View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Contents

~ Foreword
~ Central Banking in the United States:
A Fragile Commitment to
Price Stability and Independence
~ Comparative Financial Statements

~ Directors
~ Officers

Forevvord

~ ineteen ninety-one was a year of changesand often the changes took unexpected turns.
The long-awaited bank reform bill was passed,
but disappointed many in its lack of vision. The
economy, which many observers expected to
recover, seemed to stall and then founder at the
close of the year.
At the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
change also occurred with the departure of our
president, W Lee Hoskins, and the appointment
of our new president, Jerry L. Jordan.
Lee, who left to become president and chief
executive officer of The Huntington National
Bank, made noteworthy contributions on several
fronts. He developed influential public policy
positions on the importance of price stability
and financial regulatory reform. Under his
leadership, the Fourth District made significant progress toward becoming the lowest-cost
provider of high -quality services in the Federal
Reserve System. Speaking for the directors,
officers, and employees of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, I wish him well in his new
responsibilities.
Jerry, who joined the Bank in March of this year,
was most recently senior vice president and chief
economist of First Interstate Bancorp in Los
Angeles, California. He has extensive knowledge
of monetary policy, banking, and economic
issues. Jerry also has a national reputation in
the public policy arena and experience in both
the private and public sectors. We look forward
to working with him on the challenges ahead.
One of those challenges is maintaining our
progress toward a goal of price stability. Monetary
policy was eased often and much throughout
1991, and in a manner that we believe does not
compromise long-term price stability. As we
argue in this year's annual report essay, future

policy adjustments-and there will doubtless be
many - should focus on this goal.
Twenty -three directors, representing banking,
business, agriculture, consumer, and labor interests, guide the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
and its Branches. Their contributions are highly
valued, as is the participation of our Small Bank
and Small Business Advisory Councils.
Special thanks are extended to those directors
who have completed their terms of service on our
boards. We are especially grateful for the leadership of Kate Ireland (national chairman, Frontier
Nursing Service of Wendover, Kentucky), who
was chairman of our Cincinnati Branch board
of directors. We also appreciate the contributions
of Allen L. Davis (president and chief executive
officer of The Provident Bank, Cincinnati, Ohio),
who served on our Cincinnati Branch board; and
E. James Trimarchi (president and chief executive officer of First Commonwealth Financial
Corporation, Indiana, Pennsylvania), who served
on our Pittsburgh Branch board. In addition,
the Fourth District has been well represented
on the Federal Advisory Council by John B.
McCoy ( chairman, preSident, and chief executive
officer of Banc One Corporation), and we are
grateful for his continuing dedication.
Finally, on behalf of the board of directors, I want
to express my appreciation to the officers and
employees of the Bank for making 1991 a successful year. I particularly want to commend them on
their admirable performance during the transition period between presidents. To their credit,
the Bank continued to function extremely well.
Sincerely,

~~

~.Miller

Chairman of the Board

Central Banking in the United States:
A Fragile Commitment to
Price Stability and Independence

~ uring the past seven years, inflation in the
United States averaged 3.9 percent, declining to
a low of 2.9 percent in 1991. This represents a
substantial improvement from the decade of the
1970s and marks our return to an elite group
of low-inflation countries in the world. This
achievement may be largely uncelebrated,
because many Americans are currently focused
on the stability of their jobs and incomes. However, both history and research suggest that
very low inflation will improve economic performance, gi ving us reason to expect better
times are ahead.

When the Federal Reserve System wa created
in 1913 to improve the functioning of the commercial banking system, price stability was taken
for granted. Yet, the Federal Reserve's creators
recognized the dangers of political control of the
money creation process and designed the ystem
to withstand it. A review of history illustrates
the wisdom of this approach : attempts to realize
short-term objectives through the manipulation
of money and credit inevitably lead to financial
and economic distress.

Conventional measures of inflation expectations indicate that most people believe that this

This essay reviews the evol u tion of cen tral
banking in the United States and emphasizes the
deliberate efforts to create a structure that would
be insulated from partisan politics. We conclude

favorable pattern will continue in 1992. But will
the commitment to maintaining price stability

that the Federal Reserve's accountability can
be strengthened by having Congress resolve that

be fleeting or enduring?

price stability should be the Federal Reserve's
first and foremost goal. With this mandate, and

Given the mixed performance of our nation's
central bank over the past few decades, this commitment to price stability seems fragile indeed.
Over the years, the focus of policymakers ha
turned away from long-term economic growth
and price stability, and has turned toward
achieving short-term economic objectives for
production, employment, long-term interest

with continued insulation from political influence, the Federal Reserve can make a major
contribution toward efforts to achieve maximum,
sustainable economic growth .

rates, and occaSionally, foreign exchange rates.

B e for e

the Fed era ~ Res e

~ ur country's founders were aware of the
dangers involved with granting the government
or one of its agencies direct and unchecked con trol over the issuance of currency that has little
or no intrinsic value. These leaders had witnessed
firsthand the economic damage that ensued
from debasing money to serve political needs
during and in the aftermath of the American
Revolution. Similar debasements and currency
overissues had occurred during the prior century
in Europe. Unbacked paper currencies, combined
with legal tender laws, ruined the public credit
of many of the prerevolutionary colonies and of
the independent states that existed before the
signing of the Constitution. The overissue of
currency often resulted in inflation, financial
chaos, and economic ruin , and our nation's
leaders sought to guard against it.
The Constitution gave Congress the power "to
coin money" and " to regulate the value thereof.'
Historians maintain that this language reflected
specific intent that the new nation adopt a specie
standard - that is , coin actually made of a
precious commodity. Soon after the Constitution
was ratified, Congress established its monetary
standard : a dollar had to contain 371.25 grains
of fine silver or 24.75 grains of fine gold.1
In effect, the United States had adopted a silver
standard and an official exchange rate between
silver and go ld . The founders had not only
stabilized the value of the nation's currency, but
had also guarded against political influence by
failing to grant the Executive Branch the power
to issue a paper cur rency.
Paper Currency

