the 1800s, only 6 percent of people lived in urban
areas. Today, nearly two-thirds of Americans live in cities, and these cities account
for only 3.5 percent of available land in the country.1 Urbanization also is taking place around
the globe. More than half of the world’s population lives in cities today, and the World Bank
estimates that cities collectively will add another two billion people by 2045.
Not only is population in the United States concentrated in cities, the nation’s economic
activity is as well. Large cities accounted for roughly 85 percent of the country’s gross domestic product (GDP) in 2010.2 Concentrating economic activity in this way produces a number
of benefits. Places with higher population density exhibit faster growth in productivity and
per-capita GDP. Cities are also wellsprings of innovation, accounting for a disproportionate
share of new patents.3 Clearly, cities matter.
These benefits make it all the more puzzling that a number of prominent U.S. cities have
experienced large population declines in recent decades. St. Louis, Detroit, Cleveland, and
Pittsburgh, for example, each lost half or more of their populations between 1950 and 2010.
Others, such as Baltimore, Chicago, and Minneapolis suffered smaller, though still substantial,
population losses during the same period.
If these changes merely reflected shifts in population from one city to another more
desirable or more productive city, there wouldn’t necessarily be any cause for concern.
However, evidence suggests that urban population outflows have hurt some lower-income people who have been left behind. Declining city centers frequently exhibit high
and persistent poverty rates. For instance, in Detroit and Cleveland, 40.3 percent and
36.2 percent of the population, respectively, were below the poverty line in 2015.
Meanwhile, the average income of the surrounding suburbs has risen.4 In fact, the metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) surrounding many declining cities have grown in population since 1950. For example, the Detroit and Baltimore MSAs each added more than
one million people between 1950 and 2010.5 As city centers decline, those people and
firms who can leave do, and those who cannot (frequently low-income, low-skilled households) are stuck with dimming economic prospects.
Urban policymakers in declining cities justifiably want to revitalize their cities and help
the people who live there. To do so effectively, it is important to first understand what factors determine where people and firms locate, both within and across cities, and what might
cause them to move. Second, it is important to understand what policies will be effective
at reversing urban decline. The economic benefits that arise from people and firms living

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

5

Chicago generally is an
exception to the rule that
wealthier residents prefer to
live outside city centers.

and working together in a city (referred to by economists as agglomeration economies) suggest that even small-scale policy interventions could have outsized effects and potentially
improve the welfare of many individuals living in a city, not just the original target group. But
as this essay will show, policymakers must carefully consider which interventions will best
assist the households they wish to help. The mixed record of any one type of urban revitalization policy suggests that a combination of “place-based” policies (which direct resources
to help certain low-income areas) and “people-based” policies (which provide assistance to
people regardless of where they live) may be more successful. This essay reviews evidence of
the effectiveness of each approach.

Why Do Cities Exist?
In order to examine the effects of different urban policies, it is useful to first understand the
benefits that cities provide. Cities arise because there are advantages to concentrating economic activity in one place, known as agglomeration economies. When businesses in the
same industry cluster together, they can share inputs, such as tires for cars. The more carmakers that cluster in a region, the more demand they’ll generate for tires in that region, making
it more attractive for tire makers to locate in the city as well. That agglomeration reduces
costs for all the carmakers. Clustered firms in the same industry also can share a common
pool of skilled labor. For example, the high concentration of tech companies in Silicon Valley
attracts a lot of software engineers. This is particularly advantageous in the case of industries
where any individual firm may experience sudden changes in demand. Workers can transition from shrinking firms to growing ones as demand fluctuates. Finally, firms may benefit
from knowledge spillovers. Discovery of new ideas is facilitated by more people living and
working in close proximity, and new ideas spread from firms through shared labor pools and
supply chains.6

6

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

The preceding examples describe localization economies—benefits that accrue from
clusters of firms in the same industry. But agglomeration benefits also arise from concentrations of different industries. A variety of firms can take advantage of general inputs such
as transportation networks or banking and legal services. Many firms employ workers with
similar skills, even if they are not in the same industry, and cities provide access to a larger
pool of skilled labor. Firms also enjoy knowledge spillovers from businesses in different fields
or from other institutions such as universities. These benefits that arise as a result of a diverse
city are known as urbanization economies.
Cities also provide a variety of production and consumption benefits to individuals who
live there. One striking observation is that all else being equal, it appears that worker productivity and average wages are higher in more densely populated areas.7 Economists think
these gains come from the fact that the larger the city, the more opportunities workers have
to interact with other skilled workers and gain valuable experience that they carry with them
throughout their careers.8 Concentrations of people also make a variety of amenities, such as
restaurants or theaters, commercially viable.
Of course, there are limits and costs to urbanization. Higher population densities come
with higher cost of land (rents) as well as more congestion and crime. At some point, these
costs will discourage further development.

At the most basic
level, households
face a trade-off
between land and
transportation costs.

What Do Cities Look Like?
Agglomeration economies also affect where firms and households locate within a city. When
there are benefits from locating close to each other, a variety of different spatial configurations can arise. In other words, agglomeration economies can lead to “multiple equilibria.”
This provides insight into why we observe the variety of outcomes across cities that we do.
For instance, suppose that firms must decide where to set up their facilities in a context in
which they benefit from interacting with each other. These benefits, however, decline with
distance. This leads to a city with a central business district (CBD) surrounded by a residential
area. Simultaneously, some workers may either decide to live close to work, making the CBD
a mixed-use commercial/residential area, or live in the suburbs in an entirely residential area.
At the most basic level, households face a trade-off between land and transportation
costs. Living and working in the CBD lowers commuting costs, but at the same time, housing
will be more expensive if many people want to live there. Some households might choose
to reside in locations that are more distant from the CBD if they are compensated by lower
housing prices. In addition to the value of land, housing prices also reflect factors such as the
quality of schools, access to parks, crime rates, and levels of environmental quality that make
some locations within the city more or less attractive than others. For example, studies show
that people are willing to pay more to live in neighborhoods with good schools. Housing
prices rise approximately 1 percent to 2 percent when test scores, used to measure school
quality, increase by 5 percent. In dollar terms, this amounts to an increase of roughly $4,000
on average.9
In most U.S. cities, wealthier households tend to live farther away from the city center,
though there are a few notable exceptions (such as Chicago, Philadelphia, and Washington,
D.C.).10 One explanation for this is that wealthier households prefer to occupy more land and

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

7

The main underlying
assumption in
these models is that
residents can move
freely within cities,
but they balance the
various trade-offs in
such a way that leaves
residents indifferent
to moving.

8

therefore are willing to live in the suburbs despite higher commuting costs because the price
of housing per square foot is lower. On the other hand, when a household’s income becomes
sufficiently large, it may choose to move back to the city center to reduce time spent commuting. This type of trade-off could explain, for instance, why both very poor and very wealthy
households are found living in some downtowns. Cities such as Boston, New Orleans, Atlanta,
and Philadelphia are examples of this type of spatial pattern. Additionally, public transportation can help explain why poorer households live in the city center. Although the cost of
housing per unit of land is higher in the city, public transportation allows poor households
that don’t have access to cars to economize on transportation costs.11
Transportation may further explain the trend of households moving from city centers
to the suburbs, often called suburbanization. Several studies suggest that the development
of the highway system contributes to “urban sprawl.”12 One study estimated that just one
highway passing through a central city reduces its population by 18 percent.13 Cities that
experience such a decline in commuting costs do still tend to attract population, but that
inflow typically causes the city to expand geographically more than it increases the number
of people living in the city center.
Certain amenities, such as schools, also may explain neighborhood sorting by income or
race. For instance, as wealthier households move to the suburbs, the quality of schools and
other public services provided there will tend to rise. As this process unfolds, lower-income
households are left behind in the city center with limited access to high-quality local public
services. This has been observed in the suburbanization that has taken place in many large
U.S. cities starting around the mid-twentieth century. A prominent recent study, for example,
relies on the school desegregation experience to examine how a change in the public school
system affected the school choice and localization decisions of residents. The study finds that
school desegregation led to a decline in white enrollment in central city public schools in the
South, and this decline was linked to white suburban migration. In non-Southern districts,
the response was an increase in white private school enrollment.14 These kinds of forces tend
to exacerbate the initial income stratification across locations and help explain why neighborhood differences tend to persist.
To study these various trade-offs, economists rely on models (known in the field as spatial equilibrium models) to examine the economic implications of how households (and/or
firms) choose and move to their preferred locations. The main underlying assumption in these
models is that residents can move freely within cities, but they balance the various trade-offs
in such a way that leaves residents indifferent to moving. (See sidebar on page 9 and appendix on page 17.) Moving to a new neighborhood, for example, might provide the benefits of
certain amenities at the cost of more expensive housing or longer commutes. Across cities,
different characteristics will be reflected in local wages as well as housing costs. For example,
evidence suggests that households would not only be willing to pay higher housing prices to
live in more attractive cities, they also would accept lower wages.15
The basic spatial equilibrium model has implications for how cities might look in a setting where the underlying forces of technology and macroeconomic features are not changing over time. Cities are subject to all manner of dynamic forces, however, that can lead to
shifts in urban populations and, in turn, city size and composition.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Willingness to pay
for Commercial use

Commercial/Residential
District Border

VA L U E O F L A N D

Willingness to pay
for Residential use
City Border

Willingness to pay
for Agricultural use

D I S TA N C E F R O M E M P L O Y M E N T C E N T E R

Modeling Land Use

T

his diagram shows the land-price gradients for firms,
households, and agriculture. The land-price gradients,
also referred to as bid-rent functions, represent the maximum price economic agents are willing to pay at each
location. Land prices, as indicated by the functions, are
highest in the central business district (CBD), which, in
this case, is the only employment center, and they decline
as people and firms move farther away from the CBD. The
negative slopes of the commercial/manufacturing and
residential land-price gradients are a consequence of the
trade-offs between transportation and land costs when
people and firms are deciding where to locate their homes
or production facilities. The shape of the residential landprice gradient can be explained as follows. Households
commute to work in the CBD and decide where to reside.
At a locational equilibrium, households should not have
incentives to move. This means that households should
obtain the same utility at all locations. Note, however,
that residing at more distant locations entails higher
commuting costs. For households to be willing to reside
farther from the CBD, they will need to be compensated
through lower land prices. Firms face similar trade-offs, so
the same type of reasoning explains the downward slope
of the firms’ land-price gradient. A more detailed explanation can be found in the appendix.

