The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
LZS ; Xl ? A BLS Reader on Productivity R eprinted from the M o n th ly Labor Review and other sources U S D epartm ent of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics June 1983 V A ®L§ R eader ©n ProductiwSfif Reprinted from the Monthly Labor Review and other sources U.S. Department of Labor Raymond J. Donovan, Secretary Bureau of Labor Statistics Janet L. Norwood, Commissioner June 1983 Bulletin 2171 SOUTHWEST MISSOURI STATE UNIVERSITY LIBRARY U S. DEPOSITORY COPY For sa le by th e S u p erin ten d en t o f D ocum ents. U .S. G overnm ent P r in tin g Office, W ash in gton , D.C. 20402 Preface This reader presents articles from the Monthly Labor Review and other publications, which discuss concepts and measurement of productivity and related variables. They analyze productivity in a number of industries and the factors underlying productivity change over time. They examine productivity measurement and trends in the Federal Government; technological developments and their impact on employment in a variety of in dustries; and international comparisons of productivity. In addition, the reader contains a number of illustrative statistical tables and charts. Data for 1982 were not available for many of the statistical series included in the tables at the time the reader went to press. Such data will be furnished to in terested parties upon request. The reader was prepared by the staff of the Office of Productivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. Je r o m e A . M a r k Associate Commissioner for Productivity and Technology JUN iii Contents Page I. Concepts and techniques of productivity measurement........................................................................................ Concepts and measures of productivity, by Jerome A. Mark ....................................................... . Which productivity? Perspective on a current question, by Solomon F ab rican t.................... ..................... II. Productivity trends in the business e co n o m y ....................................................................................................... Multifactor productivity in the private business economy since 1948.............................................................. V'The slowdown in productivity growth: Analysis of some contributing factors, by J. R. Norsworthy, Michael J. Harper, and Kent K unze.............................................................. 30 III. Productivity trends in industries and the Federal Government............................................................................ Highlights of recent trends in output per employee h o u r.................................................................................. Measuring productivity in service industries, by Jerome A. M a rk .................................................................. 40 43 50 1 2 11 16 18 Studies of productivity in some individual industries: Bituminous coal, by RoseN. Z eisel.............................................................................. ........................ 56 Commercial banking, by Horst Brand and John D u k e ............................................................................... 58 Eating and drinking places, by Richard B. Carnes and Horst B ra n d .......................................................... 67 Farm machinery, by Arthur S. Herman and John W. Ferris........................................................................ 73 Intercity bus carriers, by Richard B. C arn es............................................................................................. ... 78 Laundry and cleaning services, by Richard B. Carnes.................................................................................. 83 Machine tools, by John Duke and Horst B ra n d ........................................................................................... 87 Non wool yarn mills, by James D. Y ork.......................................................................................................... 95 Office furniture, by J. Edwin Henneberger.................................................................................................... 99 Pumps and compressors, by Horst Brand and Clyde Huffstutler................................................................ 104 Retail fo o d stores, by John L. Carey and Phyllis Flohr O t t o ...................................................................... 112 Soaps and detergents, by Patricia S. Wilder ........................................................................................ .. 118 Measuring productivity in government, Federal, State and local, by Jerome A. M a rk .............. ................. 123 IV. International com parisons....................................................................... ............................................................. 131 International trends in productivity and labor costs, by Patricia Capdevielle, Donato Alvarez, and Brian C o o p er.............. ...................................... ......................................................... 133 The international context, by Arnold Packer and Arthur N e e f ...................................................................... 143 V. Technology studies....................................................... .................... .................................................................... 145 Impact of new electronic technology, by Richard W. R ic h e ............................................................................ 147 Technology and labor in: Electrical and electronic equipment, by Robert V. Critchlow..................................................................... Electric and gas utilities, by Robert V. Critchlow.......................................................................................... Insurance, by Gustav A. Sailas..................................................................................................................... Metalworking machinery, by A. Harvey Belitsky......................................................................................... M otor vehicles and equipment, by Robert V. Critchlow .......................................................................... Petroleum refining, by Rose N. Zeisel and Michael D. Dymmel ................................................................ Printing and publishing, by Robert V. Critchlow........................................................................................ Telephone communications, by Michael D. Dymmel .............................................. ................................... Water transportation, by Robert V. Critchlow......................................................................................... .... 150 160 170 177 190 197 207 218 228 Bibliography............................................... ....................................... ............................................................................ 238 v fpart i. <S@oie®pts arod Ttehraiques ©f Produetiwity M®®sur@mont The first section of the BLS Reader on Productivity introduces the basic concepts and ideas of productivity measurement. Productivity refers to the relationship between output and input.,:Generally speaking, a pro ductivity measure reflects the efficiency with which a given output is produced by the resources employed. This relationship takes a great variety of forms. The two essays included here discuss two types of productivity measures. Each is made up of several groups of measures. One of the two types relates output to a single input, such as labor, capital, or energy. The other relates output to a combination of inputs, such as labor and capital combined. Both types are discussed in this Reader. Although the productivity measures discussed here relate output to hours of persons engaged in production (hours of employment) or to labor and capital combin ed, they do not measure the specific contributions of labor, capital, or any other single factor of production. Rather, they reflect the joint effects of many influences, including new technology, capital investment, the level of output, capacity utilization, energy use, and managerial skill, as well as the skills and efforts of the work force. Concepts and i¥t]©as tyres ©f Productivity by <ferom@ A. i/lark* Despite the wide attention paid to productivity over the years, confusion prevails as to its meaning and meas urement. This is understandable because the concept does lend itself to ambiguity and a wide range of produc tivity measures can and have been developed in response to different analytical uses. Productivity is loosely interpreted to be the efficiency with which output is produced by the resources utilized. A measure of productivity is generally defined as a ratio relating output (goods and services) to one or more of the inputs (labor, capital, energy, etc.) which were associated with that output. More specifically, it is an expression of the physical or real volume of goods and services related to the physical or real quantities of inputs. A variety of plausible productivity measures can be developed, the particular form depending on the purpose to be served. For example, output per labor input, the most familiar measure, is useful in understanding changes in employment or labor costs. This measure might be based on man-hours paid or man-hours worked, with different results. A more comprehensive measure of in put might be more useful in studying how the economy is using labor and capital combined. Also, there are various ways of adding up diverse products into a meas ure of output. No one measure is the right or best measure. Since the interpretation of these statistics depends on the definitions and data used, an understanding of the productivity concepts used in relation to the purpose to be served is always essential. that factor to production. Rather, they express the joint effect of a number of interrelated influences on the use of the factor in the production process—such as changes in technology, substitution of one factor for another, utilization of capacity, layout and flow of material, the skill levels and the efforts of the work force, and mana gerial and organizational skills. Whether for an individual establishment, an industry, or the entire economy, the most frequently developed and perhaps most useful productivity measure is an out put per unit of labor input measure of what is frequently termed a labor productivity measure. There are several reasons for this. Perhaps the most important is that labor is almost universally required for carrying through all types of production. There is a labor element of costs in almost all endeavors; the degree varies but it is always present. In addition, as a practical matter, it is perhaps the most measurable input. Other factors, such as capi tal, are much more difficult to quantify. There are, however, various labor productivity meas ures, depending on the definition of labor input. A measure may refer to output per person or it may take account of changes in hours of work and be based on total hours. It may cover the hours of the entire labor force including proprietors, unpaid family workers, and employers; or it may be limited to selected groups of workers. Another set of productivity measures relating output to a single input is output per unit of capital. These measures are particularly useful in understanding move ments in unit nonlabor costs by relating the measures to corresponding measures of returns to capital. As in the case of other single factor productivity measures they indicate the changes in the use of capital per unit of out put not the contribution of capital alone. The measures CONCEPTS OF PRODUCTIVITY There are two broad classes into which productivity concepts and in turn measures can be grouped. One in cludes those measures which relate output of a produc ing enterprise, industry, or economy to one type of in put such as labor, capital, energy, etc.; the other in cludes those which relate output to a combination of inputs extending to a weighted aggregate of all associate inputs.1 Although the former measures relate output to one input, they do not measure the specific contribution of 0 Assistant Commissioner for Productivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. 1 Even at the level of an individual craftsman where the output-input relationships are limited, these two concepts are present. Productivity can refer to the volume of work the in dividual is able to accomplish within a given time span— i.e., output per man-hour. It can also refer to the volume of work completed per unit of his time, Ms tools, and his materials— i.e., an output per total factor input. Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 1714 (1971), The M eaning and M easurem ent o f Productivity. 2 impact on man-hour requirements depending on whether output is measured by the yard or by the pound. For the more usual case of a plant or an industry producing many heterogeneous products, the different units must be expressed on some common basis. They can also be combined in terms of their man-hour re quirements. The advantage of the latter method for measures of output per man-hour is that the change in the productivity of the entire plant or industry is then a simple arithmetic average of the changes in the pro ductivity of the individual components. When the components are combined with value or price weights, that is, on the basis of their dollar value, then the output per man-hour measure for the total reflects not only changes in the productivity of the components but shifts in the importance of the com ponents. Physical quantity data are often not readily available, so deflation of dollar value is used. That is, total value of production is adjusted for change in price by use of a price index. This type of index is usually referred to as constant dollar output or deflated value of output. Such indexes are conceptually equivalent to indexes which use physical quantities combined with price weights. The contribution of a producing unit lies in the value added, by its own labor and capital, to the materials and services purchased from other producing units— i.e., its net addition. Net output, therefore, is the constant dollar value of production minus the constant dollar value of purchased goods and services. In measuring productivity, the net measure would then be related to the particular input or all associated inputs except the material inputs. Relating a net output measure to a single input, when the various commodities produced and purchased are combined with value or price weights, will result in a single factor productivity measure that reflects not only the changes in productivity of the components and shifts in the importance of these components but also savings in material consumption. have been limited to reproduction of what has been termed “tangible” capital. Other single factor measures such as output per energy input or output per material input are relevant for plant and industry study where these inputs are of considerable importance in the production process or represent relatively scarce resources. For example, in the aluminum industry where electrical power is an import ant element in processing bauxite, output per KWH-is very useful as an indication of the efficiency with which electricity is being utilized. As mentioned earlier, all single factor productivity measures reflect the joint effect of a variety of factors including the substitution of one factor for another. For some purposes, to develop a measure which eliminates the effect of that substitution is useful. This type of measure relates output to a combination of inputs. Thus, a productivity index of output per labor and capital combined elininates the effects of changes in amounts of capital per workers These measures have been termed multifactor or “total factor” or simply “total” produc tivity measures. For both conceptual and statistical reasons they have generally been limited to labor and “tangible” capital inputs and have not included as in puts activities such as research and education which can be viewed as intangible capital.2 Output For all productivity measures, output is measured in physical or real terms. The concept is one of work done or the amount of product added in the various enter prises, industries, sectors, or economy. It refers not to activity as such but to the results of activity. In this sense, at the plant level, production and hence productivity measurement differs from work measure ment. Work measurement generally refers to the analysis of the stages of activity and the requirements at each of these stages. Productivity refers to the finished product (the result of activity) and its relationship to input. In the case of a producing unit making one homo geneous commodity, production in physical terms would merely be a count of units produced. For a commodity to be regarded as homogeneous, certain conditions should be fulfilled. The product should be of a specified quality (e.g., carbon steel) and it must conform to pre cise standards of size, volume, unit, etc. Even though the measure of production in this case is a single count, the way of defining the unit of product can have different implications for productivity measurement. For example, carpeting can be measured in pounds or square yards. A change in the density of the carpeting would affect the weight per yard and, therefore, have a different Labor input For all productivity measures where labor is rele vant, labor input is measured in physical terms. The measure can refer either to the total number of individ uals engaged in production or to only part of the work force, or it can refer to the man-hours of workers. It is usually preferable to include the entire employed work force in the labor input measure— blue-collar and 2 Denison in his w ork on the sources of econom ic growth has made estim ates of the contributions of intangible factor input such as research, education, organization, etc., to total o u tput. See Edward Denison, The Sources o f E conom ic Growth in the United States and the A lternatives B efore Us (New Y ork, 1962) and Why G rowth R ates D iffer (W ashington, D.C., The Brookings Institution, 1967). 3 white-collar workers, corporate officers, and the selfemployed. The assessment of manpower needs must take all labor input requirements into account. But of course, there are times when analysis of labor requirements and the analysis of cost components suggests the use of mea sures which include only a component of the work force. To analyze the productive capacity of labor and the effects of changes in working hours, or in use for pro jections of manpower needs, an output per man-hour measure is most relevant. The most suitable unit of measure is man-hours worked. There are some ambi guities or differences of opinion on what to include, for example, standby time, coffee breaks, etc. In general, “hours worked” refers to the time spent at the place of employment, and therefore excludes hours paid for but used on leave for vacation, holiday, illness, accident, etc. In some cases, total hours paid are utilized in the pro ductivity measures because data on hours worked are not available. In developing a labor input measure, in many cases man-hours are treated as homogeneous and additive. These measures are particularly relevant to problems of estimating total man-hour requirements. But merely adding up the number of hours ignores the qualitative aspect of an hour worked by different individuals. Therefore, a productivity measure which is based on the sum of undifferentiated man-hours will reflect changes in the composition of the work force with dif ferent qualitative characteristics. For some purposes, it may be desirable to develop a productivity measure which takes into account the dif ferences in the “quality” of an hour of labor. That is, an hour of high quality labor is counted as propor tionately more than an hour of low quality labor. To do this some methods have to be introduced to differ entiate these hours. One way which has been utilized is to combine the man-hours of various employees in terms of pay differentials. The man-hours of higher paid workers are given more weight than lower paid. This assumes that differences in earnings reflect dif ferences in education, experience, skill, and their con tribution to output. 3 Another method is to adjust the data to take into account changes in vocational training, length of schooling, or type of education, etc., of the work force, assuming there is a close relationship be tween qualifications and quality. When adjustments are made for changes in the quality of labor input the re sultant productivity measure will not reflect changes in the composition of the work force as a productivity change but rather as a change in factor input. Capital input Capital stock estimates include the constant dollar value of structures, plants, and equipment current avail able for production. These estimates may also take into account the value of land, inventories, and working capital. Generally capital stock measures are derived by ad justing the value of existing plant and equipment for new investment and the retirement of old assets. There are different ways of measuring the stock of capital; for example, they may be gross or net. Net stock estimates are derived by depreciating assets (and there are various methods of depreciation). Gross stock estimates are derived by retaining assets at their full value until they are retired from use. Since these are physical measures, the value of capital stock must be adjusted for price changes. For productivity analysis, however, the flow of capital services rather than the stock is the preferred measure. A capital stock measure does not account for differences in the intensity of use over time. Equipment, for example, may be used for several shifts during a business expansion or may be idle during a contraction. Then, too, a large part of existing capital capacity may be standby and employed only during periods when the economy is operating at very high rates. There is also a loss of efficiency of assets as they grow older. A flow measure reflects differences in usage and efficiency and how they affect varying levels of output, which is the basis of productivity estimation. Ideally flow meas ures should indicate the amount of capital employed to produce current output. To derive this capital flow measure, an aggregate of the capital hours used weighted by the rental value of each type of structure and piece of equipment is needed. The data for this measure are often not available in the detail necessary for a capital flow measure. A commonly used flow of capital service measure is depreciation. However, this is based on accounting prin ciples which often reflect current income tax regulations rather than the actual amount of capital used for cur rent production. Because of the difficulty of estimating a capital flow measure, however, most analyses of capital and production use capital stock estimates. PROBLEMS OF MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY The measurement of productivity trends involves two fundamental problems which are applicable to both out put and input data. First, because of difficulties in ob taining direct quantity measures of output and input, substitute measures or approximations must be used in many cases. Second, since most data are collected for 3 Except to the extent that regional or similar wage dif ferentials affect average hourly earnings. 4 For the bulk of service activities, however, the de flation approach is used and its validity for the resultant output measure rests on the adequacy of the price in dexes. Most of the price indexes used are components of the Consumer Price Index, which in turn have different degrees of reliability. The indexes for medical services, for example, do not adequately take into account changes in the quality of medical services performed. As mentioned earlier, the real product measure is conceptually a net output measure but in many of the service activities data are not available on the real value of the material inputs. In such cases estimates of real product are made on the basis of changes in the total volume of output. This does not present a serious prob lem, however, since in most service industries inter mediate purchases constitute a relatively small pro portion of total value. The other major activity in the national accounts where the output measure has severe limitations for pro ductivity measurement is the construction industry. The constant dollar output measure is obtained by deflation, but the price index used is really a cost index. For the most part, these are measures of the change in costs of materials and labor weighted in terms of their base period importance. These indexes do not take into ac count any savings in the utilization of materials or labor, and, as a result, there is an overstatement of price in creases. Consequently, there is an understatement of gains in real output and hence productivity. Productivity indexes based on real product for con struction show an average annual decline of 0.2 percent. This is somewhat inconsistent with studies which the Bureau of Labor Statistics has conducted of labor re quirements for various specific types of construction during this period. These studies indicate for schools there was approximately a 2% percent per year gain over much “of this period, for highways a 3-percent in crease per year, and for hospitals not mcuh change. With regard to lack of comparability of coverage be tween output and labor, perhaps the largest evidence of this occurs in the real estate activity. For national in come accounting purposes, an inputed rent for home ownership is added to the output of the real estate industry. There is, however, no corresponding labor in- purposes other than productivity measurement, defi nitions already established and procedures for reporting information on production and factor inputs must be used; these may or may not be consistent with concepts appropriate for productivity measurement. Output Economy and sector level. The problems of using the gross national product data for productivity measure ment involve primarily the inadequacies of the measures of real output for some components and the lack of comparability of coverage between output and labor input measures. Limitations in measuring output affect the reliability of productivity statistics in some sectors more than others. Since the implications for productivity move ments can be offsetting among the sectors, the effect on measures for the overall economy is not as large as it is in each of the sectors. The three areas where the real product measures as derived from the national accounts are particularly weak for productivity measurement are government, construc tion, and services (including business and personal serv ices, and finance, insurance, and real estate). In the absence of market valuation of the services of general government agencies, the practice in national in come accounting is to value government output in terms of the wages and salaries of government employees. The deflated, or constant dollar, measure is derived from changes in employment. Such an output measure, when related to a labor input measure, results in no statistical change in productivity. This measure of government out put may be increasingly difficult to continue in view of the reported increases in output per man-hour in certain government operations which are subject to measure ment. 4 Based on these data the trend of output per man-hour for the national economy would be biased downward. As a consequence, the available measures of productivity are limited to the private economy. Measuring output in the service activities is difficult because of the absence of a directly quantifiable entity which describes a unit of service. Consequently, various substitute indicators are utilized in the national accounts. These usually involve the use of some “price” index for deflating the value of the service activities or the use of an employment index to develop trends in producers of services. As in the case of government, the use of the employ ment movements as an indicator of the change in real output implies a constant labor productivity. This ap proach is utilized for such activities as security and commodity brokers, 5 insurance agents, and miscella neous business and repair services. 4 __ Nestor E. Terleckyj “ Recent Trends in O utp u t and Input of the Federal G overnm ent,” in Proceedings o f the Business and Economics Section, Am erican Statistical A ssociation, 1964, pp. 76-94. 5 In view o f the rapid spread in recent years o f electronic data processing in this industry this measure m ust be very m uch understated since the productivity gains undoubtedly were large, John Kendrick has suggested th a t data on shares o f stocks and bonds sold appropriately weighted w ould be a better measure. See “ Production and Productivity in the Service Industries,” V ictor Fuchs, Educational Studies in Incom e and Wealth No. 39, N ational Bureau o f Econom ic Research, 1969. 5 put associated with that output. Rough estimates indi cate that the removal of this activity from the output account would reduce the productivity trend for the private economy about two-tenths of a percent per year over the last two decades. Industry level. The effects of certain measurement problems are greater at the individual industry level than at the national level where there is a tendency for errors and biases to offset each other. On the other hand, at the industry level, more flexibility is possible because the output measures are not part of an overall frame work (such as the national income and product accounts) which requires certain definitions and measures not nec essarily consistent with the desired productivity measures. Three major problems are encountered in developing measures of output from available data for industry productivity indexes. First, for many industries, the appropriate detailed product data are not available. Second, there is the well known quality change problem which results from the development of new products and the changing specifications of existing products. Third, appropriate weights are often not available for deriving the desired industry measure. Some of the presently available industry indexes are based on unit man-hour weights; others are based on unit value or price. The use of unit value or price weights is not a serious problem among commodities where labor consts or inputs are a high proportion of price. Labor Input With regard to labor input measures there are several data gaps in presently available measures. They relate to changes in the composition of labor (the quality), groups of the work force for which data are lacking or incomplete, the relationship of output to the time of research development and other workers whose activities are not directed to current production, and finally, the absence of adequate hours worked data on a comprehen sive basis. 1.Quality. As mentioned earlier, changes in the com position of labor input are adjusted in some measures by weighting industry man-hours with the average hourly earnings of workers in the industry. Insofar as earnings differentials reflect productivity differences among work ers, this measure captures changes in the quality of workers of different industries. However, this approach has severe limitations. Pay differentials between indus tries reflect many factors unrelated to productivity dif ferences, such as the degree of unionization or regional and geographical differentials. Moreover, the industry hourly earnings differential does not take into account occupational changes which occut within an industry. Estimates of the effects of shifts among major sectors— farming, manufacturing, mining, etc., show that shifts contributed about 0.3 percent per year of the output per man-hour growth over the last two decades. The shift in composition of the work force within man ufacturing between production and nonproduction work ers contributed 0.1 percent per year to the rate of in crease in private output per man-hour over the last two decades. In recent years this has been reduced consid erably to less than 0.05 percentage points. In view of the limited information on occupational detail, another approach (followed by Denison) to as certain the impact of shifts and changes in the work force has been to utilize information on changes in age, sex, and education. He estimates, for example, that the increase in education of the work force contributed 0.7 percentage points to the trend rate in output per man hour from 1950-62. For a longer period, 1929-57, he estimates the effect to be 0.9 percentage points per year. Another estimate of the contribution of education to the growth rate by Schwartzman6 provides a much lower figure— three-tenths of a percent per year for a roughly comparable period, 1929-63. The magnitude of these differences in this critical area suggests that there is need for further exploration of the interrelationship between education skills, training, earnings, and pro ductivity. 2. Gaps in coverage. Payroll data on employment and average weekly hours, which are the primary source of man-hours estimates, do not include the entire economy, but are limited to nonfarm wage and salary workers. These data do not cover farm workers, proprietors, un paid family workers, and domestics. Estimates for these sectors, for the most part, are taken from the labor force series (based on household surveys) which is not strictly comparable to the payroll series. Employment is a count of persons rather than jobs as in the payroll data, so that appropriate adjustments must be made. Average hours for supervisory worker? in nonmanu facturing industries are not available. The assumption is made that the average workweek for these workers is the same as for the nonsupervisory workers in each industry. Since 85 percent of all employees in nonmanufacturing industries are nonsupervisory workers, however, the effect of this imputation may be minimal. Sampling procedures also affect the man-hours esti mates. One week of each month is used to represent the entire month. If anything unusual, such as an unpaid holiday, strike, or bad weather, occurs during this period, the estimates will reflect these aberrations for the entire 6 David Schwartzm an, “ Education and the Quality of Labor, 1929-63,” American Economic Review, June 1968. quality of new capital should be incorporated in the capital stock measures or treated as a productivity in crease, Both interpretations have been used in produc tivity analysis. Total factor measures as currently presented are not consistent with their treatment of capital and labor. In general, labor refers to actual man-hours whereas capital refers to available stock not taking into account varying levels of utilization. month. On the other hand, fluctuations in employment between survey periods may not be reflected in the sample estimates. For example, short-term layoffs and plant shutdowns of 1 to 2 weeks between survey periods would not be reflected in the man-hour estimates for the month— leading to an overestimate of man-hours and an underestimate of productivity. 3. Hours paid versus hours worked. Because of lack of data, productivity measures for the most part refer to hours paid rather than the more desirable measure of hours worked. Surveys now are being conducted biannually for the nonfarm economy where information on leave hours and hours worked will soon provide a body of data which will fill some gaps in this area. Estimates of the effects of the difference between hours paid for but not worked on output per man-hour measures developed by the Bureau of labor Statistics indicate that the effect over the last 15 years has been about 0.1 percent per year for the nonfarm economy. The effects of course can vary substantially by sector and at the industry level. Within manufacturing, the annual surveys and censuses of manufactures do provide measures of what could be termed plant man-hours, and these are used in many industry productivity measures. AVAILABLE MEASURES OF PRODUCTIVITY National measures. Each quarter, the BLS prepares and publishes indexes of output per man-hour for the private economy and for the farm, nonfarm, and man ufacturing sectors. 7 For these measures, output per man-hour refers to the constant dollar value of goods and sendees produced in relation to the man-hours of all persons employed (including proprietors and unpaid family workers). Corresponding and comparable indexes of hourly compensation and unit labor costs are also developed. • The output measure for these productivity indexes is real gross national product originating in the private economy or the individual sectors. It comprises the pur chase of goods and services by consumers, gross priyate domestic investment (including the change in business inventors), net foreign investment, and government all deflated separately for changes in prices. Final goods and services are differentiated from inter mediate products in that they are usually not purchased for further fabrication or resale. In addition to purchases in the market, final goods and services also include some items provided but not actually purchased such as food furnished to employees, food produced and consumed on farms, and the rental value of owner occupied homes. Measures for the farm, nonfarm and manufacturing sectors are derived by subtracting the value of goods and services purchased by the sector from the constant dollar value of products and services leaving the sector.8 The labor input measures for these series are based largely on a monthly survey of establishment payroll records. Since this survey does not cover total employ ment in the private economy and because there are gaps in the hours information, it is necessary to use some sup plementary data to derive man-hours estimates for all persons engaged in producing the output of the private Total fa©t@r measures Total factor productivity measures relate output to the weighted sum of labor and capital and are therefore subject to the limitations of each of these data series. The problems of measuring output and labor input have been discussed. Capital measures, however, are probably the most difficult and complex measures to derive. They contain highly differentiated elements, and to express this differentiated stock in physical terms requires ad justing dollar values of assets for price change. For the most part, available data for prices of struc tures are based primarily on cost information. As men tioned earlier, they do not take into account savings in utilization of materials and other inputs. Furthermore, the problems of obtaining representative prices for equipment which is highly differentiated severely affects the adequacy of the price measures used in capital measurement. In addition, technical advances are often built into capital so that a piece of equipment produced in an earlier period may not be as efficient as one currently produced. In constructing price indexes, some of these technical improvements may be incorporated as quality changes, but adjusting for quality is often difficult. There is some question as to whether improvements in the 7 Productivity, Wages and Prices, quarterly release issued by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. 8 This actual measures are developed according to a variety of approaches because of data limitations. However, all are attempts to approximate this concept. 7 economy. Various sources are utilized and data from them are adjusted for consistency with the establishment man-hours. The establishment man-hours are based on an hours paid rather than an hours worked concept. That is, the estimates include paid holidays, vacations, sick leave and other time off paid for by the employer in addition to actual hours worked. Another set of labor productivity indexes is developed based on man-hours obtained from a monthly survey of the noninstitutional civilian population. This survey of households provides information on the labor force, employment, unemployment as well as man-hours. The man-hours estimates for the labor force series are based on an hours worked concept, i.e., hours spent at the establishment, thus excluding vacation and sick leave but including such things as rest periods and standby time. Since compensation data are derived primarily from establishment payroll records, when relating labor pro ductivity measures to hourly compensation, the appro priate series is the one based on establishment man-hours. On the other hand, when examining the relationship between productivity changes and displacement of work ers, since the employment and unemployment measures are based on the household survey, the more consistent output per man-hour measure is the one based on labor force data. In addition to the current indexes of output per man hour published by .the BLS, John Kendrick of the National Bureau of Economic Research has published indexes of output per man-hour for the private economy and major sectors (as well as total factor productivity) which include a series that makes adjustments for changes in the composition of man-hours.9 Using average hourly earnings for weighting man-hours at the industry level he derives an index of output per weighted man-hour. The basic man-hour data for this series are generally the same as those for the establishment series and the weights are also derived from BLS average hourly earnings data. These indexes presently cover the period 1887 to 1966. Edward Denison of the Brookings Institution has published measures of output per labor input in the form of growth rates for selected periods, the most recent being 1950-62.10 These measures also take into account changes in the quality of labor; however, the procedure differs from Kendrick’s. Adjustment based on age, sex, education, and other changes in the labor force are applied to basic employment and man-hours measures to derive labor input reflecting changes in quality. These measures are available only at the national level. Industry measures. In addition to the indexes for the private economy and major sectors, the BLS publishes annually indexes of output per man-hour for selected industries.11 At the present time, measures for about 40 manufacturing and nonmanufacturing industries such as steel, motor vehicles, railroad transportation, coal, etc., are prepared. The output measures for these indexes are developed by combining the data on quantities of commodities or services within the industry with fixed period weights. As mentioned earlier, man-hour weights would be pre ferred for developing these measures and insofar as pos sible these are used. However, where such information is not available, other weights such as unit labor costs, or unit value (price) are used. These substitutions are introduced on the assumption that unit values are good commodities in an industry. In addition, for some industries where it is not pos sible to obtain any quantity information, indexes of deflated value of output are developed. For these industry measures current dollar value estimates are divided by indexes of price change for the industry to derive a real output measuer. The adequacy of these measures is dependent on the quality of the price measure. The labor input data for these measures are estab lishment man-hours. As in the aggregate measures, they are derived from payroll records and for the most part are based on an hours paid concept. For manufacturing industries, however, additional man-hours information is available in terms of hours at the plant. These data which theoretically exclude vacation, holdiays, and such leave hours are closer in concept to an hours worked measure. Unfortunately, the information on plant man hours is usually not as current as that from other sources on establishment man-hours. Capital productivity Measures of output per unit of capital are not avail able on a current basis. Historical measures have been developed by a number of researchers. Separate estimates of capital stock and hence meas ures of capital productivity are available for the private economy from sources such as the National Industrial Conference Board, National Bureau of Economic Re search, and many economists doing research in pro duction analysis, in addition, the Office of Business Economics prepares 12 different capital series depending on alternative options for service lives, depreciation, and 9 John W. Kendrick, P roductivity Trends in the United States, Princeton University Press, 1961. 10 Edward F. Denison, op. cit. 11 Indexes o f O utput per Man-Hour, Selected Industries, 1939 and 1947-70 (BLS Bulletin 1692). ices and for selected industries within these major groups. Labor input is measured in man-hours and adjusted for quality change using industrial hourly earnings. Capital includes the net stock of structure, plant equip ment, inventories, working capital and land. The capital measures do not include quality inprovements which can occur because of technical advance. The capital and labor input are added together with factor prices as weights. The base period for the weights was changed periodically to reflect economic conditions of the vari ous subperiods under analysis. The combined factor measure developed by Edward Denison relates net domestic product (excluding depre ciation) to weighted sum of capital and labor. The weights are the base period share of dollar output of each of these inputs. He also periodically shifted the base period for the factor shares to reflect current economic conditions. Denison’s analysis covers the total economy for the 1919-62 period, and he is currently updating his work. His labor input is employment adjusted for quality change using relative earnings for selected age-sexeducation groups. He also adjusts the labor input for intensity of effort as reflected in varying lengths of the workweek. His assumption is that as the workweek de clines productivity improves because the worker is less fatigued and can work more diligently. adjustment for price change. These estimates are con structed within the framework of the national accounts and are consistent with output measures used for labor productivity in the private economy. However, the vari ation among these series gives different results for the growth of capital productivity. The OBE estimates are prepared annually for the private economy, farm, manufacturing, nonfarm, and nonmanufacturing. They include equipment and nonresidential structures, but exclude such items as housing, motels, and hotels. These capital stock series are developed using the perpetual inventory method. That is, each new piece of equipment or structure is added into the stock estimates and remains there until retired from use. Retirements of assets are based on mean useful service lives published in the Internal Revenue Services Bulletin of Service Lives of Assets. Because the latter are believed to over state asset lives, OBE prepares estimates of capital series either based on Bulletin F or 85 percent of Bulletin F service lives. Net capital measures are derived using either straight line or double declining balance depreciation. Most other capital series are developed in a manner similar to the OBE measures with other variations on mean service lives and methods of depreciating assets. C@mfeimi©d factor input productivity The second group of productivity measures— those which relate output to several factors— involve the weighting together of the quantities of the separate factors. For the most part, these measures have been limited to output per unit of capital and labor combined. Just as the separate components of an output index must be combined with appropriate weights, the separate components of the input measure also must be appro priately weighted together. Capital and labor can be aggregated using their unit costs (e.g., wages, rate of re turns of capital) in a base year as weights. These weights can also be viewed as the proportion of current dollar output earned by each input (factor share) in a base period. Two sources of combined factor input or total factor productivity measures exist— the work done by John Kendrick for the National Bureau of Economic Research and that by Edward Denison in his work on sources of growth. Kendrick provided annual measures for the period 1889 to 1957, and more recent measures, 1957-69, will be available early in 1972. Estimates cover the private economy and are based on GNP output measures. Sep arate measures were made for farm, manufacturing, trade, finance, transportation, public utilities, and serv RECOMMENDATIONS Within the general constraints imposed on all users of economic data, productivity measures for the total priv ate and private nonfarm economics and for selected major sectors (manufacturing, mining, trade, transporta tion, communication, and public utilities) are reliable and useful for economic analysis. Conversely, produc tivity measures for construction and service-type indus tries are not reliable measures for identifying either the magnitude or direction of change in productivity for the reasons outlined above. To improve these measures, ad ditional information must be developed in two areas— the data base from which output, input, and price statistics are compiled, and the conceptual base upon which the output and price data are developed. Additional pries oraformati©?! More and better price information in the service and construction industries is of prime urgency. In construc tion, work is currently underway by the Census Bureau to develop price measures in order to improve the meas ures of the real volume of residential construction put in place. Additional research is also necessary for nonresidential construction. In the service sector, more adequate 9 and extensive price information on personal services is needed as well as the expansion o f wholesale prices to include business services. The BLS at the present time is trying to develop an index of the general price level. The development o f this index will materially assist produc tivity measurement because it will require the collection of a wider range o f service prices. More work is also needed in collecting data on durable equipment (such as heavy machinery and aircraft) which is highly differentiated and often custom-made. Another recommendation is to have timely (quarterly and annually) estimates on the imputed rental value of owner occupied housing so that it may be excluded from the output estimate and not bias productivity meas urement. and man-hours. Some research is being carried out using occupational and wage data to account for some changes in labor quality, but it is necessary to develop a more integrated system for collection than in currently in effect. Capital information is also needed to make a more com plete analysis o f factors affecting productivity growth. Of paramount importance are better data on changes in the quality of capital equipment and the length of service lives. The concepts used to define output need to be changed to conform to a productivity framework. This is particu larly true of government and households and institutions where actual output definitions are needed rather than merely relying on an employment measure. Financial intermediaries also present definitional prob lems. For example, banking output is currently measured as liquidity. If the output reflected changes in the num ber o f transactions weighted by some value measures, it would be more compatible with the inputs and provide a means for making a better productivity measure. These recommendations will not solve all o f the prob lems of productivity measurement. However, they will certainly improve the output and related input measures and thereby make productivity a more viable tool for economic analysis. Better man-hour and capital data Input data also need to be improved. Most important to productivity measurement would be better estimates for certain components of labor input. This would entail estimating supervisory hours in nonmanufacturing and expanding employment sampling coverage so that re sultant data refer to the entire month rather than 1 week. Adjustment for changes in labor quality calls for more detailed information on occupational wages 10 is the variety of productivity concepts and meas urem ents and thus the need to be explicit. The other is the dependence of concept on purpose: The concept m ust be appropriate to the use to which the productivity m easurement is put. Which Productivity? Perspective ®m a Current Question Variety off Concepts and M easurem ents To illustrate the variety of concepts and meas urem ents attached to the word “productivity,” let us ask an apparently specific question and see some of the answers th a t can be given to it. The question: W hat has been the average rate of growth in the N ation’s productivity over the period 1947-57? The answers, taken from a study by the National Bureau of Economic Re search,*123are as follows: (1) 3.4 percent per annum, if we measure the rate of growth by the average annual increase in real gross national product per unweighted man-hour, in the private economy; (2) 3.1 percent per annum, if we shift from product per unweighted to product per weighted m an hour, otherwise keeping everything else the same; (3) 2.3 percent, if we shift further to product per weighted unit of man-hours and tangible capital combined, still keeping everything else the same; and (4) about 2.0 percent, if we measure the rate for the entire economy, including government—• which requires even bolder estimation than do the preceding measures. This is not an exhaustive list of all the “answers” even from this single source; and, of course, in clusion of the concepts and calculations of other statisticians would add to the variety. B ut enough has been cited to m ake the point: W ithout specification of its content, the word “produc tiv ity ”—even the phrase “national productivity”— can mean more than one thing. In concept, productivity is always a ratio of output to input, and a productivity index is always the ratio for one period (or place) relative to the corresponding ratio for another period (or S o lo m o n F a b r ic a n t * “ W h e n I u s e a w o r d ,” H um pty D um pty could say to Alice in the W onderland spun out of Lewis Carroll’s dreams, “it means just w hat I choose it to m ean—neither more nor less.” In the every day world in which we have to live, we cannot afford this individual freedom of choice. Yet everyone seems to interpret the word “produc tiv ity ” in the light of his own experience and in terests, and because these vary, productivity means different things to different people and they use the word differently. Confusion results. Only by discussion and explicit definition can the confusion be cleared up or avoided. The same objective—to discuss and clarify the meaning of productivity—brought people together in 1946 a t the first productivity conference spon sored by the Bureau of Labor Statistics and the Bureau of the B udget.1 Since 1946, much has been done by the BLS and others to deepen the public’s understanding of productivity and pro ductivity change. B ut education is a perennial task. The rapid growth of Russia and other countries, widespread concern over inflation and the international balance of payments, the use of improvement factors in wage negotiations and contracts—these events since 1946 have stim ulated greater interest in the rate and process of produc tivity change and thus in the meaning and meas urem ent of productivity. The subject of productivity is large; therefore, I shall direct attention to two main points. One •Director of Research, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., and Professor of Economics, N ew York University. T his article is based on a paper presented b y Dr. Fabricant at discussions on productivity held by the Bureau of Labor Statistics in 1960. 1Summary of Proceedings of Conference on Productivity, October S8-S9,1946 (BLS Bulletin 913, 1947). 3 John W. Kendrick, Productivity Trends in the United Stales (Princeton, N .J., Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., 1961), ch. 3 and app. A. Reprinted from the M onthly Labor Review, June 1962. 1! place). B ut output can be defined broadly to cover the N ation as a whole, for example, or narrowly to cover a single industry. In p u t can refer to the simple sum of all man-hours worked, or to the weighted sum of man-hours (in which an hour put in by a skilled worker is counted as more than the hour put in by an unskilled worker), or to the weighted sum of the hours served by both labor and capital goods. B ut modifying the noun “productivity” by appropriate adjectives and defining our terms, at least at the outset of each discussion, is only p art of w hat needs to be done. Since produc tiv ity concepts and measurements vary, we m ust also choose among them before starting discussion. The choice depends on the purpose, for not every productivity concept is appropriate to every purpose. Let us consider two uses of productivity con cepts and measurements—in the analysis of output change and in wage determ ination or analysis. These are distinct purposes and require quite different concepts of productivity. Analysis off Output Change As a step in its analysis, output change m ay be viewed as resulting from change in each of two components. One is change in input, th a t is, the total quantity of resources used to turn out the product. The other is change in productivity, in the sense of change in the efficiency w ith which the resources are used to turn out the product—■ a change which results from change in technology, economic organization, and the other deter m inants of economic efficiency. M easurement of these components provides information on the quantitative contribution—the im portance—of each. The combination of both kinds of change— in input and in productivity—equals the change in output. In this analysis of output, the appropriate input is not the input of some of the resources used, b u t of all resources used. I t is total input. The appropriate productivity is output per unit of to tal input. In effect, productivity is defined and m easured in this way in order to make— O u tp u t= T o ta l I n p u tX To^ " ~ 12 Each term stands for an index number, in relative form, and all three index numbers are on the sam e base. Change in efficiency in the use of resources cannot be determined by comparing change in output with change in a limited class of inputs. Therefore, output relative to a particular class of inputs—for example, labor alone or capital alone— would be inappropriate for the present purpose. O utput per unit of plant and equipment m ay fall, for example, yet efficiency m ay rise if savings of labor’s services per unit of product exceed the increase in the services of capital per unit of product. Similarly, an increase in output per man-hour m ay overstate the rise in efficiency if some of the laborsavings result from substitution of labor by capital. I t is informative, of course, to see how each class of inputs is changing in rela tion of output. The index of output per unit of total input can, therefore, profitably be supple m ented with the “partial” indexes of output per unit of labor input and of output per unit of capital input. B ut neither of these partial indexes is a very good substitute, in measuring efficiency, for the index th a t combines them. If it is the N ation’s total output th a t is being analyzed, the productivity index refers to national productivity—th a t is, real national product per unit of labor and capital used in the entire economy. If it is an industry’s output th a t is being analyzed, the productivity index refers to the industry’s productivity—its physical product relative to the labor and capital used by the industry.3 Wage Beterminatiom or Analysis If the use of the productivity measure is in wage analysis, negotiation, or determination, the appropriate productivity concept is not ou tp u t 8 The Industry’s volume of production, it is assumed, is measured by its “net output.” (N et output is roughly equivalent to deflated value added, with value added as defined in the Census of Manufactures.) The industry’s production may also be measured by “gross output,” and most frequently is so measured. (Gross output is equivalent to deflated value of product, with value of product equal to value added plus materials consumed.) In the latter case, the appropriate total input is labor plus capital plus materials, and efficiency is measured by gross output per unit of labor, capital, and materials combined. The two productivity measures w ill seldom be equal. The second measure has some advantages over the first for measuring an industry’s overall effi ciency. The important point, however, is the need to be aware of the differ ence between the two and to avoid treating them as comparable. per unit of total input. Instead, it is output per m an-hour and, particularly, output per weighted man-hour. (The wage index is presumed to be adjusted to exclude the effects of interindustry and intraindustry shifts in the relative importance of different classes of labor. If, as is usually the case, wages are measured in such a way as to reflect these shifts, the appropriate productivity concept is o u tput per unweighted man-hour.) F urther, the appropriate concept is output per weighted man-hour in the economy a t large, whatever sector or industry happens to be under consideration. The reason for choosing output per m an-hour rather than output per unit of total resources is not th a t the economy’s efficiency is unim portant in the determination of wages. I t is very impor tant. B u t it is also insufficient. Wage levels are also determined by other factors. O utstanding among these is the scarcity of labor relative to capital in the economy a t large. O utput per weighted m an-hour combines both im portant factors, efficiency and labor scarcity. T h at is, the efficiency of the economy is measured by national product divided by weighted m an-hours plus capital. The relative scarcity of labor is measured by weighted capital divided by weighted m an hours, or (more conveniently in the present context) by weighted man-hours plus capital divided by weighted man-hours. A combination of the two factors, obtained by m ultiplying them, yields”national product per weighted m an-hour:4* they are far less relevant than national efficiency and capital per worker in the economy as a whole. They belong among the “qualifications” th a t m ust always be attached to any short list of wage factors, no m atter how im portant, in order to ex plain, or perhaps justify, a discrepancy between change in wages and change in national output per man-hour. Before turning to these qualifications, a bit more needs to be said about the rationale of the connection between national o utput per m an-hour and wages. Tie Between National Output Per M an-Hour and Wages. Technological advance and the other sources of rising national efficiency tend to cause all incomes, labor and property alike, to rise. An increase in national capital per worker tends to cause wages generally to rise more rapidly than returns per unit of capital. B ut it does not necessarily follow th a t the rise in wages m ust exactly equal, and m ay not exceed or fall short of, the combined rise in efficiency and labor scarcity. N or does it necessarily follow, as parallelism between wages and output per m an-hour implies, th at the share of aggregate wages in national income (ignoring some differences between nation al product and national income) is constant, or— it is essentially the same thing—th a t wage cost per unit of product in the economy as a whole is constant. For these to follow, certain conditions m ust hold. These conditions are: (1) Com petition prevails in the m arkets for commodities, labor, and capital, so th a t increased efficiency and greater capital investm ent are free to bring appropriate increases in wages.6 (2) The technical possibilities of sub stituting capital for labor are such th a t a change in capital per m an-hour results in an equal change in the ratio of wages to the rate of return on capital, or—in terms of the measures we are using—a given percentage change in the ratio of total input to weighted man-hours brings an exactly equal percentage change in wages. (3) The two fac tors—efficiency and labor scarcity—are inde pendent of one another, so th a t m ultiplying their indexes together gives an economically (not merely m athem atically) correct combination of them . For example, technological change does not alter the relative scarcities and thus the Weighted M an-H ours N ational Product . ._____ + Capital_____ W eighted M a n -H o u rs* Weighted M an-H ours + Capital N ational Product W eighted M an-H ours The reason for choosing national o utput per m an-hour even when the wage in a sector of the economy is under consideration is not because the efficiency and the capital per worker of the sector are irrelevant. They are relevant. In the long run, however, and as a rule even in the short run, 4If the wage index in question is not adjusted to exclude interindustry and intraindustry shifts, there is need to include a third factor—the quality of labor. This factor is measured by weighted man-hours divided by un weighted man-hours. The combination of all three factors is national prod uct per unweighted man-hour. 4This means that national product per man-hour provides the competitive norm by which to judge actual wage behavior or wage proposals in non competitive situations. 13 tions th a t would yield the same outcome) are, on the whole, not too wide of the mark, it also supports the case for dwelling on the qualifications. Indeed, even the hastiest backward glance re minds us th at up to this point our attention has been confined to real w;ages. In a regime of rising (or falling) prices, another m ajor factor affecting wages is the price trend—and when the price level is moving rapidly,, this can be the predomi nant factor.8 Explicit account can be taken of it by combining the price index with the other factors considered. This would yield an index of value (not volume) of national output per m an hour, and this also m ight be called a productivity index. B ut there seems to be little advantage in doing so. relative prices of labor and capital. These con ditions—or assumptions, for th a t is w hat they are—need to be brought out into the open if the reasoning back of the tie between output per m an-hour and wages is to be understood.6 Since m any people have become accustomed to accepting output per m an-hour as the productivity measure appropriate to wage discussion, the path we have followed in reaching it m ay strike them as rather tortuous. W hy is it not sufficient to say, as has often been said, th a t output per m an-hour is appropriate because it keeps constant the labor share in national income and the cost of labor per unit of product? I t is insufficient if we are not told w hat economic forces and w hat techno logical and other characteristics of the economy keep, or tend to keep, the labor share and unit labor costs constant. I t is necessary to say at least w hat has been said above. Laying bare some of the assumptions underlying the use of output per m an-hour in wage discussion raises questions about their validity and the reservations th a t need to be attached to this use. So does the historical record. Necessary Qualifications. History, and economic theory as well, remind us also of other things th a t m ay not be overlooked. I can discuss these here only briefly. First, changes in technology, in tangible capital per worker, in the quality of labor, and even in the cost of living take time to work out their effects in the economy and make their im pact oil wages. This is true even in a competitive economy and even with such allowance as needs to be m ade for the influence of expectations on the lags. N ot each industry in the economy, nor the economy Historical Record. The long-term record does suggest something close to parallelism between wages in various industries and national output per man-hour, and, therefore, a greater rise in wages generally than in national output per unit of total input.7 However, relative trends over shorter periods are not quite the same as over the long period for which the record is available. Further, while wages in different industries have moved up together, there have been differences in the rates of increase. From one point of view the similarities are more striking than the differences, b u t the latter are not negligible. This means th a t the wages of some industries have risen significantly more, and of others, less rapidly than national output per man-hour, in the longer as well as the shorter period. Also, the differences do not seem closely correlated w ith such clues as there are to the presence of monopoly, Even if the conditions specified above hold for the "average in dustry” and the "average period,” there is little reason to suppose th a t they hold for every industry in every period. While the historical record suggests th a t the assumptions noted (or alternative sets of assump 8 In the technical language of economics, the conditions are: (1) competi tion, so that the wage is equal to the marginal product of labor; (2) a produc tion function of such shape that the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital is unity, so that a given percentage rise in the ratio of capital to labor is accompanied by an exactly equal percentage decline in the marginal rate of substitution of capital for labor; (3) neutrality of change in efficiency. (In most formal mathematical presentations of these conditions, use is made of the weighted geometric mean of inputs, rather than the weighted arith metic mean that is implied in the text. According to available calculations, the difference between the two means is slight.) 7 Over the period 1889-1957, and for the private domestic economy as a whole, the average annual percentage rates of change are as follows: Real gross national product per weighted unit of man-hours and tangible capital_____________ ______ - ............ ................................... 1.7 Weighted man-hours and real tangible capital (total input) per weighted man-hour------- ------------------------------------------ . ----------------3 Real gross national product per weighted man-hour........................ .. 2.0 Weighted man-hours per unweighted man-hour.......................................... 3 Real gross national product per unweighted man-hour.................. 2.3 These figures may be compared with: Real hourly earnings, all workers (including proprietors and family workers)----- ------------ ---------------------------------------------------------2.4 Real hourly earnings, wage earners in manufacturing.................... 2.3 Because the hourly earnings indexes are unadjusted for the shifts noted above, the productivity index comparable with the wage indexes is real gross national product per unweighted man-hour. The approximate character of the estimates must be kept in mind; see m y Basic Facts on Productivity Change (N ew York, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., 1959), Occasional Paper No. 63, pp. 29-37. 8 Whether and what the “ wage-push” contributes to inflation cannot be considered here. 14 as a whole, is ever in full equilibrium either in the present or in the base period with which the present is compared. Consider, for example, an industry in which output per man-hour has begun to rise more rapidly than in the Nation at large. More often than not, its output will respond by rising more rapidly than national product, and its prices, by falling relative to the general price level. If the rise in its output is at a rate sufficient to cause its demand for labor to grow relatively, wages in the industry will tend to be higher than in other industries, th a t is, its wages will tend to rise more rapidly than national output per man-hour. If its output does not expand rapidly enough, labor demand will decline relatively, and the industry’s wages will tend to be lower than in other indus tries, th a t is, its wages will tend to rise less rapidly than national output per man-hour. W ith appro priate changes, much the same qualification m ust be made for industries in which capital per worker is rising more or less rapidly than in the economy a t large. Second, while the quality of labor has generally risen as skills have improved and education has spread, the rate of increase has varied among industries and occupations. This, too, will affect the relation between a particular wage and national output per man-hour. So, also, will relative changes in the “noneconomic” advantages and disadvantages attached to a job and changes in the values p u t on them. Third, with governm ent—and the taxes govern m ent levies, the transfers it makes, and the services it renders—economically so much more im portant now than in earlier periods, changes in the struc ture and level of taxes and of government expendi tures also significantly affect, at least in the long run, the relation between wages and national out p u t per man-hour. In addition, the difficulties of m easuring wages and productivity are aggravated. This explains the prevailing custom of using indexes for the “private economy” to represent national productivity. And fourth, even for a given concept, produc tivity m easurem ents m ay differ because sources, of data differ and because of differences in the ways in which gaps in the data are filled. The difference between Census labor force data and 15 BLS establishment data on m an-hours provides an example. Further, the trend in productivity, even with the concept and source of data speci fied, depends on the particular period covered, for productivity does not advance evenly from one year to another. For example, if the period chosen begins with a trough and ends with a peak in business, the rate of increase in productivity will almost always be higher than if the period begins and ends in the same business cycle phase. I m ust entirely pass over other troublesome points th a t arise when we ask the question, “Which productivity?” These include the extent to which labor and tangible capital adequately ac count for total input; the m easurem ent of tangible capital input and of labor quality; the treatm ent of unemployed resources; the term s of foreign trade, which affect the N ation’s productivity as well as its productivity m easures; and the relative merits of different formulas for particular purposes, in which the choice between “base” and “given” years in selecting weights is only one element. M ost of these and the other points raised deserve more intensive study than has yet been given to them. I t should be evident by now, however, th a t the assumptions involved in applying national output per m an-hour in wage negotiation, determ ination, or study are m any, and th a t they do not hold fully in every period and in every situation. Summary. The index of national ou tp u t per m an-hour is highly useful because it summarizes the m ost im portant general factors th a t determine changes in wages in a competitive society. I t does not cover all the relevant factors, it is tru e ; there fore, deviations of wages from national output per m an-hour m ay be expected to crop up every where. B u t because it does cover the m ost im portant general factors, in the absence of monopoly large deviations should be infrequent. The bigger the deviation, the more reason there m ust be to question and inquire into it. However, to under stand the difference between a particular wage movement or proposal and the current trend of national output per m an-hour, and to judge it, requires more than the index of output per m anhour. Fart II. Produetiwity Tr®nds °m the iy s in s s s Economy Indexes of compensation per hour measure the hourly cost to employers of wages and salaries, as well as sup plemental payments, which include employers’ con tributions to social security, unemployment insurance taxes, and payments for private health insurance and pension plans. Measures of real compensation per hour reflect the adjustment of hourly compensation for changes in the Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers (CPI-U). Unit labor cost measures the cost of labor input re quired to produce one unit of output and is derived by dividing compensation in current dollars by output in constant dollars. Unit nonlabor payments measure the cost of nonlabor items such as depreciation, rent, in terest, and indirect business taxes, in addition to cor porate profit and profit-type income of proprietorships and partnerships. This section examines the b l s measures of output per hour of all persons engaged in production and of multifactor productivity for the business economy. Developments in output per hour and in multifactor productivity in the business sector over the last three decades are outlined. The slowdown in the rate of pro ductivity improvement during the 1970’s is also ex plored. Description of Measures for the Business Economy1 Productivity and related measures are prepared for the following sectors of the U.S. economy: Quarterly and annual measures Business sector Nonfarm business sector Nonfinancial corporations Manufacturing, total, durable, nondurable Earlier this year, the Bureau began a program of multifactor productivity measurement to supplement the labor productivity measures and to provide addi tional insights into productivity growth and economic changes. This program is an outgrowth of analytic studies undertaken by the Bureau investigating some of the factors contributing to productivity growth.3 The multifactor productivity measures for the business and nonfarm business sectors are based upon capital and labor inputs. In aggregate sectors, productivity changes through time reflect movements within the various component industries as well as shifts in the relative importance of each of the industries. For example, changes in labor productivity and multifactor productivity are influenced by the relative shift of inputs (labor and capital) from low- to high-productivity industries and by productivity changes in the component sector. Within industries, other shifts occur which are not accounted for ade- Annual measures only Agriculture Mining Transportation Communications Utilities Wholesale and retail trade Finance, insurance, and real estate Government enterprises The Bureau’s output per hour measures are constructed as the ratio between gross domestic product— GDP— originating in the private business economy and its subsectors, and the corresponding hours of all persons engaged in each sector.2 The changes through time in these major indexes reflect efficiency in the use of labor, and indirectly, the effect of other input factors in the domestic production of goods and services. The changes in the productivity and related measures through the business cycle typically show patterns which differ substantially from those found in long-term move ments,- and, therefore, are the objects of special analytic studies. Labor input measures are based primarily on BLS establishment payroll data on employment and hours and reflect hours at work and paid time off for vaca tions, holidays, and sick leave as well. A survey has been introduced to develop a set of labor input measures bas ed on hours at work and will be used to extend the pres ent series. 1 A more detailed discussion of bls measures of productivity and related variables, such as compensation per hour, unit labor costs, output, etc., may be found in the b l s H an d b o o k o f M ethods, Bulletin 2134-1, December 1982. 2 Gross domestic product is gross national product less the net return on foreign investments. Net return on foreign investments is considered as originating in the “ rest-of-world” sector. 3 J.R. Norsworthy, Michael Harper, and Kent Kunze, “The Slowdown in Productivity Growth: Analysis of Some Contributing Factors.” See p. 30 of this reader. 16 series o f b l s news releases: “ Productivity and Costs in the Business Sector,” and “ Productivity and Costs in Nonfinancial C orporations.” In addition, quarterly and annual analyses are published regularly in the Monthly Labor Review. Historical indexes o f these and related data are available on request, as are detailed descrip tions o f data sources and computational procedures. Indexes o f output per hour and related cost data are published monthly in Employment and Earnings and the M onthly Labor Review, and in each edition o f the quately— changes in income and tastes, for example, may contribute to shifts in consumption patterns to higher quality goods, or to services rather than goods. Short-term movements in productivity and unit labor costs often result from cyclical variation in output; this tends to distort the long-term relationship between out put and labor input, as noted below, or output and multifactor input. A number o f studies are being con ducted to separate cyclical from long-term productivity movements. Indexes o f output per hour, compensation per hour, and related cost data are published quarterly in two Handbook o f Labor Statistics. 17 Mulfifactor Productivity in the Private Business Economy Since 1948 P r o d u c t i v i t y , a s m e a s u r e d b y o u t p u t p e r u n i t o f c o m b in e d l a b o r an d c a p i t a l i n p u t s — m u l t i f a c t o r p r o d u c t i v i t y — r o s e a n a v e r a g e o f 1 . 5 p e r c e n t p e r y e a r fr o m 1 9 4 8 t o 1 9 8 1 i n t h e p r i v a t e b u s i n e s s s e c t o r , a c c o r d i n g t o a new m e a s u r e i n t r o d u c e d t o d a y b y t h e B u r e a u o f L a b o r S t a t i s t i c s o f t h e U .S . D e p a r tm e n t o f L abor. T h i s new s e r i e s sh o w s t h e c h a n g e s i n t h e am ount o f l a b o r an d c a p i t a l u s e d i n p r o d u c tio n ( t a b l e A ) . As s u c h i t r e f l e c t s t h e j o i n t e f f e c t o f many i n f l u e n c e s , in c lu d in g ch a n g es in te c h n o lo g y , th e l e v e l o f o u tp u t, u t i l i z a t i o n o f c a p a c it y , t h e o r g a n iz a t io n o f p r o d u c t io n , m a n a g e r ia l s k i l l s , a s w e l l a s c h a n g e s i n th e c h a r a c t e r i s t i c s and e f f o r t s o f th e w o r k fo r c e . T he t r a d i t i o n a l p r o d u c t i v i t y s e r i e s — o u t p u t p e r h o u r o f a l l p e r s o n s — r e f l e c t s t h e s e i n f l u e n c e s a n d a l s o t h e im p a c t o f c h a n g e s i n c a p i t a l p e r u n i t o f l a b o r in p u t. T he n ew m e a s u r e , t h e r e f o r e , s u p p le m e n t s t h e e x i s t i n g m e a s u r e b y p r o v i d i n g a b a s i s f o r m e a s u r in g t h a t i m p a c t . O ver t h e 1 9 4 8 - 8 1 p e r i o d , w h en m u l t i f a c t o r p r o d u c t i v i t y i n c r e a s e d 1 .5 p e r c e n t p e r y e a r , th e t r a d i t i o n a l p r o d u c t iv it y m easu re o f o u tp u t p er h our r o s e 2 .4 p e r c e n t per y e a r . T h e r e f o r e , th e g r o w th i n c a p i t a l p e r h ou r c o n t r ib u t e d 0 .9 p e r c e n ta g e p o in t t o t h e g r o w th i n o u tp u t p e r h ou r ( t a b l e B ) . The g r o w t h i n m u l t i f a c t o r p r o d u c t i v i t y sh o w ed tw o d i s t i n c t p a t t e r n s : 2 . 0 p e r c e n t p e r y e a r fr o m 1 9 4 8 t o 1 9 7 3 , b u t o n l y 0 . 1 p e r c e n t p e r y e a r fr o m 1 9 7 3 t o 1 9 8 1 . T h i s slo w d o w n r e f l e c t e d a f a l l o f f i n o u t p u t g r o w t h , c o u p le d w i t h a f a s t e r g r o w th o f c o m b in e d i n p u t s o f l a b o r a n d c a p i t a l . T he a c c e l e r a t e d i n c r e a s e i n i n p u t s o f la b o r and c a p i t a l a f t e r 1 973 w as du e t o t h e f a s t e r in c r e a s e i n th e h o u r s o f a l l p e r s o n s s i n c e t h e a n n u a l r a t e o f g r o w th o f c a p i t a l w as s lo w e r a f t e r 1 9 7 3 . Reprinted from BLS news release USDL 83-153, April 6, 1983. 18 T a b le A . A v e r a g e a n n u a l r a t e s o f g r o w th i n p r o d u c t i v i t y i n d e x e s and r e l a t e d m e a s u r e s b y m a jo r s e c t o r , 1948 t o 1981 1 / P r iv a te b u s in e s s M ea su r e P r o d u c tiv ity in d e x e s : O u tp u t p e r h o u r o f a l l p e r s o n s ^ 0 • Q. « • • . O u tp u t p e r u n i t o f c a p ita l s e r v ic e s . , 0 0 M u ltifa c to r p r o d u c tiv ity 3 / • • • . • O u tp u t O o o e o 0 o o G o e o o o e e e e In p u ts s H o u rs o f a l l p e r s o n s 00 C a p ita l s e r v i c e s , o o 0e C om bined l a b o r and c a p it a l in p u ts 4 / . . * g 1/ 2/ 3/ 4/ P r iv a te n o n fa r m b u s i n e s s 2/ 2/ 19481981 1948“ 1973 19731981 19481981 19481973 19731981 2 04 3.0 0.8 2.0 2.5 0.6 -0.1 0.2 -1.0 -0.1 0.2 1.5 2.0 0 . 1 1.3 3 .3 3 .7 2 .2 0o9 3 .5 0 .7 3 .6 1.8 1.7 M a n u fa c tu r in g 19481981 194819 7 3 19731981 2.6 2.9 1.5 “ 1.1 -0.2 0.6 -2.6 1.7 0.0 1.8 2.2 0.4 3 .4 3 .9 2 .1 3 .3 4 .0 1 .2 1 .4 3 .2 1 .4 3 .6 1 .3 3 .6 1 .5 3 .3 0 .7 3 .6 1 .1 3 .5 -0.2 4 .0 2.0 2.1 2.1 2.1 1.6 1.8 0.9 A v e r a g e a n n u a l r a t e s b a s e d o n com pound r a t e fo r m u la e E x c lu d e s g o v e r n m e n t e n t e r p r i s e s . O u tp u t p e r u n i t o f c o m b in e d l a b o r and c a p i t a l i n p u t e H o u rs o f a l l p e r s o n s c o m b in e d w i t h c a p i t a l s e r v i c e i n p u t s i n d e x w e ig h t e d by la b o r and c a p i t a l s h a r e s . 19 T a b le B . A v era g e a n n u a l r a t e s o f g r o w th i n o u tp u t p e r h ou r o f a l l p e r s o n s , th e c o n t r i b u t i o n o f c a p i t a l s e r v i c e s p e r h o u r , and m u l t i f a c t o r p r o d u c t i v i t y , b y m a jo r s e c t o r , 1948 t o 1981 _1/ M e a su r e 19481981 (1 ) 19481973 (2 ) 19731981 (3 ) 2 .4 3 .0 0 .8 -2.2 0 .9 1 .0 0 .7 -0.3 1 .5 2 .0 0 .1 -1.9 2 .0 2 .5 0 .6 -1.9 0 .7 0 .8 0 .6 -0.2 1 .3 1 .7 0 .0 -1.7 2 .6 2 .9 1 .5 -1.4 0 .8 0 .7 1 .1 0 .4 1 .8 2 .2 0 .4 -1.8 S lo w down (4 ) (Col.2 - C o l . 3) P r iv a te b u s in e s s 2 / O u tp u t p e r h o u r o f a l l p e r s o n s M in u s : E q u a ls : C o n tr ib u tio n o f c a p i t a l s e r v ic e s per hour 3 / M u ltifa c to r p r o d u c tiv ity P r i v a t e n o n fa r m b u s i n e s s 4/ 2/ O u tp u t p e r h o u r o f a l l p e r s o n s M in u s: E q u a ls : C o n tr ib u tio n o f c a p i t a l s e r v ic e s p er hour 3 / M u ltifa c to r p r o d u c tiv ity 4/ M a n u f a c t u r in g O u tp u t p e r h o u r o f a l l p e r s o n s M in u s : E q u a ls : C o n tr ib u tio n o f c a p i t a l s e r v ic e s per hour 3 / M u ltifa c to r p r o d u c tiv ity ]\J A v e r a g e a n n u a l r a t e s b a s e d 2 / E x c lu d e s g o v ern m en t e n t e r p 3 / C h an ge i n c a p i t a l p e r u n i t o u tp u t. 4 / O uput p e r u n i t o f c o m b in e d 4/ o n com pound r a t e f o r m u la , r is e s . o f la b o r w e ig h te d b y c a p i t a l ’ s s h a r e o f t o t a l l a b o r an d c a p i t a l i n p u t . 20 The following note briefly describes the major data sources and the procedures used in deriving the new BLS multifactor productivity indexes* More detailed information on the methods, limitations, and data sources are available on request from the Bureau of Labor Statistics* Tables 1-6 include all the productivity and related indexes for each year* Summary of Methods The multifactor productivity indexes are derived by dividing an output index by an input index which is a weighted average of the hours of all persons and of capital services* The output indexes are computed from measures of constant dollar gross domestic product, derived from the national income and product accounts developed by the Bureau of Economic Analysis of the U,S* Department of Commerce * The labor component of the input indexes is developed from measures of employment and average hours, drawn mainly from the BLS Current Employment Statistics program (the "establishment" survey) and the Current Population Survey (the "household” survey)* The establishment survey provides information about employees on nonagricultural payrolls; the household survey about the self-employed, unpaid family workers, and those engaged in agriculture* The BLS has done considerable research on the effects on productivity growth of workforce composition (changes in the age, sex, and educational structure of the workforce)* This work is not included in the measures published today because more research is required* The capital services component of the combined input indexes is developed from measures of the stock of physical assets— equipment, structures, land, and inventories— and rental prices for each type of stock. The stock measures, in turn, are derived from data in the national accounts and other sources on investment, service lives, and capital deterioration functions* The rental prices are derived from data on depreciation costs and estimates of rates of return on the capital assets* The labor and capital components of the input indexes are combined with weights which represent each component's share of total output* The index uses changing weights where the share in each year is averaged with the preceding year’s value * Data are presented for the private business, private nonfarm business, and manufacturing sectors* The private business sector, which accounts for about 80 percent at the gross national product includes all activities in the economy with the exception of general government, government enterprises, the "rest of world" sector, owner-occupied housing, nonprofit institutions, and private household employees* The private nonfarm business sector also excludes agriculture but includes agricultural services* 21 The traditional productivity measure of output per hour slowed-— dropping from a growth rate of 3.0 percent during the 1948-73 period to 0.8 percent from 1973 to 1981. Of this 2.2 percentage point falloff, 0.3 percentage point was the result of the slowdown in the growth of capital per unit of labor input. The balance— that of multifactor productivity growth— -reflected the remaining influences. Output per unit of capital services, another productivity measure introduced today, fluctuated between 1948 and 1981 but did not register a significant trend over the period as a whole (chart A). Private nonfarm business. From 1948 to 1981, multifactor productivity growth in this sector averaged 1.3 percent annually as output rose 3.4 percent per year and combined labor and capital inputs increased 2.1 percent per year (table A). As was.the case for the private business sector as a whole, after 1973 there was a marked change in the trend. Multifactor productivity grew 1.7 percent annually from 1948 to 1973, but did not grow at all after 1973 (table B). Hence, all of the increase in output during the later period came from increased inputs of capital and labor. The traditional productivity measure for the private nonfarm business sector, output per hour of all persons, rose 2.5 percent per year from 1948 to 1973, compared with 0.6 percent per year between 1973 and 1981. The 1.9 percentage point slowdown in output per hour in this sector partly reflects a 0.2 percentage point decline in the contribution of capital services per unit of labor input. Most of the slowdown, however, was due to the 1.7 percentage point falloff in multifactor productivity growth, which in turn reflected the impact of other influences. As in private business, output per unit of capital input in the private nonfarm business sector fluctuated from year to year, but there was no evident trend between 1948 and 1981 (chart B ) . Manufacturing. From 1948 to 1981, multifactor productivity grew faster in manufacturing than in the more comprehensive business sectors. There was a 1.8 percent annual gain, reflecting a 3.3 percent average rise in output coupled with a 1.6 percent annual increase in combined labor and capital inputs. The falloff in the multifactor growth rate also occurred in manufacturing after 1973— from a rate of 2.2 percent during the 1948-73 period to 0.4 percent from 1973 to 1981 (table B). The slowdown in the traditional output per hour indexes for manufacturing after 1973 was 1.4 percentage points, less severe than for the more comprehensive business sectors. Moreover, the growth of capital per hour in manufacturing accelerated after 1973. From 1948 to 1973 the growth in capital services per unit of labor contributed 0.7 percent per year to the growth in output per hour in manufacturing and, after 1973, 1.1 percent per year. 22 Table 1. Private business sector: Productivity and related measures, 1948-81. Productivity Year Output Per Hour of All Persons Output Per Unit of Capital \J Inputs Multifactor Productivity 2/ Output v Hours of All Persons 47 Capital 5/ Combined Units of Labor and Capital Inputs, 6/ Capital per Hour of All Persons Indexes 1977=100 1948 1949 45.3 46.0 99.2 93.6 60.1 59.4 36.8 36.1 81.3 78.6 37.1 38.6 61.3 60.8 45.6 49.1 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 49.7 51.2 52.9 54.6 55.6 98.7 100.2 99.4 100.7 96.3 63.6 65.1 66.3 68.0 67.8 39.5 41.8 43.2 45.1 44.4 79.5 81.8 81.8 82.6 79.8 40.0 41.8 43.5 44.9 46.1 62.1 64.3 65.2 66.4 65.5 50.4 51.1 53.2 54.3 57.7 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 57.8 58.5 60.0 61.8 63.9 100.9 100.0 97.9 94.3 99.3 70.7 71.0 71.6 72.0 74.9 47.9 49.2 49.7 48.9 52.5 82.9 84.2 82.9 79.0 82.1 47.5 49.2 50.7 51.9 52.9 67.8 69. 3 69.4 67.8 70.0 57.3 58.5 61.2 65.6 64.4 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 64.8 67.0 69.6 72.3 75.4 98.4 98.0 101.2 102.6 105.2 75.4 76.9 79.7 82.0 84.9 53.3 54.2 57.2 59.7 63.3 82.2 80.9 82.2 82.7 84.0 54.1 55.3 56.6 58.2 60.2 70.7 70.5 71.8 72.9 74.6 65.8 68.4 68.8 70.4 71.6 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 78.1 80.4 82.3 85.1 85.3 107.8 108.0 104.9 105.5 103.7 87.6 89,3 89.6 91.7 91.3 67.6 71.3 72.9 76.7 78.9 86.7 88.7 88.6 90.1 92.5 62.8 66.1 69.6 72.7 76.1 77.2 79.9 81.4 83.7 86.5 72.4 74.5 78.5 80.7 82.3 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 86.1 89.2 92.4 94.7 92.4 98.6 98.1 101.0 103.0 96.5 90.2 92.2 95.2 97.5 93.8 78.3 80.6 86.0 91.8 89.9 90.9 90.4 93.2 96.9 97.2 79.4 82.2 85.2 89.1 93.1 86.8 87.5 90.4 94.1 95.8 87.4 91.0 91.5 92.0 95.8 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 94.5 97.6 100.0 100.6 99.6 91.9 96.1 100.0 101.8 100.3 93.6 97.1 100.0 101.0 99.9 88.0 93.7 100.0 105.5 107.8 93.1 95.9 100.0 104.9 108.3 95.7 97.5 100.0 103.6 107.5 94.0 96.5 100.0 104.4 108.0 102.8 101.6 100.0 98.8 99.3 1980 1981 98.8 100.6 95.3 95.0 97.6 98.6 106.2 108.8 107.4 108.2 111.3 114.5 108.8 110.3 103.6 105.8 Average annual percent change 7/ 1948-73 1973-81 3.0 0.8 - 1.0 2.0 0.1 3.7 2.2 0.7 1.4 3.6 3.2 1.7 2.0 2.8 1.8 1948-81 2.4 -0.1 1.5 3.3 0.9 3.5 1.8 2.6 0.2 See footnotes following table 6. 23 Table 2. Private nonfarm business sector: Productivity and related measures, 1948-81. 1/ Productivity Year Output Per Hour of All Persons Output Per Unit of Capital Inputs Multifactor Productivity 2/ Output V Hours of All Persons 4/ Capital 5/ Combined Units of Labor and Capital Inputs 6/ Capital per Hour of All Persons Indexes 1977=100 1948 1949 51.2 52.3 98.1 92.8 64.6 64.2 35.6 34.9 69.6 66.8 36.3 37.7 55.1 54.4 52.2 56.3 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 55.6 56. 6 58.0 59.0 59.9 98.4 100.6 99.7 100.9 96.2 68.2 69.5 70.4 71.5 71.0 38.3 40.9 42.2 44.1 43.2 69.0 72.2 72.8 74.7 72.1 39.0 40.6 42.4 43.7 44.9 56.2 58.8 60.0 61.7 60.8 56.5 56.3 58.2 58. 5 62.3 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 62.3 62.5 63.6 65.1 67.4 100.9 100. 1 98.0 94.0 99.5 74.1 74.0 74.3 74.3 77.5 46.8 48.2 48.7 47.8 51.6 75.1 77.0 76.6 73.4 76.6 46.4 48.1 49.7 50.8 51.9 63.2 65.1 65.6 64.3 66.6 61.7 62.5 64.9 69.3 67.7 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 67.9 70.0 72.5 74.9 77.8 98.4 97.9 101.3 102.6 105.5 77.6 78.9 81.7 83.8 86.7 52.3 53.3 56.4 58.9 62.7 77.0 76.1 77.8 78.6 80.5 53.2 54.4 55.7 57.4 59.4 67.5 67.5 69.0 70.3 72.3 69.1 71.5 71.6 73.0 73.8 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 80.3 82.2 83.8 86.7 86.4 108.1 108.7 105.3 106.0 104.1 89.2 90.7 90.7 92.9 92.1 67.0 71.0 72.5 76.5 78.7 83.5 86.4 86.5 88.2 91.1 62.0 65.3 68.9 72.1 75.6 75.1 78.3 79.9 82.3 85.4 74.2 75.7 79.6 81.7 83.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 86.8 89.7 93.0 95.3 92.9 98.6 98.0 101.1 103.2 96.5 90.7 92.4 95.7 97.9 94.1 77.9 80.1 85.8 91.7 89.7 89.7 89.3 92.2 96.2 96.6 78.9 81.8 84.8 88.8 93.0 85.9 86.7 89.7 93.6 95.4 88.0 91.5 92.0 92.3 96.3 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 94.7 97.8 100.0 100.6 99.3 91.7 96.1 100.0 101.9 100.0 93.6 97.2 100.0 101.1 99.6 87.6 93.6 100.0 105.7 108.0 92.5 95.7 100.0 105.1 108.7 95.6 97.4 100.0 103.7 107.9 93.6 96.3 100.0 104.6 108.4 103.3 101.8 100.0 98.7 99.2 1980 1981 98.4 99.8 95.1 94.4 97.3 97.9 106.2 108.5 108.0 108.8 111.7 115.0 109.2 110.9 103.4 105.7 Average annual percent change 7/ 1948-73 1973-81 2.5 0.6 0.2 -1.1 1.7 0.0 3.9 2.1 1.3 1.5 3.6 3.3 2.1 2.1 2.3 1.7 1948-81 2.0 -0.1 1.3 3.4 1.4 3.6 2.1 2.2 See footnotes following table 6. 24 Table 3. Manufacturing sector: Productivity and related measures, 1948-81. 1/ Inputs Productivity Year Output Per Hour of All Persons Output Per Unit of Capital Multifactor Productivity 2/ Output V Hours of All Persons 4/ Capital 5/ Combined Units of Labor and Capital Inputs 6/ Capital per Hour of All Persons Indexes 1977=100 1948 1949 45.1 46.9 94.4 86.0 56.2 56.0 35.8 33.9 79.4 72.4 37.9 39.5 63.7 60.6 47.8 54.5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 49.4 51.1 52.0 52.9 53.7 94.9 99.6 95.7 98.6 89.2 59.9 62.3 62.2 63.5 62.3 38.6 43.0 44.5 47.5 44.1 78.2 84.2 85.4 89.8 82.1 40.7 43.2 46.4 48.2 49.5 64.5 69.1 71.4 74.8 70.8 52.1 51.3 54.4 53.7 60.2 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 56.4 56.0 57.1 56.9 59.6 95.8 92.5 89.6 80.5 89.2 65.9 64.8 65.1 62.8 67.0 48.9 49.2 49.5 45.2 50.5 86.6 87.9 86.5 79.4 84.7 51.0 53.2 55.2 56.2 56.6 74.2 75.9 76.0 71.9 75.4 58.8 60. 5 63.8 70.7 66.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 60.0 61.6 64.3 68.9 72.3 88.0 86.9 92.9 98.3 102.4 67.0 68.0 71.5 76.3 79.8 50.7 50.7 55.1 59.6 63.9 84.4 82.3 85.6 86.5 88.4 57.5 58.3 59.2 60.7 62.4 75.6 74.6 77.0 78.2 80.0 68.2 70.9 69.2 70. 1 70.6 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 74.5 75.3 75.3 78.0 79.3 107.3 108.7 101.1 101.1 100.5 82.8 83.7 81.8 83.7 84.6 69.8 75. 1 75.0 79.1 81.7 93.6 99.8 99.6 101.4 103.1 65.1 69.2 74.2 78.2 81.3 84.3 89.8 91.7 94.4 96.6 69.5 69.3 74.5 77.1 78.9 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 79.1 83.9 88.2 93.0 90.8 91.8 92.4 99.9 108.2 99.6 82.3 86.0 91.1 96.8 93.0 77.0 78.7 86.2 95.9 91.9 97.3 93.7 97.8 103.2 101.2 83.9 85.2 86.4 88.6 92.2 93.6 91.5 94.7 09. 1 98.8 86.2 90.9 88.3 85.9 91.1 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 93.4 97.5 100.0 100.9 101.6 89.4 96.1 100.0 101.5 99.5 92.2 97.1 100.0 101.0 101.0 85.4 93.6 100.0 105.3 108.2 91.4 95.9 100.0 104.4 106.5 95.5 97.4 100.0 103.8 108.8 92.6 96.4 100.0 104.2 107.2 104.4 101.5 100.0 99.4 102.1 1980 1981 101.7 104.5 90.0 87.5 98.6 99.9 103.6 105.9 101.8 101.3 115.1 121.1 105.1 106.0 113.1 119.5 Average annual percent change 7/ 1948-73 1973-81 2.9 1.5 0.6 -2.6 2.2 0.4 4.0 1.2 1.1 -0.2 3.5 4.0 1.8 0.9 2.4 4.2 1948-81 2.6 -0.2 1.8 3.3 0.7 3.6 1.6 2.8 See footnotes following table 6. 25 Table 4. Private business sector: Productivity and related measures, 1948-81. Productivity Year Output Per Hour of All Persons Output Per Unit of Capital 1/ Inputs Multifactor Productivity 2/ Output Hours of All Persons Capital 3/ y 5/ Combined Units of Labor and • Capital Inputs 6/ Capital per Hour of All Persons Percent change 1949 1.6 -5.6 -1.1 -1.0 -3.4 4.0 -0.8 7.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 8.2 2.9 3.4 3.3 1.7 5.5 1.5 -0.8 1.3 -4.3 7.2 2.4 1.8 2.6 -0.4 0.4 5.9 3.3 4.4 -1.8 1.2 2.9 0.0 1.1 -3.4 3.7 4.4 4.2 3.1 2.7 2.1 3.5 1.5 1.8 -1.4 2. 5 1.4 4.2 2.0 6.3 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 4.1 1.1 2.6 3.1 3.3 4.8 -n.o -2.1 -3.7 5.3 4.4 0.3 o.o 0.7 4.0 8.1 2.6 1.0 -1.6 7.3 3.8 1.5 -1.5 -4.6 3.0 3.1 3.6 3.1 2.2 2.0 3.6 2.3 0.1 -2.3 3.2 -0.7 2.0 4.7 7.1 -1.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1.5 3.4 3.9 3.8 4.3 -0.8 -0.5 3.2 1.4 2.5 0.6 2.0 3.6 2.0 3.6 1.6 1.7 5.6 4.4 6.0 0.1 -1.6 1.6 0.6 1.6 2.4 2.2 2.3 2.9 3.4 0.9 -0.3 1.9 1.4 2.3 2.3 3.8 0.6 2.4 1.7 1965 1066 1967 1968 1969 3.6 3.1 2.3 3.5 0.2 2.4 0.2 -2.0 0.6 -1.7 3.1 1.9 0.3 2.4 -0.5 6.8 5.5 2.2 5.2 2.9 3.1 2.4 -0.1 1.7 2.7 4.3 5.3 5.3 4.6 4.7 3.6 3.5 1.9 2.7 3.4 1. 1 2.8 5.4 2.9 1.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1075 0.9 3.6 3.5 2.6 -2.4 2.2 -5.0 -0.5 3.0 2.0 -6.3 -4.7 -1.2 2.2 3.3 2.4 -3.8 -0.2 -0. 8 3.0 6.7 6.6 -2.1 -2.1 -1.7 -0.6 3.1 4.0 0.4 -4.2 4.3 3.5 3.6 4.6 4.5 2.7 0.3 0.8 3.3 4.2 1.8 -1.8 6.2 4.1 0.5 0.6 4.2 7.3 1976 1977 1978 1979 3.3 2.4 0.6 -1.0 4.5 4.0 1.8 -1.4 •3.8 3.0 1.0 -1.1 6.5 6.7 5.5 2.2 3.0 4.2 4.9 3.2 1.0 2.6 3.6 3.7 2.6 3.6 4.4 3.4 -1.1 -1.6 -1.2 0. 5 1980 1981 oc G 1 -5.0 -0.3 -2.2 1.1 -1.6 2.5 -0.8 0.7 3.6 2.9 0.7 1.5 4.4 2.1 1.8 See footnotes following table 6. 26 Table 5. Private nonfarm business sector: Productivity and related measures, 1948-81. Productivity Year Output Per Hour of All Persons Output Per Unit of Capital If Inputs Multifactor Productivity 2/ Output V Hours of All Persons 4/ Capital 5/ Combined Units of Labor and Capital Inputs 6/ Capital per Hour of All Persons Percent change 1949 2.2 -5.4 -0.6 -1.9 -4.0 3.7 -1.3 8.0 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 6.3 1.9 2.5 1.7 1.5 6.0 2.2 -0.9 1.2 -4.7 6.2 2.0 1.2 1.5 -0.6 9.7 6.6 3.4 4.4 -2.0 3.2 4.6 0.9 2.6 -3.5 3.5 4.2 4.3 3.2 2.8 3.3 4.5 2.1 2.8 -1.4 0.3 -0.4 3.4 0.6 6.5 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 4.0 0.3 1.8 2.4 3.5 5.0 -0.9 -2.0 -4.1 5.9 4.4 -0.1 0.4 0.0 4.3 8.4 2.8 1.2 -1.9 8.0 4.2 2.5 -0.6 -4.3 4.4 3.3 3.7 3.3 2.3 2.0 3.8 3.0 0.8 -2.0 3.5 -0.9 1.2 3.9 6.8 -2.3 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 0.8 3.0 3.6 3.3 3.9 -1.1 -0.5 3.4 1.4 2.8 0.1 1.7 3.5 2.5 3.5 1.4 1.8 5.9 4.4 6.4 0.6 -1.2 2.2 1.1 2.4 2.6 2.3 2.4 3.0 3.5 1.3 0.1 2.3 1.8 2.8 2.0 3.5 0.2 1.9 1.1 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 3.1 2.4 1.9 3.4 -0.3 2.5 0.5 -3.1 0.7 -1.8 2.9 1.7 0.0 2.4 -0.8 7.0 5.9 2.1 5.4 2.9 3.7 3.4 0.2 2.0 3.2 4.4 5.4 5.4 4.7 4.8 4.0 4.2 2.1 3.0 3.8 0.7 1.9 5.2 2.7 1.5 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 0.4 3.4 3.7 2.5 -2.5 -5.3 -0.6 3.2 2.1 -6.5 -1.6 2.0 3.5 2.3 -3.9 -1.1 2.9 7.0 6.9 CvJ CN 1 -1.5 -0.4 3.2 4.3 0.4 4.5 3.6 3.7 4.7 4.7 0.5 0.9 3.4 4.5 1.8 6.0 4.0 0.5 0.4 4.3 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 2.0 3.3 2.2 0.6 -1.3 -5.0 4.9 4.0 1.9 -1.8 -0.5 3.8 2.9 1.1 -1.5 -2.4 6.9 6.8 5.7 2.1 -4.3 3.5 4.5 5.1 3.5 2.8 1.9 2.7 3.7 4.0 -1.9 2.9 3.8 4.6 3.7 7.4 -1.5 -1.8 -1.3 0.5 1980 1981 -0.9 1.4 -5.0 -0.8 -2.3 0.7 -1.6 2.2 -0.7 0.8 3.5 3.0 0.7 1.5 4.2 2.2 See footnotes following table 6. 27 Table 6. Manufacturing sector: Productivity and related measures, 1948-81. 1/ Productivity Year Output Per Hour of All Persons Output Per Unit of Capital Inputs Multifactor Productivity 2/ Output Hours of All Persons Capital V ±1 5/ Combined Units of Labor and Capital Inputs 6/ Capital per Hour of All Persons Percent change -8.9 -0.4 -5.2 -8.9 4.0 -4.9 14. 1 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 5.4 3.4 1.8 1.7 1.6 10.4 4.9 -3.9 3.0 -9.6 7.1 3.9 -0.1 2.1 -2.0 13.Q 11.4 3.3 6.9 -7.2 8.0 7.7 1.4 5.1 -8.6 '3.2 6.2 7.5 3.7 2.7 6.3 7.2 3.4 4.7 -5.3 -4. 5 -1.4 5.9 -1.3 12. 3 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 5.0 -0.7 2.1 -0.4 4.8 7.5 -3.4 -3.2 -10.2 10.8 5.8 -1.6 0.4 -3.4 6.6 10.8 0.7 0.5 -8.6 11.7 5. 5 1.5 -1.5 -8.2 6.6 3.1 4.3 3.8 1.7 0.8 4.7 2.4 0.1 -5.4 4.8 -2.3 2.8 5.4 10.Q -5.4 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 0.7 2.7 4.3 7.2 4.8 -1.3 -1.2 6.9 5.7 4.2 0.1 1.5 5.1 6.7 4.6 0.3 0.1 8.6 8.3 7.1 -0.3 -2.5 4.1 1.0 2.2 1.6 1.4 1.6 2.4 2.9 0.3 -1.4 3.3 1.5 2.4 1.9 4.0 -2.4 1.4 0.6 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 3.1 1.1 0.0 3.5 1.7 4.8 1.3 0.0 -0.6 3.7 1.2 -2.3 2.4 1.0 9.2 7.7 -0.2 5.5 3.4 5.9 6.5 -0.2 1.9 1.6 4.2 6.3 7.2 5.4 3.9 5.3 6.5 2.1 3.0 2.3 -1.6 -0.2 7.5 3.5 2.3 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 -0.2 6.1 5.0 5.4 -2.4 -8.7 0.6 8.1 8.4 -7.9 -2.7 4.5 6.0 6.3 -3.9 -5.8 2.2 9.6 11.2 -4.2 -5.6 -3.7 4.3 5.5 -1.9 3.2 1.6 1.4 2.6 4.1 -3.2 -2.2 3.4 4.6 -0.3 9.3 5.5 -2.8 -2.8 6.1 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 2.9 4.4 2.5 0.9 0.7 -10.3 7.4 4.1 1.5 -2.0 -0.9 5.3 3.0 1.0 -0.1 -7.1 9.6 6.9 5.3 2.7 -9.7 4.9 4.2 4.4 2.0 3.5 2.0 2.7 3.8 4.8 -6.2 4.1 3.8 4.2 2.8 14.6 -2.8 -1.5 -0.6 2.7 1980 1981 0.2 2.8 -9.5 -2.8 -2.4 1.4 -4.3 2.3 -4.5 -0.5 5.8 5.2 -1.9 0.9 10.7 5.7 1 4.0 c 1949 See footnotes following table 6. 28 F o o t n o t e s , T a b le s SOURCE: 1 -6 Output data from Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), U.S. Department of Commerce, and the Federal Reserve Board. Compensation and hours data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor, and BEAo Capital measures are based on data supplied by BEA and U.S. Department of Agriculture „ (1) The private business sector includes all of Gross National Product except the rest-of-world sector, the rental value of owner-occupied real estate, the output arising in nonprofit organizations, the rental value of real estate occupied by nonprofit organizations, the output of paid employees of private households, government, and the statistical discrepancy in preparing the national income accounts. The private nonfarm business sector also excludes farms, but includes agricultural services„ (2) Output per unit of combined labor and capital inputs,, (3) Gross Domestic Product originating in the sector, in constant dollars 0 (4) Paid hours of all employees, plus the hours of proprietors and unpaid family workers engaged in the sector. (5) A measure of the flow of capital services used in the sector0 (6) Hours of all persons combined with capital input, using labor and capital shares of output as weights. (7) Average annual percent change based on compound rate formula. 29 J. R. NORSWORTHY MICHAEL J. HARPER KENT KUNZE Bureau of Labor Statistics The Slowdown in Productivity Growth: Analysis o f Some Contributing Factors L abor productivity in the private business sector grew at an annual rate of 1 percent from 1973 to 1978, about one-third of its rate of growth from 1948 to 1965. The effects of this slowdown were both substantially reduced economic growth and higher prices. A comprehensive analysis of recent economic growth has been made by Edward F. Denison, whc^examined the effects of re g u la tio n on growth in a framework That assesses the~Cbntrfbutions from various potential causal factors.1 Our_appr.oach is different from his Tn several respects, depending primarily on the defini tion of output, and the measurement of capital input.12Several other studies have focused on particular issues in the productivity puzzle, such as analyses of the effects of capital formation, energy, labor force composi tion, and intersectoral shifts of labor.3 This paper investigates productivity in the private business sector for which quarter!y.labor. productivity and-eost statistics are published by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLSri The basic methodology weights growth rates of capital and labor inputs by their shares in gross domestic prqduelj3Lthis_S£ctor. Although-growthrinriabor^pigductivitv is the tar get for explanation, the framework includes the contribution of multifac tor productivity-growth— the Hicks-neutral residuaLJQie..measurement techniques draw primarily on the work.oLDenison- and- Dale ,W^ Jorgen son,,_as outlined below. The faclors-we examine as possibly contributing to the slowdown are limited to those that can .be quantified and adapted for inclusion in a national accounts framework. Therefore, we do not explore such issues as deterioration-of The~~woTk-^thic^-aiid anv effect from such unmeasured phenomena wilLpresumablv appear in the residual of our analysis. In an alternative framawork—based-on-regression analysis7dme~could try to measure suc^phenemena-because the standards for quantifying them could be relaxed.4 However, the collinearitvin single-equation regression models-makesjthe coefficients associated with any single factor highly variable,-depending greatly upon the other factors included in a particular specification. A multiple-equation, simultaneous model might be at tempted; but it would be difficult to include a number of possible explana tory factors in a framework that allows for variable elasticities of substitution. We examine, in addition, the existence and timing of the productivity slowdown and its pervasiveness among major industry sectors of the economy. And we estimate the contribution to this slowdown of changes in the composition of the labor force, changes in capital-labor ratios, trends in the ratio of hours worked to hours paid, interindustry shifts of capital and labor, capital expenditures for pollution abatement, and in creases in energy prices. Most of these effects are analyzed by interpret ing them as augmenting or abating the effective input of capital or labor. A general point about the analysis of the slowdown needs to be made at the outset. For a particular phenomenon to contribute to a slowdown in productivity growth, its effects must be greater in the slowdown period than in the reference period. We therefore need data to estimate the effects in both periods in order to determine any contribution to the slow down. It is not sufficient that a particular negative factor is at work during the slowdown; it must be working demonstrably harder than before. The Dimensions of the Slowdown Peter Clark, after adjusting the labor productivity series for cyclical movements, selected the time periods 1948-55, 1955-65, 1965-73, and 1973-77 for analysis.5 The endpoint years, except for 1977, are peaks in Clark’s cyclically adjusted labor productivity. The year 1965 has addi tional claims as a watershed year: it marked the onset of major Vietnam War deficit financing and increasing inflation. And at about that time the first cohort from the postwar “baby boom” entered the labor force. We Table 1. Rates of Growth of Labor Productivity, Output, Capital, and Hours, and Ratio of Investment to Output, Private Business Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78° Annual average, in percent Item Labor productivity Gross domestic product Net capital stockb Total hours of labor input0 Ratio of gross private domestic investment to gross domestic product 1. Edward F. Denison, “Effects of Selected Changes in the Institutional and Hu man Environment Upon Output Per Unit of Input,” Survey of Current Business, vol. 58 (January 1978), pp. 21-44. 2. Edward F. Denison, Accounting for United States Economic Growth, 19291969 (Brookings Institution, 1974). 3. For capital formation see Peter K. Clark, “Capital Formation and the Recent Productivity Slowdown,” Journal of Finance, vol. 33 (June 1978), pp. 965-75; Eco nomic Report o f the President, January 1978, pp. 48-58; and J. R. Norsworthy and Michael J. Harper, “The Role of Capital Formation in the Recent Productivity Growth Slowdown,” Working Paper 87 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, January 1979). For energy see Edward A. Hudson and Dale W. Jorgenson, “Energy Prices and the U.S. Economy, 1972-1976,” Data Resources Review, vol. 7 (September 1978), pp. 1.24—1.37; and George L. Perry, “Potential Output: Recent Issues and Present Trends,” in Center for the Study of American Business, “U.S. Productive Capacity: Estimating the Utilization Gap,” Working Paper 23 (Washington University, CSAB, December 1977), pp. 1-20 (Brookings Reprint 336). For labor force composition and intersectoral shifts of labor see Jack Beebe, “A Note on Intersectoral Shifts and Aggregate Productivity Change,” Annals o f Economic and Social Measurement, vol. 4 (Summer 1975), pp. 389-95; George L. Perry, “Labor Force Structure, Po tential Output, and Productivity,” BPEA, 3:1971, pp. 533-65; William D. Nordhaus, S o u rc e : C o m p u te d b y a u th o r s u s in g d a ta fr o m B u r e a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s . y 1965-73 1973-78 3.32 3.71 2.62 0.38 2.32 3.77 3.67 1.44 1.20 2.62 2.05 1.42 12.3 13.5 12.8 th e U .S . B u r e a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is a n d th e U .S . a . O u tp u t, in v e s tm e n t, a n d th e c a p ita l s to c k a r e m e a s u r e d a t 1 9 7 2 p ric e s . b . T h e m e t h o d o f a g g r e g a t i o n u s e d is d i r e c t a g g r e g a tio n . S e e t a b l e 4 . c. M e a su re d a s h o u rs p a id “The Recent Productivity Slowdown,” BPEA, 3:1972, pp. 493-526; Michael Grossman and Victor R. Fuchs, “Intersectoral Shifts and Aggregate Productivity Change,” in American Statistical Association, Proceedings of the Business and Eco nomic Statistics Section (Washington, D.C.: ASA, 1972), pp. 66-75; and J. R. Nors worthy and L. J. Fulco, “Productivity and Costs in the Private Economy, 1973,” Monthly Labor Review, vol. 97 (June 1974), pp. 3-9. 4. Robin Siegel, “Why Has Productivity Slowed Down?” Data Resources Review, vol. 8 (March 1979), pp. 1.59-1.65. 5. Clark, “Capital Formation.” Reprinted from Brookings Papers on Economic A ctivity, 2:1979. 1948-65 30 Table 2. Growth of Labor Productivity and Share of Labor Input in the Total Private Business Economy, by Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Annual average, in percent Growth o f labor productivity Sector Private business Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries Mining Construction Manufacturing Durable goods Nondurable goods Transportation Communication Electric, gas, and sanitary services Trade Wholesale Retail Finance, insurance, and real estate Services Government enterprises 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 3.2 5.5 4.2 2.9 3.1 2.8 3.4 3.3 5.5 6.2 2.7 3.1 2.4 1.0 1.5 -0 .8 2.3 5.3 2.0 -2 .2 2.4 1.9 3.2 2.9 4.8 4.0 3.0 3.9 2.3 -0 .3 1.9 0.9 1.1 2.9 -4 .0 -1 .8 1.7 1.2 2.4 0.9 7.1 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.8 1.4 0.5 -0 .7 Share o f total labor hours 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 100 12 1 6 30 17 13 5 1 1 23 6 17 5 12 2 100 6 1 7 32 19 13 5 2 1 25 7 18 6 14 2 100 5 1 7 30 18 12 4 2 1 26 7 19 6 16 2 S o u r c e : B u r e a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s . P r o d u c tiv ity d a t a f o r s e rv ic e s , c o n s tr u c tio n , a n d f in a n c e , in s u r a n c e , a n d r e a l e s ta te a r e u n p u b lis h e d . n2 coefficients that describe the adjustment process. Particularly when out put changes are accompanied by substantial changes in relative prices, as in 1973-74, the adjustment process may extend beyond the next cyclical peak. At present, the cyclical adjustment issue probably cannot be dealt with in a satisfactory way except in the context of an elaborate model incorporating lagged simultaneous adjustment of inputs. Sufficient evi dence exists to suggest that any relatively simple method is inaccurate. The distribution of the slowdown in labor productivity among major industrial divisions shown in table 2 reveals different patterns in 1965-73 and in 1973-78.8 In manufacturing, the slowdown was about the same magnitude in each period. Mining productivity began to decline in 1969 when the Federal Coal Mine Health and Safety Act was passed, and pro ductivity has continued to decline in recent years as energy prices have risen and coal has played a larger role relative to petroleum mining. Pro ductivity growth in transportation slowed only slightly in 1965-73, but fell much more in the recent period when energy prices may have retarded an advance in productivity. Productivity growth in communications slowed slightly in 1965-73 and then accelerated in 1973-78. (This in dustry is clearly not part of the productivity problem.) Utilities showed a reduction in productivity growth in 1965-73 and a virtual halt in 197378. Energy prices, oil and gas shortages, and environmental regulations are commonly cited as affecting this industry. Productivity growth accel erated in the trade industries in 1965—73 and fell off sharply in 1973—78. In government enterprises, productivity declined in the base period, grew slightly in 1965—73, and declined again in 1973—78. Agricultural produc tivity growth slowed in 1973-78. Measures of output in the remaining three sectors are unreliable, and they are included in the table only to complete the productivity picture in the private business sector. The GNP Data Improvement Project— the Creamer report— urged that output measures for construction be im proved because output is now essentially measured as deflated inputs (labor and materials). Construction productivity, as measured, fell in 1965-73 and declined slightly less rapidly in 1973-78, after growing in 1948-65 at near the average rate for the private business sector. A report by the U.S. Department of Commerce found no discernible cause for the adapted Clark’s time periods (which were based initially on quarterly data) by combining the first two periods and extending the last one to 1978. The present evidence that real output is leveling off or declining during 1979 suggests that 1978 will be a reasonable endpoint for the analysis. For each of our reference periods, table 1 shows the rates of growth of output, labor and capital input, and labor productivity in the private busi ness sector— the largest sector for which the BLS publishes productivity statistics. The slowdown in the growth of labor productivity is evident in the last two periods. The growth of the capital stock is examined carefully below. It is worth noting here that it slowed substantially in the last period, even though the ratio of investment to gross product was slightly higher than in 1948-65. The growth rate of output does not explain variations in this investment fraction the way a simple accelerator model would pre dict. However, accelerator effects might help to explain part of the slow down in capital formation between the last two periods. Some investigators have chosen to examine the productivity slowdown as a single phenomenon beginning in the middle to late 1960s. The argu ment for a break at the business cycle peak in 1973 seems compelling, however. In addition to the sharp jump in energy prices that occurred, the patterns of productivity growth rates— or slowdowns— in 1965-73 and 1973-78 are quite different. And Norsworthy and Harper have found sharply different patterns of capital formation before and after 1973.6 We therefore examine the productivity slowdown in two phases: 1965-73 and 1973-78. By choosing our periods with endpoints that are years of relatively high resource utilization, we avoid the need to make cyclical adjustments in our data. Cyclical adjustment of output and input is an issue closely re lated to the choice of time periods for analysis. Clearly, productivity growth is slower— and for quarterly measurements it is negative— during economic recession. Measurement of average growth rates in output and input between peaks or over relatively long periods implicitly assumes that the various time periods between the endpoints are comparably affected by negative cyclical influences. But this is clearly not true in the time periods we analyze—-the years 1973-78 encompass a far more severe recession in fewer years than did 1965-73. Only insofar as these recession effects are captured in the factors we consider— for example, slower growth of the capital-labor ratio— will they be captured in our analysis. Nadiri and Rosen and Mohr have shown that the adjustment of any factor input to changes in output depends not only on the output change itself, but on the disequilibrium in other inputs.7 That is, with n inputs, there are Demand, and Factor Productivity in 10 U.S. Manufacturing Industries,” Staff Paper 9 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1978). 