I
Until the Civil War, the use of paper money in
the United tates largely developed outside the
direct control of the federal government. As
banks were chartered by states and established

r:. ':!~~

around the country, they began to issue their
own circulating liability notes to their customers.
These notes, which circulated as "currency,"
were implicitly backed by gold and silver held at
the issuing bank and could be redeemed for such
by the bearer. Also, the First and Second Banks
of the United States issued circulating notes that
were receivable for taxes as long as they were
redeemable at par in gold or silver.
State-chartered banks were constrained by market
forces in their ability to issue notes. The probability that the notes would be redeemed at the
bank for specie - gold and silver coin - served
as a constraint on a bank's ability to issue notes.
Under normal circumstances and market pressures, then, each bank had to be careful to reserve
an appropriate amount of specie in relation to its
issue of bank notes.
Between the charters of the First and econd
Banks of the United tates (1812-1816) and after
the expiration of the Second Bank's charter
(1836), the natural constraint on bank note
issue was tested. Banks wishing to take advantage
of the rules of the Circulating bank note regime
placed themselves at long distances from financial
and commercial centers and issued much larger
volumes of notes than their reserve of specie
warranted. However, when bank notes circulated
to places far away from their point of issue,
recipients often demanded discounts commensurate with the difficulty of sending the notes
back for redemption. Market forces, in effect,
"priced' the value of the notes.
The U.S. banking system showed great promise in
its ability to formulate private market solutions
for the problems associated with a maturing
financial system and economy. By the 1850s,
the banking system was far from perfect, but it
displayed enough stability and effiCiency so that
there was no real political impetus to change the
system until the Civil War.

Greenbacks

The outbreak of the Civil War cleared the way for
the very development that the nation's founders
had sought to prevent: discretiona ry control of
money by the Executive Branch, within loose
limits imposed by Congress.
During the early 1860s, the U.S. Treasury found
it increasingly difficult to issue more debt to
finance the war. The 'freasury had already drained
available specie from the nation's largest banks,
and there was widespread concern about the
possibility of default on government bonds.
The Legal Tender Acts were passed to provide the
'freasury with an alternate method of finanCing
its debt. Through the Acts, the 'freasury acquired
the authority to issue legal tender paper, known as
"greenbacks:' This action was strongly opposed by
creditors, because the Treasury could now use
the notes' legal tender status to force the public,
including banks, to accept them as payment for
the government's bills. The Treasury expected
greenbacks, as legal tender for all public and
private debts, to circulate as currency. In effect,
the banking system was allowed to monetize
federal debt.
In retrospect, Congress clearly was searching for
an expedient way to finance the Civil War and the
Reconstruction, despite constitutional obstacles.
In fact, the legality of the Legal Tender Acts was
challenged after the war and, although eventually
upheld by the Supreme Court, the constitutionality of the Acts is debated by legal scholars
to this day.
The new issue of greenbacks was finally terminated in 1878, but the Treasury's control of
money and credit had already been firmly established by the ational Banking Act of 1863 and
its subsequent amendments in 1864 and 1865.
These statutes created nationally chartered banks
and allowed them to issue notes only if they were
secured with deposits of U.S. Treasury bonds.

By expanding and contracting federal debt, the
Treasury could indirectly control the amount of
national bank notes in the economy. Time and
again, however, this system displayed its inadequaCies. From 1863 until the creation of the
Federal Reserve System in 1913, the U.S. economy
was marked by periodic episodes of volatile prices
and interest rates, financial panics, and severe
economic booms and busts.
Many observers attributed the intermittent
economic chaos to the "inelasticity" of note
circulation under the Treasury's bond -deposit
system. The quantity of authorized federal debt
was strictly limited because the 'freasury generally
operated with a surplus. In addition, until the
'freasury adopted modern debt auction procedures
in 1896, the process of purchaSing new bonds by
banks was unduly expensive and occaSionally
slow. Banks were therefore o&en prevented from
purchasing new bonds and depositing them with
the Comptroller, even when additional note issues
could have been justified from a strict monetary
policy perspective.
At the same time, banks had difficulty retiring
notes, since the same formalities and expense
had to be endured for cancellation. Consequently,
the banking system was unable to provide easily
for an expanding and contracting volume of currency in response to the public's seasonal and
cyclical demand for money.

Because national banks placed such a high demand
on U. . 'freasury bonds to support currency note
issues, these securities became unprofitable for
banks to hold. In what might be the first modern
financial market innovation in response to
government regulation, demand deposits became
the most important source of bank funds. Banks
were not required to hold bonds against demand
deposits and, furthermore, could count demand
deposits held by other banks as reserves.

From time to time, depositors put substantial pressure on banks for cash withdrawals. However, with
a low supply of bank notes in their reserves and
because of the difficulty in quickly obtaining an
additional supply, banks were sometimes forced to
suspend payments and sharply restrict credit, contributing to financial panics and economic collapse.
The complex system of banks that developed
under the National Banking Act was believed to
exacerbate panics. Country banks were required
to keep part of their reserves in deposits at deSignated ' reserve city banks;' and reserve city banks
were required to keep part of their reserves in
larger city banks, known as "central reserve city
banks;' located in ew York, Chicago, and St.
Louis. These relationships served to transmit
payment suspensions and panics from one region
or particular bank to another and, ultimately,
throughout the system.
Another common but somewhat more controversial belief was that financial panics stemmed
fundamentally from the lack of an institutional
mechanism that would allow the nation's money
supply to expand and contract with currency
demand, which in turn expanded and contracted
with real economic activity.

~ he political and social heritage of the United
States resulted in a confluence of pressures that
were, and to a large degree still are, uniquely
American. From the very inception of central
banking in the United tates with the chartering
of the First Bank of the United States in 1791,
the political debate about central banking has
been focused on the values and dangers of centralized authority. The structure of the Federal
Reserve System reflects the nature of these
tensions.

After a deep and acute panic in 1907, Congress
set up the ational Monetary Commission to
study these monetary problems. The Commission's recommendations resulted in two courses
of action. First, the Aldrich-Vreeland Emergency
Currency Act of 1908 authorized private bank
clearinghouses to temporarily issue bank note
currency against trade-related paper, not just
government bonds. Later, the Federal Reserve Act
of 1913 established a quaSi-governmental organization to issue currency notes based on either
gold or commercial paper.
Thus, the new Federal Reserve Banks were designed to displace the clearinghouses. In addition,
the perceived need for a mechanism to allow the
expansion and contraction of the nation's money
supply was made explicit in the very legislation
that created the Federal Reserve System. The
preamble to the Federal Reserve Act describes
it as "An Act to provide for the establishment
of Federal reserve banks, to furnish an elastic
currency... :'

An early attempt to create a central bank that
would serve to "furnish an elastic currency" was
presented by Senator elson Aldrich of Rhode
Island in 1911. The Aldrich plan proposed a
ingle central authority, with branches throughout the country, that would be run and directed
by private bankers~
This plan was fiercely opposed by so-called
progressive Democrats, most notably the threetime Democratic presidential candidate and
future ecretary of State, William Jennings
Bryan. Bryan and his allies favored a central

bank controlled by public interests, with centralized authority outside the control of private
banking interests.
But the seeming irreconcilability of these opposing views did not eliminate the impulse for
the creation of a central bank. Consistent with
the American political experience, the ultimate
outcome was a compromise that was sufficient to
satisfy the majority needed to pass the Federal
Reserve Act.