The relative slopes of the land-price gradients determine where households and firms locate and how land is
used at different locations. We can think about how land
is allocated across different uses through a mechanism
that works as follows. Suppose that (absentee) landlords
own the land, and they rent it, at each location, to whoever offers the highest price through a bidding process.
The diagram shows a case in which the firms’ land-price
gradient is steeper than the residential-price gradient. As
a result, firms outbid households at locations closer to the
CBD, so land is allocated to commercial or manufacturing
uses at those locations, and households outbid firms in
the suburbs. The size of the city is determined in this case
by the intersection of the residential land-price gradient
and the horizontal line indicating agricultural land rent.
An urban area arises when land rents for nonagricultural
uses at locations closer to the CBD are higher than the
agricultural rent. At the urban fringe, rents for nonagricultural and agricultural uses should be equalized. The
observed market land rent is determined by the party
with the highest willingness to pay at any location. Near
the CBD this will be the commercial bid-rent curve until
it intersects with the residential bid-rent curve. The residential curve will then determine the price of land until it
intersects with the agricultural line.
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

9

Sturdy row houses like
these in Baltimore often
become hotbeds of urban
revitalization.

10

The Lifecycle of Cities
Cities undergo long cycles of development and decay. When a city is new, buildings near
the CBD are the most desirable and tend to be occupied by a mix of firms and wealthier
households. But as those buildings age and deteriorate, those households may move to
newer developments surrounding the city, leaving behind lower-income households. This
process can repeat multiple times, pushing the city border outward as higher-income households retreat to the newest ring of development. Eventually, deteriorated buildings in the
city center are redeveloped, once again attracting higher-income households back to the
city and starting the cycle anew. This has taken place, for instance, in cities such as Chicago
and Philadelphia.16 This process, however, has raised some controversies since transforming
a neighborhood from low- to high-income may displace the low-income households who
live there, a process called gentrification.
In addition to the natural aging cycle, there may be other forces that contribute to gentrification as well. One view suggests that gentrification is more likely to be observed at locations
that border richer neighborhoods.17 Richer neighborhoods attract more high-income households and expand into adjacent areas that are relatively poor. Another related view states that
high-income neighborhoods are characterized by low crime rates that eventually attract additional richer households.18 Lower-income households are displaced by this sorting.
Because buildings are durable goods, it can take a long time for a city to move through
its lifecycle. When a city’s population is growing, it is profitable to construct new housing
because demand and prices for housing are rising, and the city expands rapidly. But when
the population declines, existing housing stock doesn’t simply disappear. It can take decades
before it is profitable to refurbish or replace a building. The surplus of housing depresses
house prices below the cost of construction, and the city stops growing.19 Moreover, falling
rents may draw lower-skilled and lower-income households into the city, intensifying urban
sorting by income.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Cities also experience shocks that alter their composition of firms or people. Cities such as
San Francisco, Washington, D.C., New York, and Cleveland, for example, appear to have experienced fairly rapid changes in firm composition without population changes of the same
magnitude. Discovery of a new technique by a firm in one city may shift the center of that
industry, resulting in an exodus of firms from one city and an influx into another. This leads
to sudden growth or decline across cities. Population loss can result as skilled workers follow
firms to the new center of that industry.20 Alternatively, employment in a city could decline
for other reasons, such as changes in technology leading to greater automation at major
employers. This may lead to a city with a thriving CBD but a surrounding residential area that
is too large for its current population, as seen in Detroit and other manufacturing cities in the
Rust Belt.21 Urban policymakers faced with either a sudden shock or a steady decline have a
natural inclination to revitalize their cities. But should they intervene? And if so, how?

The powerful reinforcing
effects of agglomeration
economies mean that
even small policy
changes can trigger large
transformations in a city
over time.

Justifying Policy Responses to Urban Decline
It is not easy to directly test whether people are genuinely left indifferent about moving—by
variation in the prices of housing and amenities—within an urban area, a key prediction of
the spatial equilibrium model. (See the appendix on page 17 for more detail.) Nonetheless,
there seems to be some evidence that supports this implication. Households do not migrate
disproportionately to higher-wage cities, for example. Other factors, such as higher housing prices and/or city amenities and disamenities explain differences in wages across cities.
Therefore, variations in wages and housing prices across cities should not be sufficient justification for policy intervention. For instance, high wages may be observed in relatively unattractive cities or in cities with higher housing prices.22
On the other hand, if households face hurdles to moving, policymakers may be able to
help people who are “trapped” in declining areas. Often, higher-skilled and higher-income
households can more easily move when a neighborhood declines, while poorer and lower-skilled individuals are left behind. Artificial barriers, such as zoning laws or minimum lot sizes, make the process of moving to thriving communities even more difficult. To the extent that
such mismatch exists, policy actions to alleviate these frictions could be welfare-improving.
The spatial equilibrium model also provides two justifications for the implementation of
policies aimed at revitalizing a declining city.23 The powerful reinforcing effects of agglomeration economies mean that even small policy changes can trigger large transformations in a city
over time, providing an argument in favor of promoting urban renewal. Higher concentrations
of people and firms have, on balance, positive effects on almost everyone living in a city. Higher
population density means greater learning and sharing of knowledge, more productive firms
and workers, and more efficient supply lines and labor matching. Thus, investments may well
“jumpstart” these forces in ways that could have benefits that clearly outweigh their costs. In
theory, even an announcement that a neighborhood will be revitalized could by itself trigger a
variety of positive effects before the government spends any money.24
As noted earlier, agglomeration effects create the possibility of multiple equilibria for a
city when they are sufficiently strong. In this case, efforts to “push” a city from a low-employment/low-wage equilibrium (poverty trap) to a high-employment/high-wage equilibrium
could be worthwhile. In practice, however, there is little evidence of cities that have moved

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

11

from one equilibrium to another. One study looked at the extreme case of the Japanese cities
Hiroshima and Nagasaki, which were entirely destroyed in World War II. Following the war,
they were rebuilt and returned to their long-run population trends, suggesting that a city’s
spatial configuration is both unique and stable.25
If policymakers decide that some intervention is warranted, there are a number of different approaches they could consider. One option is to focus on helping households by giving
them the tools to improve their situation. This could involve removing barriers that prevent
households from relocating to thriving parts of the city, providing housing vouchers to help
them move, or improving transportation networks to reduce commuting costs. An alternative approach is to focus on revitalizing the city itself. This includes revitalizing residential or
commercial buildings that have declined or offering incentives to employers to locate in the
city and hire local people. Economists have labeled these different approaches people-based
and place-based policies, respectively.
The ultimate goal of either approach is, presumably, to help people. One of the key
responsibilities of policymakers is to consider how effective any given policy might be at
achieving that goal. Additionally, the presence of agglomeration economies and social interactions tend to magnify the impact of policies in the context of cities and could, potentially,
end up benefitting everyone in the city. However, it remains a challenge to precisely identify
and implement those policies that fully exploit and take advantage of the external effects
that characterize urban areas.

Revitalizing Places
Enterprise Zones (EZs) are one of the most widely used, and widely studied, forms of placebased policy intervention. EZs designate an area for assistance, typically in the form of tax
credits for employers and grants for various development projects. EZs have been implemented on both the state and federal level. Connecticut established the first state-based EZ
in 1982, and forty states had some type of EZ by 2008. On the federal level, Empowerment
Zones (which are similar to EZs on the state level) were used from 1993 to around 2009.26
Under this program, local governments could apply to the Department of Housing and Urban
Development for benefits similar to state EZs. Eleven cities were selected for Empowerment
Zones in the first phase of the program, including Atlanta, Baltimore, Chicago, Detroit, New
York, and Philadelphia.27
Investment in these various programs has been substantial, but measuring their impact
has been challenging. One problem is that targeted areas often don’t align neatly with census tracts, zip codes, or other standard geographical boundaries used for collecting data.
Another challenge is controlling for other factors that influence local economic conditions
and finding appropriate control cases for comparison. A third difficulty is that any benefits
attributed to place-based interventions may come at a cost to other regions. For example,
persuading a business to relocate from one city to another city benefits the latter at the
expense of the former. On the other hand, promoting development in one part of the city
may spur private investment that benefits nearby, nontargeted areas. Any empirical study
looking to measure the benefits of these programs must account for these positive and
negative spillover effects.