8. Output is based on gross product originating in the private domestic business portion of each sector. Output and labor and capital inputs for nonprofit institutions and household workers are excluded because output for those sectors is measured in the national accounts by deflated labor compensation—thus productivity growth is necessarily zero. This deduction is largely from the services sector. We also exclude the imputation for rental value of owner-occupied dwellings both because the labor input of homeowners and their families is not measured, and because final demand categories such as home maintenance and repair and some utilities consumption should properly be considered as intermediate inputs to the imputed output. This ex clusion affects the finance, insurance, and real estate sector. 6. Norsworthy and Harper, “Role of Capital Formation.” 7. M. Ishag Nadiri and Sherwin Rosen, “Interrelated Factor Demand Functions,” American Economic Review, vol. 59 (September 1969), pp. 457-71; M. F. Mohr, “A Quarterly Econometric Model of the Long-Term Structure of Production, Factor 31 Thus when capital and labor are the only inputs, productivity decline.9 Within the finance, insurance, and real estate sector, output is measured by labor input in the banking sector, where electronic data processing has made major inroads. Any quality changes resulting from this technological change are therefore not reflected in the output measures for the sector. Measured productivity in that sector fell slightly in 1965-73 after slow growth in 1948-65, and rose again in 1973-78. In . the services sector, output is measured by labor input in several constitu ent industries, and inadequate deflation to account for quality change is commonly cited as a problem. Measured productivity growth increased in 1965-73 and declined in 1973-78.10 The U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) does not publish data on capital stocks for federal, state, and local government enterprises. Con sequently, we excluded output and labor input for government enterprises from the private business and private nonfarm business sectors. Table 3 a = o — Factors such as composition or quality change can make the effective input of capital or labor differ from the measured input. Designating qK as the change in factors influencing effective input of capital services and qL as the change in factors influencing effective input of labor services, we have a = o — wKk — wLl — wKqK — wLqL. To focus on the growth in labor productivity, we rearrange terms to obtain o — / = tVkQ< — 0 + WKqK + w^qL + o. The growth in labor productivity thus depends on growth in the capitallabor ratio, factors of composition or quality change, and change in totalfactor productivity. If all other factors are unchanged, labor productivity will grow at the same rate as total-factor productivity. A key assumption that underlies this approach to accounting for growth in labor productivity is that the returns to various types of labor and capital equal their contributions to output— that is, equal their margi nal products. This assumption, although questionable for any particular point in time, is widely used in accounting for productivity growth, and is more reasonable as a description of trends over longer periods of time dhan a single year. The particular factors whose contribution to labor productivity we analyze can be described briefly. To measure the effect on labor produc tivity of shifts in labor among sectors, qLI, the growth rates of hours of labor input in the sectors are aggregated using the proportion of total labor compensation in each sector as weights. The effects of changes in the composition of the labor force are computed by Divisia aggregation of various categories of labor input— disaggregated by age, sex, education, occupation, and class of worker. Divisia aggregation sums the growth rates of each category of input, weighting each by its share of total labor input. The index of the change in labor composition, qLC, is then the difference between the growth of the Divisia aggregate and the growth of the directly aggregated (unweighted) labor input. The effect of shifts in the capital stock among asset types, qKC, is measured by aggregating the growth rates of each type of capital asset weighted by each asset’s share in total non labor payments in the sector. The effect of intersectoral shifts in capital, qKl, is measured by aggregating the growth rates of the capital stock in each sector using the sector’s share of total nonlabor payments as a weight. The effect of pollution abatement capital on the growth of the capital stock, kPA, is also a kind of shift effect, and is treated as a deduction from the capital stock. Each of these factors affecting measured capital and labor inputs is multiplied by the shares of labor and capital in nominal output— wL and wK— to compute the associated impacts on growth in labor productivity. The framework for analyzing the effects of changes in various factors con tributing to growth in labor productivity thus can be expressed as Table 3. Rates of Growth of Labor Productivity for the Private Business and Private Nonfarm Business Sectors, Total and Excluding Government Enterprises, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Annual average, in percent Private nonfarm business Private business Period Total Excluding government enterprises 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 3.20 2.25 1.12 3.32 2.32 1.20 S o u rc e s : C o m p u te d b y a u th o rs u s in g d a ta fro m Total Excluding government enterprises 2.63 1.95 1.01 2.77 2.02 1.09 th e B u r e a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is a n d B u r e a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s . shows the effects of the exclusion on the growth of labor productivity in those sectors. In summary, the pervasiveness of the slowdown suggests that an ex amination of major economic aggregates may be fruitful. At the same time, growth in labor productivity by industry shows substantial differ ences between the 1965-73 and 1973-78 periods. An analysis that fails to separate these two periods may miss important causal patterns. We , therefore attempt to account for the slowdown in two phases: a slowdown I of 1.00 percentage point a year in 1965-73 and a further slowdown of 1.12 percentage points a year in 1973-78. Framework for Analysis Our analysis separates growth in labor productivity into growth at tributable to changes in the capital-labor ratio, selected factors that alter ./ the effectiveness of measured capital and labor inputs, and residual or otherwise unexplained growth, which may be considered as corresponding j to total-factor productivity. \ We begin by aggregating the growth rates of labor and capital inputs weighted by their respective shares in output measured at current prices. That is, the weight associated with the labor aggregate, wL, is the ratio of total labor compensation to nominal output. Similarly, the weight asso ciated with the capital aggregate, wK, is the ratio of nonlabor payments to nominal output. The measures of output in current and constant prices, .labor compensation, nonlabor payments, capital stock, and labor input are based on the national income and product accounts published by the De partment of Commerce. The flow of capital services is assumed to be proportional to the net capital stock. The price of capital services is com puted as reported by Norsworthy and Harper.11 From the definition of total-factor productivity, A, we have A = Oj ^ o — l — wK(k — 1) -f- WKqKc + WKqKi + wk(—kpf) + wLqic + w^ li + Wiqui + a, where (k — l) = qKC = qKI = kPA = qL0 = qL[ = WiXi, where O is output; is the share of input i in total-factor cost, with 2Wi = 1; and is the quantity of input i used in producing O. Using lowercase letters to denote percentage change, we obtain productivity growth, a, from — wLl. rate of growth of the capital-labor ratio effect of changes in the composition of capital effect of intersectoral shifts in capital rate of growth of pollution abatement capital effect of changes in labor force composition effect of intersectoral shifts in labor 9. H. Kemble Stokes, Jr., “An Examination of the Productivity Decline in the Construction Industry” (U.S. Department of Commerce, Office of the Chief Econo mist, March 1979). 10. Interindustry shifts within the service sector account for a major part of mea sured productivity change. 11. Norsworthy and Harper, “Role of Capital Formation.” a = o — X ) Wi*,-. i“l 32 Qlh — effect of changes in the ratio of hours worked to hours paid a = change in total-factor productivity (residual). is exact for the Cobb-Douglas specification, which requires strong sepa rability of the inputs being aggregated from other inputs appearing in the production function. Translog aggregation, which is exact for a homothetic translog production function, requires weak separability of the inputs. We performed econometric tests for each specification. The test for the conditions required for direct aggregation failed by a wide margin for all three sectors, while the test for translog aggregation passed for the pri vate nonfarm and private nonfarm business sectors and failed narrowly for manufacturing.17 We therefore chose to use translog aggregation in this study. The choice of net or gross capital stocks of equipment and structures is another issue in the measurement of the growth of the capital stock. For productivity analysis, the issue comes down to whether net or gross capital stock— or, indeed, some other measure— is the better indicator of real capital input. In accounting terms, the difference between the gross and net capital asset measures is the accumulated depreciation on the asset. The method of depreciation and the service life of the capital asset are the determinants of depreciation. There is precedent for using gross capital stock, net capital stock, and a linear combination of the two.18 Denison uses a linear combination of the net and gross capital stocks to measure real capital input, whereas we use the net stock. Although the service lives of capital assets are difficult to obtain, there is evidence that the net capital stock from the national income accounts understates and the gross stock overstates real capital input.19 The evidence is incomplete, but Deni son’s measure may be nearer to real capital input than that used here. Evidence indicates that the results for 1965-73 are not sensitive to the choice of measures: the net stock of equipment and structures in the pri vate nonfarm business sector grew at an average annual rate of 3.1 percent in 1948-65 and 4.4 percent in 1965-73, while the gross stock grew at rates of 2.7 and 3.9 percent in the respective periods. The changes in the rates of growth therefore differ by only one-tenth of 1 percentage point. The 1973-78 results, however, are sensitive to the choice between net and gross measures. In simplest terms, the translog aggregation of the capital stock that we use is a method of correcting for aggregation bias because of changes in the composition of the capital stock. The reasoning underlying the use of the technique depends on the assumption that each asset type is used in each sector in such quantity that its marginal product— the value of asset services— is just equal to the price of the services of the asset. The price of those services depends upon the purchase price of the asset, the cor porate tax rate, the service life of the asset (or the rate of depreciation), other special tax treatment (such as capital gains or investment tax credit), and the debt-equity structure of corporate liabilities.20 For exam ple, a shift in the composition of the capital stock from structures to equip ment (such as the one that took place from 1965 through 1977) repre sents an increase in the “quality” of the capital stock because the service life of equipment is shorter than that of structures. Thus the depreciation rate for the aggregate stock is higher, and the cost of capital services is higher. The marginal productivity of the capital stock as a whole is there fore higher, and the flow of capital services in economic terms is greater. The interindustry mix of the capital stock reflects differences in the rate The residual or unexplained growth in labor productivity, a, is computed as the difference between observed growth in labor productivity and the contributions of the other effects. Thus it contains the effects of any errors in measurement and of other factors not accounted for in the analysis. The approach used here to measure sources of growth in labor pro ductivity is similar to the approaches used by Denison and by Frank M. Gollop and Jorgenson in one respect— all depend on a share-weighting scheme to estimate the contributions of various factors to productivity growth.12 The focus on growth in labor productivity in this paper is an expansion of a similar framework used by Christensen, Cummings, and Jorgenson.13 Certain differences between our approach and the others should be noted, however. Those relating to measurement of capital and labor input are discussed in the appropriate sections below. Our concept of output measurement is similar to that of most other investigators except Denison. He measures output as net national income at factor cost and thus excludes replacement investment from real output. Consistent with this practice, he also excludes depreciation from the cost of capital, and hence from the share of capital in the nominal value of output. To measure output in this way seems less desirable than to include replacement invest ment because it is equivalent to assuming that the output that goes to re placing the capital stock could not be diverted elsewhere. Even at the aggregate level, this is untrue— during the 1930s, net investment mea sured in the national income accounts was negative in at least one year. And at the industry level, negative net investment in a given year is com mon. Denison’s approach reduces the measured effect of capital’s contri bution to productivity growth because, as noted above, the share of capital is considerably smaller. In addition, the impact of productivity growth on prices cannot be directly observed in Denison’s framework because output prices include the full cost of capital. In a period such as 1965-73, when the share of equipment in total investment and hence in the total capital stock was rising, replacement investment was also rising because deprecia tion occurs faster for equipment than it does for structures. Thus output in the private business sector would rise more rapidly in our accounting framework than in Denison’s, other things being equal. THE C A PITA L STOCK A number of issues arise in measuring the effects of capital input on the growth of labor productivity. These include how to aggregate the cap ital stock; whether to use net or gross stocks; whether to include land, in ventories, and tenant-occupied housing; and whether to adjust for capac ity utilization. These issues are discussed extensively by Norsworthy and Harper.14 Only the main outline of that argument is summarized here. Issues in Measurement. Disagreement about the appropriate tech niques for aggregation of the capital stock— and, indeed, inputs in gen eral— for productivity analysis has characterized the discussion of pro duction theory in the economics literature.15 This particular type of index-number problem turns on the validity of direct aggregation of the components of the capital stock, measured in constant prices, as con trasted with translog or Divisia aggregation, which are both based on ag gregation of the growth rates of the components weighted by their shares in total capital cost.16 In terms of the production function, direct aggregation “The Explanation of Productivity Change,” Review o f Economic Studies, vol. 34 (July 1967), pp. 249-83. The application of the aggregation technique in time-series analysis necessarily involves a discrete approximation to the continuous Divisia form. The particular approximation— more than one is possible—used by Jorgenson and his associates is based on the maintained hypothesis of a translog production or cost function and thus seems best called a translog index. See Laurits R. Christensen, Dale W. Jorgenson, and Lawrence J. Lau, “Transcendental Logarithmic Production Fron tiers,” Review o f Economics and Statistics, vol. 55 (February 1973), pp. 28-45. 17.. These tests are described in Norsworthy and Harper, “Role of Capital Forma tion.” 18. For gross capital stock see John W. Kendrick, Postwar Productivity Trends in the United States, 1948-1969, General Series, 98 (National Bureau of Economic Research, 1973); for net capital stocks see Laurits R. Christensen and Dale W. Jorgenson, “U.S. Real Product and Real Factor Input, 1929-1967,” Review of Income and Wealth, series 16 (March 1970), pp. 19-50; for a linear combination see Denison, Accounting for United States Economic Growth. 19. Charles R. Hulten and Frank C. Wykoff, “Economic Depreciation and the Taxation of Structures in U.S. Manufacturing Industries: An Empirical Analysis,” in Dan Usher, ed., The Measurement of Capital (National Bureau of Economic Research, forthcoming). 20. See Christensen and Jorgenson, “U.S. Real Capital and Real Factor Input.” 12. Denison, Accounting for United States Economic Growth, and Frank M. Gollop and Dale W. Jorgenson, “U.S. Productivity Growth by Industry,” in John W. Kendrick and Beatrice N. Vaccara, eds., New Developments in Productivity Measurement (National Bureau of Economic Research, forthcoming). 13. Laurits R. Christensen, Diane Cummings, and Dale W. Jorgenson, “Eco nomic Growth, 1947-1973: An International Comparison,” in Kendrick and Vac cara, eds., New Developments. 14. Norsworthy and Harper, “Role of Capital Formation.” 15. The disagreement figures prominently in the debate between Edward F. Denison, Dale W. Jorgenson, and Zvi Griliches, which is reproduced in “The Mea surement of Productivity,” Survey o f Current Business, vol. 52 (May 1972), pt. 2, pp. 1-111. 16. The term “Tornquist index” is also used. The Divisia index, properly speak ing, is a continuous index, and some of the superior mathematical properties claimed for it apply only in the continuous form. See D. W. Jorgenson and Z. Griliches, 33 prices and adjusted for price changes are reported by BEA. Correspond ing measures of land input are not available from that source. In this paper we adopt the measures used by Kendrick in his estimates of the input of land for the aggregate sectors.23 It is important to measure the capital stock that corresponds as closely as possible to the output it produces. In his analysis of productivity growth in the nonfarm business sector, Clark used the capital stock for the pri vate nonfarm sector of the economy and found that some slowdown in labor productivity was attributable to capital formation in 1965-73.24 In table 5 that capital stock is adjusted to conform to the definition of the private nonfarm business sector by eliminating the capital in nonprofit in stitutions and including tenant-occupied residential capital.25 These ad justments increase the acceleration in capital formation between 194865 and 1965-73 from 0.74 percentage point to 1.31 percentage points a year, enough to alter sharply Clark’s verdict on the role of capital in the 1965-73 slowdown. Inclusion of land and inventories modifies the pattern only slightly. To adjust real capital input— the flow of capital services— for changes in capacity utilization means that part of the corresponding growth (or decline) in output can be traced to the change in capacity utili zation. Denison argues extensively and convincingly that this cannot be done.28 He also argues that adjustment of the entire capital stock by utili zation rates in manufacturing is inappropriate because those rates inaccu rately reflect utilization rates for other sectors, and for assets other than machinery. A careful reading of Denison’s argument— which is too exten sive to reproduce or even adequately summarize here— is compelling for us and presumably for Jorgenson, who revised his measurement tech nique to eliminate adjustment for capacity utilization.27 We also make no separate adjustment for technological improvement embodied in the capital stock. Insofar as these advances are reflected in a higher price for the asset, the adjustment for changes in the asset mix will capture the effect. If the improvements are achieved at no cost, the quantity of the asset used in production will be correspondingly adjusted so that the marginal product of the improved asset is equal to its service price, as noted above. Thus in either case the equilibrium nature of the model captures embodied technological change in the quantity or “qual ity” of the capital stock. Effects of Capital Spending for Pollution Abatement. The effects of investment in pollution abatement capital (PAK) on productivity growth is assumed to operate only through the capital stock. A reliable estimate of the contribution to the 1965—73 slowdown cannot be made because data for investment in PAK are not available before 1968. The unofficial BEA estimates of PAK investment and net stock are sufficient to fill out the 1965-73 period, and this period can be used as a reasonably good baseline with which to judge the effects of PAK expenditures in 1973-78 on productivity growth.28 Even the unofficial estimates begin in 1955. We quite arbitrarily projected the estimated investment growth back to 1948 to obtain a baseline for estimating the contributions to the 1965-73 slow down. The data are poor and the technique mechanical; however, the re sulting changes in the rates of growth of the capital stock, shown in table 6, are so small for the earlier periods in all but the manufacturing sector that substantial changes in technique would make little difference. The effects on the growth of labor productivity in the private business, private non farm business, and manufacturing sectors are estimated by weighting the capital devoted to pollution abatement by the share of capital in total output in thd^ectors. of return on assets among industries. Because we only consider four asset categories, whereas the BEA capital stock information is based on more than twenty classes of equipment alone, there may also be systematic dif ferences in depreciation rates among industries reflecting the different average service lives of the stocks of equipment and structures. Even in the equilibrium model on which this aggregation technique is based, such differences may occur in the average price of capital services across in dustries reflecting different capital stock composites. Therefore differen tial rates of growth of the capital stock by industry can lead to changes in the value of the flow of aggregate capital services. As noted below, the asset and industry dimensions of changing capital stock composition can be separated in the translog aggregation process, and reported and ana lyzed separately. The translog aggregation procedure makes it possible to isolate the separate contributions of changes in asset type and changes in interindus try composition of the capital stock to the growth of the capital aggregate. We may express the growth rate of the translog index for the capital aggregate, kT, as k r = k -f- qKA + <]k i , where k = growth rate of the capital stock directly aggregated qKA = growth contributed by changes in the asset mix (among equip ment, structures, land, and inventories) qKi = growth contributed by changes in the industry mix of the capital stock.21 An additional term, not shown in the expression for kT above, accounts for the interaction between qKI and qKA. Where it is not shown explicitly, we distributed the value of this term between the values of qKI and qKA in the tables presented below. Direct and translog aggregation of the capital stock for the private business sector are compared in table 4. The translog aggregate grows more rapidly in all time periods, particularly in 1965-73 when there was a substantial shift to equipment purchases in the manufacturing sector, presumably in response to the investment tax credit. Assets and interin dustry shift generally follow the annual growth rates in magnitude. The size of the total capital composition, or quality effect, is important; it pro vides between 10 and 20 percent of the average annual growth rate in each period. The notion that aggregation effects of this sort can be ignored seems to be refuted effectively. The rates of growth changed and so did their intertemporal pattern: the increase in the rate of capital formation in 1965-73 is greater for the translog aggregate. In measuring total real capital input for productivity analysis, it is im portant to include land and inventories as well as measures of equipment and structures.22 Stocks of inventories measured in current and constant Table 4. Rates of Growth of Capital Stock, by Method of Aggregation, and Contributions to Growth from the Effect of Capital Composition, Private Business Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Annual average, in percent Effect o f capital composition Method o f aggregation Period Direct Translog Total effect 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 2.62 3.67 2.05 3.14 4.48 2.31 0.51 0.82 0.24 Inter Asset sectoral composition shifts 0.30 0.41 0.18 0.34 0.51 0.10 Interaction between asset composition and shifts - 0 .1 3 - 0 .1 0 - 0 .0 4 23. John W. Kendrick, The National Wealth of the United States: By Major Sec tor and Industry, Report 698 (The Conference Board, 1976). 24. Clark, “Capital Formation,” p. 974. 25. Aggregates in table 5 are based on direct aggregation of capital stocks. 26. Edward F. Denison, “Some Major Issues in Productivity Analysis: An Exam ination of Estimates by Jorgenson and Griliches,” Survey o f Current Business, vol. 49 (May 1969), pt. 2, pp. 1-29. 27. Ibid., and Gollop and Jorgenson, “U.S. Productivity Growth.” 28. A more complete discussion of the quality of PAK data and their meaning is found in John E. Cremeans, “Capital Expenditures by Business for Air and Water Pollution Abatement, 1973 and Planned 1974,” Survey of Current Business, vol. 54 (July 1974), pp. 58-64; and his “Conceptual and Statistical Issues in Developing Environmental Measures— Recent U.S. Experience,” Review o f Income and Wealth, series 23 (June 1977), pp. 97-115. S o u r c e s : C o m p u te d b y a u th o r s . N e t c a p ita l s to c k s e rie s f o r e q u ip m e n t, s tr u c tu r e s , a n d in v e n to r ie s a r e f r o m th e B u r e a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is . D a ta o n la n d a r e f r o m J o h n W . K e n d r i c k , T h e N a tio n a l W e a lth o f th e U n ite d S ta t e s : B y M a jo r S e c to r a n d In d u s tr y , R e p o r t 6 9 8 ( T h e C o n f e r e n c e B o a r d , 1 9 7 6 ) , e x t r a p o l a t e d f o r 1 9 7 5 -7 8 b y th e a u th o rs . 21. Only three industry sectors are recognized in the capital stock and investment data available from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis: manufacturing, farm, and nonfarm nonmanufacturing. Because the definition of asset is a general one, finer detail for each industry typically leads to a reallocation of capital “quality” change— as the sum of the q terms above is often called—from asset to industry. See Gollop and Jorgenson, “U.S. Productivity Growth.” 22. See Denison, Accounting for United States Economic Growth; Gollop and Jorgenson, “U.S. Productivity Growth”; and Kendrick, Postwar Productivity. 34 Table 5. Reconciliation of Nonresidential Equipment and Structures to Business Capital, Private Nonfarm Business Sector, Selected Years, 1948-78 * Net stock (billions o f 1972 dollars) Item 1965 1948 Non re sid en tia l eq ui p m en t a n d structures Minus: Ca pi tal of nonprofit institutions Equals: Nonre sid en tia l business eq ui p m en t a n d structures 1973 Rate o f growth (percent) 1978 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 304.41 25.23 597.08 64.67 867.47 88.58 991.86 92.37 4.05 5.69 4.79 4.02 2.72 0.84 279.18 532.41 778.88 899.50 3.88 4.88 2.92 128.42 156.73 197.46 202.00 1.19 2.93 0.46 407.60 158.11 565.71 689.14 261.09 950.23 976.34 358.47 1,334.81 . 1,101.49 388.25 1,489.75 3.14 3.03 3.10 4.45 4.05 4.34 2.44 1.64 2.23 Plus: Te n an t-o cc up ied residential capital Equals: Business e qu ip m e n t an d structures Plus: L a n d a n d inventories Equals: Business capital S o u rc e : C o m p u te d b y a u th o rs u s in g d a ta fro m a. th e B u r e a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is . F ig u r e s a r e r o u n d e d , T h e a g g r e g a te s a r e b a s e d o n d ir e c t a g g r e g a tio n o f c a p ita l s to c k s . sixty-one industries; and the manufacturing sector, twenty-one industries. The raw data for the disaggregation was compiled from records of the U.S. Bureau of the Census, special labor force reports published by the BLS, and for the last years, from tapes from the Current Population Survey.32 The growth rate in the adjustment for labor composition, qL0, is de fined as the growth in labor services adjusted for all categories of labor, h, less the growth in unadjusted hours worked, l: For the last period, the growth of the capital stock is affected notice ably by the adjustment for pollution abatement. For the periods before 1973, the table demonstrates that PAK expenditures had a minimal effect on the capital aggregates. The effects in particular sectors were obviously greater than what is shown in these aggregate data. Denison examines the proposition from a broader perspective and still finds no major impact, although his is an aggregate perspective also.29 qLc = h — /, A D JU STM EN T FORCE FOR THE CO M PO SITIO N AND FO R IN T E R IN D U S T R Y OF TH E LABOR where labor services is a function of the various categories of labor input, L {\ S H IFT We adapt the method used by Gollop and Jorgenson to analyze the effects of the composition of the labor force and interindustry shifts.30 Our procedure also follows Denison’s analysis closely.31 Denison does not ac count for different occupation groups nor is he always able to weight all the separate characteristics by their specific relative wage as we do; how ever, this is because of a lack of data rather than a difference in approach. The basic technique for translog aggregation of the various compo nents of the labor force is the same as that for aggregation of the capital stock: each category of labor input is assumed to be paid the value of its marginal product in each year. Thus relative increases in the proportion of higher paid labor categories to total labor input are taken to represent increases in effective input. This assumption underlies the adjustment by Denison as well as by Gollop and Jorgenson for changes in effective labor input. To account for changes in the composition of labor input, the total hours for each sector analyzed here— the private business, private non farm business, and manufacturing sectors— are disaggregated according to sex, age, education, occupation, and employment class of worker (selfemployed or employee) for each year from 1948 to 1978. Total compen sation for each sector was disaggregated in the same manner. In all, there are 1,600 disaggregations for each sector (two groups for sex, two for worker employment class, five for education, eight for age, and ten for occupation). The interindustry disaggregation was based on the industry detail from the national income and product accounts: the private business sector is composed of sixty-two industries; the private nonfarm business sector, H = f(L u L2, . . . , Ln). Assuming / is a linear homogenous logarithmic function, the growth in labor services is the derivative with respect to time: h = £ vJi, i=l where ”• - f h= £ i=I Sector Private business Private nonfarm business Manufacturing 1965-73 Excluding pollution abatement Total capital Excluding pollution abatement Total capital 3.14 3.24 2.93 4.48 4.59 3.93 2.31 2.37 2.16 3.11 3.21 2.86 4.37 4.47 3.64 h = qLc + /, 29. Denison, “Effects of Selected Changes,” p. 42. The effects of pollution abate ment and health and safety regulations are analyzed by Denison in a different man ner. He concludes that by 1975 the annual impact of these activities as well as private expenditures for crime prevention may have contributed as much as 0.26 percentage point a year to the slowdown measured from 1969 to 1975, reaching 0.47 percentage point from 1973 to 1975. 30. Gollop and Jorgenson, “U.S. Productivity Growth.” 31. Denison, Accounting for United States Economic Growth, pp. 30-50, 219-59. For a comparison of the analyses by Denison, Gollop and Jorgenson, and Ken drick, see Kent Kunze, “Evaluation of Labor Force Composition Adjustment,” in Measurement and Interpretation of Productivity (National Academy of Sciences, forthcoming). 32. The disaggregation of the hours and compensation was resolved by use of a multiproportional matrix model. The annual hours and compensation are controlled at the industry level for employees, with only the hours and compensation for the self-employed and unpaid family workers adjusted according to the March Current Population Survey. 1973-78 2.05 2.09 1.47 S o u r c e : C o m p u te d b y a u th o r s u s in g d a ta f r o m th e B u re a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is , a . T h e a g g r e g a te s a r e b a s e d o n d ir e c t a g g r e g a tio n o f c a p ita l s to c k s . Vi(h - / ) + /. The difference (/, — l) is interpreted as the growth rate of the propor tion of total hours worked by the fth category of workers. The growth rate of labor services can thus be expressed as the sum of the rates of changes in qLCand /. That is, Annual average, in percent Excluding pollution abatement Total capital S v<= *■ We further decompose labor services into qro and /. Adding and then subtracting the growth rate in unadjusted hours from the right-hand side yields Table 6 . Rates of Growth of the Capital Stock, Total and Excluding Pollution Abatement Capital, by Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78“ 1948-65 and 35 where Table 8. Rates of Growth of Direct Effects of Labor Characteristics on Labor Composition, by Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 qLc = S t-1 Annua! average, in percent Vi(/,- - I). 0.17 0.08 0.14 0.23 0.30 -0 .1 1 0.18 0.03 0.06 -0 .0 2 0.18 -0 .1 2 0.08 -0 .2 7 -0 .2 3 0.46 0.95 1.05 0.31 0.28 0.25 Private nonfarm business 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 - 0 .0 6 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .2 3 - 0 .0 5 -0 .0 5 0.02* 0.04 -0 .3 0 - 0 .0 8 0.33 0.85 1.00 0.06 0.11 0.24 Manufacturing 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 - 0 .0 4 -0 .0 8 - 0 .0 6 -0 .0 3 0.00 0.02* 0.17 - 0 .1 6 -0 .1 7 0.49 0.81 0.75 0.30 0.36 0.52 th e B u r e a u o f th e C e n s u s a n d C a lc u la te d f o r th e 1 9 7 3 -7 6 p e rio d . 34. The ideal target concept is hours actually worked. In this paper we use the term to denote hours at the workplace, a concept that excludes paid leave (vacation, holiday, and sick leave). 35. Bureau of Labor Statistics, “Report of the BLS Task Force on Hours Worked” (BLS, March 1976). Modification of the survey to include the collection of data on hours worked is now planned. 36. Frank P. Stafford and G. I. Duncan, “The Use of Time and Technology by Households in the United States,” in Ronald G. Ehrenberg, Orley Ashenfelter, and Ronald L. Oaxaca, Research in Labor Economics, vol. 3 (JA I Press, forthcoming). 37. The Employer Expenditures for Employee Compensation survey covered 6,000 establishments, primarily large ones, from 1966 to 1974. While the data are not comparable to the time-use diaries cited by Stafford and Duncan, the sample size and frequency is considerably larger. See ibid. -0 .0 3 - 0 .0 3 0.07 S o u rc e : C o m p u te d b y a u th o r s a s e x p la in e d in th e te x t, u s in g th e m e th o d d e s c rib e d in F r a n k M . G o llo p B e a t r i c e N . V a c c a r a , e d s . , N e w D e v e lo p m e n ts in P r o d u c tiv ity M e a s u r e m e n t ( N a t i o n a l B u r e a u o f E c o n o m i c t h e U .S . B u r e a u o f t h e C e n s u s a n d t h e B u r e a u o f L a b o r 33. The data have not been developed at this time to measure the interaction for 1977 and years following. To use only the 1973-76 period would be inappropriate. - 0 .0 2 - 0 .0 0 -0.13* H O U R S W O R K E D V E R S U S H O U R S PA ID a n d D a l e W . J o r g e n s o n , “ U .S . P r o d u c t i v i t y G r o w t h b y I n d u s t r y , 1 9 4 7 - 1 9 7 3 ," in J o h n W . K e n d r i c k a n d R e s e a rc h , fo rth c o m in g ). T h e b a s ic d a ta a r e f r o m S ta tis tic s . -0 .1 1 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .2 3 Labor productivity is generally measured using hours paid as the labor input measure. The data are taken from the current employment statistics (CES) program’s survey of nonagricultural establishments, which has far greater coverage than any currently available survey of hours worked.34 A 1976 report by the BLS found that no available survey pro vides data on hours worked that are sufficiently accurate to serve as a basis for quarterly or annual measures of labor productivity.35 Insofar as hours paid exceed hours worked, the level of labor produc tivity will therefore be understated. Measured growth in labor productiv ity will be affected only if the ratio of hours worked to hours paid changes through time; the measured slowdown in productivity growth will be af fected only if the rate of change of that ratio is altered. Recent work by Stafford and Duncan,36 based on quite small samples, shows that the di vergence between hours worked and hours paid accounts for as much as one-third of the productivity slowdown. This suggests that it is worth while to use the best available data to attempt to quantify the effect. The BLS report made rough estimates of hours worked from 1952 to 1965, based on exclusion of leave from the CES data on hours paid, and from 1966 to 1975, based on the Employer Expenditures for Employee Compensation survey.37 From these data we estimated average annual rates of change in the ratio of hours worked to hours paid for 1952-65, 1965-73, and 1973-75 in private business, private nonfarm business, and manufacturing. The results, shown in table 9, are not striking. There is a small, persistent but variable decline in the ratio of hours worked to hours paid in each sector, except for manufacturing in the last period. The effects on growth of labor productivity were estimated by assuming that the aver age annual growth rates for 1952-65 and 1973-75 characterized the periods 1948-65 and 1973-78— a rather weak technique. The resulting values were weighted 'by the share of labor in total output in the three sectors. Manufacturing 0.20 0.07 0.11 Private business 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 Education attainment increased and added to effective labor input in the 1965-73 and 1973-78 periods for all sectors. Education and occupation are highly in terrelated factors, so that adjusting for education alone also captures a significant amount of the contribution from the changing occupation mix. Interindustry Labor Interindustry Labor Labor Interindustry shifts Period composition shifts shifts composition composition 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 Age a. Annual average, in percent Private nonfarm business Employment class o f worker S o u r c e : C o m p u te d b y a u t h o r s a s d e s c r ib e d in th e te x t, u s in g d a t a f r o m th e B u r e a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s , Table 7. Rates of Growth of Adjustments to Total Hours for Changes in Labor Composition and for Interindustry Shifts, by Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Private business Occupa tion Sex Sector and period The ratio of hourly compensation between categories is assumed to be equal to the ratio of marginal products for each category of labor. Two sets of indexes are computed for each of the major sectors: one for changes in sex, age, education, occupation, and class of worker; the other for changes in labor input among industries, qLl. Separation of the industry adjustment from the adjustment for labor composition assumes independence between them. This assumption was investigated by calculating a measure of labor composition using industry as one of the characteristics. If independence exists, no difference occurs between this measure and the sum of the two measures we have used, qLl and qLC. There was virtually no difference for the private business and private nonfarm business sectors in either the 1948-65 or the 1965-73 periods.33 This was not the case in the manufacturing sector, where a sig nificant interaction seemed to occur between qLG and qLI. For all sectors, the measured interaction term was added to the adjustment for labor composition. Table 7 indicates the annual growth rates for adjusted labor composi tion and adjusted interindustry shifts as computed above. (These growth rates have not been weighted by labor’s share, wL.) The contribution to labor productivity provided by the changing composition of the labor force decreased by more than 50 percent for all sectors from the 1948-65 to 1965-73 period and increased in 1973-78. The contribution of inter industry shift, on the other hand, increased significantly from the first to second period for the private business and private nonfarm business sec tors, then decreased substantially in 1973-78. Interindustry shift has had little effect in the manufacturing sector. To obtain a better understanding of the cause for the changes in labor composition, we also examined the separate direct effects of age, sex, edu cation, occupation, and class of worker, as shown in table 8. These growth rates show the composition adjustment separately for the specific characteristics. The effects are not simply additive to qLC because they are not independent; however, they do show which characteristics exhibited the largest effect on the change in the labor composition and the direction of the effects. The growth rates presented in table 8 show that age was the major factor contributing to the downward adjustment from labor composition for the first period of slowdown. In all three sectors this characteristic went from a positive to a negative annual growth rate, corresponding directly to the large increase of young workers as the postwar baby-boom cohort entered the labor market. For the private nonfarm and private business sectors the age factor reversed itself in the third period, but the increase in female entrants to the labor force seemed to compensate for this reversal. Especially rapid entry of females took place in nonfarm nonmanufacturing industries, an area that has historically shown a smaller increase in productivity. This development did not affect the manufactur ing sector. However, the age factor did continue to depress the composi tion of the labor force in manufacturing for the third period. Educational 36 perhaps the strongest proponent of this view and his quantitative esti mate of the effects of R&D is the largest.42 Kendrick regresses the totalfactor productivity (TFP) residual on a measure of the stock of ac cumulated knowledge. The quantitative estimates from this procedure depend upon how one quantifies knowledge and on how one defines TFP: if, as in Kendrick’s case, it is defined as the ratio of output to the sum of share-weighted factor inputs, the effect will be relatively large; if, as in our analysis, factor-augmenting effects are removed from TFP, the effect will be smaller. In either case, the regression will attribute to R&D the effects of all unaccounted factors insofar as they have similar inter temporal patterns. On the other hand, to the extent that the effects of R&D can be seen in capital or labor or change the capital-labor ratio, some of the effect may be missed by attributing it to other factors in the analysis. It is not clear what approach, if any, can be relied upon to cap ture all the effects. Thus, although there seems to be a consensus that the decline in R&D expenditures is partially responsible for the slowdown in productivity growth, we found no satisfactory way to include the effect in our analysis. Table 9. Rates of Change in the Ratio of Hours Worked to Hours Paid, by Sector, Selected Periods, 1952-75 Annual average, in percent - Sector Private business Private nonfarm business Manufacturing S o u rc e s: C o m p u te d by a u th o rs 1952-65 1965-73 1973-75 - 0 .0 8 - 0 .0 6 -0 .0 6 -0 .2 2 -0 .2 1 - 0 .4 0 -0 .1 4 - 0 .1 2 0.03 fro m d a ta in B u re a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s , “ R e p o rt o f th e B L S T ask F o r c e o n H o u r s W o r k e d ” ( B L S , M a r c h 1 9 7 6 ). E N E R G Y AND PR O D U CTIV ITY We can make only a limited appraisal of the impact of higher energy prices on the growth of labor productivity in the private business and private nonfarm business sectors. Data on energy use are not available by sector, but rather by the following categories: industrial, commer cial, transportation, and residential. These categories have not been mapped into the major economic sectors with sufficient accuracy to justify their inclusion in the productivity accounting framework. In addition, our framework uses a concept of output based on gross product originat ing, so that flows of intermediate products— including energy— are ex cluded, although value-added is included in the energy-producing sectors. It is possible to appraise the effects of energy price increases based on the energy share in output in the major sectors, as Denison has done. However, his procedure implicitly assumes that the elasticity of substitu tion between energy and other factors is one, and strong evidence exists to the contrary, at least for the manufacturing sector. Bemdt and Wood and Hudson and Jorgenson find complementarity between energy and capital in U.S. manufacturing;3839Griffin and Gregory, using cross-section and time-series data for several countries, find substitution.30 Our own recent investigation relied on a dynamic adjustment model of the manu facturing sector in an attempt to remove the short-term complementary use of capital and energy suggested by Griffin and Gregory as a major cause of the Berndt and Wood findings. We found stronger complemen tarity in the long-run than in the short-run version of the model.40 Using this model of the manufacturing sector, we undertook a simula tion exercise for the 1973-78 period to assess the effects of increases in energy prices on the growth of labor productivity as these effects operate through changing the capital-labor ratio. Whatever actual effect energy prices have had on this ratio is included in the total estimated effect of capital formation on productivity. Here we suggest how much of that may be attributable to higher energy prices. The simulation assumes that energy prices rose at the same rate as the implicit price deflator for manu facturing rather than at the 22.3 percent rate that actually occurred. On this basis, the model suggests that the capital-labor ratio would have in creased at an annual rate of about 2.3 percent instead of 1.7 percent. Thus labor productivity would have risen about 0.18 percentage point a year faster in manufacturing during 1973-78 if the relative price of energy had not changed. Hudson and Jorgenson also find a large reduction in investment for. the 1972-76 period resulting from higher energy prices. Their study, which uses a more complete model of the economy, includes complementarity between energy and capital.41 Accounting for the Slowdown As the preceding discussion indicates, some hypotheses about the causes of the productivity slowdown defy quantification. In table 10 we present the estimated effects of those factors that could be incorporated into this analysis for the private business, private nonfarm business, and manufacturing sectors. All three sectors show significant declines in labor productivity for both slowdown periods: the, total effect of those slow■downs is smallest in manufacturing and greatest in private business, where the farm-to-nonfarm shifts of labor and capital contributed sub stantially to growth before 1965. In private business and private nonfarm business, total-factor productivity growth, the “other factors” category in the table, declines very little between 1965-73 and 1973-78. The changes in the growth rates from table 10 are presented in table 11 as a way of detailing the contributions to the productivity slowdown from the various factors analyzed. One conclusion is immediate— two slowdowns occurred with two different patterns of contributing causes: the 1965-73 slowdown is largely unexplained by factors quantified in this analysis; the 1973-78-slowdown is largely accounted for by the rela tive weakness in capital formation. In the private business sector, the broadest aggregate, the total effects from capital formation augmented productivity growth in the first slow down period; the effect of changes in capital composition more than compensated for the slight impacts of expenditures for pollution abate ment and the capital-labor ratio. The latter effect was due entirely to slower growth in the capital-labor ratio in the farm sector, where the growth of the capital-labor ratio slowed largely because the rapid migra tion of labor from the farm sector had ended. Labor effects in the first slowdown period in the private business sector were small, although they contributed somewhat to the slowdown. Favorable interindustry shift effects were more than offset by a decline in the ratio of hours worked to hours paid and changes in the composition of the labor force. The domi nant effect in the first slowdown period comes from other factors, which account for more than 90 percent of the total aecline in the growth of labor productivity. Different factors account for the productivity slowdown in the second period.,.Capital effects account for 0.79 percentage point out of a total decline of 1.12 percentage points. In this period the decline in growth of the .eapitaHabor. ratio contributes the largest effect, but changes in the asset and interindustry composition also add to the slowdown, and capi tal spending for pollution abatement makes a small negative contribution as well. Labpx.effects contribute somewhat more to the 1973—78 slow down than in the earlier period, but the pattern is quite different. Changes in the composition of the labor force resulting largely from increased R E S E A R C H AND D E V E L O P M E N T A number of investigators have argued that research and development expenditures have important effects on productivity growth. Kendrick is 38. Ernst R. Berndt and David O. Wood, “Technology, Prices, and the Derived Demand for Energy,” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 57 (August 1975), pp. 259-68; Hudson and Jorgenson, “Energy Prices.” 39. James M. Griffin and Paul R. Gregory, “An Intercountry Translog Model of ' Energy Substitution Responses,” American Economic Review, vol. 66 (December 1976), pp. 845-57. 40. J. R. Norsworthy and Michael J. Harper, “Productivity Growth in Manufac turing in the 1980’s: Labor, Capital, and Energy, in American Statistical Association, Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section (Washington, D.C.: ASA, forthcoming). The study was based on a four-factor model (capital, labor, energy, and intermediate materials) of manufacturing using energy data from Bureau of the Census, Census o f Manufactures, for 1958, 1963, 1967, 1972, and 1977; and Bureau of the Census, Annual Survey of Manufactures, for intermediate years. 41. Hudson and Jorgenson, “Energy Prices,” p. 1.33. 42. John W. Kendrick, The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital, General Series, 100 (National Bureau of Economic Research, 1976). Kendrick represents the stock of accumulated knowledge by the capitalized value of research and develop ment expenditures. 37 Table 10. Rates of Growth of Labor Productivity and of Capital and Labor Effects on Productivity, by Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Annual average, in percent Private business Item Private nonfarm business 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 Labor productivity growth 3.32 2.32 1.20 2.77 2.02 1.09 Capital effect Capital-labor ratio Asset composition Intersectoral shifts Pollution abatement capital Total 0.76 0.06 0.12 0.00* 0.94 0.75 0.10 0.17 - 0 .0 3 “ 0.99 0.21 0.05 0.03 - 0 .0 9 0.20 0.68 0.05 0.00 -0.01* 0.72 0.84 0.08 0.00 -0.04* 0.88 0.12 0.15 0.06 0.20 0.10 -0 .0 7 0.12 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .0 5 0.22 - 0 .1 4 0.12 - 0 .0 9 - 0 .0 6 2.16 1.21 1.06 Labor effect Labor force composition Interindustry shifts Ratio of hours worked to hours paid Total Effect o f other factors Manufacturing 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 3.13 2.47 1.70 0.20 0.04 0.00 - 0 .0 9 0.15 0.54 0.03 n.a. -0 .0 3 * 0.54 0.72 0.05 n.a. -0.09* 0.68 0.44 0.03 n.a. - 0 .1 9 0.28 0.01 0.12 0.04 - 0 .0 8 0.14 - 0 .0 2 0.05 - 0 .0 2 0.08 0.05 - 0 .0 4 0.06 - 0 .1 4 -0 .0 1 - 0 .0 8 - 0 .1 2 - 0 .0 4 0.08 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .0 4 0.02 0.15 1.99 1.15 1.06 2.51 1.83 1.27 S o u rc e s : C o m p u te d b y a u th o r s a s e x p la in e d in th e te x t, u s in g d a ta fr o m th e B u re a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is a n d th e B u re a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s , a . A s in d i c a t e d i n t h e te x t, e s tim a te s f o r th e s e p e r i o d s a r e b a s e d o n p a r t i a l d a t a , V n .a . N o t a v a ila b le . education have a positive effect on productivity growth, as does the ratio of hours worked to hours paid (though, again, the data underlying this latter estimate are weak). Interindustry shifts of the labor force have a strong negative influence. Other factors play a much smaller role than in the 1965-73 slowdown; only about 13 percent of the 1973-78 slowdown in the private business sector is not accounted for by the measured capital and labor effects. i downward push on productivity from interindustry shifts more than off setting small contributions in the other direction from the composition of the labor force and changes in hours worked. As in the private business sector, the measured capital and labor effects account for most of the 1973—78 slowdown in productivity growth in the private nonfarm busi ness sector. In the private nonfarm business sector the pattern in the first slowdown period is'generally similar to that for the private business sector, although capital effects are even more favorable to productivity growth because the capital-labor ratio grows more rapidly in 1965-73 than in 194865. The pattern of labor effects is quite similar to that in private business, although the net impact is slightly smaller. And other factors are again the dominant slowdown factor. Indeed, after adjusting for capital and labor effects, the contribution to the slowdown of other factors is some what larger than the slowdown in labor productivity itself. The productivity slowdown pattern in the manufacturing sector is similar to that for private nonfarm business in 1965-73: capital effects contribute to faster productivity growth, and total labor effects reduce it. During this period, the acceleration of the capital-labor ratio in creased productivity growth by about 0.2 percentage point a year, but was partially offset by expenditures for pollution abatement capital and a slight asset effect. Labor effects made a small contribution to the slowdown, largely through changes in the composition of the labor force. Other factors not accounted for in the analysis dominate the productivity decline in manufacturing in the first slowdown period. In the second period, capital effects contribute nearly 80 percent of the observed slowdown in labor productivity. As in the private business sec tor, the dominant impact comes from slower growth in the capital-labor ratio. Capital spending for pollution abatement and changes in the asset mix each have a small effect. Labor effects contribute somewhat, with a In the 1973-78 period, some differences emerge between the manu facturing sector and the private nonfarm business sector. The productiv ity slowdown is somewhat smaller in manufacturing. Capital effects, dominated by slower growth in the capital-labor ratio, are more strongly influenced by expenditures for pollution abatement capital. The effect, Table 11. Contributions to the Slowdown in the Growth of Labor Productivity, by Sector, 1965-78* A n n u a l average, in percentage points Private business Item 1965-73 1973- 78 slowdown slowdown Private nonfarm business Total 1965-73 1973-78 slowdown slowdown Total Manufacturing 1965-73 1973-78 slowdown slowdown Total Change in labor productivity growth - 1 .0 0 -1 .1 2 - 2 .1 2 -0 .7 5 -0 .9 3 -1 .6 8 -0 .6 6 -0 .7 7 -1 .4 3 Contribution from capital effect Capital-labor ratio Asset composition Intersectoral shifts Pollution abatement capital Total -0 .0 1 0.04 0.05 -0 .0 3 0.05 - 0 .5 4 - 0 .0 5 - 0 .1 4 - 0 .0 6 - 0 .7 9 - 0 .5 5 -0 .0 1 - 0 .0 9 - 0 .0 9 - 0 .7 4 0.16 0.03 0.00 -0 .0 3 0.16 -0 .6 4 - 0 .0 4 0.00 -0 .0 5 -0 .7 3 -0 .4 8 -0 .0 1 0.00 -0 .0 8 -0 .5 7 0.18 0.02 n.a. -0 .0 6 0.14 -0 .2 8 - 0 .0 2 n.a. - 0 .1 0 - 0 .4 0 -0 .1 0 0.00 n.a. -0 .1 6 - 0 .2 6 Contribution from labor effect Labor force composition Interindustry shifts Ratio of hours worked to hours paid Total - 0 .0 6 0.05 0.04 -0 .2 7 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .2 2 -0 .1 1 0.14 0.03 - 0 .2 0 -0 .0 8 - 0 .0 6 -0 .0 9 0.00 0.03 0.07 - 0 .0 6 0.07 -0 .0 9 -0 .1 0 0.05 -0 .1 8 - 0 .0 4 -0 .2 8 - 0 .1 0 -0 .0 7 0.06 -0 .1 1 - 0 .0 4 -0 .1 8 -0 .0 3 - 0 .1 2 0.09 0.19 0.06 0.07 Contribution from effect o f other factors -0 .9 5 -0 .1 5 - 1 .1 0 - 0 .8 4 - 0 .0 9 -0 .9 3 -0 .6 8 - 0 .5 6 - 1 .2 4 S o u r c e : D e r i v e d f r o m t h e r e s u l t s o f t a b l e 10. a . T h e 1 9 6 5 - 7 3 s l o w d o w n is m e a s u r e d r e la tiv e t o t h e 1 9 4 8 - 6 5 b a s e p e r i o d ; t h e 1 9 7 3 - 7 8 s l o w d o w n , r e l a t i v e t o t h e 1 9 6 5 - 7 3 s l o w d o w n , n .a . N o t a v a ila b le . 38 however, is still small in manufacturing, where a major impact of envi ronmental regulations would be expected to be felt. Capital effects, how ever, explain only about half of the 1973-78 slowdown in manufacturj ing, a much smaller proportion than in private nonfarm business. The labor effects augmented productivity growth. Thus, in the second period, j other factors play a larger role in the slowdown of the manufacturing secj tor than in the other sectors. I The slowdown patterns for the nonfarm nonmanufacturing sector that are implied by the nonfarm and manufacturing results in tables 10 and 11 are summarized in table 12. The capital effects were determined by weighting the capital effects in each sector by the relative size "of their capital stock. A similar procedure was used for labor productivity and labor effects based On the nonfarm nonmanufacturing share in the hours of private nonfarm business labor.43 In this sector, productivity again slows noticeably in both periods. In the first period, total capital effects work against the slowdown, while total labor effects contribute to it and are noticeably larger than those for all nonfarm business. As in the private nonfarm business sector, other x factors are the primary source of the decline in productivity growth. Al most all the second slowdown is explained by capital and labor effects that parallel those in total private nonfarm business, so that other factors play a minor role. For any of the major sectors analyzed here, to view the productivity slowdown as a single phenomenon beginning in the mid-1960s would dis tort the temporal pattern of contributions to it, and would likely lead to poor policy prescription. From the evidence of the recent period, the un explained decline in multifactor productivity growth is largely behind us, while the problem of capital formation is current. It also appears that the changing composition of the labor force has contributed somewhat less to the slowdown in either period than some other estimates have suggested and, correspondingly, may offer somewhat less hope for reversal in the future. Table 13. Rates of Growth of Input Prices, Private Nonfarm Business Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Annual average, in percent Effect o f other factors 2.57 1.78 0.80 0.78 0.95 0.11 0.11 - 0 .1 0 -0 .2 2 1.68 0.93 0.91 1965-73 slowdown 1973-78 slowdown -0 .7 9 -0 .9 8 0.17 -0 .8 4 -0 .2 1 -0 .1 2 -0 .7 5 -0 .0 2 Total - 1 .7 7 -0 .6 7 -0 .3 3 -0 .7 7 ta b le s 10 a n d to a tr a n s lo g 1 9 7 3 - 7 7 . I t is b a s e d o n t h e r a t i o o f t o t a l c o s t in d e x o f e le c tr ic ity , c o a l, c o k e , f u e l o il, a n d n a tu ra l B u r e a u o f t h e C e n s u s , C e n su s o f M a n u fa c tu r e s . T h e w h o l e s a l e p r i c e i n d e x w a s u s e d t o labor grew about 2 percentage points a year faster than the price of capital services in 1948-65, more than 4 points faster in 1965-73, and 1 point faster in 1973-78. These differences measure the relative price change of labor as compared to capital: the price incentive to substitute capital for labor was thus about twice as strong in 1965-73 as it was in the earliest period, and about four times as great as in 1973-78. A factor holding down the relative price of capital services in 1965-73 was the investment tax credit for equipment that went into effect in the mid-1960s. The relative price explanation for the acceleration in the capital-labor ratio in the 1965-73 period also explains the deceleration in 1973-78, when the relative price change was so small. The rapid rise in energy prices that took place in late 1973 and early 1974 may be another impor tant factor contributing to the slowdown in this last period. If capital and energy are complements, the rise in energy prices would have retarded capital formation.45 The weak productivity growth of recent years has corresponded with a rapid and continued rise in employment from the trough of the 197375 recession through early 1979. This phenomenon, which has been widely observed and described as puzzling, is consistent with the much closer movements in the prices of capital and labor and the complemen tarity between capital and energy. Under these conditions, increases in output would be achieved with relatively greater expansion of labor input and less expansion of capital (and hence energy) than under the price conditions that prevailed since 1948 in general, and in the 1965-73 period in particular. This tentative explanation is consistent with findings by Hudson and Jorgenson for the 1973-76 period.46 The main conclusions of our investigation of the slowdown in the growth of labor productivity can be summarized briefly. There are two distinct phases to the slowdown in the growth of labor productivity: 1965-73 and 1973-78. Differences are apparent both in the pattern of productivity growth among industries and in the factors contributing to the decline. The 1965-73 slowdown is largely unexplained by the factors we have considered. Capital formation was not a cause; changes in the composi tion of the labor force played a relatively minor role. Although R&D ex penditures slowed during this period and may well have contributed to the productivity slowdown, we devised no satisfactory means to take this factor into account. Intersectoral shifts of capital and labor did not con tribute. The 1973-78 slowdown is dominated by the effects of reduced capital formation. Some effect is also attributable to interindustry shifts in labor and capital. The sharp rise in energy prices may show up in a framework such as ours through its impact on capital formation and may help ex plain the relative weakness in capital formation in recent years. V* 11 a s d e s c r i b e d i n t h e t e x t . 43. Direct computation would have been preferable. However, the difference in patterns between the nonfarm business and manufacturing sectors did not emerge until it was too late to compute these effects directly. Although the total effects for capital, labor, and other factors reported in table 12 would change very little when directly computed, detailed effects of changes in factor composition and interindus try shifts would be revealed. 44. Data for the private nonfarm business sector are shown because the slowdown in capital formation in agriculture began before 1973-78, and the relative rise of wages in the agriculture sector further obscures the relative price movements that prevailed in private nonfarm business. -0 .7 3 4.73 22.29 in te r p o la te s o m e p r ic e c o m p o n e n ts b e tw e e n C e n s u s b e n c h m a r k s . Contribution to slowdown (percentage points) S o u rc e : D a ta a r e in fe rre d fro m 4.60 6.58 8.98 o f p u r c h a s e d f u e ls in m a n u f a c tu r in g Rate o f growth (percent) 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 2.84 2.20 7.95 g a s q u a n titie s fro m Annual average Labor effect 1948-65 1965-73 1973-78 S o u rc e : J . R . N o rs w o rth y a n d M ic h a e l J . H a rp e r, “ T h e R o le o f C a p ita l F o r m a tio n in th e R e c e n t P r o Table 12. Capital and Labor Effects on the Growth of Labor Productivity, Private Nonfarm Nonmanufacturing Sector, Selected Periods, 1948-78 Capital effect Price o f energy input“ a . T h e e n e r g y p r ic e s e r ie s is f o r 1 9 5 4 - 6 5 , 1 9 6 5 - 7 3 , a n d Because slower capital formation appears to have been a major cause of the slowdown in labor productivity in the 1973-78 period, it is impor tant to understand why. Table 13 attempts to shed light on this ques tion.41 The acceleration of the capital-labor ratio in 1965-73 may be ex plained by price-induced substitution of capital for labor. The price of Total labor productivity Labor compensation per hour d u c tiv ity G r o w t h S lo w d o w n ,” W o r k in g P a p e r 8 7 , ( B u r e a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s , J a n u a r y 1 9 7 9 ). Factors Affecting Capital Formation Item and period Period Price o f capital services 45. There are, of course, other dimensions to the problem, and therefore to a sat isfactory explanation for it. For example, an accelerator model of capital accumula tion is examined in Peter K. Clark, “Investment in the 1970s: Theory, Performance, and Prediction,” BPEA, 1:1979, pp. 73-113. The slowdown in output growth of more than 1 percentage point a year between 1965-73 and 1973-78 would also explain part of the slowdown in capital formation in the latter period. 46. Hudson and Jorgenson, “Energy Prices.” 39 Fart III. Productivity Trends nn SndMstries and the Federal Government number of studies of labor requirements for defense in dustries, such as synthetic rubber and shipbuilding. After the war, the industry studies program resumed on a regular basis, and was supplemented by a number of industry studies based on the direct collection of data from employers. Budget restrictions after 1952 prevented the continuation of direct collection of data. Consequently, the preparation of industry measures is largely limited to those industries where readily available data can be used to construct measures. In recent years, public interest in productivity has grown, and increases in output per employee hour have been recognized as important indicators of economic progress and a means to higher income levels, rather than merely a threat to job opportunities. The industry studies cover a variety of manufacturing and nonmanufacturing industries at the 2-, 3-, and 4-digit Standard Industrial Classification level. Measures for these industries are published on an an nual basis and are provided for most years between 1947 or 1958 and the most recent year for which data are available. Coverage has been expanded to include industries in trade and services, and with the increasing importance of the public sector, to various functional areas in the Federal Government. Productivity measurement in the Federal Government was initiated by a request from the Joint Economic Committee in the fall of 1970 to the General Accounting Office in conjunction with the Of fice of Management and Budget and the Civil Service Commission (now Office of Personnel Management). A joint Federal productivity measurement task force con sisting of-these agencies, with technical assistance and support from b l s , was established. This task force col lected data and constructed indexes for fiscal years 1967-71. In July 1973, the Office of Management and Budget endorsed the continuation of the project to measure Federal productivity, and b l s assumed full responsibility for collecting input, output, and related information, in addition to the development of produc tivity measures. Since July 1973, the Bureau has been expanding coverage to include organizational units not previously covered, improving the quality of some of the input and output data, and refining the methodological pro This section includes a brief historical introduction to productivity measurement in industries and in the Federal Government. Methods, sources, and uses of the measures are discussed and an excerpt from the most recently published compilation of industry productivity measures serves as an example of recent results. One essay analyzes the difficulties in measuring pro ductivity in service industries and explores their solu tion. The complexities of measuring output per hour in government are also discussed. The articles on labor productivity trends in several industries examine the fac tors underlying productivity change over time. B a c k g ro u n d Studies of output per employee hour in individual in dustries have long been a part of the b l s program. A study of 60 manufacturing industries in 1898, prompted by congressional concern that human labor was being displaced by machinery, was presented in the report Hand and Machine Labor; this provided striking evidence of the savings in labor resulting from mechanization in the last half of the 19th century. The impact of productivity advance upon employment re mained an important focus of b l s throughout the. 1920’s and 19305s. Also during this period, the Bureau began the preparation and publication of industry in dexes of output per employee hour, which were based on available production data from the periodic Census of Manufactures and employment statistics collected by BLS. In 1940, Congress authorized the Bureau of Labor Statistics to undertake continuing studies of productivi ty and technological changes. The Bureau extended earlier indexes of output per employee hour developed by the National Research Project of the Works Progress Administration, and published measures for selected in dustries. This work, however, was reduced in volume during World War II, owing to the lack of meaningful production and employee hour data for many manufac turing industries. The advent of World War II also caused a change in the emphasis of the program from problems of unemployment to concern with the most efficient utilization of scarce labor resources, b l s undertook a 40 cedures used to construct productivity indexes. The measurement program is part of a multifaceted effort sponsored by the Office of Personnel Management and includes analysis, enhancement, and diffusion of pro ductivity improvement ideas. The Bureau is also expanding its productivity measurement program by explicitly accounting for other inputs besides labor in the industry measures and developing a supplementary set of productivity measures. The new measures are referred to as multifac tor productivity measures. The industry multifactor series are designed to measure changes in productivity by relating changes in an industry’s output not only to changes in labor input but also to changes in capital and intermediate pur chases. In addition to providing indicators of produc tivity change useful for analysis in their own right, such measures also are helpful in analyzing the causes of change in output per employee hour or labor productivity. liethods and Sources industries Output per employee hour Bls computes an index of output per employee hour by dividing an output index by an index of aggregate employee hours. For most industries, measures are prepared separately relating output to (a) all employee hours, (b) production worker hours, and (c) nonproduc tion worker hours. (The standard definitions of produc tion workers and nonproduction workers are used.) Three corresponding measures also are computed relating output to the number of employees. For in dustries in trade and services, measures are prepared relating output to the hours of all persons involved in producing that output, including self-employed and un paid family workers. Output Bls industry output indexes are based on quantifiable units of products or services of the industry combined with fixed period weights. Whenever possible, physical quantities are used as the unit of measurement. For those industries lacking quantity data, constant-dollar value of shipments, sales, or revenue data are used to develop the output series. This procedure is used almost exclusively for the nongoods-producing industries. For manufacturing and mining industries, quantity data on physical output are usually most comprehensive for years covered by a census. To make maximum use of the comprehensive census data, output indexes are derived from data for two consecutive censuses; these indexes are referred to as benchmark indexes. For intercensal years, annual indexes are based on either physical out put data (generally in less detail than for census years) or, if such data are not available, value of output ad justed for price change (the value of output in constant dollars). The annual series subsequently are adjusted to the benchmark levels for the census years. Sources. Industry output indexes are prepared from basic data published by various public and private agen cies, using the greatest level of detail available. Data from the Bureau of the Census, U.S. Depart ment of Commerce, are used extensively in developing output statistics for manufacturing, trade, and service industries. The Bureau of Mines, U.S. Department of the Interior, compiles most of the information for the mining and cement industries. Other important Govern ment sources include the U.S. Department of Energy, the Department of Agriculture, the Fish and Wildlife Service, U.S. Department of the Interior, the Interstate Commerce Commission, the Internal Revenue Service, and the Civil Aeronautics Board. Important sources of trade association data include the Textile Economics Bureau, Inc., N ational Association of Hosiery Manufacturers, Inc., National Canners Association, Rubber Manufacturers Association, and the American Iron and Steel Institute. For deflated value series, industry price indexes are derived from producer and consumer price indexes developed by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Employee hours An index of employee hours is computed by dividing the aggregate employee hours for each year by the baseperiod aggregate. Employee hours are treated as homogeneous and additive with no distinction made between hours of different groups of employees. Data on changes in qualitative aspects of employee hours, such as skill, efficiency, health, experience, age, and sex of persons comprising the aggregate are not used and generally are not available. For mining and manufactur ing industries, employee hour indexes are constructed for employees, production workers, and nonproduction workers. For service and trade industries, indexes are constructed for the hours of all persons, which includes paid employees, partners, proprietors, and unpaid fami ly workers. Sources. Industry employment and employee hour in dexes are developed from basic data compiled by the Bureau of Labor Statistics or the Bureau of the Census. For trade and service industries, these data are sup plemented with data from the Internal Revenue Service. Federal Gowerninent Indexes of output per employee year, output, and employee years for selected functional areas of Govern ment activity4 and for the more than 400 participating 41 ment. Therefore, the overall statistics do not represent ‘‘Federal productivity” but rather, the weighted average of the productivity changes of the measured Federal organizations included in the sample. organizations are constructed in a manner similar to that described for industries. At the present time, these measures cover about 67 percent (1.9 million employee years) of the Federal civilian work force. Ideally, a productivity index should relate final out puts to their associated direct and indirect input(s), and, in fact, the output data are final from the perspective of the funtional areas within which these data are classified. However, since the outputs of one organiza tion may be consumed wholly or partially by another Federal organization in the production of its final out puts, all output indicators in the Federal sample may not be final from the perspective of a higher level organization; for example, the entire Federal Govern- Presentation Bls industry indexes are published annually in the bulletin, Productivity Measures fo r Selected Industries. A limited amount of the most current data is provided in an annual news release. As new industry indexes are developed, they are presented as articles in the Monthly Labor Review. The articles contain an analysis of pro ductivity, output, and employment trends in the in dustry. Technical notes describing the methodology used to develop the indexes are available on request. Unpublished indexes for all 4-, 3-, and 2-digit sic manufacturing industries are available for analytical purposes upon request. Federal Government indexes are published annually in the Monthly Labor Review. Indexes of output per employee hour also are publish ed in the Statistical Abstract o f the United States and in the Handbook o f Labor Statistics. Some indexes for earlier years are published in Historical Statistics o f the United States. 4 The 28 functions are: Audit of operations; Buildings and grounds; Communications; Education and training; Electric power production and distribution; Equipment maintenance; Finance and accounting; General support services; Information services; Legal and judicial activities; Library services; Loans and grants; Medical services; Military base services; Natural resources and environmental management; Personnel in vestigations; Personnel management; Postal services; Printing and duplication; Procurem ent; Records m anagem ent; R egula tion—compliance and enforcement; Regulation— rulemaking and licensing; Social services and benefits; Specialized manufacturing; Supply and inventory control; Traffic management; and Transpota tion. 42 Highlights of Recent Trends in Output Per Employee Hour Current developments From 1980 to 1981, output per employee hour in creased in nearly two-thirds of the industries for which data are presented in this report. In contrast, from 1979 to 1980, productivity fell in about two-thirds of the in dustries. The gains in industry productivity in 1981 were consistent with the performance of the nonfarm busi ness sector as a whole, where productivity increased by 1.4 percent. Among the large manufacturing industries, the steel industry recorded a gain of 9.0 percent in productivity after two consecutive years of productivity declines. Buoyed by strong sales to the oil and gas industry, steel output was up 9.8 percent in 1981, while hours grew by only 0.7 percent. Another large manufacturing industry, motor vehi cles, experienced a 4.7-percent growth in output per employee hour in 1981. This was in sharp contrast to the three previous years, in which productivity fell. Rebounding somewhat from a very poor year in 1980, output in the industry increased by 5.9 percent while employee hours grew by only 1.2 percent. Among the other large manufacturing industries, the tire and inner tubes industry posted a gain in produc tivity of 13.3 percent. Output in this industry was up by 8.6 percent, sustained by demand from the replace ment market, while hours continued to decline. Aside from demand strength, many old and inefficient tire plants were closed in 1980, which contributed to the sharp productivity gain 1981. Other large manufacturing industries which recorded increases in productivity in 1981 included: Synthetic fi bers (6.3 percent), bakery products (6.2 percent), gray iron foundries (5.9 percent), fluid milk (4.7 percent), fabricated structural metal (4.7 percent), corrugated and solid fiber boxes (2.7 percent), paper, paperboard, and pulp mills (2.0 percent), and electric motors and gen erators (1.3 percent). However, three relatively large manufacturing indus tries posted productivity declines in 1981. In sawmills and planing mills, output per employee hour was down 2.6 percent, while the footwear industry recorded a falloff in productivity of 3.6 percent. The construction machinery and equipment industry also posted a drop in productivity—5.4 percent in 1981. All the mining industries covered experienced pro ductivity gains in 1981. Coal mining posted its second Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 2155 (1982), Productivity Measures f o r Selected Industries, 1954-81. 43 consecutive large productivity gain, rising 9.2 percent in 1981. Although coal output was down slightly (-1.3 percent) from the previous year, hours continued to decline sharply, resulting in the productivity gain. Pro ductivity advances in the other mining industries were not as great as for coal. Iron mining (usable ore) rose 6.7 percent, copper mining (recoverable metal) in creased 5.5 percent, and nonmetallic minerals gained 1.7 percent. Both copper and iron mining had large output increases in 1981, in contrast to sharp declines in 1980. The productivity gain in nonmetallic minerals, on the other hand, was based on a drop in output, due to poor demand from the construction industry, and an even larger decline in hours. Productivity changes were mixed among transporta tion and utility industries. Productivity was up 5.4 per cent in telephone communications as output grew 5.6 percent. In railroads, productivity rose 5.2 percent. Out put in the railroad industry declined for the second straight year, dropping 0.7 percent, while hours con tinued to fall, declining 5.6 percent. After four consecu tive years of declines, productivity in the trucking in dustry advanced 4.7 percent even though output dropped 4.9 percent; the number of employees was down by 9.2 percent. On the other hand, productivity registered a small decline of 0.3 percent in the air trans portation industry. The general economic downturn and the air traffic controllers’ strike contributed to the falloff in productivity. Productivity also fell in both gas (-3.8 percent) and electric utilities (-0.7 percent). Out put was down in gas utilities as many consumers cur tailed usage due to rising prices, while hours were up due to the growing number of customers. Output was up in electric utilities only 0.8 percent, well below the long-term rate of 6.6 percent, while hours grew 1.6 per cent, resulting in the productivity falloff. Productivity dropped sharply (-8.3 percent) in petroleum pipelines as output fell for the second consecutive year due to declining demand for petroleum products, while hours increased. In trade and services, productivity changes also were varied. Productivity grew 1.5 percent in retail food stores, as output was up 1.9 percent and hours grew 0.4 percent. New car dealer productivity was up 1.4 percent. Gasoline service station productivity rose 1.2 percent. Output was down 2.1 percent in this industry, as demand was off due to increased gasoline prices and more fuel efficient cars, while hours fell even more as marginal stations were closed and self-service stations became more prevalent. Productivity in both eating and drinking places and hotels and motels declined 1.9 per cent as small gains in output were more than compen sated for by larger gains in hours. Productivity in drug stores fell 2.7 percent as output declined 1.9 percent and hours were up slightly. In the laundry and clean ing industry, productivity fell 3.2 percent due to a con tinued, decline in demand for the industry’s services re sulting in an output drop of 7.2 percent, while hours fell 4.2 percent. terial handling procedures, a new technique for firing tile became widespread. These changes resulted in sig nificant labor savings for the industry. The wood office furniture industry posted a 7.0-percent annual growth in productivity, far outstripping its rate of 1.1 percent in the previous period. Productivity was enhanced by substantial output growth in the late seventies as wood furniture captured a large share of the market from metal office furniture. Among the industries that experienced productivity declines during the 1976-81 period, the brick and struc tural clay tile industry dropped the most (-5.7 percent per year). Other industries in which productivity de clined substantially (more than 2 percent per year) dur ing the period were: Cosmetics and other toiletries (-3.4 percent), laundry and cleaning services (-3.2 percent), hydraulic cement (-2.5 percent), petroleum pipelines (-2.2 percent), and blended and prepared flour (-2.1 per cent). (See table 1.) Long-term ftreimdte With one exception, all of the industries in this re port recorded average annual increases in productivity over the long term (1947-81 for many of these indus tries). The metal forming machine tools industry re corded an average annual change in productivity of -0.1 percent over the 1958-81 period. A combination of fac tors worked against a productivity increase in the ma chine tools industry, including the tendency of machine tool firms to keep highly skilled workers on the payroll even when output falls during cyclical slowdowns. Ad ditionally, machine tools are not mass produced al though they may make mass production processes pos sible in user industries. The parts and components of a finished machine tool are usually made in relatively small batches and require comparatively large amounts of labor. On the other hand, the wet corn milling industry posted the highest long-term rate of growth in produc tivity (7.1 percent per year). Growth in this industry’s output and productivity was modest until 1972 when an explosion in output resulted from the rapid market penetration of high fructose and glucose corn syrups. The industry, previously highly capital intensive, be came even more so with large infusions of capital. Although the rates of productivity change varied widely among the industries during the 1976-81 period (see chart 1), three-fourths of the industries recorded lower average annual gains in this more recent period than during the 1947-76 period. This experience matches the productivity record of the nonfarm business economy as a whole. From 1947 to 1976, productivity in this sector grew 2.3 percent per year while from 1976 to 1981 the annual growth rate was only 0.1 percent. The slower growth in productivity among the indus tries included in this report was associated with less rapid output growth in the later period. However, there were a few notable exceptions to the falloff in productivity growth during the 1976-81 pe riod. In addition to wet corn milling, the ceramic wall and floor tile industry recorded a substantial improve ment in the rate of productivity growth in the last few years—7.4 percent a year. Coupled with changes in ma measures Millwork SIC 2431. Labor productivity in the mill work industry rose at an average annual rate of 1.4 percent from 1958 to 1980, a modest advance when compared with total manufacturing. Over this period, output in millwork increased at a rate of 2.7 percent annually and employee hours at 1.3 percent. The pro ductivity rise partly reflected low growth in capital in vestment, particularly over the past decade, and, evi dently, slow diffusion of modernized production tech nologies. These factors, combined with instability in demand for the industry’s products, retarded produc tivity growth. Approximately three-fourths of the industry’s output is used in residential housing, including additions and alterations; small amounts of output are used in com mercial and educational buildings, prefabricated wooden buildings, and in trailers and other transporta tion equipment. Millwork output is thus linked mainly to residential construction where fluctuations have been frequent and substantial. The basic technology used in millwork plants dates from the 1930’s and 1940’s; however, advances in pro duction techniques have been numerous. For example, the versatility of machines fabricating moldings has been greatly extended so that a large variety of complex molding profiles can be cut and grooved at great speeds without loss of precision and insignificnt loss in setup time. Significant advances have also been made in ad hesive applications. High-speed production requires rapid curing, and the gluing process is therefore usu ally an integral part of the production process. Certain radio-frequency gluing devices have reduced curing time from 20 to 2 minutes. A modest trend toward au tomated systems in the industry is underway, furthered 44 C h art 1. G ro w th in o u tp u t p er e m p l o y e e h o u r in s e l e c t e d industries, 1976-81 (Average annual percent change) Fluid milk Telephone communications ■ ■ '/ -L Iron mining, usable ore Malt beverages Prim ary copper, lead, and zinc AH . 0 ■ .••••• , y • , y y y . ; ;- . . . y . y y ; ■p-“ - :"v . 1 . ' . __ ■■■:.■~ .■___!■-, . r : .. - - 1 - : - . V Coal mining Tires and inner tubes Flour and other grain mill products .■ ?. - ■ ■ n B B H | mm ■f < Metal cans y:;./;;...V :a:Iaa. Air transportation _____ Steel '-H A \C n':-.r ~ ' ■ Crushed and broken stone Fabricated structural metal Electric lamps ■■ . Paints and allied products All tobacco products Machine tools Franchised new car dealers Retail food stores Motor vehicles Aluminum rolling and drawing Gas and electric utilities Construction machinery and equipment Ball and roller bearings JjglS teel foundries Bpetroleum pipelines (H ydrau lic cement __MLaundry and cleaning services (B rick and structural clay tile by the declining costs of numerical conrols, which more and more entail one-station systems featuring micro computers. This trend also involves computer-controlled materials handling systems, robotized transfer and palletizing, and carousels interfacing with con veyors, robots, and other material handling devices. tially below the 2.8-percent rate for all manufacturing. The productivity gain in the office furniture industry resulted from growth in output averaging 5.5 percent annually and employee hours averaging 3.6 percent. The growth in productivity in the industry has been comparatively low, in large part because of relatively short production runs engendered by product proliferation. A number of factors have shaped the demand for of fice furniture and the industry’s output growth. Some Office furniture (SIC 252). Between 1958 and 1980, output per employee hour in the office furniture indus try advanced at an annual rate of 1.8 percent, substan 45 of these factors are the growth of the white-collar work force, the amount of available office space, replacement demand, and the introduction of new products. Un doubtedly, the most important factor influencing the long-term output growth has been the increase of the white-collar work force. During the period under study (1958-80), white-collar employment increased from about 27 million to nearly 53 million and currently ac counts for slightly more than one-half of the total em ployed work force. Productivity growth in the industry has been en hanced by the increased use of more automatic machin ery; new materials such as particleboard, quick-setting glues, and improved finishes; better workflow layout; and computerized recordkeeping. Cosmetics and other toiletries (SIC 2844). Productivity increased at an average annual rate of 4.0 percent from 1958 to 1980—substantially above the 2.8-percent rate for the manufacturing sector. This growth was associ ated with average annual increases of 7.3 percent in output and 3.1 percent in employee hours. Productiv ity gains have resulted primarily from a trend toward fewer and larger plants producing a greater level of output, and continued improvements in production and packaging operations. The changes in output per employee hour have not been steady. Since 1958, annual increases in productiv ity have ranged from a high of 14.9 percent to a low of 0.4 percent. Declines in productivity occurred in 6 years, the most recent in 1980 when a drop of 11.4 per cent was recorded. The decline in 1980 was the largest single-year decline noted. Productivity should benefit from continued improve ments in the production process and in the equipment used. Increased utilization of computer technology may also contribute to productivity gains. Substantial de mand for the industry’s products is expected to continue. to give the workpieces their final shape. However, ad vances in the feeding mechanisms permit preforming of the pieces to such an extent that they can enter the dies without the usual need for heating. Farm and garden machinery (SIC 352). Productivity in farm and garden machinery manufacturing grew at a rate of 2.6 percent from 1958 to 1980, with output increasing at 4.2 percent per year and hours growing 1.5 percent per year. The rate of productivity gain was about the same as the average for all manufacturing in dustries over the period measured. Productivity growth in the farm machinery industry can be divided into three distinct periods. During 195865, productivity grew at a rate of 1.7 percent; in 196574, it accelerated to a rate of 3.3 percent per year; and in 1974-80, it slowed to 0.2 percent. The higher rate of gain during the 1965-74 period can be associated with a number of years of very high output and productiv ity growth, fueled by dramatic increases in farm income. The introduction of new technology including nu merical control of machine tools, computer-controlled warehousing facilities, and industrial robots, which have been adopted mainly by the larger firms in the indus try, has aided productivity growth. On the other hand, productivity growth has been moderated by the vari able nature of demand, which is affected by cyclical changes and changes in farm income. For example, al most every decline in productivity can be associated with a drop in output. In turn, industry output declines tend to be roughly coincident with downturns in the economy. Pumps and compressors (SIC 3561,3563). Output per employee hour in pump and compressor manufacturing rose at an average annual rate of 2.1 percent between 1958 and 1980—compared with a rate of 2.8 percent for manufacturing as a whole. Output increased 4.7 per cent a year, employee hours 2.6 percent. Pumps and compressors are used throughout manu facturing and in many nonmanufacturing industries, as well as agriculture. Pumps are the second most com mon machine in use after the electric motor. Compres sors generate compressed air, which may be regarded as a form of energy ranking in breadth of use only be low electricity, gas, and water. Growth in the output of pumps and compressors was, in general, related to expansion in industrial and public utility demand, gains in residential and associated public works construction, and intensified needs of energy-related extractive and pipeline industries. Foreign trade, too, played an im portant role in sustaining output: About one fifth of pump and compressor production was exported be tween 1972 and 1978. Small lot production is the rule in pump and com pressor establishments. Pumps and compressors are Hand and edge tools (SIC 3423). As measured by out put per employee hour, productivity in the hand and edge tool industry grew at an average annual rate of only 1.3 percent during 1958-80, compared with 2.8 percent for all manufacturing. Output increased at a rate of 3.3 percent and employee hours at a 2.0 percent rate. Productivity gains have been linked to the continu ing mechanization of the production process. The use of robots in material handling operations has been a factor in this regard. Improvements in the ovens used to heat the metal for the forging operation have con tributed to faster production rates. The adoption of horizontal impact forging equipment by some plants has resulted in improved production efficiencies. The adop tion of cold forming techniques is also aiding produc tivity. In the cold forming process, dies are still used 46 often large machines, manufactured to customer speci fications. While many of these machines are composed of standard parts, the economies associated with mass production are generally not available. The production process must constantly be adapted so as to cope with the many design, casting, and machining requirements that arise. Such adaptation was facilitated by the ad vent of numerically controlled machine tools in the six ties, and the introduction of computer-aided design (CAD) into engineering practice. Numerical controls (NC) and CAD have been important sources of pro ductivity advances in the industry. banking services, somewhat retarded productivity im provement, partly because scale economies became less favorable. The sources of the industry’s strong output growth were the boom conditions of the early seventies and the financial needs they generated; rapid increases in check transactions; relatively greater reliance by busi ness on external funds; and continuously heavy demand for consumer and real estate credit. Also, commercial banks expanded their share of major types of such credit, as well as of time deposits. Moreover, they emphasized the retailing aspects of their services and consequently accelerated branching. Trust department functions also grew apace as pension and welfare funds proliferated. The banking industry has been radically transformed by electronic data processing. Although computer de velopments during the fifties embodied the principle of machine readability, it was the introduction of magnetic ink character recognition (MICR) in 1958 that made the breakthrough of electronic data processing in bank ing possible. The computer became an indispensable and major factor in improving banking productivity, and the technology has rapidly permeated the industry. Commercial banking (SIC 602). Output per employee hour in commercial banking rose at an average annual rate of 1.3 percent between 1967 and 1980—nearly the same as for the nonfarm business sector as a whole (1.4 percent). Output over the period examined rose at a rate of 6.0 percent per year, while employee hours grew 4.6 percent. The rise in banking productivity was associated with strongly expanding customer services and with ad vances in computer technology and their rapid diffusion throughout the industry. However, the spread of branch banking, while enhancing the convenience of access to 47 Talbl® 1. S®l®€t®d industries: Emptoymsnt, 1881, and average anrtusS rate® ©if <§ton§® ta@utpuit p@r employ®® to u r, 1878-81 Output per employee hour: Average annual rate of change, 1976-81 (percent)1 Employment, 1981 (thousands) SIC cod® Industry All employees Production workers Non production workers All employees Production workers Non production workers2 mSsiiSinig 1011 1011 1021 1021 111,121 121 14 142 Iron mining, crude o re............................... Iron mining, usable o re ............................. Copper mining, crude ore ........................ Copper mining, recoverable m e ta l......... Coal mining.................................................. Bituminous coal and lignite mining......... Nonmstallic minerals, except fuels......... Crushed and broken stone........................ 21 21 36 36 222 219 119 37 17 17 23 23 184 181 91 30 4 4 8 8 38 38 28 7 5.3 4.6 0.1 -0.8 3.4 3.4 -0.1 1.8 5.5 4.8 0.1 -0.8 4.0 4.1 0.5 2.0 4.5 3.8 0.1 -0.8 0.1 0.1 -2.4 0.9 E^anufaeturlmg 2026 203 2033 204 2041 2043 2044 2045 2046 2047, 48 Fluid milk..................................................... Preserved fruits and vegetables............... Canned fruits and vegetables.................. Grain mill products..................................... Flour and other grain mill products......... Cereal breakfast foods............................. Rice milling................................................. Blended and prepared flour...................... Wet corn milling ........................................ Prepared feeds for animals and fowls__ 96 240 91 140 20 17 5 8 13 71 (3) 197 75 97 10 13 4 3 10 48 (3) 43 16 43 10 4 1 2 3 23 6.2 40.1 4-0.2 43.6 2.8 42.0 44.3 4-2.1 410.3 43.5 (3) 40.6 40.6 43.5 1.9 41.2 40.5 4-3.2 411.4 44.0 (3) 4-2.2 4-5.5 43.8 5.8 46.7 4-4.1 41.1 47.5 42.8 205 2061,62,63 2061,62 2063 2055 2082 2086 2111,21,31 2111,31 219 32 20 12 56 50 137 58 127 23 14 9 45 32 45 45 ©2 © 6 3 11 1© 92 13 -0.2 2.1 43.8 43.0 (3) 4.2 3.5 0.7 -0.5 1.5 42.9 44.0 (3) 4.2 5.5 1.5 0.4 5.0 47.1 4-3 .9 (3) 4.1 2.4 -3.0 2121 Bakery products........................................ S ugar........................................................... Raw and refined cane sug ar.................... Beet s u g a r................................................. Candy and confectionery products......... Malt beverages.......................................... Bottled and canned soft drinks................. All tobacco products................................. Cigarettes, chewing and smoking tobacco ................................................... Cigars........................................................... 51 7 39 6 12 1 0.5 3.0 1.3 2.8 -3 .8 5.5 2251,52 2281 2421 2431 2435,36 2435 2436 251 2511,17 2512 Hosiery....................................................... Nonwool yarn mills.................................... Sawmills and planing mills, g en eral....... Millwork....................................................... Veneer and plywood................................. Hardwood veneer and plywood............... Softwood veneer and plywood................. Household furniture................................... Wood household furniture........................ Upholstered household furniture........... 65 82 172 67 64 25 39 299 140 89 58 75 152 54 57 22 35 250 122 73 7 7 20 13 7 3 4 49 18 18 1.5 1.0 -0.3 4-1.7 4-0.3 42.6 4-1.5 40.1 4-0.7 41.2 2.0 1.3 0.5 4-1.0 40.4 42.8 4-0.5 40.5 4-0.2 41.3 -2.3 -3.1 -5.0 4-5.0 4-5.6 40.5 4-8.4 4-1.9 4-4.1 40.8 2514 2515 252 2521 2522 2611,21,31,61 2843 2651 2653 2823,24 Metal household furniture........................ Mattresses and bedsprings...................... Office furniture.......................................... Wood office furniture................................. Metal office furniture................................. Paper, paperboard, and pulp mills........... Paper and plastic b a g s ............................. Folding paperboard boxes........................ Corrugated and solid fiber boxes............. Synthetic fibers.......................................... 31 31 54 22 32 207 50 43 103 102 25 24 42 19 24 202 39 34 76 74 6 7 12 3 8 65 11 4-1.7 42.7 44.7 47.0 43.2 2.3 4-1.0 -1 .8 2.7 0.2 4-2 .0 43.5 45.3 42.9 2.5 4-1 .4 -1 .5 3.1 6.1 4-0 .8 40.3 42.7 4-2.8 44.3 4-2.2 -2.2 1.6 8.6 2834 2841 2844 2851 2911 3011 314 3221 3241 325 Pharmaceutical preparations.................. Soaps and detergents............................... Cosmetics and other toiletries................. Paints and allied products........................ Petroleum refining..................................... Tires and inner tubes................................. Footwear..................................................... Glass containers........................................ Hydraulic cem ent....................................... Structural clay products............................ 158 44 62 63 174 107 143 @8 30 41 77 29 41 31 105 75 123 5© 24 31 81 15 21 32 32 20 © 6 10 42.6 42.0 4-3.4 0.9 4-0.3 3.1 -0.0 3.3 -2.5 -0.8 42.1 41.8 4-3.8 1.8 41.3 3.2 -0.4 3.5 -2.4 (5) 42.8 4-2.6 (5) 4-3.8 2.7 -2.1 1.7 -3.2 -3.2 3251,53,59 3251 3253 Clay construction products...................... Brick and structural clay t i l e .................... Ceramic wall and floor til© ........................ 30 17 © 23 13 7 4 2 -2.2 -5.7 47.4 -1.4 48 7 9 27 28 m -4.0 40.0 1.4 (3) -5.6 -12.4 411.4 Table 1. 8©!©@t®dl Industries: Employment, 1i§H, aradl a^©rag© annual rat©Q ©! ©hang® Bn output par ®mpl®y©® hour, D®F@—©H= G®nfiBnu©d Output per employee hour: Average annual rate of change, 1976-81 (percent)1 Employment, 1981 (thousands) Industry SIC code All employees Production workers Non production workers All employees Production workers Non production workers1 2 ^anutoeturSng^CemftBmuQd] 3255 3271,72 3273 331 3321 3324, 25 3331,32,33 Clay refractories...................................... Concrete products................................... Ready-mixed concrete............................ Steel......................................................... Gray Iron foundries................................. Steel foundries........................................ Primary copper, lead, and zinc................ 11 85 88 505 121 64 22 8 82 (3) 391 08 49 17 3 23 (3) 114 23 15 5 4.3 4-o.e 4- 1 .2 2.0 -1.0 -1.8 3.6 4.6 4-0.1 <3) 2.3 <5) -1.6 3.9 3.4 4-3.2 <3) 1.1 -5.8 -2.3 2.4 3331 3334 3351 3353,54, 55 3411 3423 3441 352 3523 3524 Primary copper........................................ Primary aluminum..................................... Copper rolling and drawing..................... Aluminum rolling and drawing ................ Metal cans................................................. Hand and edge tools............................... Fabricated structural m etal..................... Farm and garden machinery................... Farm machinery...................................... Lawn and garden equipment................... 14 37 29 72 58 46 101 156 135 21 11 28 22 52 50 35 72 105 00 15 3 9 7 20 8 11 29 51 45 6 5.1 -0.1 1.8 -0.6 2.6 40.7 1.3 4-0.7 4-1.6 44.0 5.4 0.6 2.3 -0.1 2.8 41.4 0.9 4-1.1 45.1 4.2 -2.6 (5) -2.5 1.7 4-1.8 2.5 4-2.3 4-3.1 41.2 3531 3541,42 3541 3542 3531,53 3561 35S3 3532 3612 3621 Construction machinery and equipment. Machine tools .......................................... Metal cutting machine tools..................... Metal forming machine tools................... Pumps and compressors........................ Pumps and pumping equipment.............. Air and gas compressors........................ Ball and roller bearings............................ Transformers............................................ Motors and generators............................ 143 104 80 24 04 32 32 57 54 125 95 87 52 15 58 37 10 44 38 98 48 37 28 9 38 25 13 13 16 20 -1.0 0.6 1.4 -2.0 40.9 41.0 40.5 -1.5 45.1 -0.4 -0.1 0.7 1.1 -0.7 40.9 41.0 40.5 -1.8 44.5 0.3 -3.1 0.3 2.0 -4.7 40.9 41.0 40.4 -0.3 48.4 -2.8 3631,32,33, 30 3031 3632 3633 363® 3641 3045,46,47,48 3651 371 Major household appliances................... Household cooking equipment.............. Household refrigerators and freezers ... Household laundry equipment................ Household appliances, n.e.c................... Electric lamps.......................................... Lighting fixtures...................................... Radio and television receiving sets......... Motor vehicles and equipment................ 93 23 34 21 15 33 65 82 784 74 18 27 17 12 29 49 57 583 19 5 7 4 3 4 16 25 201 2.4 2.8 4.3 0.2 1.3 1.1 4-0.7 44.4 -0.3 2.1 1.9 3.5 0.1 1.7 1.1 (4 .) 45.1 1.1 3.5 5.3 8.0 0.6 -0.4 1.1 4-2.9 42.2 -4.4 1.4 40.6 (3) (3) <3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (4 S) Other 401 class I 401 class I 4111,413, 414 pts 4213 part 4213 part 4511,4521 part 4612,13 4811 481,92,93 401,493 part Railroad transportation, revenue traffic.. Railroad transportation, car miles.......... Bus carriers, class I ................................. Intercity trucking...................................... intercity trucking (general freight)........... Air transportation..................................... Petroleum pipelines................................. Telephone communications................... Gas and electric utilities.......................... Electric utilities........................................ 457 457 36 670 413 358 22 1,076 777 501 395 395 (3) (3) <3) <3) 15 r782 7632 (3) 62 02 (3) (3) (3) <3) 7 8204 8145 (3) 3.1 41.5 4 a2.4 -0.8 -1.7 ®2.1 -2.2 5.8 -0.8 -0.0 3.4 *1.7 (3) (3) (3) (3) -1.0 (3) 7-0.5 (3) 492,493 part 54 5511 5541 58 5912 602 7011 721 Gas utilities............................................... Retail food stores0 ................................... Franchised new car dealers..................... Gasoline service stations0 ....................... Eating and drinking places0..................... Drug and proprietary stores0................... Commercial banking............................... Hotels, motels, and tourist courts9 ......... Laundry and cleaning services9 .............. 210 2,420 708 691 5,097 528 1,482 1,179 419 (3) (3) (3) <3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) -0.5 -0.1 0.2 2.1 -1.8 (3) (3) (3) (3) <3) (3) (3) (3) (3) 1 Based on the linear least squares trends of the logarithms of the in dex numbers. 2 Rates of change for nonproduction worker hours are subject to a wider margin of error than other rates shown. 3 Not available. 4 1976-80. 1.2 4-0.6 -0.6 -3.2 (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) 5 Less than 0.05 percent. 8 Output per employee. 7 Nonsupervlsory personnel. 8 Supervisory personnel and force account construction workers. 0 Data relate to all persons, including proprietors, partners, and un paid family workers. 49 Measuring productivity in service industries The growth o f the service economy presents special challenges fo r productivity analysts; output is often difficult to quantify, and measurement o f labor input requires great care Je r o m e A . M ark Linking output to input The increased importance of service industries over the last two decades and current concern over productivity growth have stimulated interest in productivity mea sures for this expanding sector of the economy. The service sector, as defined here, encompasses the major industry groupings of trade, finance, insurance, communications, public utilities, transportation, and government, as well as business and personal services. It accounts for almost three-fourths of the Nation’s em ployment and provides the greatest potential, as well as some of the greatest difficulties, for developing produc tivity measures. Over the last decade, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has been expanding the number of service industries for which it publishes productivity measures, and at present provides measures for 16 industries, representing almost a third of the employment in the sector. The Bureau is continuing to develop additional measures, and hopes eventually to extend coverage to most of the service sec tor. This article describes that effort, discusses some of the problems of measuring productivity, particularly la bor productivity in service industries, and explains how the Bureau is working to resolve some of the problems. Productivity measures relate real physical output to real input. They range from single factor measures, such as output per unit of labor input or output per unit of capital input, to measures of output per unit of multi factor input. Such measures also reflect changes in tech nology, scale of production, educational levels of workers, managerial techniques, and many other factors in addition to the contributions of the particular inputs. Although b l s is currently developing multifactor pro ductivity measures, at present, the published productivi ty measures relate output to labor input. This is the most extensively developed and widely used productivi ty measure because of its relevence to economic analy ses and because, as a practical matter, labor is the most easily measured input. Problem s of m easuring output In many ways, the problems of measuring output in the service industries are similar to those of measuring output in the goods-producing industries. That is, the output indicator must be quantifiable and independent of the input measures. If an output measure for an ac tivity is based on an input measure, as is the case in some instances in the national accounts, obviously no change in productivity can be ascertained. In the case of general government, for example, output in the national Jerome A. Mark is Assistant Commissioner for Productivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M onthly Labor Review, June 1982. 