New Orleans and other regional banking centers.
The Federal Reserve System allowed equal access
to its clearinghouse by all banks. Financial shocks
could be more easily absorbed under this new
framework, because the resources of the entire
Federal Reserve, not just the resources of a single
clearinghouse, could be directed at banking panics.
The Federal Reserve System could also accom modate fluctuations in the demand for currency.
The goal of supplying an elastic currency was

Harold H. Greene, United

States District Judge,

fohn Melcher v. Federal Open Market Committee, 1986
Fashioned largely by Virginia Representative
Carter Glass, President Woodrow Wilson, and
economic advisor H. Parker Willis, the Federal
Reserve System emerged as a hybrid institution,
a balance between public and private decision
making. The genius of the compromise was to
create an entity with no dominant centra l
authority, thereby assuring each faction that it
would not be overwhelmed by the other.
The Federal Reserve Act called for not less than
8 nor more than 12 Federal Reserve Banks, each
with a substantial degree of autonomy within the
System, and a Board of Governors to provide
coordination and oversight. The Board of
Governors is a government agency, and the Board
members are government officials. The Reserve
Banks are government instrumentalitiescorporations chartered by the federal government
to act in the public interest.
Essentially, the Federal Reserve replaced or
competed directly with the private clearinghouse
arrangements, which were operated by the largest
banks. Such clearinghouse arrangements had
been created in 1853 in New York and earlier in

to avoid banking panics, in which the public
sought to shift their funds from deposits to
currency. To prevent such panics from either
destroying banks or causing the restriction of
cash payments by banks, the new central bank
aimed to convert deposits to currency without
reducing the total of the two. The issuance of
the new currency, Federal Reserve notes, could
be rapidly expanded in panics, but was fully convertible, on demand, into gold.
The Federal Reserve's discount window prOvided
an easier way for banks to convert their commercial and agricultural assets into that currency.
A measure of local control and expertise was
prOVided by the fact that each Federal Reserve
Bank was made responsible for administering the
discount window. The regional Reserve Bank
preSidents had an important voice in the operation of the Federal Reserve System, provided
practical experience in banking and commerce,
and kept the Federal Reserve Board abreast of
regional economic conditions.

central banks - that is, "bankers' banks" - were
much closer in character to the First and Second

A Modern Central Bank

Bank of the United States. The Federal Re erve
System truly was the first central banking insti-

Central banks, of course, were not unknown at the
turn of the century; virtually all industrialized

tution speCifically designed to address issues
relating to the interaction of financial instability

countries had formed central banks by 1900.
Furthermore, some central bankers regarded their

and macroeconomic risk.

responsibilitie as having grown to encompass the
same general concern for the safety of financial
markets and the payment system that motivated
the debate surrounding the enactment of the

At its inception, the Federal Reserve may have
been more dedicated to controlling short-term
fluctuations in the price level than to planning
for long-run price stability . But the long-run
stability of prices was presumed because the
creation of the Federal Reserve System occurred
in the context of the gold standard. ot until
much later, after the gold standard gave way to

Federal Reserve Act.
In important respects, however, the context into
which the Federal Reserve ystem was organized
was decidedly unique. The European and Japanese
central banks were created primarily to organize

our present monetary system, did the long-run
stability of prices emerge as a serious concern
in the conduct of monetary policy.

note issue and to facilitate clearinghouse operations among private banks. In this regard, exi ting

~ n it earl y days, the Federal Reserve Banks'
primary policy tool was making loans secured by

sound collateral through their discount lending
facilities . The interest received from these loans
was the primary source of revenue for the Federal
Reserve Banks. Today, open market operationsthe purcha e and sale of government securities
in the money market - is the major tool of
monetary policy. The transition from di count
lending to open market operations created conflicts within the Federal Reserve over the ystem's
governance.
In the early 1920s, after the war finance program
for World War I was completed, the volume of
Federal Reserve Bank loans to commercial banks
dropped severely, thus impairing ystem revenue.
In order to shore up weak profits, the Re erve
Banks took advantage of their authority '~ .. to
purchase Government bonds within the limits
of prudence, as they might see fit;'4 Open market
operation grew and noticeably influenced credit
markets and banking reserves.

Establishing the FOMC

I
The Federal Re erve Act contained no explicit
provision for the current form of open market
operations, since its use as a policy tool developed
quite unexpectedly. In fear that the U.S. Treasury
might step in and assert its authority in open
market operations, the Reserve Banks formed a
committee of four Reserve Bank preSidents in
1922, under the leadership of New York Fed
President Benjamin Strong, to coordinate the
12 Districts' open market operations. Later that
year the committee was expanded to five presidents, who at that time were called "governor ;'
Throughout the 1920s, the Board in Washington,
D.C. - which included five members, plus the
Secretary of the Treasury and the Comptroller of
the Currency as ex officio members-displayed
increasing displeasure about its lack of input in
open market operations. In fact, Board member

Adolph Miller complained that the Board should
have a more active voice in decisions concerning
open market operations?

Board's political independence was strengthened
by eliminating the Secretary of the ueasury and
the Comptroller of Currency from the Board of
Governors, and by again extending the governors'
terms - this time from 12 years to 14 yea rs.