12

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Given these challenges, it is not surprising that studies have found mixed effects from
state and federal EZ programs. At the state level, an examination of California’s EZ program
found no evidence of a significant impact on employment, while an analysis of Texas’ EZs
found a positive effect, particularly in lower-paying industries.28 At the federal level, some
studies have found positive, statistically significant effects on employment and wages from
Empowerment Zones.29 On the other hand, there is also evidence of significantly negative
spillover effects on areas geographically near or economically similar to Empowerment
Zones, suggesting that at least some of the “gains” may simply be shifted economic activity.30
Whether these programs actually help their intended recipients is also controversial. While
more recent EZs require employers to hire locally in order to receive the benefits, not all programs have had this stipulation, meaning some benefits may have accrued to workers who
moved to the city with firms rather than to the original target group of individuals.
Other place-based urban policies focus on improving residential buildings and infrastructure. Examples of federal urban renewal programs include the Housing Act of 1949,
which provided loans to cities to acquire and redevelop decaying neighborhoods, and the
Model Cities Program of the 1960s, which focused more on renewal of neighborhoods rather
than wholesale reconstruction. Evidence on the impact of these projects is also inconclusive. Studies don’t suggest they had a meaningful impact on population growth or per-capita
income, but that may be due to their relatively limited funding.31 Urban renewal projects do
seem to generate higher land values—even in nearby neighborhoods not directly targeted,
as found in one study of the Neighborhoods-in-Bloom program in Richmond, Virginia.32 One
of the main findings of that study is that after accounting for all the external effects generated by this kind of program, the overall benefits may more than compensate for the costs of
implementation.
To the extent that urban renewal programs generate higher land values, many of the
benefits may accrue to landowners rather than low-income households if those households
are mostly renters. For example, one study of the federal Empowerment Zone program found
that it had no effect on poverty and employment for residents but a large effect on property prices.33 Successful urban renewal projects also may end up displacing those households if neighborhoods become more desirable because of new construction.34 An influx of

Hiroshima was totally
destroyed during World War II,
but the city eventually
returned to its long-run
population trend.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

13

Photo: ©SuperStock/GettyImages

When Pittsburgh’s population
peaked in the 1950s, the city’s
economy relied heavily on the
steel industry.

higher-income households may bid up rents and price out the low-income households the
renewal projects were intended to help, raising the problem of gentrification described earlier. Policymakers undertaking a place-based approach to reversing urban decline should be
mindful of unintended consequences such as these.

Investing in People
Another criticism of urban renewal programs is that they encourage households to remain
in neighborhoods with few opportunities. That is, those areas may have declined for a reason, and applying a fresh coat of paint may merely address the symptoms and not the causes of decline. Enticing firms to locate in those areas through EZs could solve this problem,
but only if the firms seek the skills possessed by households living in those areas. In light of
these challenges, some economists have said that the best thing households in declining city
neighborhoods can do is move.35 And to the extent that they are constrained from leaving,
policymakers should help them.
In the mid-1990s, the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development took this
approach with the Moving to Opportunity (MTO) program. The program was implemented in
five cities—Baltimore, Boston, Chicago, Los Angeles, and New York—and it provided housing
vouchers to families living in high-poverty neighborhoods to help them move to low-poverty neighborhoods. While participation in the program was voluntary, the eligible applicants
who received vouchers were chosen randomly, making it a good case study of this policy
approach. Some households (the treatment group) received housing vouchers that could
only be used in census tracts with poverty rates below 10 percent; others received vouchers
with no geographical restrictions (Section 8 vouchers); and the control group received no
vouchers and continued receiving public assistance.
Some research has found that for adults, the program seems to have had no lasting effect
on earnings or economic self-sufficiency.36 Moreover, of the households offered a voucher to
move to lower-poverty neighborhoods, less than half accepted, and some that did move later
moved back.37 For children, the evidence was mixed. Those who were younger than thirteen
when they moved to a lower-poverty area seemed to benefit. Compared with children in the
control group, they had incomes that were about $3,500 (31 percent) higher on average in
their mid-twenties, were more likely to attend college, and were less likely to become single
parents. On the other hand, children who were older than thirteen when they moved suffered

14

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

worse long-term outcomes, possibly because they already had established social networks
in their old neighborhoods and disrupting those networks caused more harm than good.38
More recent research examines the outcomes of similar housing voucher programs and
finds more favorable evidence of this type of policy. From a research standpoint, the fact
that participation in the MTO experiment and the use of the housing vouchers was voluntary introduces potential self-selection bias into the results of the experiment. Some children
could have benefitted from the relocation to a low-poverty neighborhood, but since their
parents were not really motivated to move, they did not participate in the program. To overcome this problem, one study focuses on the outcomes of a specific program that involved
the mandatory relocation of households to other neighborhoods because the public housing
where they lived was set to be demolished. This study concludes that the relocation of households had large and positive effects on children (they were more likely to be employed and
earned higher wages as adults), and these effects were substantially larger than those found
in the MTO experiment. This suggests that the children who did not participate in the MTO
experiment were very likely those who could have benefitted most.39
Rather than attempting to move residents to more prosperous areas, another people-based
approach is to improve residents’ human capital. Certainly investing in education and human
capital has benefits on the individual level. But having a more educated, more productive
urban population has positive spillover effects on the city as a whole, too. In fact, these spillover effects seem to play a key role in defining modern successful cities. In the early postWorld War II era, city growth was tied to high concentrations of physical capital, like the car
factories of Detroit or the steel mills of Pittsburgh. But since 1980, human capital has become
a more reliable indicator of a thriving city. Average wages in cities with highly educated populations, such as Boston or San Francisco, are much higher for both college graduates and
high school graduates than in cities with low levels of college education.40
There may be other spillover benefits as well. Individuals with more education are significantly less likely to commit crimes. Thus, increasing high school graduation rates (for men
in particular) seems to provide substantial social savings to cities in the form of less crime.41
Raising human capital levels and the number of high-skilled jobs in a city also has a multiplier
effect. One study found that for each new job in an innovative field added to a city, five additional jobs were created. This includes high-skilled jobs (such as lawyers, teachers, or nurses),
and low-skilled jobs (such as waiters, baristas, or taxi drivers).42

Pittsburgh’s population is less
than half what it was in the
1950s, but the city’s economy
is more diversified.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

15

When considering
policies, something
to bear in mind is that
cities are far from
identical. The forces that
gave rise to the movie
industry in Los Angeles
or the auto industry
in Detroit may not be
replicable elsewhere.

Santiago Pinto is a senior policy
economist and Tim Sablik is an
economics writer in the Research
Department at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond. The authors would
like to thank Kartik Athreya, Thomas
Lubik, Ray Owens, Pierre Sarte, and
John Weinberg for many helpful
comments.
The views expressed are those of the
authors and not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
or the Federal Reserve System.

16

Cities with higher levels of human capital also tend to attract more individuals with high
levels of human capital, creating clusters of innovation, such as Silicon Valley near San Jose,
California, or the Research Triangle in Raleigh, Durham, and Chapel Hill, North Carolina. What
is less certain is whether policymakers in declining cities can create new innovation clusters
by investing in universities or other research institutions. Empirical evidence does suggest
that such investments could have lasting benefits for a city, but many of these studies examine the effects of well-established universities on a region. It is more difficult to say for certain
what leads individuals and firms to cluster around certain institutions and not others, and
it is unclear whether attempting to create such clusters out of whole cloth would succeed.
Moreover, the greater mobility of highly educated individuals may reduce the ability of cities
to fully benefit from investments in human capital. If a declining city doesn’t already have an
innovative sector to employ newly trained individuals, those individuals may choose to leave
the city after completing their education, taking their human capital with them.

Taking a Balanced Approach
The urban economics literature has much to say about our increasingly urban world. First,
agglomeration economies are powerful forces that have led to the dramatic urbanization of
the world’s population over the past two centuries. These forces have fed into each other to
generate remarkable economic growth. These feedback effects mean that even small changes to a city can have a large impact over the long run. Urban policies are often thought of in
terms of large-scale projects: building a new sports complex or business center, redeveloping
whole neighborhoods, or adding new public transportation infrastructure. But spatial models
of cities suggest that small-scale projects could be just as effective at promoting city growth.
Creating growth through new industries may be more challenging than maintaining
or restoring existing industries in a city, however. Because agglomeration economies arise
organically, it is hard to say what incentives could attract new firms to locations they previously avoided.43 When considering policies, something to bear in mind is that cities are
far from identical. The forces that gave rise to the movie industry in Los Angeles or the auto
industry in Detroit may not be replicable elsewhere. Moreover, policies that generated a positive response in one city have no guarantee of doing the same in another. As the studies we’ve
highlighted illustrate, policies implemented in the complex social environment of cities may
trigger all sorts of unanticipated responses. This doesn’t mean that policymakers can draw no
lessons from experiments in other cities, but the key lesson is to proceed with caution.
Finally, while this essay has presented examples of both place-based and people-based
policies, these should not be viewed as mutually exclusive. There may be practical limitations
to how far city leaders can take any one approach. Emptying out a declining neighborhood
may seem like the efficient choice in an economic model, for example, but it may not be
a realistic solution. Rather, policymakers should consider a mix of responses that would be
most appropriate for their respective cities. Two main questions should guide their choices. First, are there policies that, in the spatial context of cities, can potentially improve the
well-being of nearly all residents? Second, to what extent do more targeted policies help
their intended recipients? n

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Appendix

Basic Urban Equilibrium
Location decisions of households
Consider a linear city, where identical households commute between their place of residence and place
of work, the central business district (CBD). The distance from a household’s residence to the CBD is x
(the CBD is located at x = 0). The commuting cost per mile is denoted by t, which is assumed constant.
Total commuting costs for a consumer residing x miles from the CBD is tx. All households earn an exogenously given income w. Disposable income for a household residing x miles from the CBD is w − tx.
Households consume two goods: a nonhousing good, c, and land, denoted by ℓ. The simplest version
of the model assumes that residential consumption of land is given and equal to one, i.e., ℓ = 1, and
preferences are represented by the utility function v(c) = c. The price of the nonhousing good is equal
at all locations and it is normalized to one, and land can be rented at r per acre. The budget constraint
is w − tx = c + r. Households are perfectly mobile within an urban area (and across cities), which implies
that at a locational equilibrium all households achieve the same level of utility. In our model, this means
that u = w − tx − r for all x, where u is taken as exogenous. From this equilibrium condition, we obtain
the land-price gradient r ––– r (x, w, t, u) = w − tx − u. The latter is usually referred to as the residential land
bid-rent function since it actually represents the maximum rent a household is willing to pay for land at
different locations. Note that r/ x = − t < 0, so that residential land rent declines as distance from the
CBD increases. This condition has the following interpretation. As households move one mile farther
away from the CBD, commuting costs increase by t. Households would be indifferent between staying
and moving to the new location if the decline in land rents fully compensate for the additional commuting costs.