50 by unit labor requirements, and in sufficient detail to adjust for quality changes. In practice, however, such data are not generally available for service industries (and, in many cases, for goods-producing industries as well). As a result, approximations based on alternative approaches must be used. The principal alternative is to remove the change in price from the change in total value of the volume of services. This approach is tantamount to price weighting quantities of services provided. Insofar as price relationships among the various component serv ices of a service industry are similar to the unit labor requirements or unit labor costs, this is a close approxi mation of the desired measure. And because it is easier to measure price change for a specified group of services than it is to measure the number of services provided directly, this is the approach most generally followed. However, the adjustment requires data in sufficient detail to adequately represent the price trends of the components included in the price change. Otherwise, price movements of the covered areas will be implicitly imputed to the uncovered areas. But because the rela tionship among the price movements of similar services is much stronger than the relationship among quantity changes, this alternative still has greater viability than imputing quantity changes for uncovered services. In practice, BLS uses the two approaches to develop output measures for service industries. In some in stances, quantity data are available, particularly for util ities and transportation industries. In others, price de flation is employed, and for some, deflation at lower levels of aggregation is combined with labor input weighting at higher levels. For example, in developing the measure for gasoline service stations, gasoline sales, repair, and other services are deflated separately and summed, but in the case of retail food stores, sales by major department are deflated and combined with em ployee labor cost weights. income and product accounts is measured in terms of compensation of government employees. The deflated or constant-dollar measure is derived from changes in em ployment. Hence, changes in the output measure are closely related to changes in the input measure. It is also important to distinguish between intermedi ate and final services. In productivity measurement, we attempt to ensure that the indicators represent output flowing from the industry being measured rather than intermediate steps in the service flow. In this sense, pro ductivity measurement differs from work measurement, which generally refers to the analysis of the operation of an activity and the labor requirements at each interme diate stage. Productivity measurement refers only to the final service and its relationship to input. For example, in the trucking industry,-a count of the ton-miles of freight moved would be the appropriate in dicator of the final output— that is, the result of all the activities of the industry. The intermediate steps, such as pickup and delivery, platform work, billing, and col lecting, are considered to be subsumed in the final out put. In the case of an organization or an industry providing one type of service, output is merely a count of the units of this service, however defined. In the more usual case of an industry producing a number of heterogeneous services, the various units must be expressed in some common basis for aggregation. For example, the output of franchised new-car dealerships should be a combination of the number of cars sold and the repair activities of the dealers, with appropriate weighting. To obtain a productivity measure that is an average of the changes of individual components, the appropri ate weights for combining the various elements in the output measure are in terms of their factor input re quirements. In a labor productivity measure, the weights are unit labor requirements. Homogeneity among services, after considerations of quality and specifications, is indicated by similarity in unit labor requirements. In this way, the output mea sure for the development of labor productivity statistics differs from more traditional production measures based on total price or value-added price weighting. When there are quality changes within the service, adjustments must be made in the output measure to ac count for the fact that the output is no longer the same homogeneous unit. However, the indicator of quality change for labor productivity measurement dif fers from the usual concept of quality change associated with consumer price measurements in that it reflects dif ferences in producers’ labor requirements or labor costs rather than consumer utility differences. Ideally, then, the output measure should incorporate data on the number of services provided, differentiated M easuring labor input With regard to labor input measures, the principal problems are data gaps. Information is needed on hours worked by all persons— nonsupervisory workers, super visory workers, and self-employed and unpaid family workers—in an individual industry. But although data on hours worked are collected by various government agencies as part of such ongoing programs as the Bu reau’s occupational safety and health surveys, they tend to be limited in scope, or otherwise inconsistent with the output data developed. The principal source of data on employment and hours is the BLS Current Employment Survey of estab lishments. This payroll series provides good measures of the employment and hours of nonsupervisory workers. However, it is collected on an hours paid basis, rather SI than on an hours worked basis. To the extent that hours paid for but not worked are changing, this mea sure has limitations. To overcome this problem, the Bu reau is measuring hours at work as a proportion of hours paid for a sample of establishments in the survey and will use these data to adjust the industry hours paid series. In general, data on the hours of supervisory workers are poor. Although employment data on supervisory workers are available from the payroll survey, hours data are not. Other sources, such as the censuses of population, are used to estimate this component of the labor input measure. Data on the number of self-employed, an important component of the input series measure for retail indus tries, come from the Internal Revenue Service ( ir s ). The IRS data lag current estimates by 3 years, but may be projected forward with special tabulations from the Current Population Survey ( c p s ). These CPS tabulations break out the numbers and hours of self-employed and unpaid family workers at the 3-digit Standard Industrial Classification level. Al though the sample size at this level is small and the sta tistical error is high, the data are the only continuous series of the number and hours for unpaid family work ers and for the hours of the self-employed. The measures derived from these data are unweighted hours; that is, the hours of various types of employees are treated as being equally productive. This would not be a problem if the proportions of workers at different levels of productivity were constant over time. Howev er, to the extent that there are changes in the composi tion of the work force, such as age, sex, and occupational mix, it may be desirable to adjust the la bor input measure for these changes which otherwise would be reflected in the productivity measure. Data gaps hamper the making of these adjustments. Industry data on employment and hours by age and oc cupation are limited, although various sources, such as the CPS and BLS occupational employment surveys, pro vide some pieces. And while worker groups may be dif ferentiated into productivity levels according to their wages or compensation, pay is a factor which may re flect other than productivity differences.1 Table 1. Average annual rates of change in output per hour of all employees in selected service industries, 1965-73 and 1973-80 [In percent] SIC Code 1965-73 1973-80 4111 ;4131 ;414 (parts) . 4213 (parts).................. 4511 ............................. 4612,13........................ Transportation: Railroad transportation, revenue traffic ...................................... Bus carriers ............................... ■ Intercity trucking1 ........................ Air transportation1 ...................... Petroleum pipelines .................... 4.2 -1.5 2.7 5.3 7.9 2.2 -0.4 0.5 4.3 0.0 4811 ............................. Communications: Telephone communications......... 4.7 7.0 491 ;492;493 .................. 491 ;493 (part) ............. 492;493 (part) ............. Public utilities: Gas and electric utilities............. Electric utilities............................. Gas utilities................................. 4.9 5.4 3.9 0.7 1.3 -0.4 2.2 2.6 4.9 1.1 62 -1 .2 0.5 3.1 -1 .0 19 1.8 1.7 1.3 -1.1 401 ............................... 5 4 ................................. 5511 ............................. 5541 ............................. 5 8 ................................. 5 9 1 2 ............................. 7011 ............................. 721 ............................... Trade: Retail food stores ...................... Franchised new car dealers . . . . Gasoline service stations ........... Eating and drinking places ......... Services: Hotels, motels, and tourist courts Laundry and cleaning services .. 10utput per employee. tries in the goods-producing sector. In addition, a measure for commercial banking is be ing developed, and work has begun on measures for the insurance and hospital industries. In a related area, pro ductivity measures for Federal agencies which provide functions such as recordkeeping, insurance, libraries, building and grounds maintenance, and medical services have been published. It is not possible within the confines of this article to discuss all of the productivity measures prepared by the Bureau, but reference to some of the more important and interesting ones in each of the major areas can il lustrate the difficulties encountered in constructing such statistics. Trade. The Bureau has published measures for retail trade industries since 1975 (with the data beginning in 1958). At present, statistics are published for five im portant industries— retail food stores, new car dealer ships, gasoline service stations, eating and drinking places, and drugstores. Work is underway on a measure for apparel stores, including shoe stores, to be published separately. The effort to develop productivity measures in the wholesale area has not yet succeeded. For most retail trade industries, data on gross sales in current dollars, deflated by the appropriate price in dexes, are used to estimate real output. This method, as mentioned earlier, can yield good estimates of real out put. However, such measures can reflect shifts among services with different values, but having the same labor requirements. Therefore, the overall industry productivi Measures for service industries At present, BLS publishes indexes of output per unit of labor input for industries in each major service activ ity— trade, communications, transportation, utilities, and business and personal services, a total of 16 sepa rate measures. Data for these industries, presented in ta ble 1, indicate a wide range of productivity growth since 1973, the year in which a productivity slowdown for the general business economy appeared to begin. In many cases, the growth rates exceeded those for indus Industry 52 with the movement of goods and passengers are usually greater for short hauls than for long hauls. Therefore, a shift from a long haul to a short haul trip or vice versa could be reflected as a change in productivity although only the mix of trips had changed. For the two major freight-carrying industries, rail roads and trucking, undifferentiated ton-mile informa tion is reported for total freight operations. In trucking, the ton-mile data are also reported separately for three types of carriers— general, contract, and others. But output measures should reflect the kinds of commodities handled and the average distance they are moved. The preferred way to develop these measures would be to combine the tonnage and the average haul of each com modity by its respective labor requirements and aggre gate the results for all commodities transported. Un fortunately, this cannot be done with available data. However, supplementary information on tonnage for railroads is available from the ICC for about 200 com modity lines, ranging from agricultural and mining products to motor vehicles and scientific instruments. Until recently, similar information was also available for the trucking industry. BLS uses these data to adjust the overall measure of freight ton-miles for changes in the composition of goods carried. Although this commodity adjustment is a significant improvement, refinements to the undifferentiated tonmiles cannot be developed to the extent desired. For ex ample, separate labor requirements data are not avail able for weighting the individual commodity groups. The commodity index adjustments are therefore made in terms of unit revenue weights, the underlying as sumption being that differences between labor require ments among commodities are similar to differences in terms of unit revenues. This does not seem unreasonable because labor costs constitute more than half of each industry’s total operating costs, although the proportion could conceivably differ by commodity. For railroads, the adjusted freight ton-mile measure is combined with a measure of revenue passenger-miles to obtain the total industry output index. For air transportation and trucking, employment is the only available measure of labor input. Thus, the productivity measures for these two industries should be interpreted with caution, for if changes occur in the average workweek, the trends in productivity would not show the true relationship between output and labor time expended on the output. The transportation industries fo r which BLS publishes productivity measures all are regulated to some degree by the Federal Government. Recent efforts to reduce the paperwork burden, coupled with the effects of de regulation, have acted to eliminate some of the operat ing statistics previously published. As a result, some ty index can show movements without any change in component elements. In retail industries, a large portion of the value of sales has been provided by the manufacturer and the wholesaler of the product sold. A net output measure would be desirable, because it would most closely corre spond to the value added by the retailer. However, a gross or total sales measure will yield the same results as a net or value-added measure if the value added as a percent of sales (gross margin) does not change over time. Available data indicate that, among retail industries for which productivity data are published, gross margins have not changed significantly over time. To incorporate labor input weights, the indexes for most of the retail trade industries are developed in two stages. First, deflated output measures based on sales volume are developed for detailed merchandise lines. These are aggregated to higher levels and then com bined with labor costs weights. For example, in retail food stores, sales for 13 key merchandise lines are de flated using specially prepared price indexes based on CPI components. The merchandise lines are aggregated to five department lines— meat, produce, frozen food, dry groceries, and dairy and all others. These are then ag gregated with labor cost weights from Department of Agriculture data to develop the overall output measure for groceries. The labor input data for retail trade pro ductivity statistics are generally derived from the Bu reau’s establishment survey, supplemented by IRS and c p s data. Transportation. BLS publishes productivity measures for five transportation industries— railroads, intercity truck ing, intercity buses, air transportation, and petroleum pipelines. These measures cover 57 percent of transpor tation employment. Conceptually, productivity measures for the transpor tation industries are easier to develop than those for other non-goods producing industries. This is because transportation industry output— the movement of goods or passengers or both from one point to another— is more easily quantified. Output units in transportation have two dimensions, amount and distance; they reflect not only how much has been transported, but also how far. As such, ton-miles, passenger-miles, barrel-miles, and so forth are the primary output indicators for these industries. Although the basic information for developing good transportation productivity measures is available and is, of course, being used, there are some data gaps that place certain limitations on the BLS measures. For ex ample, it is sometimes impossible to adjust the produc tivity measures adequately for changes in the average length of haul. The unit labor requirements associated 53 productivity measures have had to be extended on the basis of more limited information. The outlook for expanding the data base, at least in the near future, is not favorable. However, BLS is cooperating with other government agencies to ensure that adequate statistics for transportation industries remain available. Communications. The BLS productivity measure for tele phone communications covers about four-fifths of the employment in the communications sector. The output index is derived from revenues of all telephone compa nies reporting to the Federal Communications Commis sion. The revenues are stratified by major source— local, toll, or miscellaneous— and deflated by specially prepared price indexes for these different services. The labor hours data are based on the Bureau’s estab lishment payroll survey. At one time, BLS published a productivity measure, the numerator of which was derived from the number of local and long-distance telephone calls, aggregated on the basis of revenue weights. This measure was dis continued in the mid-195Q’s because of concern that the labor input measure was not consistent with the output measure. For example, private line services, such as leased telephone lines, radio and TV transmission, tele type, and so forth, were reflected in employee hours but not in the output measure as defined. The same was true for calls between stations transmitted through pri vate switchboards and directory services. A different type of productivity index for the industry was initiated in 1973, with data back to 1951. The nu merator of this measure was derived from annual reve nue data stratified by major services and deflated, until last year, by price indexes furnished by American Tele phone and Telegraph Co. Beginning in 1982, the BLS producer price index for telephone communications will be used to deflate the revenue data, and productivity in dexes published for the industry since 1972 will be re vised in accordance with the new procedure. The BLS deflated revenue measure of the output of the telephone communications industry is fairly comprehen sive. It includes revenues from private Sine services, which have grown in importance over the years, as well as those arising from the maintenance of private switch boards by telephone carriers. St also accounts for TV, radio, and computer data transmission by telephone in dustry facilities, and for directory services. However, certain measurement problems remain unresolved, in cluding the unsatisfactory treatment of differences in in tensity of the use of telephone equipment by customers. Intensity of use differences occur when revenue does not vary in proportion to the number of calls made because of flat charges, as in the case of local telephone service or WATS Sines. Implicitly, the BLS output measure as 54 sumes that the maximum permissible usage takes place under any flat charge system used in the industry. Business and personal services. In the area of business and personal services, which includes not only business, personal, and repair services, but also education, social services, and political organizations, BLS currently publishes only two measures of productivity, one for hotels and motels, and the other for laundry and dry cleaning services. These measures cover 13 percent of the total employment in the sector. Because physical quantity information as not available for these two industries, output measures are developed using price-deflated value techniques. The techniques are similar to those described earlier, in that both reve nues and employee-hour weights are used to aggregate the output indicators into a total industry output index. On the input side, the hours of all persons are used as the measure of labor time. As in the trade sector, partners, proprietors, and unpaid family workers make up a significant portion of the work force. Currently, this group accounts for about 15 percent of all persons employed in laundries and 20 percent of the workers in hotels and motels. BLS efforts to expand coverage in the business and personal service area have been hampered by two major problems. First, because many business service catego ries are quite broad, it is impossible to account ade quately for changes in the mix of their component services. For example, we cannot publish a productivity index for automotive repair shops because there are al most no data available on the types of repairs that are made. The second problem is that not enough services are covered by the Consumer Price Index and, conse quently, the deflated value of the output of many un covered areas would have to be imputed. Finance. In the finance area, BLS is developing a bank ing measure in terms of the three major services com mercial banks render their customers—deposits, loans, and trust services. While banks also provide non-fundusing services, such as safe deposit and customer pay roll accounting, lack of adequate data preclude deriving a measure for theim, However, because the proportion of employees engaged in such services is very small, the overall output measure is little affected by the omission. There has been much controversy over the years as to the appropriate measure of the output of banking. Some analysts have advocated a ‘“liquidity5’’ approach, others, a “transactions” approach. In the former, the banks are viewed as holders of money, and their output is equivalent to the net interest they receive on the volume of deposits held. This interest is the income depositors are willing to forgo to maintain deposits rather than in ment. Included in the loan output measure are commer cial and residential mortgage loans; consumer loans; single-payment loans; credit card loans; and commercial and “other” loans. The number of loans can usually be derived by dividing the dollar value of total loans in a given category by the average face value of a loan. For the category of commercial loans, the actual number of loans extended has been available since the mid-1970’s. An experimental output measure for the trust depart ment services of commercial banks is derived from the trend in the number of accounts. Trust accounts are stratified into five major categories, including benefit trusts, personal trusts, and estates. After output estimates are developed for depository, loan, and fiduciary segments, they are aggregated to the industry level using employment weights. vesting directly in assets less readily converted to cash, that is, the value to customers of the liquidity they en joy from bank services. This approach can be extended to all types of savings accounts, on the principle that the forgone net interest is the value of the bank’s ser vices. The other approach views banking output as a series of transactions; the volume of the bank’s output is pro portional to the volumes of the transactions handled. BLS has adopted this second approach for its produc tivity measure. Accordingly, the final output of banks is defined as an array of depository, lending, and fiduciary services. Estimates of the number of transactions for each of the three service functions must be derived. Because no di rect count of the number of transactions is available in many instances, estimates are made from data on the total value of transactions and surveys of average trans action amounts. Deposit activity is measured in terms of the number of checks transacted and the number of time and sav ings deposits and withdrawals. (An electronic funds transfer is treated as a transaction on par with one in volving payment by check.) The data for demand de posit activities are from Federal Reserve counts and of ficial benchmark surveys. For time and savings deposit activity, the output measure is based on data published by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation and on the Functional Cost Analysis conducted annually by the Federal Reserve. Lending services provided by banks are also mea sured in terms of units. As in the case of deposit and trust activity, BLS does not use banks’ financial data to arrive at the component output measures. Use of such data would be highly misleading even if appropriate de flators could be found. For example, an increase in the aggregate deflated value of loans might simply reflect the making of a few large loans; similarly, a decrease might indicate the repayment of a few large loans, even as the number of small loans increased. Twelve types of loan output are measured, for the most part using data generated by the Federal Reserve and the Department of Housing and Urban Develop S o m e o f t h e MAJOR p r o b l e m s in developing labor productivity measures in the service activities and how BLS has tried to meet some of these problems have been highlighted above. Considerable work in this very im portant area has been conducted and the outlook for improvements in certain subareas is optimistic. For ex ample, as price measures are improved and hours worked data become available, and as work in the area of government productivity measurement progresses, BLS will be able to provide a better picture of what is happening to productivity in more activities within the sector. Additional measures in communications, finance, insurance, and real estate, and business and personal services can and will be developed, and indexes for wholesale trade are very possible. However, there are severe conceptual as well as data problems in measuring productivity in such industries as education and social services and in the important field of medical services, and progress in these areas is expected to be much slower. ' In connection with work on multifactor productivity measure ment, BLS is exploring the possibility of making adjustments for changes in work force composition. 55 Productivity Clhiariig® im th@ Bituminous 0®al Industry, R o s e M. Z e i s e l Productivity in bituminous coal mining reached a peak in 1968-69 and declined every year thereafter ex cept 1973 and 1978. From 1970 to 1979, output per employee hour declined 4.1 percent (annual average) and output per production worker hour fell 3.7 percent, as hours rose sharply and output only moderately. In contrast, productivity grew rapidly in the previous two decades. The high productivity growth rates of the 1950’s reflected very sharp declines in hours, while in the 196Q’s, average hours dropped only moderately but output rose substantially. Several factors contributed to rapid productivity growth in those 20 years. Of major importance was the diffusion of technological advances in deep mining, par ticularly continous mining, and proportionately greater output from more productive surface mines. Moreover, in that period, when coal’s competitive position was poor, only the more efficient mines were still operating, raising the industry’s level of productivity. Also, a high degree of labor-management cooperation resulted in a 20-year period free of contract strikes. The increase in surface mining contributed greatly to productivity growth. Output per miner day in surface mines in the 1960’s averaged 31 tons, compared with 14 in underground mining. And coal mined on the surface increased as a share of total output from 24 percent in 1950 to 38 percent in 1969. But in the 1970’s, the pro ductivity decline reflected declines in both surface min ing and underground mining. Output per miner day in surface mines declined from 36 tons in 1969 to 25 tons in 1979; underground productivity fell from a peak of almost 16 tons in 1969 to 8 tons in 1979. Although many different explanations have been advanced to explain the decline, research by the Department of Energy and the Department of Labor indicates that environmental and safety regulations, periodic disruptions in produc tion, and an increase in the number of less efficient mines and less experienced workers could be some of the factors. Following enactment of the 1969 Coal Mine Health and Safety Act, additional employee hours in underground mines per unit of output were required to comply with the new regulations. Mining methods had to be changed, and the production process using con tinous miners was particularly affected. The diversion of some labor and capital to activities which did not in crease output had an adverse effect on productivity. Although the impact of the legislation was less by the mid-1970’s, greater enforcement probably continued to depress productivity growth. Similarly, the implementa tion of State reclamation laws could be one of the major causes for the productivity decline in surface mining. The impact of the Federal Surface Mine Control and Reclamation Act of 1977 on the productivity of surface mines will not be known until the act is more fully im plemented. Labor disruptions in the 1970’s included three major contract strikes and many wildcat strikes. The practice of stockpiling before a strike, and catching up after ward, reduces efficiency. In addition, smaller, less efficient mines entered the industry as coal prices rose in response to the oil em bargo and to changing market conditions. From 1973 to 1976, the number of active deep mines increased by 40 percent. Smaller mines tend to have lower productivity, and their entry contributed to the decline in the mid-1970’s. Also, a younger, inexperienced work force probably depressed productivity growth. The decline in bituminous mining productivity con trasted sharply with trends in other sectors of the economy. From 1970 to 1979, output per employee hour in bituminous coal declined at an average annual rate of 4.1 percent, while in manufacturing it rose at a rate of 2.2 percent, and in nonfarm business, 1.3 percent. In contrast, from 1950 to 1970, productivity growth in coal mining had far exceeded growth in other sectors. The decline also contrasted sharply with the trends in the coal industries of Europe and the U.S.S.R., although data are not fully comparable. From 1960 to 1978, while productivity in the U.S. coal industry declined by 23 percent, it increased in Poland and West Germany by 150 and 124 percent, respectively; in Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 2072 (1981), Technology, Productivity, and L abor in the Bituminous Coal Industry, 1950-79. 56 Belgium by 76 percent; and the United Kingdom by 48 percent. Nevertheless, the level of productivity in the U.S. industry in 1978 was still more than twice as high as in West Germany and Poland. The productivity outlook for the U.S. industry is mix ed. As the shift to capital-intensive western surface mines accelerates, productivity will be favorably af fected. Western surface mines with thicker seams and less overburden are more productive than eastern sur face mines. Also, with the shift West, the proportion of miners who are union-affiliated declines, which is likely to reduce the impact of work stoppages. On the other hand, State and Federal safety and environmental pro tection laws could have an adverse effect on surface mine productivity as they are more fully enforced. T a b le 1 6 . O u tp u t per m in e r d ay b y m e th o d o f m in in g , 1 9 5 0 -7 9 T a b le 18. O u tp u t per e m p lo y e e h o u r in coal m in in g and selected sectors o f the e c o n o m y , 1 9 5 0 -7 9 (S h o r t to n s ) Year U n d e rg ro u n d m in in g T o ta l ( In d e x , 1 9 6 7 = 1 0 0 ) S u rfa c e m in in g C oal m in in g 1 Year 6 .7 7 7 .0 4 7 .4 7 8 .1 7 9 .4 7 5 .7 5 6 .0 8 6 .3 7 7.01 7 .9 9 1 5 .6 6 1 6 .0 2 16.81 1 7 .7 3 1 9 .8 0 ............................................................................... .............................................................................. .............................................................................. .............................................................................. .............................................................................. 9 .8 4 1 0 .2 8 1 0 .5 9 1 1.3 3 1 2 .2 2 8 .2 8 8 .6 2 8.9 1 9 .3 8 1 0 .0 8 2 1 .1 7 2 1 .3 7 2 1 .8 7 2 1 .8 4 2 2 .9 4 1 9 6 0 .............................................................................. 1 9 6 1 .............................................................................. 1 9 6 2 ............................................................................... 1 9 6 3 ............................................................................... 1 9 6 4 .............................................................................. 1 2 .8 3 1 3 .8 7 1 4 .7 2 1 5 .8 3 1 6 .8 4 1 0 .6 4 11.41 1 1.97 1 2 .7 8 1 3 .7 4 2 3 .3 1 2 5 .2 9 2 7 .3 1 2 9 .3 0 3 0 .0 5 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 ............................................................................... ............................................................................... ............................................................................... ............................................................................... ............................................................................... 1 7 .5 2 1 8 .5 2 1 9 .1 7 1 9 .3 7 1 9 .9 0 1 4 .0 0 1 4 .6 4 1 5 .0 7 1 5 .4 0 15.61 3 2 .7 6 3 4 .2 3 3 5 .8 7 3 4 .6 4 3 6 .0 0 1 9 7 0 ............................................................................... 1 9 7 1 .............................................................................. 1 9 7 2 ............................................................................... 1 9 7 3 ............................................................................... 1 9 7 4 ............................................................................... 1 8 .8 4 1 8 .0 2 1 7 .7 4 1 7 .5 8 1 7 .5 8 1 3 .7 6 1 2 .0 3 11.91 1 1.66 1 1.31 3 5 .8 3 3 5 .8 8 3 6 .3 3 3 6 .6 7 3 3 .1 6 1975 1976 1977 1978 1 4 .7 4 1 4 .4 6 1 4 .8 4 1 4 .2 6 1 3 .5 0 9 .5 4 9 .1 0 8 .6 9 8 .2 5 7 .9 0 2 6 .6 9 2 6 .4 0 1 9 5 0 .............................................................................. 1 9 5 1 ............................................................................... 1 9 5 2 ............................................................................... 1 9 5 3 ............................................................................... 1 9 5 4 .............................................................................. 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 19 7 9 ” ............................................................................... ............................................................................... ............................................................................... ............................................................................... .............................................................................................. 2 6 .5 9 2 5 .0 0 2 4 .8 0 p = p r e lim in a r y . N O T E : O u t p u t p e r m in e r d a y re p re s e n ts to ta l o u t p u t f o r th e ye a r d iv id e d b y th e to ta l n u m b e r o f m in e r d a y s w o r k e d . SOURCE: P riv a te b u siness s e c to r2 N o n fa r m business s e c to r2 M a n u fa c tu r in g s e c to r 2 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 ............................................... . . . ............................. ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... 3 7 .7 3 7 .4 3 9 .2 4 2 .2 4 8 .4 61 .2 6 3 .0 6 4 .8 6 6 .8 6 7 .9 6 7 .2 6 8 .4 6 9 .7 7 0 .7 7 1 .8 6 5 .8 6 7 .9 6 9 .2 7 0 .4 7 1 .4 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... 5 2 .3 54.1 5 5 .0 5 9 .9 6 0 .9 7 0 .6 7 1 .5 7 3 .5 7 5 .4 7 7 .8 7 4 .6 7 5 .0 7 6 .5 7 7 .9 8 0 .5 7 5 .0 7 4 .4 7 6 .0 7 5 .6 7 9 .0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... 6 5 .5 73.1 7 8 .6 8 3 .3 8 8 .8 7 9 .0 81 .4 8 5 .1 8 8 .3 91 .7 81 .2 8 3 .3 8 6 .9 8 9 .8 9 2 .9 7 9 .8 8 1 .6 8 5 .2 9 1 .1 9 5 .6 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... 9 4 .0 9 8 .2 1 0 0 .0 1 0 2 .2 1 0 2 .2 95 .1 9 8 .0 1 0 0 .0 1 0 3 .3 1 0 3 .6 9 6 .0 9 8 .4 1 0 0 .0 1 0 3 .2 1 0 3 .0 9 8 .4 9 9 .8 1 0 0 .0 1 0 3 .7 1 0 5 .0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... ............................................... 9 8 .9 8 8 .7 8 2 .4 8 3 .7 8 0 .9 1 0 4 .4 1 0 7 .8 1 1 1.5 1 1 3 .6 1 10 .2 1 0 3 .2 1 0 6 .4 1 10.1 1 1 2 .0 1 0 8 .6 1 0 5 .0 1 1 0 .5 1 1 5 .7 1 1 8 .9 1 1 3 .0 1 9 7 5 ............................................... 1 9 7 6 ............................................... 1 9 7 7 ............................................... 1 9 7 8 ............................................... 1 9 7 9 P ........................................ 6 9 .9 6 8 .5 6 7 .2 71 .5 6 5 .9 1 1 2 .6 1 16 .6 1 18 .7 1 1 9 .3 1 1 8 .3 1 10.7 1 1 4 .6 1 1 6 .4 1 1 6 .9 1 15 .7 1 18 .8 1 2 4 .0 1 2 7 .7 1 2 8 .2 1 2 9 .2 1 Based o n h o u rs o f a ll e m p lo y e e s . 2 Based o n in d e x e s o f real p r o d u c t and in d e x e s o f th e h o u rs o f all p e rso n s engaged. T h e in d e x o f real p r o d u c t is based o n a m aasure o f value a d d e d in c o n s ta n t d o lla r s and d iffe r s in c o n c e p t fr o m th e p h y s ic a l o u t p u t in d e x f o r c o a l m in in g . H o u rs o f a ll p e rs o n s c o v e r e s tim a te d h o u rs o f a ll p e rs o n s engaged, in c lu d in g p r o p r ie to r s and u n p a id f a m ily w o rk e rs , a n d are based p r im a r ily o n d a ta fr o m th e B L S s u rv e y o f bu sin e ss e s ta b lis h m e n ts , U .S . D e p a r tm e n t o f E n e rg y , E n e rg y I n fo r m a tio n A d m in is tr a tio n . p = p r e lim in a r y . SOURCE: T a b le 1 7 . P ro d u c tiv ity in coal m in in g , selected S tates, 1 9 6 9 and 1 9 7 8 O u t p u t p e r m in e r d a y S ta te 19 6 9 19 7 8 Change 19 6 9 -7 8 T a b le 19. U n d e rg ro u n d coal m ines, o u tp u t p er e m p lo y e e s h ift. U n ite d S tates and selected co u n tries, 1 9 6 0 and 1 9 7 8 P e rce n ta g e o f to ta l 19 7 8 p r o d u c t io n f r o m s u r f a c e m in e s S h o r t to n s C o u n tr y 19 6 0 S h o rt to n s W est: M o n t a n a ............................ N o r th D a k o t a .................. W y o m in g ............................. East: I l l i n o i s ................................ K e n tu c k y ......................... O h i o .................................... W est V i r g i n i a .................. SOURCE: 8 7 .6 7 6 .2 3 9 .2 9 7 .6 7 8 .4 2 9 .0 10 0 .0 6 1.8 10 .0 2 .2 2 2 .6 2 3 .7 13 .9 1 4 .4 -1 5 .1 -9 .3 4 8 .9 5 6 .2 2 5 .9 13 .0 -1 2 .9 7 1 .1 16 .0 8 .5 -7 .5 2 3 .6 19 7 8 P e rc e n t change, 19 6 0 -7 8 -2 2 .5 U n ite d S t a t e s ............................................................................ 10 .6 4 8 .2 5 B e l g i u m ....................................................................................... 1.2 3 2 .1 7 7 6 .4 F r a n c e ........................................................................................... 1 .3 7 2 .0 0 4 6 .0 10 0 .0 9 8 .8 U .S . D e p a r t m e n t o f E n e r g y , E n e r g y I n f o r m a t i o n A d m i n i s t r a t i o n . B u re a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s . H u n g a r y ....................................................................................... .7 7 1 .1 0 4 2 .9 N e t h e r la n d s ................................................................................ 1 .2 5 1 2 .5 4 1 1 0 3 .2 P o l a n d ........................................................................................... 1.5 9 3 .9 7 1 4 9 .7 S p a in ............... .............................................................................. .6 7 1.4 3 1 1 3 .4 U n ite d K i n g d o m ..................................................................... 1.6 8 2 .4 8 4 7 .6 U .S .S .R ........................................................................................... 1.7 0 2 2 .5 2 2 4 8 .2 W est G e r m a n y ............................................................................ 1 .7 7 3 .9 6 1 2 3 .7 1 1 9 7 4 d a ta . '1 9 7 6 d a ta . NO TE: D a ta are n o t s t r ic t ly c o m p a ra b le a m o n g c o u n tr ie s a n d m a y be used o n ly as b ro a d in d ic a to r s o f lo n g -te rm tre n d s . U .S . d a ta are o n a m in e r-d a y basis and in c lu d e b i t u m in o u s c o a l a n d lig n ite p r o d u c tio n . E u ro p e a n a n d U .S .S .R . d a ta are o n an e m p lo y e e - s h ift basis a n d in c lu d e b it u m in o u s a n d a n th r a c ite c o a l, b u t e x c lu d e lig n ite p r o d u c t io n e x c e p t f o r d a ta f o r F ra n c e in 1 9 6 0 in w h ic h lig n ite a c c o u n ts f o r o n ly a s m a ll p e rc e n ta g e o f to ta l u n d e rg ro u n d o u t p u t . A ll d a ta in c lu d e s u rfa c e o p e r a tio n s o f u n d e rg ro u n d m in e s . S O U R C E S : U .N . E c o n o m ic C o m m is s io n E n e rg y In f o r m a t io n A d m in is tr a tio n . 57 fo r E u ro p e ; U .S . D e p a r tm e n t o f E n e rg y , Productivity in commercial banking: computers spur the advance Nevertheless, output per employee hour paralleled the trend o f the economy during 1967-80, with the annual rate o f growth decelerating after 1973 H orst Br a n d and Jo h n D uke The computer was among the major forces that spurred labor productivity advance in commercial banking in 1967-80. The computer also facilitated great increases in banking output. Labor requirements per unit of out put, however, declined rather slowly during the period. Output per employee hour in commercial banking rose at an average annual rate of 1.3 percent between 1967 and 1980—nearly the same as for the nonfarm business sector as whole (1.4 percent).1 Data for a pro ductivity measure for years prior to 1967 are inade quate, and none was calculated. Output over the period examined rose at a rate of 6.0 percent per year, employ ee hours, at a rate of 4.6 percent. The rise in banking productivity was associated with strongly expanding customer services and with advances in computer tech nology and their rapid diffusion throughout the indus try. However, the spread of branch banking, while enhancing access to banking services, somewhat retard ed productivity improvement, partly because scale econ omies became less favorable.2 The labor productivity trend in banking paralleled not only the long-term rate for nonfarm business but also the significant differences in rates of change be tween the 1967-73 and 1973-80 periods. Over the earli er span, productivity in banking rose at an average annual rate of 2.1 percent, compared with 1.9 percent for all of nonfarm business. Subsequently, the rate de celerated to 0.7 percent a year; for nonfarm business, to 0.9 percent. Year-to-year swings in the productivity trend were pronounced, ranging from a drop of 6.9 percent in 1974 to a spurt of 6.1 percent in 1976. During the 12-year period, years of decline occurred 4 times, characterized by employment increases in the face of slowed advances (1969 and 1979) or declines in output (1974 and 1980). In such years, restrictive monetary policy (as in 1969 and 1979) or recession (as in 1974 and 1980) constrained the demand for funds. In years when pro ductivity gains ran substantially ahead of the long-term trend average, strong cyclical recoveries or peaks in the demand for banking services occurred (as in 1971, 1973, 1976, and 1977).3 Measuring productivity The labor productivity measure for commercial bank ing has been developed in accordance with the usual procedures of the Bureau of Labor Statistics for measur ing changes in the relation between the output of an in dustry and the employee hours expended in producing that output. Commercial banking produces a variety of outputs, that is, services to the public. These services have been summed on the basis of weights which reflect — or are close substitutes for—labor requirements per unit of service. The output index was then divided by Horst Brand and John Duke are economists in the Division of Industry Productivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, December 1982. 38 transactions, especially demand deposits, also lost some momentum during the second half of the seventies. an index of employee hours for commercial banking, so as to obtain an index of output per employee hour, or labor productivity. The labor productivity measure for banking, then, measures the change over time in the ra tio of the weighted output of the composite of services to the public to employee hours. Output has been defined in terms of the three major banking activities: (1) demand deposit transactions, in volving the crediting and debiting of checks written by the public, and time and savings deposits transactions, involving deposits upon and withdrawals from accounts held by the public; (2) lending for commercial, con sumer, and real estate purposes; and (3) fiduciary, in volving the administration of trusts and estates, and the purchase and sale of securities on their account. The output measure for constructing the indexes of labor productivity in banking has been obtained from data on the quantity of these various services rendered by the banks to the public. As noted, in aggregating these services, the labor requirement per unit of each of the major categories of service in a base period was used as the basis for combining the dissimilar activities. Where labor requirement data were not available, prox ies were employed. The labor inputs used in constructing the productivi ty measure for commercial banking have been derived from BLS data for employment and employee hours, as reported by banking establishments on the basis of their payroll records. The labor input series, therefore, is an hours paid, rather than an hours worked, measure. No adjustment has been made for differences in skill, expe rience, or other factors of labor quality, data for such adjustments not being available.4 Deposits. Periods of speedup and slowdown aside, de mand and time deposits rose rapidly over the long term. The number of demand deposit transactions more than doubled. The velocity of transactions (measured by the number of times a dollar of debits is charged against de posits in a given period) nearly tripled.5Furthermore, the importance of demand deposits, a major source of lendable funds, declined in relation to the banks’ total li abilities, from 43 percent in 1967 to 27 percent in 1979.6 Intensifying demand deposit activity, especially during 1967-73, contributed to pressures to introduce such la bor-saving procedures and equipment as electronic funds transfers ( e f t ) . 7 Thus, according to a study conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, the number of checks written by the public rose at an average annual rate of 7.2 percent during the first half of the 1970’s and declined to a rate of 5.6 percent during the second half.8 In addition to the cash-economizing efforts by the public, evident from the tendency to hold relatively low check balances after the mid-sixties,9 certain kinds of fi nancial transactions have generated large amounts of account activity. For example, the number of shares traded on the New York Stock Exchange in the seven ties averaged nearly 3 times the volume of the sixties. Such trading usually involves multiple funds transfers through the banking system. The number of commodity futures contracts traded on commodity exchanges near ly tripled between the first and the second half of the 1967-79 period.10 Such trading also entails numerous funds transfers through the banks. The underwriting of stock and bond issues, usually by syndicates, which also rose in the mid- and late seventies, spells the pooling of lender funds and ultimate transfer to the borrower; “(Debits) totaling several times the amount of the fi nancing involved may be recorded in this process. . . .” n There were some developments that tended to retard the growth of transactions and check volume—for ex ample, mergers, which cause book credit and debits to replace bank transactions; bank credit cards, which tend to consolidate individual payments; and the long term trend towards the output of services relative to goods, making for fewer intermediate transactions. These tendencies were largely offset, however, by the upswings in manufacturing and construction, which re sult in numerous intermediate transactions. Time deposits generally expanded rapidly following the progressive liberalization of permissible rates under the Federal Reserve’s Regulation Q. Liberalization strengthened the banks’ position in retaining and attracting funds which would otherwise have been in vested elsewhere. Savings and other time deposits held at the commercial banks by individuals, partnerships, Output of banking services Output of commercial banks as measured by BLS rose at an average annual rate of 6.0 percent between 1967 and 1980—twice as fast as output of the total private business sector. Sources of the strong growth were the boom conditions of the early seventies and the financial needs they generated; rapid increases in check transac tions; relatively greater reliance by business on external funds; and continuously heavy demand for consumer and real estate credit. Also, commercial banks expanded their share of major types of such credit, as well as of time deposits. Moreover, they emphasized the retailing aspects of their services and consequently accelerated branching. Trust department functions also grew apace as pension and other employee benefit funds proliferated. Banking output rose at a higher rate during the 1967-73 period (7.8 percent a year) than during the 1973-80 span (4.6 percent annually). Output was damp ened considerably more in the recession that bottomed in 1975 than in 1970. Loan demand rose more rapidly prior to the 1975 recession than after. The rate of deposit 59 and corporations climbed 106 percent betvyeen 1968 and 1980, while demand deposits rose 52 percent. Time deposits accounted for 60 percent of total commercial banking deposits in 1980, as against 54 percent in 1968 (and 35 percent in 1960). Some observers have noted that, in view of such technological advances as electron ic funds transfers, the distinction between time and de mand deposit accounts has become less significant.12 Table 1. Productivity and related indexes for commercial banking, 1967-80 [1977 = 100] Year Loans. Expansion of loan output was another source of output growth. The rate of increase of loan output had begun to accelerate prior to 1967, and some of the un derlying factors— for example, the emphasis on retail banking— have, of course, a long history. Loan volume being highly susceptible to the impact of the business cycle and of monetary policy on the demand for funds, year-to-year movements proved to be much more erratic for lending than for the volume of deposit transactions. The long-term trend was influenced by the increasing propensity of business to contract for term loans (that is, loans with maturities of more than 1 year); the con tinued accent upon retail banking; and banks’ growing share of mortgage and consumer credit. Nonfinancial business became more dependent upon funds raised in credit markets than it had been earlier (when corporations had relied more heavily upon inter nally generated funds). Between 1967 and 1980, the ra tio of credit market borrowing by nonfinancial business to its capital expenditures averaged 44 percent, com pared with 29 percent for the earlier sixties. The compo sition of commercial and industrial loans shifted toward term loans, indicating that banks were financing a growing proportion of the plant and equipment outlays as well as of inventories of nonfinancial business.13 Banks also stepped up their consumer credit opera tions. Here, too, growth, of course, originated in earlier years. The share of disposable income devoted to in stallment borrowing began to rise in the early sixties; at 16 percent in 1967, it continued to rise gradually to 20 percent in 1979. (In 1980, a recession year, the ratio dropped.) Furthermore, the commercial banks expanded their share of holdings of total consumer credit out standing from 42 percent in 1967 to 49 percent in 1973, remaining at about that level from then on. This gain was linked in part to a shift away from retail store cred it, together with growing consumer acceptance of bank credit cards and check credit.14 Growth in banks’ real estate loans was in large part tied to the expansion in residential and commercial con struction of the early seventies and to the strong recov ery of both after their slump in the mid-seventies. Banks also captured a larger share of total mortgage holdings, rising from 19 percent in 1967 to 25 percent in 1979 (as the share of insurance companies, in partic ular, declined). Growth in this area of lending was in Output per employee hour Output Employee hours Employees 1967 1968 1969 1970 ........................... ........................... ........... ............... ........................... 83.8 85.3 84.0 85.5 52.2 56.3 60.0 64.5 62.3 66.0 71.4 75.4 63.0 66.7 72.0 76.6 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ........................... ........................... ........................... ........................... ........................... 88.6 90.3 95.9 89.8 90.0 69.1 74.3 83.2 82.9 84.6 78.0 82.3 86.8 92.3 94.0 79.0 82.9 87.5 92.6 94.2 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ........................... ........................... ........................... ........................... ........................... 95.0 100.0 100.7 98.5 92.7 91.8 100.0 105.4 108.1 106.1 96.6 100.0 104.7 109.7 114.5 96.8 100.0 104.9 110.5 115.7 1.3 6.0 4.6 4.5 1967-80 average annual rate of change (in percent) ........... recent years also strongly influenced by household bor rowing against equity in existing homes.15 Trust services. Long-term gains in the trust department output of commercial banks have been associated with the growth in the number of fiduciary accounts and the activity these accounts generate. Between 1968 (when pertinent data first became available) and 1980, the number of such accounts rose 54 percent.16 The increase was linked to a more than threefold rise in employee benefit accounts, reflecting the spread of corporate retirement and other employee benefit plans, as well as of pension plans initiated by self-employed persons (Keogh plans).17 The number of personal trust accounts rose by two-thirds; they still constitute the single most important trust department service, representing more than three-fifths of bank-ad ministered trust accounts. Their rise has in part been re lated to the desire to shelter current income from taxation, notably as inflation has tended to push in comes into more heavily taxed brackets.18 Employment and changing skills Employment in commercial banking, currently num bering 1.5 million persons, rose 84 percent between 1967 and 1980, dr at an average annual rate of 4.5 per cent. Average weekly hours tended to decline some what, from 37.1 in the first 5 years of the period to 36.5 since then— owing chiefly to the employment of more part-time workers.19 In no year did aggregate employee hours decline, but their most vigorous rise occurred over the first half of the review period (5.6 percent an nually). That high rate was not equaled even during the cyclical recovery following the 1975 slump. From 1974 to 1980, gains averaged 3.8 percent annually. 60 Ncrasupervisory jobs accounted for nearly four-fifths of commercial banking employment in 1980. Of these jobs, office and clerical positions again accounted for four-fifths of employment in the top 100 banks, or 37 percent of total banking employment in 1980. Women staffed 85 percent of these jobs and about one-third of all officer positions. They accounted for two-thirds of banking personnel in 1980, compared with 41 percent of all payroll employment.20 The prevalence of relatively low-skilled jobs in banking is reflected by the ratio of average hourly earnings in the industry to average hour ly earnings in the private economy. Despite the growth of positions in computer programming and systems analysis, that ratio has tended to decline, from 0.87 in the sixties to 0.73 in 1980. Supervisory jobs in commercial banking have in creased in both absolute and relative terms. Such jobs accounted for 23 percent of employment in 1980, as against 17 percent in 1967, an increase of 144 percent. Nonsupervisory jobs rose 65 percent. The ratio of nonsupervisory to supervisory employees thus dropped from 5:1 in 1967 to slightly more than 3:1 in 1980. The increase in supervisory workers was in large part linked with the expansion of branching and the attendant needs for managerial personnel. It was also related to a rise in the number of loan officers, especially for install ment loans, and of credit analysts, who are frequently charged with supervisory responsibilities in addition to their regular work. Skills needed by commercial banking employees have changed considerably, even during the relatively short period examined here. For example, the number of bookkeeping operators has dropped by more than one half since 1969 (and by more than 90 percent since I960)— owing to the spread of electronic bookkeeping machines and computers, which require substantially fewer operators.21 Also, tellers have tended to become less specialized as branch banking has spread. The six usual teller classifications—note, commercial-savings, commercial, savings, vault, and all-round— have in many banks been reduced to one all-round teller classi fication. The practice of classifying tellers by commer cial or saving transactions has been declining.22 Most bank employees perform tasks related mainly to the banks’ depository functions and loan administra tion. A high school education is generally considered adequate preparation for entry level jobs. Bank officers, on the other hand, usually supervise the various finan cial and customer services. Loan officers, in particular, are expected to be knowledgeable about the industries from which the individual bank draws its customers and to be sensitive to the often unique problems cus tomers present— problems which frequently require handling on a personal basis. Officers usually have a college degree or an M BA.23 61 The labor inputs of commercial banks thus vary widely in terms of education, training, and skill com plexity. Also, wide differences exist between the tasks that can be automated and tasks that cannot be, with the work of loan officers being least susceptible to stan dardization and automation. However, even in this area, a growing number of supplementary tasks have been computerized.24 Fixed investment and technology Between 1967 and 1979, banks’ fixed capital, includ ing structures, furniture, and equipment, rose by a fac tor of three, while the stock of fixed nonresidential capital in the private business economy as a whole rose by a factor of nearly four.25 Price indexes to deflate the banks’ physical capital stock are not available, so no firm estimate of movements in constant-dollar value can be offered. When the deflators for the total capital stock of business are applied to that of the banks, a rise of about one-third in real terms would result. About 40 percent of the banks’ spending on fixed capital went for equipment and furniture during the re view period. In 1980, roughly half of the banks’ expen ditures for fixed capital other than structures was spent on computers and computer equipment.26 Fixed capital per employee in commercial banking, at about $16,000 in 1979, ran at three-fifths of the comparable figure for the business economy.27 Computer breakthrough. At the root of equipment spending has been the transformation of technology by electronic data processing ( e d p ). While banks progres sively mechanized their routine operations throughout the forties and fifties, the resulting efficiencies improved but gradually. Some students of the field, in fact, attrib uted these efficiencies more to the specialization of labor and economies of scale in the industry than to mechani zation.28 A 1960 study by the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia stated, “Since World War II, banks appar ently have expanded operations more by hiring extra people than by using better equipment.”29 According to the study, the technology used in banks had scarcely changed during most of the first half of the 20th centu ry. The same basic types of cash registers, punched card tabulators, billing and duplicating machines, and check signing equipment found in banks in 1914 were still the mainstay of banking technology at the end of World War II. Although computer developments during the fifties embodied the principle of machine readability, it was the introduction of magnetic ink character recognition (micr ) in 1958 that made the breakthrough of electron ic data processing in banking possible. The computer became an indispensable and major factor in improving banking productivity. Moreover, computer technology has rapidly spread throughout the industry. The first bank automation survey conducted by the American Bankers Association in 1963 showed only 7 percent of all commercial banks to be users of on-premise or offpremise computers. By 1968, 49 percent were users, and in 1980, when the latest available survey was conduct ed, 97 percent were. The pressures of cost efficiencies, organizational changes, and competition had reduced the proportion of surveyed banks without plans to auto mate from 84 percent in 1963, to 42 percent in 1968, to virtually nil in 1980.30 While the larger banks— those with $100 million-plus in deposits—generally maintain their own computer operations, smaller banks have in creasingly used their correspondent relations with the larger banks to gain access to computers. As of 1980, 26 percent of all banks operated on-premise computers, while 71 percent used off-premise computers, mostly at correspondent banks.31 Thus, size of bank, as measured by the dollar value of deposits, does not appear to have seriously inhibited the diffusion of EDP technology in the industry. The computer has had its greatest impact upon the deposit function, particularly upon check handling. Its full potential, however, is only beginning to be realized, inasmuch as optimally most payments transfers could be processed electronically, that is, without checks. But only a small proportion of payments is so processed at present. Each check is, in effect, “a special piece of cur rency, created for one transaction only, that has to pass through complex and repeated identification, verifica tion, accounting, and sorting operations before it is re tired.” 32 Until the mid-seventies, the enormous and steadily growing volume of checks (estimated at 32 bil lion in 1979) was expected to become too expensive to handle, even by computer. But evolving technology has expanded the check-processing capacity of computers, such that they are thought to be able to “handle any conceivable number” of checks.33 The currently most advanced (or “third-generation”) computer has a built-in reader-sorter processing capaci ty of 120,000 checks per hour. Manual reading and sorting of checks, which for many years has involved some machine processing such as high-speed readers, averages 1,200 to 1,400 checks, so that computer use for this phase of the check-handling process represents “order of magnitude” reductions in labor requirements.34 For other phases of check-handling, comparable pro ductivity advances have not been attained, although socalled rejects or exception items, which in earlier years required laborious interbank correspondence, have come to be processed with great efficiency thanks to coopera tive agreements. According to surveys by the Bank Ad ministration Institute, the average labor requirements for all phases of handling checks were reduced by well over one-half between 1970 and 1979 among surveyed banks, mainly because of computerized reading and sorting of checks and more efficient handling of excep tion items.35 In loan operations, EBP has been used for information retrieval, as well as in the administration and bookkeep ing operations of such loan categories as installment loans. Credit information, mortgage servicing, bank credit card billing, and accounting have also been among major computer applications. The proportion of personnel in installment loan operations has tended to decline, but the available data do not clearly point to improved productivity in this area of banking. Staff employed in handling bank credit cards— also a type of consumer credit— has expanded in recent years.36 Busi ness loan operations, which require a comparatively small proportion of bank personnel, have remained rela tively labor-intensive—largely owing to their specialized nature and the need for maintaining close customer contact. Even here, however, the computer is playing an increasing role. It is used to provide up-to-date credit analyses and to serve as a bankruptcy predictor. For the larger banks, it makes credit information on a worldwide basis rapidly available. It also facilitates the collection and arraying of data to meet the requirements of regulatory authorities, a task that is otherwise highly labor-intensive.37 Computer technology has also contributed to im proved productivity in trust departments. It has been primarily applied to information retrieval for purposes of controlling individual accounts.38 But it has been in creasingly used as well in stock trading by trust depart ments for customer accounts. With trust departments holding the largest share of assets in stocks (49 percent in 1980 by value), such trading accounts for the major part of their activity. The basis of automated stock trading has been a numbering system first devised by the American Bankers Association’s Committee for Se curity Identification Procedures in 1968. The use of committee numbers on stock certificates was mandated by the Securities and Exchange Commission in 1971. This and similar systems have tended to standardize stock identification and have contributed to the transfer of stock without the physical handling of stock certifi cates. These certificates are “immobilized,” that is, they remain in central depositories. Costly errors and redun dant bookkeeping entries have been nearly eliminated when trust departments have adopted the technology on which the bankers’ stock transfer system is based.39Pay ments and credits involving stock transfers likewise use the system. Relative to output, trust department per sonnel requirements have been evidently reduced as a result of these and other computer applications.40 Electronic Funds Transfer. Potentially the most impor tant use of the computer in banking remains electronic 62 ings in labor costs at current volumes of business—a factor that tends somewhat to retard the diffusion of the devices.45 According to one authority, 19,000 auto mated teller machines were in use at the end of 1980, each averaging about 4,600 transactions per month, more than 2.5 times the volume 4 years earlier— signi fying rapid consumer acceptance of this technology.46 The banks have also installed much technologically advanced equipment other than computers and teller machines. For example, word-processing equipment is now being operated in four-fifths of the larger and twofifths of the smaller banks. Optical character recogni tion equipment—used, for example, in the processing of credit card charge slips, checks, and direct bill pay ments— has likewise been installed in most larger banks.47 funds transfer ( e f t ). Although the technology for EFT has existed for nearly two decades, its acceptance by the public has been comparatively slow. Also, a large part of the costs of the check collection system and of de mand deposit transactions was absorbed by the Federal Reserve and the banks, rather than passed on to users. Nevertheless, EFT has been increasingly adopted by the banks since the mid-seventies. Competition among fi nancial institutions, as well as the developing cost ad vantages of ED P over conventional transfer activities, are likely further to speed adoption of EFT technology.41 EFT has been increasingly applied in interbank settle ments through automated clearinghouses and in basic kinds of teller operations involving customer services, such as deposits and withdrawals, direct deposit of pay rolls or other recurring payments, direct bill payment, and transfer of funds from savings accounts to demand deposit accounts and vice versa. Point-of-sale terminals, linking merchants with a network of local banks, have also been spreading, although their acceptance and use have remained limited.42 Automated clearinghouses have spread rather gradu ally, although they have not replaced the conventional clearinghouse process as they handle only paperless credit and debit entries between banks. Originating in San Francisco in 1972, automated clearinghouses cur rently link an estimated 14,000 financial institutions and their offices; they process an estimated 300 million items annually.43 This number represents but a small fraction of the total number of checks drawn on banks other than the payor’s own bank, but it is expected that auto mated clearinghouses will account for a rising propor tion of all items in the clearing process. Among reasons for this expectation have been the success of the direct deposit of social security payments and of a growing number of public and private payrolls; the associated savings in mailing costs; less work incident to replacing lost checks, and the cost pressures linked to the han dling of paper items (which despite the increasing effi ciency of the process has been more and more comple mented or replaced by e f t ) .44 The growth of branch banking The number of commercial banking firms barely rose 5 percent between 1967 and 1979. But the total of banking offices increased 62 percent, mostly reflecting a doubling in the number of bank branches, and a con tinuing shift of offices towards the suburban population centers of metropolitan areas. The average population served per bank office declined from nearly 6,000 per sons in 1970 to 4,400 in 198Q.48 The decline suggests that banking services became more widely and conven iently available to the public. Current-dollar disposable income per capita nearly tripled during 1967-80 (as did personal consumption expenditures), and households generated an expanding volume of banking business, supporting the spread of branch banking. Most banks are comparatively small. Those holding total deposits of up to $50 million represent 79 percent of all commercial banks, but in 1979 accounted for only 15 percent of total deposits. Smaller banks usually maintain correspondent relations with the larger banks, and this relation amounts to a “form of multi-office banking.”49 Some of the efficiencies or customer utilities associated with large-scale banking are likely, therefore, to be shared throughout most of the industry. The larger banks, however, are dominant. The share of deposits held by the Nation’s largest banks— those with deposits of $500 million or more— was 62 percent in 1979. These banks constitute little more than 2 per cent of total banks. Moreover, in metropolitan areas, the two largest banking organizations usually hold be tween 55 percent and 67 percent of deposits (the ratio tends to be lower in unit banking States, higher in statewide branching States).50 Adoption of computer technology has been shown to be closely associated with bank size, as well as with holding company affilia tion.51 As might be expected, banking employment is also concentrated in the bigger banks. Banks holding $500 Teller machines. Automated teller machines spread rap idly in the late seventies. Providing customer access by means of a magnetic-stripe bank card and unique iden tification entered upon a keyboard, the machines receive deposits and payments and dispense cash. Twenty-four hour access is a frequent feature, enhancing customer convenience and reducing waiting lines. Thus, automat ed teller machines in effect extend banking hours, al though banks also view them as “peaking” equipment, helping to reduce lobby traffic during peak hours of business. The machines substitute capital for labor, but for many medium- and smaller size banks, the relatively high fixed costs of the equipment are not offset by sav 63 million or more in deposits employed 56 percent of all banking personnel in 1979. Banks with less than $100 million in total deposits— 89 percent of all banks — employed 27 percent of all personnel.52 Among changes in the competitive pattern of finan cial institutions that have affected banks has been the spread of NOW (negotiable order of withdrawal) ac counts at thrift institutions; their effect on the share of time deposit accounts at commercial banks, however, cannot be assayed yet. In some other areas, the role of commercial banks has been eroded. More efficient cor porate cash management, spurred by high interest rates and advanced information technology, has diminished the relative importance of demand deposits. Also, com mercial banks have evidently been unable to expand their share of credit cards (15 percent of 600 million outstanding cards in recent years). Also, business and consumer credit extended by very large department store chains, automotive companies, farm equipment makers, and EDP manufacturers grew in importance un til the early seventies, although their share of financial assets has apparently stabilized since.53 have continued to improve, and processing and mailing costs of checks to rise. Direct deposit of payrolls and of other recurring pay ments, and direct bill payment will likely also expand, partly owing to the costs of float, which banks must as sess as an explicit cost under recent legislation, as well as because banks must offset the cost of handling checks against interest on demand deposits (where such interest is offered). Thus, resistance to EFT is likely to lessen as costs of processing paper items rise— speeding its diffusion. Continued technological advances and the labor sav ings expected from them will probably also arise from intensified competition by nonbank financial institu tions. Thus, money market funds have come to compete with time and saving deposits for both the small and large investor’s dollar, and this, too, may contribute to restricting commercial banks’ output growth.56 Also, more than 80 percent of all household and virtually all business firms had checking accounts in 1977, so that the expansion of banking services from including addi tional households is quite limited. A partially offsetting factor may be a continued rise in cash withdrawals from automated teller machines, which are believed to be smaller and more frequent than withdrawals by cashing checks.57 The convenience in the use of banking services made possible by the machines may encourage the banks to adopt product lines similarly appealing to customer convenience.58 With the spread of EFT, and other computerized and automated transactions, banks’ labor requirements per unit of output are bound to continue to decline. More over, new branch staffing needs should be decreasing, partly because of the technological developments dis cussed, partly because of the already low level of popu lation served per branch, and the consequent abatement in the number of new branches opened. Hence, com mercial banks will probably become less important as a source of added employment in the years ahead— also indicated by BLS projections to 1990, which imply a slower rate of banking employment growth than over the past decade. Outlook for the industry The diffusion of EFT is likely to help improve labor productivity in commercial banks in the years ahead. During the late seventies, doubts about its widespread acceptance were expressed in some quarters.54 Resis tance by consumers to abandoning payment by check and their fear of loss of control over balances were cited as two reasons. Regulatory questions concerning the off-premises installation of automated teller machines were another. Also, smaller banks were believed to have opposed EFT because of possible competition from big money-center banks. These obstacles to the diffusion of EFT have so far been only partly overcome. However, cost considerations seem likely to compel its more rapid adoption. To illustrate, in a study of the benefits of electronic government payments done in 1977, the Fed eral Reserve found the costs of EFT to run nearly twothirds below the costs of processing checks.55 The ratio has lessened since then, for the scale economies of EFT 1 Commercial banks are establishments primarily engaged in accept ing deposits from the public and making loans and investments. They are designated as No. 602 in the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) Manual of the Office of Management and Budget. The industry is part of SIC 60— banking, which also includes Federal Reserve Banks, mutual savings banks, trust companies not engaged in deposit banking, and establishments performing functions closely related to banking. Nonbanking subsidiaries of bank holding companies are not included; they are separately classified by primary activity. See Federal Reserve Bulletin, December 1972. Commercial banks account for ap proximately 90 percent of the employment of the total SIC 60 group. A detailed description of banking output and of the procedures followed in measuring banking productivity, output, and employee- 64 hours, as well as the weighting scheme underlying the output mea sure, is available upon request. 2 There is wide agreement among industry observers that scale econ omies in banking have declined with the spread of branching — that is, more resources, including labor inputs, are required per unit of output. Among definitive studies are Costs in Commercial Banking, by Frederick W. Bell and Neil B. Murphy (Federal Reserve Bank of Bos ton Research Report No. 41, April 1968), and “Economies of Scale and Marginal Costs in Banking Operations,” by George J. Benston {The National Banking Review, June 1965), reprinted in that report. Industry observers confirm that the tendencies analyzed in these works have persisted. nors, Federal Reserve System, July 1968). Banks’ adoption and opera tion of credit plans of their own has had significant implications for their output: although credit cards result in consolidation of payments and, therefore, reduce the number of check transactions, they generate sales drafts which must be cleared through merchant’s deposit ac counts. Thus, they augment “the paperwork burden to the extent that (they replace) cash in a retail transaction” (p. 63.) 15David F. Seiders, Mortgage Borrowing Against Equity in Existing 3Professor Charles F. Haywood of the College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky, interprets the swings in commer cial banks’ labor productivity as follows: . . (At) the beginning of an upswing, banks have some slack in manpower and can increase output somewhat without increasing the rate of new hires. At some point in the upswing, the rate of new hires has to be increased. By the time these new hires are in place, the upswing in the economy is near its end and recession soon follows. There may also be some variation in labor turnover rates related to cyclical variation in the economy that affects input-output relationships in banks . . . (As) turnover rates are high in banking, cyclical variation in such rates could have significant effects on productivity.” Communication to the BLS Office of Productivity and Technology. 4Among authorities upon whose conception of the banks’ functions and output the BLS definition is partially based is Professor Donald Hodgman of the University of Illinois. Hodgman has viewed banking activity as consisting of a bundle of services, grouped into three cate gories: management of the national payments mechanism; intermedia tion between borrowers and lenders; and specialized financial services (of which trust activities are by far the most important ones). See Donald Hodgman, Commercial Bank Loan and Investment Policy (Urbana, University of Illinois, 1963), p. 165 ff; and John Gorman, Com ment, “Real Output and Productivity of Banks,” in Victor R. Fuchs, ed., Production and Productivity in the Service Industries (New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1969), p. 189 ff. 5See Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1941-1970, Board of Gover nors, Federal Reserve System, p. 321 ff., for a detailed explanation of the turnover rate of demand deposits. 6These and other data on commercial banks’ shares in financial as sets or liabilities were calculated from data from Flow o f Funds Ac counts (Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System), various recent issues. 7 “Earliest concern with the payment system was rooted in the fear that growing check volumes posed a threat to the continued satisfac tory performance of the system. Studies sponsored by the Federal Re serve System and by several national associations of commercial banks in the 1960’s placed virtually their entire emphasis on two areas: measuring the national check volume, the pattern of the flows of checks into and through the banking system, and check processing costs; and offering technical and economic feasibility assessments of electronic alternatives of the time to check clearing and collection sys tem. The emphasis throughout was on the use of electronic means to replace checks, or to reduce check handling, through systems created and cooperatively operated by groups of commercial banks, with a key role implied or advocated for the Federal Reserve System.” Ed win B. Cox, “Developing an Electronic Funds Transfer System: Incentives and Obstacles,” The Economics o f a National Electronic Funds Transfer System, proceedings of a conference held in October 1974 (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston), p. 16. 1A Quantitative Description o f the Check Collection System: Vol. 1, a report of research findings on the check collection system, cosponsored by the American Bankers Association, Bank Administra tion Institute, and Federal Reserve System (Atlanta, Ga., Federal Reseive Bank, 1981), p. 1. See also Bryan Higgins, “Velocity— Money’s Second Dimension,” Monthly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, June 1978, and George Garvy and Martin R. Blyn, The Velocity o f Money (New York, Federal Bank of New York, 1970), p. 69. “New York Stock Exchange, Fact Book 1980, and U.S. Commodi ty Futures Trading Commission, Annual Report ( 1980). Homes: Measurement, Generation, and Implications for Economic Activ ity (Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System, 1978), Staff Eco nomic Studies 96. 16See Trust Assets o f Banks and Trust Companies (Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System; Federal Deposit Insurance Cor poration; and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency), 1980 and earlier years. 11Indicative of the increase in corporate pension and welfare plans is the rise in the number of such plans reported by the U.S. Depart ment of Labor. As of January 1, 1970, 157,400 such plans were re ported, the number rising to 554,000 by 1977. The bulk of the assets in which the plan administrators invest consists of stocks and bonds. See Welfare and Pension Plan Statistics, 1967, 1969, and 1971 (U.S. Department of Labor, Labor-Management Services Administration), and information from LMSA. 18Interview with a banking representative. 19Part-time workers accounted for almost one-sixth of all nonsupervisory office workers in surveyed commercial banks in 1980, up from one-eighth in 1976, according to Industry Wage Survey: Banking, February 1980, Bulletin 2099 (Bureau of Labor Statistics), p. 3. 20Equal Employment Opportunity Commission Summary Statistics, Top 100 Full Service Banks. 21 Technological Change and Manpower Trends in Six Industries, p. 51, and Industry Wage Survey: Banking, p. 4. 22Industry Wage Survey: Banking, p. 4. 23See Banking and Insurance Occupations, Bulletin 2075-7 (Bureau of Labor Statistics). 24David M. Coit, “Automated Financial Analysis: A New Tool for Commercial Lending,” The Journal o f Commercial Bank Lending, March 1977. 25Assets and Liabilities o f all Commercial Banks in the United States, Annual Report for 1980 and Earlier Years (Washington, Federal De posit Insurance Corp.). 26Information on the average annual expenditures per bank for computer equipment, 1980-82, is provided in table 224 of National Operations/Automation Survey, 1981 (Washington, American Bankers Association). 27The prices for computer hardware, as well as for calculating and accounting machinery, widely used by the banks, rose much more slowly than producer durables prices generally or tended to decline over part or all of the review period. See Robert B. Archibald and William S. Reece, “Partial Subindexes of Input Prices: The Case of Computer Services,” Southern Economic Journal, October 1979, pp. 528-40. The authors show that second generation computers, manu factured for large business uses by IBM, dropped in price by 85 per cent between 1970 and 1975. Reasons for the drop are discussed by them. At present, the BLS imputes movements in the value of com puter hardware to the office and store machines and equipment group. 28See Bell and Murphy, Costs in Commercial Banking, discussion in chapter VII, p. 105 ff. 29 “How Banking Tames its Paper Tiger,” Business Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia), June 1960. 30See National Operations/Automation Survey 1981 (Washington, American Bankers Association), p. 7. ' Garvy and Blyn, The Velocity o f Money, p. 43. 2 “Increasing Competition between Financial Institutions,” Eco nomic Perspectives (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago), May/June 1977, p. 23 ff. 13Term loans rose from 40 percent of total commercial bank loans in 1967 to 44 percent in 1973 and 48 percent in 1978. 14For some reasons why banks attempt to expand their credit card systems, see “EFT in the United States, Policy Recommendations and the Public Interest,” The Final Report of the National Commission on Electronic Fund Transfers (Washington, October 1977), p. 134. See also Bank Credit-Card and Check-Credit Plans (Board of Gover 31 Ibid. 32John E. Sheehan, “Higher Productivity Demand Deposits,” in The 1972 National Operations and Automation Conference Proceedings (Washington, American Bankers Association), p. 363. 33John S. Reed, executive vice president of Citibank, quoted in “Electronic Banking: A Retreat from the Cashless Society,” Business Week, Apr. 18, 1977. See also Sanford Rose, “Checkless Banking is 65 17. See also David A. Walker, An Analysis o f Changes in EF TS Activi ty Levels, Costs and Structure in the U.S.: 1975 to 1977 (Washington, Bound to Come,” Fortune, June 1977, p. 118 ff. 34 Information from Bank Administration Institute and Federal Re serve. Federal Deposit Insurance Corp.), Working Paper No. 77-3, especial ly p. 7. 46 Linda Fenner Zimmer, “ATM Acceptance Grows, Builds Cus tomer Base for Other EFT Services,” The M agazine o f Bank Administration, May 1981, p. 31. Cited in Statistical Information on the Financial Services Industry (Washington, American Bankers Asso ciation, 1981), p. 107. 47American Bankers Association, 1978 Survey, op. cit. On the pro ductivity effects of such equipment, see also David Cockroft, “New Office Technology and Employment,” International Labour Review, November-December 1980, p. 689 ff. 48 Statistical Information on the Financial Services Industry, p. 89. 49 Carter H. Golembe, “Growth of Bank Holding Companies,” in Herbert V. Prochnow, ed., The Changing World o f Banking (New York, Harper & Row, 1974), p. 23. 50“Recent Changes in the Structure of Commercial Banking,” Fed eral Reserve Bulletin, March 1970, p. 207. 51 See Charles F. Haywood, “Regulation, Technological Change and Productivity in Commercial Banking,” in Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries (New York, Academic Press, 1981), p. 300-01. 52Based on unpublished data of the Federal Deposit Insurance Cor poration. 53Will R. Sparks, Financial Competition and the Public Interest (New York, Citicorp., 1978), p. 23, also pp. 16, 17. 54 Reed, “Electronic Banking.” See also William Ford, The Pay ments System o f the 1980's, presented at the Second Annual Shared EFT Systems Conference, Atlanta, Ga., Feb. 5, 1981 (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta). 35 See 1979 Survey of the Check Collection System (Park Ridge, 111., Bank Administration Institute, 1980). 16 Functional Cost Analysis, 1979 Average Banks. Based on data furnished by 751 participating banks in 12 Federal Reserve districts. Computer processing of bank credit card transactions has remained similar to that of checks and therefore is technologically not as ad vanced as computer processing of transactions under credit cards is sued by the big oil companies, where optical character recognition has been part of the computer operation. (Conversation with ABA repre sentatives.) ’’“Automated Financial Analysis.” 38 Third Trust Operations and Automation Workshop, 1972 Proceed ings (Washington, American Bankers Association). See also The Bottom Line: Proceedings, 1976 National Trust Operations and Automa tion Workshop, New York, March 21-24, 1976, remarks by William Schladebeck, p. 216 ff. 39 Third Trust Operations— Proceedings, p. 58. 40 H. Russell Morrison, “CUSIP Report— Beyond Apr. 1, 1972,” Third Trust Operations <6 Proceedings, p. 58. 41 See N. Sue Ford, “Electronic Funds Transfer: Revolution Post poned,” Economic Perspectives (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago), November-December 1980, p. 16 ff. Competition between different types of financial institutions has been fostered by high interest rates together with NOW (negotiable order of withdrawal) accounts at thrift institutions, and of share drafts at credit unions. Such instru ments have been authorized on a national basis by the Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980. A detailed analysis of this law may be found in Economic Perspectives, September-October 1980, p. 3 ff. 55 Costs, Savings and Benefits o f Electronic Government Paym ents (Unpublished study by the Division of Federal Reserve Bank Opera tions, Board of Governors, Federal Reserve system, June 1977). 36See “The Changing Environment for Banking,” an address by J. Charles Partee, before the American Institute of Certified Public Ac countants Annual National Conference on Banking, Capitol Hilton, Washington, D.C., Dec. 4, 1980. Also, “America’s New Financial Structures,” Business Week, Nov. 17, 1980, p. 138 ff.; and Constance Dunham, “The Growth of Money Market Funds,” New England Eco nomic Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston), September-October 1980, p. 20 ff. 37On the factors influencing the evolution of EFT and the check payments system, see The Paym ents System o f the 1980's, op. cit. 38Some nonbank services built into ATM’s are noted in “Diebold’s Shift to Automated Tellers Works,” by Margaret Yao, The Wall Street Journal, July 15, 1982, p. 45. 42 Ford, “Electronic Funds Transfer,” p. 18. 43 Haywood, communication to the BLS. See Philip E. Coldwell, “The ACH in Perspective” (Remarks at the 4th Annual NACHA Surepay Conference, Houston, Tex., Mar. 13, 1979), p. 3. 44 Ford, “Electronic Funds Transfer,” p. 16. See also Carl M. Gambs, “Automated Clearinghouses— Current Status and Pros pects,” Economic Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, May 1978), p. 3 ff. 45 ATM’s often “substitute . . . for a more costly full-service brick and-mortar branch.” Haywood, communication to BLS. Another ob server has stated that, “The ATM also reduced the need for tellers, lowering not only the salary cost to the bank, but also of employee benefits and pension plans.” Ford, “Electronic Funds Transfer”, p. 66 Productivity and new technology in eating and drinking places Labor-saving techniques fo r preparing meals, the rapidly expanding fa st food chains and a decline in the number o f drinking places have altered output and hours in the industry , R ic h a r d B. C a r n e s a n d H o r s t B r a n d Productivity in eating and drinking establishments1 rose at an average annual rate of 1.0 percent between IS1SB (when adequate data became available) and 1976, but varied widely over the 18-year span. Output increased 3.1 percent annually and hours, 2.1 percent.2 (See table 1.) During the same period in the private economy, productivity advances averaged 2.8 percent a year. Factors that have contributed to the advance of productivity in the food service industry are the spread of modem management techniques and work organization, particularly in the rapidly expanding fast food segment of the industry. Menus have been simplified and standardized, and menu items are in creasingly prepared off premise, reducing on-premise employee-hour requirements. Layouts of establish ments are designed to minimize walking time of per sonnel. Technological innovations, such as the mi crowave oven, reduce cooking time. Finally, the decline in the number of single-unit drinking estab lishments (usually proprietorships and partnerships) has resulted in the disappearance of marginal enter prises. Trends, Between 1958 and 1964, output per hour rose at an average annual rate of only 0.5 percent, reflecting gains below the long-term trend in both output and aggregate hours. Between 1964 and 1968, productiv ity increases accelerated, averaging 2.3 percent a Output and growth factors. The industry’s output gains reflect an upward trend in real per capita spending on meals eaten away from home. At $159 per capita in 1976 (constant 1972 dollars), such spending has risen 24 percent since the mid-1960’s with all of the rise having occurred since 1973.3The relation between changes in industry output and changes in real per capita income is illustrated below: 1 9 5 8 -7 6 1 9 5 8 -6 3 1 9 6 3 -6 8 1 9 6 8 -7 6 ............................................ ............................................ ............................................ ............................................ O u tp u t R e a l p e r c a p ita in c o m e 3.1 1.6 4 .0 3 .0 2.8 1.5 4 .0 2.3 Relatively slow advances in real per capita income were associated with modest output growth in the earlier years; while rapid income increases were linked with accelerated output rates in the later years. The long-term trend in food service output was also influenced by the more rapid rise in the number Richard B. Carnes and Horst Brand are economists in the Division of Iedustry Productivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M o n t h l y L a b o r R e v ie w , September 1977. year, as output grew rapidly and hours advanced moderately. From 1968 forward, productivity im provement again slackened to 0.4 percent a year; however, output continued to expand vigorously, ac companied by relatively large increases in hours. Year-to-year changes in the trend of labor produc tivity deviated significantly from the long-term aver age. The largest annual gain, 3.4 percent, occurred in 1970; the largest decline, 2.2 percent, occurred the following year, when output rose slightly and hours expanded sharply. 67 of households headed by unattached individuals (97 percent between 1960 and 1975) than in the number of families (24 percent). Such individuals are more likely to eat out than families: according to the latest Bureau of Labor Statistics consumer expenditure survey, 1-person households, on average, spend 40 percent of their food budgets on meals away from home, compared with 25 percent for families (the proportion diminishes as size of family increases).4 Moreover, between 1960 and 1975, real incomes rose faster for unattached individuals than for families— 56 and 34 percent, in constant dollars.5 Another important factor that bolstered output gains in food service was the increase in the number and proportion of wives in outside employment, con tributing to family incomes. In 1975, 44 percent of all wives (husband present) held a paid job, com pared with 31 percent in 1960. Real income of such families climbed 37 percent over that period; real incomes increased 27 percent for families with wives not in paid employment. The absolute difference in income between the two categories, 35 percent in 1975, made a significantly larger absolute difference in their spending on meals eaten out—51 percent.6 The overall increase in spending for meals' and snacks eaten away from home was accompanied by a shift from full-service restaurants to fast-food es tablishments. This shift has given rise to greater fre quency of eating out and to consumption of lower priced meals. The share in total industry receipts of restaurants and lunchrooms declined from 62 per cent in 1958 to 50 percent in 1972; over the same period, the share of refreshment places (which in cludes most fast-food units) quadrupled, and stood at 26 percent in 1972. Commercial cafeterias raised their share from 6 to 8 percent. The remaining share T a b le 1. fo o d of industry receipts is accounted for mostly by drink ing establishments which, like restaurants, suffered a large loss in market penetration over the 1958-76 period. The average transaction in fast-food establish ments is about three-quarters of that in full-service restaurants.7This does not mean that consumer pref erences have shifted to cheaper foods; surveys of representative menus conducted by Institutions/ Volume Feeding do not indicate significant changes in the choice of the major classes of breakfast foods, dinner entrees, or desserts.8 Rather, the evident in crease in the number of transactions at fast-food es tablishments has been accompanied by fewer services rendered to consumers (when compared with fullservice restaurants) and by a decline in the variety of foods offered, reflecting standardized menus.9 Employment doubles and hours moderate. Employ ment in eating and drinking places (currently 3.7 million) doubled between 1958 and 1976, rising at an average annual rate of 3.9 percent. Its growth, like that of output, was comparatively slow between 1958 and 1963 (1.7 percent annually), but accelerated from 1964 forward at an annual rate of 4.6 percent. Total hours of persons engaged in the industry rose about half as much as employment, with aver age weekly hours for nonsupervisory workers declin ing from 35.6 in 1958 to 28.0 in 1976. This drop in weekly hours resulted in part from the expansion of part-time work. In 1975, 51 percent of all workers in the industry worked part time, compared with 32 percent in 1962.10 Moreover, the number of proprie tors and partners dropped, and the working hours of supervisory personnel declined from an estimated 61 hours in 1958 to 51 hours in 1975. The occupational composition of food service workers has not changed significantly since detailed data first became available in 1972. (See table 2.) More than half of the employees occupy positions such as waiters, waiter assistants, counter and foun tain workers, or dishwashers. About one-third were cooks and bartenders and the remainder performed clerical, or managerial and administrative tasks.11 Limited data for earlier years indicate a steady con traction in the number of waiters and waitresses, and an expansion in jobs associated with counter work. In general, trends in food and equipment technology, together with organization changes, have increas ingly favored the employment of low-skilled persons in the industry—developments also promoted by ris ing labor costs,12 and the difficulty of attracting a stable work force. Data on the work experience, age, and sex of food service workers indicate a generally high turnover rate. The proportion in full-time, year-round jobs, 22 I n d e x e s o f p r o d u c t i v i t y , o u t p u t , a n d h o u r s in s e r v ic e e s t a b lis h m e n t s , 1 9 5 8 -7 6 [1 9 6 7 = 100 ] Yoar Output par hour of all parsons Output Hours of all parsons 1958 ............................... 1959 ............................... 1960 ............................... 1961............................... 1982 ............................... 1963 ............................... 1984 ............................... 1985 ............................... 1966 ............................... 1967 ............................... 1968 ............................... 1969 ............................... 1970 ............................... 1971............................... 1972 ............................... 1973 ............................... 1974 ............................... 1975 ............................... 1976 ............................... 91.3 90.3 90.0 90.8 91.8 93.8 93.1 96.0 98.0 100.0 101.9 100.1 103.5 101.2 104.4 106.0 102.8 105.0 103.2 78.8 81.0 81.6 81.5 84.0 86.0 89.8 95.5 99.4 100.0 105.6 106.3 110.4 111.6 118.5 124.6 122.9 127.4 131.9 86.3 89.7 90.7 89.8 91.5 91.7 96.5 99.5 101.4 100.0 103.6 106.2 108.7 110.3 113.5 117.5 119.6 121.3 127.8 ! 68 of single- or multi-unit establishments are influenced by the menu offered, and therefore cannot be used to indicate changes in labor productivity of specific em ployment size classes. However, efficiencies in the use of capital, materials, and organizational inputs undoubtedly have been greater in multi-unit than in single-unit establishments, and this largely accounts for the more rapid expansion of multi-unit busi nesses. The changes in the structure of the food service industry were marked by the expansion of fast-food establishments. According to a Department of Com merce survey, there were 43,000 franchised eating establishments in 1975, representing an estimated 20 percent of all eating and drinking places, and ac counting for 25 percent of industry sales.13 A study by the U.S. Senate Select Committee on Small Busi ness shows that the number of fast food units nearly tripled between 1960 and 1971, while the number of restaurants, other than fast food, declined 9 percent to 210,000.14 The expansion of fast-food establish ments has introduced profound systemic changes in the food industry which lie at the root of recent and future productivity improvements. Fast-food operators introduced principles of in dustrial engineering in retail food services—includ ing work organization and layout—which had previ ously been applied mainly by large institutional and industrial caterers or food contractors.15 These prin ciples have been implemented throughout numerous franchised or company-owned outlets. According to a survey by The Conference Board,16 all or the great majority of fast-food franchisers participating in the survey distributed operating manuals; operated man agement training programs; trained franchisee em ployees; selected sites; and designed facilities and layout. Moreover, many services to franchisees were rendered on a continuing basis, including counseling through field personnel; training of new employees; help with maintaining quality standards; and cen tralized purchasing. These organizational features are more prevalent among company-owned fast-food chains than among franchised establishments, and represent key elements in standardizing managerial practices.17 T®bS© 2. Employment in food service occupations, 1972 and 1976 1972 1976 Occupation Restaurant, cafeteria, and bar managers . . . Food service workers................................. Bartenders............................................. Waiters and assistants.......................... Cooks.................................................... Dishwashers........................................... Counter and fountain workers................. Other (except managerial)..................... Number Percent Number Percent 494 3,263 201 1,263 866 218 307 408 13.2 87.0 5,4 33.6 23.1 5.8 8.2 10.9 505 3,919 261 1,450 1,065 251 421 471 12.1 88.6 5.9 32.8 24.1 5.7 9.5 10.6 SOURCE: BIS Employment and Earnings. Comparable data for years prior to 1972 are not available. percent in 1976, was the lowest for any occupational category reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (except for private household workers). It compared with 53 percent for all service-producing workers outside of households, and 54 percent for all occupa tional groups. Women accounted for 64 percent of all workers in the industry, compared with 51 percent for all services outside households, and 44 percent for all occupational groups. Women are generally more likely than men to hold part-time jobs in the industry. Furthermore, the average age of the work force has declined over the past 15 years, suggesting a decline in the proportion of seasoned, experienced workers. In 1975, teenagers accounted for 30 percent of all food service workers, compared with 17 per cent for all service industries, and 8 percent for total nonagricultural payroll employment. Between 1960 and 1970, the median age of food service workers declined from 42 to 33 years. For the labor force as a whole, it remained constant at 40 years. Growth in multi-unit firms The eating and drinking place industry changed considerably during the 1958-76 period. The num ber of establishments dropped 4 percent, to 359,500, between 1958 and 1972 (the most recent year for which data are available). All of the decline occurred in drinking establishments serving alcoholic bever ages. While the number of drinking places dropped 7 percent, eating places rose 10 percent with nearly all of the rise in multi-unit operations, usually run by erne firm. Multi-unit establishments almost doubled ewer the 14-year period; single-unit establishments grew by less than 2 percent; and owner-operator units without paid employees dropped by one-third. No comparable changes occurred for drinking places, virtually all of which were owner-operated in both 1958 and 1972. The impact of these changes on the industry’s labor productivity cannot be demonstrated. Eating place sales per employee rose during the period, but variations from the average by employment size class Lslbor-savifig Innovations Productivity gains in the food service industry have been associated with three kinds of technologi cal advances: (1) the off-premise preparation of foods which permits reduction in on-premise preparation time and employee-hours, (2) the simplification of work processess through improvements in materials handling and cooking devices, and (3) innovations in food preservation methods and equipment. Food serv ice establishments have not adopted these technolo gies to the same extent; many of the higher priced 69 expenditures suggests that diffusion of innovated food service equipment has been rapid for corporate establishments but slow for others. Overall, capital expenditures rose 31 percent between 1968 and 1972, but much less in constant dollars—the same rate of advance as for the plant and equipment outlays of U.S. business as a whole. Corporate food service businesses, however, raised capital expenditures by 67 percent over the period; proprietary firms and partnerships, nartly because of the decline in their number, lowered capital spending by 15 percent. Hours of all persons in the industry rose 7 percent between 1968 and 1972.22 The major improvement in food service equipment has been the microwave oven. The heat generated in microwave ovens is distributed uniformly through out the product being cooked (rather than conducted from its surface inward, as in conventional ovens). Moreover, all the energy produced is absorbed by the product, rather than by the oven walls and the sur rounding air.23 Hence, processing time is greatly re duced, although microwave ovens are often supple mented by auxiliary equipment so that an acceptable product texture and surface color is obtained. Forced convection ovens have been rapidly adopted in the industry. These ovens are reported to reduce cooking time up to 50 percent by using a recirculating loop with a built-in fan to reheat the air within the cooking chamber, thereby increasing the rate of heat transfer to the product. Forced convec tion ovens are being installed in most new operations, and are replacing free-convection ovens in many ex isting facilities.24 Fat fryers have been refined for more convenient operation and better product quality. Processing control has been improved by more accurate timers and thermostats, and by automatic basket lifts which terminate cooking after a preassigned period. Pres sure containers, which increase the heat to the prod uct and thus speed up processing time, have been introduced.25 Gas burning broilers are still widely used, but commercial installations are beginning to use infra red heat to generate high temperatures and shorten cooking time. Operations producing large volumes of processed foods are increasingly using continuousflow broilers which require only unskilled labor once the temperature and speed of the transfer belt have been set.26 restaurants, for example, capitalize on the culinary skills of their staff, and use off-premise prepared (or convenience) foods on only a limited scale.18 The numerous single-unit small diners and refreshment places that characterize much of the industry are often slow to modernize their equipment, or unable to do so altogether. The trend, however, is in the direction of shortened food preparation time and higher ratios of equipment to employment. Food preparation. According to a 1974 survey, 70 percent of all respondents used fresh frozen meats and 56 percent used meats prepared to some extent off premises (for example, pre-cut to meet portion standards). Seafood, fresh frozen or otherwise par tially prepared, was served by more than 60 percent of all respondents, and fruits and vegetables prepared fully or partially off premises were offered by 40 percent. A significant proportion of respondents also served baked goods prepared off premise. The great majority using frozen or other partially prepared foods served them regularly, and not merely as sup plements to conventionally prepared foods.19 How ever, much of the food served is still prepared on the premises. For example, roughly 40 percent of all standard meat dishes—that is, fried chicken, meat balls, roast beef, steaks—are still prepared by restau rant. staff. Food service establishments have been substitut ing off-premise for on-premise prepared foods in order to reduce labor costs and to control the por tions served. Almost three-fifths of the respondents in a 1972 survey gave these two reasons for serving convenience foods.20 Other respondents cited the broadened menu, as well as reduction in costs per portion made possible by convenience foods. (Al though a substantial proportion of off-premise pre pared food originates in central kitchens or commis saries classified in the industry, some originates in food processing industries. See the appendix for a discussion of the effects on the productivity meas ure.) The use of foods prepared off premise facilitates large-scale operations. Units with 25 employees or more are more likely to offer such foods than smaller firms. Frozen entrees, for example, were served by more than two-fifths of the larger establishments, compared with one-third or fewer of the smaller ones. Frozen baked goods and vegetables showed the same pattern.21 Also, the use of such foods has im proved the uniformity of food quality, saved on in vestment in inventory, and has enabled the industry to reduce the level of needed culinary skills—partly in response to the shortage of qualified cooks and chefs.. Food preservation. Important developments have oc curred in the quick freezing of fresh foods and in the efficient thawing of frozen foods. Minor but signifi cant changes have also been taking place in other phases of food preservation. Whether or not food service establishments operate their own food proc Food processing. The trend in the industry’s capital 70 essing and preservation equipment, these changes tend to reduce on-premise preparation time, improve ths quality, and expand the variety of foods served. The development of thawing equipment has been spurred by concern with the nutritional and chemi cal deterioration of foods allowed to unfreeze for long periods and by the larger size of frozen food packages used in the industry. Microwave thawing systems can temper frozen foods in a few minutes.27 Thus, reduction in on-premise preparation time is sustained when efficient thawing systems are used. Changes in food preservation methods, other than freezing, have been modest in their impact on the food service industry. Dehydration, the most widely used preservation method, underwent no significant evolution during the period (except for freeze-drying of coffee).28 In canning, however, the aseptic process was introduced and spread rapidly. The process, which involves packing sterilized food in sterilized containers in a sterile environment, eliminates the change in flavor, texture, and appearance that usu ally results from thermal treatment of products for canning.29 While the use of all canned foods cuts the time spent in on-premise preparation (in comparison with cooking from the raw), the introduction of aseptic ally canned foods enhances the acceptability and extends the variety of foods. Some improvements ahead Productivity in the food service industry should continue to improve. The adoption of labor-saving equipment and off-premise prepared foods is likely to be spurred by the expansion of corporate establish ments with their focus on efficient management. The continued decline in the number of smaller marginal firms, while perhaps a loss in terms of customer con venience, will nonetheless help raise industry pro ductivity. Developments in food processing and preservation technology will probably make for more widespread oil-premise preparation of food, especially insofar as such developments improve quality and help broaden menu choices. Irradiation or radiation-pas teurization may become acceptable in preserving foods high in moisture content and therefore liable to rapid bacterial decomposition (for example, fish, fruits, and vegetables); freeze-drying may spread to products such as eggs; and aseptic canning is likely to spread. Completely integrated food service systems, with precisely timed and mechanized transfer operations, may increasingly mark the spread of contract feeding (they are not likely to prove feasible in smaller retail operations). In such systems, also called a “cooking street,” two persons operate five pieces of equipment —a steam cooker, a water cooker, a deep fat fryer, a grill, and a broiler. All pieces are removable with out tools, and there is a minimum of complex mech anisms. These “cooking streets” result in a very high ratio of meals served per employee;30 however, menus are necessarily restricted and there is little if any floor service. Standard menus and simple equipment have, in part, been dictated by persistent shortages of skilled kitchen personnel, and the resulting need for equip ment that can be operated with minimum training by unskilled persons of whom a high turnover rate is expected. In addition, customer self-service has spread, to some extent, to full-service restaurants with buffet offering. In fast food shops, customers often accept the job of clearing their tables. Such self-service tends to reduce the industry’s reliance on low-skilled labor. Over the long term, the supply of low-skilled workers is expected to contract, assuming full or near full employment is attained. Based on that as sumption, recent projections indicate a relatively small rise in the number of low-skilled or unskilled workers to the end of the decade; and a decline in the first half of the 1980’s.31 Incipient labor shortages would compel the industry to upgrade its work force and to develop career progression systems.32 At the same time, the industry will very likely continue to substitute capital for labor, possibly at a stepped-up rate. Output growth in the food service industry hinges, of course, on continued gains in real family and per capita income. The expansion in the proportion of working wives should continue to raise the demand for food eaten away from home. Some productivity advances may arise from cer tain changes in patterns of eating out. The traditional concept of three meals a day—tending to bunch labor inputs at peak periods—has in part given way to and in part been supplemented by a greater fre quency of consuming snacks or “mini-meals.” To the extent this pattern prevails, more efficient utilization of labor and capital would be attained, but food out lets would have to operate longer hours and therefore would have to generate higher output volume to en sure productivity gains. 1 Eating and drinking establishments include restaurants, lunch coun ters, refreshments stands, cafeterias, and other facilities selling food or drink (including alcoholic beverages) for on-premise consumption. Eat ing facilities in department stores, hotels, and motels are excluded, unless 7! leased to outside operators. The industry is classified as Eating and Drinking Places (code 58) in the Office of Management and Budget’s 15 For some applications of industrial engineering to food services, see Raymond Pedderson et al, I n c r e a s in g P r o d u c tiv ity in F o o d S e r v ic e (Chi cago, Institutions/V olum e Feeding Management, 1973), 206 pp. E cono mies through centralized purchasing appear in large measure to have been achieved through distributors in the wholesale industries. See Charles Sirey, Jr. “Food Service Logistics: Roadsigns in the W ilderness,” I n s t itu tio n s /V o lu m e F e e d in g , December 1970, beginning on page 53. 1 9 7 2 S t a n d a r d I n d u s tr i a l C la s s ific a tio n M a n u a l. 2 The average annual rates of change are based on the linear least squares trend o f the logarithms of the index number. Extension of the indexes will appear in the annual BLS bulletin, P r o d u c tiv ity I n d e x e s f o r S e le c te d I n d u s trie s . 16 E. Patrick McGuire, F r a n c h is e d D is tr ib u tio n (N ew York, The Con ference Board, 1971). 3 Corinne LeBovit, “The Changing Pattern of Eating O ut,” N a tio n a l F o o d S itu a tio n , No. 144, May 1973, p. 31. Data for recent years were derived from data com piled by the U.S. Department o f Commerce. 17 The M cD onald’s operations manual is a 385-page book detailed down to the most minute facets of running the stand and its machffiery. See Charles G. Burck, “Franchising’s Troubled Dream W orld,” F o rtu n e , March 1970, p. 116. 4 C o n s u m e r E x p e n d itu r e S u r v e y S eries: D ia r y D a ta 1 9 7 2 , Report 448-1 (Bureau o f Labor Statistics, 1975). ! M ost o f the 15-year real incom e gain of primary' individuals occurred from 1965 forward— 33 percent, compared with 16 percent for real family incomes. Gains in the average income of primary individuals are in part attributable to the rise in the average social security benefit which, for w idows and widowers, more than tripled between 1960 and 1975. The total number eligible more than doubled. All but $6 of the $124 monthly increase in the average benefit occurred from 1965 forward. 18 Marshall C. Warfel, “Convenience Foods— What is the Score?” T h e C o r n e ll H .R .A . Q u a r te r ly , May 1971, beginning on page 33. 19 See I n s t itu tio n s /V o lu m e F ee d in g , December 1974. 20 Ibid., September 1972. 21 Ibid., December 1974. 6 S e le c te d F a m ily C h a r a c te r is tic s a n d A v e r a g e W e e k ly E x p e n d itu r e s b y I n c o m e C la s s e s o f F a m ily I n c o m e B e fo r e T axes, Consumer Expenditure Diary Survey (Bureau o f Labor Statistics, 1976). 