In March 1923, the Board decided to claim its
own jurisdiction by dissolving the Reserve Banks'
committee . The Board then reestablished a
similar group, the Open Market Investment
Committee, to carryon its work under principles
and regulations determined by the Board. Because

Thus, having confronted several opportunities
to eliminate the public - private mix that had
characterized the Federal Reserve System, legislators instead strengthened that feature by writing
into law the role of the Federal Reserve Bank
preSidents in open market operations and removing the Secretary of the Treasury and the
Comptroller of the Currency. Since the Banking
Act of 1935 and the subsequent amendment in
1942, which gave the ew York Federal Reserve
Bank permanent representation on the FOMC, no
major legislative changes have been made to the
monetary policymaking structure of the Federal
Reserve System. In short, the Banking Act of
1935 established the monetary policy structure
of the Federal Reserve System largely as it
exists today.

the ueasury was represented on the Board by both
its Secretary and the Comptroller of the Currency, this structure provided the ueasury with a
means for direct influence over monetary policy.
The Board's influence over open market operations was strengthened as a result of policy
disagreements among the Reserve Banks in the
late 1920s. However, monetary policy was used
ineffectively at the on et of the Depression. In
1930, the Open Market Investment Committee
was replaced by the Open Market Policy Conference, which included a representative of each
Federal Reserve Bank. The new Committee sub mitted all decisions to the Board for approval and,
without the Board's approval, the Committee
could not act. This reallocation of power was
ratified and somewhat amplified in the Banking
Act of 1933.
The consolidation of control over open market
operations at the Board was consistent with
sentiment in favor of a greatly enlarged federal
presence in the national economy during the
troubled Depression years . While the Banking
Act of 1933 shifted some of the administrative
power over open market operations to the Board,
the Act, at the same time, strengthened the
independence of the Federal Reserve System by
lengthening Board members' terms from 10 to
12 years.
The Banking Act of 1935 brought more sweeping
changes. The Committee (renamed the Federal
Open Market Committee, or FOMC) would now
include five voting representatives of the Reserve
Banks along with the full Board, giving the Board
a 7 -to-5 majority on the FOMe. In addition, the

Financing US_ Debt

I
When the United tates entered World War II in
December 1941, the Federal Reserve's primary
objective was to facilitate-as it did during
World War I - the Treasury's finanCing of the
country's huge deficits. The Federal Reserve's
assistance during World War II differed, however,
in two important aspects from its activities
during World War 1.
In the earlier war, the Federal Re erve encouraged banks to buy government securities by
maintaining low discount rates. Banks bought
government securities at yields higher than the
discount rate, and the discount window guaranteed short-term liquidity for those bank assets.
Of course, this steered bank credits away from
commerce, industry, and agriculture and toward
government bonds. The Federal Reserve Banks
bought few Treasury securities themselves,
largely confining their monetary operations to
discount window activities and purchases of
bankers acceptances.

During World War II, at the Treasury 's behest,
interest rates were not allowed to rise at all. As

As the postwar period progressed, the Federal
Reserve and the 'freasury increasingly disagreed

wartime financing grew, however, the Fed became
more concerned about the inflationary conse-

about the appropriate monetary policy for the
nation. In essence, the 'freasury argued that the

quences of maintaining constant interest rates.
When the Fed threatened to break away from

Federal Reserve could best support the expansion
of the economy by maintaining a relatively fixed

Treasury policy, the Treasury emphasized the
problems that a change in the structure of rates

price structure for federal debt instead of allowing
prices to fluctuate with market demand.

Allan Sproul,

"Reflections of a Central Banker," 1956

was likely to cau e, becau e federal government
securitie and government-guaranteed loans made

The Federal Reserve maintained that it could
not achieve the goals of the Employment Act by

up an important share of the assets structure of
banks and other public and private institutions?

pegging the price of government securities,
because that would subordinate monetary policy
to the fiscal needs of the U.S. 'freasury. In addition , the outbreak of the Korean War in 1950

To limit inflation and to prevent ri ing private
demands from diverting resources away from the
war effort, direct wage and price contro ls were
established. The Federal Reserve regulated the
expansion of private- ector credit directly. While
the controls kept consumer and business spending
in check, the inflationary potential wa la rge
indeed, once the controls were lifted.
Setting Goals

I

set off a wave of inflation and intensified policy
disputes between the Federal Reserve and the
'freasury.
After much debate, the Federal Reserve and the
Treasury reached an agreement, commonly
refe rred to as the 1951 Accord. The Accord
reestablished the Federal Reserve's independence
within government and gave the central bank the
flexibility to decide how, and for what purpose,
to cond uct open market operations.

After World War II, concern about inflation and
economic growth resu lted in the enactment of
the Employment Act of 1946, which called for
" maximum employment, production, and purchaSing power."8 Re pon ibility for achieving the
goals of the Employment Act of 1946 was not
assigned specifically to the Federal Re erve
ystem or to any other agency of government.
Rather, the Act was an expression of goals to be
pursued by all government agencie to the extent
that their u ual operation and powers enabled
them to do o.

Bretton Woods

The two World Wars affected more than th e
interaction between monetary and fiscal policy.
For all practical purposes, the international gold
exchange standard had effectively vani hed during
World War I. After that war, many co untries
attempted to return to their former gold standard ,

but were unsuccessful. In 1933, in the depths of
the Great Depression, the United States ceased
gold convertibility.
At the conclusion of World War II, at Bretton
Woods, ew Hampshire, a system was established
that required each country to set a "par" value
of its currency relative to the dollar. The U.S.
Treasury was committed to redeem surplus dollar
claims of foreign central banks, in gold, at the
rate of one ounce for every $35.
Under the Bretton Woods agreements , deficit
countries had to use their international gold
reserves to redeem their own currencies from the
surplus countries at the fixed exchange rate.
Alternately, countries with trade deficits would
have to use restrictive monetary or fiscal poliCies
to curb their imports, thereby restoring a balance
of payments with their trading partners at the
declared fixed exchange rates.
As long as the United States ran trade surpluses,
running out of gold reserves was not a concern .
However, pressures on the U.S. gold reserve
began as early as 1958, and despite efforts to
adjust the U.S. economy and curtail the gold outflows, these pressures continued and intensified
as Vietnam War expenditures increased. Because
the domestic economy was straining against its
productive capacity, the U.S. balance of payments position deteriorated rapidly, and inflation
escalated.
A speculative run on the dollar commenced
when world markets became convinced that the
United States would not restrict the growth of
its domestic economy to support the purchaSing
power of its dollar. After more than 25 years,
the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange
rates collapsed in August 1971, when the United
States suspended foreign gold sales.
Although severing the dollar from gold in the
international arena initially disrupted trade and
somewhat reduced U.S. foreign policy stature, it
really did not cause immense domestic economic
problems. The volume of foreign trade was small

relative to the size of our economy at the time.
evertheless, the event was highly Significant,
in hindSight, as a reminder of the lengths to which
our government was willing to go to prevent
domestic economic slowdowns. This realization
did little to restore foreigners' confidence in the
dollar during the 1970s.
Multiple Objectives