Location decisions of firms
Suppose that each firm produces a fixed amount of output q employing one unit of land and structure
capital. The price of q, denoted by p, and the cost of structure, denoted by C, are given and do not
change with x. Firms pay the land rent rf , where rf changes with x. Firms can set up their production
facilities at any location x. However, the products have to be taken to the port or transportation terminal, located at the CBD, for delivery to their final destinations. The cost of transporting one unit of q per
mile is tq , so total transportation costs to the CBD for a firm located at x are tq x q. Profits at location x are
consequently given by p = pq − C − tq xq − rf. Perfect competition and free entry of firms drive profits to
22
zero at every location, so the highest land rent a firm is willing to pay at x is:
rf ––– rf (x, p, q, C, tq ) = (p − tq x)q − C. The slope of the firm’s bid rent is r f / x = − tq q.

s of the bid rent
functions,
as a result, determine
Land
use and equilibrium
city size how the land is used. The diagram shows a

tion in which Land
the slope
of the
firms’
function isor
steeper
than
the slope of
the
can be
rented
to bid-rent
firms, households,
used for
agriculture.
Agricultural
land rent is given by rA .
ential bid-rent
function,landlords
i.e., 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑞𝑞𝑞𝑞 /𝑞𝑞𝑞𝑞rent
> 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡.the
Theland
twotocurves
intersect
at to
𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥 =
𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥�, which
defines
theThe relative slopes of the
Absentee
whoever
is willing
offer
the highest
bid.
bid-rent
functions, as The
a result,
land is is
used.
The
on page 9 shows a situation
er between firms
and households.
size determine
of the city how
in thethe
diagram
given
bydiagram
the distance
in
which
the
slope
of
the
firms’
bid-rent
function
is
steeper
than
the
slope
ofofthe residential bid-rent
the CBD to the city-rural boundary, denoted by 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ , and it is determined by the intersection
function, i.e., tq / q > t. The two curves intersect at x = x̃, which defines the border between firms and
esidential bid-rent function and the horizontal line 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 . As a result, all locations 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥 < 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥� are
households. The size of the city in the diagram is given by the distance from the CBD to the city-rural
pied by firms, all locations 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥� ≤ 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥 ≤ 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅- are occupied by households, and all locations 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥 > 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ are
boundary, denoted by x, and it is determined by the intersection of the residential bid-rent function
ted to the agricultural
use. Specifically,
sizeall
𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ is
determined
by occupied by firms, all locations x̃ ≤ x ≤ x- are
and the horizontal
line rA . the
As acity
result,
locations
x < x̃ are
occupied by households, and all locations x > x are devoted to the agricultural use. Specifically, the city
(1)
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ , 𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤, 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡, 𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢) = 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 .
size x- is determined𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 by
r (x , w, t, u) = rA
(1)
in equilibrium, the city’s population,
𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁, should fit in the city, or
Also, in equilibrium, the city’s population, N, should fit in the city, or
𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅

𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥==N.𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁.
∫0 xdx

(2)

(2)

Consider
a situation
in which
there is costless
migration
across
citiesto(usually
der a situation
in which
there is costless
migration
across cities
(usually
referred
as an referred to as an “open
city
model”),
so
the
city’s
population
adjusts
until
utility
is
equalized
at utility level u.
n city model”), so the city’s population adjusts until utility is equalized everywhere at everywhere
utility
- , it follows that x- = (w − u − r )/ t, and from (2), N = x- 2 / 2.
Substituting
r
(x,
w,
t,
u)
into
(1)
and
solving
for
x
A
𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢. Substituting 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥, 𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤, 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡, 𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢) into (1) and solving
for 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ , it -follows that 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ = (𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤 − 𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢 − 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 )/𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡, and
2 Note that since r (x, w, t, u) − r (x , w, t, u) = t (x − x ), then the equilibrium residential bid-rent function is
(2), 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 = 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ /2. Note that since 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥, -𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤, 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡, 𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢) − 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ , 𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤, 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡, 𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢) = 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ − 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥), then the equilibrium
r (x, w, t, u) = rA + t (x − x).
ential bid-rent function is

rences

𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥, 𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤, 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡, 𝑢𝑢𝑢𝑢) = 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 + 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡(𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥̅ − 𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥).

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

17

Endnotes

1
2
3
4
5

6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43

18

Cohen (2015).
Manyika et al. (2012).
Moretti (2013, 84) and Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson (1993).
More recently in the 2000s, following the nationwide trend, poverty has been rising in the suburbs
as well. However, poverty is still a phenomenon highly concentrated in inner cities.
The Census Bureau began tracking “standard metropolitan areas” with the 1950 census. These were
later renamed MSAs, and the boundaries have changed over the decades following the fluctuations of cities. Data are from the1950 Census and 2010 Census.
Audretsch and Feldman (1996) and Glaeser (1999).
Moretti (2004).
De la Roca and Puga (2016).
Black (1999) and Bayer, Ferreira, and McMillan (2007).
Rosenthal and Ross (2015).
Glaeser, Kahn, and Rappaport (2008).
Baum-Snow (2007) and Duranton and Turner (2012).
Baum-Snow (2007).
Baum-Snow and Lutz (2011). Other studies focus on different explanations for “white flight,” such as
rising crime rates in cities. See Cullen and Levitt (1999) and Boustan (2010).
Glaeser, Kolko, Saiz (2001) and Albouy (2012).
Brueckner and Rosenthal (2009).
Guerrieri, Hartley, and Hurst (2013).
O’Sullivan (2005).
Glaeser and Gyourko (2005).
Duranton (2007).
Owens, Rossi-Hansberg, and Sarte (2017).
Glaeser and Gottlieb (2008).
Kline and Moretti (2013).
Kline and Moretti (2014).
Davis and Weinstein (2002).
The Empowerment Zone designation generally expired in 2009, though it was subject to a series of
case-by-case extensions.
Ham, Swenson, Imrohoroğlu, and Song (2011).
Neumark and Kolko (2010) and Freedman (2013).
Busso, Gregory, and Kline (2013) and Ham, Swenson, Imrohoroğlu, and Song (2011).
Hanson and Rohlin (2013).
Glaeser and Gottlieb (2008).
Rossi-Hansberg, Sarte, and Owens (2010).
Hanson (2009).
Several studies show that EZ programs could have generated demographic changes in affected
neighborhoods. Neumark and Simpson (2015).
Glaeser (2005).
Kling, Liebman, and Katz (2007).
Clampet-Lundquist and Massey (2008).
Chetty, Hendren, and Katz (2016).
Chyn (2016).
Moretti (2004) and Moretti (2011).
Lochner and Moretti (2004).
Moretti (2013).
Rosenthal and Strange (2006).

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Albouy, David. May 2012. “Are Big Cities Bad Places to Live? Estimating Quality of Life across
Metropolitan Areas.” Working paper.

References

Audretsch, David B., and Maryann P. Feldman. June 1996. “R&D Spillovers and the Geography of
Innovation and Production.” American Economic Review 86 (3): 630–640.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel. May 2007. “Did Highways Cause Suburbanization?” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 122 (2): 775–805.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel, and Byron F. Lutz. December 2011. “School Desegregation, School Choice, and
Changes in Residential Location Patterns by Race.” American Economic Review 101 (7): 3019–3046.
Bayer, Patrick, Fernando Ferreira, and Robert McMillan. August 2007. “A Unified Framework for
Measuring Preferences for Schools and Neighborhoods.” Journal of Political Economy 115 (4):
588–638.
Black, Sandra E. May 1999. “Do Better Schools Matter? Parental Valuation of Elementary Education.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (2): 577–599.
Boustan, Leah Platt. February 2010. “Was Postwar Suburbanization ‘White Flight?’ Evidence from the
Black Migration.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (1): 417–443.
Brueckner, Jan K., and Stuart S. Rosenthal. November 2009. “Gentrification and Neighborhood Housing
Cycles: Will America’s Future Downtowns Be Rich?” Review of Economics and Statistics, 91 (4):
725–743.
Busso, Matias, Jesse Gregory, and Patrick Kline. April 2013. “Assessing the Incidence and Efficiency of a
Prominent Place Based Policy.” American Economic Review 103 (2): 897–947.
Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, and Lawrence F. Katz. April 2016. “The Effects of Exposure to Better
Neighborhoods on Children: New Evidence from the Moving to Opportunity Experiment.”
American Economic Review 106 (4): 855–902.
Chyn, Erik. October 2016. “Moved to Opportunity: The Long-Run Effect of Public Housing Demolition
on Labor Market Outcomes of Children.” Working paper.
Clampet-Lundquist, Susan, and Douglas S. Massey. July 2008. “Neighborhood Effects on Economic
Self-Sufficiency: A Reconsideration of the Moving to Opportunities Experiment.”
American Journal of Sociology 114 (1): 107–143.
Cohen, Darryl T. March 2015. “Population Trends in Incorporated Places: 2000 to 2013.”
United States Census Bureau Report P25–1142.
Cullen, Julie Berry, and Steven D. Levitt. May 1999. “Crime, Urban Flight, and the Consequences for
Cities.” Review of Economics and Statistics 81 (2): 159–169.
Davis, Donald R., and David E. Weinstein. December 2002. “Bones, Bombs, and Break Points:
The Geography of Economic Activity.” American Economic Review 92 (5): 1269–1289.
De la Roca, Jorge, and Diego Puga. July 2016. “Learning by Working in Big Cities.” Review of Economic
Studies 84 (1): 106–142.
Duranton, Gilles. March 2007. “Urban Evolutions: The Fast, the Slow, and the Still.”
American Economic Review 97 (1): 197–221.
Duranton, Gilles, and Matthew A. Turner. October 2012. “Urban Growth and Transportation.”
Review of Economic Studies 79 (4): 1407–1440.
Freedman, Matthew. Spring 2013. “Targeted Business Incentives and Local Labor Markets.”
Journal of Human Resources 48 (2): 311–344.
Glaeser, Edward L. September 1999. “Learning in Cities.” Journal of Urban Economics 46 (2): 254-277.
Glaeser, Edward L. September 2005. “Should the Government Rebuild New Orleans, Or Just Give
Residents Checks?” The Economists’ Voice 2 (4): 1–6.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joshua D. Gottlieb. October 2008. “The Economics of Place-Making Policies.”
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 14373.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joseph Gyourko. April 2005. “Urban Decline and Durable Housing.”
Journal of Political Economy 113 (2): 345–375.
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