22 The long-term growth rate of capital in the food service industry (eating and drinking places) has been estimated at 3.4 percent annually for 1929-63, nearly twice that for total retail trade. The growth o f capital per em ployee-hour has been estimated at 0.6 percent annually for the same period, which compares with 0.7 percent for total retailing. See David Schwartzman, T h e D e c lin e o f S e r v ic e in R e t a i l T r a d e (Pullman, W ashington, State University, 1971), p. 67. 7 Corinne LeBovit, “The Changing Pattern,” p. 30. 8 See I n s t itu tio n s /V o lu m e F e e d in g (Chicago, Cahners Publishing Co.), April 1975. 9 See Theodore Levitt, “Production Line Approach to Service,” H a r v a r d B u s in e s s R e v ie w , September-October 1972, beginning on page 41. 23 The conversion of electrical into radiation energy remains relatively inefficient, although one manufacturer reportedly has claimed that his brand of microwave oven converts 72 percent of electrical into radiation energy. The average conversion range is estimated at 30 to 50 percent for all brands. See Frank W. Schmidt and Stephen Bartlett, “Food Processing and Preparation Equipment as It Shapes the Future of Food Service,” in Thom as F. Powers, ed. T h e F u tu r e o f F o o d S e r vic e , p. 94. A lso Thom as F. Powers, “Food Service in 1985,” T h e C o r n e ll H . R . A. Q u a r te r ly , May 1976, p. 47. 10 Unpublished data on work experience of the population in 1962 and 1975, Bureau o f Labor Statistics. 11 “The food services have been drastically reducing the number of skilled workers by simplifying the operation so that it can be run by quickly trained, low-paid, high-turnover em ployees.” See Daniel M. Seifer, “The Service Industries: Automation, Minimum Wages, Unem ployment,” B u lle tin o f B u s in e ss R e s e a rc h , The Ohio State University, Vol. 46, No. 8; G. E. Livingston, “Changes in the Food Service Indus try,” T h e C o r n e ll H . R . A. Q u a r te r ly , May 1974, p. 15; and “Young Women Who Work, An Interview With Myra W olfgang,” Irving Howe, ed., T h e W o r ld o f T h e B lu e - C o lla r W o r k e r (New York, Dissent Publish ing Co., 1972), p. 26. 24 Ibid., p. 93. 25 Ibid., p. 100. 26 Ibid., p. 104. 27 Ibid., pp. 89-90. 28 Ibid., p. 149. 29 Ibid., p. 191. 30 See the section on com pletely integrated systems in “Food Process ing and Preparation Equipment,” T h e F u tu r e o f F o o d S e rvic e , beginning on page 109. A lso see “Health Services,” T e c h n o lo g ic a l C h a n g e a n d M a n p o w e r T r e n d s in S ix I n d u s tr ie s , Bulletin 1817 (Bureau o f Labor Statistics 1974) p. 58. 12 See Thomas F. Powers. “Labor Supply, Payroll Costs and Changes.” T h e C o r n e ll H . R . A . Q u a r te r ly , May 1974, beginning on page 5. 11 Andrew Kostecka. F ra n c h isin g in th e E c o n o m y , 1974-76 (W ashing ton, D.C., U.S. Department of Commerce, 1976), p. 7. See also Philip B. Dwoskin, “Fast Food Franchises: Market potentials for agriculture products in foreign and domestic markets,” M a r k e tin g a n d T r a n s p o r ta tio n S itu a tio n , No. 196, February 1975, beginning on page 20. 14 31 See Harold Wool, “Future labor supply for lower level occupa tions,” M o n th ly L a b o r R e v ie w , March 1976, pp. 27-28. Quoted in Thomas F. Powers, ed., T h e F u tu r e o f F o o d S e r v ic e : A B a s is f o r P la n n in g (University Park, Pa., The Pennsylvania State Univer sity, Food Service and Housing Administration, 1974), pp. 35 and 41. 72 32 The Employment and Training Administration o f the U.S. Depart ment of Labor has sponsored several studies on em ployment and career progression in the food service industry. For example, see Gary L. Hotchkin, D e v e lo p m e n t o f C a r e e r P ro g ressio n S y s te m s f o r E m p lo y e e s in th e F o o d S e r v ic e I n d u s tr y (Chicago, National Restaurant Association, 1975). in farm machinery manufacturin Productivity gains, aided by new technology, especially computers, but moderated by cyclical downturns, averaged 2.6 percent a year over the 1958-80 period A rthur S. H erm an a n d Jo h n W. F e r r is Productivity, as measured by output per employee hour, in farm machinery manufacturing1 was about the same as the average for all manufacturing industries over the 1958-80 period. Growth was aided by numerically con trolled machine tools, automatic welding, computerized ma nufacturing, industrial robots, and computerized au tomatic warehouses, but was partially offset by sharp declines in demand. Almost every decline in productivi ty during the period studied can be associated with a drop in output, which, in turn, usually coincides with downturns in the economy. During the 22-year period, productivity in the farm machinery industry grew at a rate of 2.6 percent a year, compared with 2.7 percent per year for all manufacturing industries; 1.9 percent for construction machinery, an industry which uses similar manufacturing techniques; and 3.2 percent for motor vehicles, another similar industry. Output, productivity follow farm income Productivity growth in the farm machinery industry can be divided into three distinct periods. From 195865, productivity grew at an annual rate of 1.7 percent; from 1965-74, it accelerated to a 3.3-percent rate; and from 1974-80, slowed to 0.2 percent. (See table 1.) The higher rate of gain during the 1965-74 period can be as sociated with years of very high output, fueled by dra matic increases in farm income. Arthur S. Herman is an econom ist and John W. Ferris is a statistician in the Division of Industry Productivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Sta tistics. Reprinted from the M o n t h l y L a b o r R e v i e w , O ctober 1982. Productivity changes in the farm machinery industry are closely tied to output changes over the short term. Demand for farm machinery is based on a number of interrelated factors. A major factor is the overall state of the economy. However, an even more directly related factor is farm income. Changes in the output of farm machinery closely parallel changes in farm income. When farm income is up, farmers tend to purchase new equipment. Among the determinants of income are crop size, both actual and anticipated in the near future, and farm prices. Crop size is, of course, affected by a num ber of variables, including the weather, farm prices, government policies, and the worldwide food supply. Other important factors affecting the production of farm machinery are farmers’ costs, such as for loans, new machinery, land, fertilizers, and pesticides, as well as age and condition of existing equipment and imports and exports of farm equipment. When income is low and prospects appear poor, farmers tend to make do by repairing, rather than re placing, existing equipment. Conversely, when income is growing and prospects for further expansion of profits appear good, they tend to purchase new, more produc tive equipment. Demand for machinery increases signifi cantly during these expansive periods, as does produc tivity. The impact of the numerous variables affecting demand changes rapidly over time; therefore, output of farm machinery shows wide swings. Productivity, how ever, moves in a less volatile manner. For example, out put grew by 6.3 percent between 1958 and 1959, but then dropped precipitously in 1960, a recession year, falling 18.3 percent. Concomitantly, productivity had no growth in 1959 and dropped sharply, by 7.1 percent, in 1960. In 1966, output increased substantially, up 19.4 percent, then declined for 4 consecutive years, one of which was the recession year of 1970. Following output, productivity also grew substantially in 1966, up 6.2 per cent, and then dropped sharply, averaging 0.8 percent from 1967 to 1970. The early 1970’s were a period of high output growth, with gains of 16.5 percent in 1972, 21.3 percent in 1973, and 14.3 percent in 1974. This strong growth can be attributed to a sharp increase in farm income re sulting, in part, from large exports of farm products, in cluding sales of grain to Russia. Productivity recorded its largest advances during this period, with increases of 8.9 percent in 1971, 9.3 percent in 1972, 5.2 percent in 1973, and 3.6 percent in 1974. In the more recent period— 1980, a recession year— output dropped 15.1 percent, as farm income declined precipitously. In turn, productivity declined 6.7 percent. A factor affecting output over the long term is the continuously increasing size of farms. The average farm in the United States has shown a significant increase in size, growing about 40 percent in acreage over the peri od studied.2 This created a need for an increase in the physical dimensions and horsepower of farm machinery. To cope with the growing acreage, farmers purchased larger, more powerful equipment, rather than increasing their labor force. For example, the average horsepower ( p t o ) rating of tractors was 106 in 1980, compared with 67 in 1958. Demand for farm equipment has also been enhanced by such equipment as 4-wheel drive tractors, which allow farming in previously marginal areas, and such amenities as air conditioning and stereo radio and cassette equipment in the cabs of the larger units. Demand for larger, more productive farm machinery has been one factor leading to the industry’s long-term growth rate in output of 4.2 percent, somewhat higher than the 3.8 percent for the total manufacturing sector. Highly advanced farm equipment is one of many rea sons that productivity has been significantly higher in the farm sector than in the nonfarm sector. Table 1. Output per employee hour and related indexes in the farm machinery equipment industry, 1958-80 [1977=100] Output per hour Year 1958 . .. 1959 . .. 1960 . .. 65.1 65.1 60.5 64.9 63.4 61.3 65.5 70.3 58.6 49.4 52.5 42.9 75.9 80.7 70.9 76.1 82.8 70.0 75.4 74.7 73.2 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 ... ... . .. ... . .. 62.9 65.1 66.6 70.2 72.2 61.3 65.1 64.3 66.9 68.6 67.7 64.8 74.3 82.0 84.8 45.7 48.8 53.7 60.1 64.0 72.7 75.0 80.6 85.6 88.6 74.5 75.0 83.5 89.9 93.3 67.5 75.3 72.3 73.3 75.5 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ... . .. ... ... ... 76.7 76.8 76.7 73.8 75.7 72.3 73.3 75.0 73.2 75.2 92.7 88.8 82.1 75.9 77.3 76.4 73.6 70.8 65.8 65.1 99.6 95.8 92.3 89.1 86.0 105.6 100.4 94.4 89.9 86.6 82.4 82.9 86.2 86.7 84.2 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 .. . ... ... ... ... 82.4 90.1 94.8 98.2 97.7 83.0 87.0 90.7 92.6 95.3 81.0 99.9 109.2 118.3 105.2 66.2 77.1 93.5 106.9 100.0 80.3 85.6 98.6 108.9 102.4 79.8 88.6 103.1 115.4 104.9 81.7 77.2 85.6 90.4 95.1 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ... .. . .. . .. . ... 101.1 100.0 100.8 103.2 96.3 100.5 100.0 100.1 101.7 99.6 103.1 100.0 103.1 108.0 88.1 98.9 100.0 95.6 114.7 97.4 97.8 100.0 94.8 111.1 101.1 98.4 100.0 95.5 112.8 97.8 95.9 100.0 92.7 106.2 110.6 Average annual rates of change (percent)1 1958-80 1958-65 1965-74 1974-80 2.6 1.7 3.3 0.2 2.7 1.0 3.4 1.2 2.4 3.9 2.9 -2 .9 4.2 3.9 3.7 -0.1 1.5 2.2 0.5 -0.3 1.5 2.9 0.4 -1.4 1.8 ( 2) 0.8 2.9 ' Based on the least squares trend of the logarithms of the index numbers. •2Rate of change is less than 0.05 percent. employees per establishment has remained fairly con stant, dropping slightly from 74 in 1958 to 70 in 1977 (the average for all manufacturing industries was 53). The industry has a few very large firms with numer ous establishments making a variety of equipment— tractors, combines, and other harvesting equipment, crop sprayers, plows, harrows, planters, cultivators, hay balers, and fertilizing equipment. These firms are highly integrated and manufacture many of the parts that are assembled into the final products, including both gaso line and diesel engines, as well as replacement parts for the older units in operation. The large firms generally produce the larger equipment, such as grain harvesting combines, 4-wheel drive tractors, and accessories. There are numerous medium and small firms in the industry. They usually specialize in a particular line or type of equipment, such as milking, poultry, or irrigation equip ment. Many of them serve local markets for highly spe cialized equipment. The smaller firms also make lawn and garden equipment, such as walk-behind lawnmowers and snowblowers. Farm machinery manufacturers are concentrated in the Farm Belt, with most plants in mid western States— Illinois, Wisconsin, Minnesota, Iowa, Nebraska, and Plants located in Farm Belt The farm machinery manufacturing industry has paralleled the growth of agriculture in the United States. Some of the larger firms can trace their origins to the development of horse drawn harvesting equip ment in the early 1800’s. Therefore, farm machinery manufacturing is a mature industry, producing a variety of equipment for both U.S. markets and export. There were 2,148 establishments in the farm machin ery industry as of 1977, a significant increase over the 1,949 establishments reported in 1958. The number of Employee hours Production Nonpro All Production Nonpro Output All employees workers duction employees workers duction workers workers 74 an assembly operation which uses welding and fastening with air powered tools. Farm machinery is usually fin ished by painting, either in the parts stage or as a com pleted unit. Because of the complex nature of many of the products, the varied manufacturing operations involved in producing units, and the fact that farm machinery manufacturing is a mature industry with many old plants, there are numerous areas that are subject to technological change. The larger companies usually make most of the parts they assemble into the final product. Therefore, the technological innovations they employ cover a range of manufacturing operations and have resulted in significant labor savings. During the 1960’s, capital expenditures per employee for new plant and equipment were consistently below the average for all manufacturing industries. However, because of sustained demand for farm equipment in the early 1970’s which strained the industry’s capacity,5 firms began to increase their capital expenditures for new plant and equipment. By 1975, capital expenditures per employee had almost tripled, compared to the level in 1970. This resulted in the installation of advanced manufacturing equipment and large scale plant modern ization and probably was one of the factors leading to a higher rate of productivity increase during the 1970’s than during the earlier decade. Computers are among the widespread innovations with significant impact upon the industry. They are used for many functions, including inventory control, data collection, tracking progress of semi-completed products, design, and for numerous accounting and oth er business purposes. In recent years, computers have been more directly used for manufacturing operations on the factory floor. Numerically controlled machine tools are used exten sively by major companies in the manufacture of the parts used in assembling farm machinery. A recent in novation is computerized numerically controlled ma chine tools, which are more versatile than standard equipment because they can be programmed for chang es by the operator rather than from tapes. One unit in stalled in a large firm is a completely computercontrolled gear case transfer line, using numerically controlled machine tools, where parts automatically go through 87 machining operations.6 One plant is experimenting with a change in machine tool layout, from the traditional setup consisting of banks of individual machines designed for a single oper ation to cells of machine tools based on workflow. This new layout requires high volume, but has cut bottle necks in production and has resulted in operating effi ciencies. Automatic welding has replaced manual welding in a number of installations. In addition, industrial robots Kansas. Texas and California also have a large number of plants. The largest export market for U.S. manufacturers is Canada. In turn, Canada provides the largest amount of imports of farm machinery into the United States. Employment and faoinrs rapidly adjusted Over the 1958-80 period, the number and hours of production workers and nonproduction workers in the farm machinery industry have grown at similar rates. Production workers increased at an average annual rate of 1.7 percent and their hours grew 1.5 percent. Nonproduction workers grew at rate of 1.7 percent, and their hours increased at a rate of 1.8 percent. Year-to-year changes in employment and hours in this industry tend to move in a similar but less volatile pattern than changes in output. This indicates that the industry can adjust its hours and employment fairly rapidly to changing demand. For example, when de mand is falling overtime usually is cut, the number of shifts worked are reduced, the normal summer shut downs may be extended, and workers may be laid off. The extent of the adjustments in hours due to chang es in demand is influenced by the occupational makeup of the work force. In the farm machinery industry, the largest occupational group is operatives, most of whom are assemblers. Welders, precision machine operators, punch and stamp machine operators, and transportation operators also are important. These employees, along with laborers (mainly freight handlers) are most affected by reductions in demand. The industry also employs a large group of craftworkers— machinists, mechanics, tool and die makers, and blue-collar supervisors.3 Craftworkers are least affected by declines in produc tion; because of their skill levels, employers are reluc tant to lay them off for fear that they may not be available when demand picks up. Technology aids productivity Technological change varies greatly among plants in the farm machinery industry. The more advanced highly sophisticated equipment is used, for the most part, by larger firms engaged in mass production of various products. Slower changes are undertaken by the smaller firms which make short runs of highly specialized prod ucts and generally have limited capital.4 The level of complexity of farm machinery manufac turing differs greatly depending on the product, which can range from a simple plow pulled by a tractor to a complex self-propelled grain harvesting combine. How ever, there are factors common to most farm equipment manufacturing: most of the components are made of iron and steel; they are shaped by such processes as casting, cutting, stamping, punching, boring, and ma chining; and they are joined to form the final product in 75 is run by a single operator. The assembly lines are set up so that fasteners and other small parts are fed di rectly to the assemblers at the correct height for their use. This plant’s design significantly cuts parts invento ry, reduces handling, increases manufacturing efficiency, and results in overall labor savings. Besides robotic painting, which is just being intro duced in the industry, there are a number of other inno vations that increase painting efficiency. One system, electrostatic painting, has been used for a number of years. In this process, electrically charged parts move through an automatic paint spray booth, with the paint mist attracted to the charged part. Another innovation is electric dip paint lines, in which charged parts are dipped into a paint-filled tank from which paint is pre cipitated out on the part. These systems have resulted in savings in both paint and labor. While the advanced innovations are most readily adapted by the larger multiline companies, smaller firms in the industry tend to introduce new technology more slowly. Many of the latter specialize in a particular product, such as pipeline milking units or self-propelled irrigation systems. Although these units are usually pro duced from common components (pipes, tanks, spray guns, and pumps), they are generally assembled to fit a particular farmer’s need. Because of the semicustom na ture of production used by these smaller firms, it is dif ficult to adapt much of the available new technology which is designed for volume production. In addition, many of the smaller firms are located in rural areas near the farms they serve and do not have the access to the capital markets as do the major companies. are being introduced for welding functions, resulting in more versatile automatic welding operations. Significant efforts have been made to increase efficien cy in materials handling and warehousing functions. These functions are very important because of the nu merous parts that must be moved, the many operations that must be carried out, and the large size of the facto ries involved in the manufacture of the more complex farm machines. A number of plants have installed computerized automatic warehousing and materials han dling systems. In one plant, such a system is used for the materials receiving warehouse. The system is located in a special high rise building attached to the single story plant. Materials are shipped in using the plant’s containers, logged on the computer, and moved auto matically to a preassigned location. When needed, they are called for by the computer, which automatically sends a remote controlled sideloader for them, and are sent via conveyor to the location requesting them. This warehouse is run by a single computer operator. The in stallation of this system resulted in substantial labor savings, while doubling warehouse capacity, because the previously used equipment required numerous forklift operators. Sideloaders are an important innovation in the indus try, even though they require operators. They are narrower and higher than the conventional forklifts which they replace, allowing for increased storage space and versatility in the warehouse. Sideloaders are in creasingly being used in semi-automatic computerized high rise warehousing systems installed in a number of plants. An example of the most advanced technology for as sembly line manufacture in the industry is a recently built tractor plant designed specifically for computer control.7 This plant is unique in that almost all phases of its operations are computer controlled or directed. The plant has high rise computerized automatic ware houses. The parts to be assembled are programmed to move in the correct sequence to produce a finished trac tor via conveyor through the various assembly lines. This is a major advance over the system where parts are made in advance and stored until needed, boxes of parts are moved to the assembly line via forklift trucks, and assemblers pick the correct parts out of the boxes to as semble the final product. The new plant uses industrial robots for welding and painting. The robotic painting machines are programmed to move their spray guns to paint the correct part of the tractor chassis as it moves by on the conveyor line. This differs from conventional automatic spray painting equipment, which uses fixed spray guns, in that it more closely approximates a hu man spray painter. Almost all welds for the frame of the tractor cabs made at this plant are done on an electronically controlled automatic framing buck which Future trends uncertain Changes in output and productivity in the farm ma chinery industry are expected to continue to reflect changes in farm income. In the near future, the outlook for farm income is uncertain. It has been falling since 1979; and currently, there are pressures on farm prices that are expected to slash farm profits. In addition, such factors as high interest rates and high fertilizer and pes ticide costs are also expected to reduce farm income. The export market is uncertain, and farm prices are down. This situation could result in a continuation of the recent negative pressure on demand for farm ma chinery. In addition, technological changes in the near future may be affected by the financial difficulties of a number of the major companies in the industry, which are expected to limit capital expenditures for new plant and equipment. Over the long term, modernization of plant and equipment is expected to continue in the farm machin ery industry, with particular emphasis on labor savings and cost reduction. These changes will be fueled by possible competition with Japan in the market for larger 76 and increasing use of industrial robots for welding, painting, and other high volume, difficult operations. Computers will increasingly be used for manufacturing operations and in design functions. farm equipment, which is presently dominated by U.S. concerns. Japan currently holds a large share of the U.S. market for small tractors.8 The future will see growing installation of automatic welding equipment 2 S ta tis tic a l A b s tr a c t o f th e U n ite d S ta tes , 1 9 8 0 (U.S. Department of 1 Average annual rates of change are based on the linear least Commerce, 1980), p. 686. squares trends of the logarithms of the index numbers. The farm ma chinery and equipment industry is- designated industry 352 in the 3 1 9 7 0 C e n su s o f P o p u la tio n , O c cu p a tio n b y I n d u s tr y , Vol. PC(2)-7C S ta n d a r d I n d u s tr ia l C la ss ific a tio n M a n u a l, 1 9 7 2 E d itio n , issued by the (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1972), pp. 281-88. Office of Management and Budget. The industry comprises establish 4 Based on discussions with industry experts. ments primarily engaged in the manufacture of farm machinery and 5 U.S. I n d u s tr ia l O u tlo o k , 1 9 7 4 (U.S. Department of Commerce, equipment, and garden tractors and lawn and garden equipment. A 1973), p. 301. technical note describing the indexes is available from the Office of 6 J o h n D e e r e H a r v e s te r W o rk s (Deere and Company, 1979), p. 10. Productivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington, 1 J o h n D e e r e T r a c to r W o rk s (Deere and Company, 1980), pp. 6-18. D.C. 20212. The indexes for this industry will be updated and includ 8 U.S. I n d u s tr ia l O u tlo o k , 1 9 8 1 (U.S. Department of Commerce, ed in the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ annual bulletin, P r o d u c tiv ity 1980), p. 260. M e a s u r e s f o r S e le c te d I n d u s trie s . 77 Productivity trends for intercity bus carriers During 1954-79, modest advances in technology, and more package and charter service, were offset by declining passenger demand and reduced bus speeds, resulting in a 0,4-percent rise in productivity R ic h a r d B. C a r n e s Lower speeds have increased the labor time needed to drive a given distance, and have reduced productivity. However, lower speeds have also cut fuel costs. Al though total transportation travel might be expected to decline because of higher fuel costs, the relative fuel effi ciency of buses enhance future demand for this mode of transportation, especially for shorter distance travel. Productivity movements were uneven over the 195479 period, ranging from a 9.4 percent increase in 1962 to a decline of 11.9 percent in 1975. Generally, these changes have been in response to cyclical swings in in dustry output. There were three distinct trend periods. During 1954-60, output per hour rose at a 1.2-percent average annual rate. Output declined at an average yearly rate of 1.3 percent and hours dropped more sharply, by 2.6 percent. From 1960 to 1966, demand for bus service increased 4.7 percent annually, but em ployee hours increased at only a 1.3 percent average an nual rate. The more efficient utilization of equipment and facilities, which resulted from this higher demand, raised productivity at a 3.6 percent annual rate during those 6 years. Load factors and average length of haul both increased appreciably. Load factor is the percent age of capacity actually utilized. In the third period, 1966-79, all of the measures turned down. Productivity and output fell at an annual rate of 1.4 and 2.5 percent, respectively, while employee hours dropped 1.1 percent. Output fell in all years ex- During 1954-1979, output per employee-hour in the class I bus industry rose an average of 0.4 percent a year, a rate significantly below those of other segments of the transportation industry.1Class I bus carriers pro vide intercity service and may also provide local or charter service. Not included are those public and pri vate transit systems that provide urban mass transpor tation service and do not come under Interstate Commerce Commission (icc) reporting requirements.*2 The 0.4-percent growth in productivity resulted from a small average annual increase in industry output of 0.1 percent combined with an average annual decline in employee hours of 0.3 percent. (See table 1.) By com parison, other transportation industries for which mea sures are available showed productivity increases over the same period that equaled or exceeded overall pro ductivity growth for the private nonfarm business sector of the economy. For example, productivity in air trans portation, an industry which competes for public pas senger traffic, rose 6.3 percent, compared with 2.1 percent for the private nonfarm business sector. (See ta ble 2.) Bus operations have suffered from the recent energy shortages. Longer running times between cities have re sulted from the 55-mile-per-hour national speed limit.3 Richard B. Carnes is an econom ist in the Office of Productivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M o n t h l y L a b o r R e v i e w , M ay 1981. 78 cept 1967, 1974, and 1979. Since 1974, the beginning of the energy crisis and the year of the 55-mile-per-hour speed limit, productivity trends have been mixed, as ta ble 1 indicates. There were sharp rises in 1974 and 1977, and a small gain in 1979. These were offset by a serious drop in 1975, and smaller declines in 1976 and 1978. More travelers rode buses in 1974 when fuel for private passenger cars became scarce. But when gasoline once again became plentiful in 1975, even at higher prices, bus travel declined drastically. Again in 1979, gas shortages in the second quarter helped boost indus try output by 6.1 percent for the year and productivity by 0.4 percent. Table 2. Productivity comparison, private nonfarm business and selected transportation industries, 1954-79 Average annual rate of change Industry Private nonfarm business .............. Transportation sector ................ Petroleum pipelines ’ .............. Air transportation1 ................ Class 1railroads .................... Intercity trucking 1 .................. Class 1bus carriers1 .............. P r o d u c t iv it y a n d r e la t e d in d e x e s f o r c la s s I b u s [1967 - 100] Output per employee-hour Output Employeehours ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. 77.4 80.4 81.2 81.6 81.9 80.5 79.0 78.0 78.3 74.0 104.0 98.3 96.1 96.0 90.3 1959 ................................. 1960 ................................. 1961................................. 1962 ................................. 1963 ................................. 84.6 83.7 85.3 93.3 94.6 74.0 75.4 77.1 86.2 86.6 87.5 90.1 90.4 92.4 91.5 1964 ................................. 1965 ................................. 1966 ................................. 1967.................................. 1968 ................................. 95.7 101.2 103.4 100.0 98.6 90.2 95.0 99.2 100.0 97.5 94.3 93.9 95.9 100.0 98.9 1969 ................................. 1970 ................................. 1971................................. 1972 ................................. 1973 ................................. 95.7 93.4 91.3 93.0 92.5 94.2 92.5 86.9 83.3 79.8 98.4 99.0 95.2 89.6 86.3 1974 ................................. 1975 ................................. 1976 ................................. 1977 ................................. 1978 ................................. 1979' ............................... 95.9 84.5 81.7 87.1 86.8 87.2 86.5 78.0 75.2 74.7 73.7 78.2 90.2 92.3 92.1 85.8 84.9 89.7 1954 1955 1956 1957 1956 : ] | Average annual rates of change 1954-79 .......................... 1974-79 .......................... 0.4 - .9 0.1 -1.9 -0.3 -1.0 1Preliminary. 1.9 2.7 7.5 6.3 4.9 2.4 .4 3.7 2.9 5.6 11.0 1.2 5.6 .1 1.7 .2 -1.8 4.5 -3.5 3.1 - .3 ] bile travel represents the primary source of competition to the industry, followed by air and then train service. Expansion of charter bus and package express service has helped to offset passenger declines. (See table 3.) Intercity bus operations have the potential to provide service over a wide area because of the national high way network. Nonstop intercity buses can operate at speeds similar to those of an autombile. And, over shorter distances buses generally provide lower cost ser vice than air or rail travel.4 Most demand comes from short-haul passengers even though the average length of trip for intercity service has more than doubled from 62 miles in 1954 to 130 miles in 1979.5 When intercity bus service began in the early 1900’s it was characterized by a large number of local and re gional carriers. Startup costs were modest and there was rapid growth. By the 1930’s, the industry had evolved into its present form, with fewer bus companies and with national systems operating over longer dis tances. These national networks were thought to facili tate through-service for passengers and improve bus and terminal utilization. During World War II, industry o u tp u t in c re a se d ra p id ly d u e to ra tio n in g of a u to p a rts and gasoline. Load factors during this period reached nearly 80 percent. Passenger-miles peaked in 1952 and did not reach that level again until 1967. Since 1954, few new intercity bus carrier operations have been au thorized by the ICC. Presently, Greyhound and Trailways dominate the market.6 The bus industry is subject to both Federal and State regulation. There are restrictions on the entry of new firms, fares, route requirements, and service levels. Competition along joutes is limited. Federal regulation has encouraged merger activity of carriers into larger national companies. Recently there has been an effort on the part of the ICC to liberalize entry controls and to provide greater carrier rate making autonomy. General deregulation of the industry, however, has not been for mally introduced. The sources of revenue for bus carriers have changed substantially since 1954 as table 3 indicates. Intercity and local passenger revenue has declined in relative The class I regulated bus industry comprises 43 intercity and 13 local carriers certified by the ICC. In 1978, these companies operated about 9,700 buses and had 34,000 employees. During that year, they moved 237 million passengers, and generated $961 million in passenger revenue and $175 million in freight revenue. For most of the 15,000 communities served by intercity bus carriers, there is no other form of public transportation. Despite this, the bus passenger market has declined during the period of this study. Automo Year Output Employeehours 1Output per employee. Industry profile T a b l e 1. c a r r ie r s Output per employee-hour 79 terms while charter and package express services have shown significant growth. Charter service has expanded due to the increase in group travel and tourism, while package express service has benefited from the large dis tribution network provided by intercity buses. The private automobile has been a major factor in the slow growth of intercity bus travel. The doubling of new car registrations since 1955 and the use of these cars for both personal and business trips impacted bus travel, and is expected to be the primary source of bus industry competition in the foreseeable future. Autos accounted for 89 percent of all intercity passenger-miles in 1954, and for 83 percent in 1979. Passenger-miles flown during this period increased their relative share of the market from 3 to 15 percent while both bus and rail passenger-miles declined.7 of drivers in the industry, by increasing the proportion of administrative and service workers. Since 1954, workers paid on a daily basis, mostly supervisory personnel, as opposed to hourly wage employees, have increased from 8 percent of total employment to 10 percent. In the intercity portion of the regulated bus industry, women represent 12 percent of the work force, up from 10 per cent in 1960. By contrast, women make up 40 percent of the work force in the total private nonfarm sector. Changes in technology associated with the bus indus try have been characterized by a gradual trend toward innovation, fuel efficiency, and greater passenger com fort. Diesel-powered buses, in primary use since the ear ly 1950’s, have undergone steady advances in performance and reductions in maintenance require ments. Current-model intercity buses have a seating ca pacity of 47 passengers and have space for large amounts of baggage and cargo. Typically, buses are 8 feet wide and 40 feet long, and weigh 13 tons. Including resale after use by class I carriers, useful bus life is over 20 years and mileage may exceed 3 million.8 The aver age number of seats for the bus fleet in 1955 was 39.1 and increased 10 percent to 43.1 by 1978. However, the seating capacity utilized during this period has remained at about 47 percent, and load factors have changed lit tle since 1954, which helps explain the low rise in pro ductivity in the industry. From 1950 to 1973, average bus speeds increased from 50 to 60 miles per hour because of improved high ways and urban beltways. But the introduction of the national speed limit in 1974 reduced average speeds to less than 55 miles per hour,9 and has also slowed pro Employment and influences on productivity Employment in the class I regulated bus industry de clined from 39,000 in 1954 to an estimated 35,300 in 1979. Employment dropped steadily in the 1950’s, then advanced irregularly through 1967, and thereafter gen erally declined again to the present level. Recent excep tions to the downward trend were in 1974-75 and again in 1979. Energy shortages resulting from the Organiza tion of Petroleum Exporting Countries oil embargo boosted both employment and passenger service in 1974, the year that also marked the introduction of the 55-mile-per-hour national speed limit. Employment needs increased partially as a result of the decline in the number of bus miles per driver. Again in 1979, fuel shortages reversed the downward trends in both em ployment and p a s s e n g e r service. Since 1954, there has been a change in the composi tion of employment. The number of equipment mainte nance and garage personnel has declined from 22 to 17 percent of the work force because of reduced service re quirements. Station workers, however, have increased from 11 to 19 percent of total employment, reflecting the greater demand for package express traffic. Drivers have accounted for about half of industry employment since 1954. However, more fully utilized and larger ca pacity buses may, in the future, reduce the percentage d u c tiv ity g ro w th . The growth in package express and charter services, however, has aided productivity. Delivering package ex press while engaging in regularly scheduled passenger service has resulted in more efficient use of vehicle and driver time. Charter services have also offered signifi cant economies of scale for bus companies. Charters typically have a 50»percent greater load factor and 100-percent longer average trip length than regular route carriers. This form of passenger service also pro vides economies in baggage handling, ticketing, and scheduling terminal facilities. Reduced investment has hurt industry productivity. Since 1954, investment in plant and equipment by intercity bus carriers has declined. Buses, which present ly cost about $135,000 each, account for about 80 per cent of industry capital expenditures. Annual constant dollar investment dropped from $78 million in 1954 to $56 million in 1974, the latest year for which data are available. Similarly, the constant dollar stock of plant and equipment fell 18 percent, while capital investment per worker declined more than 20 percent. In contrast, gross constant dollar investment in the transportation Table 3. Revenue distribution for class I bus carriers and percent of total service, 19S4 and 1978 1054 Service 1978 Revenue in millions Percent Revenue in millions Percent Total.................. $467 100 $1137 100 Passenger: Intercity .................... Locai....................... Charter .................... 306 112 33 66 7 678 73 211 60 6 19 Freight......................... 16 3 175 15 24 80 Factors are emerging which are both favorable and unfavorable to demand and productivity growth in the bus industry. Energy and demographic variables are likely to be positive factors while negative public image and low capital investment may retard growth. Restructuring the industry has been suggested as a way to increase capacity utilization and spur productivity. With current low rates of bus utilization, increased demand would likely result in higher load factors and enhance productivity. Several projections of growth in the bus industry for the next decade have been made. The Federal Energy Administration (now part of the Department of Energy) estimates a 25 percent growth in passenger-miles over the next decade. This projection is not altered substantially even when based on different fuel availability assumptions. The Department of Trans portation ( d o t ) makes a similar growth projection but notes the negative effect of rising income levels and shift from longer-haul bus travel. DOT sees potential for greater demand through improved service and regulato ry reform. A third projection estimates a more optimis tic 40-percent growth based on assumptions of fuel shortages and restricted auto use. In contrast to these three optimistic scenarios the ICC concludes that regular route traffic will continue to experience flattened de mand and market share loss.11 In a period of energy shortage, bus operations are likely to increase because of the comparative fuel effi ciency of this mode of transportation. This was demon strated both during World War II and in 1974 when fuel shortages existed. Given energy priorities, buses would make inroads into the use of the private automo bile. Presently, diesel turbocharged engines are being in troduced into service because of their potential for fuel savings and reduced emissions. Gas turbine buses now being used experimentally are able to run on non-petro leum based fuels and may aid future productivity growth because of their increased reliability.12 Fuel shortages would likely create more reliance on the use of buses for lower density routes to and from small towns and rural areas. Higher utilization of existing capacity in the industry would boost labor pro ductivity. However, a recent DOT study projects that over the next two or three decades the passenger auto mobile will continue in its dominant transportation role because of its flexibility and tailored service.13 Demographic changes may also help to increase the demand for bus service, raising both load factors and productivity. The trends toward population dispersion, smaller households, and an older population are all fac tors which favor increased use of intercity bus service. Population dispersion reduces the availability of other forms of transportation; private cars are more cost effi cient for larger families; and many older persons prefer the relative comfort and safety of bus travel. However, a history of low productivity growth, lack of demand, and reduced profits may impair the ability of the industry to attract needed capital and enhance future performance. The ICC sees a need for changes in policy to insure a balanced transportation network. Such changes would include bus and engine design studies, similar to those conducted for air transporation and other forms of mass transit, to find ways to in crease productivity. Improvements in the quality and location of bus terminals and facilities have also been recommended.14 Because the price differential between long distance air fares and bus fares has narrowed over the years, some analysts argue that bus carriers should drop coast-to-coast service and concentrate in shorthaul markets of 100 to 200 miles. Such a system could enlarge the number of daily departures and increase bus utilization from its current average of 7 hours a day to 16 hours.15Further advances in productivity are possible through improvements in intermodal linkages. Con struction of municipal transportation terminals to serve as connectors for bus, train, and plane service could im prove productivity for all of these forms of transporta tion. ' This study is based on statistics reported to the Interstate Commerce Commission for all class I motor carriers of passengers. Class I carriers are those that have 3-year average annual revenues of more that $3 million. This portion of the bus industry, as defined in the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) manual, makes up a small part of SIC 4111 (local and suburban transit), and a more sub stantial part of both SIC 4131 (intercity and rural highway passenger transportation) and SIC 414 (passenger transportation charter ser vice). Based on their major source of revenue, class I carriers have been divided by the ICC into local or intercity service. Local service is defined as transportation performed within a city or town, includ ing service for the contiguous suburban area. Intercity service includes all transportation performed beyond the limits set for local service. Either of these carrier types may also engage in intercity, local, or charter operations. 2The output measure underlying the productivity series for the bus industry has been constructed using data on passenger-miles, passen gers, and express freight service, combined with appropriate weights relating to labor importance. A technical note describing the methods used in the construction of the index is available upon request. 1Lawrence Leist, Intercity Bus Service: Frequency and Running Time, Report No. WP-220-04-20 (Washington, U.S. Department of Transportation, 1975). 4 Transportation and the Future (Washington, U.S. Department of Transportation, 1975), p. 35. 5Derived by dividing revenue passenger miles by revenue passengers. 6 The Intercity Bus Industry: A Preliminary Study (Washington, In terstate Commerce Commission, 1978), pp. 2-3. 7 Transportation facts and Trends (Washington, Transportation sector as a whole increased more than 150 percent, while gross stocks of capital increased 35 percent.10 Outlook Association of America, 1980), p. 18. "America's Most Fuel Efficient Passenger Transportation Service (Washington, American Bus Association, 1979), p. 5. ’ The Intercity Bus Industry, p. 26. See Capital Stock Estimates for Input-Output Industries: Methods and Data, Bulletin 2034 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1979). " The Intercity Bus Industry, pp. 106-08. I: America's Most Fuel Efficient, p. 5. " Transportation and the Future, p. 111. 14 The Intercity Bus Industry, pp. 121-27. '■ Rush Loving, Jr., “The Bus Lines are on the Road to Nowhere,” Fortune, Dec. 31, 1978, pp. 58-64. Laundry and cleaning services pressed to post productivity gains Increases in 1958-76 averaged 1.6 percent, as hours dropped twice as fa st as output; wash and wear fabrics and home appliances have displaced m any traditional laundries R ic h a r d B. C a r n e s celerated to 2.8 percent. However, both output and hours decreased. Output fell at a 1.4-percent yearly rate; hours fell more rapidly—about 4.0 percent per year. Textile manufacturers introduced wash and wear fabrics during these years—a development which reduced both industry demand and industry labor requirements. M any significant technological changes also contributed to the reduction in hours in the late 1960’s. D uring the m ore recent period, 1 9 7 0 -7 6 , p rod u c tivity grow th averaged on ly 0.7 percent per year. A very rapid increase betw een 1 9 7 0 -7 3 w as partially offset by a 1 9 7 3 -7 6 decline. T h e below -average pro d uctivity grow th since 1970 w as accom p an ied by substantial d eclines in both ou tp u t and hours; 5.3 percent and 6.0 percent, per year, respectively. O u t put declines in the private business sector in 1970, 1974, and 1975 had a negative im pact on the laundry and cleaning services industry. C onstant dollar per sonal consum ption expenditures for laundry and cleaning services are estim ated to have d eclin ed 30 percent from 1970 to 1976. H om e laundering— d evoid o f yesteryear’s drudgery by the use o f m odern m ach in es and easy care fabrics — has increased significantly in recent tim es, slack en ing the dem and for traditional, labor-intensive, fam ily laundry and drycleaning services. T his trend, in conjun ction w ith the grow th o f m ore capital-in ten sive op eration s such as industrial launderers and linen suppliers, has resulted in a large drop in the hours w orked by all persons in the in d u stry .1 B e tw een 1958 and 1976, hours dropped at an average annual rate o f 3.1 p ercen t.*2 But. because the in dus try’s ou tp u t d eclin ed at about on ly h a lf that rate, 1.6 percent per year, ou tp u t per hour “grew ” at an aver age annual rate o f 1.6 percent over the 19-year pe riod. O ver the sam e period, p roductivity in the n on farm bu sin ess sector rose at an annual rate o f 2.2 percent. O n the w h ole, the cleaning in d u stry’s m o d erate p rod u ctivity perform ance has been bu oyed by gradual ad van ces in tech n o lo g y and the introduction o f easy-to-clean apparel. A lth o u g h the ann u al productivity gain in the cleanin g industry averaged 1.6 percent from 1958 to 1976, grow th w ith in th e period varied m arkedly. (See table 1.) During the 1958-65 period, for example, the average annual increase in productivity was 0.9 per cent. Output grew at a 1.5-percent annual rate, while hours increased at a rate o f 0.6 percent per year. From 1965 to 1970, the rate o f productivity growth ac Cleaning industry composition T he chan ge in the dem and for various types o f laundry and cleaning services has changed the in d u s try’s structure. (See table 2.) T hus, alth ou gh overall output dropped at an average annual rate o f 1.6 per cent in 1 9 5 8 -7 6 , diverse m ovem en ts occurred at the subindustry level. T h e focus o f service has shifted from personal clean in g services to com m ercial and industrial custom ers. Richard B. Carnes is an economist in the Division of Industry Productiv ity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, February 1978. 83 D esp ite the 1 9 5 8 -7 6 increase in real per capita in com e in the U n ited States (57 percent), real per capita expenditures for fam ily laundry and cleaning services declin ed by 50 percent. The sharp decline in the ou tp u t o f fam ily laundry establishm ents has been a direct result o f increased hom e laundering as w ell as easy-to-care-for fabrics. N o w , fam ilies consider w ashers and dryers to be necessary appliances. T he output o f the h o u seh o ld laundry equipm ent industry is estim ated to have increased nearly 70 percent be tw een 1958 and 1976. In 1975, m ore than 4 m illion hom e w ash in g m ach in es w ere sold, increasing m ar ket penetration to 70 percent, from 53 percent in I9 6 0 .3 T h e in trod u ction o f perm anent press fabrics in the m id -1 9 6 0 ’s alon g w ith m ore recent m arketing o f knit garm ents has further reduced the dem and for fam ily laundry services. C onsequently, d eclines in output have occurred for non sp ecialized pow er lau n dries, n on p ow er laundries, and drycleaning plants. In addition, there have been declines in ou tp ut for garm ent pressing estab lish m en ts, rug clean in g and repairing plants, and diaper services. F rom 1958 to 1972, the pow er and n on p ow er laundries declined from 32 percent o f industry sales to 14 percent. D ryclean in g plants lost 3 percent o f the m arket, and garm ent pressing sales dropped from 7 to 5 percent over th is period. B etw een 1958 and 1972 (the latest year for w hich detailed data are available), sales by industrial lau n dry and linen supply establishm ents— w h ich provide both rental and clean in g services to businesses and institu tion s— increased from 19 percent to 34 per cent o f total industry sales. In 1972, sales per estab lish m en t for industrial launderers and linen suppliers T a b l© 1. Table 2. The distribution of receipts and employment, laundry and cleaning services, 1958 and 1972 Percent distribution Industry segment [1967 = 100] Output Hours of all persons 1958 ....................................... 1959 ....................................... 1960 ....................................... 83.9 87.1 82.7 86.1 89.7 85.1 102.6 103.0 102.9 1961....................................... 1962 ....................................... 1963 ....................................... 1964 ....................................... 1965 ....................................... 86.9 86.9 86.6 92.7 87.3 88.6 88.9 92.4 97.0 93.6 101.9 102.3 106.7 104.6 107.2 1966 ....................................... 1967 ....................................... 1968 ....................................... 1969 ....................................... 1970 ....................................... 1971........................................ 92.8 100.0 103.4 101.7 99.3 102.9 98.6 100.0 98.2 94.4 87.6 80.3 106.3 100.0 95.0 92.8 88.2 78.0 1972 ........................................ 1973 ........................................ 1974 ....................................... 1975 ........................................ 1976p........................................ 107.0 109.6 107.3 104.1 105.2 79.7 75.7 69.3 65.4 63.2 74.5 69.1 64.6 62.8 60.1 ^ Paid employees Receipts Paid employees Total.................................... 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Laundry services..................... Power laundries................. Coin-operated laundry and drycleaning..................... Laundries, except power___ Drycleaning services............... Drycleaning plants.............. Rug cleaning and repairing. . . Rental services....................... Linen supply..................... Industrial launderers............ Diaper service................... Garment pressing, alteration and repair................................ 33.6 29.9 41.0 37.7 24.8 13.1 30.0 20 7 2.1 1.6 38.8 37.0 1.8 20.7 12.6 6.8 1.3 1.9 1.4 39.5 38.3 1.2 14.5 8.8 4.8 .9 10.7 1.0 35.9 34.5 1.4 34.7 18.2 15.3 1.2 8.7 .6 43.4 42.0 1.4 23.0 15.2 6.8 1.0 6.9 4.9 4.6 3.6 fivefold increase since 1958. Currently there are 40,000 self-service laundry and drycleaning stores in the United States.4 Limited capital requirem ents have encouraged the growth of franchising in laundry and cleaning serv ices. The available data on franchised laundry and drycleaning services show that average investment and startup funds totaled $71,000 in 1974. In that p = preliminary. Receipts w ere 12 tim es greater than th e industry average o f $60,000. B ecause o f the sim ilarity in types o f item s to be cleaned, these establishm ents have introduced m any standardized p rocessing techniques. T hese new m ass-production m eth od s, in conjunction w ith m ore m odern equipm ent, have greatly increased the efficiency o f these typ ically large-scale laundries. Industrial laundry establishm ents perform w ork on a con tract basis, sp ecializin g in personalized w ork garm ents, w iping cloth s, m ats, and dust control item s. G arm ents are identified so they can be re turned after servicing to the sam e custom er. In m any cases, businesses rent these item s from the laundry, w h ich then provides service on a regular schedule. L inen suppliers w ork on a sim ilar rental-contract basis, except that laundered item s are not usually personalized. L inen services include the rental o f ap parel, tow els, table and bed linen, uniform s, and a variety o f other cloth item s. C ustom ers served by industrial launderers and linen suppliers in clu d e fac tories, restaurants, hospitals, lod gin g places, and sch ools. O ther establishm ents that experienced sales grow th from 1958 to 1972 w ere coin-operated lau n dry and drycleaners. B ecause few er new apparel re quire professional cleaning, th e grow th in com m er cial coin-operated laundry and drycleaning facilities has been encouraged. C oin-operated services a c cou n ted for 11 percent o f industry sales in 1972— a In d e x e s o f p r o d u c t iv it y , o u tp u t, a n d h o u r s o f Productivity (output per hour) 1972 SOURCE: US. Department of Commerce. Basedon1967 StandardIndustrial ClassificationManual. Data are for those establishments with payrolls. a ll p e r s o n s , la u n d r y a n d c le a n in g s e r v ic e s , 1 9 5 8 -7 6 Year 1958 84 new technology. In addition, improvements in fab rics, detergent products, and drycleaning solvents have helped to reduce washing and drying times as well as finishing requirements. Although data on new capital expenditures are not available for the laundry and cleaning services indus try, some insights into equipment purchases have been obtained from data published for manufactured commercial laundry equipment.9 In 1972, the com mercial laundry equipment industry had sales of $219 million—more than double the 1958 sales level of $107 million. (During this period, the Wholesale Price Index for laundry equipment showed no in crease.) Laundry equipment accounted for 75 per cent of 1972 sales; drycleaning equipment accounted for the remaining 25 percent. The distribution of these sales has not changed since 1958. However, the type of equipment sold has changed, reflecting im proved fabrics and newer, laborsaving, cleaning and drying methods. In 1958, laundry pressing equip ment represented 16 percent of sales, but by 1972, had declined to just 2 percent of sales. Similarly, flatwork ironers have also declined in relative impor tance as “no iron” fabrics became prevalent during the period of this study. Combination washer and water extractors have advanced from 5 percent of equipment sales in 1958 to 38 percent in 1972. An innovation which has diffused rapidly through the industry is steam tunnel finishing. After cleaning, conveyors transport hangered garments through a steam bath which relaxes the fibers and restores the garments to their original shape. They are then dried by high-velocity hot air. This equipment, when used on synthetic fabrics or blends, significantly reduces the amount of hand-operated pressing that was previously required. The use of synthetic fabrics has also led to a grad ual phasing out of older types of industrial and com mercial laundry equipment. Synthetic fabrics reduce the machine cycle and process times because they are lightweight and heat resistant. Lightly soiled gar ments, such as office apparel, are increasingly being drycleaned or are being cleaned by dual-phase wash ing and drycleaning equipment. Labor time has also been reduced by the introduc tion of fully automated, large-scale washers and dry ers. Washer-extractors can be self-loaded, while the washing, extracting, and conditioning operations can be programmed for different load conditions to per form automatically. These automated controls have reduced operating personnel to as few as one person for this stage of processing. Labor requirements for large amounts of flatwork finishing have been signifi cantly reduced by the use of more fully automated flatwork spreaders and high-speed folders and stack ers. Electronically controlled folders can process up year, there were 3,700 franchise establishments with sales of $237 million—about 5 percent of total indus try receipts. Three companies accounted for about 85 percent of both franchise establishments and sales/ To enhance sales, many franchise establishments specialize in convenient 1-day drycleaning and shirt service. Shrieking labor input Changes in employment among the subindustries have mirrored the changes in industry organization. From 1958 to 1976, the number of persons engaged in laundry and cleaning services fell from 688,000 to 445,000—an average annual industry decline of 2.3 percent. As with output, the largest employment losses occurred in power and nonpower laundries, drycleaning plants, and garment services. Coinoperated laundry and drycleaning establishments along with industrial laundry and linen supply estab lishments experienced employment growth. Over the 19-year period, the industry average weekly hours for nonsupervisory workers declined from 38.7 to 35.9; average weekly hours for manag ers and the self-employed dropped from 52.9 to 46.2. As a result of the overall decreases in employment and average weekly hours, total hours fell at an aver age annual rate of 3.1 percent from 1958 to 1976. The occupational composition within the laundry and cleaning service industry has also been changing. Since 1970, when detailed data first became availa ble,6 industry employment has been decreasing for most occupations. Only white-collar occupations have posted employment gains in recent years. Tra ditional blue-collar workers—craft and service workers, operatives, and laborers—lost a significant share of industry employment, dropping from 64 percent in 1970 to 58 percent in 1974. Improvements in fabric finishes have reduced demand for pressing operatives, stock handlers, laundry and drycleaning operatives, and craftworkers such as tailors, station ary engineers, and Vehicle mechanics. Demand for route drivers has also fallen for family laundries as their sales have declined. Clerical workers, manag ers, salesworkers, and professional and technical workers have had corresponding increases in their relative share of employment, growing from 36 to 42 percent over the same 5-year period.7 Cleaning technology Increased mechanization and new cleaning meth ods for synthetic fabrics are the primary areas of technological change in the industry/ Significant ex penditures for larger, more efficient washers and dry ers, “steam tunnels,” ultrasonic drycleaning ma chines, high speed sorters and folders, and mechanical transfer devices reflect the demand for 85 to 1,500 items per hour with various automatic width and fold combinations possible. Manual material handling for small-piece flatwork has been reduced by the use of air jets to propel items from extractors to ironers or mechanized folders.10 Gains in productivity have resulted from the intro duction of integrated systems for material handling. Conveyors are often used for loading washing wheels and to move cleaned loads to in-line extractors, tum bler-dryers, and to the finishing department. In in dustrial laundries, these material handling systems are further used to automatically route personalized garments through the steam tunnels to the proper assembly area. Interest currently centers on the de velopment of a hangered garment system which can be automatically scanned and sorted.11 Looking down the line The decline in family laundries and the growth of high-volume, rental-cleaning services is expected to continue. Productivity should advance over the next decade as technological innovations continue to be introduced and diffused throughout the industry. In many cases, further improvements in textiles will result in longer lasting garments that will be even easier to clean. Polyester fabrics, for example, are being improved so they can be washed at lower tem peratures. Lower temperatures and improved fabrics will reduce detergent requirements and shrinkage as well as improve color retention. 1The study covers paid and unpaid persons (including paid employees, partners, proprietors, and unpaid family members) working in laundry and cleaning service establishments. The industry is designated as laun dry, cleaning, and garment services, SIC 721, in the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) Manual. SIC 721 is composed of 9 subin dustries: 7211, Power Laundries Family and Commercial; 7212, Gar ment Pressing and Agents for Laundries and Dry Cleaners; 7213, Linen Supply; 7214, Diaper Service; 7215, Coin-operated Laundries and Drycleaning; 7216, Drycleaning Plants Except Rug Cleaning; 7217, Carpet and Upholstery Cleaning; 7218, Industrial Launderers; 7219, Laundry and Garment Services not elsewhere classified. 2 All average annual rates of change are based on the linear least squares trend of the logarithms of the index numbers. Updated indexes will appear in the annual BLS Bulletin, Productivity Indexes for Selected Industries. Because comprehensive delivery routes already exist, many laundry and cleaning establishments are expected to increase sales by broadening the product lines and services they offer. Rental service firms, for example, are now marketing such items as disposable rest room products and air fresheners. More stringent environmental air and water stand ards have acted to reduce gains in productivity as plants divert labor and capital from the production process to meet these new demands. The impact of collecting and processing waste products and meet ing fabric flammability standards has affected plant operating methods and equipment needs. In some cases, customers must be screened to insure that their garments will not cause unacceptable levels of water and air pollution. This has led to industry requirements for sophisticated ventilation and filtra tion equipment along with hot water and heat recov ery systems. As new technology is developed to meet these environmental and health needs, future trends in productivity and output could be enhanced. For example, “sniffer” units which help reduce solvent emissions into the air can also be used to reclaim and recycle usable solvent, thus increasing operating effi ciency. Demand in some segments of the industry could increase as establishments which currently launder their own textiles turn to commercial laun derers and cleaners who have developed the equip ment and expertise needed to meet stricter environ mental standards. 4 Information provided by the National Automatic Laundry and Cleaning Council. 5 Andrew Kostecka, Franchising in the Economy, 1974-76 (Washing ton, Department of Commerce, 1976), p. 71. 6 Bureau of Labor Statistics, unpublished data for 1970-85, National Industry Occupational Matrix. 7 Ibid. 8 For an earlier study of technology in this industry, see Mary L. Vickery, “New technology in laundry and cleaning services," Monthly Labor Review, February 1972, pp. 54-59. Bureau of the Census, Census of Manufacturers, 1972 Industry Series: Service Industry Machines and Machine Shops, MC72 (2)-35G 1975 10 Vickery, New technology, p. 56. 3See “ 1976 Statistical and Marketing Report,” Merchandising, March 1976. 11 The Year 75-76 in Review,” Industrial Launderer, November 1976, p. 7. Cyclical behavior of productivity in the machine tool industry Productivity growth was slow during 1958-80, partly because o f the industry's tendency to retain skilled workers during cyclical downturns; computers and other electronic equipment aided production, but diffusion o f such innovations has been slow Jo h n D uke and H o rst B r a n d Output per employee-hour in the machine tool industry rose at an average annual rate of 1.1 percent over the 1958-80 period—significantly below the 2.8-percent rate for manufacturing.1 A combination of factors slowed productivity in the machine tool industry, in cluding the tendency of machine tool firms to keep highly skilled workers on the payroll, even when output fell during cyclical slowdowns, and the slackened de mand for capital goods after the mid-sixties. However, the slowdown was moderated by technological advances in the manufacture of machine tools, as well as by high rates of productivity improvement in periods of cyclical recovery. Until 1966, productivity in the machine tool industry rose at a high annual rate, but thereafter the rate de clined for several years. Its subsequent recovery re mained incomplete— the high levels of the mid-sixties were not reattained. The recovery was again interrupted by a slump in 1974; it resumed in 1977, continuing to 1979, but even then productivity did not top its 1966 peak. (See table 1.) The cyclical behavior of productivi ty in the industry and in manufacturing is shown in the following tabulation (average annual changes in per cent): M a c h in e to o ls M a n u fa c tu rin g Upswings: 1958- 59 ................... 1961-66 ...................... 1971-74 ...................... 1976-80 ...................... 23.1 5.6 7.8 2.4 4.8 4.4 2.9 0.9 Downswings: 1959- 61 ................... 1966-71 ...................... 1974-76 ...................... -2 .0 -4.2 -5 .2 1.7 2.0 3.7 Productivity in both the metal cutting and metal forming segments of the industry paralleled the cyclical patterns shown above, although amplitudes differed. Productivity improvement averaged 1.5 percent annual ly in metal cutting (which accounts for three-fourths of total industry employment), and 0.1 percent in metal forming. Upswings in productivity were more pro nounced in metal cutting than in metal forming; down swings were more pronounced in metal forming. In metal cutting, productivity dropped in 8 of the 22 years examined (table 2); in metal forming, in 12 (table 3). The drops were only in part associated with general business cycles; they occurred in years of economic ex pansion as well as during contractions. O utput recovery slow in the seven ties John Duke and Horst Brand are economists in the Office of Produc tivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, November 1981. The machine tool industry manufactures cutting tools for boring, drilling, gear cutting, grinding, and milling machines and lathes, as well as forming tools such as punching, shearing, bending, and forming presses. These tools are usually shipped as units, that is, as single-pur pose machines, but their basic features may also be combined into “machining centers.” The machine tools may be equipped with manual controls or with pro grammed numerical controls which require little labor by users. Machine tools are not mass produced, al though they may make mass production processes pos sible in user industries. Rather, the parts and components of a finished machine tool are usually made in relatively small batches, and require comparatively large amounts of labor. Output in the machine tool industry rose at an aver age annual rate of 1.6 percent between 1958 and 1980, compared with 3.8 percent for manufacturing. Underly ing the long-term trend were cyclical swings of consid erable amplitude. The metal cutting and metal forming segments of the industry traced similar cyclical patterns. (See table 4.) The following tabulation shows the cyclical behavior of output in the machine tool industry and in manufac turing, 1958-80 (average annual changes in percent): M a c h in e tools Upswings: 1958-59 1961-66 1971-74 1976-80 Table 1. Productivity and related indexes for the machine tool industry, 1958-80 [1977 = 100] Output per employee-hour Output 1958 ........... 1959 ........... 1960 ........... 71.5 88.0 84.7 63.0 79.2 82.8 88.1 90.0 97.8 Employee-hours 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 84.5 88.5 90.1 99.9 101.4 77.4 88.0 93.0 112.3 125.3 91.6 99.4 103.2 112.4 123.6 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 111.7 101.8 97.9 100.1 91.7 156.1 149.9 137.6 137.8 112.0 139.8 147.3 140.5 137.7 122.1 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 87.9 98.0 107.3 109.4 103.0 81.4 91.2 116.3 127.4 109.1 92.6 93.1 108.4 116.5 105.9 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 98.4 100.0 102.6 107.0 106.9 93.9 100.0 111.8 125.9 129.1 95.4 100.0 109.0 117.7 120.8 Average annual rates of change (in percent) 1958-80 ....... 1975-80 ....... 1.1 1.3 1.6 5.4 0.5 4.0 M a n u fa c tu rin g ................. ................. ................. ................. 25.7 14.6 17.2 9.1 11.7 8.2 5.9 2.9 Downswings: 1959-61 ................. 1966-71 ................. 1974-76 ................. -1.1 -11.1 -14.1 0.2 1.0 0.9 Recoveries in machine tool output during the seven ties were less vigorous than they had been in the 1958— 59 and 1961-66 upswings. Slumps were deep. Longterm factors contributing to the comparative weakening of output included the volatility in the demand for pro ducers’ durable equipment. Following 12 percent annual increases in the 1961-66 period, growth in demand for producers durable equipment contracted to 2 percent a year for 1966-71. Demand rebounded at an 11-percent annual rate in the early seventies, declined by 3 percent annually over the 1974-75 period, then recovered to a 10-percent annual growth rate in 1976-79. Even so, the long-term growth in the demand for producers’ durable equipment slackened in the seventies (compared with the demand in the sixties) from an average annual growth rate of 8.1 percent in 1958-68 to 4.8 percent in 1968-79. However, the levels of the sixties were consis tently exceeded subsequently—contrary to the situation in machine tool output and productivity. Thus, the rela tion between producers’ durable output and machine tool output clearly weakened. Year 88 During the seventies, a number of metalworking in dustries representing key markets for machine tools reg istered comparatively slower growth or actual declines in output. For example, production of motor vehicles after the mid-sixties rose at pnly about one-half the rate for 1959-66. Similarly, output growth of construction machinery contracted. Steel output, which had ad vanced at more than 5 percent a year until 1966, be came stagnant thereafter, then fell, as did output of electric motors and generators, nonferrous metals, household appliances, and household furniture.2 Furthermore, expenditures for machine tools dropped as a proportion of total equipment expenditures by manufacturing firms. In the sixties, such expenditures accounted for 11 percent of the total, in the seventies, for only 9 percent. Moreover, imports increasingly displaced domestic machine tools. In the sixties and up to 1973, machine tool imports averaged well under 10 percent of total U.S. machine tool units purchased; thereafter, the volume of machine tool imports soared, and by 1978, they accounted for 21 percent of total units purchased.3In contrast, exports did not rise mark edly relative to output—exports represented 8 percent of machine tool units purchased in the sixties and about 10 percent in the seventies. Still another factor underlying slackened output of machine tools has been the rapid rise in their productive capacity. (This factor will be explained more fully later in this article.) A study of more than 350 companies showed that reduced machining time for numerically controlled (or programmed) machine tools ranged from 35 percent to 50 percent.4 According to the American Machinist's periodic inventories of metalworking equip ment, the “population” of machine tools in use did not change significantly between 1963 and 1976-78, but the output of the metalworking industries using them gener ally increased, indicating rising productive capabilities of the machine tools, particularly those equipped with numerical controls.5 Some engineering authorities main tain that numerically controlled machine tools permit “drastically reduced” handling time because they elimi nate the separate operations of transferring and clamping and unclamping.6 The relative importance of all categories of machine tools lessened during 1958-80, except lathes, drill ing machines, and machining centers. (Machining cen ters combine the separate operations of boring, drilling, and milling units.) Most of the shift toward machining centers occurred after 1968, when the diffusion of nu merical control, an essential component of machining centers, began to accelerate. In 1978, the number of ma chining centers shipped was half again as high as in 1968. During that decade, the number of numerically controlled metal cutting machine tools shipped more than doubled and the number of metal forming machine tools rose by 14 percent. The diffusion of numerically controlled machine tools has remained limited, however. According to the Amer Table 3. Productivity and related indexes for metal forming, 1958-80 (1977 = 100] Output 67.6 83.2 81.5 58.1 74.2 81.0 85.9 89.2 99.4 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 80.0 83.2 84.3 94.9 98.7 72.7 83.0 88.4 109.2 124.8 90.9 99.7 104.9 115.1 126.4 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 107.8 98.0 95.7 97.5 89.5 154.7 150.6 139.8 139.0 107.2 143.5 153.6 146.1 142.5 119.8 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 85.5 94.8 105.5 108.9 102.9 75.2 83.9 108.6 122.3 107.5 92.5 88.0 88.5 102.9 112.3 104.5 95.1 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 97.3 100.0 103.6 109.7 111.2 100.0 113.7 130.6 138.3 100.0 109.7 119.0 124.4 1.5 2.3 1.9 7.2 78.4 95.1 88.9 93.8 92.5 94.1 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 98.0 105.7 108.4 115.5 109.3 91.9 104.3 107.5 122.2 127.1 93.8 98.7 99.2 105.8 116.3 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 123.1 112.7 103.9 107.0 98.5 160.8 147.9 131.7 134.3 126.2 130.6 131.2 126.8 125.5 128.1 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ........... ........... .......... .......... ........... 95.7 107.5 114.1 111.9 104.0 99.6 112.1 139.2 142.5 114.1 104.1 104.3 122.0 127.4 109.7 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 101.7 100.0 99.9 100.4 95.2 98.1 100.0 107.2 114.8 106.1 96.5 100.0 107.3 114.3 111.5 0.1 -1.4 0.7 0.5 0.6 1.9 E m ploym ent concentrated in m etal cutting In 1980, employment in the machine tool industry numbered about 108,000 persons, with about one-quar ter of them in metal forming establishments. Employeehours rose quite slowly over the 1958-80 period (0.5 percent, compared with 1 percent in manufacturing) but, like productivity and output, were characterized by pronounced cyclical swings. The cyclical volatility of employee-hours in the machine tool industry, compared Average annual rates of change (in percent) 1958-80 . . . . 1975-80 . . . . 83.6 102.8 94.5 Employee-hours ican Machinist's 1976-78 inventory of metalworking equipment, only 2 percent of the machine tools in the United States were numerically controlled, and only 7 percent of machine tools 10 years old or less were nu merically controlled.7 The output capacity of metal forming machine tools, like that of metal cutting tools, significantly increased during 1958-80, tending to retard demand and, hence, output growth. For example, the size of presses used in the automotive and appliance industries— which ac count for the lion’s share of the demand for presses— has increased such that, in the past 15 years, it tended to be four times greater than that in the preceeding 35 years.8 Changes of dies, which used to require 30 to 40 minutes, now take only 90 seconds— hence, long pro duction runs are no longer needed to justify die chang es.9 Numerical controls have been applied to operations such as bending— now tube benders perform more than 30 types of bends.10 Employee-hours 1958 ........... 1959 ........... 1960 ........... 1958 ........... 1959 ........... 1960 ........... Output Average annual rates of change (in percent) [1977 = 100] Output per employee-hour Output per employee-hour 1958-80 ....... 1975-80 ....... Table 2. Productivity and related indexes for metal cutting, 1958-80 Year Year 0.5 4.8 89 with manufacturing, is illustrated in the following tabu lation (average annual change in percent): M achine tools M an ufactu ring ............... ............... ............... ............... 2.2 8.5 8.8 6.6 6.6 3.6 2.9 1.9 D ow nsw ings: 1959-61 ............... 1966-71 ............... 1 974-76 ............... 0.9 -7 .3 -9 .5 -1 .4 -1 .0 -2 .6 U psw ings: 1 9 58-59 1 9 61-66 197 1 -7 4 1 976-80 0.9 percent per year versus 0.3 percent. There were 43 percent more nonproduction workers in 1980 than in 1958, and 38 percent more production workers, al though employment of both groups was below the 1967 peak. In metal cutting, the proportion of nonproduction workers remained above 30 percent of total employment during the period, reflecting the continued importance of engineers, designers, and other leading personnel. The proportion of women also rose, from 9 to 13 per cent of total employment, but was still far below the manufacturing average of 31 percent. In metal forming, the number of production workers showed no change on average; in contrast, non production workers rose 2.6 percent—from 31 percent of total employment in 1958 to 34 percent in 1980. Oc cupational data are not available for the machine tool industry, but are available for the metal working ma chinery group of industries, of which the machine tool industry accounts for about 30 percent of employment. The occupational mix in the machine tool industry is unlikely to differ very much from that in metalworking. In 1978, metalworking machinery had an unusually high percentage of craft and kindred workers—nearly one-third of its employment, compared with just under one-fifth for manufacturing. As might be expected, the proportion of metal craftworkers and machinists consid erably exceeded the manufacturing average. Operatives accounted for a smaller proportion of employment in metalworking than in manufacturing (33 percent versus 43 percent), although the proportion of semiskilled workers in metalworking was nearly three times higher (15 percent versus 6 percent). As for professional and technical workers, the employment differences were small between the metalworking and all manufacturing industries— 9 percent versus 10 percent—and this was true for other white-collar categories. However, from 1970 forward, the rise in the number of professional and technical workers was almost three times greater in metalworking than in manufacturing—-14 percent ver sus 5 percent— reflecting the growing relative impor tance of electronic technicians and computer and numerical control specialists and programmers. Although recoveries in employee-hours in the seven ties were about as strong as in the sixties, the levels of the mid-sixties were not reached. In 1980, employeehours were one-fifth below those of the sixties. Employ ment was less affected by cyclical swings and was 17 percent lower in 1980 than in 1967, the peak year of the 22-year period. The metal cutting and metal forming segments of the industry displayed comparable cyclical patterns in employee-hours. (See table 4.) The cyclical declines in output and, hence, in employ ee-hours, probably aggravated the industry’s perennial shortages of skilled help when business picked up again. In part, these shortages were met through overtime work. Following are relatives of overtime hours in the metal cutting and metal forming segments of the ma chine tool industry (overtime hours in manufacturing = 100): M etal cutting: 1958 ................. 1959 ................. 1960 ................. 1 9 6 1 ................. 1962 ................. 1963 ................. 1964 ................. 1965 ................. 1966 ................. 1967 ................. 1968 ................. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 122 144 113 143 157 181 175 203 206 131 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 150 110 55 117 168 191 138 103 154 178 188 211 M etal forming: 1972 ................. 1973 ................. 1974 ................. 1975 ................. . . . . . 134 . 189 . 206 . 154 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... ........... 129 140 172 191 161 T echnology diffused gradually A number of important innovations have been adopted in the manufacture of metal cutting and metal forming machine tools, but diffusion among machine tool producers has been slow— slower than among in dustries which apply the innovations in mass produc tion. As will be documented, this slowness is related to the predominance of small firms which produce small batches of frequently complex machinery and compo nents. The machine tool industry is labor-intensive, rel ative to most manufacturing industries, as indicated by the high ratio of payroll to value added. Over the 1958— 77 period, this ratio averaged 58 percent for metal cut- In only 2 years (1958 and 1971) of the review period did overtime in metal cutting fall below the manufactur ing average. In all other years it was above, and often was half again to twice as high. Metal forming (for which pertinent data exist only since 1972) showed the same overtime pattern. The number of nonproduction workers in metal cut ting rose more rapidly than that of production workers, 90 Table 4. Cyclical behavior of productivity in the machine tool industry and its components, 1958-80 [Average annual rates in percent] i Output per employee-hour Period 1958-80 ................. Machine tools Meta! cutting Output Metal forming Machine tools Metal cutting Employee hours Metal forming Machine, tools Metal cutting Metal forming 1.1 1.5 0.1 1.6 1.9 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.6 ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... 23.1 5.6 7.8 2.4 23.1 6.3 8.7 3.7 23.0 3.8 5.4 -1.3 25.7 14.6 17.2 9.1 27.7 16.1 18.7 11.3 21.3 10.6 13.8 3.0 2.2 8.5 8.8 6.6 3.8 9.2 9.2 7.4 -1.4 6.5 7.9 4.3 Downswings: 1959-61 ...................... 1966-71 ...................... 1974-76 ...................... -2.0 -4.2 -5.2 -1.9 -4.0 -5.5 -2.4 -4.6 -4.7 -1.1 -11.1 -14.1 -1.0 -12.4 -13.0 -1.7 -7.8 -17.0 0.9 -7.3 -9.5 0.9 -8.8 -8.0 0.7 -3.4 -13.0 Upswings: 1958-59 1961-66 1971-74 1976-80 ting establishments, and 60 percent for metal forming establishments, compared with 52 percent for non electrical machinery, 52 percent for transportation equipment, and 47 percent for all manufacturing. The mass production techniques made possible by machine tools generally cannot be used in building them, al though significant improvements in small-batch produc tion processes have resulted from some basic techno logical advances. By far the most important development in machine tool technology has been the evolution of numerical control. In fact, numerical control has reshaped ma chine tool technology, and continues to transform it. Essentially, numerical control made multifunction ma chine tools possible (exemplified by the machining cen ter, discussed earlier). According to Iron Age, numerical control tools have been decisive in achieving “the criti cal balance . . . . in machine construction and rigidity, horsepower, speed and feed ranges, standard tooling and management control over the machine cycle and operation.” " Numerical control was first applied in the manufacture of machine tools in the mid-fifties, but cer tain innovations were required to lower its cost and, thus, spur adoption by the smaller machine tool firms. Although these innovations have occurred, their impact on productivity was retarded by the severe cyclical downturns in the industry’s business in the early and middle seventies. Numerical control is a method whereby metal cutting (and to some extent metal forming) machine tools are controlled by instructions which are programmed and then punched on a tape. Information from the tape is converted into instructions which position the tools with respect to the workpiece; no templates, drill jigs, or stops are used and manual operation is not neces sary. (The operator can service more than one numeri cally controlled machine tool.) A feedback mechanism adjusts (or stops) the tool’s movement if programmed distance does not adhere to commanded tolerance, and stops it when the process is completed.12 Numerical control has always required drives which 91 would ensure that performance followed command. Hy draulic servomechanisms are still used for this purpose. In the late sixties, however, silicon-controlled rectifiers (which are solid-state devices) were introduced; these, together with improvements in the control motor, made possible much higher degrees of accuracy in machining work. Also, tool life was extended as gear transmission, hand wheels, and clutches were eliminated.13 Perhaps most important, the substitution of transistors, and lat er of integrated circuits, for electric relays reduced the number of control components by up to 90 percent, and the amount of wiring by up to 80 percent.14These devel opments slashed costs, and also allowed less highly trained personnel to program the machines. Thus, im proved control mechanisms gave impetus to the dif fusion of numerical controls. Numerical controls accelerated the consolidation of machine tool production—as well as the production of metalworking equipment— into machining centers. Ma chining centers are basically milling machines which also drill, ream, bore, tap, and so forth. In machining centers, complex shapes may be made by mounting cut ting tools of varying sizes and power configurations on a single spindle. The cutting tools then are automatical ly changed by transfer arms, which also store the tool. These automatic tool changes take only a few seconds; formerly several minutes of an operator’s time were re quired.15 Machining centers also eliminate the need to design, build, and store the jigs and fixtures needed by single-purpose machines.16 Single-purpose machines also have been much im proved by numerical controls. For example, numerically controlled boring machines have reduced downtime for loading and unloading by up to 30 percent.17 Numerical control applied to grinding machines often halves lay out time; programmable electronic wheel feed and wheel retraction have been developed which reduce labor time and enhance precision. The design of hobs for gear cut ting has been subjected to computer calculation, saving cutting time.18 Cutting tool materials have become harder, permit gures for all manufacturing; for metal forming machine tools, the ratio was 40 percent. Fixed assets per worker in metal cutting and metal forming were 77 percent and 81 percent of the manufacturing average in 1976. More over, the long-term growth in the industry’s expendi tures for new plant and equipment, expressed in constant dollars, averaged 2.7 percent annually between 1958 and 1978— compared with 4.6 percent for all manufacturing industries. However, these long-term trend indicators obscure significant cyclical changes. Following are average annual rates of change in expen ditures (in constant dollars) for new plant and equip ment in the machine tool industry and in all industries, 1958-78:24 ting increased cutting speeds (albeit at the cost of re quiring heavier, more powerful machines). Tungsten carbide which replaced high-speed steel in 1929 was in turn supplanted by ceramic materials and polycrystal line diamond-tipped tools. Until 1900, cutting speeds ran up to 25 feet per minute; high-speed steel tools av eraged 90 feet per minute; tunsten carbide, 150 feet per minute; ceramic materials, 650 feet per minute; and polycrystalline diamond-tipped tools can cut several thousand feet per minute. Meanwhile, the older cutting materials have been improved— for example, steel tools are hardened by cobalt and continue to be widely used. Naturally, the high speeds enlarge the machine tool’s output capacity.19 Metal cutting tools predominate over the use of metal forming tools in the manufacture of either type of ma chine tool. Thus, technological improvements in metal forming tools and increases in their output capacity have, of course, greatly benefited those who use the tools intensively, but have only marginally affected pro ductivity of those who produce the tools.20 Computers are used in tandem with or incorporated into numerically controlled machine tools where reli ability or control is crucial (as in the machining of frames for aircrafts), or where minimizing of downtime is essential. The recent trend has been toward relatively small computers interfacing with individual machines, rather than a single computer controlling a number of machines.21 The computer has also been used in produc tion management, as well as in the design of machine tools, significantly reducing labor requirements of engi neering and drafting personnel. Conventionally, engi neers and aides graphed the design for a machine tool on drawing boards, according to a customer’s specifica tions; corrections usually required redrawing of all or most of the design to preserve proportionalities. Now, computers do the corrected redrawing, cutting the time required for such corrections. This so-called interactive graphics has permitted a 4-fold increase in the design er’s productivity. Memory storage of given designs fur ther aids productivity.22 M achine tools 2.3 29.5 28.0 16.7 7.3 10.2 7.3 10.5 D ownswings: 1959- 61 ................... 1966-71 ...................... 1974—76 ...................... -9.5 -1 8 .0 -9 .6 2.4 1.4 -3.8 Cyclical patterns in the real value of the industry’s capital outlays parallel those for productivity, output, and employee-hours. Even though capital outlays were strong during the upswings of the seventies, they did not reattain the levels of the sixties. In the 1976-78 up swing, the outlays were nearly one-third below those of the mid-sixties, while outlays for all industries were nearly a third higher. The machine tool industry’s low levels of expendi tures for plant and equipment are reflected in the relatively high average age of its equipment. According to the American Machinist, 23 percent of the industry’s machine tools were less than 10 years old in 1976-78, compared with 31 percent for all metalworking indus tries; 37 percent were 10 to 19 years old, compared with 35 percent for all metalworking and 40 percent were more than 20 years, compared with 34 percent. The American Machinist's periodic inventories suggest that user industries tend to delay replacement of aging machine tools. On average, only 31 percent of machine tools in service in all metalworking industries were less than 10 years old in 1976-78, compared with 36 per cent in 1968 and in 1963; 34 percent were more than 20 years old in 1976-78, compared with 23 percent in 1968 and 21 percent in 1963.25 The rising average age of machine tools may have been offset to some degree by the high proportion of parts and rebuilt machine tools shipped by toolmakers. Parts for metal cutting tools and rebuilt machine tools accounted for 19 percent of total shipments in 1976, Relatively old capital stock The machine tool industry, although vital for the expansion and modernization of industrial machinery, has spent relatively little for its own plant and equip ment. During the review period, the long-term growth in such spending was significantly below that for all in dustries. One of the results has been that the average age of equipment in the machine tool industry is well above that in all other metalworking industries.23 According to 1977 census data, plant and equipment expenditures per employee in metal cutting machine tools represented only 52 percent of the comparable fi A ll industries Upswings: 1958- 59 ................... 1961-66 ...................... 1971-74 ...................... 1976-78 ...................... 92 are anticipated from automotive and aircraft manufac turers, and from manufacturers in other metalworking industries requiring more “flexible” technology for small-batch production.26 For the next several years, the automotive industry will be retooling for the production of smaller, more en ergy-efficient vehicles, at an estimated cost of $60 bil lion. Undoubtedly, this will strain machine tool manufacturing capacity. However, in the long run, de mand for machine tools from the automotive industry is likely to slacken because of the prospective reduction in the number of automobile models.27 Similarly, the air craft industry may replace about one-half of its 6,000 commercial air carriers, some of which were placed in service 20 years earlier. New configurations of air frames will be needed which conform with mandated re quirements to reduce noise levels and fuel consumption. Therefore, the aircraft industry will need more costeffective machine tools.28 Metalworking firms generally have become concerned with more efficient production of small batches of parts and components; their interest in automated batch manufacturing systems is likely to intensify. In such systems, electronically-controlled as semblages of machine tools are linked by material-han dling equipment so as to convert a system of discrete parts manufacturing into one of continuous (or nearly continuous) processing.29 Automatic-batch manufactur ing systems have been increasingly used in the construc tion machinery industry.30 The building of craftworkers skills into the machine began when Eli Whitney constructed musket-making machines in the early 19th century.31 The need “to build the skill in the machine” arose partly from the perennial shortage of craftworkers (which often resulted in un skilled workers operating complex equipment) and part ly from the increased precision demanded of machine tools. Quite possibly, the diffusion of numerically con trolled machine tools will accelerate the trend “to build the skill in the machine” in the eighties. As noted in the discussion on occupational patterns, this trend has af fected the machine tool industry less than most other industries. This occupational pattern has been projected to persist: in 1990, the Bureau of Labor Statistics proj ects that 31 percent of metalworking machinery indus try employees will be skilled craftworkers (only slighly below the 1980 proportion), compared with 20 percent for all manufacturing. Thus, the Bureau’s projections implicitly assume that skill needs in the metalworking industry will change little; and that in the machine tool industry, it will continue to be difficult, at times even infeasible, to build the skill of craftworkers into ma chine tools. Nevertheless, the diffusion of numerically controlled machine tools will probably accelerate under the Spur of compared with 14 percent in the late sixties. Parts for metal forming tools and rebuilt machinery constituted 33 percent of shipments in 1976, compared with 20 per cent in the late sixties. The proportion rises in periods of slack business, but the rise may, in part, indicate intensified efforts to retrofit and upgrade aging machine tools, in lieu of purchasing new machines. However, the high average age of equipment in the machine tool industry may have been partially offset through the replacement of worn-out parts, or by the rebuilding of machines along more up-to-date lines. Furthermore, the industry has an above-average propor tion of numerically controlled machine tools— nearly 4 percent of its tools are numerically controlled, com pared with 2 percent for all metalworking industries. Because numerically controlled machine tools are gener ally under 15 years old, they probably represent at least 6 percent of the industry equipment that has been in service less than 20 years, and surely a much larger pro portion of its total output capacity. Industry structure, The structure of the machine tool in dustry does not differ much from that of manufacturing as a whole. In 1972, the latest year for which data are available, the four largest of the nearly 900 companies making metal cutting machine tools accounted for 25 percent of the industry’s total employment, 22 percent of its value of shipments, and 30 percent of its capital expenditures. In metal forming, concentration was slightly less. The 50 largest metal cutting companies, representing 10 percent of all establishments in the in dustry, accounted for three-quarters of employment, value of shipments, and capital expenditures. Trends in value added per employee by employment size class of establishment suggest that productivity has risen at a somewhat higher rate in establishments with 100 or more employees than in smaller establishments. A ccelera ted dem and m ay aid diffusion Industry observers generally expect that demand for machine tools will remain strong. Whether this means that skilled labor shortages will persist is arguable. Skilled workers who have been laid off because of slow business in key metalworking industries such as auto mobiles may be available. But, because average hourly wages in these industries are often higher than those in machine tools, it may be difficult for the machine tool industry to attract such workers. Hence, incentives for technological advances in the machine tool establish ments may remain fairly strong. Therefore, unless the machine tool industry also suffers from slow business, productivity should improve at somewhat higher rates than the long-term rates reported here. Continued high levels of demand for machine tools 93 strong demand (which justifies the investment) and re current labor shortages. Also, as new generations of managers, engineers, and technicians enter the industry, numerical control and other computer-related methods will be more widely applied. The costs of these systems are likely to fall; hence, they will become more widely diffused.32 Although some manufacturing industries use un manned machining systems,33 demand is likely to be small for them. It would not be feasible financially for the machine tool industry to use such complex systems — downtime being very expensive.34 Thus, the “un manned factory” cannot be envisioned for the machine tool industry; its manufacture by this industry, however, can be. It is said that automotive engine plants rely heavily on the machine tool industry for advances in their pro duction equipment.35 In turn, the machine tool industry increasingly relies on electronics and the computer for its technological advances. Electronics and computers will likely be dominant in machine tool production in the years ahead. 1The machine tool industry consists of machine tools, metal cutting types (SIC 3541) and machine tools, metal forming types (SIC 3542) as designated in the Office of Management and Budget’s 1972 Stan dard Industrial Classification Manual. 2In this article, metalworking industries conform with those includ ed in the American Machinist inventory of metalworking equipment and include the furniture industry (SIC 25); primary metals industry (SIC 33); fabricated metal products industry (SIC 34); nonelectrical and electrical machinery industries (SIC 35 and 36); transportation equipment industry (SIC 37); precision instrument industry (SIC 38); and miscellaneous manufactures industry (SIC 39). According to BLS data, average annual rates of change of the out put of some major metalworking or other major machine tool using industries moved as follows: 12 McGraw-Hill Encyclopedia o f Science and Technology, vol. 13, (McGraw Hill, 1977), p. 692. 1,1 Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 166. 14 Machine Design. 15 Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 200. 16 Iron Age, Aug. 8. 1976, p. 174. 17 Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 189. 18 Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 256. 19 L.T.C. Rolt, A Short History o f Machine Tools (Cambridge, The M.I.T. Press, 1965), p. 223. American Machinist, Sept. 2, 1974. 20 Information obtained from an industry representative. 21 Agis Salpukas, “Computerizing machine tools,” The New York Times, June 5, 1980, p. D2. 22 Information obtained from industry representatives. Industry and sic number 1959-66 Household furniture, 251 . . Steel, 331 ............................. Copper rolling and drawing, 3351 ........................... Aluminum rolling and drawing, 3353,4,5............. Metal cans, 3411................... Construction machinery, 3531 ................................... Electric motors and generators, 3621 ................... Household appliances, 3631,2,3,9 ........................ Motor vehicles, 371 ........... 11973-78 Output 1966-73 4.8 5.1 21American Machinist, December 1978. 24 Expenditure data for the machine tool industry available to 1978 only. Data are from the 1980 Economic Report o f the President. D e flators are for private nonresidential fixed investment. 1973-79 4.5 0.7 1.9 -0.8 0.1 -0.5 9.4 2.8 6.7 3.9 10.7 26 Manufacturing Technology— A Changing Challenge to Improve Productivity (W ashington, General Accounting Office, 1976). 5.8 3.3 1.5 7.4 -1.2 1.4 7.6 9.1 2.8 4.8 2.7 4.8 27 “A paucity of new models means layoffs and toolmaking plant closings, while continual changes, such as those that occurred during the mid-sixties, signal exciting mechanical challenges, full work force utilization, and extended overtime premiums . . .” H.E. Arnett and D .N . Smith, The Tool and Die Industry, Problems and Prospects (Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan Graduate School of Business A d ministration, 1975), p. 18. Estimated retooling cost from Facts and Figures 1980, (Detroit, M otor Vehicle Manufacturers Association 1980), p. 5. 7.2 - 25 Of the leading industrial countries, the United States has the smallest percentage of machine tools in service less than 10 years. Even so, the actual number of such tools in the United States was 803,000 in 1976-78, nearly half again as many as in Germany and Ja pan. (See American Machinist, December 1978.) 2.2 3Metalworking Machinery, Current Industrial Reports, Series MQ 35-W (U.S. Department of Commerce, various issues). 4 Donald N. Smith and Larry Evans, Management Standards fo r Computers and Numerical Controls (University of Michigan, 1977). 5 “Fewer, more productive machines: The 12th American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equipment, 1976-78.” American Machin ist, December 1978, pp. 133-43. 6 L. Mackay, and R. Leonard, “NC and Conventional Manufactur ing Systems— A General Comparison.” Proceedings o f the 18th International Machine Tool Design and Research Conference (London, The Macmillan Press, 1978), pp. 651 ff. 1American Machinist, December 1978. 8 “The Machine Tools That Are Building America,” Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 269. 9Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 271. 10Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 274. 28 Iron Age, Mar. 17, 1980, p. 37. 29 Iron Age, Nov. 20, 1978, p. 75 ff. 30 John Duke, “Construction machinery industry posts slow rise in productivity,” Monthly Labor Review, July 1980, pp. 33-36. 31 A Short History o f Machine Tools. See especially pp. 147—48, and 223. See also David F. Noble, “Social Choice in Machine Design: The Case of Automatically Controlled Machine T ools,” in Andrew Zimbalist, ed., Case Studies on the Labor Process (N ew York, M onthly Re view Press, 1979), pp. 18-50. 32 A. Harvey Belitsky, “M etalworking Machinery,” in Technology and Labor in Five Industries (Bureau of Labor Statistics, forthcoming). 33 Iron Age, Dec. 17, 1979. 34 American Machinist, December 1979, p. 82. 35 William J. Abernathy, The Productivity Dilemma, Roadblock to Innovation in the Automobile Industry (Baltimore, The Johns Hopkins Press, 1978), p. 61. " Iron Age, Aug. 8, 1976, p. 165. 94 Nonwool yam mills experience slow gains in productivity During 1958-80, new equipment and techniques aided productivity growth; although the 2.3-percent rate o f increase was less than fo r manufacturing as a whole, it accelerated during the last 8 years o f the period Ja m e s D . Y o r k As measured by output per employee hour, productivity in the nonwool yarn mill industry increased at an aver age of 2.3 percent during 1958-80, somewhat below the 2.8-percent rate for all manufacturing.1 (See table 1.) Output increased at an average annual rate of 4.5 per cent while employee hours advanced at a rate of 2.1 percent. For the most recent period, 1973-80, produc tivity has risen at a faster annual rate— averaging 3.0 percent. Improved preparatory and spinning equipment have contributed to these gains. Growth varied over the period of study. From 1958 to 1965, productivity increased every year, rising at an average annual rate of 5.2 percent. The largest jump oc curred in 1961 with a rise of 9.3 percent. The 5.2-percent average gain in productivity reflected an average annual growth of 6.7 percent in output and 1.5 percent in employee hours. Since 1965, productivity gains have slowed considerably. During 1965-73, output per em ployee hour grew at an average annual rate of only 1.2 percent. Output increased at a 4.6-percent rate—just slightly faster than that of 3.4 percent for employee hours. Productivity movements displayed much year-toyear fluctuation during this time. There were increases in only 5 of 9 years, with the largest— 7.1 percent— oc curring in 1971. In contrast to productivity movements for most in dustries, the growth in this industry accelerated during* James D . York is an econom ist in the Division of Labor Force Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, March 1982. 95 1973-80, rising at an average annual rate of 3.0 percent. Output grew at a rate of 2.6 percent, while employee hours declined at a rate of 0.4 percent. Recessionary conditions in the economy in 1974 and 1975 had a strong impact on the trends in output and employee hours. In 1974, the yarn industry began sharp reduc tions in employee hours, as output fell 3.5 percent. The more than proportional drop in employee hours of 7.9 percent led to a 4.8-percent rise in productivity. In 1975, output posted a further decline of 4.2 percent. In the face of this continuing deterioration in output, em ployee hours experienced their largest single-year de cline in the entire 1958-80 period, 15.7 percent. The resulting productivity increase, 13.6 percent, was the largest of the two-decade period. Employment and plant size Total employment in the spun yarn industry in creased by more than 28 percent between 1958 and 1980, rising at an average annual rate of 2.1 percent. There were 67,800 employees in 1958, but by 1980 the total had risen to 86,900. However, the increase in em ployment was not steady; cyclical patterns were evident throughout the period, which were related to trends in the overall economy. The establishments which produce yarn vary in size but, generally, are rather large. According to the 1977 Census of Manufactures, nearly 40 percent of all estab lishments employ 100 to 249 employees and these ac count for more than 30 percent of industry value of population changes, housing starts, changes in lifestyle or consumer tastes, and general economic conditions. Non wool yarn is purchased by many different manu facturers. Broad woven fabric mills are major users of spun yarn. These mills produce goods made from cot ton, synthetic fibers, and silk, such as sheets, pillow cases, draperies, and towels. The firms which use synthetic fibers and silk are the largest purchasers of spun yam. From 1963 to 1977, purchases by non wool spinning mills increased nearly 90 percent, but those by broad woven cotton mills changed very little.2 Mills which produce knit fabric also account for a large proportion of total spun yam purchases. These mills knit tubular or flat fabric and dye or finish knit fabric; their output increased rapidly from 1963 for ward. This increase in output translated into rising yarn purchases by these mills. It is estimated that between 1963 and 1967, purchases of spun yam by both circular and warp knit fabric mills increased by approximately 136 percent. Other types of knitting mills also use spun yarn, in cluding knit outerwear and underwear mills and hosiery mills. The first type manufactures products such as suits, slacks, shirts, neckties, and skirts. Although com plete information is not available for all years, estimates indicate that purchases of spun yam by knit outerwear mills decreased during the 1963-77 period. Exports have historically accounted for a negligible portion of the total market. In 1979 and 1980, although exports increased rapidly, they only accounted for ap proximately 2 percent of yam shipments. Imports have had little impact on the domestic market, making up less than 1 percent of apparent consumption in recent years.3 T a b le 1. P r o d u c tiv ity a n d r e ia te d in d e x e s f o r n o n w o o l y a m m ills , 1958-BO [1977=100] j Output per employee hour Output Employee hours Employees 1958 ............. 1959 ............. 1960 ............. 59.5 62.3 65.3 39.4 44.8 42.5 66.2 71.9 65.1 72.9 72.9 68.6 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 ............. ............. ............. ............. ............. 71.4 74.7 76.3 80.6 84.6 45.1 48.7 50.3 57.4 66.5 63.2 65.2 65.9 71.2 78.6 65.6 66.3 66.3 69.1 73.8 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ............. ............. ............. ............. ............. 81.8 77.5 80.2 84.5 84.3 66.7 61.7 68.2 74.4 70.9 81.5 79.6 85.0 88.0 84.1 78.0 80.1 83.3 89.3 86.3 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ............. ............. ............. ............. ............. 90.3 91.0 85.0 89.1 101.2 82.0 91.2 88.9 85.8 82.2 90.8 100.2 104.6 96.3 81.2 89.2 96.4 102.7 101.2 87.7 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ............. ............. ............. ............. ............. 93.5 100.0 104.2 103.9 106.1 89.7 100.0 103.8 99.0 97.5 95.9 100.0 99.6 95.3 91.9 97.7 100.0 100.3 95.8 93.4 Year ! Average annual rates of change (in percent) 1958-80 ....... 1975-80 ....... 2.3 1.7 4.5 3.4 2.1 1.7 2.1 0.7 shipments. Of the 456 establishments in the industry, almost 20 percent employ 250 to 499 employees and also account for more than 30 percent of total value of shipments. Only about 7 percent of all establishments employ 500 to 999 employees but these produce more than 20 percent of industry value of shipments. Production workers have always represented a high proportion of total industry employment and that pro portion has changed very little over time. In 1958, they accounted for slightly more than 94 percent of total em ployment and in 1980 their share was still about 92 per cent. The proportion of female employees has increased in recent years, rising from approximately 44 percent of the work force in 1972 to 46 percent in 1980. Average hourly earnings in the spun yarn industry have remained well below those of all manufacturing. In 1972, the first year for which such data are available, average hourly earnings were $2.53, significantly less than the $3.82 for all manufacturing. By 1980, average hourly earnings in the industry had risen about 89 per cent to $4.78. However, this was still well below the av erage for all manufacturing, which was up to $7.27. Advances in technology The production of spun yam involves a number of dif ferent operations. Improvements in technology have taken place at different stages of the production process and have contributed to the industry’s overall growth. Much of the advance has resulted from gradual im provements in the equipment over time. The raw material arrives at the mill as bales. The adoption of automatic bale opening and blending equip ment, which eliminates the need for manual perfor mance of this operation, has led to greater efficiency in this initial stage of the production process. Likewise, improvements have occurred in the carding operation. In it, the fibers of the raw material are made parallel to each other and most of the foreign matter is removed. The fibers emerge in a form known as sliver. Formerly, the yam entered a picker which formed it into a roll before being fed into the carding machine. However, the introduction of the automatic chute feed which permits the blended fibers to be fed directly into Diverse industry markets Spun yam is used for the manufacture of the great majority of textile products; household items which contain yarn include carpets and mgs, bedspreads, draperies, and towels. Its demand can be influenced by 96 rapid productivity growth. During 1958-66, the rate of increase in output per employee hour was 4.6 percent. Both productivity and capital expenditures posted in creases in all but one year of the 1958-66 subperiod. The tremendous growth in capital expenditures dur ing this time caused the ratio of capital expenditures per employee to go up far more rapidly than for all manu facturing. In 1958, capital spending per employee was only $229 in the spun yarn industry, compared with $619 for all manufacturing. However, by 1966, capital spending per employee in the industry had risen to $1,368, compared with $1,112 for all manufacturing. From 1966-79, the trends in both capital expendi tures and productivity were quite different from the pre ceding years. The rate of increase in capital expend itures declined to 4.9 percent. There were even substantial decreases in a number of years. Productivity growth likewise experienced a slowdown, dropping to an average annual rate of increase of 2.2 percent. As in the case of capital expenditures, there were declines in some years. The decline in the growth rate of capital ex penditures caused the rate of increase in the ratio of capital expenditures per employee to fall behind that of all manufacturing. From 1966-79, capital spending per employee in the spun yarn industry advanced at an av erage annual rate of only 3.0 percent, compared with a rate of 9.2 percent for all manufacturing. Consequently, capital spending per employee was only $1,607 in 1979, compared with $3,118 for all manufacturing. the carding machine, has eliminated the need for a picker. The carding machinery itself has increased in speed, further contributing to productivity gains. The drawing and roving operations follow the carding process. The drawing operation makes the sliv ers more uniform. In the roving process, a twist is imparted to the sliver by the roving frame. This results in greater strength. The product that emerges is known as roving and is wound onto bobbins which are taken up when full. The adoption of larger bobbins has re duced the amount of tending necessary because they do not have to be removed as often. Improved roving equipment has been introduced which is faster and eliminates the need to remove the flyers (which insert twist into the fibers) for doffing (removal of the bob bins). After the roving operation, the roving bobbin pro ceeds to the spinning operation. The spinning drafts (draws out) the fibers to size the yam and puts the de sired twist into it, providing necessary strength. Yarn is spun onto bobbins; the use of larger ones on spinning machines has reduced the frequency with which bobbins have to be removed. The introduction of automatic doff ing equipment— equipment which removes the full bob bins and replaces them with empty ones—has also im proved productivity. Increased operating speed of the spinning equipment itself has also contributed to pro ductivity gains. After spinning, the yarn is taken to the winding de partment. Here, winding machines remove the yarn from the spinning bobbins and wind it onto cones for direct customer shipment or onto tubes for dyeing. Au tomation in winding equipment has taken place and has increased productivity growth immensely.4 A number of plants have introduced open-end spin ning, which has also aided productivity. This combines into one process the three separate operations of roving, spinning, and winding, thus eliminating the need for a separate roving and winding operation. Open-end spin ning can wind the yarn onto a package rather than a spinning bobbin; thus, a separate winding operation to transfer the yarn from the spinning bobbin to a cone is no longer needed.5 s h o u l d c o n t i n u e to increase as im provements in production equipment take place and as more manufacturers take advantage of these. Some of the newer equipment, which embodies more advanced technologies than past models, is capable of producing better quality yam with fewer imperfections and weak spots. This top quality is increasingly demanded by cus tomers as they adopt higher speed weaving and knitting machinery.6 This is accelerating the adoption of more modern production equipment by nonwool yarn mills. Some industry officials expect labor market condi tions to provide added stimulus for use of improved production equipment.7 Relocation of the manufacturing operations of many industries into major textile produc ing areas exerts additional pressure on existing labor and wages. This, in turn, is impelling more yam manu facturers to utilize the equipment and techniques which provide the greatest levels of output per employee hour. Open-end spinning will continue to contribute to pro ductivity gains as it becomes more widely adopted. This form of spinning has a particularly favorable effect on production efficiency because, as noted earlier, it com bines the separate operations of roving, spinning, and winding into a single process. P r o d u c t iv it y C apitol spending Rises in labor productivity are frequently linked to increases in capital formation. Data available through 1979 indicate that, over 1958-79 as a whole, currentdollar new capital expenditures rose at an average annu al rate of 9.4 percent. However, the advances were not uniform throughout the period, and the most rapid ones took place in the earlier years. From 1958 to 1966, new capital expenditures increased at a 22.1-percent rate. This acceleration in capital spending coincided with 97 ‘ See McAllister Isaacs III, “Winding a 138 Percent Boost in Oper ator Pounds,” Textile World, February 1980, pp. 79-82. 