I
In their 1962 Report, the Council of Economic
Advisers argued that discretionary policy was
essential for achieving the employment, production, and price stability goals of the Employment
Act of 1946? Some economists called for closer
coordination of fiscal and monetary policies.
Throughout the 1960s and 1970s, as policymakers
learned that monetary and fiscal poliCies could
have powerful effects on the economy, they began
advocating frequent policy changes (that is, using
fiscal and monetary policies to "fine-tune" the
economy) in an attempt to keep the economy constantly at full capacity. Legislation was enacted
that encouraged fine-tuning.
The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act
of 1978, also known as the Humphrey-Hawkins
Act, expanded the list of national goals to include
"... full employment and prodUction, increased
real income, balanced growth, a balanced federal
budget, adequate productivity growth ... an
improved trade balance ... and reasonable price
stability."lo
Like the original Employment Act of 1946, the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act established general
goals for all agencies of government rather than
specific assignments for each one. The 1978 Act
also established procedures to help coordinate
the policies of the various agencies of government
to achieve those goals. For example, the Federal
Reserve is required to report its monetary policy
plans to Congress semiannually, and to comment on the relationship of those plans to the
President's goals.

Balancing Goals

I
In contrast to those laws, the Federal Reserve
Reform Act of 1977 assigned some specific goals
to the nation's central bank. Congress amended
the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 to require the
Federal Reserve ~ .. to promote effectively the
goals of maximum employment, stable prices,
and moderate long-term interest rates:'u However,
the Federal Reserve has the responsibility to
decide how best to pursue those goals.

goal over time. The absence of any prioritization
of the legally mandated goals emboldens political
and special-interest groups to campaign for the
policy stance of greatest current importance to
each group.
Ironically, elevating the importance of price
stability could enhance the Federal Reserve's
ability to craft short-run policy actions in response to problems and crises without affecting
inflation expectations. Although the long-term
relationship between money and prices appears

Edvvard.J_ Kane, 'Bureaucratic elf-Interest as an
Obstacle to Monetary Policy Reform;' 1990

The major drawback to the statutory encouragement of fine-tuning is its infeasibility. To st rike
a balance among the multiple goals requires that
they be reliably linked to one another. Furthermore, the existing legislative framework assumes
that monetary policy is capable of influenCing

to be strong and stable, temporary and unforeseen factors may cause the price level to deviate
from its desired course. Fortunately, achieving
long-run price stability does not require close,
short-run control of the price level. Taking full

imultaneousl y all three economic dimension
(maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates) in the desired
directions and quantities. This approach to

advantage of the hort-term flexibility that these
relationships afford, however, requires a profound

economic policymaking is no longer supported
by most new academic thinking nor by practical
experience.

The United tates has experienced long periods
of both price tability and inflation. A sober

respect for the price stability objective.

assessment of our modern history brings the
conclusion that inflation neither buys economic

By attempting to maintain a balancing act among
complex economic goals, the Federal Reserve

growth nor eliminates business cycles. How much
more beneficial for the country it would be to

causes substantial confusion about its capabilities
and intentions. Rather than being held account-

aim for something that monetary policy can
actuall y deliver - price stabili ty - than to un rea -

able for accomplishing anything in particular, the
Federal Reserve is expected to manage the entire

sonably demand satisfaction on all fronts.

economy without possessing the tools to do so.
Having multiple goals permits the Federal Reserve
to choo e which goal is emphaSized at any
moment, rather than committing to a particular

~ rom our early history, we know that political leaders aspired to achieve one simple goal
for the country's monetary standard - to protect
it from debasement. In particular, they wanted
to prevent the government from issuing debt
and repaying it later with inflated dollars . They
did not countenance unbacked, governmentissued paper money.

A Strong Commitment

I
Thi commitment to a Single goal of price
stability seems to be gathering adherents around
the world. By law, the German central bank is
"not subject to instructions from the Federal
Government or, of cour e, to instructions from
any other authority." Legislation pas ed in 1957

The transformation of the pre-1933 economy into
today's economy required the abandonment of

also specifies that the Bundesbank "support the
general economic policy of the Federal Govern-

commodity-backed money for two main reasons:
gold and silver are expensive to move around

ment, but only in 0 far a this is consistent with
its duty of safeguarding the currency."13

safely in large quantities, and a banking system
chained to convertibility of bank liabi lities
proved to be inflexible in accommodating changes
in money demand. These shortCOmings gave rise
to our Federal Reserve System and to other
central banks around the world.
But eventually, along with the development of
central banks came the belief that monetary and
fiscal poliCies could be used to precisely control
the growth of the economy. This view was imposed
on the Federal Reserve System by Congress, and
the result wa that our central bank became
accountable for all of the nation's economic
goals-an impossible mission.

In this respect, the Bundesbank's situation is
different from the Federal Reserve's. More than
one goal is specified by law for the German bank,
but the law states that the goal of price stability
is to be given highest priority whenever another
goal might conflict with maintaining price
stability. That is a major reason why Germany's
price performance has surpassed that of the
United tates. The U. . inflation rate was twice
the German rate between 1960 and 1990.14
Austria and ew Zealand have amended their
central bank laws to make price stability the
central bank's primary mandate. In addition, the
Maastricht agreement, which spells out the

How can nations design their monetary authorities to be both independent within government,

framework for establi hing a European central
bank in 1999, makes price stability the primary

and yet accountable to government? Accountability, improperly framed, can become a serious

objective for the new central bank.

impediment to the necessary functioning of
central banks. But if expectations are limited to

Even ome countries with poor inflation performance, such a Chile, have sought to restore their

achieving one goal, and if expectations for
achieving that goal are correspondingly strength-

central bank's credibility. By enacting legislation
that gives them more formal independence from

ened by CongreSSional mandate accountability
can provide useful support for central banks.

their governments in conducting monetary policy,
such nations have taken the first step toward
achieving price stability. imilar steps are being
considered in Argentina, Czechoslovakia, and
Poland.