19

References

Glaeser, Edward L., Matthew E. Kahn, and Jordan Rappaport. January 2008. “Why Do the Poor
Live in Cities? The Role of Public Transportation.” Journal of Urban Economics 63 (1): 1–24.
Glaeser, Edward L., Jed Kolko, and Albert Saiz. January 2001. “Consumer City.”
Journal of Economic Geography 1 (1): 27-50.
Guerrieri, Veronica, Daniel Hartley, and Erik Hurst. April 2013. “Endogenous Gentrification and
Housing Price Dynamics.” Journal of Public Economics 100: 45–60.
Ham, John C., Charles Swenson, Ayşe Imrohoroğlu, and Heonjae Song. August 2011.
“Government Programs Can Improve Local Labor Markets: Evidence from State Enterprise Zones,
Federal Empowerment Zones and Federal Enterprise Community.” Journal of Public Economics 95
(7-8): 779–797.
Hanson, Andrew. November 2009. “Local Employment, Poverty, and Property Value Effects
of Geographically-Targeted Tax Incentives: An Instrumental Variables Approach.”
Regional Science and Urban Economics 39 (6): 721–731.
Hanson, Andrew, and Shawn Rohlin. January 2013. “Do Spatially Targeted Redevelopment Programs
Spillover?” Regional Science and Urban Economics 43 (1): 86–100.
Jaffe, Adam B., Manuel Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson. August 1993. “Geographic Localization
of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3):
577–598.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. November 2013. “Local Economic Development, Agglomeration
Economies, and the Big Push: 100 Years of Evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (1): 275–331.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. August 2014. “People, Places, and Public Policy: Some Simple Welfare
Economics of Local Economic Development Programs.” Annual Review of Economics 6: 629–662.
Kling, Jeffrey R., Jeffrey B. Liebman, and Lawrence F. Katz. January 2007. “Experimental Analysis of
Neighborhood Effects.” Econometrica 75 (1): 83–119.
Lochner, Lance, and Enrico Moretti. March 2004. “The Effect of Education on Crime: Evidence from
Prison Inmates, Arrests, and Self-Reports.” American Economic Review 94 (1): 155–189.
Manyika, James, Jaana Remes, Richard Dobbs, Javier Orellana, and Fabian Schaer. April 2012.
“Urban America: U.S. Cities in the Global Economy.” McKinsey Global Institute.
Moretti, Enrico. 2004. “Human Capital Externalities in Cities.” Handbook of Regional and Urban
Economics 4: 2243–2291.
Moretti, Enrico. 2011. “Local Labor Markets.” Handbook of Labor Economics 4b: 1237–1313.
Moretti, Enrico. 2013. The New Geography of Jobs. New York: Mariner Books.
Neumark, David, and Jed Kolko. July 2010. “Do Enterprise Zones Create Jobs? Evidence from
California’s Enterprise Zone Program.” Journal of Urban Economics 68 (1): 1–19.
Neumark, David, and Helen Simpson. 2015. “Place-Based Policies.” Handbook of Regional and
Urban Economics 5: 1197–1287.
O’Sullivan, Arthur. January 2005. “Gentrification and Crime.” Journal of Urban Economics 57 (1): 73–85.
Owens, Raymond III, Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, and Pierre-Daniel Sarte. February 2017.
“Rethinking Detroit.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 23146.
Rosenthal, Stuart S., and Stephen L. Ross. 2015. “Change and Persistence in the Economic Status of
Neighborhoods and Cities.” Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics 5: 1047–1120.
Rosenthal, Stuart S., and William C. Strange. 2006. “The Micro-Empirics of Agglomeration Economies.”
In A Companion to Urban Economics, edited by Richard J. Arnott and Daniel P. McMillen, 7–23.
Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell Publishing.
Rossi-Hansberg, Esteban, Pierre-Daniel Sarte, and Raymond Owens III. June 2010. “Housing
Externalities.” Journal of Political Economy 118 (3): 485–535.

20

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Fifth District Economic Report
Fifth District Economy Grew Moderately in 2016

A

necdotal reports and economic data on the Fifth District in 2016 revealed a regional
economy that continued to grow throughout the year. Employment rose at a moderate pace with more robust growth coming out of North and South Carolina. Wage
growth picked up overall, including, according to survey responses, for starting wages across
a number of firms. Services firms generally reported expanding activity throughout the year,
while manufacturers began the year with less universally positive reports and ended the year
on somewhat more optimistic notes. Real estate markets continued to improve in 2016, but
real estate professionals expressed concerns about regulatory delays and shortages of buildable lots and skilled workers.

Labor Markets
Labor market conditions continued to tighten over the course of 2016. Payroll employment expanded 1.4 percent in the Fifth District as employers added 201,800 jobs. Among
the District’s jurisdictions, North Carolina posted the largest year-over-year growth rate in
December of 2.2 percent, followed by South Carolina’s 1.8 percent. The Carolinas were the
only Fifth District states to outpace the national rate of 1.6 percent. Employment grew in the
other Fifth District jurisdictions except for West Virginia, which reported a 0.8 percent decline
as the state continued to shed a large number of jobs from the mining and logging sector.
In the District overall, the most jobs were added over the year to education and health
services (50,200 jobs) followed by trade, transportation, and utilities (35,200 jobs) and professional and business services (35,000 jobs). The only industry to lose jobs in 2016 was information, which shed 3,100 jobs (1.3 percent); information is the smallest industry in the District,
and employment in the sector has generally been declining or flat since 2000.
Although construction employment grew in 2016 and has been growing at a healthy
pace since the beginning of 2014, total employment in the industry has not returned
to its prerecession level. (See Figure 1.) In fact, in December 2016 the industry’s total
employment stood at 82.9 percent of the level reported in December 2007. Similarly,
employment in the manufacturing and information industries has yet to return to prerecession levels. Employment in mining and logging had returned to its prerecession levels,
but the industry began to shed jobs again in 2012 and is now below its December 2007
level. Employment in mining has fluctuated, primarily in response to changes in coal and
natural gas markets.
Despite the fact that a few industries still have not returned to their prerecession
employment levels, employment in the District as a whole exceeded its December 2007 level
in April 2014 and has remained above that level. Moreover, the professional and business
services and leisure and hospitality industries surpassed their prerecession marks in 2011.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

21

Figure 1: Fifth District Employment Growth by Industry
INDEX, DECEMBER 2007=100

120

Educational and
Health Services

110

Leisure and Hospitality
Professional and
Business Services

100

TOTAL

90

Manufacturing

80

Information
Construction

70

Mining and Logging

60

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

YEARS
SOURCE: Current Employment Statistics, Bureau of Labor Statistics
NOTES: Gray area indicates the recession. Industries that closely followed the overall growth trend (the total
line) have been omitted from this graph. They are: trade, transportation, and utilities; financial activities; and
other services. Government employment growth also is not shown because it was essentially flat.

The education and health services industry and the government sector were the only two
categories that did not decline either during or since the recession.
In 2016, the unemployment rate in the Fifth District declined from 5.0 percent in December
2015 to 4.6 percent in December 2016—the lowest rate since early 2008. All of that 2016
improvement came in the first half of the year; the rate has remained at 4.6 percent since June.
At the jurisdiction level, unemployment rates declined in every state except Virginia, where
the 4.1 percent rate in December 2016 matched the rate reported in December of the previous
year. The greatest improvement came from South Carolina, where the jobless rate declined
1.2 percentage points to end the year at 4.3 percent.
Anecdotes throughout the Fifth District indicated that as the labor market tightened in
2016, employers increasingly struggled to find skilled workers. In particular, there were consistent reports of challenges in finding tradespeople, construction workers, hospitality workers, and IT professionals. Anecdotal information also suggested that the tight labor market
might be driving up starting wages. According to a survey of employers conducted by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond in May 2016, more than 60 percent of respondents said
they were raising starting wages. The same result was obtained when the survey was repeated in November 2016. Furthermore, the number of respondents who reported raising wages
for “most” jobs (as opposed to “some” jobs) was higher in November than in May.
Data on wage growth from the Bureau of Labor Statistics supported the anecdotal information. Using the most recent data from the bureau’s Quarterly Census of Employment and
Wages, Figure 2 shows that Fifth District wage growth over the trailing four quarters through
September 2016 slightly outpaced the same four quarters of the prior year. Additionally,

22

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Figure 2: Year-over-Year Wage Growth in the Fifth District
Total
Construction
Manufacturing
Trade, Transportation, and Utilities
Information
Financial Activities
Professional and Business Services
Education and Health Services
Leisure and Hospitality
Other Services
Government

0
■ 2016

■ 2015

1

2

3

4

5

PERCENT INCREASE

SOURCE: Richmond Fed calculations using Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, Bureau of Labor Statistics
NOTES: Calculations are based on nominal average wages from the trailing four quarters through September of 2014,
2015, and 2016. Calculations for manufacturing and construction do not include data from the District of Columbia.
For the trailing four months ending September 30, 2016, the District of Columbia accounted for 2.1 percent of
construction employment and 0.1 percent of manufacturing employment in the Fifth District.

the largest wage growth came from the construction industry (4.9 percent), which was also
the industry with the most persistent reports of difficulties in finding workers. Wage growth
accelerated in most other industries as well, with the most notable deceleration coming in
the financial services industry.