5 See Brenda V. Lloyd, “Meeting the Challenges of Modernization,” Textile Industries, September 1979, pp. 114-17. Also, see McAllister Isaacs III, “Avondale Open-End Cuts Labor, Ups Output,” Textile World, May 1980, pp. 63-66. 6W. Bud Newcomb, “U.S. Sales-Yam Firms Are Poised For Fu ture Growth,” Textile World, September 1980, p. 203. 7 See Douglas A. Bowen, “Linn-Corriher: Yam Making Pioneer,” Textile Industries, March 1980, p. 50. Also, see Joseph L. Lanier Jr., “Plants and Equipment,” America’s Textiles, June 1976, p. 21. 1The non wool yam mill industry consists of establishments primar ily engaged in spinning yam wholly or chiefly by weight of cotton, synthetic fibers, or silk. It is designated as industry 2281 in the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) Manual. All average annual rates of change are based on the linear least squares trend of the loga rithms of the index numbers. Extension of the indexes will appear in the annual BLS Bulletin, Productivity Measures fo r Selected Industries. 2The discussion of yam purchases from nonwool yam mills by the consuming industries is based on constant-dollar estimates. 3 U.S. Industrial Outlook (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1981), p. 402. 98 The office furniture industry: patterns in productivity Product proliferation and short production runs limited the use o f laborsaving equipment in office furniture establishments; as a result, productivity grew only moderately during 1958-80 J. E d w in H enneberger ing at much higher rates in the wood component (7.2 percent and 5.5 percent) than in metal (4.6 percent and 2.8 percent). The metal office furniture industry, which experienced five output downturns between 1958 and 1980, was, nevertheless, able to maintain productivity growth in all but 2 of these years. This suggests that the industry’s work force is flexible and can be rapidly reduced if in dustry sales are declining. However, the wood office fur niture industry was never able to maintain positive productivity during the six declines in output from 1958 to 1980. The more highly skilled work force, utilizing craftworkers, in the wood segment may be more diffi cult to periodically layoff and rehire. Productivity growth (as measured by output per em ployee hour) in the office furniture industry1 has been low, in large part because of relatively short production runs engendered by product proliferation. Between 1958 and 1980, the industry posted an average annual pro ductivity gain of 1.8 percent, substantially below the 2.8percent rate for all manufacturing industries. The gain resulted from growth in output of 5.5 percent, annually, and employee hours of 3.6 percent. In many industries, declines or small gains in output are associated with reduced or even negative growth in productivity. This seems to be true of the office furni ture industry as a whole. (See table 1.) Thus, in the 9 years in which output either declined or grew at a less than average rate, productivity either fell or grew at a less than average rate in 5 of these years. The trend in productivity for the overall office furni ture industry must be viewed in light of the underlying trend movements of the two component industries— wood office furniture and metal office furniture. Metal furniture is the dominant industry in the office furniture group, employing about two-thirds of the 53,000 work ers and accounting for roughly the same percent of shipments. Although both industries exhibited nearly the same growth in productivity between 1958 and 1980 (1.7 percent for wood furniture and 1.8 percent for met al furniture), the growth in output and employee hours was more diverse, with both output and hours grow-* Productivity trends have varied The industry’s long-term productivity growth can be divided into three periods (table 1). From 1958 to 1966, productivity grew at a rate of 3.6 percent annually. Slowing dramatically, productivity growth advanced by only 0.1 percent per year during the middle time span — 1966 to 1975. However, from 1975 to 1980, the rate of advance increased to 5.1 percent per year. Recession-induced falloffs were particularly acute from 1966 to 1975. During the 1970 recession, industry output dropped 17 percent while employee hours were reduced by 6.6 percent. Consequently, productivity in 1970 fell by more than 11 percent. During the 1974-75 recession, output declined 5.3 percent in 1974 and 17.7 percent in 1975 while productivity posted its largest falloff in 1974 ( - 8 .3 percent). More recently, produc tivity exhibited positive growth during the short reces- J. Edwin Henneberger is an econom ist in the Division of Industry Productivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M o n t h l y L a b o r R e v i e w , December 1982. 99 industry’s output growth. Some of these factors have in cluded the amount of available office space, growth of the white-collar work force, replacement demand, and the introduction of new products. The most important factor influencing the long-term growth of office furniture undoubtedly has been the growth of the white-collar or office work force. Between 1958 and 1980, white-collar workers have grown from about 27 to nearly 53 million. Currently, officeworkers account for slightly more than one-half of the total employed work force.2This translates into a 2.9-percent average annual increase. Available office space also is a determinant of office furniture demand. The amount of public and private detached office space doubled be tween 1958 and 1980.3 As the stock of existing office furniture grows, the de mand for replacement of womout or obsolete equip ment grows also. The data suggest that in recent years roughly one-third of office furniture production has been consumed by the replacement market.4 The introduction of new products also stimulates in creased demand for office furniture. In the past, office furniture usually consisted of desks, chairs, tables, and storage equipment, sold as individual pieces. Now, modular or systems furniture is sold as complete inte grated packages that include movable partitions, storage components, and service modules. Advantages claimed Table 1. Productivity and related indexes for the office furniture industry, 1958-80 [1977 = 100] Year Output per employee hour Output All employee hours Employees 1958 .......................... 1959 .......................... 1960 .......................... 64.0 69.8 70.4 33.1 37.5 39.4 51.7 53.7 56.0 51.8 52.9 54.7 1981.......................... 1982 .......................... 1983 .......................... 1964 .......................... 1985 .......................... 72.5 74.4 75.9 82.1 84.2 38.4 42.1 45.6 50.8 57.5 53.0 56.6 60.1 61.9 68.3 51.8 55.8 58.7 60.0 64.9 1966 .......................... 1387 .......................... 1988 .......................... 1989 .......................... 1970 .......................... 86.7 86.5 85.2 88.0 78.2 67.9 69.7 70.9 81.4 67.6 78.3 80.6 83.2 92.5 86.4 74.7 78.2 78.7 88.9 82.7 1971.......................... 1972 .......................... 1973 .......................... 1974 .......................... 1975 .......................... 83.9 91.8 90.6 83.1 85.5 64.8 82.7 87.5 82.9 68.2 77.2 90.1 96.6 99.8 79.8 74.9 87.3 94.4 98.9 81.8 89.7 100.0 100.1 75.8 100.0 108.1 107.3 108.9 125.9 84.5 100.0 108.0 112.9 115.6 85.6 100.0 107.8 110.9 118.4 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 .......................... ........................ .......................... .......................... .......................... 121.1 Average annual rates of change 1958-80 1958-66 1988-75 1975-80 .................... .................... .................... .................... 1.8 3.6 0.1 5.1 5.5 8.4 1.4 13.9 3.6 4.6 1.4 8.3 3.8 4.1 2.0 8.0 sion in 1980. However, this gain in productivity (1.5 percent) was somewhat less than the industry’s long term growth (1.8 percent per year). Among the component industries, the same midterm pattern of productivity slowdown is evident. (See table 2.) From 1958 to 1966, productivity advanced in both industries at about 3.6 percent per year. But from 1966 to 1975, productivity fell at an annual rate of 1.1 per cent in the wood component while advancing by only 0.5 percent per year in the metal furniture industry. Rebounding from the recession-marked middle period, productivity advanced sharply from 1975 to 1980 in the wood and metal industries— 7.2 and 3.8 percent, re spectively. Output in this recovery period was up sharp ly in both industries, paced by the nearly 22-percent average annual growth in wood furniture. Lagging somewhat behind wood furniture, the output of metal furniture increased by about 10 percent per year during this later period, as market share was lost to the more natural look and feel of wood. . Tab!® 2 P r o d u c tiv ity index© © f o r th@ o f f ic e fu rn itu r® a n d t w o c o m p o n e n t, 1©5@-80 [1977=100] Gffle© furniture demand growing Between 1958 and 1980, output of the office furniture industry grew at an average annual rate of 5.5 percent per year, substantially above the 3.8-percent average rate for all manufacturing industries. A number of fac tors have shaped the demand for office furniture and the All office furniture Wood furniture Metal furniture 1958 ....................................... 1959 ....................................... 1960 ....................................... 64.0 69.8 70.4 67.1 69.5 68.0 64.5 71.6 72.7 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... 72.5 74.4 75.9 82.1 84.2 70.5 69.9 80.4 84.5 82.8 74.7 77.9 75.9 82.9 86.3 1966 1967 1968 1989 1970 ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... 86.7 86.5 85.2 88.0 78.2 85.9 88.1 87.7 91.9 83.9 88.3 87.6 86.2 88.5 78.0 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... 83.9 91.8 90.6 83.1 85.5 81.2 84.5 78.5 83.0 80.5 86.4 96.7 97.9 84.5 88.9 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... ....................................... 89.7 100.0 100.1 107.3 .108.9 81.9 100.0 100.7 110.7 109.2 94.8 100.0 99.9 104.8 108.6 Average annual rates of change 1958-80 1958-66 1966-75 1975-80 ICO ................................. ................................. ................................. ................................. 1.8 3.6 0.1 5.1 1.7 3.5 -1.1 7.2 1.8 3.6 0.5 3.8 turing office furniture increased from 289 in 1958 to 486 in 1977—most of this growth occurring in the wood furniture segment. At the same time, the proportion of industry shipments accounted for by the four largest companies in each industry increased modestly. Between 1975 and 1980, the average annual growth in capital expenditures per employee was lower for the office furniture industry than for all manufacturing. For example, from 1958 to 1975, capital expenditures per employee grew at an annual rate of 6.3 percent in office furniture, while the all manufacturing rate over the same time period was 7.5 percent. Productivity growth over this period was also lower in the office furniture in dustry than in all manufacturing. From 1975 to 1980, however, capital expenditures per employee accelerated to 29.6 percent per year, compared with a rate of 11.1 percent for all manufacturing. Productivity from 1975 to 1980 increased sharply also, growing at a rate of 5.1 percent. The level of expenditures per employee, howev er, has been substantially less than all manufacturing. In 1980, the office furniture industry expended roughly $2,900 per employee for new capital equipment while the all manufacturing average was almost $3,700. for systems furniture include design flexibility, more ef ficient use of floor space, low rearrangement costs, and built-in electrical outlets. In recent years, systems furni ture has outpaced the growth of conventional office fur niture. Currently, systems furniture accounts for about 20 percent of the total office furniture market. Comput ers and word processors, which require support furnish ings, have also resulted in increased demand for office furniture. Industry employment more than doubles The number of employees in the office furniture in dustry increased from 23,000 in 1958 to about 53,000 in 1980. Sustained expansion of the work force during the 1960’s accounted for much of this growth. While the overall employment growth for the indus try was 3.8 percent per year from 1958 to 1980, em ployment trends varied among the subindustries. The work force in the wood office furniture industry expanded at an average of 6.0 percent per year. The metal furniture industry grew at less than half of that— 2.8 percent per year. Compared with other manufacturing industries, office furniture production is relatively labor intensive. About 10 percent more production worker hours are needed to generate $1 of added value in office furniture than in all manufacturing. Among the component industries, wood office furniture is the most labor intensive. Production workers accounted for 79 percent of total industry employment in 1980, down slightly from the 81 percent reported in 1958. About 25 percent of the indus try’s workers in 1980 were women, slightly less than the 31 percent level for all manufacturing. Average hourly earnings of production workers— $5.92 in 1980— were somewhat below that of the all manufacturing rate of $7.27. Over the long term, employee turnover has been slightly below that of the all manufacturing rate. Manufacturing innovations limited Typically, production in the office furniture industry takes place at mechanized work stations with workpiece transfer accomplished by conveyor line, forklift truck, or handcart. The wood furniture industry employs gen eral purpose woodworking machinery such as saws, planers, glue presses, and sanders. Basic operations in the metal furniture industry include metal cutting, stamping, welding, and tubeforming. With minor differ ences, both industries have common operations such as painting and upholstering. Obviously, many of the pro cesses used for manufacturing wood furniture bear little resemblance to those used for metal furniture. However, even within the component industries, variations in equipment and processes are evident. This is particular ly true of wood furniture. Some of the finer grades are produced almost entirely by hand, while the less expen sive grades are produced in assembly line fashion. Product proliferation is a problem within the office furniture industry, and this has hindered the introduc tion of special purpose and highly efficient machinery and equipment. While the household furniture industry finds it relatively easy to drop product lines and styles, office furniture companies must maintain the capacity to produce old as well as new product lines. This problem is particularly acute in the more expensive wood office furniture lines. Reorders of wood furniture must match style as well as wood grain pattern and color (which may not be the same as when the pieces were new). Therefore, the potential number of product types, styles, and colors, coupled with the bulkiness of furni Imdissfry establishment size Increasing Although office furniture production is geographically dispersed throughout the United States, there is a large concentration of firms in Ohio, Indiana, Illinois, Michi gan, and Wisconsin, with many plants clustered in and around Grand Rapids, Mich. Until World War II, the Grand Rapids area had been a major center for house hold furniture. After the war, the household furniture industry dispersed, and commercial and office furniture manufacturers moved in to fill the void. From 1958 to 1977, the number of establishments in the industry has been growing. In the wood segment, the number of establishments more than doubled, while in metal furniture, the number increased by only 25 per cent. For the industry as a whole, average employment size per establishment increased by about 12 percent. During the same period, companies primarily manufac 101 ture, discourage factories from accumulating large in ventories of finished goods. Most office furniture, per haps as much as 90 percent, is for order rather than inventory. Office furniture dealers do not stock large in ventories either; rather, an accumulation of customer orders is periodically sent to the factory. This results in short production runs of individual items. This diminished ability to control production runs may be one of the reasons productivity growth in the office furniture industry has been less than that of the house hold furniture industry.5 The office furniture industry must remain even more flexible in terms of production capabilities than household furniture manufacturers, many of whom are also troubled by short, inefficient production runs and difficulty in incorporating highly specialized and efficient equipment. Nevertheless, some notable advances in the technology of manufacturing office furniture have been introduced. In the wood office furniture industry, one of the most pronounced trends in innovation has been increased use of particleboard. While the primary impetus for the expanded usage of particleboard has been its lower cost in relation to the cost of solid lumber, the industry has focused considerable attention on new technologies to handle the material. A wide variety of surface laminates and films and application techniques have eliminated several time-consuming production and assembly opera tions. Groove-folding, a technique whereby V-shaped grooves are cut in the particleboard substrate, but not through the flexible surface material, produces seamless furniture edges which are held in place by the continu ous outer wrap.6 Although somewhat hampered by increased petro chemical prices in recent years, the use of plastic materials has simplified construction and added strength to furniture components, and can also produce mar-resistant surfaces. Reconstituted wood veneer, an other advance in materials, has uniform thickness, grain, and quality and can be evenly stained. Its use eliminates the need for the labor intensive procedure of manually grading, selecting, and removing defects from natural veneers. In addition to new materials, notable advances have occurred in woodworking machinery. Abrasive planing, introduced in the early 1960’s, combines heavy stock re moval with direct dimensioning at the sanding machine.7 Machines which glue and trim veneer strips to the edges of particleboard can eliminate the complicated set of clamps and pressure bands which formerly had to be locked in place until the glue dried. In the metal office furniture industry, machines have recently been installed that automatically position and cut shapes into the large flat metal blanks that later will be fashioned into desks, file cabinets, and so forth. This equipment is more efficient because it does not require 102 moving the workpiece to a separate machine for each cut. Also, setup time is considerably reduced. Savings in the time needed to produce tubular shapes have been accomplished by new tubeforming and cut ting equipment. Tubemaking, which starts from flat coiled steel, has been speeded up by the use of automat ic welders which join the ends of the coils so that the tubeforming equipment need not be shut down while coils are being changed. Metallic inert gas (mig ) welding has largely supplant ed most other forms of welding. Its advantage is that the parts being joined do not have to be as thoroughly cleaned as with brazing. Although robot welders are not common, automatic welding is. Once travel and an gle of the welding arm have been adjusted, a worker is required only to load and unload workpieces onto and from the equipment. Although not designed specifically for the metal office furniture industry, automated parts inventory storage and retrieval systems are being used by several plants in the industry. Operating under the control of a computer which “explodes” or breaks down orders for the re quired number of finished pieces of furniture into the necessary parts demand, robot crawlers and unmanned forklift trucks retrieve and deliver the parts to various pickup stations where they are transferred to the assem bly line in the correct sequence for manufacture. Upholstering, an operation which is similar in both wood and metal office furniture, is a particularly labor intensive operation and requires a skilled work force. Although still used in many plants, manual pattern lay out and fabric cutting have in some cases been phased out, superseded by diecutting of fabric. Computer-controlled cutting equipment, which combines high speed with accuracy and eliminates manual pattern layout, is also available.8 Steam tables, installed at upholsterers’ work stations, expand the cut fabric workpiece. Once removed from the steam and stapled around the foam rubber cushion, the fabric shrinks back to its normal size and becomes taut. Airpowered plunger tables, used to compress the fabric-covered foam shape, have made button insertion and tiedown operations easier. Electrostatic finishing, used widely by the metal fur niture industry, can be used successfully on wooden fur niture,9 resulting in increased labor productivity in the finishing area and a substantial reduction in material and maintenance costs. Automatic electrostatic spray lines allow closer spacing of pieces to be painted and, thus, greater efficiency. With these automatic lines, col or changeover is automatic and can be done in 30 sec onds rather than the 2 minutes previously required on the nonautomatic electrostatic lines. Electrodeposition lines, which are powdered coatings in a medium of ei ther air or water, are particularly efficient with respect to labor, materials, and solvent emissions. Likewise, both the metal and wood office furniture in dustries have shared the advances made in portable, handheld power fastening tools, resulting in added worker efficiency through more power, greater capacity, and less weight and maintenance. Productivity has also been enhanced by improved workflow layout, compu terized recordkeeping, and new materials such as quick setting glues and improved finishes. Recent trends may continue If continued, the industry’s capital spending surge of the last few years may provide the plant and equipment necessary to maintain the recent above average growth in productivity. However, the current economic downturn may have a negative effect on demand and productivity. Although the full consequences of the current eco nomic downturn cannot be foreseen, it is worth noting that previous recessions have had only limited ef ' The office furniture industry is classified as SIC 252 in the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification Manual and its 1977 supplement, is sued by the U.S. Office of Management and Budget. The subindustries within the office furniture group include establishments that are pri marily engaged in manufacturing furniture commonly used in offices— wood (SIC 2521) and metal (SIC 2522). 2Employment and Training Report o f the President, 1981 Report (The White House, 1981), pp. 148— 49; see also table 3, p. 73, of the April 1982 issue of the Monthly Labor Review. 3 See P. W. Daniels, ed., Spatial Patterns of Office Growth and Loca tion (New York, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1979), pp. 67-69. 4 “Equipment Purchases Planned by Readers in 1980,” The Office, January 1980, p. 26. 5See J. Edwin Henneberger, “Productivity Growth Below Average in the Household Furniture Industry,” Monthly Labor Review, Nov 103 fects on the growth of the white-collar work force, one of the key factors in the output growth of the office fur niture industry. In fact, even though there have been four recessions since 1958, the total white-collar work force has never declined. With the forecasted continued expansion in the white-collar work force,10 demand for the industry’s products should continue to increase and may, therefore, present the industry with opportunities to expand productivity. Also, the industry’s output should be further bolstered if the growth of systems fur niture continues. While the “paperless office” is not as yet a reality,11 over the long term, the increasing sophistication of elec tronic office equipment may result in officeworkers becoming more productive. This, in turn, can influence output of the office furniture industry by dampening growth in the white-collar work force and affecting de mand and productivity in the office furniture industry. ember 1978, pp. 23-29. 6 Darrell Ward, “Groove Folding for Contract and Contemporary,” Woodworking and Furniture Digest, June 1981, pp. 42-45. 7 ---- , “Abrasive Planing Challenges Your Knife Cutting Tech niques,” Hitchcock's Wood Working Digest, November 1963, pp. 2932. 8 Robert Michael, “New Techniques of Computerized Fabric Cut ting,” Furniture Methods and Materials, June 1971, pp. 12-15. 9 Richard D. Rea, “Electrostatic Disks Win,” Woodworking and Furniture Digest, April 1982, pp. 22-25. 10 Economic Projections to 1990, Bulletin 2121 (Bureau of Labor Sta tistics, 1982), pp. 34-47. " See Paul Lieber, “Office Automation: The Job Threat that Never Happened,” The Office, May 1980, p. 158. Productivity in the pump md compressor industry During 1958-80, the industry experienced long-term advances, reflecting improvements in metalworking machinery and computer aid; but since 1965 productivity has decelerated, being especially slow from 1973 forward , H o rst B r a n d and Cl y d e H uffstutler Output per employee hour in pump and compressor manufacturing rose at an average annual rate of 2.1 per cent between 1958 and 1980—compared with a rate of 2.6 percent for manufacturing as a whole.1 Output in creased 4.7 percent a year, employee hours 2.6 percent. Among the sources of the industry’s long-term produc tivity advance were improvements in metalworking ma chinery, which lies at the core of the production processes for pumps and compressors, and computer technologies, which were increasingly applied to engi neering design. The labor productivity trend for the industry was marked by strong advances during the early part of the period (from 1958 to 1965), followed by deceleration during 1965-73, and a further slowing thereafter. As the tabulation shows, using average annual rates of change in percent, the trend pattern paralleled manufac turing: 1958-80 .................. 1958-65 ............. 1965-73 ............. 1973-80 ............. Pumps and compressors 2.1 3.4 2.1 1.0 By 1980, the level of labor productivity in the industry had risen 55 percent from 1958, as against 78 percent for all manufacturing. The long-term productivity trend, in addition to evi dencing divergent medium-term movements, was punc tuated by sharp year-to-year swings. These swings were generally related to the business cycle, although they show no uniform pattern. Thus, labor productivity fell steeply in 1960 (3.2 percent), 1975 (5.6 percent), and 1980 (2.6 percent). In these years, output either grew more slowly than employee hours (1960), or fell more rapidly (1975), or fell while hours rose (1980). Yet, in 1961, 1967, and 1971, years when the economy slowed, significant increases in productivity occurred (3.9 per cent, 1.7 percent, and 1.5 percent)— which, however, stemmed from drops in employee hours exceeding drops in output. Years of recovery or boom in which productivity soared to more than twice its long-term rate, displayed a more uniform pattern of change in output and em ployee hours. In 1959 and 1976, gains in productivity were linked with large output increases but slight em ployee hour declines. Separate data for pumps and pumping equipment, and for air and gas compressors, are available only from 1972 forward. Average annual rates of change in labor productivity for the two separate industries com pare as follows for the 1972-80 span: Manufacturing 2.6 2.7 2.4 1.8* Horst Brand and Clyde Huffstutler are economists in the Division of Industry Productivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the Monthly L abor Reivew, December 1982. 104 Percent Pumps and compressors ................................... Pumps and pumping equipment ................. Air and gas compressors .............................. 1.2 1.2 1.1 All manufacturing ............................................ 1.9 Reflecting contrasting trends in output and employee hours, labor productivity movements in the pump and pumping equipment segment were considerably less vol atile than in compressor manufacturing. The former attained a productivity level in 1979 that exceeded 1973 by 7 percent (both years registered cyclical peaks); the latter failed to reattain its 1973 high. Output increases Pumps and compressors are used throughout manu facturing and many nonmanufacturing industries, as well as agriculture. Pumps are the second most com mon machine in use after the electric motor.2 Compres sors generate compressed air, which may be regarded as a form of energy ranking in breadth of use only below electricity, gas, and water, in addition to being indis pensable in the transportation of gas.3 Between 1958 and 1980, output of pumps and com pressors rose 175 percent, or at an average annual rate of 4.7 percent. Manufacturing output grew at a rate of 3.8 percent over the period. Like the long-term trend in the industry’s labor productivity, the long-term trend in output rose less after 1965 than earlier, as the following tabulation indicates by showing average annual rates of change in percent: 1958-80 ............ 1958-65 ___ 1965-73 1973-80 Pumps and compressors Manufacturing 4.7 6.5 2.5 4.2 3.8 5.9 3.0 2.5 Output of pumps and compressors reached a peak in dex level of 115 (1977=100) in 1979, from which it re ceded slightly in 1980. The dip was caused by a decline in compressor manufacturing, which had climbed 51 percent between 1973 and 1979. Pump and pumping equipment output had risen 22 percent between those 2 years of cyclical highs. Of the total output of pumps and compressors, the former accounted for about two-thirds, according to the 1977 Census of Manufactures, the latter for the remain ing one-third. Industrial pumps represented more than half of the output of pumps and pumping equipment (other than accessories). Hydraulic fluid power pumps, oil well and oilfield pumps, and other pumps and equip ment installed in appliances, fire engines, and structures, made up the remaining output. Parts and attachments constituted close to one-quarter of pump manufacturing 105 output in 1977. Given the often difficult climatic and environmental conditions in which pumps must operate, and the abrasiveness of fluids often transferred by them, speedy replacement of worn and damaged parts consti tutes a vital function of the manufacturer, and is the reason for the high proportion of shipments of parts and attachments. Air compressors accounted for well over one-quarter of the shipments of compressor manufacturers, accord ing to the 1977 census, gas compressors for just under one-tenth. They consisted preponderantly of the station ary type. Portable compressors, which are relatively small machines, made up one-fifth of total air and gas compressor shipments. Industrial spraying equipment also added one-fifth to compressor manufacturers’ ship ments. Compressors, like pumps, are frequently exposed to rough operating and environmental conditions, hence a comparatively high proportion of shipments (20 per cent) represented parts and attachments in 1977. Factors underlying output growth In general, growth in the output of pumps and com pressors was related to expansion in industrial and public utility demand, particularly during the boom years of the early and mid-1960’s; gains in residential and associated public works construction, such as sew age and waterworks, during the 1960’s and 1970’s; and intensified needs of energy-related extractive and pipe line industries, especially during the 1970’s. Foreign trade, too, played an important role in sustaining out put: about one-fifth of pump and compressor produc tion was exported between 1972 and 1978. Expansion in the productive activities of a wide array of users lay at the base of output growth of pumps and compressors. No precise statistical link can be established between the former and the latter. However, movements in the plant and equipment expenditures, adjusted for price changes, by major pump and com pressor users are indicative, as are put-in-place data for construction. Among large-scale users of pumps and compressors was the chemical industry, which accounts for about one-tenth of total pump and compressor output.4 Chem icals nearly doubled plant and equipment outlays (ad justed for price changes) in the early 1960’s, then reduced them. After 1973, however, outlays were once again raised, so that in 1979 they stood nearly twice above the 1973 level. The industry has increasingly used pumps made of fiberglas, plastics, and stainless steel to transfer salt solutions, acid, and chlorine.5 Steel mills and blast furnaces, whose capital spending patterns compared roughly with that of the chemical in dustry over the review period, purchase about 7 percent of pump and compressor output. They use a variety of industrial and hydraulic pumps as well as compressors to move sources of energy such as liquid fuels, as well as water to absorb waste energy. Installation of multi stage pumps to achieve higher pressure has, in part, been prompted by the shift from open-hearth to basicoxygen and electric-arc steelmaking processes. The par tial replacement of slabbing mills by continuous casting has required more water, hence a larger number of and more powerful centrifugal pumps.6 More than 18 percent of pumps and compressors are bought by energy-related extracting, processing, and distributing industries. Thus, growth in extractive activ ities spurred the demand for industrial as well as oil well and oilfield pumps. Between 1960 and 1970, the number of crude oil and gas wells drilled dropped sharply (by nearly two-fifths), as did footage drilled (by 27 percent). After 1970, the decline was reversed; in 1978, the two indicators ran 72 percent and 68 percent above 1971 levels. Concomitantly, output of oil well and oilfield pumps, which had risen at an average annu al rate of less than 4 percent between 1958 and 1973, soared to a rate of more than 10 percent between 1973 and 1980. Oil extraction also requires reciprocal pumps for mud circulation; submersible centrifugal units to lift the crude oil; and centrifugal pumps for waterflooding (to prevent subsidence and maintain pressure).7 Compressors are required in oil drilling and oilfield maintenance operations, and particularly in secondary recovery efforts. The continued expansion of natural gas pipelines (whose mileage increased 9 percent between 1973 and 1978) spelled the installation of additional large compressors for gas transmission; and increases in new wells—more than twofold between 1973 and 1978 — required numerous smaller compressors for gas gath ering, as did the prohibition of flaring of waste gas (which now must be stored in tanks). Also, steep in creases in capital expenditures of the coal mining indus try— 162 percent between 1958 and 1972 (after adjustment for price changes), and 169 percent between 1973 and 1977—indicate expansion in this industry’s demand for compressors. Expansion of petroleum pipeline capacity also raised the demand for pumps, particularly of the high-horse power centrifugal kind, and for stationary compressors. While the network of petroleum pipelines operated by petroleum pipeline companies increased 16 percent be tween 1960 and 1970, and contracted somewhat thereaf ter, total oil transported rose 81 percent during the 1960’s, and 48 percent in the 1970’s.8At the same time, the average diameter of pipes was enlarged by onethird, roughly doubling capacity.9 This required signifi cant increases in the size and capacity of pumping equipment and compressors. Expanding electrical generating capacity spurred the output growth especially of centrifugal pumps. These are used as boiler-feed pumps, as well as in many other Table 1. Productivity and reiated indexes for pump and compressor manufacturing, 1958-80 [1977 = 100] Output per employee hour Output Employee hours Employees 1958 ............... 1959 ............... 1960 ............... 64.5 68.8 66.6 41.1 43.4 44.6 63.7 63.1 67.0 63.1 62.6 66.1 1961............... 1962 ............... 1963 ............... 1964 ............... 1965 ............... 69.2 73.6 78.1 79.4 80.9 43.9 48.6 51.7 59.0 65.2 63.4 66.0 66.2 74.3 80.6 62.6 64.9 64.6 71.5 77.9 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... 81.1 82.5 82.3 86.3 85.8 70.5 70.1 68.3 74.0 74.8 86.9 85.0 83.0 85.7 87.2 82.9 82.4 80.3 83.3 85.8 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... 87.1 91.1 97.8 96.7 91.3 69.4 76.2 87.7 94.0 87.0 79.7 83.6 89.7 97.2 95.3 79.4 82.5 88.6 97.3 96.0 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... 96.8 100.0 102.6 102.5 99.8 91.4 100.0 107.1 114.5 112.9 94.4 100.0 104.4 111.7 113.1 94.3 100.0 105.1 112.7 113.9 Average annual rates of change (in percent): 1958-80 ......... 1975-80 ......... 2.1 1.9 4.7 6.0 2.6 4.1 2.7 4.2 Year operations requiring the circulation and condensation of steam and water. While the total number of electrical generating stations did not advance very much over the review period, the proportion of stations generating 500,000 kilowatts or more rose from under 3 percent in 1960 to 12 percent in 1979. Nuclear and gas-turbine driven, power-generating plants likewise increased. The rise in the number of larger electric generating plants spelled a shift to larger, more powerful pumps.10 Construction accounts for another 18 percent of pump and compressor output. Centrifugal and trash pumps (which accommodate up to 25 percent of small solids in the water being pumped) are used in the clear ing and preparing of construction sites.11 Portable com pressors are indispensable in the many pneumatical operations at construction sites. Between 1960 and 1973, the volume of total construction put in place rose at an average annual rate of 2.9 percent; thereafter it declined at a rate of 1.5 percent. However, some con struction sectors with high demand for pumps continued to expand— for example, sewage system construction (spurred by more stringent environmental regulations). Employmemt sum ! hours Employment in the pump and compressor manufac turing industry currently numbers approximately 91,000 persons. It rose 81 percent between 1958 and 1980, or at an average annual rate of 2.7 percent (compared with 1.1 percent for all manufacturing). 106 2.9 percent a year (versus 2.7 percent). Nonproduction workers account for a comparatively high proportion of the industry’s employment—41 percent in 1980, as against 30 percent for all manufacturing. The propor tion did not change significantly over the review period. One of the reasons for the high proportion of nonproduction workers resides in the larger share accounted for by mechanical engineers in the industry groups’ occupational makeup (the data are, again, for the general industrial machinery group). Such engineers represented 6 percent of all white-collar workers in the group in 1980— three times the comparable manufac turing ratio. Engineering and science technicians, among them drafters, made up 11 percent of white-col lar workers in the group, as against 8 percent for manu facturing. The group also employed a somewhat higher proportion of clerical and secretarial workers (42 versus 40 percent). The share of blue-collar nonproduction workers, such as truckdrivers and service employees, was generally lower than for manufacturing. The long-term trend in employee hours in the indus try did not differ significantly from the long-term trend in employment. They rose at a rate of 2.6 percent a year over the period, compared with 1.1 percent for manufacturing as a whole. Production worker employment rose somewhat faster over the 1958-80 period than production workers’ hours (2.7 percent a year versus 2.4 percent). Year-toyear changes ranged from an increase of 12 percent in 1974 to a decline of 10 percent for production worker employment; the range was wider still for hours. Over time exceeded the manufacturing durables average in 17 of the 22 years examined here.12 Comparatively high overtime hours were probably related to hiring and sep aration policies which, judging by the pertinent labor turnover data, have been such as to ensure retention of a relatively skilled work force. Labor turnover in the in dustry ran less than three-fifths of the manufacturing average for the period.13 High overtime and low turn over rates were probably also related to the skill com position of the industry’s work force. Data on the skill composition of employees in pump and compressor manufacturing are not directly avail able. Such data have been compiled by the BLS only for the general industrial machinery group (sic 356), of which pumps and compressors represent 29 percent by employment. Craft and related workers accounted for 30 percent of the production workers employed by es tablishments in this group in 1980, compared with 26 percent for total manufacturing. Metalworking craftworkers represented 12 percent of all production work ers in the group, compared with 5 percent for manufac turing; and machinists 3 percent, compared with 1 percent. Operatives accounted for slightly more than three-fifths of all production workers in the general in dustrial machinery group, the same as in manufacturing as a whole. But metalworking operatives in industrial machinery, constituting one-third of production work ers, had three times the share of their counterparts in all manufacturing. Laborers, with 6 percent of produc tion workers in the group, had little more than half their share for all manufacturing. Wage differentials also suggest a somewhat higher skill composition for production workers in pump and compressor establishments than in all manufacturing. In 1980, hourly earnings of the former ran 10 percent above the manufacturing average, and 3 percent above the manufacturing durables average. These ratios re mained substantially unchanged during 1958-80. (Hour ly earnings were about the same for production workers in the industry and in the general industrial machinery group of which the industry is part.) Employment of nonproduction workers by pump and compressor manufacturing establishments rose at a slightly faster rate than that of production workers— Technological changes Small lot production is the rule in pump and com pressor establishments. Pumps and compressors are often large machines, manufactured to customer specifi cation. While many of these machines are composed of standard parts, the economies associated with mass pro duction are generally not available in producing pumps and compressors. The production process must con stantly be adapted so as to cope with the many design, casting, and machining requirements that arise. Such adaptation was facilitated by the advent of numerically controlled machine tools in the 1960’s, and the intro duction of computer-aided design into engineering prac tice.14 Numerical controls and computer-aided design have been important sources of labor productivity ad vances in the industry. The impact of these technologi cal changes will be outlined, following a brief survey of the kinds and age of the metalworking machinery used in manufacturing pumps and compressors. According to the 12th American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equipment for 1976-78 (latest avail able), about one-third of all metal cutting and metal forming machine tools in the pump and compressor manufacturing industry were less than 10 years old; 70 percent were less than 20 years old. Comparable data for earlier years are available only for the general indus trial machinery group (sic 356). For general industrial machinery, no distinct trend in the age composition of metalworking machinery is observable. Thus, in 1958, 34 percent of such machinery installed in the plants of this group was less than 10 years old, 74 percent was less than 20 years. In 1968, as well as in 1978, the com parable figures read 33 and 72 percent.15 Despite the absence of a trend toward a more mod107 ern stock of metalworking equipment in terms of age, output capability per machine tool unit improved con siderably. According to the American Machinist's 10th Inventory of Metalworking Equipment (1968), “For the last 5 years, the number of machine tools has increased by 4.5 percent, while the value of production, as meas ured in constant dollars by the American Machinist pro duction index, has gone up by 39 percent.” In the text accompanying its 12th Inventory (1976-78), the Ameri can Machinist again confirmed this trend. It noted that while the total machine tool “population” had declined by about one-tenth between 1968 and 1978, the produc tion index had risen 40 percent.16 Table 2. Productivity and related indexes for pumps and pumping equipment manufacturing, 1S72-80 [1977 = 100] Year 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... ...................... Average annual rates of change (in percent): 1972-80 ................. Output per employee hour Output Employee hours Employees 90.8 94.1 93.6 89.9 92.7 100.0 101.1 100.7 97.2 81.0 91.7 91.9 90.4 92.9 100.0 106.1 111.6 112.5 89.2 97.4 98.2 100.6 100.2 100.0 104.9 110.8 115.8 88.1 94.8 98.3 101.4 99.7 100.0 106.2 113.0 117.6 1.2 3.9 2.6 3.1 MacMmmg time eet The increase in the output capacity of machine tools has undoubtedly contributed to gains in the labor pro ductivity of pump and compressor manufacturing. For example, machining time for pump casings, which often are of great weight and size, has in the leading plants been drastically reduced by specially designed milling machines. These milling machines also require less setup time, and a smaller number of setups than formerly. In one case, machining time for large centrifugal pump casings, weighing up to 18,000 pounds, was reduced from 48 to 17 employee hours; in other words, where three 16-hour shifts, involving two operators, were re quired earlier, only one operator working 17 hours is needed now.17However, electric energy requirements are considerably greater.18 Reductions in machining time are frequently achieved by combining in one large metalworking operation sev eral previously separate ones. An example is the simul taneous milling, radial drilling, and facing (smoothing) of different parts of the same workpiece. Sequential op erations on a given workpiece are speeded up by means of automatic tool changers, commanded by taped in structions, causing different kinds of tools (or different configurations of the same kind of tool) to be advanced, retracted, and changed, as programmed. (Such appara tus may be bypassed by manual controls, when neces sary in the operator’s judgment.)19 Reductions in setup time have also been made possible for many single-purpose machines, for example, grinders. Pump shafts must in some cases be tapered, and this has usually required several setups depending upon the length and desired fit of the shaft. In some of the industry’s plants, separate setups for this purpose have been eliminated by grinders that adapt automati cally and will grind several fits simultaneously.20 Advances in the foundry operations of pump and compressor manufacturers have also contributed to la bor productivity gains. In the technically more ad vanced plants, molding and coremaking have been speeded up by rapid-cycle machinery, and by discarding the time-consuming sand baking process. The no-bake process uses a resin binder and a catalyst to produce the sand mold, saving energy as well as unit labor re quirements.21 Several of the same core patterns (from which pump casings and other pump and compressor parts are cast) can be cut simultaneously by means of synchronous fabricating machinery, operating on the principle of key-making apparatus. Engineering plays a key role in pump and compressor manufacturing. As noted, much of the industry’s output is manufactured to customer specifications, which of ne cessity involves engineering staff. Additionally, the ad vent of numerically controlled machine tools, and of computer numerical controls, has centered more pro duction responsibilities in engineering departments, away from the shop floor. The growth of engineering staff has intensified concern with promoting its ef ficiency. Engineering efficiency has been raised in the more advanced establishments of the industry by apply ing certain computer technologies; designing production processes which economize on engineering time; and standardizing common parts. Efforts have also been made to bypass engineering where feasible.22 Computer graphics have simplified drafting by allowing corrections to be made to the draft without manually redrawing it. Detailed drawings can be made within minutes, where before it took hours. Comput erized data banks permit access to all drawings on file. Computer graphics has permitted the elimination of 7 to 8 drafter jobs in one of the establishments visited by BLS staff. The computer-aided design can be program med directly upon tape, and fed to the machine tool. This represents a considerable advance for numerical controls, inasmuch as programs previously had to be punched, or prepunched programs had to be purchased. With design and production closely linked, owing to the computer and numerical controls, engineers con ceive of computer-aided design and computer-assisted manufacturing as integral operations. Calculation of for mulae, design of the product, and production are 108 viewed and operated as a single process. Uniformity of product dimension and quality are ensured. Changes in the detail of design are quickly and inexpensively incor porated. Engineering time saved by computer-aided de sign and computer-assisted manufacturing has been estimated at two-thirds of conventional engineering pro cedures.23 As noted, replacement of parts and attachments ac counts for a sizable proportion of the output of pump and compressor manufacturing. Computer-aided design and computer-assisted manufacturing helps ensure that replacement parts are dimensionally accurate, while economizing on engineering time. Dimensional confor mance is further ensured by certain process innovations. Thus, cores or molds for impellers and other pump and compressor components are now frequently ceramic in stead of wood. Capital expenditures Plant and equipment outlays by pump and compres sor manufacturers rose at an average annual rate of 8.1 percent between 1958 and 1980—compared with 4.9 percent per year for all manufacturing. (The expenditure data underlying these rates have been adjusted for price changes.24) The industry’s capital spending rose at a particularly high rate during the 1960’s, nearly tripling between 1958 and 1969. For a few years thereafter, such spending receded from the 1969 level, but it resumed its rise in 1972, and doubled between 1972 and 1980. Comparable figures for all manufacturing are considera bly more modest, as the tabulation shows (average an nual rates in percent): 1958-80 ........... 1958-69 . . . . 1969-80 ___ 1969-72 . . ' 1972-80 . . Pumps and compressors 8.1 12.2 6.9 -10.2 7.6 Manufacturing 4.9 8.2 4.6 -3.0 5.4 [1977 = 100] Output per employe® hour Output Employee hours Employees ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... 92.1 108.8 103.0 96.7 108.4 100.0 105.5 106.0 105.7 66.7 79.8 98.2 80.5 88.4 100.0 109.1 120.3 113.7 72.4 74.7 95.3 85.0 83.1 100.0 103.4 113.5 107.6 71.6 76.6 95.3 85.3 83.8 100.0 102.8 112.2 106.6 Average annual rates of change (in percent): 1972-80 ......... 1.1 6.5 5.4 5.2 Year 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 with 100 workers or more represented less than onequarter of the total number of establishments in the in dustry but well over four-fifths of total employment and value of shipments. Concentration was high. The industry’s four largest companies employed more than half of its workers in 1977, and accounted for half of its value of shipments. For manufacturing as a whole, the comparable ratios were 6 and 7 percent. Even so, the establishments are mostly small, employing fewer than 100 persons. The smaller plants accounted for 79 percent (pumps) and 70 percent (com pressors) of all industry establishments in 1977. At the same time, however, they recorded only 14 and 9 per cent of total industry employment. These relationships had not changed much from earlier phases of the review period. Outlook Continued advances in the labor productivity of pump and compressor manufacturing are likely over the longer term. The diffusion of numerically controlled ma chine tools and computer-aided design within the indus try’s establishments, as well as among them, has still some way to go. The age distribution of metalworking machinery should continue to favor higher-capacity, modernized equipment. Organizational changes result ing from a widening scope of computer applications— for example, more centralized decisionmaking in refer ence to machining processes—will probably also im prove productivity.26 So far, robots appear not to have been introduced widely. Even in the more advanced shops, they are used chiefly for paint spraying and other marginal opera tions. Industry observers, however, expect that robots, as their costs decline, will handle workpieces more and more during the noncutting portion of the work cycle.27 Such a development is also bound to raise labor pro ductivity. Strasftmr® of the industry In 1977, pumps and pumping equipment were manufactured in 613 establishments, air and gas com pressors in 175. The former had increased 10 percent since 1972, the latter had more than doubled. In the preceding 9 years, no change in the number of estab lishments making pumps and compressors had oc curred. The number of companies in the industry owning these establishments barely changed during the 1970’s.25 Pumps and compressors are manufactured mostly in larger plants. Five percent of all establishments in the industry employed 45 percent of its workers in 1977, and accounted for about the same proportion of the to tal value of shipments. More generally, establishments Table 3. Productivity and reiated indexes for air and gas compressor manufacturing, 1S72-80 m The nearer-term outlook is somewhat clouded, how ever. The industry’s output is likely to suffer from weakened demand from major users of pumps and com pressors. When output slackens, a slowed rate of pro ductivity advance, even declines in the rate, are more probable. A source of weakened demand is the stagna tion in housing starts, which tends to diminish the need for pumps and compressors used in construction, as well as for such public works as water and sewage, which often require pumps and related equipment on a large scale. Another source of declining needs for (hence output of) pumps and compressors are reductions in projected increases in oilfield exploration and develop ment. (These reductions have been linked to smallerthan-expected energy demand increases, and lessened price pressures.)28 At the same time, the widespread concern with cut ting energy costs may bolster the demand (and output) of more energy-efficient pumps and compressors. For example, variable displacement pumps may to some ex tent replace fixed displacement pumps. The latter rejects excess flows by means of a relief valve, dumping them back into a reservoir. This wastes pump energy, which a variable displacement pump can avert.29 Piston pumps, furthermore, are thought by industry observers to be also favored over fixed displacement pumps, as high- pressure hydraulics is more widely adopted in industry and transportation (especially in aircraft and mobile equipment). High-pressure hydraulics permits the use of lighter pipes, pumps, and actuators.30 Industry observers believe that pumps and equipment of larger size will continue to be installed in such uses as steampower generation, pipelines, and petroleum re fining. The shift from gasoline to heavy fuel refining31 requires heavier rotary rather than lighter centrifugal pumps. Slurry pipelines— which move water-suspended solids such as coal and wood chips—are believed to gain wider acceptance, because they offer important economies in transportation. The BLS has projected a somewhat faster rise in the number of nonproduction workers than production workers for the general industrial machinery group.32 In 1990, professional and technical workers will make up 12.4 percent of all of the group’s employees, according to the projections, compared with 11.4 percent in 1980; and the share of clerical and related workers will rise slightly. The proportion of craftworkers will remain unchanged, and that of operatives will edge downward. It seems reasonable to assume that changes in occupa tional pattern projected for the general industrial ma chinery group will, by and large, be repeated by pump and compressor manufacturing. 1The pump and compressor manufacturing industry consists of two segments, pumps and pumping equipment, designated as SIC 3561 of the Standard Industrial Classification Manual 1972 of the Office of Management and Budget; and air and gas compressors, SIC 3563. SIC 3561 consists of establishments primarily engaged in manufactur ing pumps and pumping equipment for general industrial use. Meas uring and dispensing pumps for gasoline stations are not included, nor are pumps installed in automobiles. SIC 3563 consists of estab lishments primarily engaged in manufacturing air and gas compres sors for general industrial use. Refrigeration compressor units are not included. Prior to 1972, pumps and compressors were classified to gether in SIC 3561. Average annual rates of change are based on the linear least squares of the logarithm of the index numbers. Extensions of the in dexes will appear in the annual BLS Bulletin, Productivity Measures for Selected Industries. 2William C. Krutzsch, “Introduction and Classification of Pumps,” in Igor I. Karassik and others, Pump Handbook (New York, McGraw-Hill, 1973), p. 1 ff. 3John P. Rollins, ed., Compressed Air and Gas Handbook (New York, Compressed Air and Gas Institute, 1973), p. 1. The range of compressed air uses are discussed on pp. 1-44. 4 U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, The Detailed Input-Output Structure o f the U S. Economy: 1972 (Washington, D.C., Government Printing Office, 1979). 5John R. Birk and James H. Peacock, “Chemical Industry,” Pump Handbook, p. 10-74 ff. Also, conversation with industry observer. 6 E. R. Pritchett, “Steel Mills,” Pump Handbook, p. 10-159; and telephone conversation with author. ty Measures for Selected Industries, 1954-80 (Washington, D.C., Gov ernment Printing Office, 1982), table 179. 9 Mary Vickery, “Petroleum Pipeline Transportation,” U.S. Depart ment of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Technological Change and its Labor Impact in Five Energy Industries, BLS Bulletin 2005 (Wash ington, D.C., Government Printing Office, 1979), pp. 39 and 42. 10Telephone conversation with Krutzsch, an author of Pump Hand book. " Benjes, H.H., “Sewage,” Pump Handbook, telephone conversation with author. 10-2. Also, 12Overtime in pump and compressor manufacturing compared with overtime for all of manufacturing durables (all manufacturing = 100) as follows: Pumps and compressors 1958 ........... 1959 ........... 1960 ........... 1 9 6 1 ........... 1962 ........... 1963 ........... 1964 ........... 1965 ........... 1966 ........... 1967 ........... 1968 ........... 1969 ........... 1970 ........... 1 9 7 1 ........... 1972 ........... 1973 ........... 7Elvitsky, Pump Handbook. 8U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Productivi- p. 110 ____ ____ ____ ____ ____ ____ ____ ........ .. .. ____ .. . . .. . . ____ ____ . . . . ____ 63 111 104 83 96 90 103 113 123 114 103 103 110 93 103 105 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 .. .. . . .. .. . . .. . . . . . . . Pumps Compressors 126 119 131 114 100 103 100 112 115 103 116 113 114 161 15 Labor turnover in pump and compressor manufacturing com versity of Michigan, 1977). See also John Duke and Horst Brand, “Cyclical Behavior of Productivity in the Machine Tool Industry,” pared with manufacturing (all manufacturing = 100) as follows (data Monthly Labor Review, November 1981, pp. 27-34. from 1972 forward for pumps and pumping equipment only; data for air and gas compressors are not available): 17William H. Parker, “Cutting time out of pump machining,” American Machinist, January 1979, pp. 112-13. Accessions Separations 18 “The Machine Tools that are Building America,” Iron Age, Aug. 1958 ........................................ 52 66 30, 1976, p. 163. According to the report, electric horsepower require 1959 ........................................ 69 56 ments for lathes rose from 150 in the 1950’s to 400 to 600 in the 1960 ........................................ 55 65 1970’s. Many other examples are also cited in the article. 1961 ........................................ 54 58 19Observation of industry operations. See also Iron Age, cited 1962 ........................................ 56 51 above. 1963 ........................................ 56 56 20 Observation of industry operations. 1964 ........................................ 63 46 21 Observation of industry operations. See also Richard W. Lyon, 1965 ........................................ 60 58 “Foundries,” in U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statis 1966 ........................................ 68 63 tics, Technology and Labor in Four Industries, Bulletin 2104 (Washing 1967 . . . . ............................. 57 59 ton, D.C., Government Printing Office, January 1982), p. 12. 1968 ........................................ 57 57 1969 ........................................ 68 65 22 Industry sources, and observation of industry operations. See also 1970 ........................................ 60 76 A. Harvey Belitsky, “Major technology changes in metalworking ma 1971 ........................................ 54 56 chinery,” Technology and Labor in Four Industries, pp. 20-33. 23 Industry source. 60 49 1972 ........................................ 24 Adjustment for price changes was made by using the implicit de 1973 ............................. 67 55 flator for nonresidential investment in structures and producers’ 71 67 1974 ........................................ durable equipment. See Economic Report o f the President, February 1975 ........................................ 51 68 1982, p. 236. 1976 ........................................ 59 53 25 U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, General 1977 ........................................ 63 55 Report on Industrial Organization, 1977 Enterprise Statistics (Washing 1978 ........................................ 51 49 ton, D.C., Government Printing Office, 1981). 1979 ........................................ 53 54 1980 ........................................ 54 58 26A. Harvey Belitsky, “Major technology changes,” especially pp. 24—25. 14See Comptroller General of the United States, Manufacturing 27 See American Machinist, June 1980, p. 147 fF. Technology— A Changing Challenge to Improved Productivity, Report 28 “Biggest U.S. Oil Concerns Likely to React to Glut by Cutting to the Congress, Washington, June 3, 1976, especially p. 37 ff. 1982 Capital Budgets,” The Wall Street Journal, Apr. 7, 1982, p. 7. 15 The Eighth American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equip 29 “Curbing the Energy Appetite of Hydraulic Systems,” Machine ment— 1958, New York, McGraw-Hill. Reprinted from the American Design, June 26, 1980, p. 95. Machinist, Nov. 17, 1958; The Tenth American Machinist Inventory of 30 “Modem Hydraulic Systems: the Pressure Mounts,” Machine De Metalworking Equipment— 1968, New York, McGraw-Hill, 1968. The sign, Jan. 24, 1980, p. 81 ff. data cited for pump and compressor manufacturing from the 12th In 31 Rose Zeisel and Michael D. Dymmel, “Petroleum refining,” Tech ventory are based on unpublished printouts. nological Change and Its Impact in Five Energy Industries, p. 26. 16American Machinist, December 1978, p. 135. The reduction in 32 See the articles on the Bureau’s projections in Monthly Labor machining time is confirmed in Donald N. Smith and Larry Evans, Review, August 1981, pp. 9-42. Management Standards for Computers and Numerical Controls (Uni 11J Output per unit of labor input in the retail food store industry Productivity, as measured by output per hour o f all persons, increased 2A percent annually during 1958-75, because o f industry structural changes and some technological improvements Jo h n l . C a r e y and Ph y l l is F l o h r O t t o Output per hour of all persons in the retail food in dustry increased at an average annual rate of 2.4 percent from 1958 to 1975, compared with a gain of 2.3 percent for the nonfarm business sector.1 This growth reflect increases of 2.4 percent in output and 0.1 percent in hours. Growth in output per hour of all persons has been influenced by a trend to fewer and larger stores serving a growing population, a correspond ing decline in the number of small stores, as well as some changes in technology and store operations designed to increase efficiency. The decline in the number of small stores has led to decreases in the number of partners, proprietors, and unpaid family workers in the industry, which has counteracted the increase in the number of paid employees. Hours of paid employees grew at an average rate of 1.9 per cent from 1958 to 1975, offsetting the decline of 4.5 percent per year in the hours of the self-employed and unpaid family workers. There are widely disparate growth rates in the two components of the retail food store industry. From 1958 to 1975, the output of grocery stores* John L. Carey and Phyllis Flohr Otto are economists in the Division of Industry Productivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Robert S. Robinowitz, an economist formerly with the Division, and Mark Segal, a student, assisted with the research for the article. This study was fi nanced in part by the National Center for Productivity and Quality of Working Life. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, January 1977. 112 (which comprises the largest portion of the industry and includes supermarkets as well as small grocery stores) increased at an average rate of 2.8 percent each year. Specialty food stores (such as bakeries and meat markets) averaged only 0.7 percent each year. The number of specialty stores continued to decline as they lost business to supermarkets, which offer similar products with the convenience of onestop shopping. On the other hand, supermarkets have lost some business to the convenience food stores. Although many items are higher priced, these stores are conveniently located and provide fast service. Efficiency in the retail food industry has been aided by improvements in displaying merchandise and electronic innovations, such as computerized scales and cash registers. Also contributing to effi ciency is the trend toward prepackaging merchan dise at the distributor, cutting and packaging poul try at a centralized location, and price marking at the warehouse. Trends in output per hour During 1958-72, output per hour showed in creases, ranging from 1.2 to 5.5 percent, every year except 1969, when a decline occurred. (See table 1.) During 1958-72, the average annual rate of increase was 3.0 percent. (In the nonfarm business sector the rate for the same period was 2.6 percent.) However, as shown in the following tabulation, the 1973-74 price levels, increased about 10 percent from 1958-71, though it has dropped each year since then.3 Because most products can be packaged in differ ent sizes, packaging practices by the m anufacturer have an effect on the utilization of labor in retail food stores. For example, economy size packages result in a larger volume being sold in a single transaction. In a similar fashion, disposable cans and bottles have largely superseded deposit bottles and eliminated much handling time. However, the growing concern with environmental and conserva tion factors may reverse this trend. In 1973 and 1974, as the economy moved into a recession, coupled with large increases in food prices, output per hour fell in retail food stores— 5.1 percent in 1973, and an additional 2.1 percent in 1974. O utput fell 3.3 and 0.5 percent, respec tively; despite this drop, hours rose in both years, 1.8 percent in 1973, and 1.6 percent in 1974. Food prices, as measured by the Consumer Price Index for food at home, soared 16 percent and 15 percent in 1973 and 1974, higher than increases in per cap ita disposable income (12 and 8 percent). Am ong the reasons for the increase in hours (despite the drop in output) was the continued industry trend tow ard Sunday openings, the longer hours of opera tion during the week, and the growth of serviceoriented operations in supermarkets. As the economy began to improve in 1975, out put per hour in the retail food store industry re corded a gain of 2.7 percent— output grew 0.8 per cent and hours declined 1.9 percent, as hours of employees fell slightly and the hours of partners, proprietors, and unpaid family workers continued their historic movement downward. Per capita dis posable income rose 9 percent in 1975 as com pared with the slightly lower gain of 8 percent in food prices. Employment and hours The total num ber of persons working in retail food stores increased 21 percent from 1958-75, while total hours increased less than 1 percent. This disparity can be attributed directly to the growth of part-tim e help, along with the decline in the num ber of partners, proprietors, and unpaid family workers in the retail food industry. The average weekly hours for nonsupervisory workers fell from 36.3 in 1958 to 32.3 in 1975, even though there was a general trend to longer store hours and Sunday sales. In June 1966, part-tim e help accounted for over 40 percent of the work force in retail food.4 Today, one survey shows that p art-tim e help ac counts for over 50 percent of the work force in superm arkets.5 recession slowed the growth to an average annual rate of 2.4 percent for 1958-75: O utput p e r hour o f a ll persons 1 9 5 8 -7 5 ................ 1 9 5 8 -7 2 ................ 2.4 3.0 O utput H ours o f a ll persons 2.4 2.8 0.1 - .2 In the overall economy, the period 1958-72 was m arked by increasing per capita income, relatively stable prices (the Consumer Price Index rose at an average annual rate of 2.7 percent), and increasing per capita food consumption. Retail food store out put increased every year. From 1958-72, people continued to switch from small food stores to su perm arkets and the average superm arket became larger, as firms closed their small, inefficient opera tions. The num ber of retail food stores fell 26 per cent from 1958 to 1972. Grocery stores with sales greater than $500,000 a year increased their share of total retail food store sales from 51 percent in 1958 to 70 percent in 1972.2 Supermarkets accounted for alm ost 76 percent of all grocery store sales and about 70 percent of all retail food store sales in 1972. Today, nearly 9,000 items are sold in superm arkets— a 50-percent in crease since 1960. This vast num ber of items, along with the procedures that are necessary to order, stock, and m arket them have acted to limit the gains in output per hour. However, this has been offset to some extent by an upward trend in the size of the average custom er transaction. A lthough pre cise figures are not available, estimates indicate that the average superm arket sale, adjusted for changing T a b le 1. O u t p u t p e r h o u r o f a ll p e r s o n s a n d r e la te d d a ta , re ta il f o o d s to r e s , 1 9 5 8 -7 5 [1 9 6 7 = 1 0 0 ] Y es Output perhour of all persons Output Hoursof all persons 1 9 5 8 .................................................................... 1 9 5 9 .................................................................... 1 9 6 0 .................................................................... 75.4 78.4 80.9 78.4 81.9 84.1 104.0 104.4 103.9 196 1 .................................................................... 1 9 6 2 .................................................................... 1 9 6 3 .................................................................... 1 9 6 4 .................................................................... 1 9 6 5 .................................................................... 84.0 85.3 89.4 91.4 93.8 86.1 88.0 88.7 93.0 96.4 102.5 103.2 99.2 101.8 102.8 196 6 .................................................................... 196 7 .................................................................... 196 8 .................................................................... 196 9 .................................................................... 1 9 7 0 .................................................................... 96.3 100.0 105.1 104.8 110.5 98.0 100.0 104.6 105.6 111.7 101.8 100.0 99.5 100.8 101.1 197 1 .................................................................... 197 2 .................................................................... 19 7 3 .................................................................... 1974P.................................................................. 1975P.................................................................. 111.9 113.3 107.5 105.2 108.1 114.1 116.8 112.9 112.3 113.2 102.0 103.1 105.0 106.7 104.7 p= preliminary. 113 The 21-percent increase in the num ber of persons engaged in retail food sales consists of a 54—percent increase in the num ber of paid employees (nearly 2.0 million in 1975) offset by a 52-percent decrease in the number of partners, proprietors, and unpaid family workers (272,000 in 1975). Partners, propri etors, and unpaid family workers now account for only about 12 percent of the total number, as com pared with 31 percent in 1958. Some of the decrease in the num ber of partners and proprietors may be due to changes in business organization. (For exam ple, a num ber of firms may have incorporated and the partners or proprietors may have become paid employees, but there are no specific data on the change.) It is believed, however, that most of the decline was due to the decrease in the num ber of single-store firms— a 34-percent decline from 1958 to 1972. Retaining experienced personnel is a m ajor prob lem confronted by retail food stores. Labor turn over is extremely high. In 1968, the overall separa tion rate for superm arkets was over 60 per 100 employees.6 (In comparison, the separation rate for the m anufacturing sector is around 4 to 5 per 100 employees.) In 1971, the highest turnover among full-tim e superm arket employees was in cashiers (14 separations per 100) and m eatcutters (10 sepa rations per 100). Turnover in store m anagers was negligible.7 The high turnover rate among store em ployees is one of the factors hindering the gain in output per hour in this industry, as new employees m ust be trained and, therefore, are not as produc tive during the training period as more experienced persons. One factor that might be contributing to the high turnover is the low hourly earnings in retail food. In 1975, wages in retail food stores were 13 percent below the hourly average for the total private nonagricultural sector, and 18 percent lower than the m anufacturing average. all retail food stores with employment was 10 in 1972. More than 30 percent of the retail food stores are operated entirely by proprietors or partners and, therefore, have no paid employees. Most superm arkets are in suburban locations— frequently in shopping centers. Eighty percent of the superm arkets opened in 1971 were located in shopping centers, com pared with 47 percent in 1958. Developers of shopping centers are usually willing to lease sites only to firms with high finan cial ratings, making it difficult for small grocery stores to lease space.8 To generate traffic and increase sales within the store, many superm arkets have installed large spe cialty food and nonfood departm ents. Bakeries, del icatessens, pharmacies, and liquor departm ents are common. Although longer hours and Sunday sales are the most visible changes, services, such as check cashing, money orders, film processing, and cater ing services are now provided by many superm ar kets. Consumers choose to shop in superm arkets rather than small, proprietor-run stores for many reasons. Small stores frequently cannot compete with large stores on price and variety of selection because their low sales volume and small space limit volume discounts. In addition, many chains9 own some of their own production facilities, or carry private label goods which usually are offered at a lower price than widely advertised, national brand name goods. Some independent stores are able to overcome price problems by joining or forming a wholesale affiliation group (voluntary or cooperative chain), which can obtain volume dis counts for all the member stores. Frequently, they also carry some types of private label goods. Voluntary chains lack in-store data about trading areas and customer shopping habits, but have more flexibility with respect to store locations than cor porate chains. Corporate chains operate in a consis tent m anner and the use of experimental tests can be conducted in a controlled environm ent.10 The small retailer who does not belong to a chain generally pays higher prices for merchandise; there fore, in order to compete, the retailer m ust be very efficient or provide a service not readily available in a supermarket. A significant num ber of speciality stores and small grocery stores survive by locating in areas which are not profitable for large retailers (such as inner city, high-density areas, and large apartm ent buildings) because some custom ers are willing to pay extra for service or credit. A new trend in food retailing is the grow th of small (2,000-4,000 sq. ft.) convenience food stores. These stores, located prim arily near residential a r C hanges in industry structure Retail food distribution has been dom inated for quite some time by superm arkets. Supermarkets came into existence around 1930 and were well es tablished by the beginning of W orld W ar II. G row th was slowed during the war but increased rapidly during the postw ar years. Supermarkets combine the functions of separate establishments (or specialty stores) which, for the m ost part, are small and independently owned. Small specialty stores and grocery stores account for a large portion of employment, about 30 percent in 1972. While a superm arket usually employs 25 to 75 people, the average num ber of paid employees in 114 Also affecting the utilization of labor, are trends tow ard prepackaged produce, precut and packaged poultry, and some increase in centralized cutting and packaging of fresh meat. These trends vary greatly, however, because consumer acceptance has not been uniform. For example, although much m ore produce is w rapped by distributors and grow ers than in the past, m ost retailers continue to dis play, package, and weigh more than half of their produce within individual stores. On the other hand, precut and prepackaged poultry has gained wide consumer acceptance; in fact, much of the poultry now sold in retail food stores is cut, pack aged, and weighed at poultry processing plants.13 A t the present time, most meat is cut and pack aged at the retail store, after it has been broken into primal and subprim al cuts at a centralized location. Only about 3 percent of the firms operating retail m arkets have centralized the cutting and packaging of final cuts. Frozen meat, which can be cut, pack aged and shipped by the m eatpacking plant, has not gained sizable consumer acceptance.14 O ther changes in technology include the use of conveyor belts in the warehouse and overhead “rail way” systems for unloading and transporting sides of beef. Central warehouses are used m ore effi ciently now because com puters are used for inven tory control and space m anagement as well as for forecasting sales. Detrim ental to the growth ?n output per hour of all persons over the period studied was the time spent by employees issuing stam ps and games to customers. Although this trend has been replaced by the use of coupons and foods stam ps by shop pers, the effect remains the same— increased check out time. New shopper aids, such as unit pricing, also can slow growth in output per hour during pe riods of rapid price changes because of the addi tional num ber of labels that have to be changed. eas, provide the consumer with ease of access, quick selection, and virtually immediate checkout. Items requiring extensive labor time, such as fresh meat and most fresh produce, are not carried. The selec tion is much smaller than in a supermarket; in fact, four products (tobacco, beer and wine, soft drinks, and dairy products) make up more than one-half of the sales of one convenience store chain.11 Convenience stores grew rapidly during the late sixties. Their net profits before taxes were 4.8 per cent of retail sales in 1974— double that of indepen dent superm arkets.12 These stores are supplied largely by outside wholesalers and distributors rather than by their own warehouses. Changes in technology and store operations Technological developments, including changes in distribution practices, have been a source of im provem ent in output per hour in this industry. The technological changes that occurred during 1958-75 were small improvements, rather than in novations that greatly altered store operations. Am ong such improvements were refrigeration sys tems with fast defrost, self-defrosting freezers, spe cial surface floors in the meat departm ent that help to reduce cleanup time, and faster m eat sheers and grinders. O ther improvements included meat wrap ping machines, shrink and heat pressure wrapping film, and scales that autom atically print a weight and price tag. Improvem ents have also been m ade in display techniques. Produce, for example, is now kept in refrigerated display cases, eliminating the need to remove the perishable produce to the back room each night. Other changes include standup refriger ato r cases with doors that face the custom er and backs that open into a refrigerated storeroom. (A variation is the roller cart which can be placed in a refrigerator case direct from delivery.) O ther tech niques include the use of cardboard display cases provided by m anufacturers and “dum p” displays where goods are simply put in wire baskets in no particular order. M ost superm arkets are arranged so that the typi cal custom er will have to walk though m ost of the store to buy groceries. (Exposing the custom er to the full array of products encourages larger transac tions.) Certain m anufacturing and distribution tech niques have also aided growth in output per hour of all persons within the retail food store. The use of shrink film (a form of clear plastic wrap) rather than complete cardboard cartons has decreased the time spent opening boxes and disposing of waste cardboard. Shrink film also allows instant identifi cation of merchandise. O utlook A growing trend in the retail food industry is the emergence of the com bination or “superstore” with a large nonfood departm ent. This departm ent may cover 40 to 50 percent of the total selling area. To tal space in these “superstores” is around 40,000-50,000 square feet, or twice the size of the average superm arket today. One trade association reported that 9 percent of all superm arkets opened in 1973 were com bination stores. Conventional stores, however, still account for over 95 percent of all superm arkets.15 The trend tow ard central, as opposed to retail, m eat cutting may grow. The prim ary advantage is the reduction in labor time at the retail level. With 115 central meat cutting, the waste problem is reduced and retailers can be more specific in their orders.16 Electronic cash registers and the uniform product code are beginning to be used in retail food stores. W ith this system, a unique, m achine-readable sym bol is placed on each product, and is translated into a price by an optical scanner. The price can be read on a screen and the data are then transm itted to a com puter which prints out a detailed receipt for the customer. In the most prevalent system, the checker runs the symbol over the optical scanner and bags at the same time, decreasing checkout time for shoppers. In addition to eliminating cashier errors, the com puter can also keep inventory autom atically and assist in reordering for the store when levels decline to a predetermined point. Labor savings can be obtained by eliminating the need to m ark prices on items, and to take inventory manually. Training time for cashiers can also be reduced significantly. The development of scales fo r weighing and simul taneously marking meat and produce with the uni form product code symbol will assist the diffusion of this technology. The main obstacle to the imme diate use of this system is the high cost of the regis ters and computers. Also, there have been some ob jections to the lack of price m arkings on individual items. Retailers may have to continue to m ark prices, thereby losing some of the labor saving ad vantages of this system. 1The study covered paid and unpaid persons (including paid em ployees, partners, proprietors, and unpaid family members) working in retail food establishments. (Data for 1974 and 1975 are preliminary.) Retail food stores are defined as those establishments primarily en gaged in selling food for home preparation and consumption (major group 54 in the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification Manual). All average annual rates of change are based on the linear least squares trend of the logarithms of the index numbers. Current indexes for this industry are published in the annual BLS bulletin, Productivity Indexes for Selected Industries. 6 Super Market Industry Speaks: 1969, pp. 25-26. 7 Super Market Industry Speaks: 1972, pp. 15-16. s See Food: From Farmer to Consumer (National Commission on Food Marketing), pp. 69-83. 4 The definition of a “chain” differs among industry sources. A chain is usually considered to be either 4 or more, or 11 or more stores under some form of common operation or control. 10 Saul B. Cohen, “Location Research Programming for Voluntary Food Chains, ” Economic Geography, January 1961, pp. 1-11. 2 The definition of supermarkets in terms of annual sales volume differs among industry sources. The amount of $500,000 is used by the Department of Agriculture and some trade publications. The Super Market Institute, however, uses a $1 million annual sales volume. Dis cussions and data pertaining to that source in this article, therefore, should be viewed with the difference in mind. 11 See “The Threat to Southland’s Growth,” Business Week, Oct. 28, 1972, pp. 60-62. 12 See “Forty-second Annual Report of Grocery Industry,” Progress ive Grocer, April 1975. 13 See The Chicken Broiler Industry: Structure, Practices, and Costs, Marketing Research Report 930 (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service), May 1971, p. 34. 3 See annual issues of The Super Market Industry Speaks (Super Mar ket Institute, Inc.). This should be interpreted with care since many factors can influence the size of a transaction—number of trips to the store per week and shifts to higher (or lower) valued merchandise, for example. 14 See “Chain Store Age 1972 Meat Study,” Chain Store Age, No vember 1972, beginning on page 55. 15 Super Market Industry Speaks: 1972, p. 10. 4 Employee Earnings and Hours in Retail Food Stores, Bulletin 1584-3, (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1968). 16 See “Central Cutting: The Only Way to G o,” Chain Store Age, November 1972, beginning on page 72, and “Central Prepackage Meat Operations Holds Line On Expenses for a Three-Store Organization,” Progressive Grocer, February 1961, beginning on page 50. 5 See The Super Market Industry Speaks: 1969 {Super Market Insti tute, Inc.) p. 25. APPENDIX: Measurement techniques and limitations Thus, those goods which require more retail labor are given more importance in the output index. Data on the quantities of goods sold usually are not available for trade industries, including retail food. Therefore, real output was estimated by removing the effects of changing price levels from the current dollar value of sales. This technique was used at various levels of aggregation for both grocery stores and for specialty food stores. Because an adjustment for changing price levels usually lowers the dollar value, such a series is usually referred to as a deflated value measure. Output measures based on deflated value have two major char Indexes of output per hour of all persons measure the change in the relationship between the output of an in dustry and the hours expended on that output. An index of output per hour is derived by dividing an index of out put by an index of industry hours. The preferred output index for retail trade industries would be obtained from data on quantities of the various goods sold by the industry, each weighted (that is, multi plied) by the employee-hours required to sell one unit of each good in some specified base period. This concept also embodies the services associated with moving the goods from the retail establishment to the consumer. 116 tions. This has shifted some of the hours in retailing from the employee to the consumer. However, data are not available to measure the impact of this change. Like wise, adjustments could not be made for changes in the quality of products sold. Such adjustments are implicit, however, to the extent that changes in quality have been accounted for in the price indexes used to deflate the cur rent dollar value of sales. In the noncommodity producing sector, there are many more conceptual problems with the definition of an industry’s “output” than in most other sectors of the economy. There are differences of opinion about many of these concepts. One problem is the definition of quality change. In the retail food industry, for example, soft drinks are now sold largely in cans and “no return” bottles, while previously they were sold in deposit bot tles. This can be treated as a factor that aids output per hour of all persons because cans and “no return” bottles eliminate much handling time in the store. Such packag ing, however, can also be considered as a change in qual ity to the consumer, and, therefore, a different product requiring an adjustment to the measure. In any case, available data did not permit adjustments to be made for this change. Other changes in store operations can also affect the utilization of labor. The shift to produce, poultry, and other products that are prepackaged by food processing industries eliminates much retail labor time. Although the available data do not allow adjustments to be made each year, the measure is adjusted periodically through the use of relative labor importance weights. This re duces the possibility for bias in the measure, but does not, of course, eliminate it entirely. The basic sources for the output series for this mea sure consist of the total sales data and sales by merchan dise line data reported by the U.S. Department of Com merce. The deflators were developed using various Consumer Price Indexes published by the Bureau of La bor Statistics. The labor importance weights were devel oped from data reported by the U.S. Department of Commerce and the U.S. Department of Agriculture. The basic sources for the all-persons-hour series con sist of data on employment and hours published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, supplemented by data re ported by the Internal Revenue Service and special tabu lations compiled for the Bureau of Labor Statistics by the Bureau of the Census. acteristics. First, shifts in sales can occur among prod ucts of different value which have the same unit labor requirements. (For example, if customers begin to pur chase more “nationally advertised” brands instead of store brands, dollar sales will increase if the “nationally advertised” brand is priced higher.) Thus, a change can occur in the output per hour index even if the labor re quired to sell the merchandise does not change. Second, the sales level, both in current and constant dollars, reflects differences in unit values for identical products sold in different types of establishments. For example, the unit values associated with a product sold in a self-service “discount” store may be lower than the unit value associated with the same product sold in a store that provides many sales clerks and delivery serv ice. The output measure, therefore, reflects changes in the level of service provided to customers insofar as dif ferences in unit values reflect the differences in service among the various types of establishments. In addition to the deflated value technique, weights relating to labor importance (that is, labor cost and em ployment) were used to combine segments of the output index into a total output measure. These procedures re sult in a final output index that is closer, conceptually, to the preferred output measure. The index of hours for the retail food industry is for all persons—that is, hours for paid employees, partners and proprietors, and unpaid family workers. As in all of the output per hour measures published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, hours and employment in retail food stores are each considered homogeneous and additive. Adequate information does not exist to separately weight the various types of labor. The indexes of output per hour relate total output to one input—labor time. The indexes do not measure the specific contribution of labor, capital, or any other single factor. Rather, they reflect the joint effect of many inter related influences such as changes in technology, capital investment, capacity utilization, store design and layout, skill and effort of the work force, managerial ability, and labor management relations. No explicit adjustments were made to the measure for retail food to take into account increases or decreases in service provided to the consumer. With the growth of supermarkets and convenience food stores, there has been a continuation of the trend to self-service opera 117 During 1958-77, annual productivity increased an average o f 2 .9 percent, as the industry responded to a strong dem and fo r soap and detergent products and was aided by improved technology P a t r i c i a S. W i l d e r Productivity in the soaps and detergents industry has increased in line with the rise in output per employee hour for the manufacturing sector since 1958.' While annual output doubled, employee hours in creased by more than one-fourth between 1958 and 1977. The average annual increase in productivity was 2.9 percent. The rise in productivity was associated with an annu al increase in output of 4.1 percent coupled with a 1.2-percent average annual increase in employee-hours. Productivity gains have resulted prim arily from sustained high levels of capital investment for new ma chinery and equipment, and improvements in produc tion and packaging operations. Output per employee hour has fluctuated during the period of this study. Since 1958, annual increases in productivity have ranged from 1.0 to 10.6 percent. De clines in productivity have occurred in 4 years, includ ing 1977. For the most recent 5-year period, 1973-77, productivity has declined at an annual rate of 0.6 per cent. (See table 1.) From 1958 to 1965, average growth in productivity was 1.9 percent; output rose 4.6 percent, and hours ad vanced 2.7 percent annually. During this period, the in dustry experienced a general expansion. The number of establishments manufacturing soaps and detergents in creased from 608 in 1958 to 704 in 1963. Patricia S. Wilder is an economist in the Division of Industry Produc tivity Studies, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, February 1980. From 1965 to 1974, productivity grew much faster, averaging 4.3 percent each year. The acceleration was in sharp contrast to the productivity movements of other industries in the economy. More than two-thirds of the industries for which productivity measures are available showed slackening productivity growth since 1966. Pro ductivity growth in the soaps and detergents industry during 1965-74 reflected average annual increases of 4.9 percent in output and 0.6 percent in employeehours. The slower growth in employee-hours was asso ciated with an overall decline in the number of estab lishments—from 704 in 1963 to 642 by 1972. In 1975, a recession year, productivity fell 7.1 percent. Output recorded its largest decline of 9.4 per cent, and employee-hours declined 2.4 percent. In 1976, productivity growth resumed with a 3.0 percent gain with both output (5.8 percent) and hours (2.8 percent) increasing over the depressed levels of the preceding year. In 1977, however, output growth slowed to 2.2 percent, while employee hours increased 2.8 percent. This resulted in a 0.6-percent decline in productivity. Output doubles Productivity gains in the soaps a '^detergents indus try have been closely linked to output expansion, which doubled between 1958 and 1977. Some significant fac tors affecting this growth are expanded use of home laundry equipment and dishwashing appliances, popula tion growth, and successful advertising and sales pro motions.2 Table 1. Productivity and related indexes for the soaps and detergents industry, 1958-77 temperatures. The household laundry equipment indus try followed the development of permanent press gar ments within a few months by the introduction of properly matched cycles in washers and dryers to han dle this new concept in clothing.5 At present, many au tomatic washers include permanent press cycles and various combinations of wash and rinse temperatures. The increase in the sales of home laundering equip ment, as well as the increase in wash and wear fabrics, favorably affected the demand for soap and detergent products. The output of the household laundry equip ment industry is estimated to have increased nearly 70 percent between 1958 and 1976. In 1975, more than 4 million home washing machines were sold, increasing market penetration to 70 percent, from 53 percent in I960.6 i [1967 = 100] Employee-hours Output per employee-hour Year 1958 ... 1959 . . . 1960 . . . All Produc Nonpro employ duction tion ees workers workers Output 77.7 84.4 81.7 78.3 85.4 81.5 76.3 82.2 82.0 64.7 71.8 71.9 83.3 85.1 88.0 82.6 84.1 88.2 84.8 87.3 87.7 All Produc Nonpro employ tion duction workers workers ees 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... 82.6 83.9 90.7 90.7 88.1 94.2 100.0 101.1 101.1 105.7 81.7 81.7 87.5 88.3 87.0 94.0 100.0 102.4 104.1 110.4 84.2 89.7 98.8 96.5 90.7 94.6 100.0 98.2 95.0 96.3 75.7 78.8 85.2 88.7 88.5 93.8 100.0 106.0 109.9 115.3 91.7 93.9 93.9 97.8 100.4 99.6 100.0 104.8 108.7 109.1 92.6 96.5 97.4 100.4 101.7 99.8 100.0 103.5 105.6 104.4 89.9 87.8 86.2 91.9 97.6 99.2 100.0 107.9 115.7 119.7 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 ... ... ... ... ... ... ... 108.6 120.0 127.5 132.7 123.3 127.0 126.2 114.8 125.1 134.4 139.6 129.0 135.0 135.6 96.5 110.1 114.2 119.3 112.1 112.0 109.1 111.7 125.9 135.1 137.9 125.0 132.3 135.2 102.9 104.9 106.0 103.9 101.4 104.2 107.1 97.3 100.6 100.5 98.8 96.9 98.0 99.7 115.7 114.3 118.3 115.6 111.5 118.1 123.9 ; Employment shows moderate rise Employment in the soaps and detergents industry, currently at 40,000, has increased moderately since 1958, when employment was at 32,000. This change is equivalent to an average increase of 1.1 percent each year. The growth in employee hours—an average annu al rate of 1.2 percent— reflected a very small increase in average hours per employee. Labor turnover in the industry has been comparative ly low, providing a stable and experienced work force. Since 1958, accessions have averaged 2.5 per 100 em ployees annually, compared with 3.6 for all manufactur ing. Separation rates have been 2.4 per 100 employees, compared with 4.1 for all manufacturing. Lower layoff and quit rates occurred in the industry than for all manufacturing almost every year. Average hourly earn ings for production workers in the soaps and detergents industry have risen steadily. Hourly earnings averaged $7.81 in 1977, compared with the manufacturing aver age of $5.68. The proportion of nonproduction workers in the in dustry is somewhat higher than is the case in other manufacturing industries— 37 percent of total employ ment in 1977, compared with 28 percent for all manu facturing. The higher proportion reflects the larger number of professional and technical, clerical, and sales personnel employed. Although data on the occupational composition of employees in the industry are not available, some in sights can be obtained from the broader aggregation, soaps and cosmetics.7 In 1976, an estimated 6 percent of all workers employed in soaps and cosmetics were chem ical and industrial engineers, chemists, and chemical technicians. Sales and clerical personnel accounted for 26 percent of total employment. The industry also em ploys a large number of semi-skilled workers, such as packers, wrappers, examiners, assemblers, and mixers who accounted for 32 percent of the work force in 1976. Average annual rates of change (in percent) 1958-77 1973-77 2.9 -0.6 3.4 -0.2 1.9 -1.5 4.1 -0.4 1.2 0.2 0.7 -0.2 2.1 1.1 ! The growth in output has also been influenced by the availability of a wide variety of soap and detergent products which can handle different types of cleaning problems. Among synthetic detergent products are light-duty, mild, sudsing detergents mainly used for dishwashing by hand; all-purpose and heavy-duty laun dry detergents, which' can be used for a number of tasks; presoak products; and automatic dishwashing de tergents. Laundry soaps are also available as flakes and blown granules. The predominantly used soap product is the refined bar of toilet soap. As shoppers are aware, these bars are available in a variety of sizes, colors, and scents, some containing additives such as cold creams and deodorants. The industry is very competitive and has been able to gain public acceptance of new products through advertising, and by dispensing free samples in large numbers when new products are introduced.3 The growth in output has also been influenced by the interactions among the household laundry equipment, textile, and detergent industries. The development of permanent press garments in the mid-1960’s by the textile industry was followed by reformulations in deter gent products. Because oily soils are more difficult to remove from synthetic fibers, their increased use in clothing required improved detergent products. Also, because higher wash temperatures may cause oily soils in some synthetics to become “set,” lower wash temper atures are often recommended for wash and wear gar ments.4 The detergent industry developed improved products that would perform adequately at lower wash 119 Larger plants dominate output German scientists are credited with developing the first synthetic detergents during World War I.10 Syn thetic detergents were introduced into the United States during the early 1930’s. The first synthetic detergents performed well in hard water; however, their cleaning ability was limited in laundry usage. In the 1940’s, the discovery and development of phosphates, primarily so dium tripolyphosphate, led to the first “built” synthetic detergents which not only performed well in hard wa ter, but provided the cleaning power necessary for laun dry use.11 By 1958, soap for many centuries the chief cleansing agent for household laundry and dishwashing use, had been largely replaced by synthetic detergents. Most of the soaps and detergents industry’s output is produced by large establishments. By 1972, more than 80 percent of the value of shipments was accounted for by units having 100 employees or more. These units represented only 9 percent of the industry’s establish ments because most of the industry’s establishments are small. In 1972, 69 percent of the 642 manufacturing es tablishments had fewer than 20 employees. Prior to the introduction of synthetic detergents, the soaps and detergents industry tended to concentrate near the sources of its principal raw materials. In more recent years, with increased detergent usage, more em phasis is given to locations near distribution centers when new sites are considered. Although production es tablishments are located throughout the Nation, about half of the industry’s production originates in the North Central region of the United States. Increases in labor productivity are frequently related to increases in the stock of capital. Over the period of this study, new capital expenditures per employee in the soaps and detergents industry increased at an average annual rate of 10 percent, compared with 7.8 percent for all manufacturing. Moreover, the levels were sub stantially above the average for all manufacturing in al most every year. By 1976, capital expenditures per employee were 82 percent higher than the manufactur ing average ($4,191, compared with $2,300). About three-fourths of the expenditures have been for new ma chinery and equipment, the same as for all manufactur ing. Detergents reformulated. Developments over the past 15 to 20 years have resulted in many changes in product composition. Because of environmental concerns, deter gent products have been and are still being reformu lated. One of the first changes in detergent composition occurred in 1964-65 involving the replacement of the organic surfactant with a type which degrades rapidly in the environment.12 Specifically, “hard” branchedchain alkylbenzenesulfonate (ABS) was replaced by “soft” biodegradable linear alkylbenzenesulfonate (LAS). LAS is still a major detergent ingredient. By the late 1960’s, the focus of environmental con cern shifted to phosphate levels in detergent products because of the controversy over the effect of phosphates upon rivers, streams, fish, and other wildlife. Legislation restricting phosphate levels in detergents was intro duced, including a total ban on phosphate in detergents in several States. To maintain detergent performance with reduced phosphate levels, surfactant levels are gen erally increased. Also, the use of surfactants, which are even less sensitive to water hardness than LAS, helps to maintain cleaning performance. For this reason, surfac tants based on long-chain alcohols have become more popular. These detergent formulation changes which occurred in the mid- and late 1960’s coincided with years in which productivity grew substantially less than the in dustry long-term average. Also, exceptionally large an nual increases in nonproduction workers occurred which suggests that the industry, in response to the en vironmental concerns, expanded its research efforts into the development of environmentally more acceptable products. Although sodium tripolyphosphate is still the leading detergent builder, new builders are beginning to appear and are currently used as phosphate substitutes. These include sodium carbonate, sodium silicate, and various surfactant blends. Other possible phosphate replace ments are being developed and tested, but none of these materials has proved to be a total replacement on a one-to-one basis. Technology changes Soap has always been made by combining the basic ingredients, fat and alkali. The early American commer cial soapmakers made soap outdoors in large iron ket tles over an open fire, according to a uniform formula. The kettle method of soapmaking was used until 1940 when a major improvement was achieved’in soap pro duction technology. A continuous process was perfected which reduced soapmaking time from about a week to less than a day.8 Today, the continuous process is dom inant, although the “kettle” process is still used in some establishments. Soap reacts with the minerals in hard water to form lime soap, which sometimes appears as a white scum in the wash water. Synthetic detergents, however, do not react this way. The term detergent usually refers to a product, which for heavy-duty laundry use, generally contains an organic surface active agent (surfactant), an inorganic builder, and various other ingredients. Also, “detergent” is sometimes used to denote the organic surfactant.9 120 Production processes improved. By 1958, virtually all of the basic equipment currently used in soap and deter gent making had been developed. Most of the improve ments which became available later were technological refinements of the basic equipment and production pro cesses. However, some notable improvements have been introduced. One of the major processes in the manufacture of synthetic surfactants is sulfonation. In this process, a nonsurface-active hydrocarbon (alkylbenzene, for in stance) is converted into surface-active alkylbenzenesulfonic acid, and subsequently neutralized to a salt. Oleum is the sulfonating agent.14 In the mid-1950’s, an innovation was developed which permitted the industry to convert batch sulfonation into a continuous process. With the continuous oleum process, a high-quality, uni form product could be obtained which met the impor tant production criteria, principally light color and low free oil (unconverted hydrocarbon) in the final sulfona tion product. Time saving is another advantage; the continuous sulfonation process is completed in a matter of minutes, whereas the batch process requires 6 to 10 hours.15 In the mid-1960’s, a further improvement was intro duced in the continuous sulfonation process involving a change from oleum to sulfur trioxide (S03) gas, mixed with air, as the sulfonating agent. The industry-wide trend towards the use of continuous S 03 has occurred mainly because former sulfonating agents, such as ole um, have higher chemical costs, and present disposal problems of spent sulfuric acid. Also, some of the newer types of raw materials mentioned earlier cannot be pro cessed efficiently except with S 0 3. This process provides a high-quality product by minimizing product degrada tion due to the short reaction time, reducing costs, and realizing labor savings in the handling of the acid dis posal product.16 Continuous sulfonation processes with automatic con trols minimize labor requirements. An entire continuous sulfonation plant can be operated with one operator, rather than the two or three operators needed in the batch and semi-continuous plants.17 Packaging operations in the industry have long used automatic equipment. However, some technological modifications have been introduced. For example, ma chines have been developed to handle larger powder packs and at the same time are capable of erecting car tons, and filling and closing them at higher speeds. For liquids, machines have also been introduced that can achieve higher filling speeds. High-speed soap bar production. Changes have also been made in soap bar finishing operations.18 Although con tinuous soap production lines have been in operation for many years, the need for faster production rates and 121 the development of more complex shapes of bar soaps spurred improvements over the past 15 years. Extensive changes have occurred in the design of the equipment and the line configurations. New high-speed lines for production of simple or uni form type bar soap formulas have broken the tradition al line speed barrier of 150-200 bars per minute. With the high-speed lines, 200-300 soap bars can be pro duced each minute. Modern specialty lines are available which provide flexible processing capability. A variety of toilet bar formulations such as synthetic detergent bars, soap-synthetic bars, and translucent soaps can now be produced at reasonable speeds. New high-speed stamping machines have also been developed which can produce up to 400 bars per minute either banded or bandless. In addition, refrigerated stamping dies have become standard in the industry. They serve to improve product appearance, to lessen die-fouling, and to im prove production rates. New developments have also been made in the ma chinery that is widely used to package bar soaps. These developments complement the development of the high speed finishing lines and have been directed primarily toward wrappers, cartoners, and bar soap transfer units. This new equipment has the capability of attaining higher speeds and has the flexibility of handling various shapes of bar soap.19 In the past, bar soap transfer units were limited to maximum speeds of 200 bars a minute. In the last 4 to 5 years, the speed has been increased. Wrappers, cartoners, and bar soap transfer units are be ing introduced that are capable of average production speeds of up to 300 bars a minute for the mass-pro duced soaps. Computer technology has made possible the central ized instrumentation of the production processes, although the industry has always been highly mecha nized. Computers are increasingly being used for jobs such as inventory control, flow and measurement of raw materials, formula calculations, and in mixing opera tions to assure uniformity of soap and detergent mixes. Marketing analysis can more easily be accomplished with computer-based information systems. The use of computer processing provides information that can be used to better allocate the time required for many activ ities, resulting in improved utilization of labor. Shortrun changes in productivity in the soaps and de tergents industry will continue to be affected by changes in demand. Over the longrun, the high levels of capital investment per employee should help to keep industry productivity gains in line with the average for all manu facturing. Substantial demand for virtually all of the products produced by the industry should continue into the im mediate future. The output of dishwasher detergents should especially show growth as the utilization of existing dishwashing machines is increased, and the ownership of home dishwashers is expanded. The num ber of washing machines in U.S. households is also expected to increase, thus generating additional growth for the soaps and detergents industry. 8“About Soap,” Procter and Gamble Service Bulletin, Procter and Gamble, Cincinnati, Ohio. 9 Based on information provided by Dr. Arno Cahn, Development Director, Household Products, Lever Brothers Co. 10“Some Facts About Procter and Gamble Detergents,” Procter and Gamble Information Bulletin. 11Anne L. Lyng, “Detergents in Review,” Detergents— in Depth, a symposium sponsored by The Soap and Detergent Association, Wash ington, D.C., Mar. 28-29, 1974, pp. 2 -7 . 