If the United States were to legislate a clear price
stability objective for the Federal Reserve, the
nation would benefit. The next best solution (the
one actually followed, in fact, in this country
from the time of Alexander Hamilton) calls for
a central bank whose structure provides the most
independence that the political system can bear.

The framers of the Federal Reserve Act intentionally built in provisions to keep the Federal
Reserve independent from political pressures.
Subsequent revisions to the Federal Reserve's
structure, especially in 1935, added more layers
of insulation to protect the System from the
countervailing economic and political realities
that evolved.
Long terms for members of the Board of Governors
are a keystone of the System's structure. The
seven governors are appointed by the President
of the United States and approved by the enate.
Governors are appointed for 14-year terms, which
are staggered, every two years, to keep turnover
on the Board at a measured pace. 0 two governors
can be from the same Federal Reserve District.
RemOving the ecretary of the Treasury from the
Board in 1935 further emphasized the congressional desire to shield the Federal Reserve from
the partisan political arena.
Reserve Bank presidents and directors also contribute to the Federal Reserve's independence.
Directors oversee Bank operations, which are
conducted like for-profit businesses. These
individuals have vast experience in banking and
commerce, and continue to provide the practical
and regional input to the Federal Reserve that
was a hallmark of the System at its inception.
Because directors are not political appointees (in
fact, they are prohibited from partiCipating in
partisan politi cal activities during their tenure
as directors), they provide an added degree of
insulation to the System .

The Board of Governors appoints three of the
nine directors and, from those three, designates
a chairman and deputy chairman of each Bank's
board. Each Reserve Bank's board of directors,
in turn, is responsible for appointing the president
of its Reserve Bank - subject to approval by the
Board of Governors. The presidents participate
in the monetary policy process through the
FOMe. The president of the ew York Fed is a
permanent voting member, along with the 7
governors. The remaining 11 presidents vote on
the FOMe on a rotating basis (only 4 of the 11
vote at each meeting).
The entire process yields an FOMe consisting of
a majority set of public officials and a minority
set of Reserve Bank presidents acting for the
public good. The majority set of officials ensures
that the legitimate interests of government are
represented. The President of the United States
also designates and appoints the chairman of the
Board of Governors to a four-year term. The
Board of Governors has exclusive power to
determine the discount rate upon receiving
recommendations for changes from the boards
of directors of the Federal Reserve Banks.
The minority set of FOMe members is selected
by a process designed to minimize the effects of
short -term political pressures. Their presence
se rves as an institutional, flesh-and-blood
buttress to the commitment of central bank
independence within government.
To some, the Federal Reserve System 's design
might appear needlessly complex, but an appreciation of history and politics reveals why
economic statesmen crafted an institution with
such a broadly dispersed power structure. If they
had thought of monetary policy as a cookie jar,
eternally tempting to politicians, the Federal
Reserve's sponsors would have regarded their
structure as a means of placing that jar on the
top shelf of a tall, locked cupboard. A determined
and persistent government could eventually get
that jar down from the shelf, but it would have
to be very serious about its mission to do so.

Conclusion

Our performance on price stability since 1935
could have been better. Once the nation formally
broke away from the gold exchange standard , the
U.S. dollar lost its anchor to price stability, and
inflation rapidly spun out of control in the 1970s.
The political will to rein in inflation took nearly
a decade to muster. More recently, the Federal
Reserve has made great progress in reducing
inflation from the high levels of the late 1970s
and early 1980s. However, inflation has not been
eliminated, and the important progress of recent
years rests on a fragile commitment that may
be abandoned.
The nation should not be wholly satisfied with
the performance of the Federal Reserve System.
By assigning the Federal Reserve multiple monetary policy objectives, Congress has provided
insufficient guidance. Consequently, some people
are correctly suspicious of the Federal Reserve's
ultimate commitment to price stahility.
A price stability mandate would shift the focu
of monetary policy away from short-term finetuning to the long term, where it belongs. Such
a mandate would enforce accountability for the
one vital objective that the Federal Reserve can
achieve, and it would officially sanction those
sometimes unpopular short-run policy actions
that most certainly are in our nation's longterm interestFortunately, the Federal Reserve has a structure
that permits it to operate with some degree of
independence from partisan political pressures.
The present structure originated in a different
era, when the responsibilities and powers of the
Federal Reserve were thought of quite differently.
As the role of the central bank evolved, Congress
contemplated changing the structure many times,
but essentially has not done so for more than
50 years. Changes that are made should be conistent with strengthening, not weakening, the
Federal Reserve's commitment to price stability
and its independence.

Contemplated changes to the Federal Reserve
System should be debated widely, openly, and at
length. In this e say, we argue that the focus of the
debate should be on how to improve the Federal
Reserve's performance. Setting clear, achievable
objectives and holding the Federal Reserve publicly accountable for achieving those objective
will result in monetary policy that contributes
to maximum ustainable economic growth .

Footnotes

I
Edwin Vieira, Pieces oJ Eight: The Monetary Powers
and Disabilities oJ the United States Constitution
(Darby, 1983), pp. 98-9.

r'

2

uggested Plan for Monetary Legislation, Senate
Document 0.784,61 Congo 3 Sess. (Government
Printing Office, 1911).

3

fohn Mekher V. Federal Open Market Committee,
United States District Court for the District of Columbia,
Civil Action 0.84-1335 (1986).

4

Board of Governor of the Federal Reserve System,
First A nnual Report oJ the Federal Reserve Board,
1914 (GPO, 1915), p. 16.

5

Le ter V. Chandler, Benjamin trong, Central Banker
(The Brookings Institution, 1958), p. 222.

6

Allan proul, "Reflections of a Central Banker,"
journal oJ Finance, vol. XI (March 1956), pp. 4-5.

7

A. Jerome Clifford, The independence oJthe Federal
Reserve System (University of Pennsylvania Press,
1965), pp. 163-96.

8

Employment Act ofl946, ection 2, as recorded in the
United States Code: Congressional Service, Laws oJ 79th
Congress, Second Session (West Publishing Company),
p.20.

9

Economic Report oJthe President, January 1962
(GPO,1962).

10

Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978,
as recorded in the United States Code: Congressional
Service and Administrotive News, Laws oJ 95th Congress,
econd Session (West Publishjng Company).