Business Conditions
Manufacturing activity was mixed in 2016, but it ended on a generally optimistic note. The
Richmond Fed maintains a composite manufacturing index based on the Bank’s Fifth District
Survey of Manufacturing Activity. It is a diffusion index, meaning that a positive reading
indicates that the share of firms reporting expansion exceeds the share of firms reporting
contraction. As was the case last year, the index fluctuated between positive and negative
readings throughout the year; however, 2016 ended with two consecutive months of positive
index values and included more comments expressing optimism.
Throughout the year, anecdotal reports indicated that some segments of manufacturing
were more consistently positive. For example, manufacturers of automobiles, auto parts, and
aerospace products reported growth, fairly robust at times, for most of the year. Conversely,
some manufacturers continued to be adversely affected by sluggish global demand and
declining commodity prices.
According to the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Service Sector Survey, conditions were
generally upbeat for services firms throughout the year. The revenues index for nonretail service firms was positive in every month except February. For 2016, the average index reading was six, a survey measure that indicated a slow and steady expansion for services firms.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

23

Anecdotally, tourism and hospitality services generally experienced robust growth as contacts reported rising demand at hotels and restaurants.
Retail firms experienced a somewhat more varied business climate in 2016. According
to the Richmond Fed survey, the revenues index for retail services remained above zero for
the majority of the year but experienced a few months of negative values, including a sharp
decline in August. Throughout the year, brick-and-mortar retailers commented on the challenges of competing with online retailers and reported unreliable foot traffic.
The surveys’ measures of employment and wages were generally consistent with labor
market data from other sources. Throughout the year, most manufacturers reported more
employees, with a notable exception in September, when the index fell steeply into negative territory. The index for manufacturing wages has been positive since early 2010, but the
average index value has trended higher in recent years. In 2016, the average index value was
sixteen compared with thirteen in 2015—both up from nine in 2010.
Similarly, in the service sector, the index for number of employees remained above zero
for all of 2016, and the average index value rose slightly compared to the prior year. As was
the case with the revenues index, the nonretail services subsector followed the overall trend
while the retail subsector was more volatile, with four months of negative employment
index values. Average wages, on the other hand, mirrored the manufacturing industry, with
persistently positive index readings in 2016 that were just slightly higher than in 2015 and
considerably higher than 2010 through 2014. Furthermore, this trend was consistent among
both retail and nonretail services.

Real Estate
Fifth District housing markets continued to improve in 2016, but they lagged national averages in some metrics. According to CoreLogic Information Solutions, District house prices grew
4.1 percent on a year-over-year basis, a rate that lagged the national average of 6.3 percent.
The sharpest increase in the District was in South Carolina, where home prices rose 5.9 percent, while West Virginia reported the lowest house-price growth of 2.6 percent. Real estate
agents throughout the District also reported rising prices and home sales throughout the year,
but results varied by region and price level. In some cases, low inventory levels simultaneously
reined in sales growth and spurred on new construction.
On balance, residential construction continued to accelerate in 2016 but was somewhat
constrained by the availability of lots and a tight market for construction workers. Again,
reports varied by location, with some reports of lot shortages driving up lot prices and, in
at least one case, contributing to an increase in multifamily leasing and rents. Jurisdictions
across the Fifth District issued a combined 138,900 residential building permits in 2016, which
was a 1.3 percent increase over the previous year. About 27 percent of those permits were for
multifamily units, down slightly from the 31 percent share of total units in 2015. Growth in
single-family housing starts was more robust at 4.0 percent.
Commercial real estate (CRE) activity generally expanded throughout 2016. Groceryanchored retail centers, hotels, health care facilities, and schools were, anecdotally, some
of the faster-growing segments. Demand for construction in the retail segment also picked
up; however, the square footage of a typical project was smaller than in the past. Office and

24

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

industrial leasing also rose on the whole, but there were some reports of supply constraints,
particularly among the highest quality, Class-A properties.

Banking Conditions
Amid industry consolidation and earnings pressures from the continued low interest rate
environment in 2016, Fifth District banks experienced steady loan growth, particularly in the
CRE sector, and overall improvement in credit-quality indicators.
Although 94 percent of Fifth District banks were profitable in 2016, earnings remained
under pressure, contributing to the industry’s consolidation, mostly among smaller banks.
The District’s overall bank population declined by 8 percent, double the national consolidation rate. This trend helped some District banks improve earnings by achieving economies of
scale. The District’s median return on average assets (ROAA) of 0.73 percent improved slightly
from a year ago with about half of District banks reporting an increasing ROAA. However,
the District’s median ROAA continued to lag the nation’s by 0.20 percentage points due, in
part, to higher than average overhead and personnel expense. Earnings improvements were
mostly attributable to higher noninterest income and declining overhead costs related to
greater efficiency gains at mid- and large-sized banks. While interest rates have risen, rate
increases have yet to augment Fifth District margins, which remained compressed due to
competition and the low-rate environment.
Balance sheets expanded, with median loan growth of 7.3 percent outpacing the national
median of 5.8 percent. The fastest-growing segments were in CRE categories, namely nonowner-occupied CRE, and construction, land, and development. CRE loan growth led to higher
CRE loan concentrations, a continuing trend in the District, and weighed on capital ratios.
Credit quality indicators improved, on average, with the Fifth District’s level of nonperforming loans declining, but nonperforming loans remained above prerecession levels and
0.25 percentage points higher than the national average. While overall loan delinquencies
improved, some District banks’ provision expenses ticked up from the previous year.

Conclusion
Overall, 2016 was a year of continued economic expansion in the Fifth District. Employment
expanded and wage growth accelerated slightly. However, the tightening labor market may
have made it more difficult for businesses to find appropriately skilled employees. In some
industries, such as construction, these difficulties could have constrained growth. Residential
and commercial construction activity did pick up, though, as house prices rose and new
home inventories continued to dwindle. Meanwhile, both manufacturers and services firms
across the District reported positive developments in 2016 and were optimistic about the
near future.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

25

Boards, Councils, Officers, and Senior Professionals
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND BOARD OF DIRECTORS
The Bank’s Board of Directors oversees management of the Bank and its Fifth District offices, provides
timely business and economic information, participates in the formulation of national monetary and credit policies, and serves as a link between the Federal Reserve System and the private sector. Six directors
are elected by banks in the Fifth District that are members of the Federal Reserve System, and three are
appointed by the Board of Governors. Directors who are not bankers appoint the Bank’s president and first
vice president with approval from the Board of Governors.
The Bank’s Board of Directors annually appoints the Fifth District’s representative to the Federal
Advisory Council, which consists of one member from each of the twelve Federal Reserve Districts. The
council meets four times a year with the Board of Governors to consult on business conditions and issues
related to the banking industry.

BALTIMORE AND CHARLOTTE BRANCHES BOARDS OF DIRECTORS
The Bank’s Baltimore and Charlotte branches have separate boards that oversee operations at their respective locations and, like the Richmond Board, contribute to policymaking and provide timely business and
economic information about the District. Four directors on each of these boards are appointed by the
Richmond directors, and three are appointed by the Board of Governors.

COMMUNITY DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS ADVISORY COUNCIL
Created in 2011, the Bank’s Community Depository Institutions Advisory Council advises the Bank’s management and the Board of Governors on the economy, lending conditions, and other issues from the perspective of banks, thrifts, and credit unions with total assets under $10 billion. The council’s members are
appointed by the Bank’s president.

COMMUNITY INVESTMENT COUNCIL
Established in 2011, the Community Investment Council advises the Bank’s management about emerging
issues and trends in communities across the Fifth District, including low- and moderate-income neighborhoods in urban and rural areas. The council’s members are appointed by the Bank’s president.

PAYMENTS ADVISORY COUNCIL
Created in 1978, the Payments Advisory Council serves as a forum for communication with financial
institutions about financial services provided by the Federal Reserve. The council helps the Bank respond
to the evolving needs of its banking constituency. Council members are appointed by the Bank’s first
vice president.

THANK YOU
Thank you to those directors who completed their service in 2016: Russell C. Lindner, Charles R. Patton, and
C. Richard Miller Jr. of the Richmond Board; Samuel L. Ross of the Baltimore Board; and Deborah AguiarVélez, Elizabeth A. Fleming, and Paul E. Szurek of the Charlotte Board. Also, Kelly S. King completed his
service as the Fifth District’s representative to the Federal Advisory Council.
In 2017, the Bank welcomed seven new directors: Calvin G. Butler Jr., Ángel Cabrera, and William A.
Loving Jr. joined the Richmond Board; Wayne A.I. Frederick joined the Baltimore Board; and Michael D.
Garcia, Michelle A. Mapp, and R. Glenn Sherrill Jr. joined the Charlotte Board.
Listings of boards and councils on the following pages include members and titles as of December 31, 2016, unless otherwise noted.

26

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Board of Directors—Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

From the left: Kathy J. Warden, C. Richard Miller Jr., Catherine A. Meloy, Charles R. Patton,
Margaret G. Lewis, Russell C. Lindner, Susan K. Still, Thomas C. Nelson, Robert R. Hill Jr.
CHAIR

Russell C. Lindner

Executive Chairman and
Chief Executive Officer
The Forge Company
Washington, D.C.
DEPUTY CHAIR

Margaret G. Lewis

Retired President
HCA Capital Division
Richmond, Virginia

Robert R. Hill Jr.

Chief Executive Officer
South State Corporation and
South State Bank
Columbia, South Carolina

Catherine A. Meloy

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Goodwill of Greater Washington
and Goodwill Excel Center
Washington, D.C.