12T. E. Brenner, “Soaps and Detergents: North American Trends,” The Soap and Detergent Association, in Proceedings— World Confer ence on Soaps and Detergents, Oct. 9 -1 5 , 1977, Montreux, Switzer land, pp. 5 -8 . Reprinted in Journal o f the American Oil Chemists' Society, January 1978. Also see, O. Carl Kerfoot and H. R. Flammer, “Synthetic Detergents: Basics,” Hydrocarbon Processing, March 1975, pp. 74-78. 13 Brenner, “Soaps and Detergents.” 14Based on information provided by Dr. Arno Cahn, Development Director, Household Products, Lever Brothers Co. 15 Oleum Sulfonation Process Equipment, The Chemithon Corp., Se attle, Washington, 1968. Also conversation with respresentative of The Chemithon Corporation. 16Sulphur Trioxide Detergent Process Equipment, The Chemithon Corp. Ibid. 17 Oleum Sulfonation Process Equipment and Sulphiir Trioxide Deter gent Process Equipment. Ibid. 18 A. B. Herrick, “Bar Soap Finishing— New Trends in Soap Pro cessing Line Design and Layouts,” Armour-Dial Company, in Proceedings— World Conference on Soaps and Detergents, Oct. 9 15, 1977, Montreux, Switzerland. Reprinted in Journal o f the Ameri can Oil Chemists' Society, January 1978, pp. 147-50. 19 L. Spitz, “Bar Soap Packaging,” ACMA S.p.A., in Proceedings — World Conference on Soaps and Detergents, Oct. 9 -1 5 , 1977, Montreux, Switzerland. Reprinted in Journal o f the American Oil Chemists’ Society, January 1978, pp. 151-55. 1The soap and other detergents industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in manufacturing soap, synthetic organic deter gents, inorganic alkaline detergents, or any combination thereof, and refined glycerine from vegetable and animal fats and oils. The indus try is designated as number 2841 in the Office of Management and Budget’s Standard Industrial Classification M anual (SIC), 1972 edition. Data prior to 1958 are not comparable. All average annual rates of change are based on the linear least squares trends of the logarithms of the index numbers. Extensions of the indexes will appear in the an nual BLS Bulletin, Productivity Indexes fo r Selected Industries. A tech nical note describing the m ethods used to develop the indexes is available from the Division of Industry Productivity Studies. 2 U.S. Industrial Outlook, various issues. 3 Industrial Outlook, 1970, p. 181. 4 Dieter H. Von Hennig, “The Role of Detergent Alcohols in the Soap and Detergents Industry, A Bicentennial Update,” Shell Chemi cal Company, at Chemical Industry Association, Inc. Workshop Meeting, Absecon, New Jersey, June 14, 1976. 5 Richard C. Davis, “Washer-detergent-textile Interactions,” H ydro carbon Processing, March 1975, pp. 9 0 -9 2 . 6 Richard B. Carnes, “Laundry and cleaning services pressed to post productivity gains,” Monthly Labor Review, February 1978; and “ 1976 Statistical and Marketing Report,” Merchandising, March 1976, pp. 3 8 -4 2 . 7 Bureau of Labor Statistics, unpublished data for 1 9 7 0 -8 5 , N ation al Industry Occupational Matrix. 122 Measuring P’roiictivity in Government Federal, State, and Local JEROME A. MARK S a result o f the growth o f government, which now em ploys one out o f every six members o f the workforce, and public concern over the rising costs o f government, the need to develop measures o f productivity for public agencies has becom e increasingly important. However, the concepts underlying productivity measurement are so com plex, that experts do not share a com m on perception o f the field; rather, they define the nature and purpose o f productivity measures in a number o f ways, particularly with regard to the public sector. The public sector literature variously defines productivity measurement as measure ment o f efficiency, effectiveness, cost reduction, input-output, management im provem ent, performance, m ethods improvement, work standards, and program evaluation. Efforts to evaluate productivity can be grouped into three broad areas; programs em ploy either efficiency type measures, opera tional type measures, or effectiveness type measures. Efficiency type measures compare the inputs or resources an organization uses with the final goods or services it produces. This measurement approach does not, however, determ ine whether these products should be produced or relate them to some desired goal. Where efficiency type measures assess the productivity o f a given activity by relating that activity to its result or som e kind o f fin ished product, work m easurem ent or operational type measures are mainly concerned with the activity itself. As Joh n P. Ross and Jesse Burkhead point out, “ work measures exam ine the work ac tivity itself rather than its results and are usually measured in terms o f activity per unit o f tim e.” 1 Work measures evaluate interm ediate activity by assessing resource requirements under a given tech no logy or set o f conditions; in contrast, productivity measures relate inputs to final products. A Unlike efficiency or operational type measures, effectiveness type measures quantify a program’s im pact on society and deter mine whether that program makes optim um use o f inputs or re sources to achieve its goals. The output indicator for this approach to m easurement is the effect that an activity has on a portion o f the public. The thrust o f measurem ent changes from a comparison betw een the goods and services that a program or activity produces and the inputs used, to a study o f the public that consum es those goods and services. The principal differences betw een the three productivity evalu ation system s lie in the definition and m easurem ent o f outputs. Bradford, Malt, and Oates have classified efficiency type measures as measures o f “ direct ou tp u ts” and effectiveness type measures as measures o f “ consequ en ces.” 2 In m any cases, however, this dis tinction is more apparent than real. Although there is a substantial am ount o f confusion about the specific meaning o f “ produ ctivity,” it seems clear that all o f these performance measures help public sector managers make decisions. The degree o f difference between efficien cy and effectiveness measures is greater in the public sector than in the private sector. In the private sector, com petition and market forces encourage businesses to operate efficien tly and effectively so that they can provide the goods the public demands at prices consumers are willing to pay. Because market forces and com petition do not af fect the public sector, the relationship between efficiency and effectiveness becom es more tenuous. For this reason, it is far more im portant to separate these tw o measures in analyses o f the public sector than in analyses o f the private sector. Each o f the three kinds o f m easurement system s—efficiency, work, and effectiveness—is im portant in its own right, and each plays a role in evaluating productivity. However, much o f the re- * J e r o m e A . M a r k is A s s i s t a n t C o m m i s s i o n e r f o r P r o d u c t i v i t y a n d T e c h n o l o g y a t t h e B u r e a u o f L a b o r S t a t i s t i c s , U .S . G o v e r n m e n t D e p a r t m e n t o f L a b o r . T h e a u t h o r g r a t e 1 John f u l l y a c k n o w l e d g e s t h e a s s i s t a n c e o f C h a r l e s A r d o l i n i , D o n F i s k , a n d J a m e s U r i s k o in Dimensions o f Productivity Research: Proceedings o f the Conference on Productivity Research, April 21-24, 1980, E d i t e d b y J o h n D . H o g a n , ( H o u s t o n , T X : A m e r i c a n P r o d u c t i v i t y v ic e s: C e n t e r , 1 9 8 0 ) , V o l u m e II. 1 8 5 -2 0 2 . th e p re p a ra tio n o f th is a r tic le . A s lig h tly Productivity in the Local G overnm ent Sector 2 D .F . B r a d f o r d , R . A . M a l t , a n d W .E . O a t e s , “ T h e R is i n g C o s t o f L o c a l P u b l i c S e r Reprinted from the P u b l i c P r o d u c t i v i t y R e v ie w , March 1981. P. R oss a n d J e s s e B u rk h e a d , ( L e x in g to n , M A : L e x in g to n B o o k s , 1 9 7 4 ) , 1 4 . d i f f e r e n t v e r s io n a p p e a r e d in 123 Som e E v id e n c e and R e fle c tio n s ," National Tax Journal, X X II (Ju n e 1969) search on productivity focuses on efficiency type measures and these are the measures which this paper principally addresses. Productivity M easurement at the Federal Level For several years, the principal effort to measure the produc tivity o f agencies in the federal government has been the Bureau o f Labor Statistics’ program to develop labor productivity indexes for all governm ent agencies with 200 or more em ployees. This program was undertaken first in conjunction with the General A ccounting O ffice, the O ffice o f Management and Budget, and the Civil Service Com m ission, later with the N ational Center for Pro ductivity and Quality of Working Life, and is currently administered with the O ffice o f Personnel M anagem ent.3 The program currently obtains data anddevelops measures for approxim ately 350 agencies representing about sixty-five percent o f federal em ploym ent. Table 1 shows the growth in the coverage o f the project over the years. The measures developed are indexes o f output per unit o f labor input (generally, em ployee-year) and the agency measures are grouped into functional categories that have com m on characteris tics. Table 2 shows the functional categories for which measures are derived and the associated average annual rates o f change for productivity and related series. The productivity indexes developed compare the current ou t put-input relationship with that o f a previous reference period, in this case fiscal year 1967, and the measures reflect the changes which have taken place in labor input per unit o f output regardless of the m ission o f the organization. Where it is possible, the relevant concept o f outp ut for a govern m ent agency is its final product—that is, what the given organiza tion produces for use by the public or other governm ent agencies. The output data included in the overall sample used for this study is final from the perspective o f both the agency itself and the func tional groupings in which these agencies are classified. However, since one federal agency may consum e all or some o f the outputs o f another federal agency to produce its own final outputs, all output indicators are not final from the perspective o f the entire federal government. Therefore, the overall statistics presented in the study do not represent “federal governm ent pro du ctivity,” but rather the average o f the productivity changes o f the measured federal organizations included in the sam ple.4 It is particularly im portant to understand the meaning o f these statistics in order to use this data for improving the measurement o f general government output in the National Incom e and Product accounts. Real gross product originating in general governm ent at present is measured by moving the base year com pensation o f government em ployees by changes in em ploym ent adjusted for shifts in grade structure. As a result, the implied productivity change for this measure is biased toward zero reflecting only the impact o f the change in grade structure o f federal em ployees. Since real gross product is a net measure, it is necessary to net out inter mediate output in order to use it in the developm ent o f improved GNP m easures.5 3 F o r d e s c r ip tio n s o f th e w o r k o n th is p r o j e c t a n d th e p r e s e n ta tio n o f re s u lts , se e U .S . C o n g r e s s , J o i n t E c o n o m i c C o m m i t t e e , the Federal Sector A. M ark and Measuring and Enhancing Productivity in ( W a s h i n g t o n , D .C .: U .S . G o v e r n m e n t P r i n t i n g O f f i c e , 1 9 7 2 ) ; J e r o m e C h a rle s W . A r d o lin i, “ D e v e lo p m e n ts in M e a s u rin g P r o d u c tiv ity in th e F e d e r a l S e c t o r , ” Proceedings o f the Business and Economics Section o f the American Statistical Association ( W a s h i n g t o n , D . G , 1 9 7 4 ) 2 3 6 - 4 5 ; J o i n t F i n a n c i a l M a n a g e m e n t I m p r o v e m e n t P r o g r a m , Productivity Programs in the Federal G overnm ent ( W a s h i n g t o n , D . C . : U .S . G o v e r n m e n t P r i n t i n g O f f i c e , 1 9 7 5 ) . 4 M a rk a n d A r d o lin i, “ D e v e lo p m e n ts in M e a s u rin g P ro d u c tiv ity .” 5 F o r a d is c u s s io n o f t h e p r o b le m s o f u s in g th is d a ta in th e n a tio n a l in c o m e a n d p r o d u c t a c c o u n t s , s e e C h a r l e s A . W a ite a n d A l l a n D . S e a r l e , “ C u r r e n t E f f o r t s t o M e a s u r e P r o d u c tiv ity in th e P u b lic S e c to r : H ow A d e q u a te fo r th e N a tio n a l A c c o u n ts ,” a n d New D evelopments in Productiv ity Measurement and Analysis; Studies in Incom e and Wealth, E d i t e d b y J o h n W . K e n J e r o m e A . M a r k , “ C o m m e n t s o n S e a r le a n d W a i t e , ” i n d r i c k a n d B e a t r i c e N . V a c c a r a ( C h i c a g o : U n i v e r s i t y o f C h ic a g o P r e s s , 1 9 8 0 ) . 124 F is c a l Y e a r 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 197 8 17 45 46 49 51 51 50 50 O r g a n iz a tio n a l U n its 114 187 200 245 279 307 319 347 O u t p u t I n d ic a t o r s 948 1120 1201 1581 1747 2035 2334 2660 C iv ilia n E m p lo y e e - 1 .6 1 .7 1.7 1.8 1 .9 1 .9 1 .8 1 .8 2 .9 2 .8 2 .8 2 .8 2 .8 2 .8 2 .8 2 .8 A g e n c ie s Y e a rs C o v e re d ( m illio n s ) T o t a l C iv ilia n E m p lo y e e - Y e a r s ( m illio n s ) E m p lo y e e - Y e a r s 54% 60% 61% 65% 66% 66% 64% 65% C o v e re d as P e rc e n t o f T o t a l ( m illio n s ) T a b le 1: C o v e ra g e o f t h e F e d e r a l P r o d u c tiv ity M e a s u r e m e n t P ro g ra m Although it would be desirable to have a net measure o f federal government output and productivity, this is not possible at present. While it is possible to identify some o f the measured outputs that are consum ed inside the federal governm ent, sufficient data is not available to determine the degree o f internal consum ption. To determine final output indicators, the agencies and the Bureau o f Labor Statistics (BLS) must identify specific units o f services which are countable, fairly hom ogeneous over time, flexible enough to be adjusted for quality changes, and represen tative o f the agencies’ workload. In addition, since historical trends are o f interest, it is im portant that the measures are easy to contruct from readily available records. The indicators vary substantially. They include such diverse items as trademarks disposed, tanks repaired, weather observations made, square feet o f buildings cleaned, electrical pow er generated, and deportable aliens located. The output volum es range from sev eral hundred units com pleted per year (e.g. river basin studies) to billions (e.g. mail delivery items). Em ployee-indexes are developed from the data each agen cy submits. As in all labor input measures used to develop produc tivity indexes, em ployee-years are treated as hom ogeneous and additive and no distinction is made betw een different groups of em ployees. Since the productivity measure is a labor productivity series, the line item output indicators arc com bined with the correspon ding labor input weights. These weights arc constructed from the detailed output and input data provided by each participating organization. BLS productivity indexes measure both the overall sample and also tw enty-eight major functions representing relatively h om ogen eous groups o f activities such as library services, procurem ent, finance and accounting, electric pow er production, and postal ser vice. Although indexes for each o f the 350 organizational units have also been constructed, they arc not published. Rather, they arc returned to each organization for its own use (e.g.to stim ulate further exam ination o f productivity changes). M E A S U R E M E N T P R O B L E M S . There are several im portant prob lems in measuring productivity in the federal sector. Because most federal activities are service oriented, it is often difficult to define and quantify outputs; governm ent agencies usually do not produce clearly specified physical products comparable to the goods produced by the private sector. Moreover, after the output indicators are specified, they m ust be in su fficien t detail to repre sent a hom ogeneous group o f services. If the outp ut units repre sented by the output indicator are not hom ogeneous, and if over time the proportion changes betw een units that are more or less F u n c tio n a l G roupings T o ta l A u d it o f O perations B uild in g s & G rounds M aintenance C o m m u n ica tio n s'* E d u ca tio n & T ra in in g ! E le c tric Power P ro d u c tio n & D is trib u tio n E q u ip m e n t M a in te n a n ce ! Finance & A c c o u n tin g Genera! S u p p o rt Services In fo rm a tio n Services Legal & Ju d icia l A c tiv itie s L ib ra ry Services Loans & Grants M edical Services M ilita ry Base Services N atura l Resources <k E n v iro n m e n t Managem ent Personnel Investigations Personnel Managem ent Postal Service P rin tin g & D u p lic a tio n P rocurem ent Records M anagem ent R eg u latio n -C o m p lia n ce & E n fo rce m e n t R eg u latio n -R u le m a kin g & Licensing Social Services & B enefits Specialized M a n u fa ctu rin g S u p p ly & In v e n to ry C o n tro l T r a ffic M a n a g e m e n t** T ra n s p o rta tio n O u tp u t p e r E m p lo y e e -Y e a r O u tp u t E m p lo y e e Years C om pensation Per E m p lo y e e Year U n it L a b o r C ost 1.4 1.3 -0.1 8.7 7.2 2.5 2.5 10.1 0.9 0.3 0.4 2.4 3.9 0.3 -0.3 5.3 4.2 -0.1 -0.4 1.3 3.6 1.8 1.3 -1.5 2.0 3.1 2.0 2.6 2.8 1.9 2.0 1.3 2.6 -1.2 0.6 9.8 -1.2 7.9 -3.2 0.2 6.0 1.7 3.9 8 .6 5.1 1.9 -4.6 1.0 12.6 6.6 0.8 -3.5 -0.9 -1.4 5.0 4.6 7.5 -0.7 -4.8 -3.4 3.4 -3 .6 -1.9 -0.2 -2.0 7 .6 -3.6 -2.1 2.1 1.5 4.2 3.2 0.9 2 .0 -4.2 -0.3 8.7 4.7 -0.4 -2 .0 -2.9 -4.4 3.0 2 .0 4.6 -2.6 -6.7 -4.6 0.8 7.2 9.5 6.8 8.1 8.1 7.8 7.7 7 .3 5.7 5 .6 8 .4 7.9 7.9 7 .4 7.0 6 .6 5 .4 10.2 9 .4 5 .4 8 .3 6.9 6.7 7 .0 8.5 7.4 5.7 8.5 4.6 6.8 -3.0 7.1 7.8 7.4 5.2 3.3 5.5 5.9 3.0 3.6 8 .0 7.9 5.6 2.9 3.5 8.8 11.0 3.3 5.0 4.9 4 .0 4.1 6.5 5.3 4 .4 5.7 Source: Bureau o f Lab o r S tatistics, U.S. D e p a rtm e n t o f Labor. Average annual p ercent change based on lin e a r least squares tre n d o f the lo g a rith m s o f the index num bers. * is fiscal year 1973 -1 97 8 . t is fiscal year 1968 -1 97 8 . * * is fiscal year 1972-1 978. Table 2: Functional and summary average annual rates o f change in output per em ployee-year and related data for the measured portion o f the federal civilian government, fiscal years 196 7-1978 labor intensive, the resultant output per em ployee-year measure will reflect not only the change in productivity—the change in the am ount o f labor required to produce the base year com posite— but also shifts in the types o f output. A nother related problem is that some reported outputs do not reflect changes in output quality. Adjustm ents for changes in ou t put quality are necessary in order to appropriately measure the changes in resources used per unit o f similar type good or service. If a reduction in labor requirements per unit o f outp ut results from a change in the dim ensions o f the outp ut or in the quality o f the service, then the resultant measure does not reflect productivity improvement. For purposes o f labor productivity m easurement, changes in outp ut quality, which reflect an altered production process with different base period labor requirements, can be considered as ba sic changes in the output. Similarly, changes in outp ut character istics, which affect the value o f the output to the user but not an altered production process or different base period labor require ments, do not require special treatment. The main remedy for these difficulties is to collect more de tailed data. For exam ple, initially the only output indicator used to assess the productivity o f the Postal Service was the number o f pieces o f mail handled. By exam ining other Postal Service data, BLS learned that output indicators covering various types o f mail (e.g. registered and first class) and other services (e.g. m oney orders) were available. The measure for the Postal Service is now based on this detailed data and takes into account shifts in the importance o f the different types o f mail services, all o f which require differ ent levels o f unit labor. A lthough the use o f this additional product detail has improved the accuracy o f the measure for this function, opportunities for further im provem ent remain. For exam ple, at the present time t h e 125 measure reflects shifts betw een the less labor intensive deliveries to large office buildings which have centralized mail distribution facilities, and the more labor intensive deliveries to scattered pri vate, suburban residences, as well as productivity changes in these com ponent activities. It would be desirable to adjust the measures for these shifts. BLS has sought, and in some cases obtained, detailed output indicators, but in many cases the reported measures only summar ize an agency’s activities. For exam ple, the indicators record the total number o f weapons overhauled rather than breaking this figure down by type o f w eapon and specifying type o f repair. In order to ensure that units o f reported outp ut were hom ogeneous, BLS asked each participating agency to specify typical maximum and minimum am ounts o f time required to produce one output unit. A narrow range indicated that the labor requirements for each unit o f output were relatively hom ogeneous within a given year and that the effects o f a shift in output mix would be minimal. Conversely, a wide range indicated that the units measuring ou t put were n ot standard and thus could not reliably reflect changes in a shift in output mix. M ost outputs had a relatively narrow range; however, a lim ited number o f output indicators showing wide ranges had to be dropped from the study. O utputs having long production cycles (i.e. requiring many m onths or in som e cases, years to com plete) also present difficult measurement problems. Q uantifying such outputs only in the year they are com pleted produces output measures that are inconsistent with the associated factor input. When production time extended beyond one year, estim ates o f the proportion o f long term outputs produced in each year were made. Closely related to the problem o f quantifying output are the difficulties that emerge when the federal governm ent contracts out work. In these cases, the final output measure for a govern m ent agency may reflect the activities o f not only the agency’s em ployees, but also its private contractors. It is important to de termine which output is exclusively associated with government em ployees, because the input measure should be lim ited to them. For exam ple, the Em ploym ent and Training Adm inistration o f the Departm ent o f Labor administers contractor-operated job training programs. Analyses o f the productivity o f these programs did not directly use the outputs o f the contractors since it could not be established that the outp ut o f the federal em ployees was propor tional to the results or the activities o f the contractors. The project attem pted to com pensate for this problem. Departm ental reorganizations also present difficulties in ob taining consistent output and em ployee-year data. Whenever a reorganization occurred, respondents were asked to subm it consis tent data on the basis o f either the new or the old organizational structure. Within the Departm ent o f Labor’s Em ploym ent and Training Adm inistration, for exam ple, the offices overseeing train ing, em ploym ent, and un em p loym ent com pensation services were reorganized several tim es during the fiscal years 1967-1978. BLS has developed a separate measure for the un em p loym ent insurance activities, but since the training and em ploym ent counseling ser vices are so closely related and their records are so intertwined, it was considered more appropriate to construct a com bined m ea sure for these activities. Using budget and other docum ents, BLS developed indexes based on the current organizational structure for the fiscal years 1967-1978. C U R R E N T E F F O R T S . BLS is attem pting to expand the program’s coverage o f the federal sector. It is believed that the sam ple’s cov erage can be expanded from the sixty-five percent o f federal em ployees it n o w includes to a m axim um o f perhaps eighty-five per cen t o f federal em ployees. Much work needs to be done before measures can ever be developed for areas such as the research activ ities in the N ational Aeronautical and Space A dm inistration and the National Bureau o f Standards. Therefore, BLS concentrates on improving the outp ut indica tors currently reported. This process involves developing indicators that more accurately represent the results of an agency’s activities; these improved measures will use more clearly defined and de tailed product inform ation than some o f the indicators presently in use. On the input side, BLS devotes some attention to exploring ways o f accounting for changes in the characteristics o f the feder al work force. In the present set o f measures, all em ployee-years are treated as hom ogeneous and additive. It w ould be desirable to learn how shifts in the com position o f the work force effect changes in output per unit o f labor unit input. In addition to the work o f BLS and the O ffice o f Personnel M anagement (OPM), various federal agencies have undertaken other activities generally reflecting efficiency-type measures. O T H E R E F F O R T S A T F E D E R A L L E V E L . While BLS conducts the annual productivity data call to construct measures for the overall federal governm ent and the functional categories, partici pating federal agencies conduct their ow n research efforts to develop m easurem ent system s. These measurem ent system s are developed internally but often are technically supported by BLS or aided by outside contractors. As the system s becom e operational, BLS will review the m ethods they use and may incorporate their results in the overall federal statistics. The exam ples that follow dem onstrate the approaches that are being developed to overcom e conceptual problems in productivity measurement. The Naval System s Command has enlisted BLS support to de velop meaningful measures o f productivity for its ship overhaul activities. Ship overhaul presents tw o significant m easurem ent pro blems. This activity involves outputs with a long production cycle time; it som etim es takes more than eighteen m onths to retrofit a ship. Recording these outputs only in the year they are com pleted produces an output measure that is inconsistent with the associated input measure. In addition, the custom ized nature o f the outp ut precludes the developm ent o f a standard unit o f output that re mains hom ogeneous over time. These problems can be addressed by estim ating the proportion o f long-term output produced in each year or by breaking the final outputs down into com ponent parts, each o f which is com pleted within a m easurement period. The thrust o f this productivity meas urement program is to analyze ship overhaul in terms o f repairs to the ship’s major system s such as its hull, armament, and propulsion and electrical system s. Within each o f the system s, the navy has selected sample indicators that reflect the output o f the system and are hom ogeneous over time. Data is now being collected and the final results should yield an accurate and useful measure o f pro ductivity in ship overhauling. A research project in the area o f hospital care is underway at the Veteran’s Adm inistration. Traditionally, productivity meas urement has been weak in this area because the output indicators generally used in these activities (beds occupied, patient-days, or patients treated) have severe lim itations. The measures which result from the use o f these indicators do not reflect the varying resource requirements needed by type o f illness (e.g. fractures versus cardio vascular diseases). The measures also contain a bias o f unknown direction and magnitude because the length o f stay per type o f ill ness varies over time. A more accurate measure o f productivity would distinguish betw een type o f illness, diagnostic category, etc., and would make allowance for the fact that varying units o f labor are required to treat each type o f illness. BLS staff have provided technical assistance to the Veterans Adm inistration in its effort to portray trends in productivity more accurately. This project is part o f a new integrated m anagement inform ation system. The purpose o f the system is to provide more tim ely data on costs and to develop a firmer basis for estim ating em ploym ent needs.6 Som e agencies are conducting measurem ent activities that are designed along the lines o f the M undel hierarchy o f work un its.7 This approach classifies service outputs into well-defined quantifi able units o f work. The various classifications serve as a guide for tracing the production cycle from resource input to the organiza tion’s outputs or achievements. The m eth odology begins with time and m otion studies, moves to the measurement o f interm ediate and final output, and ends with an attem pt to measure effectiveness. While the basic model postulates eight levels o f work units, it can collapse or expand to m eet the needs o f the organization. The V et erinary Service o f the Departm ent o f Agriculture, which has the mission o f ensuring that livestock herds are free o f infectious di seases, uses this system to evaluate animal inspection activities. The Department o f the Interior, HEW, and the Secret Service have also em ployed this measurement technique. At the Department of Housing and Urban D evelopm ent (H UD), a new management control system allocates regional staff. The system classifies major programs into categories depending on the activities required to com plete defined outputs. K nown as the operating plan system, this program planning tool permits HUD to allocate staff on the basis o f workload projections. For instance, the system develops standard times required to process a housing application. Given a reasonably accurate estim ate o f the number o f applications it will have to process in the upcom ing year, HUD S26 6 A r e c e n t d is c u s s io n o f th e v a r io u s a p p r o a c h e s to p r o d u c tiv ity m e a s u r e m e n t in h o s p i t a l s is p r o v i d e d b y W . R i c h a r d S c o t t , “ M e a s u r i n g O u t p u t s i n H o s p i t a l s , ” i n m ent and Interpretation o f Productivity Measure (W a s h in g to n , D .C .: N a ti o n a l R e s e a r c h C o u n c il, N a tio n a l A c a d e m y o f S c ie n c e s , 1 9 7 9 ) , 2 5 5 - 7 5 . 7 M a r v in E. M u n d e l, G overnm ent Organizations Measuring and Enhancing the Productivity o f Service and (H o n g K o n g : A s ia n P r o d u c tiv ity O r g a n iz a tio n , 1 9 7 5 ). can determine labor requirements for that output. The operating plan is set at the beginning o f the year and each m onth accom plish ments and staff-years utilized are compared to targeted forecasts. This permits HUD to exam ine staff utilization rates and re-allocate resources when unplanned disruptions occur. While the HUD pro gram springs from detailed work measurement concepts, the system is flexible to permit data aggregation at any level o f analytical need. Thus, when the system becom es fully operational, BUS will be able to derive productivity data from an autom ated system. Lastly, mention must be made o f OPM’s experim ental project in the area o f administrative services. The project is designed to measure productivity o f a com m on support service and has stan dardized definitions to facilitate inter and intra-agency compari sons so that managers have an adequate am ount o f inform ation on which to base decisions. The project began with the function o f personnel services'and is now in the second year o f data collec tion .8 Data is being collected on outputs and inputs within the categories o f staffing actions, position classification, labor rela tions, em ployee developm ent, and general administration. In con trast to the existing Federal Productivity Measurement System , which directly collects outputs and associated inputs, OPM’s meas urement system em ploys random sampling techniques to generate weighting factors. As the pilot project proves feasible, OPM o f ficials hope to extend it to other administrative services such as finance, procurement, and data processing. Som e federal agencies have aggressively pursued efficiency re search activities and are exam ining indicators that may dem on strate how effectively they are m eeting their mission statem ents. These measures go beyond the efficiency measures contained in the federal productivity data base. For the purposes o f efficiency, the Drug Enforcem ent Agency is measuring the number o f nar cotics arrests forwarded for prosecution. For the purposes o f effec tiveness, that is, how well the agency is discharging its mission to protect society from illegal drugs, the measure may be an index o f narcotics prices (i.e. rising prices indicate a declining supply) or a measure o f drug-related deaths and hospitalizations. Som e agencies involved in activities such as awarding grants have been attem pting to develop effectiveness measures. Where the grant is for research, as in the physical or behavioral sciences, one approach has been to have a peer group evaluate the quality o f the research or to record the number o f times the findings o f the research are cited in professional journals. The National Science Foundation uses this approach to measure the quality o f the re search activities it funds. In agencies that disburse m onies, com m on measures o f e ffe c tiveness are the percent o f paym ents made on tim e, the timeliness with which lost checks are reissued, and the percent o f financial reports for public use com pleted on time. Within the E m ploym ent and Training Adm inistration (ETA) o f the Department o f Labor, a primary function is to issue con tracts for the operation o f J ob Corps centers. ETA measures this effort by expressing the number o f trainees placed in J o b Corps centers as a percent o f expected slots to be filled. ETA believes this approach permits it to analyze its success in m eeting expansion targets o f the Job Corps program. Som e organizations attem pt to com bine efficiency and effec tiveness into a single overall performance indicator. The Army Material Command, for exam ple, has adopted a procedure which develops one measure for effectiveness and a separate measure for efficiency for each o f the com m and’s depots. The results o f all the depots are then numerically ranked on a scale from one to fifteen. The procedure assigns one score for effectiveness and one for e f 8 A l l a n S . U d l c r , “ A n E x p e r i m e n t in t h e P e r s o n n e l O f f i c e , ” Civil Service Journal X IX (J a n u a ry /M a rc h 1 9 7 9 ), 3 2 -3 5 . 127 ficien cy; the com bined score represents each d ep ot’s performance. Thus, with one indicator, the ArmyM aterial Com m and shows both how well a mission is accom plished (effectiveness) and how com pletely resources are utilized (efficiency). It seems better to keep the tw o types o f productivity measure ment systems separate. D ifferent types o f productivity measures serve different purposes. For exam ple, assessing the am ount o f resources used per unit o f output in order to improve resource allocation may call for an efficiency type measure. Evaluating the impact o f resource use on program goals may call for an effective ness type measure. It is doubtful that com bining different types o f measures into a single measure would produce satisfactory measures in m ost cases. F U T U R E D I R E C T I O N S . While BLS has extended productivity measurement to cover agencies representing two-thirds o f the fed eral governm ent’s civilian work force, further expansion is required. In the future, however, the measurement program’s rate o f growth will slow because it is difficult to define and quantify the output o f many o f the government agencies not currently covered by the program. Research and developm ent and policy-oriented activities, such as those in the National Institutes o f Health, the State Depart ment, and defense activities fall into this category. Innovative ap proaches to measurement must be developed for these activities. BLS must continue to refine and improve existing output measures in the present m easurement system . It will be necessary to m odify reporting system s to provide more suitable indicators. Moreover, as the federal establishm ent places increased em pha sis on gauging the performance o f organizations, federal agencies will have to expand and develop existing measures so that they become far more detailed. As a result, the governm ent will begin measuring outputs that arc not currently measured because, under the present reporting system , they are considered as intermediate rather than final outputs. For exam ple, an overall productivity As the federal establishment places increased emphasis on gauging the performance of organizations, federal agencies will have to expand and develop existing measures so that they become far more detailed. measure o f an agency may be useful when the entire agency is re viewed. However, such a measure, which masks the performance o f the agency’s many bureaus, administrations, or programs fails to supply enough inform ation to the executives directing the sub activities o f the agency. They need more detailed data. This need is amply demonstrated by a request to BLS from the Department o f Agriculture. In the department, one o f the many organizations furnishing productivity inform ation is the Soil Con servation Service. The outputs and associated inputs for the entire Department o f Agriculture are collected, processed, and returned to the service for its analysis. This measure is useful for analyzing the Department o f Agriculture, but the executives o f the Soil Con servation Service felt additional inform ation would be more use ful. They wished to have productivity measures for the service’s many programs. BLS m et this need by developing productivity measures for individual programs such as flood prevention services, snow forcasts, and soil mapping. Because the Soil Conservation Service now has its own detailed set o f productivity measures, it is possible to analyze the specific programs o f the service as well as the overall performance o f the Departm ent o f Agriculture. It is clear that we must adopt this type o f approach in order to provide managers with m eaningful data. BLS has always offered to provide technical assistance in developing measures for detailed agency use, but unfortunately, the response from the agencies has been poor. Finer levels o f measurem ent must be stressed and en couraged if the federal agencies are to have reasonably accurate productivity measures for use in resource allocation and budgeting. Currently, the m easurement system relates output to a single factor, labor input. Since there are as many productivity measures as there are factors o f production, Som e people are interested in professional em ployees or shifts in levels o f educational attain ment, the results are reflected as productivity m ovem ents and not as factor input changes. Productivity measures could be refined so that they are able to adjust for such things as the age, sex, and e x perience o f the work force. This area o f research should be co n sidered one o f the more feasible expansions o f the federal produc tivity measurement system . It is generally agreed that the m ost suitable unit o f labor input measure is the number o f hours worked. The current input meas ure, em ployee-years, is based on the number o f hours paid. Thus, the denom inator o f the productivity expression includes actual hours expended to produce the output plus hours paid for sick and annual leave, overtim e, and accrued leave paid at separation. This probably does not present a measurement bias if the ratio o f hours worked to total hours paid is stable over time. However, in the public sector, this issue has never been analyzed. While the exten t o f any potential bias is thought to be minimal, this subject should be researched. The O ffice o f Personnel M anagement, which is responsible for improving the productivity o f the federal government, would like in see effectiveness measures supplem ent tire existing data base.9 As m entioned earlier, this is a most difficult area o f productivity measurement. The com plexities o f defining and quantifying ou t put measures involve normative judgem ents and a variety o f as sum ptions. The research literature has extensively questioned the value and availability o f standards, norms, or targets.10 Even if it is possible to develop multiple measures of effectiveness, there is no clear conceptual basis for aggregating them with an efficiency measure into an overall performance m easure.I11 An exam ple will illustrate these problems. Suppose the focus o f the productivity analysis is the Social Security Adm inistration. For an efficiency type measure, the final output indicator is the exploring alternative measures o f productivity for the federal gov ernment. The m ost com m on alternative to single factor measures is output per com bined unit o f labor and capital. There has been a great deal o f research on m ultifactor productivity estim ates, but these efforts have been lim ited to analyses o f the private sector. W ithout listing every problem inherent in the developm ent o f cap ital estim ates, it is necessary to discuss a few difficulties that make the federal government unique when considered from the perspec tive o f m ultifactor analysis. The com m on form of the capital input estimate in m ultifactor productivity measurement is a capital stock measure. However, the governm ent’s current accounting system precludes the devel opm ent o f such a measure because the system charges purchases o f equipm ent and structures in the year o f acquisition. Thus, there is no convenient m ethod for estim ating the value o f the capital stock available for the production o f goods and services^ For e x ample, a vehicle acquired for a m otor pool fleet is expensed in the year it is purchased. That vehicle has a useful life o f several years I S ec O P M m e m o ra n d u m fo r h e a d s o f e x e c u tiv e d e p a r tm e n ts a n d a g e n c ie s , “ F e d e ra l P r o d u c t i v i t y M e a s u r e m e n t P r o j e c t : F is c a l Y e a r 1 9 7 9 I n s t r u c t i o n P a c k a g e , ” d a t e d J a n u and will be contributing a flow o f capital services over the period o f time it is in use. However, there is now no m ethod o f measuring the depreciated value o f the vehicle in any year after the year o f acquisition. Thus, it is necessary to introduce a system for fixing the value o f capital equipm ent and structures before beginning to research m ultifactor productivity in the federal governm ent. An official o f the Departm ent o f the Treasury has suggested the G overnment Financial Operations unit within the Treasury Department, a heavily com puterized organization, as a possible candidate for a m ultifactor study. Perhaps som e initial pilot stud ies will provide insights on developing a governm ent-wide frame work for extending productivity measures beyond com parisons o f output per unit o f labor input. New ways o f measuring labor input in the present system can also be explored. Current m ethodology considers labor input as hom ogeneous and additive; that is, an hour’s worth o f work per formed by any general schedule em ployee regardless o f his position, expertise, or experience, is weighted equally in the measure. This procedure, therefore, does not take into account the com position o f the work force. Furthermore, as changes occur in the co m p o sition o f labor, such as changes in the ratio o f professional to n on number o f checks disbursed. For purposes o f effectiveness type measures, however, the choice o f the proper indicator is not as ob vious. The manager o f the program might evaluate effectiveness by measuring the percent o f the number o f recipients who receive their checks on the first o f the m onth. The political scientist or welfare econom ist may define effectiveness as the degree to which the incom e o f the population served is above or below the poverty line. Thus, various disciplines would select different measures o f effectiveness. In addition, the feasibility o f com bining the measures o f effectiveness and efficiency into a meaningful overall measure o f performance remains questionable. The work which some federal agencies have carried out on e f fectiveness measurement is still in the experim entation stage. Much research remains to be done on the standards against which e ffe c tiveness can be measured and on possible techniques for data col lection. The disciplines concerned with public sector productivity face the challenge o f developing m odels for measuring effective ness which accurately convey to both the public and policy planners the degree to which a public sector organization is accom plishing its goals. Productivity Measurement at the State and Local Level Compared with our knowledge o f measurement in the federal government, we know very little about state and local government productivity measurement. The diversity and m ultiplicity o f state and local governments and the absence o f a continuing productivi ty information system makes it difficult to assess their productivity. The knowledge we have com es from three sources: local govern ment surveys, academic studies, and work by the federal govern ment on state and local government enterprise funds. Most surveys o f state and local government have concluded that the majority o f governments collect and use efficiency-type productivity measures, although in many cases the measures arc limited to a small group o f activities. These measures are important for budgeting, auditing, review, and daily operations. A 1976 sur vey o f local government found that about sixty-five percent o f the cities and fifty percent o f the counties regularly used efficiency measures at some stage o f their operations.12 More recent surveys in North Carolina and the Denver M etropolitan area alsouncovered ary 2 1 , 1 9 8 0 . 10 H a r r y P. H a tr y , “ T h e S ta tu s o f P r o d u c tiv ity in t h e P u b lic S e c t o r ," istration Review, II J e s s e D e fin itio n X X X V III (J a n u a ry /F e b ru a ry B u rk h e a d and and O r d e r ," P a tric k J . Public A d m in 1 9 7 8 ), 2 8 . H e n n ig a n , “ P r o d u c tiv ity A n a ly s is : A S e a r c h f o r Public Adm inistration Review, 12 X X X V III (J a n u a ry /F e b ru a ry R ackham F u k h u h a ra , The Status o f Local G overnm ent Productivity D .C : T h e I n t e r n a tio n a l C ity M a n a g e m e n t A s s o c ia tio n , 1 9 7 7 ) . 1 9 7 8 ), 3 4 . 128 (W a s h in g to n , frequent but uneven use o f efficiency m easures.13 On the other hand, a 1976 exam ination o f budget docum ents o f 247 cities and counties found that only ten percent contained any efficiency m easures.14 Many local governm ents use efficiency measures but do n ot include them in their budget docum ents. Inform ation on state use o f efficiency measures is even more lim ited than that on local governm ent. A survey o f state budget docum ents and statistical reports in 1975 found m ixed use o f ef ficiency-type m easures.15 In fields such as corrections and edu cation, about one-third o f the states included atleast one efficiencytype measure in their budgets. These included such measures as “ dollar cost o f caring for inmate per inmate day” and “number o f offenders per parole officer.” For functions such as tourism and licensing,less than ten percent o f the states included any efficiencytype measures in their budgets. Several conclusions emerge from these surveys o f state and local governm ent use o f efficiency-type measures. First o f all, larger jur isdictions are more likely to develop and use efficiency-type meas ures than smaller jurisdictions. Secondly, the use o f efficiency-type measures is very uneven from service area to service area. Thirdly, service areas subsidized or regulated by the federal governm ent are more likely to have efficiency-type measures than other areas. In addition, services with tangible outputs, such as solid waste collec tion, are more likely to be measured than those with intangible outputs, such as general management. Tw o other conclusions emerge from these surveys which bear m entioning. State and local governm ent docum ents include more effectiveness-type measures tiian efficiency-type measures. A lso, state and local governments are increasingly interested in the developm ent o f engineered work standards. A lthough they can be a useful tool in increasing pro ductivity, engineered work standards do n o t measure productivity themselves; rather, they measure normal, optim al, expected, or other am ounts o f time required to perform individual tasks. Cost measures calculated by state and local government do not assess productivity either. Changes in unit costs, such as “cost per stu dent” reflect factor price changes, as well as changes in resources used. Over the past decade, several members o f the academic com m unity have prepared state and local government productivity in dexes. For the m ost part, these indexes have been parts o f larger research issues, such as Robert D. Reischauer’s projections o f state and local governm ent cost and revenue.16 These studies have taken one o f tw o approaches. One approach has been to com pute a cost per unit o f service such as “ cost per pupil day” in the case o f education and infer changes in productivi ty from changes in unit costs over tim e.17 The other approach has been to specify unit cost as an independent variable and identify changes in productivity (and quality) through the residual term .18 There are a number o f problems with the academic research. F orm ost service areas, researchers have had to use “persons served” or “ persons elegible for service” as the indicator o f output. For exam ple, in public safety, the “population at risk” is often used as the output measure. Such measures, unfortunately, do not define or distinguish the number o f people served or the type o f R e s e a r c h T r i a n g l e I n s t i t u t e , Comparative Performance Measures fo r Municipal Services ( R a l e i g h , N . C : D e c e m b e r 1 9 7 8 ) ; D e n v e r R e g i o n a l C o u n c i l o f G o v e r n m e n t s , I D em onstration o f Comparative Productivity Measurement, ( D e n v e r : R e g i o n a l C o u n 1 :l o f G o v e r n m e n t s , 1 9 7 8 ) . 14 i l a t r y , “ T h e S ta t u s o f P r o d u c tiv ity in th e P u b lic S e c t o r ,” 2 9 . U rb a n I n s titu te , In Initial Examination, 16 R o b e r t 1972 Budget D. The Status o f Productivity Measurement in State Government: ( W a s h in g to n , D .C .: T h e U r b a n I n s t i t u t e , 1 9 7 5 ) . R e is h a u e r in C h a rle s I ,. S c h u l t z e , Setting National Priorities: The ( W a s h in g to n , D .C .: T h e B r o o k in g s I n s t i t u t i o n , 1 9 7 1 ) . 17 B r a d f o r d , M a l t , a n d O a t e s , “ T h e R is i n g C o s t o f L o c a l P u b l i c S e r v i c e s . ” 18 R o s s a n d B u r k h c a d , Productivity in the Local Government Sector. 129 service provided. In these measures, a shift in population could appear incorrectly as a change in productivity. The availability o f data has dictated the selection o f outputs, and aggregate data on state and local governm ent operations is not generally available. Data that is collected nationally, such as crime rates, does not lend itself to productivity calculations, and data which would be useful for output measurem ent, such as tons o f solid waste collected, is not tabulated nationally. O utput data is available for state and local government Enter prise Funds, which account for about seven percent o f all state and local government expenditures. Governm ent services included in Enterprise Funds are: toll highways, water transport, airports, li quor stores, parking, off-track betting, lotteries, transit and water supply system s, gas and electical utilities, housing and urban re newal, and sewerage. Enterprise Funds form the only area where the federal governm ent calculates state and local government produc tivity on a continuing basis. These services are managed like private businesses; they sell goods and services, make profits or losses, and pay taxes. Changes in Enterprise Fund activity are reflected in the BLS quarterly index o f private sector productivity. The process used in calculating Enterprise Fund outputs is to take total sales, add any governm ent subsidies, and deflate to ob tain the outputs. These statistics are drawn from the annual census o f governments and are supplem ented with trade association in formation and other data. The labor data is also taken from the same sources. E m ploym ent data is taken from the current em ploy ment survey by BLS. State and local governm ent Enterprise Funds are currently in cluded in private sector non-farm business productivity calcula tions. It would be possible to identify Enterprise Funds separately, by service, and calculate a specific state and local government Enterprise Fund productivity index if that were desired. C U R R E N T E F F O R T S . Research on state and local government productivity m easurement has decreased in recent years, partly due to the term ination o f the N ational Center on Productivity and Quality o f Working Life. Financial support from the N ational Sci ence Foundation and the D epartm ent o f H ousing and Urban D evelopm ent has also decreased. However, BLS has launched a new effort. Its investigation assesses the possibility o f calculating state and local governm ent productivity indexes and gross output measures. The effort is similar to those underway in individual industries and the federal government. The services focused on include state liquor stores, electric pow er distribution, mass transit, elem entary and secondary education, and hospitals and roads. In each case, researchers exam ine prior studies, specify a series o f outputs, identify quality or service factors that m ust be adjusted for, survey the available data, id en tify labor input data, and docu m ent the results. If researchers can not calculate an index from existing data, they suggest procedures to accum ulate data and esti mate resources. The project has been underway for only a short time, and has focused almost entirely on the Enterprise Funds, but it has yielded several tentative findings. Som e service areas, such as mass transit and public power have been extensively researched and there is general agreement about m ethods o f m easurement for these areas. In other service areas, such as liquor stores, there has been little research on productivity techniques, but evidently measurement o f these activities does not present serious problems. In other areas, such as education, there is considerable research but little agreement about productivity measurement. Also, some o f the data necessary for com puting a state and local productivity index is readily available from federal sources (e.g. public power statistics); other data appears tob e available from the states (e.g.liquor stores); and some data is not currently available but the Departm ent o f Transportation is now devising a system that should eventually pro vide the needed inform ation. Finally, the study indicates that each service area must be exam ined in depth. Very little knowledge or data can be transferred from one service area to another. As far as the federal government is concerned, the clim ate is not bright for new initiatives in this area. The National Productivity Council recently concluded that the federal government should not make a major investm ent in the measurement o f state and local governm ent productivity: Th e costs and relative benefits o f a federal effort in this area com pa re d to o th e r forms of federal s uppor t do n o t w arra nt a m ajor federal invest ment at this time. More analysis o f the c once ptual proble ms and approaches should be made. In the meantime , federal agencies should be encour aged to c ontinue their individual efforts to s upp ort state and local gove rnment produc tiv ity m e asu re ment and, where possible within their own budget priorities, ex pan d such e ffo r ts .19 F U T U R E D I R E C T I O N S . One thrust o f the BLS study o f state and local government productivity measurement is to identify those areas needing additional research. The m ost difficult issue, o f course, is output measurement, particularly in areas, such as edu cation, where there is a large body o f research hut little agreement on measurement approaches, or parks and recreation, where there is little research and no agreement on productivity approaches. Most state and local govenm ent services fall into these two categories. Related to the quantity o f outputs is the quality and level o f service. The need to account for quality differences when calcu lating state and local productivity has been discussed at length. There has been little research on the impact quality variations have on the production costs o f specific state and local government ser vices. Properly adjusting for changes requires a thorough under standing o f these relationships. Data availability is an im portant research issue in its own right. Given tod ay’s fiscal restraints, it is almost impossible to collect vast am ounts o f data. In some cases, it should be possible to use existing data to com pute state and local government productivity indexes. In other instances, it may be necessary to establish new data col lection procedures. For each service area, it is necessary to deter mine the m ost cost-effective way to fill the gaps in existing data. 19 N a tio n a l P r o d u c tiv ity C o u r.c il, m ent 1‘roductivity Im provem ent Federal Actions to Support State and Local Govern (W a s h in g to n , D .C .: N a tio n a l P ro d u c tiv ity C o u n c il, 1 9 7 9 ) , v ii. 130 Inform ation on the quantity o f labor hours is necessary for calculations o f state and local government labor productivity. Reports on the state and local governm ent work force in current surveys, such as the Census o f G overnments, Current Population Survey, and U nem ploym ent Insurance Report, have major lim ita tions. A system atic exam ination o f the current situation and the opportunities for m odification is needed. This exam ination should assess m ethods o f indicating shifts in the com position o f the work force. For m ost state and local governm ent operations, labor is the m ost im portant resource, and in som e cases, it accounts for eightyfive to ninety percent o f operating costs. Thus, it is only appropri ate that state and local governm ent productivity programs start by focusing on labor productivity. However, for som e services such as streets, pow er utilities, and water and sewer system s, where capital input is a substantial factor, an additional measure o f m ulti factor productivity including labor and capital is desirable. By addressing a lim ited number o f state and local governm ent service areas, it should be possible to develop a better appreciation for the problems and opportunities in developing efficiency-based produc tivity indexes. BLS has used this approach for its industry work and its state and local governm ent work. Conclusion A lthough public sector productivity measurem ent has been e x tensively studied and a system of productivity reporting has been established at the federal level, much research and additional work remain. A m bitious output definitions and measures for e f ficiency-type productivity measurement must be elim inated or refined, and innovative approaches to output measurement must be developed so that the system o f productivity reporting can e x tend to areas such as research and developm ent and defense acti vities. Future research efforts on input measures should be directed to developing measures that take into account changes in com p o sition o f labor input and include other factor inputs such as capital. These activities are applicable to productivity m easurement for federal and state and local governm ent activities although the ap proaches will have to vary depending on the nature o f the activity. At the same tim e, research directed toward the developm ent o f effectiveness-type measures should be continued. However, resolution o f the conceptual and measurement problems for these types o f measures may be less promising. Part IV„ International Comparisons Comparable measures of productivity and labor costs for industrial countries are described here. The first report represents the latest in a regular, annual series, and shows how the measures are applied and analyzed. The broad international setting within which significant differences in productivity trends occur is discuss ed, and some of the reasons for the differences are suggested. Background From its inception, the Bureau has collected and published statistical information on labor conditions and developments abroad. Foreign labor research and statistical analyses have been undertaken because (1) in formation on labor conditions published by a majority of foreign countries is not readily available to U.S. labor representatives, employers, Government officials, and others, and is often not available in English; (2) often, only an expert can judge the quality of foreign statistical sources; (3) comparisons between U.S. and foreign labor conditions shed light on U.S. economic performance relative to other industrial nations; and (4) comparisons provide information on the competitive position of the United States in foreign trade, which has an important influence on the U.S. economy and employment. Description of measures The b l s foreign labor statistical reports cover a variety of international comparative measures, mainly for the Western industrial countries. The principal measures cover the labor force, employment, and unemployment; productivity and labor costs; hourly compensation of manufacturing production workers; and trends in consumer prices. Hourly compensation. Measures of total compensation per hour worked for production workers in all manufac turing and in over 30 selected manufacturing industries are prepared annually for about 30 countries. The measures are developed from data on average earnings, as published by each country, plus information on other direct payments to the workers and employer expen ditures for legally required insurance programs and con tractual and private benefit plans. They are expressed in national currency and in U.S. dollars at prevailing com mercial exchange rates. Hourly compensation, when converted to U.S. dollars at commercial exchange rates, indicates comparative levels of employer labor costs. It does not indicate relative living standards of workers or the purchasing power of their income. Prices of goods and services vary greatly among countries and commer cial exchange rates are not reliable indicators of relative differences in prices. Productivity and labor costs. Comparative trends in manufacturing productivity (output per hour), hourly compensation, unit labor costs (labor compensation per unit of output), and related measures are compiled on an annual-average basis for the United States, Canada, Japan, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. Trends are expressd in index form (1977= 100) and as percen tage changes at annual rates. For most countries, the series begin with 1950. Indexes of unit labor costs for foreign countries are calculated in national currency and in U.S. dollars converted at prevailing commercial ex changed rates. Comparative levels and trends in productivity and labor costs in the iron and steel industry in the United States, Japan, France, Germany, and the United Kingdom have been compiled annually beginning with 1964. The measures express levels of foreign output per hour, hourly compensation, and unit labor costs relative to the U.S. level (United States = 100). They also show trends in index form (1977 = 100) and at annual rates of change. Comparative levels (United States =100) and trends (1977= 100) in gross domestic product (GDP), g d p per capita, and g d p per employed person are calculated on an average-annual basis for th United States, Canada, Ja p an , Belgium, France, G erm any, Italy, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom beginning with 1950. The g d p level comparisons, which are based on estimated purchasing-power-parity exchange rates, are benchmarked to data from the United Nations Interna tional Comparison Project. Purchasing-power-parity exchange rates represent the number of foreign currency units required to buy goods and services equivalent to what can be purchased with one unit of U.S. currency. A common practice has been to base such comparisons on official market exchange rates. However, market ex change rates seldom reflect the relative purchasing power of different currencies. 131 Analysis and presentation The presentation of foreign labor statistics varies with the degree of analysis and major use of the data. Com prehensive bulletins have been published, covering manufacturing productivity and labor cost trends, steel productivity and costs, unemployment and labor force comparisons, and youth unemployment comparisons. For more current developments, articles are published periodically in the Monthly Labor Review. Also, an an nual news release is issued on comparative trends in manufacturing productivity and labor costs. The b l s Handbook o f Labor Statistics and the Bureau of the Census’ Statistical Abstract o f the United States publish many of the principal foreign data series, and some series are published in the annual Economic Report o f the President. Many unpublished tabulations of current comparative data are available on request. Analyses of international labor statistics focus upon comparisons with U.S. data. Wherever possible, foreign data are adjusted to U.S. definitions and concepts to facilitate comparisons; for example, the adjustment of foreign unemployment rates to approximate U.S. con cepts and the adjustment of production worker earnings to total hourly compensation. Productivity and unit labor cost data are analyzed to explain the relative contributions of changes in output, employment, average hours, compensation, and ex change rates upon changes in the measures. Changes in employee compensation are analyzed to determine the relative contributions of direct pay and other elements of compensation. 132 International trends in productivity and labor costs Output per employee hour in manufacturing generally improved and unit labor cost trends moderated in the US. and 10 other nations in 1981; relative productivity and labor cost indexes are introduced P a t r ic ia C a p d e v ie l l e , D o n a t o A l v a r e z , a n d B r ia n C o o p e r Manufacturing productivity increased in 1981 in the United States, Japan, and most European countries studied, with gains ranging from about 2 to 4 percent in the United States, Japan, France, Germany,1 Italy, and the Netherlands, to almost 6 percent in the United Kingdom and Denmark, and more than 7 percent in Belgium. In Canada and Sweden, productivity remained essentially unchanged. These productivity changes occurred in what was for most countries the second year of recession. In most European countries, productivity rose because employ ment and hours declined more than output. In the United States, Canada, and Japan, productivity gains were accompanied by modest output growth— tempo rary recoveries from 1980 declines in the United States and Canada. Unit labor cost increases, which reflect changes in both productivity and hourly compensation costs, ranged from 2 to 5 percent in Japan, Germany, Bel gium, Denmark, and the Netherlands, up to 15 percent in France and 18 percent in Italy. When measured in U.S. dollars, however, unit labor costs declined substan tially in all the European countries— 5 to 20 percent— because of the sharp appreciation of the dollar, while rising 7 to 8 percent in Canada and Japan as well as in the United States. Patricia Capdevielle, Donato Alvarez, and Brian Cooper are econo mists in the Division of Foreign Labor Statistics and Trade, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Reprinted from the M o n th ly L a b o r R eview , December 1982. 133 While the 1981 appreciation of the dollar partially offset the lower long-term U.S. cost trend, unit labor costs in the United States nevertheless declined 29 per cent between 1970 and 1981, relative to the average costs of our trade competitors. Unit labor costs in Can ada, Belgium, Denmark, the Netherlands, and Italy also declined relative to those of their trade competitors while those of Japan, France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and Sweden increased. This article describes developments in manufacturing productivity (as measured by output per hour), hourly compensation, and unit labor costs in 1981, and com pares the 1980-81 trends with those of the 1974—75 re cession, for the United States, Canada, Japan, France, Germany, Italy, the United Kingdom, and four smaller European countries— Belgium, Denmark, the Nether lands, and Sweden.2 Percent changes in productivity, la bor costs, and related measures for selected periods and for each year from 1973 are shown in tables 1 through 3;3 percent changes are also presented for the eight Eu ropean countries and for the 10 foreign countries com bined.4 (Annual indexes for the years 1950 to 1981 are available from the authors.) The data for 1981 are based on preliminary underlying statistics, while those for other recent years reflect revised underlying statistics for several countries. Although the productivity measure relates output to the hours of persons employed in manufacturing, it does not measure the specific contributions of labor as a single factor of production. Rather, it reflects the joint effects of many influences, including new technology, Output. With the exception of a small gain in Denmark, manufacturing output fell in each of the European countries in 1981—by more than 6 percent in the Unit ed Kingdom and about 1 to 4 percent in the other countries. In the non-Scandinavian countries, productiv ity increased because employment and hours declined even more than output. Most of Denmark’s productivi ty gain also resulted from decreases in employment and hours. In Sweden, hours and output fell equally. The 1981 drop in British output followed an even larger 1980 decline of 9 percent. For France and Bel gium, 1981 marked the second consecutive year of de clining output, but the 1980 declines were under 1 percent. Germany, Denmark, Sweden, and the Nether lands had zero or only slight 1980 output increases — under 1 percent— while Italy had a more substantial gain. In most countries, output turned down during the first half of 1980, and showed little if any recovery by late 1981 or early 1982. Only in Italy did output recov er in late 1980 and turn down again in 1981. In the United States and Canada, 1980 manufactur ing output levels declined about 3 to 4 percent from previous year levels, but 1981 annual output levels were up 2 percent. In both countries, manufacturing produc tion dropped in the second quarter of 1980, recovered in the fourth quarter, then turned down again during the second half of 1981. In Japan, manufacturing out put increased more than 9 percent in 1980, and rose an other 3 percent in 1981, but then turned down during the first half of 1982. capital investment, the level of output, capacity utiliza tion, energy use, and managerial effectiveness, as well as the skills and efforts of the work force. This article also introduces new measures of relative trends in productivity and labor costs. Table 5 presents indexes of relative output per hour, hourly compensa tion, and unit labor costs in national currency and in U.S. dollars for the 11 countries. Each relative index represents the ratio of a country’s own index to a weighted geometric average of the corresponding index es for the other 10 countries; the weights used to com bine the other country indexes reflect the relative importance of each country as a manufacturing trade competitor (table 4). Productivity trends In 1981, manufacturing productivity increased by more than 7 percent in Belgium, almost 6 percent in the United Kingdom and Denmark, and about 2 to 4 per cent in the United States, Japan, France, Germany, Ita ly, and the Netherlands. In Canada and Sweden, it rose less than 0.5 percent. (See table 1.) For the United States, the 1981 productivity gain was the largest annual increase since 1976. And for Belgium and the United Kingdom, the 1981 gains were the larg est in many years. For Japan and Italy, the 1981 in creases represent substantial slowdowns from large 1980 gains, but for most other countries, they were improve ments over small gains or productivity declines in the previous year. Table 1. Annual percent changes in manufacturing productivity and output, 11 countries, 1960-81 Eight European countries Ten foreign countries United States Canada Japan France Germany Italy United Kingdom Belgium 2.7 3.0 1.7 3.6 4.5 1.4 9.2 10.7 6.8 5.5 6.0 4.6 5.2 5.5 4.5 5.8 6.9 3.7 3.6 4.3 2.2 7.2 7.0 6.2 6.1 6.4 4.1 7.1 7.6 5.1 5.0 6.7 2.2 5.3 5.8 4.1 5.9 6.4 4.7 ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... -2.4 2.9 4.4 2.5 .9 .7 .2 2.8 2.2 -2.6 5.3 4.0 1.6 1.7 -3.3 .3 2.4 3.9 9.4 7.2 7.9 8.9 6.8 3.2 3.5 3.1 8.2 5.1 5.7 4.9 1.6 1.6 5.4 5.3 7.1 4.9 3.3 4.9 1.4 2.7 4.9 -4.4 8.6 1.1 3.0 7.3 5.8 3.4 .8 -2.0 4.0 1.6 3.3 3.3 5.9 5.8 4.4 10.4 6.5 5.0 6.5 3.1 7.3 3.3 10.4 3.8 2.1 2.4 5.8 1.4 5.6 8.3 -1.8 12.8 4.1 6.6 4.9 1.3 3.1 3.6 -.4 1.0 -1.5 4.3 8.4 1.2 .1 4.1 1.6 7.2 3.3 4.0 5.3 2.8 3.8 3.8 2.0 7.5 4.3 4.9 6.1 3.6 3.3 Output: 1960-81 ..................... 1960-73 ..................... 1973-81 ...................... 3.6 4.7 2.3 4.8 6.3 2.0 10.0 13.0 6.5 5.2 6.6 2.3 3.8 5.2 1.9 5.4 6.8 3.3 1.6 3.0 -1.7 5.0 6.5 1.1 4.0 5.2 1.8 4.7 6.4 1.7 3.2 5.1 -.3 4.0 5.4 1.5 5.3 6.8 2.9 -4.2 -7.1 9.6 6.9 5.3 2.7 -4.3 2.3 3.6 -5.9 5.9 2.0 5.0 4.7 -3.1 1.6 -2.0 -4.0 13.3 7.3 7.3 9.9 9.4 3.2 3.2 -2.1 7.0 3.7 3.2 2.6 -.1 -2.7 -.3 -4.8 8.0 2.4 1.3 4.8 .5 -1.4 6.4 -9.7 12.6 2.1 1.8 6.7 6.3 -1.0 -1.2 -7.0 2.0 1.9 4.6 -7.4 8.6 .7 .9 3.7 -1.4 -2.5 1.5 -2.1 4.8 .6 .7 6.5 .0 .5 4.4 -6.7 8.0 .9 2.8 2.7 .9 -.9 4.8 -1.5 -.4 -5.6 -1.3 6.9 .0 -3.6 1.8 -5.2 7.0 2.1 1.6 3.8 -.4 -2.4 -.9 -5.0 8.5 3.5 3.4 5.6 2.4 -.4 Year Output per hour: 1960-81 ..................... 1960-73 ...................... 1973-81 ...................... 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 N o te: ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... Rates of change computed fromthe least squares trend of the logarithms of the index numbers. 134 .6 .6 .2 -9.1 -6.3 Denmark Netherlands Sweden Employment and hours. Manufacturing employment and aggregate hours both increased only in .Canada in 1981; in Japan, employment rose slightly but total hours were essentially unchanged. In 1980, hours had increased slightly in Canada and by more than 2 percent in Ja pan. In the United States, employment and hours de clined only slightly in 1981, after falling more than 3 percent in 1980. (See table 2.) In Europe, employment declined 10 percent in the United Kingdom and 2 to 6 percent in the other countries in 1981. Those declines followed 1980 drops of 6 percent in the United Kingdom and 1 to 2 percent in most of the other countries. Employment had in creased slightly in Germany in 1980 and was essentially unchanged in Italy and Sweden. Aggregate hours fell even more than employment in 1981— except in Den mark—as average hours were also reduced. Comparisons with 1974-75. Comparisons of develop ments during the years 1980 and 1981 with the recession of 1974-75 cannot be precise, particularly when dealing with annual average data, because of dif ferences among countries in the extent and timing of the 1974-75 recession and the 1980-81 downturns. Nevertheless, certain broad comparisons can be made. Over the 1974—75 period, manufacturing output fell in one or both years in all 11 countries studied. During 1980-81, neither Japan nor Denmark experienced annu al average declines in output, although Denmark had virtually no output growth over the period and Japa nese output slowed sharply in 1981; most of the other countries had smaller output declines than in 1974—75. However, there were exceptions. The recent output de clines in the United Kingdom were substantially greater than during 1974-75, and those in France and Sweden also appear to have been larger. Only in the United States did output regain its pre-1974 average rate of growth during the 1976-79 recovery period. As in the case of output, manufacturing employment and hours declined less sharply during 1980-81 than during 1974-75 in most of the countries studied. For example, German employment declined about 2 percent in 1980-81, compared with 9 percent in 1974—75, and total hours declined 5 percent versus 15 percent. Again, major exceptions were France, where employment and hours declined somewhat more in 1980-81, and the United Kingdom, where the recent declines— 16 per cent for employment and 21 percent for total hours— were substantially greater than those in 1974—75. In Sweden, the employment effects of the 1974—75 reces sion were delayed; therefore, direct comparison between the two periods is not appropriate. Although employment losses over the 2-year period of 1980-81 were less severe in most countries than in 1974—75, employment in most of Europe also declined during the intervening 1976-79 period. The rate of de cline ranged from about 1 percent per year in France and Germany to almost 4 percent annually in Belgium. Only in Denmark and Italy was employment essentially stable during the recovery period. By 1981, employment in manufacturing was down 6, 11, and 14 percent from 1973 levels in Sweden, France, and Germany; 17 per cent in Denmark and the Netherlands; and almost 25 percent in Belgium and the United Kingdom. In con trast, employment in the United States and Canada was higher in 1981 than in 1973. All European countries have taken actions, through collective bargaining or government programs, to short en average hours worked to preserve manufacturing jobs. Most countries have partial unemployment benefit programs to provide wage replacement to employees on short work schedules for economic reasons. In addition, minimum annual holiday (vacation) entitlements have been increased in Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden, and the United Kingdom (and are scheduled to increase in France) as a job creation measure as well as a fringe benefit improvement. (In Italy, on the other hand, several national holidays were abolished in 1977 as a labor cost cutting measure, although many employ ees receive extra annual holidays in lieu of the national holidays.) In Belgium, the standard workweek was shortened through collective bargaining from 40 hours in 1977 to 38 hours for most employees in 1981; the shorter hours are provided as either a shorter workweek or a longer annual holiday. Given the relative output and employee-hours changes, manufacturing productivity increased in most countries during both the 1974—75 recession and in 1980-81. The following tabulation shows average annual productivity changes over the two periods: 1974-75 1980-81 C anada ................................. Japan .................................... France ................................. G e rm a n y ............................... I t a l y ....................................... U nited K ingdom .............. Belgium .............................. D e n m a rk ............................... N e th e rla n d s ......................... S w e d e n ................................. 0.2 -.2 3.2 3.3 5.4 .2 -.6 5.1 6.8 3.2 1.6 1.5 -1.5 5.0 1.6 2.1 4.6 3.2 5.2 3.5 2.2 .7 In the United States, Japan, Italy, and the United King dom, the productivity trend was higher during 1980-81, while productivity gains were higher during 1974—75 in France, Germany, Denmark, the Netherlands, and Swe den. In Belgium, productivity rose equally in both peri ods. In Canada, productivity declined in both periods. H o u rly com pensation Hourly compensation increases in 1981 varied considerably among the 11 countries studied. The 135 Table 2. Annua! percent changes in manufacturing employment and hours, 11 countries, 1960-81 Sweden Eight European countries -2.3 -1.1 -3.2 -1.7 -1.5 -2.5 -1.2 -.4 -2.4 -.6 .4 -1.7 -1.7 -11.3 ' 1.0 -1.4 -1.7 .7 -1.4 -4.8 -3.6 -5.0 -4.3 -3.0 -3.6 -2.1 -.4 -3.8 1.2 -1.1 -1.5 -4.1 -5.4 -1.3 -1.2 -3.7 -2.2 -6.7 -.2 -1.2 -2.3 -1.5 -3.1 -6.0 -2.7 -6.8 1.0 -.8 -1.5 -.5 -1.1 -3.7 -.7 .6 -3.6 -.7 .2 -1.8 -1.0 .0 -2.4 -.3 -.2 -1.0 -.2 .5 -1.7 .3 1.1 -1.2 1.9 -3.8 -2.2 -.4 -2.4 -2.5 -6.0 -10.1 1.1 -6.1 -4.1 -3.9 -4.1 -2.7 -1.9 -5.5 -3.6 -8.4 .6 -.5 -.5 .8 -2.0 -4.8 -.4 -3.2 -4.0 -2.7 -2.5 -1.0 -1.2 -3.3 2.4 .9 -.2 -3.5 -2.8 .3 -.1 -3.2 .3 -3.9 -1.7 -.7 -1.5 -.9 -1.6 -4.5 .4 -4.2 -1.0 -.6 -1.2 -.5 -.3 -2.8 -1.4 -1.5 -.3 -.9 -.7 -1.0 -1.4 -1.0 -1.2 -1.3 -1.4 -.5 -1.2 -1.1 -.8 -1.4 -1.3 -1.5 -1.0 -.9 -.9 -.8 -.8 -.5 -1.1 -5.1 3.5 .9 -.2 -1.0 .3 -2.4 -3.8 -1.3 .3 .6 -.2 -.5 -3.9 -1.6 -2.2 -5.6 2.5 -1.6 .3 .1 -2.5 -3.8 2.0 -3.2 .4 -.9 -1.2 -.1 .7 .0 -3.2 -1.8 -.3 -.3 -1.1 -1.1 .8 -.6 -1.1 -2.0 -1.3 -.7 -2.6 -1.6 -1.1 -.6 -2.5 -2.9 1.5 -.4 -.8 -.6 -1.5 -1.6 -3.1 -2.8 2.0 -.2 -.3 .0 -.8 -.9 United States Canada Japan France Germany Italy United Kingdom Aggregate hours: 1960-81 ..................... 1960-73 ..................... 1973-81 .. .................. 0.9 1.6 .6 1.1 1.7 .5 0.7 2.1 -.3 -0.2 .6 -2.2 -1.3 -.2 -2.5 -0.4 -.1 -.4 -1.9 -1.2 -3.8 -2.0 -1.1 -2.2 ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... -1.9 -9.7 4.9 4.2 4.4 2.0 -4.5 -.5 1.4 -3.4 .5 -2.0 3.4 2.9 .2 1.3 -4.3 -7.6 3.6 .1 -.5 1.0 2.5 -.1 -2.1 -.5 -4.8 -1.2 -.3 -5.0 -1.1 -1.3 -2.3 -2.2 -1.7 -4.3 -5.4 -9.6 .8 -2.4 -1.9 -.1 -.9 -4.0 1.4 -5.5 3.8 1.0 -1.2 -.6 .5 -4.3 -2.0 -5.1 -1.9 .2 -2.6 -3.0 -9.6 -11.5 -11.3 -1.7 -5.4 -3.9 -2.6 -4.3 -9.2 Employment: 1960-81 ..................... 1960-73 ..................... 1973-81 ..................... .9 1.5 .7 1.4 1.9 .8 1.5 3.0 -.4 .5 1.2 -1.4 -.4 .5 -1.6 1.1 1.4 .0 -1.1 -.5 -2.9 ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... -.4 -8.6 3.7 3.6 4.2 2.6 -3.4 -.5 2.0 -2.2 .4 -2.0 3.2 3.7 .3 1.8 .2 -5.1 .4 -.2 -1.1 -.1 2.5 .5 1.3 -2.7 -1.0 -.5 -1.6 -1.8 -1.3 -3.6 -2.6 -6.7 -2.4 -.8 -.6 .3 .6 -2.4 2.5 -.4 .2 .1 -1.0 .5 .2 -1.9 Average hours: 1960-81 ..................... 1960-73 ..................... 1973-81 ...................... -.1 .1 -.2 -.3 -.2 -.3 -.8 -.9 .1 -.7 -.5 -.8 -.9 -.8 -.9 -1.5 -1.2 1.2 .6 .2 -.6 -1.0 .0 -.6 -1.1 .1 .0 .3 -.7 -.1 -.5 -4.5 -2.6 3.2 .3 .6 1.1 -.1 -.6 -1.5 -2.3 -.1 -.9 -.7 -.4 -.3 -.7 -2.9 -3.1 3.2 -1.6 -1.4 -.4 -1.5 -1.6 Year 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 N o te: ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... ......................... Belgium Denmark Netherlands Ten foreign countries Rates of change computed fromthe least squares trend of the logarithms of the index numbers. smallest gain was 5 percent in the Netherlands and the largest, 22 percent in Italy. In the United Kingdom and France, the increases were also large— over 16 percent. In Japan and Germany, the gains were relatively small— under 8 percent— while in the United States, Canada, Belgium, Denmark, and Sweden, they were 9 to 12 per cent. (See table 3.) Four countries—the United States, Germany, Den mark, and the United Kingdom— showed some degree of moderation in hourly compensation gains for 1981. In the United Kingdom, there was a substantial slow down from the 24 percent recorded in 1980. (In the Netherlands, a significant slowdown occurred in 1980.) In Canada, Japan, Italy, and Sweden, however, the 1981 increases were higher than those of the previous year, and in France, Belgium, and the Netherlands, the increases in both years were virtually the same. Compared with the hourly compensation trend dur ing the 1974-75 recession, annual rates of increase dur ing the 1980-81 period were considerably lower in every country except the United States and France. In the United States, however, the 1974—75 increases were rel atively small. The moderation in wage gains and other labor costs occurred even though consumer price trends w ere g e n e ra lly a b o u t as h ig h in 1 9 8 0 -8 1 as in 1974—75 — with Japan and Belgium as principal exceptions. However, growing concern with moderating labor costs and containing inflation, as well as preserving manufac turing jobs, had a significant impact on recent compen sation trends. Concerted action was taken in several countries to moderate wage settlements during 1980-81. Temporary pay freezes were imposed in Belgium and the Nether lands and a temporary price freeze was undertaken in Sweden. The Dutch government subsequently imposed statutory pay controls. In several countries with wage indexation systems, the price indexes used were adjust ed to exclude fuel and energy prices, or the cost-of-liv ing allowances ( c o l a ’s) normally payable were reduced or rescinded. In Japan and Germany, annual wage agreements in 1980 and 1981 continued the moderate pattern of recent years. In Japan, the average manufacturing settlement was 6.7 percent in 1980 and 7.6 percent in 1981, and in Germany, the average settlements were 6.7 percent in 1980 and 4.6 percent in 1981. In the United States and 136 additional reductions. Because wage rates are adjusted to compensate for the shorter workweek, the hours re ductions are measured as hourly compensation gains. Wage rates are also indexed for consumer price in creases in Italy, and cost-of-living allowances are paid under collective agreements in Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. In Italy as in Belgium, the indexation system continued unchanged during 198081. In Denmark and Sweden, COLA payments were re stricted. In Denmark, the index used to compute the c o l a ’ s was changed in December 1979 to exclude fuel and energy prices, and was also rebased. As a result, one of the c o l a ’ s was eliminated in 1980. In Sweden, the 1981 pay agreements specified exclusion of energy prices from the consumer price index used in COLA computation. The government imposed a price freeze in September 1981 and cut value-added taxes in Novem ber, and thereby kept the price rise below the COLA threshold (trigger) specified in the pay agreement. In Denmark, early 1981 wage settlements at the in dustry level provided moderate wage increases and re stricted additional company-level wage negotiations. In the United Kingdom, wage-and-salary concessions were made in some impacted companies or industries. In the Netherlands, a pay freeze was imposed from January through April 1980, followed by statutory con trols which were later extended through 1981. No basic wage increases were allowed. Furthermore, the June 1980 cost-of-living adjustment was restricted to a flatrate amount, and the January 1981 adjustment was re duced by 2 percent. In 1981, holiday bonuses were low ered slightly, and extra annual holidays delayed. The Belgian Government imposed a pay freeze in January 1981. The national wage agreement signed in February, under threat of statutory pay controls, pro vided either a 1-percent wage rate increase or an extra hour off the standard workweek by 1983. Wages are indexed for consumer price increases in Belgium, how ever, and the indexation system was not changed. The emphases of recent wage settlements in Belgium have not been basic wage increases but reductions of stan dard hours. Standard weekly hours were reduced from 40 hours per week in 1977 to 38 hours for most work ers by 1980, and the 1981 national agreement allowed Table 3. Annual percent changes in hourly compensation and unit labor costs in manufacturing, 11 countries, 1960-81 Sweden Eight European countries Ten foreign countries 12.9 12.8 9.7 12.0 10.4 13.0 12.0 9.8 13.7 11.9 10.1 12.4 21.0 19.3 11.7 10.6 10.2 11.8 10.9 9.3 19.2 14.3 12.5 8.6 8.7 7.8 5.0 5.3 17.6 21.2 18.5 9.2 11.3 7.8 10.9 12.4 18.3 18.4 13.0 12.0 11.6 12.4 14.9 13.8 21.4 18.0 11.2 11.3 9.8 10.7 12.0 11.5 5.1 3.5 5.6 6.8 5.1 8.0 5.5 4.8 4.4 10.0 6.7 3.5 10.6 6.3 3.8 9.2 5.8 3.5 7.4 24.1 32.5 12.7 10.8 12.8 15.0 22.9 9.7 15.7 16.3 2.5 5.2 2.9 1.1 6.4 2.1 17.1 8.0 7.6 8.4 7.6 5.7 9.4 3.5 16.4 -.3 4.3 1.9 2.8 3.7 2.1 13.5 21.7 17.3 11.0 6.7 -.5 9.6 12.3 13.7 16.6 5.5 8.4 7.2 6.7 11.8 9.7 17.0 15.6 3.5 6.7 4.7 4.3 8.1 7.9 7.1 2.6 15.0 7.8 4.6 8.6 7.9 5.0 7.7 8.7 6.1 8.0 7.7 4.2 9.6 7.6 4.2 9.9 7.2 3.9 8.8 18.5 25.8 -8.5 7.1 24.0 27.3 34.6 -4 .5 15.5 23.2 -2.5 13.3 17.3 8.4 6.8 -19.5 16.0 14.6 2.1 9.1 17.3 10.6 2.2 -18.0 13.9 23.8 -4 .8 12.3 15.8 10.7 4.8 -18.5 11.5 30.2 11.5 8.2 5.6 4.8 11.1 -5.7 11.4 22.6 -5 .0 10.0 18.8 14.5 13.6 -12.0 13.5 19.3 -3.8 9.9 19.3 8.2 8.6 -7.4 United States Canada Japan France Germany Italy United Kingdom Belgium Hourly compensation: 1960-81 ............................. 1960-73 ............................. 1973-81 ............................. 6.9 5.0 9.6 8.7 6.4 11.1 14.8 14.6 9.7 11.9 9.2 15.1 10.1 9.3 9.4 16.2 12.3 19.8 13.1 8.6 19.1 12.6 10.7 12.1 13.2 11.8 12.5 1974 .................................... 1975 .................................... 1976 .................................... 1977 .................................... 1978 .................................... 1979 .................................... 1980 .................................... 1981.................................... 10.6 11.9 8.0 8.3 8.3 9.7 11.8 10.2 15.8 14.2 14.2 11.0 6.7 10.1 9.1 11.1 31.2 17.0 6.7 9.7 5.9 6.5 6.5 7.4 19.6 19.0 14.1 13.7 12.7 13.8 16.6 16.5 15.0 12.4 7.8 10.5 8.5 7.3 8.6 7.5 24.6 28.9 19.8 18.8 14.5 17.6 18.5 22.3 25.0 29.9 17.2 12.6 16.5 18.9 23.6 16.2 22.5 21.4 13.2 12.0 8.0 7.7 9.6 9.6 Unit labor costs: 1960-81 ............................. 1960-73 ............................. 1973-81 ............................. 4.1 1.9 7.7 4.8 1.8 9.5 5.1 3.5 2.7 6.1 3.1 10.0 4.6 3.7 4.7 9.8 5.1 15.5 9.2 4.1 16.6 1974 .................................... 1975 .................................... 1976 .................................... 1977 .................................... 1978 .................................... 1979 .................................... 1980 .................................... 1981.................................... 13.3 8.8 3.4 5.7 7.4 9.0 11.6 7.2 13.3 17.2 8.4 6.7 5.0 8.3 12.8 10.7 28.1 12.6 -2.5 2.4 -1.8 -2.2 -.2 4.0 15.6 15.4 5.5 8.2 6.6 8.5 14.8 14.6 9.1 6.8 .6 5.3 5.0 2.4 7.0 4.7 18.7 34.9 10.4 17.5 11.2 9.6 12.1 18.3 Unit labor costs in U.S. dollars: 1960-81 ............................. 1960-73 ............................. 1973-81 ...................... 4.1 1.9 7.7 4.4 1.9 6.5 7.9 4.9 7.2 6.5 2.8 9.4 9.1 6.1 9.1 1974 .................................... 1975 .................................... 1976 .................................... 1977 .................................... 1978 .................................... 1979 .................................... 1980 .................................... 1981.................................... 13.3 8.8 3.4 5.7 7.4 9.0 11.6 7.2 15.8 12.7 11.9 -1 .0 -2.1 5.4 13.0 8.0 19.0 10.7 -2.4 13.3 26.2 -6.5 -3.5 6.7 6.7 29.6 -5.4 5.1 16.5 14.7 15.7 -10.5 11.9 12.3 -1.8 14.2 21.6 12.0 8.1 -15.7 Year Note: 7.6 ■ 5.4 8.1 6.2 34.5 -13.3 10.5 15.6 12.0 8.9 -10.6 Rates of change computed from the least squares trend of the logarithms of the index numbers. 137 Denmark Netherlands France, there were no government restrictions on wage increases during 1980-81, and wage rate increases followed the consumer price index although there is no formal indexation system. Minimum-wage increases above the price index rate raised average wages further in some lower wage industries. In Italy, the major wage agreements were concluded in 1979 and expired in late 1981. Their wage rate provisions and the indexation system were not limited, although there were discus sions of labor cost reductions and indexation changes for 1982. In Italy and several other European countries, actions were taken to cut employers’ social security tax rates, although in other cases tax rates were raised to fi nance system deficits. U n it labor co sts Unit labor costs, which reflect the interplay between hourly compensation and output per hour, increased about 7 percent in the United States and 10 to 12 per cent in Canada, Sweden, and the United Kingdom in 1981, compared with more than 14 percent in France and 18 percent in Italy, but only 2 to 5 percent in Den mark, Japan, Germany, Belgium, and the Netherlands. (See table 3.) In every country except Japan, France, Italy, and Sweden, unit labor costs increased less in 1981 than in the previous year. In the United Kingdom, the slow down from the 23 percent recorded in 1980 was sub stantial, and reflected both a smaller compensation increase and a larger productivity gain. In most other countries also, the moderation in unit labor costs re flects a slowdown in hourly compensation and improve ments in productivity. In France, the 1981 increase in unit labor costs, as well as in productivity and hourly compensation, was essentially the same as the previous year’s. In Japan and Italy, the acceleration in unit labor costs primarily reflects their productivity slowdowns. The 1980-81 increases in unit labor costs were gener ally much smaller than those of 1974-75 because hourly compensation gains were relatively moderate, in con trast to the substantial wage gains during the 1974-75 recession. The average annual unit labor cost increases for the two periods are shown in the following tabula tion: United States.................. Canada ........................... Japan ............................. France ........................... Germany ...................... Italy............................... United Kingdom ........... Belgium ........................ Denmark ...................... Netherlands .................. Sweden........................... 1974-75 11.0 15.2 20.3 15.5 7.9 26.8 28.3 16.0 12.5 13.2 17.6 1980-81 9.4 11.8 1.9 14.7 5.9 15.2 16.3 4.2 6.4 2.9 10.9 138 For some countries— Japan, Belgium, Denmark, and the Netherlands— the differences are substantial. Even for the countries with the largest unit labor cost in creases in 1980-81— Italy and the United Kingdom— the recent increases are down considerably from 1974— 75 peaks. The differences are less marked for the United States and Germany, which had the smallest 1974-75 unit labor cost increases. In U.S. dollars. In comparing trends in unit labor costs among countries, an important analytical element is the shift in relative currency values through international exchange rate adjustments. In recent years, the number and extent of such adjustments have been so great as to constitute a major variable in competitive assessment. The relationship between exchange rate shifts and unit labor cost trends is partial and indirect but none theless important. The two are linked by the price mechanism, a main determinant of trade directions and competitive relationships. Because labor cost is the prin cipal cost factor in the production of manufactured goods, it exerts a strong influence on the price at which goods can be offered in international markets. Relative changes in exchange rates alter the effect of relative changes in costs in national currency. Consequently, in assessing relative changes in unit labor costs in competi tive terms, changes in exchange rates need to be taken into account. Changes in currency exchange rates in 1981 had a significant effect on relative changes in unit labor costs measured in U.S. dollars. The dollar appreciated sub stantially— from about 15 percent to more than 30 per cent— relative to the European currencies. (By September 1982, the dollar had further appreciated— compared with the annual average for 1981 — 10 per cent versus the German mark and Dutch guilder, and 8 to 30 percent versus the other European currencies.) The dollar also appreciated somewhat relative to the Canadian dollar, but declined slightly versus the Japa nese yen. (By September 1982, however, the dollar had appreciated 19 percent versus the yen, as well as anoth er 3 percent versus the Canadian dollar.) Therefore, when measured in U.S. dollars, unit labor costs in the European countries fell about 5 percent in Sweden and the United Kingdom; 11 percent in France and Italy; 16 percent in Germany; and 18 to 20 percent in Belgium, the Netherlands, and Denmark. In U.S. dollars, unit labor costs increased 8 percent in Canada and 7 percent in Japan— about the same rate as for U.S. costs. (See table 3.) The largest contrast was between Japan and Germa ny. On a national currency basis, they had increases of 4 and 5 percent, respectively. On a U.S. dollar basis, Japanese unit labor costs rose 7 percent while German unit labor costs fell 16 percent. lowing section introduces indexes of trade-weighted rel ative trends in manufacturing productivity, hourly com pensation, and unit labor costs in national currency, as well as unit labor costs in U.S. dollars. Because trade involves individual products, the use of aggregate manufacturing measures as indicators of trade competitiveness has certain limitations. In general, labor productivity growth rates in export sectors probably ex ceed those for manufacturing as a whole. On the other hand, hourly compensation tends to grow at similar rates in all manufacturing sectors within a country. Overall, therefore, trend measures for the total manu facturing sector would be expected to overstate, to some extent, the growth of unit labor costs for the export sec tor. However, this would probably be true for every country, and, in any case, the measures are intended to represent relative changes only. In addition, exchange rate changes have a significant effect on relative unit la bor cost developments, and these affect unit labor costs in all manufacturing industries equally. While the 5-percent decline in the United Kingdom was not as large as in the other European countries, it was the sharpest trend reversal among all the countries, for British unit labor costs had increased 35 percent in 1980. Unit labor costs in Japan had posted a small de cline in 1980; among the other countries, they had risen 2 to 16 percent. The trend in unit labor costs in U.S. dollars for the 1980-81 period differs significantly from that for the years 1974-75 in most countries covered. First, unit la bor costs in national currency increased much less dur ing 1980-1981 in most countries. Secondly, the U.S. dollar appreciated versus all European currencies and the Canadian dollar in 1981, while in 1974—75, the dol lar appreciated versus the Japanese yen, Italian lira, and British pound but depreciated versus all the other cur rencies. Therefore, unit labor costs in U.S. dollars in creased substantially more in most other countries than in the United States during the 1974—75 recession, while in the 1980-81 period, unit labor costs in U.S. dollars declined in all European countries covered. Index calculation methods. The indexes of relative trends in manufacturing productivity and labor costs represent ratios of each country’s own indexes to weighted geometric averages of the corresponding in dexes for the other 10 “competitor” countries. The weights used to combine the other 10 countries’ indexes into an average “competitors” index reflect the relative importance of each country as a manufacturing trade competitor. The weights are those developed by the IMF for computation of their own relative cost and price indicators— except that they have been adjusted from the 14-country coverage of the IMF series to the 11-country coverage of the BLS series.6 The weights are based on disaggregated trade data for manufacturers in 1975. They take into account the relative importance of each country’s trading partners in its direct bilateral trade with them and the relative importance of those partners in competition in “third country” markets, ad- Relative productivity and cost trends Indexes of manufacturing productivity and labor costs are often used in analyses of changes in the rela tive competitive position of countries in the internation al trade of manufactures. Unit labor costs are an important element in determining the underlying price competitiveness of manufactured products, with relative productivity and hourly compensation trends determin ing unit labor cost performance. The International Monetary Fund (IM F) and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development ( o e c d ) publish indexes for key cost and price measures—including unit labor costs in U.S. dollars— which show the trend of each country’s own indicators relative to those of other in dustrial (competitor) countries.5The BLS unit labor cost measures are used in the computation of the IMF and OECD indicators for most countries they cover. The fol Table 4. Trade weights used to compute competitor indexes [In percent] Competitor country Reference country United S ta te s ............................... C a nada........................................ Japan .......................................... Belgium ........................................ D enm ark...................................... France .......................................... G erm any...................................... Ita ly ............................................... Netherlands................................. Sw eden........................................ United Kingdom ........................... Note: United States Canada Japan Belgium Denmark France Germany Italy Netherlands Sweden United Kingdom 76.9 36.2 5.7 12.7 16.7 17.5 16.3 11.9 18.0 25.0 19.3 — 2.9 .5 .9 1.1 1.5 1.4 .7 3.5 2.0 17.3 5.1 — 6.2 10.3 11.9 12.1 12.2 9.1 11.6 11.6 3.3 .9 3.8 — 2.9 4.0 7.8 4.5 8.7 3.3 5.4 1.1 .2 1.4 .9 — 1.3 1.2 1.4 1.5 4.8 2.1 13.1 2.5 11.3 22.9 9.6 — 21.0 10.8 16.5 10.3 13.7 18.8 5.3 18.2 34.1 23.4 31.1 — 34.3 33.9 23.4 22.5 7.4 1.7 7.4 7.7 6.4 13.3 12.8 — 4.2 6.5 7.8 4.9 .9 4.4 9.5 4.7 5.0 8.1 4.9 — 3.8 5.3 3.2 2.0 3.7 2.4 13.2 3.0 5.3 2.8 2.7 — 4.7 11.6 4.5 10.8 10.1 15.9 12.5 12.8 11.5 10.7 14.8 — Because of rounding, sums of individual items may not equal 100.0. 139 Relative productivity trends. The countries in which manufacturing productivity grew more rapidly than that of trade competitors since 1970 were Japan, Belgium, the Netherlands, and Denmark. Productivity had risen 11 to 12 percent more in Denmark and the Netherlands and 16 percent more in Japan and Belgium by 1976. By 1981, their relative trends had diverged: For Japan, pro ductivity gains were 41 percent higher and for Belgium, 29 percent, while in Denmark and the Netherlands the gains were 12 and 13 percent higher. justed for the importance of foreign trade to the manu facturing sector as a whole in each country.7 Table 4 shows the weights used for each of the 11 countries. The relative indexes of output per hour, hourly com pensation, and unit labor costs in national currency and in U.S. dollars are shown in table 5. The underlying “own country” and “competitor countries” indexes used to compute the relative indexes, and indexes of trade-weighted exchange rates, not shown in table 5, are available from the authors. Table 5. Relative indexes of output per hour, hourly compensation, and unit labor costs in manufacturing, 11 countries, 1970-81 [1970 = 100] United States Canada Japan France Germany Italy United Kingdom Belgium Denmark Netherlands Sweden 100.0 100.7 98.5 96.5 91.0 92.6 100.0 101.2 100.0 100.3 103.6 98.4 100.0 101.0 105.9 109.5 110.2 112.3 100.0 100.4 98.9 96.9 97.2 98.4 100.0 98.9 98.0 96.2 98.7 102.9 100.0 98.1 99.0 103.8 105.8 98.1 100.0 98.7 99.4 98.4 96.5 92.1 100.0 101.4 105.6 109.2 111.1 113.4 100.0 101.2 102.2 105.2 105.5 114.6 100.0 101.7 102.4 105.5 110.6 105.4 100.0 100.0 98.2 98.3 99.2 96.5 ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ 90.3 88.8 85.9 82.3 81.0 81.1 98.7 99.8 99.6 99.4 95.4 93.0 115.9 120.4 126.3 132.9 140.3 140.5 99.6 101.0 103.0 103.0 102.3 100.6 102.8 104.2 103.2 103.1 102.1 101.6 99.6 96.6 95.8 98.3 102.1 102.3 89.5 87.5 87.1 86.0 84.8 87.4 116.5 119.2 120.0 121.7 123.1 128.5 112.0 110.7 109.1 109.8 109.2 111.9 111.2 111.0 113.9 113.9 113.1 112.9 91.4 86.6 87.2 90.4 89.8 87.0 Hourly compensation: 1970 ........................................ 1971 ........................................ 1972 ........................................ 1973 ........................................ 1974 ........................................ 1975 ........................................ 100.0 94.2 88.7 82.4 75.4 71.4 100.0 99.8 99.9 100.7 103.0 103.5 100.0 104.8 110.5 120.8 136.3 136.5 100.0 99.3 99.2 98.4 98.7 99.7 100.0 99.8 98.7 96.3 91.8 86.1 100.0 103.0 106.1 118.3 124.4 137.9 100.0 102.9 105.1 102.5 108.7 121.7 100.0 101.8 105.6 107.4 110.5 114.2 100.0 102.2 101.3 107.8 109.3 109.9 100.0 101.8 104.6 109.4 109.7 106.7 100.0 100.2 100.7 98.8 97.4 100.3 ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ 68.6 66.6 65.8 65.2 65.3 64.5 108.4 110.4 108.2 108.3 105.5 106.1 130.6 129.4 124.3 119.2 112.5 108.1 102.3 104.4 107.0 110.2 114.8 120.5 82.0 80.9 79.2 75.9 72.6 69.0 149.7 161.0 168.3 180.4 192.1 213.5 128.8 130.8 139.5 151.2 168.4 176.6 115.6 115.9 113.2 109.9 107.2 105.3 109.2 108.7 108.4 109.4 107.8 105.6 108.1 105.4 104.1 101.7 95.2 90.2 106.8 105.0 106.1 103.1 101.6 102.7 Unit labor costs in national currency: 1970 ........................................ 1971 ........................................ 1972 ........................................ 1973 ........................................ 1974 ........................................ 1975 ........................................ 100.0 93.6 90.0 85.4 82.9 77.1 100.0 98.6 99.9 100.4 99.4 105.2 100.0 103.7 104.4 110.3 123.6 121.5 100.0 98.9 100.3 101.6 101.6 101.3 100.0 101.0 100.7 100.1 93.0 83.6 100.0 105.0 107.2 113.9 117.7 140.6 100.0 104.3 105.8 104.2 112.7 132.1 100.0 100.4 100.0 98.4 99.5 100.7 100.0 101.0 99.1 102.5 103.6 95.9 100.0 100.1 102.1 103.7 99.1 101.3 100.0 100.2 102.4 100.5 98.2 103.9 ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ 76.0 75.0 76.6 79.3 80.5 79.6 109.9 110.6 108.6 108.9 110.6 114.0 112.8 107.5 98.4 89.7 80.2 76.9 102.7 103.4 103.9 107.0 112.2 119.8 79.7 77.7 76.7 73.7 71.1 68.0 150.3 166.5 175.6 183.5 188.1 208.6 143.9 149.6 160.1 175.7 198.5 202.2 99.2 97.2 94.3 90.3 87.1 82.0 97.5 98.2 99.3 99.7 98.7 94.3 97.2 94.9 91.4 89.3 84.2 79.9 116.9 121.2, 121.7 114.1 113.2 118.1 Unit labor costs in U.S. dollars: 1970 ........................................ 1971 ........................................ 1972 ........................................ 1973 ........................................ 1974 ........................................ 1975 ........................................ 100.0 91.1 81.5 71.1 70.9 64.9 100.0 101.3 102.6 99.9 102.1 103.3 100.0 105.2 116.1 129.0 136.6 128.8 100.0 96.6 100.3 106.0 99.9 110.2 100.0 104.3 106.4 119.2 118.6 109.1 100.0 103.7 104.6 100.3 93.8 108.5 100.0 104.2 101.2 88.9 93.8 100.8 100.0 100.0 102.0 101.4 104.9 107.5 100.0 100.0 97.7 107.0 109.8 105.0 100.0 101.1 104.4 109.9 111.2 116.4 100.0 99.5 102.6 101.1 99.4 110.3 68.1 66.4 61.7 61.8 62.4 70.8 113.5 105.2 93.5 90.2 91.5 95.4 127.4 133.5 148.2 123.6 105.7 118.7 107.6 102.2 101.0 105.1 110.3 106.6 111.0 116.9 122.7 124.3 120.2 107.8 95.9 96.1 94.2 95.5 94.1 91.1 93.5 91.5 98.4 115.4 143.2 146.0 109.1 112.2 111.1 107.2 102.8 92.5 109.2 108.6 109.0 108.8 99.2 87.6 113.9 116.1 113.7 113.2 106.7 95.6 126.4 125.0 112.4 106.1 105.9 106.8 Year Output per hour: 1970 ........................................ 1971 ........................................ 1972 ........................................ 1973 ........................................ 1974 ........................................ 1975 ........................................ 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 Note: ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ ........................................ Relative indexes are calculated from the ratio of the reference country index to a trade-weighted average index for the other 10 countries. 140 In France, Germany, and Italy, productivity in creased at about the same rate as that of trade competi tors from 1970 to 1981. Their relative rates of change varied during the period, however. In the early 1970’s, productivity in France and Germany rose somewhat less rapidly, and in Italy it rose more rapidly, but dur ing the late 1970’s, the relative rates were reversed. Productivity rose less rapidly than in competitor countries for the United States, Canada, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. From 1970 to 1981, U.S. relative productivity had increased 19 percent less, while in Sweden and the United Kingdom, gains were 13 per cent lower, and in Canada, 7 percent lower. The slower gains were quite consistent throughout the entire peri od. Relative compensation trends. Hourly compensation rose less than in competitor countries in the United States, Germany, and the Netherlands. From 1970 to 1981, compensation increased about 35 percent less in the United States, 30 percent less in Germany, and 10 per cent less in the Netherlands. For the United States and Germany, the slower relative trend was fairly consistent over the whole period. For the Netherlands, however, compensation rose more rapidly than competitors’ dur ing the early 1970’s, then less rapidly after 1976, with the greatest relative declines occurring in 1980-81, fol lowing the imposition of wage controls. Hourly compensation rose more rapidly than in com petitor countries in Italy, the United Kingdom, Japan, and France. From 1970 to 1981, compensation had in creased about 100 percent more in Italy and about 75 percent more in the United Kingdom. Almost without exception, both had consistently larger gains than their competitors throughout the 1970-81 period. Hourly compensation in Japan rose more rapidly during the early 1970’s—by 1975, Japanese compensation had in creased about 35 percent more than that of competitors — but grew less rapidly after 1975. By 1981, Japanese compensation gains were only 8 percent higher than competitors’. In France, hourly compensation rose at about the same rate as in competitor countries until the mid-1970’s, then rose more rapidly to end in 1981 with about a 20-percent larger cumulative increase. Canada, Belgium, and Denmark also ended the 1970— 81 period with somewhat larger compensation increases. But in each country, the 1981 relative gains were down from previous peaks— in Canada, 6 percent down from 10 percent in 1977; in Belgium, 5 percent down from 16 percent in 1976-77; and in Denmark, 6 percent down from 9 percent in 1974-79. In Sweden, hourly compen sation generally rose at about the same rate as competi tor countries’ over the 1970-81 period. Relative unit labor cost trends. Unit labor costs in national currency increased less from 1970 to 1981 in 141 six countries— the United States, Japan, Germany, Bel gium, Denmark, and the Netherlands— than in their competitor countries. The relative trend was 6 percent lower in Denmark by 1981, and about 20 to 30 percent lower in the other countries. The relative change for the United States was down because hourly compensation had fallen more than out put per hour. In Japan, Belgium, and Denmark, relative productivity gains more than offset relative compensa tion increases; in Germany, the relative productivity trend was about level, but relative compensation was sharply down; and the Netherlands had both productiv ity and hourly compensation advantages. The relative trend for the United States was steadily downward from 1970 to 1977, up moderately from 1977 to 1980, and down again slightly in 1981. Relative unit labor costs in Japan rose over 20 percent more than those of competitors by 1974-75, then declined steadily to 23 percent less than competitors’ by 1981. Relative unit labor costs declined steadily in Germany from 1973, in Belgium and the Netherlands from 1975, and in Denmark from 1979. For the Netherlands, the most significant relative cost declines occurred during 1980 and 1981. Unit labor costs in national currency increased by at least 100 percent more than competitors’ in Italy and the United Kingdom and by about 15 to 20 percent more in Canada, France, and Sweden, The large relative increases in Italy and the United Kingdom are attribut able to hourly compensation gains as the relative pro ductivity trend was down in the United Kingdom and essentially level in Italy. In Canada and France, hourly compensation was up slightly, and the productivity trend was down in Canada and even in France. In Swe den, hourly compensation trends were equal to those of competitors, but productivity fell from 1970 relative levels. In U.S. dollars. AJter adjustment for the relative change in the foreign exchange rate of the dollar, U.S. unit la bor costs showed a decline of nearly 30 percent versus those of competitors from 1970 to 1981, compared with about 20 percent in national currency. In 1980, relative unit labor costs adjusted for the dollar exchange rate were down almost 40 percent. However, the U.S. dollar appreciated 10 percent against trade-weighted U.S. competitor currencies from 1980 to 1981. This primarily reflected the dollar’s appreciation relative to the Ger man mark, French franc, and British pound, because, on a trade-weighted basis, the 2.5-percent appreciation of the Japanese yen was balanced by a 2.5-percent de preciation of the Canadian dollar. Unit labor costs adjusted for relative exchange rates for Canada, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands, and Den mark were also down— 5 to 12 percent— versus com petitors. For Canada, a 16-percent decline in the exchange rate, primarily against the U.S. dollar, offset higher increases in unit labor costs in Canadian dollars. For Italy, the exchange rate posted a 55-percent decline versus U.S. and German currencies. On the other hand, trade-weighted exchange rates were up 13 and 20 per cent for Belgium and the Netherlands; therefore, rela tive unit labor costs in dollars declined less than in na tional currency terms. For Germany and Japan, unit labor costs in U.S. dol lars increased 8 and 19 percent more than those of trade competitors (principally the United States for Japan, and France and the United States for Germany) even though unit labor costs in national currency were down about 25 to 30 percent, because their relative exchange rates rose 55 to 60 percent over the 1970-81 period. In the United Kingdom, relative unit labor costs in creased 100 percent in national currency terms, but 46 percent in U.S. dollars, because the British pound de clined 28 percent overall against competitor currencies— primarily the dollar and the German mark. In France and Sweden, unit labor costs in U.S. dollars posted 197081 relative increases of 7 percent, as costs in national cur rency rose nearly 20 percent more than those of competi tors, but trade-weighted exchange rates declined about 10 percent versus competitor currencies. 1The Federal Republic plus West Berlin. 2The data relate to all employed persons, including the selfemployed, in the United States and Canada, and to all wage and sala ry employees in the other countries. Hours refer to hours paid in the United States, hours worked in the other countries. Compensation includes all payments made by employers directly to their employees (before deductions), plus employer contributions to legally required insurance programs and to contractual and private welfare plans for the benefit of employees. Labor costs include, in ad dition to compensation, employer expenditures for recruitment and training; the cost of cafeterias, medical facilities, and other plant facil ities and services; and taxes (other than social security taxes, which are part of compensation) levied on payrolls or employment rolls. An nual data are not available for total labor costs. As used in this arti cle, labor costs approximate more closely the concept of compensation. However, compensation has been adjusted to include all significant changes in taxes that are regarded as labor costs. For the United States and Canada, compensation of self-employed work ers is measured by assuming that their hourly compensation is equal to the average for wage and salary employees. ? Percent changes for 1960-81, 1960-73, and 1973-81 shown in the tables are computed using the least squares method— that is, from the least squares trend of the logarithms of index numbers— in order to remove much of the effect of cyclical changes on the average rates of change, and thereby estimate the underlying trends. 4To compute the series for the eight European countries and 10 foreign countries, the data have been combined by aggregating the output, compensation, and hours figures for each year, adjusting where necessary for compatibility of coverage and concept. Average exchange rates for 1974-81 were used to aggregate the output and compensation data. The use of 1974-81 exchange rates, however, does not imply that these rates reflect the comparative real value of curren 142 cies for manufacturing output. Moreover, the use of exchange rates for a different period would have little effect on the combined series. 