11

Federal Reserve Reform Act of 1977, as recorded in the
United States Code: Congressional Service and
Administrotive News, Laws oJ 95th Congress, First Session
(West Publishing Company).

12

Edward J. Kane, "Bureaucratic elf· Interest as an
Obstacle to Monetary Reform," in Thomas Mayer, ed.,
The Political Economy oJ American Policy (Cambridge
University Press, 1990), pp. 287-8.

13

Bank for International ettlements, Eight European
Central Banks (George Allen and Unwin Ltd.,
1963), pp. 56-7.

14

Economic Report oJ the President, January 1991
(GPO, 1991), p. 408.

Comparative Financial Statement
For years ended December 31

Assets

Gold certificate account
Special drawing rights certificate account
Coin
Loans and securities:
Loans to depository institutions
Federal agency obligations bought outright
U. . government securities
Bills
otes
Bonds
Total U. . government securities
Total loans and securities
Cash items in proces of collection
Bank premises
Other assets
Interdistrict settlement account
TOTALA

ETS

1

9

1

1

9

$

692,000,000
645,000,000
30,183,268

$

688,000,000
645,000,000
39,289,608

9

9

0

-0378,205,795

-0379,907,713

8,299,003,637
6,352,112,831
2,022,987,976
16,674,104,444
17,052,310,239
353,848,298
34,300,807
1,777,907,651
1,765,980,255

6,740,802,414
5,475,949,688
1,866,912,501
14,083,664,603
14,463,572,316
256,888,868
36,121,850
2,126,715,647
1,076,627,132

$22,351,530,518

$19,332,215,421

$19,949,460,886

$17,005,076,555

1,571,163,262
7,755,000
87,808,726
1,666,726,988
269,814,840
143,216,304

1,816,463,408
8,250,000
2,061,427
1,826,774,835
82,867,142
166,785,489

$22,029,219,018

$19,081,504,021

$

161,155,750
161,155,750

$

125,355,700
125,355,700

322,311,500

$

250,711,400

Liabilities

Federal Reserve notes
Deposits:
Depository institutions
Foreign
Other deposits
Total deposits
Deferred availability cash items
Other liabilities
TOTAL LIABILITIES
Capital accounts

I
Capital paid in
urplus
TOTAL CAPITAL ACCOU T
TOTAL LIABILITIES AND CAPITAL ACCOU TS

$22,351,530,518

$19,332,215,421

Current income

199

Interest on loans
Interest on government securities
Earnings on foreign currency
Income from services
All other income
Total current income

1

1

477,189
1,181,833,460
129,935,784
43,638,765
635,040
$ 1,356,520,238

$

$

773,106
1,176,904,432
143,052,007
43,460,030
623,087
$ 1,364,812,662

77,244,050
8,545,603

69,518,138
10,432,184

$ 1,270,730,585

$ 1,284,862,340

Current operating expenses
Cost of earnings credits
CURRE T NET I COME

990

Profit and loss

Additions to current net income
Profit on foreign exchange transactions
Profit on sales of government securities
All other additions
Total additions
Deductions from current net income
Loss on foreign exchange transactions
All other deductions
Total deductions
et additions or deductions

$

$
$

$
$

21,833,126
8,018,932
935
29,852,993

$

-06,240
6,240
29,846,753

$

9,694,406
6,028,900
16,602,497
32,325,803

$

$

$
$

3,772,191
117,666,511
11,432
121,450,134
-01,712
1,712
121,448,422

Assessments by Board of Governors

I
Cost of Unreimbursable Treasury ervices
Board of Governors expenditures
Federal Reserve currency costs
Total assessments by Board of Governors

$

NET I COME AVAILABLE FOR DI TRIBUTIO

$ 1,268,251,535

11,878,601
5,676,400
12,427,914
29,982,915

$ 1,376,327,847

Distribution of net income

Dividends paid
Payments to U.S. Treasury
(in terest on Federal Reserve notes)
Transferred to surplus
Total distributed

$

9,032,226

1,223,419,259
35,800,050
$ 1,268,251,535

$

7,488,534

1,366,983,763
1,855,550
$ 1,376,327,847

As of December 31, 1991

Cleveland Directors
(standing) Alfred C. Leist; William T. McConnell; Frank Wobst;
Laban P. .Jackson, .Jr.; (seated) Deputy Chairman
A. William Reynolds; Chairman .John R. Miller.

Cleveland

I
Chairman & Federal Reserve Agent
John R. Miller
Former Presiden t & Chief Operating Offi cer
Standard Oil Company of Ohio Cleveland, Ohio
Deput y Chairman

A. William Reynolds
Chairman & Chief Executive Officer

Douglas E. Olesen
Pres ident & Chief Execu tive Officer
Battell e Memorial In stitute Columbus, Ohio

Frank Wobst
Chairman & Chief Execu tive Officer
Huntington Ban cshare Incorpora ted Columbu , Ohio

GenCorp Fairlawn , Ohio

Verna K. Gibson
Business Con s ultant Columbu s, Ohio

John R. Hodges
Pre ident , Ohio AFL·CIO Columbu , Ohi o

Laban P. Jackson, Jr.
Chairman , Cl earcreek Properti es Lexington , Kentu cky

Alfred C. Leist
Ch airman, Presiden t & Chief Executive Officer
Th e Appl e Creek Banking Co. Appl e Creek, Ohio

William T. McConnell
President , The Park

alional Bank

ewark , Ohio

Federal Advisory Council

John B. McCoy
Chairman, President & Chief Executi ve Officer
Ban c On e Corporation Columbus, Ohio

Cincinnati Directors
(standing) Harry A . Shavv. III; .Jack W. Buchanan;
Clay Parker Davis. (seated) Marvin Rosenberg; Allen L. Davis.

Cincinnati

Pittsburgh Directors
Sandra L. Phillips; William F. Roemer;
I.N. Rendall Harper• .Jr.