C. Richard Miller Jr.

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Woodsboro Bank
Woodsboro, Maryland

Thomas C. Nelson

Chairman, President, and
Chief Executive Officer
National Gypsum Company
Charlotte, North Carolina

Charles R. Patton

President and
Chief Operating Officer
Appalachian Power Company
Charleston, West Virginia

Kathy J. Warden

Corporate Vice President
and President,
Mission Systems
Northrop Grumman
Corporation
Linthicum, Maryland
FEDERAL ADVISORY COUNCIL
REPRESENTATIVE

Kelly S. King

Chairman and
Chief Executive Officer
BB&T Corporation
Winston-Salem, North Carolina

Susan K. Still

President and
Chief Executive Officer
HomeTown Bankshares
Corporation and
HomeTown Bank
Roanoke, Virginia

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

27

Board of Directors—Baltimore Branch

From the left: Mary Ann Scully, Kenneth R. Banks, Laura L. Gamble, Christopher J. Estes,
Susan J. Ganz, Austin J. Slater Jr., Samuel L. Ross
CHAIR

Samuel L. Ross

Chief Executive Officer
Bon Secours Baltimore
Health System
Baltimore, Maryland

Kenneth R. Banks

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Banks Contracting Company
Greenbelt, Maryland

Christopher J. Estes

President and
Chief Executive Officer
National Housing Conference
Washington, D.C.

Laura L. Gamble

Regional President
Greater Maryland
PNC
Baltimore, Maryland

28

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Susan J. Ganz

Chief Executive Officer
Lion Brothers Company, Inc.
Owings Mills, Maryland

Mary Ann Scully

Chairman, President, and
Chief Executive Officer
Howard Bancorp
Ellicott City, Maryland

Austin J. Slater Jr.

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Southern Maryland Electric
Cooperative, Inc.
Hughesville, Maryland

Board of Directors—Charlotte Branch

From the left: Claude Z. Demby, Elizabeth A. Fleming, Michael C. Crapps, Laura Y. Clark,
Paul E. Szurek, Jerry L. Ocheltree
CHAIR

Laura Y. Clark

Elizabeth A. Fleming

Michael C. Crapps

Jerry L. Ocheltree

Claude Z. Demby

Paul E. Szurek

Chief Impact Officer
United Way of Central Carolinas
Charlotte, North Carolina
President and
Chief Executive Officer
First Community Bank
Lexington, South Carolina
Vice President and
General Manager
Cree, Inc.
Durham, North Carolina

Former President
Converse College
Spartanburg, South Carolina

In Memoriam:

Deborah Aguiar-Vélez
Sistemas Corporation
Charlotte, North Carolina

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Carolina Trust Bank
Lincolnton, North Carolina
Former Chief Financial Officer
Biltmore Farms, LLC
Asheville, North Carolina
Resigned on September 1, 2016

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

29

Community Depository Institutions Advisory Council
CHAIR

Robert A. DeAlmeida*

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Hamilton Bank and Hamilton
Bancorp, Inc.
Towson, Maryland

Suzanne S. DeFerie

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Asheville Savings Bank and
ASB Bancorp, Inc.
Asheville, North Carolina

Michael P. Fitzgerald
Vice Chairman
United Bank, Inc.
Washington, D.C.

William A. Loving Jr.

Ronald D. Paul

Judy Tharp

Gary R. Mills

Jan Roche

Michael O. Walker

R. Arthur Seaver

*In 2016, Robert A. DeAlmeida
served as the Fifth District’s representative on the Community Depository
Institutions Advisory Council at the
Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Pendleton Community
Bank, Inc.
Franklin, West Virginia
President and
Chief Executive Officer
First Community Bank
Bluefield, Virginia

David L. Morrow

President and
Chief Executive Officer
CresCom Bank
Charleston, South Carolina

Chairman and
Chief Executive Officer
EagleBank and
Eagle Bancorp, Inc.
Bethesda, Maryland
President and
Chief Executive Officer
State Department Federal
Credit Union
Alexandria, Virginia
Chief Executive Officer
Southern First Bank
Greenville, South Carolina

Community Investment Council
CHAIR

Mary M. Hunt

Senior Program Officer
The Claude Worthington
Benedum Foundation
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania

MaryAnn Black

Associate Vice President,
Office of Community and
Local Government Relations
Duke University Health System
Durham, North Carolina

Tamea L. Franco

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Global Metal Finishing, Inc.
Roanoke, Virginia

Earl F. Gohl

Federal Co-Chair
Appalachian Regional
Commission
Washington, D.C.

30

Deborah L. Hooper

Deborah McKetty

Jody Keenan

Paul Phillips

Chief Operating Officer
Greensboro Partnership
Greensboro, North Carolina
State Director
Virginia Small Business
Development Center
Fairfax, Virginia

John Maneval

Deputy Director, Multifamily
Housing and Business Lending
Maryland Department of
Housing and Community
Development
Lanham, Maryland

Charles Martin

Administrative Vice President,
Regional Community
Reinvestment Officer
M&T Bank
Baltimore, Maryland

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Executive Director
CommunityWorks Carolina
Greenville, South Carolina
President and
Chief Executive Officer
Freedom First Federal
Credit Union
Roanoke, Virginia

Kent R. Spellman

Executive Director
The West Virginia Community
Development Hub
Stonewood, West Virginia

President and
Chief Executive Officer
Piedmont Advantage
Credit Union
Winston-Salem, North Carolina
President and
Chief Executive Officer
Benchmark Community Bank
and Benchmark Bankshares, Inc.
Kenbridge, Virginia

Payments Advisory Council
CHAIR

E. Stephen Lilly

Executive Vice President and
Chief Operating Officer
First Community
Bancshares, Inc.
Bluefield, Virginia

William E. Albert

Senior Vice President
First Century Bank
Bluefield, West Virginia

Tim Boike

Robert E. Dael

President and
Chief Executive Officer
MACHA—The Mid-Atlantic
Payments Association
Hanover, Maryland

Peter Davey

Vice President and Director,
Enterprise Payments
Capital One Bank
Richmond, Virginia

Jeff W. Dick

Senior Vice President
Wells Fargo and Company
Minneapolis, Minnesota

Chairman and
Chief Executive Officer
MainStreet Bank
Fairfax, Virginia

Ronald L. Bowling

Kristi A. Eller

President and
Chief Executive Officer
First Peoples Bank
Mullens, West Virginia

Karen Buck

Head, Commercial, Retail and
Payment Operations
TD Bank
Mount Laurel, New Jersey

Kim L. Bunn

Senior Vice President and
Operations Executive
Bank of America
Jacksonville, Florida

Richard Chin

Senior Vice President
and Treasurer
Pentagon Federal Credit Union
Alexandria, Virginia

John Kevin Cranford

Senior Vice President
BB&T Corporation
Charlotte, North Carolina

Chief Information Officer
and Executive Vice President,
Operations
Yadkin Bank
Statesville, North Carolina

Margo D. Foust

Senior Vice President, Operations
and Process Improvement
American National Bank and
Trust Company
Danville, Virginia

Terry Garner

Senior Vice President,
Deposit Operations
Southern First Bank
Greenville, South Carolina

Jamin M. Hujik

Executive Vice President
CresCom Bank
Charleston, South Carolina

Adrian S. Johnson

Steve Shuford

Alison Lyewski

Woody Shuler

Senior Vice President and
Chief Financial Officer
MECU of Baltimore, Inc.
Baltimore, Maryland
Senior Vice President, EIS
Transaction Operations
SunTrust Bank
Orlando, Florida

Carla A. Nealy

Executive Vice President and
Chief Operating Officer
The Harbor Bank of Maryland
Baltimore, Maryland

Tracy J. Nelms

Executive Vice President
TowneBank
Suffolk, Virginia

Holly Pingatore

Senior Vice President and
Director of Deposit Operations
South State Bank
Charleston, South Carolina

Rick Rhoads

Senior Vice President, E-Services
State Employees’ Credit Union
Raleigh, North Carolina

Susan G. Riel

Senior Executive Vice President
and Chief Operating Officer
EagleBank
Bethesda, Maryland

Senior Vice President and
Director, Treasury Management
Paragon Bank
Raleigh, North Carolina
Vice President, Finance
SRP Federal Credit Union
North Augusta, South Carolina

Steve Stone

Executive Vice President
United Bank
Charleston, West Virginia

Chris Tolomeo

Senior Vice President,
Banking Services
M&T Bank
Amherst, New York

Paul Trozzo

Senior Vice President
PNC Bank
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania

David Willis

Senior Vice President,
Debit Card and Funds Services
Navy Federal Credit Union
Vienna, Virginia

Gayle Youngblood

Assistant Vice President,
Product Management
State Employees
Credit Union of Maryland
Linthicum, Maryland

D.J. Seeterlin

Chief Information Officer
Chesapeake Bank
Kilmarnock, Virginia

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

31

Management Committee

From the left: Roland Costa, David E. Beck, Michelle H. Gluck, Becky C. Bareford, Mark L. Mullinix,
Kartik B. Athreya, Jeffrey M. Lacker, Jennifer J. Burns, Janice E. Clatterbuck, Matthew A. Martin,
Michael D. Stough

Jeffrey M. Lacker
President

Mark L. Mullinix

First Vice President and
Chief Operating Officer

Kartik B. Athreya

Executive Vice President and
Director of Research

Becky C. Bareford

Senior Vice President,
Human Resources and Finance

David E. Beck

Senior Vice President and
Baltimore Regional Executive

Jennifer J. Burns

Executive Vice President,
Supervision, Regulation,
and Credit

Janice E. Clatterbuck

Senior Vice President and
Chief Information Officer

Roland Costa

Senior Vice President and
Chief Technology Officer

Michelle H. Gluck

Executive Vice President,
General Counsel, and
Chief Risk Officer

Matthew A. Martin

Senior Vice President and
Charlotte Regional Executive

Michael D. Stough

Senior Vice President and
General Auditor

Listings include officers, senior professionals, and titles as of December 31, 2016.