5The IMF publishes annual and quarterly indexes of relative unit labor costs and relative normalized unit labor costs in manufacturing — as well as relative value-added deflators, relative wholesale prices, and relative export unit values in manufacturing— for 14 industrial countries, in their monthly statistical publication International Finan cial Statistics. The OECD publishes quarterly indexes in chart form of relative unit labor costs in manufacturing, relative export unit values (prices) for manufactures, and relative consumer prices for 15 indus trial countries in their monthly statistical publication Main Economic Indicators. Series descriptions, data sources, and compilation methods for the IMF measures are described in “Intercountry Cost and Price Com parisons,” a paper by Michael C. Deppler, Research Department, In ternational Monetary Fund (November 1979); the OECD measures are described in The International Competitiveness of Selected OECD Countries, OECD Economic Outlook Occasional Studies, July 1978. ‘ The IMF weights were derived from disaggregated 5-digit Stan dard International Trade Classification data (up to 1,400 individual commodity classes) for each of the 14 countries covered by their se ries. The IMF weights have been simply adjusted to the 11-country BLS comparative series by eliminating the weights for the three un covered countries— Austria, Norway, and Switzerland— and propor tionately increasing the weights for the remaining 11 countries so that they equal 100 percent. The result should be little different from a comprehensive reweighting based on trade data for the 11 countries alone, because the omitted countries account for no more than 8.1 percent of the total 14-country weight for any of the 11 countries, and for a total of only 4 percent in the case of the United States. ’ The weighting system is described in detail in Deppler, “Intercountry Cost and Price Comparisons.” THE INTERNATIONAL CONTEXT Arnold Packer and Arthur Neef ro d u c tiv ity g ro w th is a m ajo r d e te r m in a n t of a n a tio n 's a b ility to c o m b a t in fla tio n , to m a in ta in c o m p e titiv e n e s s in in te rn a tio n al tra d e , a n d to in c re a se its s ta n d a rd of liv in g . G ro ss d o m e s tic p ro d u c t (G D P) p e r e m p lo y e d p e rs o n , w h ic h covers th e e c o n o m y 's total o u tp u t of g o o d s a n d se rv ic e s, p ro v id e s a b ro a d m e a s u re of la b o r p ro d u c tiv ity . O v e r th e p e rio d 1960 to 1979, real G D P p e r e m p lo y e d p e rs o n in creased at a n a n n u a l av e ra g e rate of 1.5 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r in th e U n ite d S tates. T his c o m p a re s w ith a n n u a l a v e ra g e g a in s of a ro u n d 2 p e rc e n t in C a n a d a a n d th e U n ite d K in g d o m , 4 p e rc e n t in B elgium , F rance, G e rm a n y , th e N e th e rla n d s , a n d Italy, a n d 7 p e rc e n t in Jap an . R o u g h ly c o m p a ra b le fig u re s for so m e ra p id ly d e v e lo p in g e c o n o m ie s are 5.4 p e rc e n t for K orea, 5.8 p e rc e n t for T a iw a n , a n d 3.3 p e rc e n t fo r M exico (1960-1977). S in ce 1973, th e a v e ra g e ra te of g a in in real G D P p e r e m p lo y e d p e rs o n in th e U n ite d S tates h a s b e e n o n ly 0.3 p e rc e n t p e r y ear; in th e p e rio d fro m 1960 to 1973 it w as 2.1 p e rc e n t p e r y ear. S in ce 1973, o th e r in d u s tria l c o u n trie s h a v e also e x p e rie n c e d p ro d u c tiv ity P Arnold Packer is the assistant secretary for policy, evaluation, and research in the U.S. Department of Labor and Arthur Neef is chief of foreign labor statistics and trade in the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Brian Brosnahan assisted substantially in the preparation o f this article. slo w d o w n s — so m e as s h a rp as th e U n ite d S ta te s' s lo w d o w n . W ith th e ex c e p tio n of C a n a d a , h o w e v e r, all c o n tin u e d to h a v e la rg e r a n n u a l a v erag e g a in s in G D P p e r e m p lo y e d p e rso n . p e rs o n b e c a u se of sig n ific a n t re d u c tio n s in a v e ra g e w o rk in g h o u rs . T h e U .S . ra te of g ro w th sin c e 1973 of 1.4 p e rc e n t p e r y ear— c o m p a re d w ith 3 DP p e r e m p lo y e d p e rc e n t p e r y e a r fro m 1960 to 1973— p e rs o n d o e s p ro e x c e e d e d th e ra te of la b o r p ro d u c tiv ity v id e a m e a s u re of g a in in th e U n ite d K in g d o m , b u t w as e c o n o m y -w id e less th a n in a n y of th e o th e r c o u n trie s p ro d u c tiv ity , b u t it c o m p a re d . also h a s so m e W h ile th e U n ite d S ta te s h a s h a d th e sh o rtc o m in g s. Let slo w e st ra te of p ro d u c tiv ity g ro w th , it u s b rie fly n o te th e m ostill st reex le vceed a n t.s Ga nDyP o th e r c o u n try in c o v ers th e area of p u b lic a d m in is tra o v erall efficien cy . A s of 1979, G D P p e r tio n , th o u g h th e U n ite d S tates a n d e m p lo y e d p e rs o n in C a n a d a w as m o st o th e r c o u n trie s a s s u m e z ero p r o a b o u t 95 p e rc e n t of th e U .S . level; in d u c tiv ity g ro w th fo r th is secto r b e F ran ce, G e rm a n y , a n d th e B enelux c a u se of m e a s u re m e n t d iffic u ltie s. c o u n trie s, it w a s a ro u n d 90 p e rc e n t; in G D P d o e s n o t tak e in to a c c o u n t Ja p a n , tw o -th ird s of th e U .S. level; c h a n g e s in a v e ra g e h o u rs w o rk e d . A n d a n d in Italy a n d th e U n ite d K in g d o m , it in c lu d e s th e effects of re so u rc e sh ifts 60 p e rc e n t. B ecau se of th e fa ste r ra te s a m o n g se c to rs w ith v e ry d iffe re n t of p ro d u c tiv ity g ro w th a b ro a d , th e re lev els of p r o d u c tiv ity (all th e c o u n trie s h a s b e e n a n a rro w in g — in so m e cases m e n tio n e d a b o v e h a v e u n d e rg o n e a v e ry s u b s ta n tia l n a rro w in g — of th e sh ifts in re la tiv e e m p lo y m e n t as w o rk p ro d u c tiv ity g a p . In 1960, th e c o rre ers m o v e d b e tw e e n a g ric u ltu re , in d u s s p o n d in g fig u re s w e re , C a n a d a , 90 try , a n d serv ices). p e rc e n t of th e U .S . level; F ran ce, G e r F or so m e p u rp o s e s of a n a ly z in g in m a n y , th e B en elu x c o u n trie s , a n d th e te rn a tio n a l c o m p e titiv e n e s s , m a n u fa c U n ite d K in g d o m , a b o u t 55 to 60 p e r tu r in g p ro d u c tiv ity , as m e a s u re d b y cen t; Italy , 35 p e rc e n t; a n d J a p a n , o n ly o u tp u t p e r h o u r, is a b e tte r in d ic a to r. 25 p e rc e n t. U n fo rtu n a te ly , s im ila r level M a n u fa c tu rin g p ro d u c tiv ity e x h ib its a c o m p a ris o n s fo r m a n u f a c tu r in g a re n o t p a tte rn sim ila r to G D P p e r e m p lo y e d a v a ila b le . p e rs o n , w ith th e U .S . s h o w in g th e T h e m u c h lo w e r re la tiv e lev els of sm a lle st a v e ra g e ra te of g a in sin ce p ro d u c tiv ity in Ja p a n a n d E u ro p e in 1960. A lso , all th e W e ste rn in d u s tr i 1960 p a rtia lly e x p la in th e ir fa s te r ra te s a liz e d c o u n trie s sh o w a m a n u fa c tu rin g of p ro d u c tiv ity g ro w th . C o m p a ra tiv e p ro d u c tiv ity slo w d o w n sin c e 1973— ra te s of p ro d u c tiv ity g ro w th b e tw e e n a lth o u g h , for m o s t c o u n trie s, a less th e U n ite d S ta te s a n d c o u n trie s a p sig n ific a n t slo w d o w n th a n fo r G D P. p ro a c h in g th e U .S . o v erall lev el o f effi cien c y s h o u ld , p re s u m a b ly , n a rro w . F or n a tio n s su c h as F ran ce, W e st G e r C Reprinted from Executive, Vol. 7, No. 1, Graduate School o f Business and Public Administration, Cornell University. m a n y , a n d th e B en elu x c o u n trie s , o u t p u t p e r h o u r in m a n u fa c tu rin g slo w e d m u c h less th a n G D P p e r e m p lo y e d 143 H o w e v e r, m a n y o th e r fa cto rs also af fect re la tiv e ra te s of p ro d u c tiv ity g ain . G e rm a n y a n d th e N e th e rla n d s sh o w th e h ig h e s t a v e ra g e ra te s of g a in — a b o u t 9 p e rc e n t p e r y ear. In th e p e rio d sin c e 1973, C a n a d a also h a d a sm a lle r g a in th a n th e U n ite d S tates in u n it la b o r co sts as m e a s u re d on a U .S. d o l lar b a sis. H o w e v e r, Ja p a n , G e rm a n y , B e lg iu m , a n d th e N e th e rla n d s , w h ic h h a d sm a lle r n a tio n a l c u rre n c y -b a se d ra te s of in c re a se th a n th e U .S. in c re a se of 8 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r, sh o w a v erag e g a in s of a b o u t 9 to 12 p e rc e n t p e r y ear. L a b o r p ro d u c tiv ity g a in s are th e p rin c ip a l m e a n s of ra is in g liv in g s ta n d a rd s . In c re a se s in o u tp u t p e r h o u r can b e tra n s la te d in to g re a te r o u tp u t of g o o d s a n d se rv ices o r in to in c re a se d le is u re tim e . C h a n g e s in real h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n are o n e m e a s u re of c h a n g e s in liv in g s ta n d a rd s . For th e e c o n o m y as a w h o le , real h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n of w o rk e rs can o n ly in c re a se if o u tp u t p e r h o u r in c re a se s o r la b o r re c e iv e s a n in c re a sin g p ro p o r tio n of to ta l fa c to r in c o m e s. O f c o u rse , i n d i v id u a l w o rk e rs o r w o rk e rs in p a rtic u la r in d u s tr ie s can also re c e iv e real g a in s in h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n at th e e x p e n se of o th e r w o rk e rs. R eal h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n of U .S. m a n u fa c tu rin g w o rk e rs, u sin g th e c o n s u m e r p ric e in d e x as th e p rice m e a s u re , ro se a t a n a v e ra g e ra te of 1.4 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r fro m 1960 to 1979. In th e p e rio d u p to 1973, real h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n ro se 1.7 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r; fro m 1973 to 1979, o n ly 0.8 p e r c e n t p e r y e a r. W h ile th e g a in s in real h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n w e re less th a n e ith e r th e to tal e c o n o m y o r m a n u fa c tu r in g p ro d u c tiv ity g a in s , th e p a tte rn w a s sim ila r— a su b s ta n tia lly re d u c e d ra te of in c re a se in th e p e rio d o f th e p ro d u c tiv ity slo w d o w n . M a n u fa c tu rin g w o rk e rs in all of th e o th e r c o u n trie s h a d m u c h la rg e r in creases in real h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n , ra n g in g , o v e r th e 1960 to 1979 p e rio d , fro m d o u b le th e U .S . a v e ra g e ra te of e s p ite th e fact th a t th e U .S . h a d th e lo w e st ra te of p r o d u c tiv ity g ro w th am ong C anada, Ja p a n , a n d all W e s te rn E u ro p e a n c o u n trie s from 1960 to 1979, m a n u fa c tu rin g u n it la b o r co sts ro se less in th e U n ite d S tates th a n in a n y of th e o th e r c o u n trie s. A n d for g o o d re a so n . T h ese c o u n trie s h a d larg e r g a in s in h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n — in Ja p a n a n d E u ro p e , ro u g h ly d o u b le th e U .S. a v e ra g e yearly in c re a se of a b o u t 6V2 p e rc e n t. U .S. u n it la b o r costs ro se at a n av erag e rate of 3.7 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r, c o m p a re d w ith a b o u t 4 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r in C a n a d a , 4.5 p e rc e n t p e r y e a r in Ja p a n , B elg iu m , a n d G e rm a n y , 5.5 p e rc e n t in th e N e th e rla n d s , 6 p e rc e n t in F ran ce, a n d a ro u n d 9 p e rc e n t in Italy a n d th e U n ite d K in g d o m . W h ile re lativ e c h a n g e s in n o m in a l u n it la b o r costs p o te n tia lly affect tra d e c o m p e titiv e n e s s , u n it la b o r co sts a d ju s te d for c h a n g e s in e x c h a n g e ra te s are th e m o re re le v a n t m e a s u re . O v e r th e y e a rs, p a rtic u la rly sin c e th e 1971 a n d 1973 d e v a lu a tio n s of th e U .S . d o l lar, th e re h av e b e e n s u b s ta n tia l sh ifts in cu rre n c y v a lu a tio n s — w h ic h h a v e a s ig n ific a n t im p a c t on ra te s of c h a n g e in u n it la b o r costs. In g e n e ra l, th e cu rre n c ie s of Ja p a n , G e rm a n y , a n d th e sm aller E u ro p e a n c o u n trie s h a v e a p p re c ia te d re la tiv e to th e U .S . d o lla r, w h ile th e B ritish a n d Ita lia n c u rre n cies h a v e d e p re c ia te d . F ro m 1960 to 1979 th e F ren ch fran c h a s also a p p re c ia te d s o m e w h a t w h ile th e C a n a d ia n d o llar, b e c a u se of s u b s ta n tia l d e c lin e s in th e p a st few y e a rs, h as d e p re c ia te d . A fter a d ju s tm e n t fo r th e s e sh ifts in ex ch a n g e ra te s , C a n a d a sh o w s a lo w er ra te of g a in in u n it la b o r c o sts sin c e g a in in C a n a d a to o v e r fo u r tim e s th e 1960 th a n th e U n ite d S ta te s w h ile U .S. av e ra g e ra te of g a in in Ja p a n a n d 144 th e c o n tin e n ta l E u ro p e a n c o u n trie s. B ut b e c a u se of s u b s ta n tia l re d u c tio n s in a v e ra g e w o rk in g h o u rs in Ja p an a n d E u ro p e , in c re a se s in real h o u rly c o m p e n s a tio n o v e rs ta te th e in c re a se s in real in c o m e fro m w o rk . Still, th e in c re a se s w e re n o tic e a b ly g re a te r th a n in th e U n ite d S tates. W o rld W ar II left m u c h of th e in d u s tria liz e d w o rld in ru in s . In m o s t of th e m a jo r c o u n trie s , a n d in th e fo rm er A xis p o w e rs in p a rtic u la r, th e p ro cess of e c o n o m ic d e v e lo p m e n t w a s e ith e r a rre ste d o r se t b a c k m a n y y ea rs. In c o n tra st, th e w a r g re a tly a c c elerated th e d e v e lo p m e n t of th e U .S . ec o n o m y . S in ce th e U .S . e c o n o m y w as a lre a d y th e m o st h ig h ly d e v e lo p e d b e fo re th e w a r s ta rte d , in 1945 p r o d u c tiv ity a n d p e r c a p ita in c o m e in th e U .S . w e re far h ig h e r th a n in o th e r c o u n trie s. In 1945, th e U n ite d S ta te s w a s a t th e fro n tie r of te c h n o lo g y . B ut th e secrets to h ig h e r p ro d u c tiv ity te c h n o lo g y c o u ld b e b o u g h t fro m th e U .S. th ro u g h p a te n t lic e n se s a n d o th e r te c h n ic a l a g re e m e n ts . A c o m p a riso n of th e re le v a n t c o u n trie s ' im p o rts a n d e x p o rts of te c h n o l ogy w ill illu s tra te th e p o in t. In 1971 th e ra tio of Ja p a n e se p a y m e n ts for im p o rts of te c h n o lo g y (p a te n t lic e n ses, k n o w -h o w , a n d a ss o c ia te d e x p en ses) to Ja p a n e se re c e ip ts fo r te c h n o lo g y ex p o rts w as a b o u t e ig h t to o n e. In G e rm a n y , th is ra tio w as n e a rly th re e to o n e , a n d in F rance it w a s close to tw o to o n e . In th e m o re m a tu re e c o n o m ie s of G re a t B rita in a n d th e U .S ., h o w e v e r, re c e ip ts o u tw e ig h e d p a y m e n ts. F or B rita in , th e d ifferen ce w a s sm all; b u t U .S . p a y m e n ts for te c h n o lo g y sto o d at o n ly $218 m illio n w h ile re c e ip ts w e ig h e d in a t a w h o p p in g $2.5 b illio n . In m a n y fie ld s, th e U .S . is still o p e ra tin g on th e te c h n o lo g ic a l fr o n tie r. A s in d u s tria liz e d c o u n trie s a p p ro a c h te c h n o lo g ic a l p a rity , th e s p e c ta c u la r g a in s a tta in e d in G e rm a n y a n d Ja p a n w ill c o n tin u e to d im in is h . Part V. Technology Studies One of the important efforts of b l s has been to ex amine the impact of technological change upon produc tivity, employment, and occupational change. This part describes the scope of this research, including the sources and data collection methods. A study of the employment effects of new electronic technology is in cluded, together with a representative series of studies of technological change and its effect upon labor and other economic variables. Projections of possible future effects of specific technologies on employment and oc cupational structure are also included. Background Studies of technological changes and their labor im plications have been undertaken by b l s over the years for a variety of purposes. During the 1930’s, public in terest focused on the unemployed, and reports were prepared on technological changes and displacement of workers in various industries. During World War II, emerging technologies were studied for purposes of im proving manpower utilization. Beginning in the mid-1950’s, nationwide attention was focused on the implications of new developments classified under the general term “ automation.” b l s made a series of studies on a plant basis, in the in surance, petroleum refining, bakery, air lines, and elec tronics industries, to explore the manpower implications of various changes. Later, broader studies were under taken, including a survey of the manpower impact of changeover to electronic computers in 20 large com panies and intensive studies of technological change in the coal and paper industries. These studies formed the basis, beginning in the early 1960’s, for a more systematic investigation of future changes. R esearch now underw ay p inpoints technologies which will become increasingly important over the next decade in key industries and attempts to provide advance information about their manpower im plications. Analysis and Interpretation For a better understanding of research results in this field, it is important to keep in mind the meaning of cer tain key ideas and concepts. Some of the problems of in terpretation and analysis in this type of research are, therefore, set forth briefly. Definition of technological change Technological change is defined broadly in the b l s studies as encompassing significant changes in processes and equipment, and product and services produced, and materials, fuels, and energy used. The term “ automa tion,” which is sometimes popularly used as a synonym for “ technological change,” designates, strictly speak ing, a particular type of current development. It has been variously defined, for example, as “ automatic operations,” “ the mechanization of sensory control and thought processes,” and “ a concern with produc tion processes as a system.” While b l s studies have been concerned with developments in autom ation, particularly in an ticipating long-term trends, they are not the only technological changes taking place that affect labor re quirements and industrial relations. For example, new ways of generating power, piggybacking in transporta tion, use of synthetic materials in manufacturing, mechanized methods of material handling, and faster steelmaking processes are important technological developments, not usually covered by technical defini tions of automation, but having significant manpower implications. Impact of productivity Since one of the principal consequences of technological change, so far as manpower utilization is concerned, is an increase in productivity (output per Description of Studies The Bureau’s research program on technological change involves a variety of reports and studies of dif ferent degrees of detail and approach. The current pro gram thus provides: Summary reports surveying trends in major industries; detailed industry studies; and studies of major technological innovations, such as computers, that affect workers in different industries. 145 employee hour), special attention is given in b l s studies to analyzing changes in industrial productivity. Such trend analysis is a useful method of measuring the pace of technological change. Changes in productivity, however, also reflect changes in capacity utilization and many other nontechnical factors. It is important to recognize that the productivity trend is only a partial measure of the rate of technological change. In determining the Impact of a specific technology, b l s studies try to indicate the reduction in unit labor re quirements that the new process is designed to achieve. In some cases, estimates of labor savings are derived on the basis of comparisons with the estimated average technology of the industry under study; in others, with the best equipment that is available; or in actual plant studies, with the technology that is actually displaced. It is also important to distinguish between the impact on productivity of the operation directly affected and on productivity of the plant as a whole. An advanced machine tool, for example, may result in a relatively large reduction in unit labor requirements in the machining opeations, but would have little impact on finishing and assembling, and may even require addi tional labor in engineering and maintenance work. The impact of plant productivity, therefore, would be con siderably less than the effect on productivity of any department or operation directly affected. impaet @n employment In assessing the impact of technological change on employment, it is necessary to consider the implications of plant manpower policies and the effects of economic changes, with which technological changes interact. Analysis of the impact of technological change purely in terms of machinery is incomplete. At the plant level, for example, the substitution of machinery for labor may substantially reduce job op portunities in operations directly affected. If efforts are made, however, to eliminate these jobs by not filling vacancies created by quits, deaths, and retirement of employees, or by transfer of affected workers to other positions in the plant or office, labor savings could be achieved without displacing the workers affected. Moreover, the employment impact of technological change is also interrelated with the effects of the business cycle. Thus, workers whose jobs are eliminated by technological changes may not be displaced from a plant until a decline in demand results in layoffs—a long time after the change has been made in some cases. In th e ' subsequent recovery, however, they may not be 146 hired back because their jobs no longer exist. Since many changes exert their effects on employment through the competitive market, the employment trend for the industry as a whole must also be examined. The plant which reduces its unit costs through technological improvement may be able to gain a larger share of the market and increase its employment, but at the expense of the less technically advanced competing plants, which may be forced to shut down, displacing workers far from the location of the change. Because of the whole complex of economic factors that operate through the market, including changes in demand, location, foreign competition, corporate organization, and consumer taste, it is very difficult to isolate the expanding and displacing effects of technological change. Impact @f ©eeupatiomis Two aspects of occupational change resulting from technological changes are examined. Changes in job structure—the distribution of the plant or office work force by function or broad skill grouping—are studied to determine the extent of upgrading or downgrading. Since the content of jobs may be altered as a result of changes in equipment or processes, attention also is directed to intensive before-and-after analysis of job duties and the knowledge and abilities required to per form these duties as indicated by job descriptions and observation. The content of newly created jobs also is studied and the qualifications required and personal characteristics of individuals selected for these new posi tions are described, so far as possible. Adjustment! t@ technological change Technological change has important implications for personnel management and collective bargaining within plants. The introduction of new machinery, products, or processes often requires movement of workers among jobs within the plant or office by transfer or pro motion, the setting of wage rates, and selection of per sons for new jobs. Often the adjustment proceeds accor ding to rules established in advance through collective bargaining. Provisions to assist workers whose jobs are eliminated include severance pay, retraining, and early retirement. Besides analyzing the operation of formal provisions under collective bargaining, Bureau studies describe informal efforts to provide training, to utilize attrition, and to obtain, jobs for displaced workers elsewhere. The limitations of these measures as well as their advantages are important matters studied. Impact of eew electronic technology R ic h a r d W . R ic h e The steady stream of technological progress that has characterized our society in America has resulted in higher productivity, elimination of many menial and dangerous jobs, higher wages and shorter hours, and a continuous flow of new products and services which have resulted in a higher standard of living. New indus tries employing thousands of workers have been formed to manufacture computers, electronic products, and technologies to provide energy and control the environ ment. To be sure, innovation in industries such as longshoring, agriculture, and printing, to name a few, has eliminated jobs and required workers to acquire the un familiar skills associated with new technology. For some, the adjustment has been painful. But on balance, there is general agreement that the benefits of new tech nology far outweigh the disadvantages, and that innova tion has led to economic progress, new job oppor tunities, and a more prosperous society. At this point, early in the decade of the 1980’s, there is widespread agreement that the pace of diffusion of technologies which incorporate advanced electronics will be accelerated over the next few years. The experi ence in the United States suggests that as long as the economy is growing, the introduction of innovations with potential for productivity gains can be compatible with rising employment. When computers were first in troduced for office data applications, for example, fre quently predictions were made that large numbers of clerical and kindred workers would be displaced and that job opportunities for millions would be curtailed. What actually did happen was quite different. In 1960, clerical workers in the United States numbered about 10 million and accounted for about 15 percent of total employment. By 1980, there were more than 18 million clerical workers and they accounted for about 19 per cent of the total. Thus, instead of decreasing as had been predicted, clerical employment increased about 85 percent. And, it is projected to grow significantly to 1990. Why did clerical employment increase instead of de creasing as predicted? First, normal growth in the volRichard W. Riche is an economist in the Office of Productivity and Technology, Bureau of Labor Statistics. This report was adapted from his presentation at the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development’s Second Special Session on Information Technologies, Productivity, and Employment, held in Paris, France, Oct. 19-21, 1981. Reprinted from the M onthly L abor Review, March 1982. 147 ume of clerical work exceeded jobs eliminated by the computer. Second, computers made possible work that was previously impractical because it would have been too costly and too time consuming. Using computers, managers can now prepare reports and analyses that previously were desirable but too costly. In addition to creating employment by expanding the scope of activities for many industries, the computer re quired new occupations such as systems analysts, pro grammers, keypunch operators, console operators, and tape librarians. And new industries were established to manufacture computers and related equipment, creating a variety of occupations and employing thousands. Technological change can cause job displacement, es pecially when the industry is concentrated in a particu lar region or locality. Sometimes the employment impact is direct, as in the case of agriculture. In most cases, however, the effect is less obvious. Output does not advance at the same rate as productivity in all in dustries or plants, and consequently some industries register employment declines while others register in creases. Regardless of the reason, displacements are costly for both the individual and the Nation. This report examines four major technological chang es under way in the United States and discusses pros pects for their further diffusion. The four areas are microelectronics, industrial robots, telecommunications, and office automation. The development of microprocessors and microcomput ers in the early 1970’s, and their widespread diffusion as we enter the 1980’s, is a major innovation in electron ics. Over the past three decades, the transistor that re placed the bulky vacuum tube was a first step in the development of miniaturized semiconductor integrated circuits which provide more power and reliability in a significantly smaller package. A microprocessor unit contains thousands of electronic components and com plex circuits on a silicon chip less than one centim eter square. The unit can be combined with memory and in put-output capability to build a microcomputer. The use of microelectronics has had a significant im pact on American consumers, workers, and manu facturing operations. A vast array of products— calcu lators, digital watches, video games, TV sets, and mi crowave ovens, to name a few—incorporate micro processors and microcomputers. But behind the scenes in American manufacturing plants, production technol ogies and manufacturing methods are undergoing equal ly dramatic changes. Microelectronics are being incorporated in systems which control key production equipment, such as industrial robots and numericallycontrolled machine tools. Moreover, microelectronic de vices increase the processing capability of word proces sors, computers, data transmission and copying devices, automatic checkout counters, and other such equipmer’ used by banks, insurance companies, and retail and wholesale establishments. The industrial robot is a second major technological innovation capturing current attention. The Robot In stitute of America defines a robot as “a repro grammable multifunctional manipulator designed to move material, parts, tools, or specialized devices through variable programmed motions for the perfor mance of a variety of tasks.” According to the institute, about 4,000 robots are in use in U.S. establishments, with a large share in automobile manufacturing plants. They perform tasks such as material transfer, die cast ing, spot welding, spray painting, and limited assembly. Although U.S. industry is increasing its use of robots, Japan leads the world in robot use with more than tri ple the number of installations in the United States. There is little information on the impact of robots on productivity and employment. However, evidence sug gests that, following installation of robots, productivity is increased, unit labor requirements frequently are low ered, and quality control is improved. At one large manufacturer of refrigerators, for example, a robot sprays paint on refrigerator liners twice as fast as the two-person crew that it replaced.1The future impact of robots on productivity and employment will depend on the extent of development and diffusion of new genera tions of robots that can “see and feel.” Technological changes in telecommunications are un derway in all major segments- of the industry. These innovations are boosting productivity and changing the type of labor required in the two basic processes of tele phone ^communication— call switching and signal trans mission. The electronic computer is used extensively in bo$Ji processes, as. well as in other operational tasks and in ipapagerqent and accounting functions. Jn pall switching, electronic, switching systems use high speed computers to handle local and long-distance calls, iA growing share of calls is handled by electronic? sv^itcfeing systems! Total conversion is anticipated by the year 2000. These systems cgn handle thfee to four times m@rq palls fhan electromechanical systems. Sharp gains in long-distance volume have led to two innovative and important technologies in signal trans mission— the millimeter waveguide and fiber optic ca bles. Both have far greater call-handling capabilities than the existing coaxial cables and microwave relays. The millimeter waveguide is essentially an underground tube through which signal-carrying waves are transmit ted. It is designed for use on high density communica tion routes. Currently, this technology is being tested; future diffusion will depend on call volume growth. Fiber optic cables for signal transmission are expected to become a major transmission medium in the 1980’s. In this technology, glass fiber cables are combined with semiconductor light sources for very high capacity transmission. The fiber cables are com 148 pact, resist electrical interference, and interface well with digital switching and transmission techniques. Other major changes anticipated for the telecommu nications industry include further expansion of satellite communication, digital transmission, computerized sys tems for maintenance and testing, and automation of switching and billing tasks. Experts also foresee nontraditional uses of the communications network for electronic funds transfer in banking, electronic postal service functions, and data systems for the home which will combine communications and data processing capa bilities. Office data handling and communication is a fourth area where major technological change has occurred. A large segment of the Nation’s work force, including more than 18 million clerical workers, is engaged in producing and processing data. Historically, capital in vestment in the office has lagged that of other opera tions, with investment per office worker amounting to less than $2,000, compared with about $25,000 per fac tory worker.2 This “investment gap” may be closed in the years ahead. Investment in office technologies will likely ac celerate during the 1980’s, as managers turn to modern data handling technologies to . reduce labor, material, and related expenses.. The largest. share of office costs are deemed to be labpr-related— a strong incentive for further mechanization. Specific technologies to be diffused more widely in clude more .powerful electronic .'Computers; advanced model w©rd processors; new equipment and techniques to stqre, retrieve, and transmit data on microfilm; and electronic mail networks. Increasingly, paper will be re placed ; by electronic images on a screen which can Jbe transmitted by telecommunication methods. Genef&I impact off innovations Following are conclusions from the Bureau’ of La&or Statistics, research on the implications of technological change for the work force. © While all industries are experiencing technological change, the pace varies among and within industries. Each industry has its own story and it is not always in terms of computer technology and advanced auto mation. But even conventional changes, such as mate rials handling mechanization or the installation of larger capacity equipment or machines with faster speeds, are often major developments requiring work ers to obtain new skills. © The size of investment required, the rate of capacity utilization, and institutional arrangements are some of the factors that act as an “economic governor” on the speed of diffusion of technological change and, in turn, possible employment implications. © Industries with greater application of technological advances generally experience larger increases in pro ductivity (examples, air transportation and telephone communication); industries lagging in application of technological advances generally experience smaller or negative changes in productivity (examples, foot wear and wood household furniture). © The content of jobs and the qualities required of workers are being modified by technological changes. There is less demand for manual dexterity, physical strength for material handling, and for traditional craftsmanship. In contrast, employers are placing more emphasis on formal knowledge, precision, and perceptual aptitudes. As many manual tasks are mechanized, unskilled workers become monitors of very expensive equipment. The reduction in repetitive tasks that are so dissatisfying to the industrial worker may be welcomed, but the isolation and constant monitoring associated with advanced technology can create new stresses. © Higher educational achievement of workers is becom ing essential. The ability to read and write at a func 149 tional level is mandatory to interpret operating instructions of complex equipment, and to be re trained for the new skills demanded by changing technology. © Many new occupations created by new technologies can be filled by retraining employees. Most retraining is accomplished in-plant and includes on-the-job and classroom instruction. © In general, relatively few employees have been laid off because of technological change. This is due, in part, to the use of various techniques by the private sector to minimize adverse effects to the worker— tech niques such as providing advance notice, retraining, and reassigning displaced employees to new jobs. 1“Robots Join the Labor Force,” Business Week, June 9, 1980, pp. 62-76. 2Philip H. Dorn, “The Automated Office— The Road to Disaster?” Datamation, Nov. 15, 1978, pp. 154-62. Teehn@S©gy amd lalbor in ESeetrieal and Electronic Equipment Robert V. Critchlow Summary appliance industry experienced the highest rate of productivity growth. Productivity gains in these industries were most rapid during the earlier portion of the 1960-79 period. Expenditures for plant and equipment have been in creasing, with capital outlays highest for electronic com ponents and communication equipment. Capital spend ing is expected to increase as those parts of the industry experiencing rapid technological development continue spending for new plant and equipment. Employment rose at a relatively low annual rate of 1.6 percent between 1960 and 1980; the growth rate was highest in the early half of the period. Employment is projected to increase at an average annual rate of 1.7 to 2.5 percent between 1980 and 1990. The pace of technological change has been uneven in the diverse group of industries that make up the electrical and electronic equipment group. The electronic compo nents sector, for example, is a leader in technological innovation and has experienced strong growth in produc tion, employment, and capital investment. The electrical machinery industries, however, are experiencing less rapid technological change. Production and employment growth also has been slower in these industries. A number of occupations will be affected by technolog ical change. Improvements in assembly procedures, primarily in the use of automatic equipment, including robots, are changing skill requirements and increasing productivity for several kinds of operatives. In the largest occupation—assemblers—work is shifting from manual assembly toward machine monitoring, loading, and maintenance tasks. The need for welders and painters may decline, while more mechanics and repairers may be needed. Engineers and technicians will make greater use of video terminals and computer techniques in designing machines and electronic circuits—which should improve their productivity and reduce the need for drafting em ployees. Solid-state controls, which are manufactured in this industry, will also be used in appliances and other products manufactured in this industry. They will in creasingly replace mechanical controls (switches, timers, etc.) and bundles of electrical wires, which will increase the need for scientists, engineers, and technicians, while reducing the amount of manual assembly and soldering work required. Production in the electrical and electronic equipment industry has grown steadily during the 1960-80 period. The electronic component sector has grown most rapidly, due to strong demand for integrated circuits and other semiconductors. Production has also increased in each of the other industries within this sector. There is no BLS index of output per employee hour (productivity) for the broad industry group, but indexes are available for several individual industries. Produc tivity has increased, at varying rates, in each of the industries for which data are available. The household Technology in the 1080’s Technological changes are taking place in most sectors of the electrical and electronic equipment industry (SIC 36). To varying degrees, these changes will affect employment levels and occupational structures. Improve ments in assembly operations include more automatic equipment to assemble printed circuit boards, and production lines with automatic stations to manufacture household appliances and television receivers. The trend toward more automated operations may lower unit labor requirements somewhat and shift job skills more toward machine monitoring and maintenance. Computer techniques are being developed to assist engineers in designing solid-state (semiconductor) electronic comp onents and integrated circuits. Solid-state controls artd switches, and printed circuits, important products of this industry, are replacing mechanical controls and electrical wires in household appliances, television and radio receivers, communication equipment, and other products made by this industry. Designing and installing solidstate controls generally require more engineers and technicians, and fewer assemblers, solderers, and machine operators than the older processes. Numerically controlled machine tools are achieving labor and other savings in turning out communication equipment and Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 2104 (1982), Technology and L abor in Four Industries. ISO Table 3. E^ajor technology changes in electrical and electronic equipment Technology Description 1-abor implications Diffusion Equipment to design and fabri cate semiconductors and re lated dev ices, including micro processors Computers and video display terminals can be used to design and lay out complex integrated circuits in less time than is necessary for older methods. This is especially appli cable to microprocessors, which are among the most com plex semiconductor devices. Designing and fabricating semi conductors require relatively more scientists, technicians, and engineers and fewer assemblers and machine operators than the manufacture of electron tubes or mechanical switches and controls which they replace. Computer-assisted design ( C A D ) of semiconductors could reduce the demand for drafting employ ees, because engineers using C A D can do more of the design and layout work themselves, in stead of delegating this work to drafters. If automated packaging technology becomes more wide ly used, it could reduce the de mand for workers involved with manual packaging operations. Computer-assisted design and automatic packaging equipment are in limited use due to their high cost. Highly automated fabrication equipment is stand ard. Fabrication of semiconductors is highly automated. Pack aging the semiconductors after the fabrication step can be either very labor intensive or very automated, but the latter requires substantial capital investment. Increased automation in assem bly-line operations Computer controlled automatic sequencing and inserting equipment for electronic components, along with a new assembly line where operators control the line speed while inserting components manually, are being put into use to manufacture television receivers. In the production ol household appliances, larger capacity presses and a range ol automatic assembly processes are being introduced, includ ing limited applications of robots; and automatic equip ment for some welding, fastening, material handling, and production operations. New assembly technology gener ally lowers unit labor require ments and modifies job duties. New technology for assembly of appliances, for example, requires a higher proportion of worktime for equipment monitoring, ma chine feeding and loading, and maintenance. Manual tasks are reduced. This TV assembly line is the first U.S. installation of a technology expected to be used more widely in the United States and already in general use in Japan. Most of the automated assembly equip ment used in appliance manufac turing has been introduced in the last 5 years. Robots are likely to increase in use. Numerically controlled machine tools Numerically controlled machine tools are being used to turn out a wide range of products which are produced in small volume. In advanced systems, cutting sequences, machine speed, and other operations are controlled by a computer. Unit labor requirements in ma chining operations are lower in numerical control, and skill re quirements for machinists are modified. Operators monitor the machine tool operation rather than directly manipulate equip ment. with programmer and maintenance workers skilled in electronics required in numerical control installations. Nearly 5.000 numerically con trolled machine tools were in use in the industry in 1978, with in creased diffusion anticipated. The communication equipment and electrical industrial app ara tus sectors of the industry lead in application of numerical control. Advanced production equipment Advanced equipment is being used to turn out several key products of the industry. For example, some portions of electric motors are now produced on automatic equipment, resulting in increased productivity, in the manufacture of automobile headlights, filaments are positioned more accu rately and testing time reduced by use of new equipment. Flousehold appliances can be painted on automatic lines, with the use of electrostatic painting technology. I he elec trostatic spray process uses either liquid or dry powder paint. An electrocoating process, in which metal parts are dipped into paint, is also used lor high-volume finishing work on household appliances. Advanced production technolo gy generally reduces unit labor requirements. New electrostatic painting lines, for example, fea ture modern conveyor lines and little or no manual painting, l a b o r requirements are lower with dry powder paint than with liquid paint. Labor requirements are also low for electrocoating operations. Electrostatic and electrocoating processes are in use in a number of plants. other industry products. Electrodeposition painting technology is being used in household appliances, resulting in reduced labor requirements and materials costs. Table 3 provides a brief overview of the major technological changes taking place in this industry, their labor implications, and their expected diffusion. Produetion of electronic components Manufacturing electronic components (SIC 367) has traditionally been labor intensive, involving assemblers, machine operators, inspectors, and related occupations.1 This industry’s development of semiconductors since the mid-1960’s has changed its production methods and labor requirements considerably. Semiconductor devices perform most functions of electron tubes (except cathode ray tubes), but are smaller, more reliable, and generally 151 less expensive. As a result, semiconductor devices have replaced most electron tubes. The switch from manufacturing electron tubes to semiconductor devices requires more engineers, scientists, and technicians; and fewer assemblers and operators since many manufactur ing operations are automated. The impact of this technology is marked. Employment in the part of the industry manufacturing electron tubes has declined 'Electronic components (sic 367) consists of two major product groups. One group comprises all types of electron tubes: Television cathode ray picture tubes (sic 3672), all other radio and television tubes (sic 3671), and transmitting, industrial, and other special-purpose electron tubes (sic 3673). The second group contains several products; the most important from the standpoint of technological and occupational changesare semiconductorsand related devices(sic 3674). are larger and stronger than the circuit dies, and contain the electrical connections needed for electronic appli ances. In general, the packaging process involves bonding individual circuit dies onto metal stampings, then attach ing very fine wires to make the electrical connections between the dies and the electrodes on the stampings. Plastic covers are then molded around the dies, sealing them inside the now-complete packages. Finally, each circuit is tested to insure proper operation. Circuits are most commonly packaged manually, which is quite labor intensive. An alternative has been to use automated handling equipment, although high equip ment costs have limited this option. However, since labor costs are rising and packaging technology is improving, use of automated equipment may increase. steadily, while employment in the rest of the industry— including semiconductors—has risen sharply. The first steps in fabricating a semiconductor device— circuit design and mask making—are complex and re quire high-level technology. Many months are needed to design a complex integrated circuit and to make photo masks from which the circuits will be produced. Design and layout involve determining which electronic compo nents (transistors, resistors, etc.) are required to make the circuit perform as desired; then deciding how to arrange the circuit components in the circuit base material. Conventional methods of circuit design and layout— drawing circuits by hand on graph paper and assembling “bread board” circuits for testing—are slow and require skilled scientists and technicians. Computer-assisted design (C A D ) is faster, more accurate, and allows the designer flexibility in circuit design and layout. Developing a CAD system requires complex programming to store information in the computer and to display and position the simulated circuits on a cathode ray tube terminal. CAD is used by only a few manufacturers, since equipment and software costs are high and the system must be used intensively to be cost effective. But where it can be used, results can be dram atic: In some applications for thick-film integrated circuits, computer-aided design reduced costs by 300 percent.2 As CAD technology is diffused more widely, several occupations will be affected. Computer specialists will be needed for initial program set-up, but this could be a one time operation for each CAD system. Drafters might be largely bypassed as engineers use video terminals for design and layout. Computer control may also be extended to photographic and mask-making operations, similar to automatic printing plate technology used in the graphic arts industry. This could reduce employment of technicians who presently do the photographic work in mask making. Integrated circuit fabrication is a highly automated, batch-type process that can produce hundreds of sepa rate, complete circuits in each production run. Silicon cylinders several feet long by several inches in diameter are sliced into thin wafers, loaded onto special trays, and put through production steps as a group. During produc tion, many tiny circuits are fabricated, side by side, across the surface of each wafer. Labor costs in integrated circuit fabrication are rela tively low because of extensive automation. Most labor requirements are associated with loading and unloading the trays of wafers, and with operating fabricating and testing equipment. After the wafer is cut into individual circuits, the tiny circuits are encased in protective packages. The packages PflicroeSeietraniie technology Microprocessors are a fairly recent development of semiconductor technology, and are of importance to the electronics industry both as a product sold to others and as a technology that can be applied to the industry’s own design and production operations. A microprocessor contains a complete miniature processing unit on a single silicon chip. It can be combined with otherchips contain ing memory, timer, and input-output functions to build a complete microcomputer system on a single circuit board. Designing and fabricating microprocessor chips is a very complex undertaking, but the range of applications is already substantial and is growing rapidly. The largest volume of microprocessors in use are low-powered 4-bit devices that provide relatively simple control functions. More powerful 8-bit devices, however, account for most of the revenue from sales related to microprocessors. Microprocessor-based systems are expected to dra matically change the function and capabilities of house hold appliances during the 1980’s. Estimates vary on the rate of diffusion of microelectronics in the appliance industry through the mid- 1980’s, but one industry source estimates that 50 percent of all major appliances will be controlled by microelectronic devices.3 One of the most popular applications of microcomput ers will continue to be microwave ovens, where sophisti cated controls allow a wide range of cooking sequences and temperatures (including ovens that can be pro grammed by the user). Microcomputers also are being used in cooking ranges, dishwashers, clothes washers and dryers, and other household appliances. The growing application of microelectronics to indus trial and household appliance controls has brought about changes in design and production operations. Mechanical engineers and industrial designers work more closely with electrical engineers to develop electronic controls as substitutes for mechanical and electromechanical con- 2“Hybrid-circuit Technology Keeps Rolling Along," Electronics, July 22, 1976, p. 104. ’Donald L. Owens, “ Microelectronics: A New Horizon for Appli ances,” Appliance, July 1979, pp. 28-31. 152 trols. Assembly operations and labor requirements change when solid-state controls are used. It is no longer necessary, for instance, to route and solder large numbers of individual wires into place; thus fewer solderers are needed. Also, flat electrical cables and flexible printed circuits with plug-in connectors are replacing bundles of separate wires. There may be a secondary impact in that fewer components and less equipment are needed to produce electronic controls. This could reduce the labor needed for stock control, material handling, warehous ing, and transportation. Improvemonts in assembly technology Many types of assembly operations take place in the diverse group of industries that make up the electrical and electronic equipment industry. Technological innovations in assembly include increased automation and improved manual assembly lines for TV receiver producers and, in appliance manufacturing plants, automated assembly operations for household appliances and in-house assembly of printed circuit boards. A major domestic TV manufacturer has begun oper ating a new assembly line that has increased productivity and product quality. This is the first such TV receiver assembly line in operation in the United States, although this type of assembly line has been used for several years in Japan with considerable success. The new line features both computer-controlled automatic sequencing and component inserting equipment, as well as new tech nology for inserting parts manually, and is achieving productivity gains. On the new line, solid-state compo nents come packaged in reels from vendors. Only one type of component is included in each reel, and each reel may contain several hundred components. A number of these one-of-a-kind reels are mounted on a component se quencing machine which—under computer control— automatically removes individual components and de posits them on a conveyor in the sequence required for the automatic inserting machine. The conveyor transports each component through an automatic testing station to insure that it functions properly and is in the correct sequence. Finally, the components are automatically taped onto a new reel for use in the inserting machine, which automatically inserts components onto the circuit boards and then cuts and crimps the wire leads on each component to secure them to the board. Completed circuit boards are transported through an automated wave soldering machine that solders all electrical connec tions in one operation. Most operators on the new line originally held assem bly jobs involving manual insertion of components into circuit boards or manual assembly of parts onto the television chassis. When the automated equipment was brought into the plant, this group was retrained to load and operate the machines. The machine operator posi tions involve higher skill and pay levels. 153 Productivity is increased with the automatic sequenc ing and inserting equipment in that operators can insert more components per hour than is possible with the same number of people manually inserting components into circuit boards. Additionally, quality is improved since every component in the automatic line is tested before being inserted into the boards. A major feature of the new line is the specially designed assembly equipment for manually inserting components that cannot be handled on the automatic equipment. In the manufacture of appliances, improved tech nology is being installed in major production tasks. Sheet-metal components are being fabricated by larger capacity presses fed directly from coils of sheet metal. These components are produced at high speeds with a minimum of manual handling. New technology for high-volume assembly also is being introduced. Assembly tasks are labor intensive. When assembly lines become automated, unit labor requirements are lowered and job skills frequently shift to machine monitoring, machine feeding and unloading, and machine maintenance. One manufacturer is using automatic assembly tech niques to insert a retaining pin into the spout cap of a tea kettle, in place of a manually fastened screw-and-nut assembly. The automatic equipment has increased the assembly rate by 84 percent, lowered unit labor require ments, and decreased fastener costs. Another appliance manufacturer has installed an automatic line to assemble washing machine cabinets that has a maximum output of 350 cabinets an hour. Sheetmetal blanks pass through presses that shape them into cabinets, which then move past automatic welding stations where gussets and brackets are attached. The cabinets next are transported by conveyor through a manned inspection station and then to the finishing area. The entire line is staffed by three operators and one inspector, who checks-cabinets as they come off the line. In a less mechanized, conventional system with the same volume of output, labor requirements would be higher. A solid-state control system with a cathode ray tube (CRT) display terminal provides data on malfunctions and defects which facilitate repairs. The automatic assembly line has increased output by 40 percent, raised cabinet quality, and improved operator safety.4 Robots are being used in several assembly applications by one large manufacturer of appliances to cut costs and improve productivity. In one application, two robots are used to load and unload a press that trims plastic liners used in refrigerators. In another application elsewhere on the assembly line, two more robots spray the interiors of the refrigerator cabinets with an adhesive that holds a layer of foam insulation;each robot takes the place of two ■Uames Stevens. “A New Cabinet Line Pays off for Maytag.” Appliance, February 1976, pp. 34 35. workers and there is a 10-percent reduction in the amount of adhesive material used.5 One manufacturer recently built a highly mechanized assembly line for energy-saving refrigerators that speeds production and testing procedures, and reduces labor requirements for machine operators, welders, and mate rial handlers. The cabinets are produced on a semiauto matic line that includes an automatic destacker (which transfers metal cabinet blanks onto the production line) and an automatic electric. resistance welding station. Serpentines -the metal tubes that carry freon inside refrigerators—are made in an off-line operation. Coils of metal tubing are fed into a machine that automatically straightens the tubing, then cuts and bends it into the proper dimensions for installation in refrigerators. Solidstate controls give flexibility in programming the equip ment to make serpentines of varied sizes. Foam insulation is injected into the cabinets on a 6station automatic foaming installation that utilizes solidstate controls. Only one person is needed to operate this equipment. Cabinets are brought by conveyor belt, where a system of photo cells and magnetic tape readers routes the cabinets—via a turntable and runout conveyors—to the proper foaming station. The cabinets are automatical ly positioned on the foaming fixtures, filled with insula tion, and lowered onto another conveyor to leave the foaming operation.6 Appliance manufacturers have begun to assemble their own printed circuit boards instead of purchasing them from electronic component suppliers. Thus, technology and labor are “transferred” from one sector of the electrical and electronic equipment industry to another. The assembly of printed circuit (PC) boards involves inserting resistors, capacitors, integrated circuit (ic) chips, and other components onto the boards, soldering all connections, then cleaning and inspecting the completed boards. Assembly-methods range from largely manual tasks—the predominant method at this time—to semiautomatic and fully automatic processes. There are several “aided manual” systems that allow relatively unskilled operators to assemble complete PC boards. One of these systems, for example, positions the PC board in a machine which guides the operator through a sequence of production steps by illuminating the appropriate holes in the PC board into which each succeeding component is to be inserted. At the same time, a tray of parts is positioned so that only the proper component is accessible to the operator. If the more automatic processes become more prominent, the employment of assemblers will be affected. increasingly in the electrical and electronic equipment industry. They are used most extensively in the communication equipment and electrical industrial apparatus sectors of the industry to turn out a wide range of products which are produced in small volume. More than 1,000 numerically controlled machine tools are being used in each of these two major sectors.7 In advanced numerical control systems, cutting sequences, machine speed, and other operations are controlled by a computer with significant savings in unit labor requirements, tooling costs, and lead time. The function of the machine operator has changed from direct manual manipulation of equipment to monitoring the operation of the machine tool and loading and unloading parts. A programmer—a new position -develops the sequence of operations, tools to be used, and feed and speeds of the machine tool. Maintenance workers with a knowledge of electronics are needed to service numerical control systems. The outlook is for furtheradvances in numerical control technology including its use for inspection of parts. Advanced production equipment Other production processes where new technology is being used include the manufacture of portions of elec tric motors, testing of automobile headlamps, and paint ing of household appliances. Automated stator production. Automated equipment is being used to manufacture stators for electric motors. Automatic presses stamp out selected parts, insulation is inserted automatically into the stator core, and coils are wound and inserted automatically. The new equipment has considerably increased line speed, increasing the output without increasing the work force. Automobile headlamp testing. Photometric equipment that evaluates and records headlamp performance auto matically is helping manufacturers test headlamps to ensure they meet specifications set by the Federal Govern ment. The time required to test headlamps has declined from 20 minutes to less than 5 minutes, with sophisticated optical equipment available to position headlamp fila ments to close tolerance, thus increasing worker output and productivity. Advanced painting technology. New technology for the electrical depositing of paint onto household appliances is being introduced more widely. In electrostatic painting, paint particles are electrically charged and sprayed onto surfaces carrying an opposite electric charge to form a strong bond. The painted surface is then baked to a hard finish. The electrostatic process can be used with liquid or “wet” paint or the increasingly popular dry powder paint. Numerically controlled machine tools Numerically controlled machine tools are being used 5“Robots Join the Labor Force,” Business Week, June 9, 1980, p. 68. hGene Morgan, “A Sophisticated System Speeds Production, "A p p li ance. September 1977, pp. 50 52. 154 7“The 12th American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equip ment 1976 78,” American Machinist. December 1978. Labor requirements in the new electrostatic systems are lowered since material handling and painting tasks are largely automatic; robots are used in some installations. At one plant manufacturing household appliances, an operator manning a control console on a newly installed wet painting electrostatic line can change paint colors in 60 seconds. Quality of painting is improved and main tenance costs are lowered. Dry powder paint, used in the electrostatic process, is expected to be employed more widely during the 1980’s. Dry powder painting systems require fewer operators than liquid or “wet” systems since paint mixing is elimi nated and manual touch-up is reduced. Other factors favorable to further diffusion include easier paint han dling and clean-up operations. Energy requirements also are lower. One firm which replaced a wet system with a porcelain enamel powder system reported labor costs were lower by 33 percent, rejects and materials were re duced by 50 percent, and quality was improved.8 A dis advantage is the inability of dry painting systems to handle frequent color changes. In 1976, nearly ^ e le c tro static thin-film powder spraying systems for appliances were in use. Additional installations are forecast for the 1980’s.9 Another form of electrodeposition—electrocoating— involves immersing a metal part into a tank of coating material. The metal and the liquid in the tank carry oppo site electrical charges, which form the bond, providing a continuous, evenly deposited film on the metal part. This process was introduced for high-volume finishing opera tions in the mid-1960’s, and has since gained wide accept ance, especially for applying primer coats on appliances. The process is less labor intensive than conventional painting processes, gives a uniform coating even on intri cately shaped objects that have hidden or recessed areas, minimizes material costs because there is almost no wasted paint, and causes much less air and water pollu tion.10 Output and Productivity Out0©@lk Output The electrical and electronic equipment industry turns out a variety of products for government, industry, and consumer use. This product diversity is shown in table 4, which presents output growth in major industry sectors. Output in the industry as a whole has increased at a relatively high annual rate. According to the Federal Reserve Board production index for this industry, output grew steadily from 1960 through 1980, averaging a 8“Plant Experiences with Porcelain Enamel Powders,” Appliance, November 1978, pp. 49, 67. ’Gene Morgan, “Focus: Powder Coating,” Appliance, September 1976, pp. 45-49. l0Gene Morgan, “Electrocoating," Appliance, November 1978, pp. 39-41. 155 TabB@ 4. Output growth in electrical and electronic equipment, 19SO-80 SIC 36 361,2 363 365 366 367 369 Industry sector Total electrical and elec tronic equipment2 ........... Electrical equipment and parts ........................ Household appliances .. Radio and TV receiving equipment .................... Communication equipment .................... Electronic com ponents .......................... Miscellaneous electrical equipment .................... Average annual percent change' 1960-80 1960-67 1967-80 5.9 10.5 4.2 4.2 4.6 8.1 8.7 2.8 2.5 3.3 13.8 .6 3.8 7.0 2.7 12.5 22.0 8.8 5.5 7.2 5.0 ' Least squares trend method. includes data for SIC 364, electric lighting and wiring equipment, not available separately. SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. growth rate of 5.9 percent a year. As shown in table 4, the rate of growth in output was substantially higher during 1960-67 than in 1967-80. There was a slight dip in output during 1970 and 1971, after which output climbed to a peak in 1974, dropped rather abruptly in 1975, and then rose sharply in 1976 through 1980. Output in the electronic components industry (electron tubes, semiconductors, integrated circuits, etc.) has grown more rapidly than in any other industry in the group, increasing at an average annual rate of 12.5 percent during 1960-80, more than double the annual growth rate for total electrical and electronic equipment over the same period. Most of this expansion in output has been in integrated circuits—which include micro processors, introduced in the mid-1970’s and gaining widespread acceptance. Passive components (such as capacitors, resistors, and connectors) and discrete semiconductors have made lesser contributions. Output of electron tubes was fairly stable during the 1970’s; the decline in production of receiving tubes (as solid-state components became more widely used) was offset by slight gains in TV picture and specific-purpose tubes. Output growth was slowest in radio and TV and communication equipment. Consumer discretionary income and imports affect the level and growth of output in the radio and TV industry—which includes a number of consumer electronic components in addition to radio and TV receivers. In communication equipment, telephone and telegraph products account for almost onethird of the value of industry shipments. The remaining two-thirds consist of electronic systems and equipment for which the U.S. Government is the major purchaser— especially the Departments of Defense and Transporta tion, and the National Aeronautics and Space Adminis tration. Output growth, therefore, depends heavily upon 1 the demand from new households, business communica tion needs, and Federal Government procurement policies. Table 5. Output per employee hour in selected electrical and electronic equipment industries, 1SS0-79 Output per employee hour The expansion of output in the major sectors of the electrical and electronic equipment industry will continue to depend on several factors. In electronic components, for example, the growing commercial diffusion of a relatively new product, microprocessors (a complex integrated circuit finding application throughout the economy in a growing number of products from games to industrial robots), will require further expansion of production facilities. In electrical equipment, demand for electric transformers and switchgear depends heavily upon residential, commercial, and industrial construc tion. In major household appliances, population growth, family starts, and housing construction influence final demand. SIC Industry Average annual percent change 1960-79 1960-67 1967-79 3621 Motors and generators 2.1 5.6 1.2 3631,32, 33,39 Major household appliances .................. 4.4 6.1 3.9 3641 Electric lamps ............... 1.8 2.8 2.1 3645,46, 47,48 Lighting fixtures ........... '2.6 22.9 32.6 3651 Radio and TV receiving sets ............................... 3.9 6.0 3.4 '1961-78. 21961 -67. 31967-78. SOURCE : Bureau of Labor Statistics. Productivity Although a productivity measure for total electrical and electronic equipment is not published by the b l s , the measures available for several of the individual industries indicate that productivity change varies significantly by industry, and that growth rates have slowed over the past decade.11 The rate of increase in output per employee hour in the industries for which BLS publishes measures ranged during 1960-79 from an annual rate of 1.8 percent in electric lamps to an annual rate of 4.4 percent in major household appliances (table 5). In household appliances, output grew more rapidly than employee hours during 1960-68; output continued to grow slowly and employee hours declined during 1969-79. In all five of the industries included in table 5, the rate of increase in output per employee hour was lower from 1967 to 1979 than from 1960 to 1967. The sharpest decline in productivity was in motors and generators. The extent to which technology affected the movement of productivity cannot be measured precisely. In all five of these industries, and in others for which BLS measures are not available, new technology has reduced unit labor requirements in selected production operations. The anticipated higher levels of spending for new plant and equipment could contribute to further productivity gains in key production tasks. invested substantial funds for capital improvements, including the latest production technologies discussed in this report. In 1976, expenditures for new plant and equipment totaled $1.7 billion (constant 1972 dollars), more than twice the $800 million invested in I960.12 Capital expenditures per production worker averaged $1,385 in 1976, well above the average of $803 in 1960. The pace of capital spending has been uneven. Over the longer term 1960-76 period, expenditures for plant and equipment rose at an annual rate of 5.3 percent. Capital spending during 1960-67 increased at a substantially higher annual rate of 14.0 percent. In the 1967-76 period, however, during which expenditures fluctuated markedly, outlays (in constant dollars) declined by an average annual rate of 0.2 percent. Between 1973 and 1976, the decline averaged 7.8 percent a year. Capital spending also varied significantly among the individual industries which make up the total electrical and electronic equipment industry. The electronic components industry led all industries in the group with $478 million soent for new plant and equipment in 1976. Expenditures in communication equipment were the second highest, $399 million in 1976. Combined, these two industries were the source of more than one-half of capital spending. Capital expenditures The electrical and electronic equipment industry has Research and development The electrical and electronic equipment industry is a leader in research and development ( r & d ) spending. According to the National Science Foundation, R&D expenditures by the electrical and electronic equipment 11 Productivity measures are published by the b i . s for the following five industries: Motors and generators (sic 3621); major household appliances (sic 3631, 32, 33, and 39); radio and TV receiving sets (sic 3651); electric lamps (sic 3641); and lighting fixtures (sic 3645, 46, 47, 48). See Productivity Measures fo r Selected Industries, 1954-79, Bulletin 2093 (1981). 12Capital expenditures data are from unpublished, deflated total annual investment series developed in the b l s Office of Economic Growth and Employment Projections. See Capital Stock Estimates fo r Input-Output Industries: Methods and Data, Bulletin 2034 (1979). Expenditures for 1976 are the latest available. Investment 156 industry totaled $7.6 billion in 1979, up from the $2.9 billion allocated in 1963.'1 In 1979, this industry ranked second only to aircraft and missiles in total funds allocated to R&D. Federal Government R&D funds accounted for 42 percent of the $7.6 billion spent in 1979, and company funds, 58 percent. Since 1973, company funds for R&D in electrical machinery and communica tions have exceeded Federal Government R&D funds. The electrical and electronic equipment and communi cation industries employed 94,700 R&D scientists and engineers (full-time equivalent) in 1980, leading all other major industry groups for which the National Science Foundation provides data. Table 6. Average annual rates o f change in employment, electri cal and electronic equipment, 1SSQ-8G SIC 1960-67 1967-80 Total electrical and electronic equip ment ................................. 1.6 4.1 0.6 Electrical transmission and distribution equipment __ .1 2.3 -1.6 Electrical industrial apparatus............................. 1.7 3.0 1.1 363 Household appliances ......... .8 2.5 -.3 364 Electrical lighting and wiring equipment .............. 2.2 6.3 .6 Radio and TV receiving equipment ........................... .0 6.8 -2.6 Communication equip ment ..................................... .7 3.0 -.5 367 Electronic components ....... 3.4 7.8 2.4 369 Miscellaneous electrical equipment ........................... 2.9 1.0 3.3 36 361 362 365 ''These are current-dollar data; the increase in real terms is not as great. Before 1978, the National Science Foundation published r&d expenditure data for both electrical and electronic equipment (sic 36) and communications (sic 48) as one combined figure. Very little R&D work is done in sic 48. It is largely a service industry that uses equipment developed and manufactured insic 36. Beginning in 1978, R&Ddata for the two industries are published separately. http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ 157 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Average annual percent change’ (all employees) 1960-80 Employment amd Occupational Trends Employment The industry employed slightly over 2.1 million workers in 1980 compared to 1.4 million in 1960—a 1.6percent annual growth rate (chart 9). More than one-half of the industry work force in 1980 was engaged in manufacturing communication equipment and electronic components. The trend in employment, as in other measures for this group of industries, varied among the major industry sectors (table 6). Employment in electronic components increased at the greatest annual rate (3.4 percent) during 1960-80, a period of generally strong demand for these products, particularly integrated circuits (which include microprocessors). The average annual employment growth rate has been slowest in electric transmission and distribution equipment and radio and TV receiving equipment. Employment in these industries increased during the 1960’s, then declined during the 1970’s, so that by 1980 the level was about the same as in 1960. Employment growth in the electrical and electronic equipment industry was highest during 1960-67, compared to the more recent 1967-80 period. As indicated in chart 9, employment increased at an annual rate of 4.1 percent during 1960-67, compared to an annual rate of 0.6 percent during 1967 -80. Employment dropped sharply (by about 14 percent) between 1974 and 1975 as demand slackened. This pattern of employment g ro w th -a higher rate during the earlier of the two periods discussed in this report, followed by a lower growth rate or a decline in employment during the latter portion—was experienced in all industry sectors except miscellaneous electrical supplies. Industry sector 366 ' Based on least squares trend method. SOURCE : Bureau of Labor Statistics. The outlook is for employment in this group of industries to increase at an average annual rate of 1.7 to 2.5 percent between 1980 and 1990, according to b l s projections based on three versions of economic growth.14 Occupations The structure of occupations is expected to undergo change. As shown in chart 10, all the major occupational groups except sales workers are expected to increase between 1978 and 1990. Operatives, the largest occupational group in the industry, accounting for about 45 percent of total employment in 1978, are projected to increase by more than one-fourth between 1978 and 1990. They will continue to be by far the largest occupational group (47 percent of total employment in 1990). Assemblers make 14 Projections for industry employment in 1990 are based on three alternative versions of economic growth for the overall economy, developed by b l s . The low-trend version is based on a view of the economy marked by a decline in the rate of expansion of the labor force, continued high inflation, moderate productivity gains, and modest increases in real output and employment. In the high-trend version I,the economy is buoyed by higher labor force growth, much lower unemployment rates, higher production, and greater improvements in prices and productivity. The high-trend version II is characterized by the highGNP growth of high-trend I, but assumes the same labor force as the low trend. Productivity gains are quite substantial in this alternative. On chart 9, level A is the low trend, level B is high-trend I, and level C is high-trend II. Greater detail on assumptions is available in the August 1981 issue of the M onthly Labor Review. up more than one-third of the operatives; they are expected to increase in number at a slightly higher rate than the average for all occupations in the industry. Although new technologies applicable to assembly operations will be diffused more widely, assembly of household appliances and other products is expected to continue to involve a high degree of manual tasks. In some assembly operations, however, manual tasks are expected to decline and job skills increasingly will involve more equipment monitoring, machine feeding and unloading, and equipment maintenance. In contrast to assemblers, employment of solderers is expected to decline by 30 percent and welders and flamecutters by 8 percent between 1978 and 1990 as automated equipment is diffused more widely. In craft occupations, employ ment of mechanics, repairers, and installers is expected to increase sharply as mechanization of production operations continues in the 1980’s. The rate of employment change in the major occupational categories presented in chart 10 is expected to vary among the industry sectors. Thus it is useful to examine Bl.S occupational projections for three industry groups: Household appliances (SIC 363); radio and TV and communication equipment (SIC 365,6); and a miscellaneous group that covers SIC 361, 2, 4, 7, and 9. Less change in the composition of occupations is expected in the radio, TV, and communication equipment group than in the others. Employment of operatives, who account for more than one-third of the employees in this industry group, is expected to increase by about 12 percent between 1978 and 1990. However, fewer solderers will be needed. Professional and technical workers are expected to increase at a greater rate, while sales workers, service workers, and clerical workers are projected to decline. Strong employment growth is expected in household appliances—numerically the smallest of the three industry groups. Sales workers is the only major occupational group in which a decline is expected. Professional and technical workers should increase, although at a lower rate than the other occupational groups. Employment in all occupations except sales workers is expected to grow in the miscellaneous group. Large increases are expected for managers, clerical workers, craft workers, operatives, and laborers. Professional and technical workers and service workers should experience smaller employment increases. Adjustment of workers to technological change Although new technology is not expected to result in major displacement, some collective bargainingcontracts in the electrical and electronic equipment industry contain specific provisions concerning technological change. One such agreement requires that the company provide the union (the International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers) with at least 4 weeks’advance notice before installing numerical-control or computer-control equipment that will displace employees. The contract also requires that, where reasonable and practicable, the company will retrain displaced employees in order of seniority. The Communications Workers of America (CWA) and the International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers both have contracts with one large firm that contain a clause providing early retirement, under certain conditions, for workers displaced by technological change. A CWA contract recently negotiated with a large employer contains provisions for a joint labormanagement Technological Change Committee to establish methods to avoid adverse impacts of techno logical change on the work force. The CWA contract also provides protection for employees downgraded because of technological change. Where no specific provision relating to technological change is included in the contract, general provisions pertaining to seniority, retirement, training, supplemen tal unemployment benefits, and related topics can facilitate adjustment of employees to the requirements of new technology. About two-thirds of the industry’s production workers are estimated to be unionized. The major unions, all AFL-ClO affiliates, are the International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers; the International Union of Electrical, Radio and Machine Workers; and the Communications Workers of America. SELECTED REFERENCES Carnes, Richard B. “Productivity and Technology in the Electric Lamp Industry,” Monthly Labor Review, August 1978, pp. 15-19. Hunter, Karl. “What Microelectronics Is Doing for Your Competitor,” Appliance, May 1978, pp. 65-68. “Hybrid-circuit Technology Keeps Rolling Along,” Electronics, July 22, 1976, pp. 91-109. Morgan, Gene. “Electrocoating," Appliance, November 1978, pp. 39-41. Morgan, Gene. “A Sophisticated System Speeds Production,” Appliance, September 1977, pp. 50-52. Oldham, William G. “The Fabrication of Microelectronic Circuits,” Scientific American, September 1977, pp. 111-128. Otto, Phyllis Flohr. “The Pattern of Productivity in the Lighting Fixtures Industry,” Monthly Labor Review, September 1978, pp. 31-37. Owens, Donald L. “Microelectronics: A New Horizon for Appliances,” Morgan, Gene. “Focus: Powder Coating,” Appliance, September 1976, Appliance, July 1979, pp. 28-31. pp. 45-49. http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ 158 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis “The Microprocessor: A Revolution for Growth,” Business Week, Mar. 19, 1979, pp. 42B-42X. Phillips, Donald C., and Steve Wiseman. “Trends in Microelectronics for Appliances,” Appliance, May 1978, pp. lb-19. “Robots Join the Labor Force,” Business Week, June 9, 1980, pp. 62-65, 68, 73, 76. Stevens, James. “A New Cabinet Line Pays Off for Maytag ” Appliance, February 1976, pp. 34-35. 159 York, James, and Horst Brand. “Productivity and Technology in the Electric Motor Industry,” Monthly Labor Review, August 1978, pp. 20-25. Technology and Labor in Electric and Gas Utilities Robert V. Critchlow S u m m a ry is expected to continue to increase at an average rate of 0.7 percent a year between 1977 and 1985. Occupational requirements may change somewhat in response to changes in the size of electric generating plants and the type of fuel used: Nuclear plants, for instance, will require a larger proportion of scien tists, engineers, technicians, and security staff com pared to fossil-fuel plants. The construction and maintenance of nuclear power plants require highly skilled welders and other craft workers. Some con cern exists that possible labor shortages in some craft and technical occupations could delay con struction of nuclear generating plants, and, if ex haust gas scrubbers become mandatory on coal-fired plants, the number of engineers, technicians, and maintenance personnel could increase substantially. Technological changes in the electric power and gas industry continue to lower labor requirements in some occupations and raise productivity. Major in novations underway include the more widespread use of computers to assist generating plant control room operators in logging data, monitoring equip ment, and performing calculations; an increase in the number of nuclear power stations, which generally require a more highly skilled work force than con ventional plants of similar capacity; and the return to coal as a major fuel source. The development of highly mechanized vehicles for power line construc tion and repair has changed the size and occupation al makeup of power line work crews. The more widespread use of extra-high-voltage transmission also has brought about changes in power line repair techniques. Capital expenditures have increased considerably since 1960, reaching a level of $25.8 billion in 1977. (In real terms, however, the increase is not this great because the price of new plant and equipment has increased.) Electric utility companies account for most of the industry’s expenditures—about 84 per cent in 1977. Capital spending is expected to in crease fairly steadily over the next decade. Electric utilities cancelled or postponed part of their planned capital expenditures for 1974 and 1975 for a combi nation of reasons, including unfavorable economic conditions, forecast reductions in demand, and prob lems with regulatory and environmental concerns, but expenditures rose again in 1976 and 1977. Output per all-employee hour increased at an aver age annual rate of 4.6 percent from 1960 to 1977, with the most rapid increase occurring between 1960 and 1967. Due in part to technological changes, labor requirements for operating and maintenance employ ees in electric generating plants have declined since 1960, and are lower per kilowatt of capacity for large plants than for small plants. Employment grew at the rather slow rate of 1.2 percent a year between 1960 and 1977, reaching a peak of 684,200 workers in 1974 and declining to 673,000 in 1977. Employment Technology in the 1@7©5s Major technological changes are taking place in the electric power and gas industry which directly affect the industry’s work force and productivity. These include the more widespread use of electronic computers, nuclear power generation, and coal as a major fuel for electric generating plants. Extra-highvoltage transmission will continue to make possible the economical transmission of large quantities of electric power. In constructing and maintaining transmission lines, labor requirements are being re duced through the more efficient utilization of skilled workers and fleets of mechanized vehicles by com puterized scheduling of work assignments. The me chanized fleets, however, require an increase in ve hicle maintenance crews. Innovations such as pro cess control computers, being introduced in an al ready highly instrumented environment, will have a less extensive impact on employment and occupa tions than such changes as nuclear power installa tions, which require substantially more scientific and technical staff than conventional installations of sim ilar capacity. Research noW underway on coal lique faction and gasification processes may ultimately provide a clean-burning fuel from an abundant ener gy source to replace oil and natural gas. Reprint from BLS Bulletin 2005 (1979), Technological Change and its L abor Im pact in Five Energy Industries. 160 Electronic e@mpyt©rs Computers are used extensively in the utilities industry. In addition to their now commonplace use in business operations, computers are being applied to generating plant operations, control over transmis sion systems, and scheduling of work assignments for line crews. Process control computers in generating plants provide assistance to control room operators in start up operations, data logging, monitoring, and per formance calculations, and they are becoming stand ard equipment in new plants and in many older large plants. Of the plants sampled in a recent survey, nearly 76 percent used automatic data collection for computerized performance calculations, and 24 per cent had computers with control-function capacity.1 Fuel savings, increased safety and reliability, re duced chance of operating errors leading to equip ment damage, and improvements in equipment utili zation are claimed. Many large plants have opera tions that are so complex that a substantial amount of automatic control is required for safety and relia bility. Process control computers are commonly applied to economic dispatch and automatic load control— operations principally concerned with dispatching power over transmission lines and the coordination of power generation and interchange. These opera tions have become so complex that dispatching per sonnel have difficulty assimilating the vast amount of data available. The solution has been the develop ment of automatic control systems typically con sisting of digital computers, local and remote cath ode ray tube (CRT) terminals, animated diagram boards, and a network of telemetering devices. These systems provide dispatchers with the informa tion and control necessary to supply power economi cally at proper voltage and frequency throughout the power system. The’ optimization of power produc tion, continuous control of generating units, and improved reliability and accuracy of the system provide direct economic benefits. Indirect benefits include the improved coordination of loads between interconnected utilities. There are some applications of process control computers to full closed-loop control of generating plants—although this is generally limited to hydroe lectric stations. Sn one such application, a 4-unit 285megawatt (Mw) hydroelectric plant can be operated automatically, either locally or by remote control from a central dispatching center. In another appli cation, a 4-unit 225-Mw hydro plant is controlled from a location 8 miles away; the only personnel at the plant are security guards. The extent to which closed-loop remote control of generating plants is used is not known, but, where used, it allows some reduction in operating personnel. Computers can be applied to a number of other operations, such as plant design, long- and short-term planning, fossil-fuel scheduling, and nuclear core analysis. The range of computer applications will probably grow in the future as computer hardware and software technology continues to develop. Many of the computer applications require the use of sophisticated mathematical models and techniques —which, in:turn, require programmers, systems ana lysts, peripheral-equipment operators, and others in computer-related occupations. The demand for peo ple with computer-related job skills should increase along with the increasing range of computer apptica<-tions. Also, utility engineers must have training in computer techniques to use computers for transmis sion and distribution (T&D) systems planning and for studies of T&D operations. Computers ,are also being used more widely to schedule line trew s with highly mechanized vehicles to reduce time and cost in constructing and main taining transmission and distribution lines. Mydtear p©w©r Nuclear generation of electric power has become increasingly important over the past several years as costs of commercial power generation have risen and as concern has mounted over the future availa bility of petroleum. Problems associated with air pol lution caused by conventional power plants also have been a factor. By the end of 1977, 49 licensed nuclear plants were in operation, with 49,881 Mw, or 9.0 percent of total generating capacity.-2 The Feder al Energy Regulatory Commission has estimated that, by 1985, nuclear power plants may account for 18.6 percent of total generating capacity.-1 The increase in the number of completed nuclear power plants over the past several years has been less than anticipated. Inflation, combined with tight money markets and uncertainty as to future demand growth, has caused postponements and cancellations in the construction of a number of nuclear plants. Opposition to nuclear power plants based on con cern over safety and environmental factors, nuclear fuel reprocessing, and waste disposal also has caused delays and cancellations. In addition, the lead time for bringing a nuclear plant on line has in creased as a result of the growing complexity and size of the plants themselves, changing Federal regu lations concerning construction and operation proce dures, and problems in finding suitable sites. In late 2 M onthly Power Plant Reports, FPC Form 4, U.S. Department of Energy, 1977. 2 Department of Energy estimates. 1Gordon D. Friedlander, “ 20th Steam Station Cost Survey,” Electrical World , Nov. 15, 1977, p. 51. 162 Y afete & K3<a|©ir S@€ta@S®g y eham g® © in ©l©cfiric a n d g a s u t ilit ie s T echnology D escription L abor im plications Diffusion Electronic com puters Process control com puters in generating plants are used for d ata logging, m onitoring, and per form ance calculations, providing fuel savings, increased safety and reliability, and im provem ents in equipm ent and labor utilization. Process control com puters are com m only used in dispatching pow er over transm ission lines and coordinating generating and inter change operations. C om puter scheduling of labor and vehicles has reduced tim e and costs in m aintenance and construction operations. N u clear pow er generation Light-w ater reacto rs currently dom inate the industry and one high-tem perature gas reacto r is in use. Some developm ent w ork has been done on breed er reactors. Efforts are underw ay to standard ize nuclear pow er plant design in o rd er to facilitate the increasingly com plex licensing procedures. G reater dem and for scientific and technical specialists and security personnel than conventional pow e r plants. H igher skill require m ents for control room operators and construction and m aintenance crew s. B y the end of 1977, 49 licensed nuclear plant w ere in operation, providing about 9 percent o f total generating capacity. E x h au st gas scru b b ers for solid coalbum ing plants Exhaust gas scrubbers rem ove sulfur dioxide by forcing exhaust gases through a w ater and lime stone slurry o r som e o th er chem i cal process prior to venting the gases into the atm osphere. Scrubbers still have a num ber of problem s that must be solved before they can be considered com pletely successful. Increased labor requirem ents for constru ctio n , operating, and m aintenance activities. M ore than 24 scrubbers w ere in stalled or under construction in 1974, according to Federal Pow er C om m ission data. The num ber of installations is expected to in crease. Extra-high-voltage (E H V ) tran s mission o f electric pow er EH V technology has m ade possi ble the econom ical transm ission o f large blocks of pow er, facilitat ing the developm ent of regional pow er pools. Some increase in difficulty of w ork due to use of higher tow ers and need to use heavier equip m ent on higher voltage lines. Use of “ bareh an d ” m aintenance tech niques speeds repairs but requires special training. EH V technology now dom inates the transm ission of electric pow er. Productivity has been increased in the construction and m aintenance o f transm ission and distribution lines by the com bination of small, highly trained line crew s w ith a large num ber o f especially devel oped work vehicles. Line crew s now handle a greater am ount of w ork than was pre viously possible; consequently the num ber of people in this occupa tion has not grown as rapidly as the size of the transm ission and distribution netw ork. D em and has increased for vehicle m aintenance personnel. Presently in wide use. M echanized vehicles fo r con struction and m aintenance of pow er lines 162 R educes the tim e control room o perators and system load dis patchers spend reading instru m ents, logging d ata, and perform ing calculations. Load dispatchers would have difficulty assim ilating the am ount of available d ata w ithout com puter assistance. Increased dem and for people in com puter-related occupations. Som e utility engineers required to learn com puter techniques. Seventy-six percent of generating plants use autom atic d a ta collec tion for com puterized perform ance calculations, and 24 percent have com puters with control function capacity. 1972, lead time was about 7 years;45 by mid—1977, lead time had increased to roughly 10-12 years.5 Most nuclear plants are virtually custom built, which is time consuming and expensive. Standardized plant designs (perhaps based on previously approved de signs) that can be mass produced and approved as a group could shorten lead times by several years. The Nuclear Regulatory Commission is encouraging such an approach, and standardized plants are beginning to be constructed. To hasten the process of approv ing sites for nuclear power plants, the Federal Gov ernment is proposing that States create, in effect, “ site banks” by approving areas for nuclear plant construction in advance of any licensing requests by utility companies.6 There are several types of nuclear reactors in commercial operation or under development. Lightwater reactors (LWR’s) presently dominate the nu clear power industry. These reactors use enriched uranium-235 for fuel, which is somewhat limited in supply, and they utilize heat energy from the reactor core to convert water into the steam that drives the turbine-generator units. Light-water reactors with over 1,000-Mw capacities are now in operation. High temperature gas reactor (HTGR) technology is well developed in Europe. Only one gas-cooled reactor, of 330 Mw, is operating in the United States. Gas-cooled reactors offer greater thermal efficiency than light-water reactors (39-percent effi ciency for HTGR’s, compared to the 33- to 34-percent efficiency of LWR’s), reduce the effect of ther mal pollution, and use thorium as well as enriched uranium for fuel. For gas-cooled reactors to be commercially successful, their total generating costs must be Competitive with those of light-water reac tors and coal-fired plants, and conclusive cost data are not yet available. A third type of reactor—the breeder reactor—is in the development stage. The breeder reactor converts uranium-238 or thorium-232 to fissionable plutonium239 or uranium-233 at a faster rate than it consumes fuel, in effect creating more fuel than it uses. Most of the development work has been concentrated on the liquid-metal fast-breeder reactor, as this type of reactor has the fastest conversion rate. The future of breeder reactor technology is uncertain, however, since development work is expensive and technically difficult and requires extensive use of plutonium. Labor requirements in nuclear plants differ from those in fossil-fuel plants of similar capacity. Nucle ar plants tend to have more highly trained staffs, in 4 “ Nuclear Survey: Lead Times Stabilizing,” Electrical World, Oct. 15, 1972, p. 7. 5 “ Carter Seeking Speed-Up of Nuclear Plant Licensing,” The W ashington Post, Aug. 4, 1977, p. A4. 6 Ibid. 163 eluding a larger number of scientists, engineers, and technicians. More security personnel are required at nuclear plants—a service which used to be contract ed out to private guard and detective agencies but is now being handled to a larger extent by the utility firms themselves. Nuclear plant operators must be trained to work with fissionable material and must be licensed by the Federal Government. Construction and maintenance work in nuclear plants is done to very exacting specifications and requires craft work ers with very high levels of skill. Maintenance crews may be slightly larger at nuclear plants because maintenance procedures are more complex. Regula tions concerning radiation exposure sometimes ne cessitate the use of protective clothing, which might hamper working ability and decrease efficiency to some extent. Coal for fuel Coal is the most abundant energy source in the United States and was the primary fuel for steam generating plants before 1965. Between 1965 and 1972, many utility firms switched from coal to oil. Initially, this switch occurred because oil was less expensive, but during the latter part of this period pollution control also became an important consider ation. Much of the coal available in the United States has a high sulfur content and is a major source of air pollution from generating plants. Oil is a cleaner burning fuel. By 1974, the problems inher ent in heavy reliance upon oil became clear; limited domestic supplies and dependence upon foreign sources. Coal, therefore, has become important again to electric utilities. The sulfur dioxide emissions that result from burning solid coal remain a major air pollution prob lem. There are several possible solutions. There is low-sulfur coal available, primarily in the western part of the United States. This coal generally has a lower Btu (British thermal unit) content than highsulfur coal, requiring a greater quantity to be burned for the same energy input. The differences in quanti ty used would have an impact on generating plant storage capacity and on fuel and ash handling. There are also transportation expenses involved when us ing western low-sulfur coal in the eastern part of the country. A somewhat controversial solution is the installa tion in generating plants of exhaust gas scrubbers, which are cleaning devices that remove much of the sulfur dioxide from exhaust gases. Scrubber technol ogy is still developing and needs further refinement to be fully effective. Scrubbers are expensive—they can add up to 50 percent of the cost of a boiler-gen erator system. They also consume from 1.5 to 5 per cent of the plant’s output. 7 Reliability has also been a problem. The solution so far has been to build in redundant equipment or to step up maintenance op erations—both of which are expensive procedures. In one of the earliest scrubber installations, the plant maintenance force had to be increased by 50 percent to handle equipment breakdowns and corrosion problems.K Many scrubbers produce large amounts of watery sludge as a waste product. The disposal of this sludge is a major unresolved problem. The number of scrubber installations will probably increase because, in spite of the problems and ex penses involved, scrubbers do provide control over some of the pollutants caused by generating plants. Scrubbers are complex equipment, and, as the num ber of installations increases nationwide, the number of maintenance workers needed in the industry also will rise. An alternative to the direct burning of coal is the conversion of coal to a gas or a liquid. For electric utilities, advantages include the capability to remove sulfur and ash during the conversion, thereby reduc ing air pollution when the converted coal is burned. The coal converted by at least some of the several gasification and liquefaction procedures that have been proposed can be transported by pipeline. At present, however, coal gasification and liquefaction on a large scale are not commercially available, and the cost and reliability of the processes have yet to be proven. Given the present technology, these al ternatives are more expensive than the installation of exhaust gas scrubbers in generating plants.9 Some generating plants that were designed to burn oil or natural gas can also burn coal in liquid or gas eous form. Converting these plants to burn solid coal, however, would be prohibitively expensive and, in some cases, where insufficient land is availa ble for coal storage and for coal and ash handling equipment, technically impractical. Labor requirements in coal-fired plants tend to be higher than those in oil- or gas-fired plants. Using coal requires moving it from storage areas near the plant to furnaces in the plant and cleaning out the ash residue after the coal is burned. This work is performed by “ fuel and ash handlers,” a semiskilled occupation. The future use of coal in liquid or gas eous form, if ultimately proven commercially attrac tive for U.S. utilities, would eliminate the need for this occupation (as has occurred in gas-fired plants) and reduce total utility industry labor requirements. Research on conversion of coal into synthetic gas or to liquid form has been intensified because of vast coal resources available within the United States and concern over future availability of oil and natural gas. High-voltage transmission Extra-high-voltage (EHV) technology now domi nates the transmission of electric power. Develop ments that have facilitated the growth of EHV trans mission include the introduction of bundles of two or more conductors, insulator strings set in “ V” configurations to control swing, the use in some in stances of guyed structures in place of self-supporting towers, the use of aluminum and special steels in line structures for reduced maintenance require ments, and the use of helicopters to facilitate con struction. As of August 1977, there were almost 117,000 miles of EHV transmission lines in serv ice. 10 The development of EHV technology makes possible the economical transmission of large amounts of electric power over long distances, with significant reductions in right-of-way requirements and corresponding reductions in right-of-way mainte nance operations compared to what would have been required using lower voltage lines. EHV inter connections presently cover most of the country. The higher voltages involved in EHV transmission have caused some changes in work techniques. Line crews work on higher towers using longer, heavier “ hot sticks” and the more modern “ barehand” tech nique. “ Barehanding” is a process in which the worker handling an energized circuit becomes a part of the circuit, with precautions against grounding (such as working in an insulated fiberglass bucket or on a fiberglass ladder suspended from the line tow er). Under the proper circumstances, barehand re pairs can be completed in a fraction of the time re quired by more traditional methods. Power Bine construction and maintenance Construction and maintenance techniques continue to improve, with crew size and productivity un dergoing change. The use of helicopters in rough ter rain, chemicals to control brush on rights-of-way, and lighter metals in structures are among changes that have reduced construction time and mainte nance requirements for line crews. The vehicles used in constructing and maintaining transmission and distribution (T&D) lines have un- 10 Department of Energy, Federal Energy Regulatory Commis sion. 11 “ Mechanization Revolutionizes Construction,” Electrical World, June I. 1974, p. 164. 12 Ibid. 7 Paul H. Weaver, “ Behind (he Great Scrubber Fracas,” For tune , Feb. 1975, p. 112. 8 Ibid. 9 Lawrence H. Weiss, “ Clean Fuel and Scrubbing Compared,” Electrical W orld , Oct. I, 1976, pp. 70-73. 164 dergone considerable technological change over the past 10-15 years—a change that has had quite an impact on T&D workers. These vehicles (mostly truck chassis weighing 22,(XX) to 40,(XX) lbs.) carry hydraulically operated equipment, such as- 360-de gree rotating derricks and pole hole diggers, or aerial lifts with booms that can range from 20 to 150 feet high, or plows, backhoes, earth augers, cable pull ers, etc. This mechanization of mobile equipment was well underway by the early 1960’s and has con tinued to grow rapidly, as illustrated by the in creased use of aerial lifts: The average utility used 10 aerial lifts in 1962 and 97 lifts in 1974. M Vehicle mechanization grew so rapidly because utilities needed to keep up with increasing construc tion demands with minimum increases in cost and in the size of construction work crews. Additionally, the cost of labor was increasing more rapidly than the cost of construction equipment. In the mid1960’s, for example, the price of a 1/2-ton pickup truck was equal to a top line crew worker’s pay for 455 hours of work. In 1974, the cost of a new pickup truck was equivalent to a top line crew worker’s pay for only 325 hours.12 Mechanized mobile equipment has made possible a reduction in the size of construction work crews and T&D line crews. Large, all-purpose line trucks are used where work is concentrated in one area— but generally with crews of 6 people rather than the traditional 8- to 9-person line crews. A fleet of small er special-purpose vehicles with 2 or 3 crew mem bers each, equipped with 2-way radios and backed by computerized scheduling of work assignments, can generally provide the greatest productivity for work scattered over large areas. A modern transmis sion line crew might typically consist of 4 aerial lifts, an earth auger, and a digger/derrick truck with 2 crew members each, and a pickup truck for the su pervisor—7 specialized vehicles and a crew of 13 highly skilled workers. The growing mobile fleet requires an increasing commitment of resources—labor, equipment, and managerial skill—for maintenance and repair opera tions. Over 90 percent of the utilities that own their vehicle fleets operate service and repair facilities (al though some major repair work may be contracted out). 12 Scheduled maintenance programs are neces sary to maximize vehicle availability and minimize fleet operating costs. Managerial ability, sometimes combined with computerized scheduling and record keeping, is necessary to operate such programs. Maintenance personnel need to be familiar with both automotive and hydraulic servicing and repair.13* Investment Capital expenditures Expenditures for new plant and equipment in the major industry group electric, gas, and sanitary serv ices (SIC 49)<4 rose from $5.2 billion in 1960 to $25.8 billion in 1977, an average annual increase of 11.6 percent. (In real terms, however, the increase is not as great since the price of plant and equipment has risen over this period.) Most of the growth occurred after 1967, with expenditures increasing at an aver age rate of 10.8 percent a year between 1967 and 1977. The average rate of growth between 1960 and 1967 was 7.8 percent a year. Capital expenditures per nonsupervisory worker in the industry have grown almost fivefold over the past 17 years, from $10,143 per worker in 1960 to $46,638 per worker in 1977—an average increase of 10.8 percent a year. The average annual growth rate was 7.9 percent during 1960—67 and 10.0 percent during 1967-77. Electric utilities account for the largest portion of the industry’s capital expenditures, with 69.1 percent of 1960 expenditures and 83.7 percent of 1977 ex penditures. Electric utilities spent $3.6 .billion in 1960 and $21.6 billion in 1977—an increase averaging 13.2 percent a year. The average annual growth in spending during 1960 —67 was 8.9 percent; the rate during 1967-77 was 12.1 percent. The industry went through a period of economic uncertainty during the mid-1970’s which had an Im pact upon its capital spending activities. This is a highly capital-intensive industry which for more than 15 years had a steady, predictable growth in demand averaging 7.4 percent a year1-5 —a situation that al lowed an orderly growth in capital expenditures. However, in 1974 and to a lesser extent in 1975, construction and fuel costs rose rapidly while the growth in demand was well below the historical rate. High interest rates and low stock market prices lim ited the ability of utilities to raise funds in the mo ney market. Problems with regulatory and environ mental concerns continued. In response to this situa tion, electric utility firms cancelled or postponed a considerable part of their planned capital expendi tures. According to Business Week, 170,000 Mw or 14 Data are available from the Department of Commerce only for this broader SIC 49 industry grouping, which, in addition to including establishments which generate, transmit and/or distrib ute electricity, gas, or steam (SIC 491, 492, and 493), also in cludes establishments which distribute water, provide sanitary services, supply steam, and operate water supply systems for irri gation. 15 Carol J. Loomis, “ For the Utilities It’s a Fight for Surviv 13 Michael G. McGraw, “ Fleet Management Becomes More al,” Fortune, Mar. 1975, p. 97. Sophisticated,” Electrical World, Aug. 1, 1975, p. 38. http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ 165 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 47.2 percent of a planned 360,090-Mw generating capacity were cancelled or significantly delayed in 1974.16178 Electrical World noted that in 1975 capital spending declined for the first time in the industry’s history. 