Pittsburgh

I
Chairman

Chairman

Kate Ireland

Robert P. Bozzone
President & Chief Executive Officer

alional Chairman
Frontier urs ing ervice Wendover. Kentucky

.Jack W. Buchanan
President. phar & Company. Inc. Winche ter, Kentucky
Allen L. Davis
President & Chief Executive Officer
The Provident Bank Cin innali , Ohio

Clay Parker Davis
President & Chief Executive Officer
Citizens

ational Bank

omer et, Kentucky

Eleanor Hicks
Advisor for International Liaison
Univer ity of Cincinnati Cincinnati, Ohio

Marvin Rosenberg
Partner, Towne Propertie ,Ltd. Cincinnati, Ohio

Harry A. Shavv. III
Chairman & Chief Execu tive Officer
Huffy Corporation Dayton , Ohio

Allegheny Ludlum Corporation Pittsburgh, Penn ylvania

George A. Davidson• .Jr.
Chairman & Chief Executive Officer
Con olidated Natural Gas Company
Pittsburgh , Pennsylvania

Sandra L. Phillips
Executive Director, Pittsburgh Partnership for
eighborhood Development Pitt burgh , Pennsylvania

.Jack B. Piatt
Chairman of the Board
Millcraft Industrie , In c. Washington, Pennsylvania

William F.. Roemer
Chairman & Chief Executive Officer
Integra Financial Corporation Pitt burgh, Pennsylvania

E . .James Trimarchi
President & Chief Executive Officer
First Commonwealth Financial Corporation
Indiana, Pennsylvania

I.N. Rendall Harper, .Jr.
Pre iden!, American Micrographic Co., Inc.
Monroeville, Pennsylvania

As of December 31, 1991

William H. Hendricks

Andre\IV .1 . Bazar

First Vice Presiden t

Vice President

Randolph G. Coleman

Jake D. Breland

Senior Vice President

Vice President

John M. Davis

William S. Bro\IVn

Senior Vice President
& Director of Research

Vice President

Andre\IV C . Burkle, Jr.

John .1. Ritchey

Vice President

Senior Vice Pres ident
& General Counsel

Jill Goubeaux Clark

Samuel D. Smith
Senior Vice President

Donald G. Vincel
Senior Vice Presid ent

Robert F. Ware
Senior Vice President

John .1. Wixted, Jr.
Senior Vice President

Vice President
& Associate General Counsel

Patrick V. Cost
Vice President & General Auditor

La\IVrence Cuy
Vice Pre ident

Creighton R. Fricek
Vice President

Elena M. McCall
Vice PreSident

R . Chris Moore
Vice PreSident

Sandra Pianalto
Vice President & Secretary

Robert W. Price
Vice Presiden t

Ed\IVard E. Richardson
Vice President

Mark S. Sniderman
Vice Pre ident
& Associate Director
of Research

Joseph C . Thorp
Vice President

Robert Van Valkenbu r g
Vice President

Andre\IV W. Watts
Vice President

& Regulator y Counsel

Margret A. Beekel

James W. Rakovvsky

Assistant Vice Pre ident

A si tant Vice President

Terry N. Bennett

David E. Rich

As istant Vice President

Assistant Vice President

Thomas J. Callahan

John P. Robins

As i tant Vice Pre ident
& Assi tant ecretar y

Ex amining Offi cer
A sistant Vi ce Pres ident

A istant Vice Pre iden t
& Econ omist

Susan G. Schueller

A i tant Vice President

Charles A. Cerino
Senior Vice President

Roscoe E. Harrison
A sistant Vice President

Terrence J. Roth

Randall W. Eberts

John J. Erceg

Cincinnati

Barbara H. Hertz
A si tant Vice President

Jerry S. Wilson

Assistant Vice Pres ident

Burton G. Shutack

& Economist

A si tant Vice Pres id ent

William T. Gavin

William J. Smith

A si tant Vi ce Pre id ent
& Economist

Ass is tan t Vice Pres iden t

Edvvard J. Stevens

Assistant Vice Presid ent

Pittsburgh

I
Harold J. Svvart
enior Vice Pres iden t

As istant Vi ce Pre ident

Raymond L. Brinkman

Assistant Vice Pre ident

& Economist

Assistant Vice Presid ent

Robert J. Gorius

James B. Thomson

Lois A. Riback

Elaine G. Geller

Assistant Vice President

Norman K. Hagen
A si tant Vice Pre ident

Eddie L. Hardy
Examining Officer

David P. Jager
Assistant Vice Pres id ent

Rayford P. Kalich

A i tant Vice Pres ident
& Eco nomi t

Walker F. Todd
A sistant General Coun el
& Re earch Offi cer

Charles F. Williams

Robert E. White

Vice President

Kevin P. Kelley

Darell R. Wittrup

As i tant Vice Pres id ent

Ass istant Vice Pres ident

William J. Major
Assistant Vice Pre ident

Laura K. McGovvan
Ass istant Vice Pre ident

Columbus

Ass istant Vi ce Pre ident

Assi tant Vice Pre ident

As istant Vice President

Assistant Vice President

Henry P. Trolio

A i tant Vice Pres ident
& Assistant General Auditor

John E. Kleinhenz

Assistant Vice Pres ident

Robert B. Schaub

~ he Federal Reserve

ystem
is res pons ibl e for formulating
and implementing U. . monetary

policy. It also upervi es ban ks
and bank h oldin g co mpani e ,
and provide finan cial services
to depo itor y in tituti ons and
the federal governm ent.
Th e Federal Rese rve Ban k o f
Cl eveland is on e of 12 regional
Reser ve Banks in th e nit ed
ta te that , toge th er with th e
B oa rd o f G ove rn o r i n
Washington, D .C. , compri e the
Federal Reserve y tern .
Th e Fede ra l Rese r ve Bank o f
Cl eveland , its two bran c hes in
Cin cinn ati and Pitts burgh , and
its Columbu Offi ce se r ve th e
Fourth Federal Reserve Di trict.
Th e Fourth Di s tri ct in cl ud es
Ohio, western Penn ylvania, the
n o rth e rn pa nh a ndl e o f We t
Virginia, and eas tern Kentu cky.

Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland
Main Office
East 6th Street and
Superior Avenue
Cleveland, OH 44114
216.579.2000

Cincinnati Branch
150 East 4th Street
Cincinnati, OH 45202
513.721.4787
Pittsburgh Branch
717 Grant Street
Pi ttsbu rgh, PA 15219
412.261.7800

Columbus Office
965 Kingsmill Parkway
Columbus, OH 43229
6]4.846.7494
Design: Michael Galka
Photography: Bill Pappas
This annual report was prepared
by the the Public Affairs and Bank
Relations Department and the
Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
For additional copies of this
report, contact the Public Affairs
and Bank Relations Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, OH 44101, or call
1-800-543-3489.