32

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Officers
John A. Weinberg

Senior Vice President and
Special Advisor to the President

Huberto M. Ennis

Group Vice President

Thomas A. Lubik

Group Vice President

Lisa T. Oliva

Group Vice President

Michael L. Wilder

Group Vice President and
Chief Financial Officer

Hattie R.C. Barley
Vice President

Christy R. Cleare
Vice President

Todd E. Dixon

Vice President

Kevin W. Fergusson
Vice President and
Medical Director

Joan T. Garton
Vice President

Richard B. Gilbert
Vice President

Rebecca Goldberg
Vice President

Anne C. Gossweiler
Vice President

Bruce E. Grinnell
Vice President

Mattison W. Harris
Vice President

Kathleen R. Houghtaling
Vice President and
Chief Diversity Officer

Cathy I. Howdyshell
Vice President

Gregory A. Johnson

Vice President and Assistant
General Auditor

Senior Professionals
H. Julie Yoo

Vice President

Niranjan Chandramowli

Borys M. Grochulski

Patricia A. Perry

Cary B. Crabtree

Assistant Vice President

Robert L. Hetzel

Bary M. Dalton

Assistant Vice President

Jeffrey B. Deibel

Assistant Vice President

Jacqueline R. Draper

Assistant Vice President

Senior Economist and
Research Advisor

Markus A. Summers

Assistant Vice President

Christian Matthes

Adam M. Drimer

Alexander T. Swartz

Assistant Vice President

Urvi Neelakantan

Gina E. Friese

Sandra L. Tormoen

Raymond E. Owens III

Kimberley D. Fuller

Assistant Vice President

Keith R.G. Goodwin

Assistant Vice President

Jennifer J. Hall

Assistant Vice President

Pierre-Daniel G. Sarte

Ann S. Harrison

BALTIMORE BRANCH

Nicholas Trachter

Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President

Assistant General Counsel
Assistant General Counsel
Assistant Vice President

Senior Economist

Senior Policy Economist

James Trotta

Senior Economist and
Policy Advisor

Lauren E. Ware

Senior Policy Economist

Santiago M. Pinto
Senior Advisor

Chad K. Harper

Senior Economist

Steven T. Bareford

Senior Economist and
Policy Advisor

Kerri A. Coard

Zhu Wang

John R. Walter

Senior Economist

CHARLOTTE BRANCH

Lisa A. White

Senior Economist and
Policy Advisor

Terry J. Wright

SUPERVISION, REGULATION,
AND CREDIT

Assistant Vice President

D. Keith Larkin

Assistant Vice President

Chuck Lewis

Assistant Vice President

Steve V. Malone

Assistant Vice President

Randal C. Manspile

Assistant Vice President

Jonathan P. Martin

Assistant Vice President

Diane H. McDorman
James T. Nowlin

Dennis H. Ott Jr.

Brielle M. Stanley

Christopher J. Palumbo

Vice President

John Bailey Jones

Diane R. Knapp

Johnnie E. Moore

Alexander L. Wolman

Michael J. Seifert

Assistant Vice President

Assistant Vice President

Andrew S. McAllister

Vice President

Senior Advisor

Pinkaj R. Klokkenga

Cheryl R. Moore

Vice President

Andreas L. Hornstein

Assistant Vice President

Assistant Vice President

Bennie R. Moore

Vice President

Jason C. Schemmel

Senior Economist and
Research Advisor

James R. Hart

Ann B. Macheras
Vice President

Melanie M. Rose

Senior Economist

Vice President

Malissa M. Ladd
Vice President

RESEARCH

Assistant Vice President and
Corporate Secretary

Laura H. Mayer

Vice President

Christin L. Patel

Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President

Senior Vice President
Group Vice President and
Charlotte Deputy Regional
Executive

Roy H. Webb

Azamat Abdymomunov

Lead Financial Economist

Jeremy B. Caldwell

Eliana Balla

Kerri R. O’Rourke-Robinson

Craig S. Edwards

Richard F. Westerkamp Jr.

Craig W. Frascati

Ronald G. Barnes

D. Keith Maglinger

Joshua R. Daulton

Hemangini R. Parekh

Jeffrey R. Gerlach

Stanley F. Poszywak

Kelly J. Stewart

Todd M. Ryan

Lead Financial Economist

Vice President
Vice President
Vice President

Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President

In Memoriam:

Large Bank Principal Examiner
Large Bank Principal Examiner
Large Bank Principal Examiner
Large Bank Principal Examiner
Large Bank Principal Examiner
Large Bank Principal Examiner

Steven D. Sanderford

Large Bank Principal Examiner

P.A.L. “Trish” Nunley
Deputy General Counsel

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

33

Federal Reserve Information Technology (FRIT) Management Council

From the left: Matthew D. Larson, Kathryn K. Smith, Scott C. Furman, Robert I. Turner, Lyn McDermid,
David N. Alfano, Devon A. Bryan, James A. Lammers

Lyn McDermid

System Chief Information Officer

Devon A. Bryan

Executive Vice President and
Chief Information Security Officer

James A. Lammers

Senior Vice President and
Chief Administrative Officer

Scott C. Furman

Senior Vice President,
Treasury Services

Executive Vice President and
Chief Technology and
Strategy Officer

Matthew D. Larson

Robert I. Turner

Kathryn K. Smith

Executive Vice President and
Chief Operating Officer

34

David N. Alfano

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

Senior Vice President,
End User Services
Senior Vice President,
Project and Program Delivery

Federal Reserve Information Technology (FRIT) Officers

Senior Professionals

Jeffrey F. Crow

Jon C. Jeswald

James A. Caulfield

Elise P. Ott

Donovan O. Harper II

Frederick B. Johnson

William C. Conway II

Andy Hendrickson

Carie L. Kelleher

John F. Crabtree

Gerald L. Moreno

Vicki L. Kosydor

Michael S. Everett

Christopher A. Tignor

S. Craig Minyard

William H. Fenerty

Kevin J. Craig

Mahnaz Moosa

Lisa Marie Gravely

Gary M. Patton

A. Vinton Myers III

Gary A. Helfrich

Paul R. Sans

Peter J. Purcell

M. Polly Helm

Scott D. Auble

R. Nathan Ragan

Peter B. Holleran

Nicole E. Bennett

Victoria F. Riendeau

M. Brannon Howle

Reginal L. Bryant

Joyce M. Romito

Bradley M. Joiner

Jane Y. Burk

Apurva A. Shah

John T. Lines

Gerry P. Collins

Hunter R. Shomo

Garland H. McKenzie

Michael E. Cortese

Stephen B. Silverman

Ellen D. Mitchell

Albert M. D’Avanzo

Joshua N. Snell

Arthur J. Papa Jr.

Fay T. Donahue

Sherri L. Thorne

Heidi R. Patterson

Frank J. Doto

Jeannie L. Willette

Irina V. Piven

Valerie A. Freund

Abigail T. Baker

Kevin A. Reed

Mark A. Hamilton

Michael L. Bellanti

Stephanie T. Shetterly

Kristofer K. Hogan

Jeffrey S. Borneman

Christopher T. Szymonik

Christine M. Holzem

Cynthia S. Bullington

Thomas J. Weber

Tamera S. Hornsby-Fink

Melissa E. Butler

Senior Vice President
Senior Vice President
Senior Vice President
Senior Vice President
Senior Vice President
Group Vice President
Group Vice President
Group Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President

Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President
Vice President

Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President

Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President

Chief Application
Integration Engineer

Michael T. Shaughnessy
Chief Application
Integration Engineer

L. Sergio Altomare

Business Architect (Treasury)

Ian W. Beirnes

Business Architect (Treasury)

Pedro E. Fong

Business Architect

Devin D. Gordon

Business Architect

M. Scott Hannah

Business Architect

Robert B. Klank

Business Architect

Darren L. Knutson
Business Architect

Donald H. Larmee
Business Architect

Susan L. Perlmutter

Information Architect

Eric B. Stanley

Information Architect
Listings include officers, senior
professionals, and titles as of
December 31, 2016.

Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President
Assistant Vice President

Assistant Vice President

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

35

Financial Statements

T

he audited annual financial statements of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond as of
and for the years ended December 31, 2016, and December 31, 2015, are incorporated
here by reference. They are available at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System at www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed/files/richmondfinstmt2016.pdf. That public
disclosure also provides: Notes to Financial Statements, Management’s Report on Internal
Control over Financial Reporting, and the Independent Auditors’ Report.
The Board of Governors’ Statement of Auditor Independence is provided below.

Statement of Auditor Independence
The Federal Reserve Board engaged KPMG to audit the 2016 combined and individual financial statements of the Reserve Banks.1
In 2016, KPMG also conducted audits of internal controls over financial reporting for each
of the Reserve Banks. Fees for KPMG services totaled $6.7 million. To ensure auditor independence, the Board requires that KPMG be independent in all matters relating to the audits.
Specifically, KPMG may not perform services for the Reserve Banks or others that would place
it in a position of auditing its own work, making management decisions on behalf of the
Reserve Banks, or in any other way impairing its audit independence. In 2016, the Bank did
not engage KPMG for any non-audit services.
____________________________________

1

36

In addition, KPMG audited the Office of Employee Benefits of the Federal Reserve System (OEB), the Retirement Plan for Employees
of the Federal Reserve System (System Plan), and the Thrift Plan for Employees of the Federal Reserve System (Thrift Plan). The
System Plan and the Thrift Plan provide retirement benefits to employees of the Board, the Federal Reserve Banks, the OEB, and
the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

The Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
2016 Annual Report was produced by the
Research Department, Publications Division.
MANAGING EDITOR: Karl Rhodes
DESIGN: Janin/Cliff Design
GROUP PHOTOGRAPHY: Larry Cain
PRINTING: Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Special thanks to Gina Karp, Lisa Kenney, Susan Maxey, and Joseph Mengedoth.
The 2016 Annual Report also is available on the
Bank’s website: www.richmondfed.org.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond l 2016 ANNUAL REPORT

FIFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT OFFICES
RICHMOND
701 East Byrd Street
Richmond, Virginia 23219
(804) 697-8000

www.richmondfed.org

BALTIMORE
502 South Sharp Street
Baltimore, Maryland 21201
(410) 576-3300

CHARLOTTE
530 East Trade Street
Charlotte, North Carolina 28202
(704) 358-2100