17 Expenditures turned upward again in 1976 and 1977. This resumption of capita! spending reflected the general improvement in economic conditions af ter 1975, the inability of utility companies to further postpone to a significant degree generating plant construction in the face of growing demand, and concern over power shortages and service reliability. The outlook over the next several years is for a continued increase in expenditures. McGraw-Hill’s 1977 annual survey of business plans for capital spending^ indicated that the electric utility industry planned to spend $25.2 billion for new plant and equipment in 1978, $27.5 billion in 1979, and $29.2 billion in 1980. Approximately 87-88 percent of these funds were to be for machinery and equip ment; the balance was for buildings and vehicles. A slower rate of growth in demand could ease the pressure on generating capacity. Demand (kilowatthour sales) actually dropped slightly in 1974—a short-run response to conservation efforts, the eco nomic downturn, and unexpectedly large increases in the price of all energy sources, including electric power. After a period of adjustment to higher ener gy costs, demand began to grow again, but at less than the historical rate of 7.4 percent a year. The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission’s Bureau of Power considers a growth rate of 5.7 percent a year to be likely between 1977 and 1986. Funds for research and development There are several sources of research itnd devel opment funds in the electric power industry: Equip ment manufacturers, the Federal Government, and the utility companies themselves. Equipment manu facturers perform much of the basic research and development (R&D) work applicable to the electric power industry, recouping their costs by selling the equipment they develop to the power companies. Federal R&D funds have been largely concentrated in the development of nuclear power. According to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, annual R&D expenditures for class A 16 “ Utilities: Weak Point in the Energy Future,” and class B electric utilities19 were in the range of $37 million to $47 million between 1966 and 1970, rising to $239 million in 1973. Expenditures declined slightly to $234 million in 1974, but rose again to $290 million in 1976. Only about 20 percent of theSe funds were spent directly by utility companies. The majority of the funds went to organizations such as the Edison Electric Institute, the Electric Power Research Institute, and the Battelle Memorial Insti tute. Production and Productivity Outlook Output Output per employee hour increased at an average an nual rate of 4.6 percent from 1960 to 1977. The growth rate was higher during the 1960-67 period (6.3 percent per year) than between 1967 and 1977 (3.0 percent per year). Output has grown steadily for many years. In 1974, however, demand for electricity declined in response to price increases, economic conditions, and conservation efforts. This contributed signifi cantly to the first drop in this industry’s output since at least 1947. In 1975, output returned roughly to the 1973 level, and increased again in 1976 and 1977. Output will probably continue to increase through the coming decade for the industry as a whole. Demand for electricity, as discussed earlier, is ex pected to increase steadily. For gas utilities,, howev er, the outlook is not so positive. The supply of domestic natural gas is declining and synthetic gas is not expected to be available in significant quantity until the late 1980’s. Use of imported natural gas can be increased to some extent. The net result is a pro jected slight decline in the gas supply through 1985.20 Productivity Output in electric power and gas (BLS weighted in dex) increased at an averaged annual rate of 5.9 percent between 1960 and 1977. During the 1960-67 period, growth in output averaged 6.9 percent a year, while the 1967-77 period experienced a lower average annual growth rate of 4.2 percent. There may be a long-term decline occurring in the rate of productivity growth. Although output contin ues to rise at a faster rate than employee hours, the rate at which output is growing peaked in 1970 and declined through 1977, while the rate of change for Business Week, Jan. 20, 1975, p. 46. J 17 “ 27th Annual Electrical Industry Forecast,” Electrical World, Sept. 15, 1976, p. 58. 18 Business Plans for N ew Plants and Equipment, 1977—80, 30th 19Class A and class B electric utilities have accounted for i roughly 80 percent of total kilowatt-hour sales over the past de cade. Annual McGraw-Hill Survey (New York, McGraw-Hill Publica 20 United States Energy Through the Year 2000 (R evised) (U.S. tions Co., Economics Department) May 6, 1977. Department of the Interior, Bureau of Mines, Dec. 1^75), p. 65. http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ 166 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in 1960 and 1967 but then grew between 1967 and 1977 at an average annual rate of 0.8 percent. employee hours continued to grow steadily through 1974 and was only slightly lower in 1975, 1976, and 1977. Hence, output p e r‘employee hour is growing, but the average annua! rate of growth has been grad ually declining since reaching a peak in 1964. The productivity growth rate for nonsupervisory workers has been higher, and the increase in employment has been lower, than for all employees. Electrical World publishes a continuing survey of generating costs for electric utility steam plants that includes data bn' the humber of operating and maintenance employees' per Mw of net output. In 1960, 0.306 employees were required per Mw of net output.21 By 1976, hoWever, labor requirements had declined by 60 percent to 0.122 employees per M w .2 2 The survey indicates that labor requirements tend to? be lower for larger generating plants. The survey also indicates that labor requirements vary by type of generating plant. Nuclear plants have the greatest labor requirements per Mw, needing more people in all occupations (except fuel and ash han dlers) than the other types of generating plants. Coal-fired plants have the- second highest level of labor requirements* oil-fired plants the next, and gasfired plants the lowest. ‘ ~ The- size of generating units is not likely to in crease as rapidly in the future as over the past 20 years, and nuclear and coal-fired plants are expected to be the main sources of electric power in the fu ture. Labor requirements per Mw, therefore, may not continue to decline, as much as they have over the past decade. Oscypati@ns Technological and other factors are altering to some extent the occupational structure in the electric power and gas industry. One area of change is in the balance of supervisory and nonsupervisory workers: Nonsupervisory workers have declined from 89 per cent of total employment in 1960 to 83 percent in 1976. •; A comparison was made of labor costs for various ipccupations between a group of large generating plants (averaging 2,626 Mw) and a .group of smaller plants (340 Mw) in 1975.23 Labor costs5 per net Mw for the smaller plants were approximately 35 percent higher for supervisors, 315 percent higher for operat ing personnel, 48 percent higher for maintenance personnel, 200 percent higher for fuel and ash han dlers, and 188 percent higher for clerks. The types of fuel used by generating plants also affect occupational requirements. Fuel and .ash handlers are not required for plants using natural gas but are needed in plants that burn coal and, to some extent, in plants that burn oil. Also, nuclear plants ' require more specialists than any type of fossil-fuel plant. As nuclear plants and coal-fired plants are expected to become the dominant types of power plants over the next decade, the occupations of spe cialist and fuel and ash handler should become more important. ; H j Employment and Occupational Trends Employment Employment in electric power and gas, according to BLS data (SIC 491, 492, 493), increased rather slowly from 582,300 in I960 to a peak of 684,200 in 1974 and then declined to 673,000 in 1977. The aver age annual growth fate over' the 1960 —77 period was 1.2 percent, with most of the growth occurring after 1967. The average annual rates of change for 1960— 67 and 1967—77 were 0.4 percent and 1.3 percent, respectively. BLS projections to 1985 indicate that growth in employment may average 0.7 percent a year between 1977 and 1985. Employment growth for nonsupervisory employ ees has been slower than for all employees; nonsu pervisory workers increased at an average rate of 0.8 percent a year between I960 and 1977. The num ber of nonsupervisory workers was about the same 2! Leonard fyj. Olmsted, “ 14thj Steam Station Cost Survey,” E lectrical W orld , Oct. !8, 1965, p. 104. 22‘Fried|lander, “ 20th Steam Station Cost Survey,” E lectrical W orld , Nov. 15, 1977, p. 4 4.’ 167 Employment is projected to increase in six of the • eight major occupational groups, with the largest ■ increases expected to occur among professional apd technical workers, managers and administrators, and craft workers. Specific occupations in which increases are expected include electrical engineers, electronic technicians, computer specialists, computer peripheral equipment operators, construction electricians, plumbers and pipefitters, boiler-truckdrivers. Some of the occupations for which declining employment is pro jected are keypunch operators, furnace tenders and stokers, cleaning service workers, and construction laborers (except carpenters). 23 Results from the survey of steam generating plants by E lec trical W orld indicate that the cost of operating and maintenance employees per Mw of net output declined steadily from I960 to 1970, then rose somewhat in 1972, and declined again in 1974 (al though not returning to the 1970 level). In this study, 1960 data are from the 14th Steam Station Cost Survey, E lectrical W orld. Data for 1962-72 are from Leonard M. Olmsted, “ 19th Steam Station Cost Survey,” E lectrica l W orld , Nov. 15, 1975, p. 44. The 20th Cost Survey, in 1977, did not have such detailed information for labor cost Some decline in the number of power plant opera tors is anticipated. Larger and more efficient equip ment is expected to create increases in output with little or no increase in labor requirements. The same number of people, for instance, can operate a large generator or a small orid. The occupational structure at a fossil-fuel generat ing plant visited by BLS staff tends to support this projection. This plant utilizes three generating units: Two small units (175 Mw each) operated from one centralized control room and one large unit (850 Mw) that has its own control room. Both control rooms are run by fouL-person operating crews, al though the skill requirements are higher for the larger generating unit. However, a nuclear generating plant also visited by BLS staff has somewhat different occupational requirements. This plant uses larger and more highly skilled control room operating crews—seven to eight people, including a minimum of five operators li censed to work with fissionable fuel. Additionally, there is an ongoing training/retraining program at the plant to which operators are assigned on a rotating basis.. If this plant is representative of nuclear plants in general, then an increase in the number of nuclear plants could reduce the projected decline in the number of power plant operators. There has been some concern in the electric pow er industry about possible shortages of skilled con struction and operating personnel during the coming decade. Such shortages would have greater impact upon nuclear generating plants because of the many special skills involved. Among the occupations criti cal for constructing and operating nuclear plants, where shortages are possible, are nuclear, mechani cal, and electrical engineers, reactor operators, health physics/radiation monitor technicians, mill wrights, and nuclear-qualified welders (most of whom come from the ranks of steam/pipe fitters and boilermakers). 24 A new labor demand model that forecasts power plant construction employment has been developed by the Departments of Labor and Energy and the Tennessee Valley Authority. 25 The model covers 1978—81 and breaks employment estimates down by region, occupation,. and type of generating plant. This model could be a useful tool for utility compa nies in estimating their employment needs. Some increase is expected in occupations Con cerned with the transmission and distribution of electric power. The number of line and cable work ers should increase. Increased use of automatic equipment in substations—allowing more remote control operations—may cause a decline in regular substation operators but an increase in the more highly skilled mobile substation operators, who trav el from one remote-controlled substation to another. Adjustment of workers to technological change Training programs are being, established to facili tate adjustment of employees to. thei^equirement^ of new technology. Control room operators in nuclear generating plants, for example, are licensed by the Nuclear Regulatory Commission (NR(|) to manipu late the controls of a nuclear reactor. The training program used in the plant visited by BLS staff to prepare operators for the NRC licensing test re quires between 6 months and a year to complete and includes'extensive training in nuclear physics, radia tion protection, and .power plant operations. The NRC operator’s license must be renewed every 2 years; since nuclear power generation is a rapidly evolving technology, the power company maintains an ongoing retraining program for its operators. Some utilities are installing simulators that will be used to train nuclear operators. Control room super visors are required to hold a senior operator’s li cense which, in the company visited, requires an additional 6 months of training. About one-half of the workers in electric and gas utilities are unionized.. Of the several unions repre senting utility industry employees, the largest are the International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers and the Utility Workers Union of America. Specific provisions relating to technological change are not commonly found in collective bargaining contracts for this industry. There are, however, con tract provisions pertaining to seniority, layoffs, job training, and promotions that could be applied to job losses resulting from technological change. 24 Project Independence (Federal Energy Administration, Nov. 1974), pp. 6 1 -7 2 . 2<iWillis J. Nordlund and John Murrtford, “ Estimating Employ ment Potential in U.S. Energy Industry” , Monthly U ihor R eview , May 1978, pp. 10—13. 168 SELECTED REFERENCES Comar, C. L. “ Putting Plutonium in Perspective,” World, December 1, 1976, pp. 39—41. Electrical “ Mobile Equipment Paces System Growth and Slows Spread,” Electrical World, June 1, 1974, pp. 2 5 2 -5 3 . Federal Energy Administration. National Energy Outlook — 1976. , Cost “ Nuclear Power Claims Major Capacity Role,” Electrical World, June I, 1974, pp. 83—89. “ From Fossil to Fusion:,A Milestone Century of Technological Progress,” Electrical Wo^ld, June 1, 1974, pp. 76-78. U.S. Department of Energy. Electric Power Supply and Demand 1978—1987 for the Contiguous United States. July 1978. Graham, John. “The New; Coal Age, Utility N eeds will Bring Unprecedented D em ands’ Electrical World. June 1, 1975, pp. U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration. 3 7 -4 4 . Projections of Energy Supply and Demand and Their Impacts: Annbal Report to Congress, Vol. II, 1977. Chapter 10, pp. 2 0 5 - “ Flow to Enhance Productivity,” Electrical World, November 1, 26. 1976, pp. 3 9 -4 1 . Electrical McGraw, Michael G. “.Fleet Management Becomes More Sophis ticated,” Electrical World, August 1, 1975, pp. 35—50. “ Utilities .Weigh Economics of Nuclear vs C oal,” World, January 1 1976, pp. 21 —23- “ Mechanization RevolutioaiaeS Construction,” Electrical World, June I, 1974, pp. 164—6&. Weaver, Paul H ., “ Behind the Great Scrubber Fracas,” Fortune, February 1975, pp. 106-14. 16 9 Technology and Labor in Insurance Gustav A. Sallas Summary Employment in the insurance industry increased at an annual rate of 2.0 percent during 1960-78 as personal consumption expenditures for insurance reached higher levels. A total of 1.2 million persons were employed in the industry in 1978. The number of persons working in clerical occupations is expected to rise at a slower rate than total employment during the period 1978-85 as computers and related technologies increasingly reduce labor requirements in data processing tasks. Insurance carriers (SIC 63) were the first industry to apply computers to business office procedures on a wide scale with the advent of electronic data processing (EDP) in the early 1950’s.1 Since then, the industry’s substantial accounting and statistical requirements, its vast data storage and retrieval operations, and the mass of paperwork it produces have pushed it to the forefront of EDP utilization. Practically every function of an insurance carrier has been computerized, and almost all firms have applied EDP and related technology to at least part of their operations. By 1985, the industry may employ more than 30,000 persons in computer positions.2 The spread of EDP and the growth of the industry have been mutually supporting. A rising population in a growing economy, with concomitant increases in per sonal income and expenditures for insurance, have made it nearly impossible for firms to function without EDP. Moreover, computers have made it easier for carriers to take advantage of statutes allowing the underwriting of different lines of insurance by the same company. The main problems created by this rapid growth have been gigantic and cumbersome files, interminable transcrip tion of the same data from one form to another, and a myriad of tedious and repetitive operations; for all of these, EDP and related technology is ideally suited. New technology has brought about substantial improvements in productivity in a wide range of laborintensive insurance processing operations. The more widespread use of computers, along with optical character recognition equipment, remote computer terminals, microfilm technology, and related in novations, has reduced unit labor requirements in data storage and retrieval, computations, billing functions, and processing of claims, bids, and proposals. Technology in the 1980’s Technological developments in the insurance industry have centered on the application of EDP to an increasing number of the industry’s functions, particularly to the management of information. A summary of the major technological changes is presented in table 4. To cope with the huge volume of paperwork, calculations, and records generated by rapid industry growth, an increasing number of firms are using EDP. Computer programs have been developed for a wide range of insurance industry functions, ranging from actuarial research to claims processing. In addition, EDP is used extensively by the industry to perform basic office tasks such as word processing (typing, copying, printing), mail handling, and check writing. Technological advances in the industry have led to the merger of a vast electronic data base and computation capability with on-line communications networks, output devices, and office operations equipment. Utilizing this technology, many of the major operating functions for all insurance lines may be performed by a central computer on demand from a terminal in the home office or in any field office (including overseas offices), with the results made available either through visual display devices or on hard copy. More complex operations are constantly being devised, and worldwide electronic communications and operations networks are being created. In addition to EDP, more extensive use of equipment such as closedcircuit TV and other audiovisual equipment for training, new and improved copying devices, text-management equipment, and electronic calculators also have improved efficiency in insurance industry operations. ■Standard Industrial Classification 63 comprises stock and mutual enterprises which underwrite all types of insurance, primarily life, accident and health, property, casualty, surety (financial responsibility), and title insurance. This study does not include independent agents and brokers (SIC 64) who sell insurance underwritten by others or who render services to insurance carriers or policyholders. 2Unpublished BLS data which include both insurance carriers (SIC 63) and insurance agents and brokers (SIC 64). Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 2033 (1979), Technology and Labor in Five Industries. 170 Table 4. Major technological changes in the insurance industry D escription Labor implications Diffusion Electronic data processing (ED P) E D P is being applied to an increasing num ber of insur ance industry functions including billing and collection, actuarial research, underw riting, and claims processing. M inicom puters are being introduced more widely in various departm ents within an insurance firm and in some instances are being joined with a central computer. These small com puters edit, correct, and preprocess data at the departm ent level before the data are transm itted to the main com puter installation. They also retrieve and m anipulate data already stored in integrated electronic d ata b ase/d ata com m unications systems and carry out other functions. E D P technology has reduced unit labor requirem ents for file clerks, typists, and other cleri cal staff. Em ploym ent of pro grammers, com puter operators, and related staff has increased along with the num ber of in stallations. E D P technology will be dif fused more widely over the next decade as new, less costly, and technologically improved small com puters become avail able. Integrated electronic data base/ data com m unication systems All d ata are recorded on magnetic tape, discs, or drums and processed through a central com puter installation. Inform ation can be retrieved instantly at base or remote locations anywhere in the country and displayed on video screens or in printed form. The data may be updated, de leted, o r segmented for specific functions. The central processing unit can activate various electronic devices which will utilize the stored d ata to perform functions such as accounting, billing, internal and statutory reports and statistical tables, correspondence, and prom otional brochures. Reduces the num ber of file clerks required. The num ber of systems in use is increasing. M ost of the m ajor carriers have already accom plished the conversion to the system; others are using the building block approach, com puterizing their files and opera tions systems function by func tion, with a view to eventual integration. Photoelectric devices are being used to scan encoded docum ents, interpret them, and produce a magnetic tape which triggers operating systems and also constitutes a perm anent record of each transaction. They can produce outp u t as disks or video display devices. Reduces the num ber of keypunchers and mechanical sys tems required for EDP. W idespread, particularly in pre mium billing and collection operations, prom otional cam paigns, and data bank input. M ark sense input system Special writing tools which trace symbols (lines, dots, or curves) on ordinary paper are being used to produce in form ation readable by computers. Reduces the num ber of keypunchers required for ED P. N ot widely used as yet. Ex pected to gain acceptance in the near future. Portable com puter terminal M icrocom puters in briefcases, complete with keyboard, video display unit and line printer, are being joined to integrated electronic d ata b ase/d ata com m unications systems by ordinary telephone. As yet minimal. Expected to be used more ex tensively by salespersons. Technology D ata input devices: Optical character recognition stalled increasingly larger and more complex EDP hardware. This compelled the user to attempt to process through a large computer a growing number of minor operations (as for example, the management of office supplies). The minicomputer will be used more extensive ly to perform such tasks as payment of policy dividends and claims and, through a terminal, to edit and process data prior to input into the central system. A minicom puter programmed for an increasing number of insurance applications ultimately may replace the desktop cal culator in an insurance firm’s head office and branches.3 Billing and collection. A common EDP application is premium billing and collection. Although some carriers prefer to collect premiums through their agencies, the trend is toward home office collection, often through the “turnaround” billing system. In turnaround billing, a machine readable notice of premium due produced by the computer is returned by Planning and implementing EDP applications are preceded by intensive analysis of existing procedures and practices in order to develop the appropriate program, and conversion to EDP (including personnel retraining) is accomplished gradually to' avoid disrupting current operations. With the advent of the new generation of small computers and the corollary drop in computer system operating costs, EDP and integrated systems will be widely applied in the industry during the 1980’s. EDP applications The number of insurance industry functions which are being converted from manual to EDP operation is growing. Computers are being applied to a wide range of major activities including billing and collection, actuarial research, underwriting, and claims. The industry consen sus is that during the balance of the decade and through the 1980’s computer technology will be extended to other areas, with unit labor requirements in clerical operations expected to continue to decline. Employment of com puter programmers, systems analysts, and other com puter specialists is expected to continue to increase as computer use grows. The further introduction of minicomputers is expected to bring about additional changes in insurance industry operations. Until recently, the insurance industry in 3At present, branch offices have little or no processing equipment and often no EDP systems whatever. Most branch equipment consists of key-entry devices for input to home office computers. This is particularly the case among property and liability insurance carriers. Current technology permits the home office to transmit computer programs from the central EDP installation, thereby eliminating the need for programmers in field offices. 171 the policyholder with the remittance. The computer puts the payment data on a magnetic tape or disk for the accounting department, calculates the agent’s commis sion on each premium, and credits the appropriate account. These systems are currently operating at the rate of about 5,000 remittances an hour, but equipment already available is capable of handling over 40,000 remittances an hour. Actuarial research. Computers also are reducing unit labor requirements in actuarial tasks. In life insurance, actuarial research yields studies and projections based on mortality and morbidity (the proportion of disease cases to population) rates as well as on records of premium earnings and of policy lapses and maturity. An actuarial department calculates each carrier’s premium and dividend rates and provides risk selection guidelines, among other things. Actuarial work is well suited for EDP since it requires the quick retrieval of large amounts of statistical data, the performance of sophisticated mathematical analyses and complex computations, and the production of statistical tables to meet the company’s reporting requirements. Underwriting. Underwriters review all policy applications, pass upon endorsements (changes to policy conditions), and determine the amount and type of reinsurance required. Although the decision to accept or reject each risk must still be made by a trained under writer, EDP experts and underwriters are working together to expand the computer’s participation in under writing. Operations already performed electronically include logging for transaction control, file search for possible related material, and coding, rating, and policy issuance.4 Electronic processing can control and monitor a policy application through the entire underwriting and policy issuance cycle, producing daily reports on case status at each work station, thereby saving time and labor—an important factor since 10,000 new and renewal applications may be processed daily in the underwriting department of a major carrier. One property and liability company, for example, reduced the personnel in its policy-issuing operation alone by one-third after conver sion to EDP.5 involved. The widest variation in claims procedures occurs within the life and health insurance companies. Claims that call only for death benefit payments require only eligibility verification and check issuance. In integrated electronic systems, the search capability of the system identifies all policies for a given claimant, and the data base will show the current status of the policies, compute the amounts payable, activate the check-issuing devices, make the appropriate entries into the general ledger, and block any other transaction from occurring. Health and disability insurance claims involve more intricate processes which require complex EDP programs. These policies provide for payments for services as well as income protection and indemnity. Health and disability claims require large numbers of examiners, file clerks, and typists. In an EDP system, the examiner can view the claim history file on a video screen, determine coverage, adjudicate the claim, calculate the benefits, issue payment checks, and generate the required correspondence. In the property and liability field, the growing complexity of the coverage has placed a strain on claims processing and encouraged more extensive application of EDP. For example, no-fault automobile insurance in many cases sets a time limit for the insurer to respond to the claim. To achieve growth with a stable work force will require improvements attainable only through electronic automation—a significant challenge in light of the substantial manual processing of claims that occurs in many property and liability companies. The potential of EDP to improve efficiency in claim processing is illustrated by the following example of a system in operation. An appraiser involved in an auto damage claim first checks eligibility and coverage through the home office computer, assesses the damage, and then writes a check to settle the claim. A form filled out at settlement is fed into a transceiver which sends an image by telephone line to the home office (usually at night) for accounting and central files. At the receiving end, the unattended device produces a photograph of the forms and turns itself off when the transmission is completed. Integrated ©©mmyrnication interns Electronic data base/data communication systems are being applied to the substantial data handling re quirements associated with the insurance industry. These data generally must be maintained in current form for several decades and are periodically required for immediate use at various locations in the home office and in the field. As many as 12 separate records are maintained on a given policy, spread among various departments and often duplicated in field offices. Inm ost instances, these functional files include duplicate infor mation. The data overlap often results in one file being current while its duplicates remain static and become out dated. Integrated electronic data base/data communication systems have several advantages, including the capability Claims. The application of EDP to claims processing varies widely with the type of insurance involved; even within the same line, the time frame over which a claim must be serviced greatly affects the automated processes insurance policies usually consist of three parts: (1) A jacket, or printed section, which contains only constants applicable to a given carrier or kind of policy; (2) the declarations—a printed form bearing a typed description of the variables involved, such as premium or particular risks; and (3) endorsements, which usually are extensions of either the jacket or the declarations. (Both the printing and typing of policies have been computerized.) Surveys in the property and liability lines have shown that electronic processing of the declarations eliminates an error factor of approximately 8 percent which plagues the manual operation. . 5LOM A Resource, March/April, 1976. Life Office Management Association, S 72 to consolidate all data related to a single policy in the company’s central computer installation. The systems search capability permits instant identification of all policies connected with one name and of all names connected with one policy; review of all documents which meet a given specification; and browsing through entire files by flashing their contents on a video screen document by document. In advanced installations, the information is stored on magnetic tape or in disk packs which can hold up to about 30,000 pages of data. The files may be updated or deleted at will, and may easily be segmented for specific purposes and the various segments protected from unauthorized use. To protect the data from accidental destruction, duplicate disks or tapes are kept, usually off premises. Through advances in communica tion technology, data are accessible rapidly at all sta tions—immediate and remote—at terminals equipped with video display devices and line printers. Each system is linked by a communication and teleprocessing network of ordinary telephone circuits and leased telephone or telegraph lines. The integrated electronic data base/data communication system produces internal statistical statements on demand as well as the periodic reports required by regulatory agencies. Because of their capability to improve data handling, electronic data base/data communication systems will be used more extensively over the next decade. Data Input devices Electronic devices which feed into a computer directly from documents are increasing accuracy and displacing keypunch operators. Optical character recognition technology is expected to assist the industry to cope with the massive increase in paperwork to accompany future growth. Without such devices it would already be impossible for the large carriers to handle expeditiously the huge number of inquiries, applications, remittances, and claims they receive every day. Optical character recognition (OCR) is the instant interpretation and transmission of the symbols and alphanumeric characters which constitute a coded entry, by a photoelectric device known as an optical scanner. In the insurance industry, the optical scanner is used primarily for premium billing and collection. Additional uses are being developed in the processing of other documents which can be preprinted or encoded in machine readable form, such as policy applications, surrender notices, and reinstatement requests, as well as loan applications in life insurance and loss statements in property and casualty claims. Coded machine readable documents can be produced by the computer or independently by special purpose typewriters and by the “Mark Sense” system, which involves the use of graphic input devices. These consist of a form listing a number of specific pieces of information, a writing tool for touching the items to be entered, and a photoelectric device which converts the data to digital 173 form for the computer. Data from graphic input devices can be fed onto magnetic tape through a multiplex unit which can support up to 15 stations, each capable of carrying the data stream for- a different insurance operation—such as underwriting, claims, or investments. These devices generally cut data entry time by 30 percent. In one instance, a carrier which processed about 400 bids and proposals a month with a staff of 11 was able to process nearly twice as many with a staff of 9 after switching from keypunch to an electronic pen. Increasing utilization also is seen for the portable input-output device, or “briefcase terminal.” The latest of these devices, which weighs under 15 pounds, is equipped with a keyboard, a microprocessor, a small video screen, and a compact line printer. Connected to an ordinary telephone (by placing the telephone receiver on a cradle in the device) and plugged into an electrical outlet, this device links an agent anywhere in the world with the company’s central EDP installation. Hard copy is produced at the rate of 1,800 characters per minute. With instant access to the company’s central computer 24 hours a day the year round, the agent can make a presentation and place the order for a policy. Userofslnt technology Advances in microfilm technology are resulting in space savings in records storage, faster retrieval of policy holder information, and lower labor requirements for file clerks, typists, and other clerical staff. Microfilm processes are particularly advantageous to the insurance industry since large quantities of records are produced, such as policy and loan applications, paid drafts, and Medicare reports, that cannot be stored in the computer in digital form because of their format or statutory requirements. The original microfilming process (which insurance companies pioneered in the 1940’s) is giving way to micro fiche, in which the roll film is replaced by 4" * 6" cards each holding about 100 frames (microphotographs) of legal size documents. (Already under development is a high-reduction technique known as ultrafiche, which will increase the capacity of the card substantially.) Micro fiche expedites handling of hard copy documents and practically eliminates the storage space required for these items: The contents of about 140 file cabinet drawers can be stored in an 18-inch card tray. When microfiche is coupled with computer-output-micrographic (COM) devices, data are transferred directly from the computer to microfiche without need for intermediate hard copy. Multiple hard copies can be produced rapidly from the microfiche through a nonimpact printer.6Thus, the COM system can produce in a few seconds, from data in the computer, a microfiche frame for the record, available for instant viewing on a screen, and a number of hard copies for distribution. One life insurance carrier made two hard copies each of 230,000 documents from computer tape through microfiche in 15 hours—an operation that would have required 200 hours with an impact printer. Another carrier, which produced nearly 300 million microfiche frames in 1974, has plans to double this volume within the decade. The COM process is particularly advantageous for use in property and casualty underwriting where there are frequent changes in policy data (as when an automobile is traded in) many of which require transferring or reprogramming data needed for historical purposes. Industry Outlook The outlook is for continued expansion in the three major segments of the insurance industry—life, health, and property/liability. About two-thirds of the Nation’s total population are covered by life insurance policies issued by the 1,750 life insurance companies with headquarters in the United States.7 The face value of policies in force totaled $586 billion in 1960, $2,583 billion in 1977, and was projected by the U.S. Department of Commerce to reach $3,097 billion in 1979. The number of life insurance policies in force totaled 390 million in 1977, 38 percent more than in 1960. Purchase of new life insurance totaled $367.3 billion in 1977, compared to $74.4 billion in 1960, with the average amount of life insurance in force per insured family rising steadily and amounting to $36,900 in 1977. Group life insurance, in particular, is gaining rapidly as life insurance benefits increasingly are being included in employee benefit programs, with coverage extended to dependents of group insurance certificate holders. Over 89 percent of all group life insurance contracts covered employer-employee groups in 1973 (most recent year for which data are available), and the average coverage per employee for these contracts was about $12,000. In addition, millions of employed and retired people are participants in retirement plans operated by life insurance companies. Even greater growth is anticipated in individual retirement plans under the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974, which permits persons employed in firms with no private retirement plan to purchase an individual plan of their own. Health insurance has expanded substantially. Expan sion has been accelerated by the increasing inclusion of health benefits in labor contracts and by insurance 6Several printing techniques are available which do not involve striking paper with a mechanical hammer, but use photographic, chemical, or magnetic ink processes and specially treated paper. In one of the most sophisticated of these, the Ink-jet Printer, a stream of magnetic ink droplets is shot towards the paper and deflected by elec trostatic plates to form the desired character. Speeds in excess of 75,000 lines per minute are possible with the Ink-jet Printer, although such speeds are not yet available in commercial versions. 7The sources of statistics on amounts of insurance in force, number of policies in force, premiums written, number of persons covered, and related data included in this section for these three segments of the insurance industry are as follows: Life insurance, American Council of Life Insurance; health insurance, Health Insurance Institute; and property and liability insurance, Insurance Information Institute. 174 company participation in the Medicare program enacted in 1966. At the end of 1976 (latest year for which data are available), 177 million persons were covered under provisions of one or more forms of private health insurance. Individuals under age 65 accounted for 93 percent of the total. The older groups were insured under private plans to supplement Medicare benefits. Premiums received by the industry for health insurance coverage rose to $24.3 billion in 1976, nearly double the premium income received in 1971. The property and liability segment of the insurance industry also has recorded substantial growth. Between 1960 and 1977, net premiums written for property and liability insurance increased by almost 400 percent, from $15 billion to $74 billion. Auto insurance in 1977 accounted for about 42 percent of total property / liability premiums. Accompanying the premium growth in the major categories of insurance, as discussed above, has been increasing diversification in the types of insurance under written by insurance carriers. Insurance companies also are merchandising mutual fund shares and other investment plans, and giant department store chains have formed insurance subsidiaries and are selling policies through in-store booths at their hundreds of outlets. Already many carriers have formed holding companies encompassing estate planning and equity investment, real estate, and data processing. Employment and Occupational Trends Employment Insurance is a major industry that employed 1.2 million persons in 1978, or about 1 out of every 4 persons working in the finance, insurance, and real estate sector. Employment in insurance has been rising steadily as gains in personal consumption expenditures for insurance resulted in a steady rise in policies issued, premiums written, and insurance in force per insured family. Total employment in insurance increased at an average annual rate of 2.0 percent during 1960-78. The annual employment growth rate was 1.8 percent during 1967-78 and 1.7 percent during the earlier 1960-67 period. Employment in the three largest components of the insurance industry—which combined accounted for about 94 percent of the total industry work force—fluc tuated over the period 1967-78. Establishments primarily engaged in underwriting life insurance (SIC 631) continued to employ the largest number of employees, 522,500 in 1978, but their share of total employment declined from over 50 percent in 1967 to about 44 percent in 1978. Second in size of work force is the fire, marine, and casualty insurance segment of the industry (SIC 633) which employed 460,600 people in 1978, a gain of 44 percent since 1966. Its share of total employment in the insurance industry rose slowly, reaching 39 percent in 1978. The accident and health segment of the industry (SIC 632) is third in terms of employment, but it is the fastest growing and accounted for about 12 percent of the work force in 1978. Employment in establishments which underwrite accident and health insurance reached 138,900 persons in 1978, more than double their 1966 employment. The rise in total employment in the industry has been accompanied by increased use of computer and related technology. Despite the fact that in many applications unit labor requirements have declined substantially, with the computer doing in a few hours the work dozens of employees formerly turned out in one day, the adverse effect on employment has been mitigated by several factors. The high rate of attrition which prevailed among the clerical work force required to perform the industry’s massive, repetitive data processing tasks has facilitated conversion with minimum dislocation. Moreover, rapid business expansion and advance planning of work force changes appear to have obviated the need for any significant layoffs, and conversion has been carried out mainly by retraining and relocating personnel. Some companies however, have imposed a total freeze on the hiring of clerical workers for protracted periods after computerization to facilitate reassignment of existing staff. Occupations A wide range of occupations in the insurance industry has been affected by the application of EDP and related technologies. Because of these innovations, employment in clerical occupations is expected to increase at a slower rate than that envisioned for all employment in the industry. Consequently, clerical workers, who constitute nearly half of the insurance carrier work force, will make up an increasingly smaller proportion of total insurance industry employment by 1985. The demand for and relative importance of a number of clerical positions, including secretaries and typists, keypunch and other office machine operators, bookkeepers, and file clerks, is expected to decline. However, employment in managerial and technical positions including those related to the planning, installation, and operation of electronic computer systems is expected to increase. Demand will rise for executives and other officials to determine EDP policy, manage data base and teleprocessing networks, and supervise program development and the recruiting and training of computer applications personnel. Employ ment of systems analysts, programmers, and computer console operators and related computer operating staff is expected to continue to increase. The insurance industry will continue to be receptive to further application of technology to insurance operations since the industry ranks second only to commercial banks in the proportion of its work force engaged in data processing activities. Employment of persons engaged full time in selling all lines of insurance directly for the carriers (excluding 175 general agents and brokers) is not expected to keep pace with the rapidly expanding volume of sales, primarily because of the increasing number of policies sold to groups and the increasing sales of policies which cover several perils previously covered by separate policies.8 As indicated earlier, occupations in clerical fields have been those principally affected by technological change; these include file clerks, keypunch operators, and typists. Although the insurance industry will continue to employ substantial numbers of young high school graduates, many of them women, computerization of practically every mechanical operation is expected to reduce the availability of low-skilled, entry-level clerical positions. Adjustment ©f workers to technotogical change The further diffusion of computer and related tech nology in the insurance industry is not expected to bring about major displacement. In most cases, the initial impact of the transition to new technology in data processing operations has been slight because of the increased workload entailed in the conversion. Often, a special department was established during the early stage of the changeover to handle the corollary personnel problems. Moreover, as already indicated, a high degree of attrition of clerical workers—the occupational group most affected by new technology—has eased the transition from manual operations to electronic data pfocessing and made layoffs unnecessary. Continuous industry growth has permitted absorption of displaced personnel in all categories, and coordinated retraining and relocation by the employers have reduced dis locations to a minimum. Relatively few employees affected by new technology in the insurance industry are union members. The principal union in the insurance industry, the Insurance Workers International Union (IWIU), thus far has concentrated on organizing insurance agents (salespersons), and this has been the category least affected by technological innovation. In late 1976, the IWIU negotiated to organize the clerks of one of the largest insurance carriers. The Office and Professional Employees International Union also has organized in the industry. The very few union contracts in effect in the industry incorporate specific provisions relating to technological displacement. One such provision which provides job security for employees whose jobs have been affected by new technology reads as follows: “... It is further agreed by the parties that no persons filling jobs within the presently existing collective bargaining unit will be subject to layoff in the event that jobs are abolished or altered by the introduction of data processing equipment, computers or other automated equipment. . . ” For displaced workers, provisions are in effect which provide retraining and preference for any jobs resulting from automation or conversion to electronic data processing. 8Occupational Outlook Handbook, 1978-79 Edition, Bulletin 1955 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1978), p. 763. No information is available concerning the effect of reorganizations, mergers, and consolidation of branch offices on employment. There is, however, no evidence that these trends have caused any widespread dislocation. SELECTED REFERENCES Bowers, Dan M. “Intelligent Terminals and Distributed Processing,” The Office, September 1976, pp. 86 ff. International Business Machines Corporation. Property I Liability Field Office Application Systems— Executive Overview, May 1975. Cantrell, Gary L. “Remote Job Processing as an Alternative,” Best’s Review, Life/Health Edition, July 1976, pp. 68-70. Life Office Management Association. Insurance Information Process ing: A Look at Our Future, LOMA Systems and Procedures Report 28, 1975. Fischer, Robert A. “Insurance Tomorrow: The Data Processing Picture,” Best’s Review, Property/Liability Edition, May 1975, pp. 104-09. Roach, Thomas. “The Data Processing Organization of the 1980’s,” LOM A Resource, November 1975, pp. 29-30. Fromm, Erwin F. “The Mechanical Underwriter,” Best’s Review, Property/Liability Edition, June 1975, pp. 16-18. “Telecommunications Speed Settlement of Auto Claims,” Best’s Review, Property/Liability Edition, November 1975, p. 102. Goldbeck, George. “Mini-Computers—A Big Part of the Future,” Best’s Review, Property/Liability Edition, January 1975, pp. 78-81. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Impact o f Office Automation in the Insurance Industry, Bulletin 1468, 1966. Goldbeck, George. “Information Processing in the P/ C Business,” The National Underwriter, Sept. 5, 1975, p. 2. Valovic, Stefan. “Survey Shows Risk Managers Make More Use of Computers,” Business Insurance, Dec. 1, 1975, pp. 19-20. International Business Machines Corporation. Group InsuranceApplication Description and System Planning Guide. White Plains, N.Y., May 1975. Vanderbeek, Robert E., and H. Thomas Verdonk. “Conputer System Offers Personalized Customer Service,” Best’s Review, Life/Health Edition, February 1976, pp. 66-67. International Business Machines Corporation. Individual Life In surance: D B / D C Information Systems Design Concepts, January 1975. Wray, Theodore S. “Field Office Video Units Improve Policyholder Service,” Best’s Review, Life/Health Edition, June 1975, pp. 81-84. 176 Technology and Labor in Metalworking Machinery A. Harvey Belitsky Employment in the industry stood at the relatively high level of 371,500 persons in 1980. The average annual increase from 1960 to 1980 was 1.4 percent (about the same rate as for all durable goods manufacturing). The outlook for employment growth from 1980 to 1990 is in the range of 0.8 to 3.8 percent (average annual rates) as projected by BLS, based on alternative versions of economic growth. Increases are projected for virtually all of the industry’s occupational groups, but the number of craft workers is expected to grow only half as rapidly as the number of operatives. A shortage of skilled workers could remain a principal obstacle to expansion in the metal-cutting machine sector for at least the immediate future. Summary The metalworking machinery industry is rapidly increasing the application of the numerically controlled (N C ) machine tool. NC machines accounted for an estimated 30 percent of the value of machine tools installed in the metal-cutting machine tool sector in 1979. Increased diffusion of NC is expected in the 1980’s in response to a host of economic conditions, including the advanced age and low productivity of the machine tools in use, the need to meet increasingly precise and complex requirements for machined parts, and the shortage of skilled workers. While utilization of NC machine tools is likely to increase steadily among the industry’s large and mediumsize plants, the many small shops which manufacture simple parts will still rely heavily upon manually operated machine tools. Other, more sophisticated technologies such as machining centers (multifunction NC machines), controls utilizing sensors, and NC by computer are also economically feasible, principally for the larger plants. Complex microprocessors, which have fallen sharply in price, permit firms of all sizes to use various intermediate technologies which are not as sophisticated as NC. In general, these technologies increase output per employee hour, improve quality, and reduce occupational skill requirements. Although definitive measurements of productivity for the industry as a whole are not available, very small productivity improvement in 1960-78 is suggested by an average annual rise in output of about 2 percent and in employee hours of less than 1 percent. Wide swings in output—with associated lags in adjustment of hours— and aging equipment are major reasons for the industry’s comparatively low productivity growth rate. While the industry’s dollar outlays for new plant and equipment rose by nearly two-thirds from 1966 to 1978, expenditures in real terms did not surpass the 1966 peak. Real expenditures rose to a comparatively high level in 1974, declined in 1975, and then rose in the succeeding 3 years. They have generally continued to increase, and this may enable manufacturers to compete more effectively with imports for the large tooling requirements of automobile, commercial aircraft, and defense-related manufactures. Industry Structure This study examines' the metalworking machinery industry as a whole (SIC 354) and three major sectors within the industry: Metal-cutting machine tools (SIC 3541); special dies and tools,die sets,jigsand fixtures,and industrial molds (SIC 3544); and machine tool accessories and measuring devices (SIC 3545). Reference is also made to metal-forming machine tools (sic 3542). The other metalworking sectors not covered in this study are: Power-driven handtools; rolling mill machinery and equipment; and such machinery as gas cutting and welding equipment. Some characteristics of this industry tend to limit productivity growth. An estimated three-fourths of the industry’s output is in batches of less than 50 pieces. This holds true particularly for the machine tool makers, who often produce special machines for their customers, and for the tool-and-die firms, which frequently produce oneof-a-kind parts. Moreover, establishments in metalwork ing are comparatively small and highly specialized. Such firms often find it economically unfeasible to invest in new equipment. For example, the tool-and-die sector of the industry (SIC 3544) is made up of 7,100 establishments, averaging only 15 employees. In comparison, the average size of all manufacturing establishments is 55 employees. Additionally, the sharp fluctuation in industry output over the course of the business cycle tends to reduce productivity growth. Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 2104 (1982), T echnology a n d L a b o r in F ou r Industries. 177 T@e!hiT)®S©gy in tb® 19®05s Numerical control (NC) of machine tools is the most significant new technology introduced in the metalwork ing industry in the past 25 years. It has experienced substantial and frequent changes in concept and/or design. However, some metalworking firms are investing in intermediate technologies, i.e., technologies which are not as sophisticated or expensive as NC, but which nevertheless improve productivity. These include digital readouts and manual-data-input controls which are applied largely to conventional machine tools. Innova tions have also taken place in management techniques and cutting-tool materials. The major technologies, their diffusion, and their labor impact are discussed in more detail below and are presented in table 2.1 WumeroeaSly ©ontrolledl machine tools Numerical control (NC) involves the automatic control of a machine tool’s movement by an electronic controller or special computer which reads instructions in digital form. NC tools are more productive than manually operated tools. They reduce setup time; consequently a higher proportion of working time is spent on cutting. The need for costly jigs, templates, and other tooling devices is eliminated. NC tools can produce parts with greater precision and uniformity, thereby further saving machining time and minimizing scrap losses. NC may make possible the production of complex parts that could otherwise not be turned out, or only at great cost; and the process permits engineering changes on a part by merely changing portions of the input program. NC enhances managerial control by predetermining and coding every stage of machining onto a control tape. It becomes possible for managers to plan more accurately such operations as machine loading and shop scheduling, and >t is much easier to predict labor and machine requirements. NC prc\ ides the opportunity to attain some automation in the small batch production which characterizes this industry. The innovation may be more fully appreciated by characterizing NC as a manufacturing system, and not merely a means to control a machine. Despite the advantages of NC, only about 3 percent of all metal-cutting tools in the metalworking industry in 1976-78 were NC.2 However, they accounted for a much larger proportion of output. Another indication of the importance of NC is the value of recently installed NC machines. In the metal-cutting machine tool sector, value 'This study does not include the more than 20 technologies that are identified as nontraditional machining processes, although production and application of some of these processes are increasing. Two of these are electrochemical machining and electrical discharge machining. Electrical discharge machining is used widely in tool-and-die shops. 2“The 12th American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equipment 1976-78,” A m erican Machinist, December 1978, p. 136. 178 of shipments was estimated to be 30 percent of all machine tools installed in 1979. The reason for the lack of diffusion of NC throughout the metalworking machinery industry is the small size of the majority of the firms; they have limited funds for investment in this comparatively expensive technology. Although NC is intended for small batch operations, the risk of investment may be too great because of the volatility of demand for the industry’s products. Moreover, firms producing simple parts are unlikely to utilize NC. In addition, NC is not feasible, technically, for some machining methods, such as broaching. It is also interesting to note that surveys disclose that only a few of the general managers in firms without NC fully understood its workings.3 Currently, except for a small number of comparatively large firms which use advanced sophisticated NC, most machine tool shops still rely heavily upon skilled workers working on conventional tools. Nonetheless, numerous modest-sized contract tool-and-die shops—also referred to as contract tooling and machining shops—have adopted NC because they do a significant amount of precision machining. However, if, as expected, NC replaces a large proportion of conventional tools in the 1980’s, it could have considerable impact on the metalworking industry. The application of NC should be accelerated by shortages of skilled workers and by the growing need for parts of greater precision. Adding urgency is the steadily increasing demand for variety and versatility in products. Firms which introduce or expand their use of NC can experience pronounced savings in labor and material. A study of over 350 companies4disclosed direct and indirect savings of NC over manually operated tools. Reduced machining time ranged from 35 to 50 percent. Indirect savings of 25 percent or higher were found for material handling, scrap, and inspection. A majority of firms did not even have higher outlays for NC programming if “process planning” on conventional machines is taken into account. With the introduction of NC, the occupational composition of the work force generally changes. The number of machine operators is likely to decline for a given level of production, since one person can often operate two NC machines. In many cases, skill requirements are reduced. For example, operators no longer need to interpret a blueprint in selecting machine settings. On the other hand, they must be perceptive to a malfunction. Some firms try to enhance the duties of the operator of a very expensive NC machine to make the job ’Edwin Mansfield and others, Research an d Innovation in the C orporation (New York, Norton and Company, Inc., 1971), pp. 201-202; George P. Putnam, “Why More NC Isn’t Being Used,” M achine a n d Tool Blue Book, September 1978, pp. 100- 101. M odern 4Donald N. Smith and Lary Evans, M anagem ent S ta n dards f o r N um erical C ontrols (Ann Arbor, University of Michigan, 1977), pp. 185, 192, 212, 214, and 222. C om pu ter a n d attractive to a skilled machinist. The new position of programmer required with NC is being filled in a growing number of firms by skilled machinists who have received supplementary training. A somewhat larger number of maintenance personnel may be required, and their skill requirements are higher, calling for special training. In general, NC machinery is operated in two or three workshifts, without comparable labor additions on the later shifts. Numerical control by coimiputer According to some experts, the combination of the computer with NC in small batch production compares in impact to the introduction of the assembly line and interchangeable parts. Software advances in the late 1960’s made it possible for a computer to convey numerical data directly to a machine control unit, thereby eliminating the need for a special control system to operate a machine tool by tape commands. Computer NC (CNC), first with minicomputers and later with microcomputers, made it possible to operate one or more machines and even to connect to larger computers. CNC eliminates the problem of the constant redoing of tape. Also, workpiece program data can be changed in the control system without the necessity for reading an entire program tape. A computer can also keep track of the. time each machine tool is in use. A significant proportion of the NC units in the metalworking industry are the CNC type. Costs of electronic controls have declined so sharply in recent years that some CNC units are competitive with tapedriven control units and are economically feasible for small and medium-size firms. Whereas minicomputers accounted for 50 percent of the cost of a CNC tool in the late 1960’s, they now account for less than 20 percent. All the reasons for the lack of diffusion of NC apply even more to CNC. And direct numerical control (D N C ), in which a central computer may control up to 100 or more machine tools, is currently used by only a few of the larger toolbuilders in the metalworking industry. The principal new job classifications arising from the use of CNC are computer programmers, electronic maintenance personnel, and, in some firms, systems analysts. Personnel skilled in preventive maintenance assume great importance with CNC, and machine problems require a multiskill approach. H/taefolnlng c©nt®r§ Machining centers are more elaborate and costly than basic, single-purpose NC. The centers may have automatic tool-changing systems for selecting among 20 to 100 tools that bore, drill, mill, and tap. With rotary heads and tables, a center can work on many surfaces of a part in a single setup. The centers substantially improve manager ial flexibility. Moreover, they raise productivity because tool changing is less than on basic NC; one operator may control several machines. While NC may be most suitable for low-volume metalworking shops, a machining center can be justified whether the volume of parts is small or large. Nevertheless, this technology has only been minimally adopted by the metalworking machinery industry. There are many reasons for this slow acceptance, including high initial cost, simple products which are unsuitable for machining centers, and lack of managerial knowhow. Adaptive controls Adaptive controls utilize sensors that automatically control such factors as vibration, tool wear, tool or workpiece deflection, and cutting temperatures. Such sensors can be integrated within an NC controller, or they can operate with conventional machine tools. Although the technology has been available for about 20 years, the application of these controls in metalworking machinery is limited to large shops. Utilization by small shops will depend upon development of improved sensors, their cost effectiveness relative to the availability of skilled workers, and the type of work performed. Reported improvements in productivity in currently available controls range from 20 to 40 percent, with largest gains when a part requires diverse cutting condi tions and the material is hard to machine. Resides im proved machining time, scrap and cutter breakage are reduced.5 Sensory devices tend to reduce worker skill require ments because they assume many functions traditionally performed by the operator. These devices help to standardize unit labor time. While machining time on an identical part can vary by over 30 percent for different operators, adaptive controls virtually eliminate the differences. Computer-aided design and manufacture Computer-aided design and computer-aided manufact ure (C A D /C A M ) constitute a system which utilizes computer-controlled methods to unite several technologies. Computers are used to assist in developing designs for products to be manufactured (C A D ). CAM, among other things, directs numerically controlled machines and automatically guides workpieces among machines on computer-controlled material handling systems. CAD/CAM is influenced by continuing improvements and applica tions in various phases of manufacturing, including: Assembly with industrial robots; adaptive control; systems to monitor maintenance; and systems to inspect parts automatically. The total impact on productivity and the work force is substantially greater than that of any single technology. Currently, only the largest machine tool manufacturers utilize CAD/CAM . Its diffusion to medium-size firms will continue to be severely limited by cost and lack of technical expertise. Higher productivity resulting from adoption of CAD/CAM is associated with the shift of workers to more skilled jobs 5D.N. Smith and L. Evans, op. cit., pp. 123, 129, 151. 179 and the reduction in the number of lesser skilled jobs. Skilled machinists continue to be needed. The number of drafting personnel is reduced because of less need for extensive lettering and layouts. Some workers have to be retrained for new tasks associated with computer terminals. In addition, worker involvement in decisionmaking will increase although it will be informal, unlike the practice in some other industries.6 Ipterm ecfete S©<gta@togs<gg There are other technologies being introduced into the industry which are not as sophisticated or expensive as NC, but which improve productivity.7 Digital readout (dro ). This device enables a machine operator to position the moving portion of a machine tool more rapidly and accurately. A major change in the d r o followed the introduction of an electronic display panel separate from the metering component. A measure of automatic control is added to almost any manually operated machine, although readouts can be used for verification on NC tools, too. The DRO also enables an operator to change a cutting machine from inch to metric measure by flipping a switch; this is the most economical way of providing certain machines with metric capability. Increases in efficiency result from fewer operator errors and faster machining cycles. Shop efficiency is also raised because less time is required for setups, repetitive tasks, and inspection. The devices decrease positioning times by up to 80 percent.8 Although machine setups require highly skilled machinists, operators need less training than previously to carry out a job with the aid of a DRO. Also, operator fatigue is reduced. The use of DRO ’s is expanding among machine tool builders and is already widespread among tool-and-die shops. DRO manufacturers anticipate 25-percent yearly growth in sales to the metalworking industry for several years. Major improvements on some DRO ’s since their introduction about 15 years ago can make programming easier for operators. DRO ’s can be installed on existing machines and are also relatively reasonable; the payback period is usually considered to be less than 1 year. Consequently, they are feasible for the job shop which cannot afford NC Manual-data-input control. Manual-data-input (MDl) control of machine tools is more sophisticated than the DRO. Both types of controls inform an operator of 6Proceedings, Eighth A n n u al Tri-Service M anufacturing Tech n o lo g y C oordination Conference, Arlington, Texas, Nov. 8-12, 1976, p. 170. ’Programmable controllers, normally associated with massproduction industries, and programmable hand calculators are also intermediate technologies which have had successful appli cations in small batch manufacturing. See National Center for Productivity and Quality of Working Life, New Technologies an d Training in M etalw orking, Summer 1978, pp. 4-7. 8George Schaffer, “Digital Readout Systems,” Am erican M a chinist, May 1979, p. SR-4. 180 machine position, but the M Dl also enables an operator to change the machine’s position automatically, reducing further the chance of error. Many M D l’s can be transformed into NC systems by inserting a tape reader; most current NC systems contain editing capabilities to accept programs manually. M Dl usually controls simpler machines and turns out simpler workpieces than does NC. Further, some firms do not want or may be unable to add NC machines. A major difference is that an M Dl machinist (and not a programmer, as with NC) usually plans and enters the program for a part. Increased use of M Dl in recent years by the metalworking industry has been stimulated by substantial improvements, in microcircuit technology and declining costs compared with other controls. A separate programming department is not needed with M Dl, and it can be applied in large as well as small shops. While precise data on the utilization of MDl are unavailable, its use is spreading among machine tool builders, and even more rapidly in the contract tool-and-die shops. Higher labor productivity and improved product quality are credited to M Dl. In addition, M D l can help alleviate the shortage of skilled workers because a machine operator may be able to tend two machine tools. Also, some M D l’s utilize “shop language” for programming so that a moderately skilled machinist can use the programming language after brief training. Gutting-tool materials Improved cutting-tool materials can play a substantial role in the application of highly productive, advanced technologies. The performance of a $250,000 NC machine tool depends on the cutting capability of a $30 end mill. Firms which can utilize the improved tool materials can more efficiently satisfy material and quality specifications of customers. The new cutting-tool materials improve productivity because, unlike older materials, they do not wear out as fast and thus do not have to be changed as often. Such new materials as coated carbides, polycrystalline diamonds, and special ceramics are being used in place of tungsten carbide. Applications of the relatively longlasting coated carbides will continue to increase because of sizable price increases for tungsten. According to an industry analyst, the coated carbides will increase from a current application of some 15 percent to at least 25 percent of cutting-tool materials used by the metalwork ing machinery industry in 1985. Group technology Group technology (GT), a management technique, can be as important to productivity as new machines. It involves the grouping of parts on the basis of similar shapes and/or processing requirements. GT revises the belief that small batch manufacturing consists of making distinctive parts from design to end-product. Marked savings are attributed to GT as a result of improved production scheduling, reduced inventory, and greater efficiency in machine loading. Design rationalization and reduced, as well as more efficient, setup and tooling are also credited to the process. GT also could reduce skill specializations which often exist in medium-size and large machine tool shops. Unlike the usual practice in Europe and Japan, only a small proportion of the U.S. metalworking firms which Table 2. have introduced GT have broadened the skill require ments of their w ork forces. Small firms cannot afford the sophisticated effort needed to install GT, and it is used by less than 20 percent of all toolbuilders. Tool-and-die shops do not utilize GT as such, but elements of it are present in shop layout procedures among firms engaged in precision machining and the manufacture of machine tools. Ma|®r technology changes in metalworking machinery Technology Numerically controlled machine tool (NC) Description • Tool is controlled by instructions received from tape, punched cards, plugs, or other media. Allows rapid change to new product designs; permits stricter tolerances for parts; and reduces setup time. Useful for small batch production, because parts can be machined by merely changing tapes and resetting tool. Labor implications Diffusion Estimated reduction in machin ing time of 35-50 percent; typi cally used two or three shifts. Reduces unit requirements for machine operators; requires less skill than manually operated tools, creates new job of pro grammer; requires more broadly trained maintenance personnel. Three percent of all machine tools in metalworking are NC, but they account for a much larger propor tion of total output. In metal cutting sector, the value of NC machines is estimated at 30 per cent of all machine tools installed in 1979. Considerable growth in the number of NC tools and their share of total output is expected in the I980’s. Significant proportion of NC machines; mainly limited to larg er and medium-size machine tool shops. Expected to increase sub stantially in the 1980’s as result of cost reductions in electric con trols; some smaller shops will introduce it. Numerical control by com puter (CNC) O n-board com puter stores and conveys inform ation direct ly to NC control unit; utilizes latest microprocessor tech nology. Same labor implications as NC but, unlike NC, may require com puter personnel. Saves time in reprogram m ing to remove errors or make design changes. Requires maintenance personnel with electronic skills. Machining center An autom atic tool changer makes the center a multifunc tion NC machine. Each center is equivalent to several ma chines, each having a specific function. Raises productivity by perm it Accounts for a small but grow ting operations on many surfaces ing percentage of machine tools of a part in a single setup. O pera in larger plants, but a dispropor tor may control several ma tionately large share of the in chines. dustry’s output. Adaptive control A utomatically controls feed rate to reduce or eliminate such factors as vibration, tool wear, and cutting temperatures, and alerts operator. Can be used with conventional tools or with NC. Raises productivity in m achin ing through substitution of sen sors for workers’ own percep tions. Reduces skill require ments. Used by large plants. Utilization by small shops will depend upon development of improved sen sors and their cost effectiveness relative to the availability of skilled workers and also the type of work performed. Computer-aided design/com puter-aided manufacture (CAD/CAM) C om puters are used to develop designs for products to be m anufactured (CAD). CAM directs numerically controlled machines and autom atically guides workpieces among machines on com puter-controlled handling systems. Reduces need for low-skilled op erators; increases requirements for higher skilled workers. Used by large machine tool m an ufacturers only; diffusion to medium-size firms will be severe ly limited by the technology’s cost. Digital readout (DRO) A device is applied to movable portion of a machine tool to measure its actual movement; can provide some a u to matic control; measurement appears on a display unit. O perator efficiency and accuracy are enhanced during the position ing phase of the machine cycle. O perators are trained in less time and fatigue is reduced. Use is limited but increasing am ong machine tool builders; al ready widespread am ong tooland-die shops. Producers of DRO's expect a 25-percent an nual grow th in their sales to the m etalworking machinery indus try in the next several years. M anual-data-input control (MD1) Enables an operator to change the position of a machine autom atically; also identified as “operator-program m ed NC.” M achinist can plan and enter part programs; possible in “shop language." Training period short er than for NC programm ing. Precise data on utilization are unavailable, but its use is spread ing am ong machine tool builders and even more rapidly in the contract tool-and-die shops. Cutting-tool materials D urable new materials, such as coated carbides, polycrys talline diam onds, and special ceramics more efficiently meet continued increases in machining speed. Reduce labor requirements somewhat because tools do not have to be changed as often. Tungsten carbide expected to re main the m ajor m aterial, but coated carbides may increase from current 15 percent to 25 percent of all cutting-tool ma terials in m etalworking machin ery in 1985. G roup technology (GT) M anagement skills used to reduce small batch operations. Involves the grouping of parts on the basis of similar shapes a n d /o r processing requirements. W orkers may perform a wide range of tasks. | Improves efficiency and quality of output. Workers may broaden skills and replace narrow spe cializations. Used by some large machine tool builders; elements of GT likely to spread slowly to smaller build ers and tool-and-die shops. 181 Output and Productivity Outlook ©ytpyt The metalworking industry has undergone sharp fluctuations in output in response to the business cycle, typical of the experience of other capital goods industries. Although reliable output data are not available for the total metalworking machinery industry, Census value of shipments data adjusted for price changes (used as a crude measure of output) suggest an average annual growth rate of about 2 percent in 1960-78. Output grew very rapidly (8-9 percent a year) in the period 1960-67. However, in 1967-73, average output declined by about 2 percent and, in 1973-78, the average rate of decline was still about 1 percent, reflecting the 1970 and 1975 recessions. Although later data are not available, there is evidence that some sectors of the industry are recovering in response to the large tooling requirements of the automobile, aircraft, and defense industries. While all sectors had impressive rates of growth in 1960-67, the pattern of the sectors varied considerably in the next decade.9 Metal-cutting tool output advanced at a double-digit rate annually (12.0 percent) in 1960-67, and then experienced a very steep decline (8.9 percent annually) in 1967-73. However, in 1973-80 a moderate rate of recovery (2.7 percent) occurred, as output grew strongly after the 1975-76 recession. A similar rise and fall, but not as pronounced, occurred in metal-forming output in 1960-67 and 1967-73. However, in the succeeding period, 1973-80, metal-forming output declined—more steeply than in 1967-73. As in the recession years of 1975 and 1976, output again fell sharply in 1980. Nevertheless, in certain sectors, e.g., metal cutting, delivery time for some orders was as much as 2 years. One explanation for the decline in metal-cutting output over the longer period of 1967-79 is the tardiness of customer industries in buying new tools. The aging of the machines in the U.S. economy has been a long-term problem. The percentage of metal-cutting machines that are less than 10 years old has been declining steadily since the end of World War II; an estimate of 31 percent for 1976-78 approaches the rate at the end of the depression in 1940. Moreover, when all U.S. metal-cutting and metal-forming tools are combined and compared with tools in six other major industrial nations, the United States had the smallest percentage of machines less than 10 years old and the highest percentage of machines over 20 years old.10 ’Output data for the metal-cutting (sic 3541) and metal-forming sectors (sic 3542) are weighted output measures developed by b l s for 1958 to 1980. The data for all other sectors, as well as the entire industry (sic 354), are deflated Census value of shipments data; latest year, 1978. l0“The 32th American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equipment 1976-78,” American Machinist, op. cit., pp. 133, 135, and 137. The data for the six foreign industrial nations are based on the most recent studies in each country, ranging from 1973 to 1978. Of major importance is the change in the mix of output as the proportion of numerically controlled tools has increased. It is estimated that, in 1973, about 40 percent of the value of shipments of NC milling machines and machining centers plus comparable conventional machine tools was accounted for by NC machines; the percentage rose to 66 percent by 1977, according to estimates of a consultant to the industry. In the case of NC lathes and conventional lathes, the estimated rise in NC shipments was from 32 percent of the total value in 1973 to 52 percent in 1977. Because NC is considerably more productive, fewer machines are required for a given amount of production. To some extent, output growth in the industry has been held back by the lack of skilled workers to accommodate to periods of higher demand. While the industry has undertaken considerable worker training in strong growth periods, numerous trained skilled workers had to be laid off when slumps in production took place. Some of these workers left the industry for more stable jobs in other industries; this was especially the case for workers who experienced more than one long spell of unem ployment. ■Foreign trade. Traditionally, the United States has enjoyed a comfortable advantage in the export of metal cutting machines. In 1958-65, the value of exports was at least three times as large as the value of imports. Although a trade advantage was maintained in the years 1966-76, it was no longer as large as in earlier years, and in only 2 years (1970 and 1971) was the trade advantage as high as 2 to 1. in 1977, imports of metal-cutting machines exceeded exports for the first time. Although exports of cutting machines continued to average more in the 1970’s than in the 1960’s (83.5 percent higher), the rise in imports was considerably more rapid (4.2 times as high in the 1970’s). In 1978, the continued deterioration in the trade position of metal-cutting machines- offset the favorable trade balance of the metal-forming sector for the first time, and the trade imbalance rose even higher in 1979. U.S. machine tool manufacturers have not been competing successfully with foreign producers in domestic markets, as is evident by the increase in the import penetration ratio, that is, imports as a percent of apparent consumption (imports plus domestic production, excluding exports). This ratio more than doubled between 1972 and 1979, rising from 9 percent to 22 percent, with the biggest jump in 1978. It rose again in 1980. U.S. manufacturers may be unable to recapture a large portion of the imports of conventional machine tools from Japan and Taiwan. As a result, U.S. firms will have to become more competitive with Japan and also West Germany in the production and sale of NC machines, machining centers, and specialized machines. In addition to the very rapid expansion in imports, the unfavorable balance of trade in metal cutting was also affected by the way in which foreign trading relationships 182 in these machines are established. During several prosperous years in the 1960’s, machine tool builders did not have much incentive to expand their exports to new customers. Yet, machine exports depend upon the establishment of a long-term relationship. Machine buyers often rely upon the machine makers to service and ultimately even rebuild their machines after several years of usage. In the absence of more commercial ties abroad, U.S. machine tool firms could not take advantage of their excess capacity during the recessions of the 1970’s to increase their exports. More recently, the sizable upswing in domestic orders has again been reducing interest in exports, as numerous firms are operating at or near capacity levels, and skilled workers are in short supply. Prospective exporters are also handicapped because their lead times for delivery of new machines are relatively longer than in some other countries. Productivity Although a reliable measure of productivity is unavail able for the metalworking machinery industry as a whole, trends can be estimated from available output and employee-hours data. Deflated value of shipments, used as a crude measure of output, increased by about 2 per cent annually in 1960-78, while the rate of change in employee hours was less than 1 percent for the same period (chart 6). These data suggest that the productivity growth rate averaged only 1-2 percent annually in the 1960-78 period. While productivity (estimated as above) grew moderately from 1960-67, it rose more slowly in 1967-73 and then edged down in 3973-78. In the metal-cutting sector, for which a BLS weighted measure is available, productivity growth averaged only 1.2 percent in the 1960-80 period, approximately the rate of growth for the whole industry. While productivity grew at an average of 4.1 percent annually from 1960 to 1967, it only edged up at less than 1 percent from 1967 to 1973, when output dropped about 9 percent. In the succeeding 7 years, 1973-80, productivity showed no growth. While growth was relatively strong after 1976, it just offset the recession declines. Traditionally in capital goods manufacturing, which is highly cyclical, there is a lag in the adjustment of hours to output changes. In this industry, there is often consider able reliance on changes in the overtime component of employee hours in order to adapt to the wide shifts in output. This is especially evident in the metal-cutting sector. Metal-cutting production has characteristics that are not present to the same degree in other industries, particularly labor intensity, high skill needs, and the considerable time and cost to train workers. Moreover, there is a shortage of skilled workers. Consequently, during an upturn, overtime hours are increased; in a downturn, firms keep as many of their employees on the payroll for as long a period as they regard practicable, but reduce overtime. In contrast, the products of the accessory sector, which include perishable tools and various attachments and 383 accessories for machine tools and other metalworking machinery, enable these manufacturers to benefit from a production process of typically shorter time frames and larger batches than in machine tools. The accessories firms stock numerous standardized products to accom modate anticipated industry demand. Moreover, while the accessory sector needs skilled instrumentmakers to produce measuring devices, the bulk of its output requires a relatively less skilled work force than does metal cutting. Therefore a downturn in the accessory sector output is more likely to be matched by a comparable decrease in employment than in the metal-cutting sector. The machine tool builders have less flexibility in the adjustment of employment. This can be attributed to the length of time required to complete orders for metal cutting machinery and the limited standardization that is possible in its production. Such machinery is usually only manufactured when purchase orders are in hand and requires several months to make. The special machines that are manufactured in this sector are necessarily made in small production runs. Even many of the so-called universal machines are in some way modified to meet individual buyer specifications, thereby ruling out some of the economies associated with longer production runs. The industry has made some attempt to overcome the obstacle of small batch production to improve productivity in the machine tool sectors. For instance, construction standards have been developed over a 20year period by NC committees of the Electronic Industries Association to enable greater output of standard components and interchangeable subassemblies. In addition, standards have been revised to accommodate advances in technology, such as the capability of computer NC systems to handle manual data input. Aging machinery is a factor which limits productivity growth in firms throughout the metalworking machinery industry. It has been stated that many of the rather old manually operated tools in use actually cut metal for much less than 10 percent of the time a workpiece is in a batch production shop. Considerable time is involved in setting up to make a part, or parts are being loaded or unloaded, or tools are being changed. As noted in the next section, an upswing in investment in new plant and equipment was underway in the metal-cutting sector. Future data may better reflect the installation of newer, more productive machines, because, in general, optimiza tion of new plant and equipment can be a lengthy process. investment Capital ©Kp©ndstyr®s Real capital expenditures11 by the metalworking ma chinery industry in 1978 were less than 80 percent of peak levels in 1966, although in current dollars they rose by nearly two-thirds. The cyclical volatility of capital outlays "Deflated chinery. by implicit price deflator for metalworking ma in this industry is pronounced. Expenditures (in constant dollars) rose almost steadily to their highest level in 1966, moved down rapidly in 1970, and plummeted in 1971 to reach the lowest level since 1963. After rising to near peak levels in 1974, expenditures fell sharply again in 1975. Although they recovered in succeeding years, the peak outlays of 1966 were not surpassed. Approximately the same pattern is reflected in the three major sectors of the metalworking machinery industry. In metal-cutting machinery, peak expenditures (real) oc curred in 1967. In 1978, over a decade later, real expendi tures were less than 65 percent of the peak. Machine tool accessories and measuring devices attained their summit in real capital expenditures in 1966-67; by 1978 they were only about 85 percent of the level for those 2 years. The third major sector—special dies and tools, die sets, jigs and fixtures, and industrial molds—which typically accounts for well over one-third of capital expenditures in metalworking machinery, surpassed its 1966 peak in expenditures in 1974. More pronounced, however, than in the other sectors, was the decline in outlays in 1975, to half of those of the previous year. By 1978, real outlays were about 80 percent of the peak. No more recent Census data are available, but, according to industry reports, outlays by the machine tool builders were rising sharply in response to increasing demand, noted earlier, by the automobile, aircraft, and 184 defense industries. Capacity of this sector may be greatly enlarged in the early 1980’s. The more productive, automated machinery being installed may improve the industry’s competitive position vis-a-vis foreign imports. Research m d development A few of the relatively large machine tool builders have undertaken research as well as development. However, in general, most of these firms are in development only. For example, large machine tool makers are involved in the development of improved computer controls for machine tools. To some extent, large companies outside the industry have undertaken R&D at least in part to improve machining standards in their own work. For instance, a firm pioneered in the recent development of a cutting tool with polycrystalline diamond material. Some joint interindustry development has taken place, including the pooling of development costs by several machine tool builders and an automobile manufacturer in order to increase the speed of lathes. However, there is currently relatively little in the way of joint efforts by government, industry, and labor compared with those in some countries, notably Japan.12 1Comptroller General of the United States, Manufacturing Technology—A Changing Challenge to Improved Productivity, June 3,1976, pp. 74, 88 89. growth through 1967 when peak levels were attained. Subsequently, the industry reflected the economy’s recessions with deep employment declines in 1971 and again, but not as steeply, in 1975 and 1976. Since then, employment has moved up sharply. As mentioned earlier, overtime hours play an impor tant role in this industry. By expanding and contracting overtime hours of production workers in response to changes in output, employers tend to moderate short term hirings and layoffs. While this is true for the entire metalworking machinery industry, it is more marked in the metal-cutting sector. Overtime hours in metal cutting during the sector’s cyclical peaks and troughs of 1960-61, 1969-70, and 1973-75 ranged, respectively, from 5.5 to 1.9 hours, 6.5 to 1.8 hours, and 7.8 to 1.8 hours (average weekly data). The proportion of production workers to all employees in the industry has not changed significant ly in the last two decades. Production workers accounted for 75 percent of all employees in 1960 and 73 percent in 1980. The comparable figures for all durable goods manu facturing industries were 74 percent and 69 percent. The three largest industrial sectors in metalworking machinery—namely, tool and die, metal cutting, and machine tool accessories—accounted for slightly over three-fourths of the industry’s total employment in the years 1960 through 1980, but the metal-cutting sector declined in relative importance. They all exhibited growth from 1960 to 1967, but the tool and die and machine tool accessory sectors grew at faster average annual rates than did metal cutting. In spite of its recent sharp rise, employ ment in metal cutting has not recovered fully from its low levels of 1971 and 1972, while the other two sectors re covered more rapidly and attained their peaks in 1979 and 1980 (chart 7). Tool and die and machine tool accessories firms increased their share of employment within the metalworking industry from 50 percent in 1960 to 55 percent in 1980. The share of metal-cutting employment declined from 27 percent in 1960 to 21.5 percent in 1980. Considerable RAD effort has been directed toward standardization. Whereas once there were more than 30 adapters in use by machine tool builders, the industry is moving toward more universal use of an adapter developed by a large machinery manufacturer. The adapter makes possible substantial reduction in cuttingtool inventories and is considered particularly useful for small firms with NC machines. The National Bureau of Standards is also advancing the pace of innovation within the industry. The Bureau has research underway to improve the ability of NC and industrial robots to work together. The Bureau is also trying to improve the adaptability of robots. According to a Bureau research analyst, the largest share of robot applications during the 1980’s will be in loading-and unloading machine tools. Employment and ©©(g&jp®ts®Gii!! Trsondli The industry’s employment increased at an average annual rate of 1.4 percent in 1960-80, about the same as for all durable goods manufacturing industries. While employment growth averaged 5.1 percent in 1960-67, it declined 3.0 percent annually during 1967-73, but rose again at 2.3 percent annually in 1973-80. For the period 1980-90, three employment projections by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, based on alternative versions of economic growth, fall in the range of 0.8 percent annually (only about half the 1960-80 rate) to 3.8 percent (296 times the 1960-80 rate).13 The low-trend estimate for metalworking machinery is only half the growth rate expected for all durable goods by 1990, while the hightrend estimate (Level B on chart 7) exceeds the projected growth rate for durable goods manufacturing. At 371,500 persons, employment in 1980 was exceeded only during 2 World War II years. After dropping to a postwar trough in 1949, employment rose steadily to 314,000 in 1953, and was not surpassed until the second half of the 1960’s. Over the years 1960-80, there were three periods of sharp cyclical fluctuations affecting every major sector of the metalworking industry. Employment hit a low in 1961 and then exhibited strong continuous ©©gypiitteois B l s projects an employment increase from 1978 to 1990 for all but the smallest occupational group (sales workers) in the metalworking machinery industry. Craft workers and operatives, the two largest of the blue-collar groups, each constituted nearly one-third of all employees in metalworking in 1978. While operatives are expected to grow 36 percent by 1990, the increase for craft workers is expected to be about half that rate (chart 8). By 1990, operatives will account for a somewhat larger percent of total employment than in 1978, while the proportion of craft workers is expected to decline slightly. A major influence on occupational skills and responsibilities in the past decade has been the use of numerically controlled machines. For example, the more rapid growth in employment of operatives is at least partly attributable to the recent expansion of NC '^Projections for industry employment'in 1990 are based on three alternative versions of economic growth for the overall economy developed by bls. The low-trend version is based on a view of the economy marked by a decline in the rate of expansion of the labor force, continued high inflation, moderate productivity gains, and modest increases in real output and employment, in the high-trend version I, the economy is buoyed by higher labor force growth, much lower unemployment rates, higher production, and greater improvements in prices and productivity. The high-trend version II is characterized by the high gnp growth of high-trend I, but assumes the same labor force as the low trend. Productivity gains are quite substantial in this alternative. On chart 7, Level A is the low-trend, Level B is high-trend 1, and Level C is high-trend II. Greater detail on assumptions is available in the August 1981 issue of the Monthly Labor Review. 185 Chart 7. Employment in metalworking machinery and selected industry sectors, 1960-80, and projections for 1980-90 Employees (thousands) 560 Note: See text footnote 13 for explanation of alternative projections. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. 186 Chart 8. Projected changes in employment in metalworking machinery by occupational group, 1978-90 Occupational group Percent of industry employment in 1978 Professional and technical workers 9.0 Managers, officials, and proprietors 8.4 Sales workers 1.9 Clerical workers 12.1 Craft workers 32.3 Operatives 32.5 Service workers 1.8 Laborers 2.0 Percent change 10 20 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. machines and various intermediate technologies. A shortage of skilled workers is a major reason certain firms have turned to NC. Over 800 member firms of the National Tooling and Machining Association indicated that they needed on average a 26-percent increase in skilled toolmakers and machinists.14 Similarly, the great majority of nonelectrical machinery manufacturing plants responding to an Industry Week survey reported shortages of skilled workers; the most pressing needs were for machine operators, mechanics, electricians, and tooland-die makers.15 A study which compared the skills of machinists on NC with those on manually operated machine tools revealed that NC machines are associated with a decline in demand for motor skills and decisionmaking abilities.16 According to a BLS study, NC operators need less knowledge because tapes are programmed to control speed, feed, and width u National Tooling and Machining Association, Record, Vol. 2, No. 5, May 1979, p. 4. l5Daniel D. Cook and John S. McClenahen, “Skilled Worker Nears Extinction,” Industry Week, Aug. 29, 1977, p. 46; also see Michael Marley, “If They Could Clone Skilled Workers,” Iron Age, Vol. 221, No. 37, Sept. 11, 1978, pp. 36-38. I6R.J. Hazlehurst, R.J. Bradbury, and E.N. Corlett, “A Comparison of the Skills of Machinists on Numerically Controlled and Conventional Machines,” Occupational Psychology, Vol. 43, Nos. 3 and 4, 1969, p. 177. 187 and depth of cut.17 At the same time, the study referred to the need for greater conceptual skills on NC machines. There will, however, be continued need for highly skilled machine operators on the most advanced NC machines. Moreover, the costliness of NC machines and the intricacy of their control systems increase the need for preventive maintenance mechanics trained in electronics with practical knowledge of hydraulics and pneumatics. Bls projects that employment of mechanics, repairers, and installers, a subdivision of the craft worker group, will expand five times as fast as all craft employment. While employment of professional and technical workers is projected to grow by 22 percent from 1978 to 1990, the projected increase for managers, officials, and proprietors will be only at one-fourth that rate. The former’s share of total industry employment will be virtually unchanged by 1990, while the latter’s share will decline. Changed skills and responsibilities, also largely related to NC equipment, are occurring for these occupational groups. The competitive structure of the industry and complexity of NC equipment and other technologies require not only knowledge of the new machines but also the capability to organize a shop’s production so that the machines are utilized optimally, 17Technological Change and Manpower Trends in Five Indus tries, Bulletin 1856 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1975), p. 42. Engineers will remain the dominant occupation for the professional and technical worker group in 1990, with about half the engineers still in the mechanical field. Drafters will remain, by far, the largest single occupation in the technician group. While computer specialists are expected to increase at only half the rate for total industry employment, the number of numerical tool programmers will more than double by 1990, but will still account for less than one-half of 1 percent of the industry’s employees. The programmer position on advanced NC tools requires mathematics, the ability to visualize objects and motions in dimensions, and an understanding of cutting and tooling principles. Adjustment ©If workers t® tediinologicali sHissiig® Programs to protect the worker from the adverse affects of changes in machinery and methods may be incorpora ted into union contracts or they may be informal arrange ments between workers and management. In general, such programs are more prevalent and detailed in formal contracts. Both formal and informal labor-management arrangements are influenced by the state of the economy and the availability of labor. Training may be the major factor in the adjustment of workers to technological change in this industry. Officers of leading machine tool manufacturing firms refer to shortages of trained machinists and other technical and skilled workers as a principal obstacle to maintaining high levels of production or increasing them. Provision for an adequate level of training is complicated by demographic factors. An aging work force is making it steadily harder to maintain a nucleus of skilled workers as many, including tool-and-die makers, continue to retire. To cover the skill shortages, NC tool builders have provided short, intensive training program s in the fundamentals of maintenance to electricians and other skilled workers. Machinists and even experienced machine operators are being trained in programming. The extent of training provided by employers is not precisely known. In some cases, small firms have taken a multiemployer approach to apprenticeship and other qualifying training. While some form of training is provided by most employers, local union bargaining agreements typically do not refer specifically to training. A BLS survey of structured training in the nonelectrical machinery industries disclosed that only 18 percent of the surveyed establishments provided training in one or more skilled occupations; and only about one-third of the training was for skill improvement, while two-thirds was training to qualify for the job. The survey excluded the most common forms of training, namely, learning through experience and informal training. The survey included metalworking machinery establishments but data for them were not available separately. Since 1966, the U.S. Department of Labor (D O L) has provided training funds which have been distributed by 188 the National Machine Tool Builders Association. As of fiscal year 1979, trainees hired by the machine tool manufacturers for the DOL program have to be economically disadvantaged persons. The training (including classroom instruction) is conducted on the job site. Typically, the training is in such fields as machine operation, assembly, and machine repair, and the programs run 13 to 16 weeks. More than 14,000 graduates have proven a good screening source for apprentices who can later qualify for more skilled, higher paying jobs requiring further training. The National Tooling and Machining Association has enrolled over 15,000 persons in their preemployment training program funded by the DOL. The program, which previously consisted of 16 weeks of institutional training followed by 36 weeks of on-the-job training, now is a 12week program of institutional training only for economically disadvantaged persons. An industry spokesman believes that this program alone is not providing a sufficient number of persons who are qualified for further training in more highly skilled occupations. Since skilled workers are in short supply, some firms have sought foreign workers. However, the firms do this reluctantly because of the time involved in completing paperwork and securing approval for immigration. A survey in Milwaukee disclosed that the careers of machinist or machine operator ranked rather low with high school students, even though the city is a major machine tool producer.18 However, some metalworking firms are making greater efforts to attract young people to the industry by enrolling high school students in cooperative programs (involving morning school attend ance and afternoon work), much as they have done successfully with engineering personnel. The International Association of Machinists and Aerospace Workers (1AM) is the major union in this industry. The United Automobile Workers (UAW ) and the United Steelworkers of America (U SA ) are the other two leading unions. Overall, these unions plus several others have organized about one-third of the workers in the industry. Contract provisions for nine metalworking firms studied by BLS which each employ at least 1,000 workers appear to be representative of the bargaining agreements negotiated by the three leading unions. In general, the prevalence of seniority provisions acts as a measure of job security when technological change takes place. Agree ments provide for seniority rights in the event of layoff and for purposes of rehiring. Interplant transfers are quite uncommon. A provision requiring advance notice of layoff is present in a majority of the agreements studied, ISJ.G. Udell and others, Skilled Labor in the Milwaukee Area: The Supply, Education, Problems and Opportunities, Wisconsin Economy Study No. 15 (Madison, University of Wisconsin, Graduate School of Business, July 1977). but such notices are generally unrelated to technological change. Nevertheless, some agreements specifically refer to “new equipment” and most u a w agreements deal with “new jobs.” Companies in these instances are normally required to consult with the union regarding changes in job description or occupational assignment of the job, and provisions exist for resolving grievances. Considerable effort by management to improve job security is related to the shortage of skilled workers. The problem is complicated by the cyclical nature of the industry. A Connecticut machine tool builder visited by BLS made the following arrangement: During a 9-month slack period, the firm employed its work force for 3-week periods, and unemployment insurance (ui) payments were secured for the fourth week of each month. (In Connecticut, no waiting period is required for Ul payments.) SELECTED REFERENCES Ashburn, Anderson. “The 1980 Machine-Tool Standings,” American Machinist, February 1981, p. 93. National Center for Productivity and Quality of Working Life. New Technologies and Training in Metalworking, Washington, U.S. Gov ernment Printing Office, 1978. Ashburn, Anderson, and others. “The Machine Tool Task Force Re ports on Metalcutting-Machine-Tool Technology,” American Ma chinist, October 1980. National Machine Tool Builders’ Association. 1980-1981 Economic Handbook o f the Machine Tool Industry. McLean, Virginia, 1980. Bellows, Guy. Nontraditional Machining Guide—26 Newcomers for Production. Cincinnati, Metcut Research Associates, Inc., 1976. Putnam, George P. “Why More NC Isn’t Being Used,” Machine and Tool Blue Book, September 1978, pp. 98-107. Beman, Lewis, and Steven E. Prokesch, “Foreign Competition Stirs U.S. Toolmakers,” Business Week, Sept. 1, 1980, pp. 68-70. Schaffer, George. “Digital Readout Systems,” American Machinist, May 1979, pp. SR-2-4. Comptroller General of the United States. Manufacturing Technolo gy—A Changing Challenge to Improved Productivity, Report to the Congress, lcd-75-436, June 3, 1976. Smith, Donald N., and Lary Evans. Management Standards for Com puter and Numerical Controls. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan, 1977. Cook, Daniel D., and John S. McClenahen. “Skilled Worker Nears Extinction,” Industry Week, Aug. 29, 1977, pp. 38-48. Dallas, Daniel B. “Machining Outlook for 1978,” Manufacturing Engi neering. January 1978, pp. 46-50. “The 12th American Machinist Inventory of Metalworking Equipment 1976-78,” American Machinist, December 1978, pp. 133-48. Gettelman, Ken. “Numerical Control’s Tech Explosion,” Modern Machine Shop, July 1979, pp. 79-88. Udell, J.G.,and others. Skilled Labor in the Milwaukee Area: The Sup ply, Education, Problems and Opportunities. Wisconsin Economy Study No. 15, Madison, University of Wisconsin, July 1977, Golembe, Stanley, “Application, Justification and Selection of Digital Readouts,” Modern Machine Shop, May 1977, pp. 88-96. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Outlook for Numerical Control o f Machine Tools, by John Macut. Bulletin 1437, March 1965. Hatschek, R.L. “Manual-Data-lnput Controls,” American Machinist, May 1978, pp. SR -18-SR-19. Macut, John. “New Technology in Metalworking,” Occupational Out look Quarterly, February 1965. Mansfield, Edwin, and others. Research and Innovation in the Modern Corporation. New York, Norton and Company, Inc., 1971, pp. 186— 205. 189 U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics and Employ ment and Training Administration. Occupational Training in Se lected Metalworking Industries, 1974. B ls Bulletin 1976, ETA R&D Monograph 53, 1977. Technology and Labor in Motor Vehicles and Equipment Robert V. Critchlow S u m m a ry managers, sales workers, and semiskilled operatives will in-, crease while declines are expected ip the other major occu pational groups. Although new technology will reduce unit, labor requirements in some operations, industry growth will result in higher long-term employment levels for computer specialists, assemblers, and others who work with new tech nology. Semiskilled workers will continue to constitute the largest occupational category. These workers are engaged in production operations which generally are the most labor intensive and have potential for further technological change. New equipment and manufacturing methods are ex pected to continue to be introduced in the motor vehicle and equipment industry. Specific innovations which may be applied more widely include electronic computers, im proved equipment for automatic assembly, use of plastic and powdered metal materials, numerical control, and im proved transfer lines. New technology in some instances is expected to improve quality and achieve productivity gains. A total of $2.1 billion was spent by the motor vehicle industry for new plant and equipment in 1975, and an estimated $2.4 billion was spent in 1976. These amounts are about three times as much as the 1960 expenditure of $790 million, although the increase would be less in real terms due to increases in plant and equipment prices over the period. The average annual rate of increase in spending was lower during 1967-75 than during the 1960-67 period. Capital expenditures are expected to increase considerably over the next several years in order to produce cars that can meet Federal Government standards for safety, exhaust pol lution levels, and fuel economy. Output per employee-hour in the motor vehicle and equipment industry (BLS data) increased at an annual rate of 3.2 percent between 1960 and 1975. The productivity growth rate in the motor vehicle industry was 3.6 percent annually during 1960-67, slightly above the 3.2-percent average annual rate achieved during 1967-75. Growth in output per employee-hour was particularly strong during 1971 and 1972 as output rose sharply from the 197f) strike-year level in response to very strong demand for cars and trucks. Further productivity growth occurred in 1975 when employment fell more rapidly than output. Produc tivity gains in assembly, machining, and other production operations are expected as new technology is introduced. Industry employment rose from 724,000 in 1960 to a peak of 955,300 in 1973, then dropped during the eco nomic downturn of late 1974-75 to 774,100 in 1975.1 As sales and production improved in 1976, employment rose to 850,600. BLS projections indicate that employment may decline to 808,000 by 1985. Technological and other changes will continue to alter the structure of occupations in this industry. Demand for Technology in the 1®7®?s Technological changes in the motor vehicle and equip ment industry are underway in major phases of production, with productivity gains and laborsavings anticipated. These changes include more extensive use of electronic com puters, improved equipment for automatic assembly and inspection, more widespread use of plastics and other light weight materials, more widespread application of numerical control, and improvements in transfer lines. (See table 5.) Modifications of automobile engines also are underway to meet stricter emission standards and to raise fuel econ omy. Electronic computersComputers are a jkey technology in the automobile in dustry, initially applied to business operations such as pay roll and bookkeeping records and subsequently extended to an increasing number of research and production opera tions. According to International Data Corporation, more than 400 computers are in use in the industry, with fur ther growth in computer use expected. Examples ,qf com puter applications gaining prominence, and their labor im plications, are presented below. Auto styling and design. Mathematical information, repre senting automobile body surfaces can be store4 in %com puter memory system. A designer, working with a graphic display terminal, can use this information to design auto Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 1961 (1977), Technological Change and its Labor Impact in Five Industries. 190 TabS® 5. Major technology changes in the motor vehicle and equipment industry D e s c rip tio n L a b o r im p lic a tio n s D if fu s io n E le c tr o n ic c o m p u te rs T h e use o f g ra p h ic d is p la y t e r m in a ls can in te g ra te and speed w o r k f lo w b e tw e e n d e sig n , to o lin g , a nd p r o d u c tio n . T im e re q u ire m e n ts f o r R & D w o r k are lo w e re d . N u m e ro u s a p p li c a tio n s in q u a lit y c o n t r o l in crease p r o d u c t iv it y o f in s p e c tio n p e rs o n n e l. C o m p u te r c o n t r o l o f m a c h in in g a nd assem b ly o p e ra tio n s m a y incre a se p r o d u c tio n ra te s a nd re d u c e la b o r re q u ire m e n ts . E m p lo y m e n t increases in c o m p u te r -r e la te d o c c u p a tio n s su c h as s y s te m s a n a ly s ts , p ro g ra m m e rs , a nd p e rip h e ra l e q u ip m e n t o p e ra to rs . D e c lin e s e x p e c te d fo r d r a fte r s a n d k e y p u n c h o p e ra to rs . M o re th a n 4 0 0 c o m p u te r s are e s ti m a te d to be in use. C o n tin u e d g r o w th e x p e c te d in th e n u m b e r o f c o m p u te r s a n d ty p e s o f a p p lic a tio n s . M a c h in e a s s e m b ly o p e ra tio n s (a u to m a te d a s s e m b ly lin e s) A u to m a te d a s s e m b ly a p p lic a tio n s range fr o m tig h te n in g b o lts to w e ld in g ca r b o d ie s t o g e th e r . A u to m a tic a sse m b ly s ta tio n s are f r e q u e n tly in t e r m ix e d w it h m a n u a l s ta tio n s , d e p e n d in g u p o n th e n a tu re o f th e jo b . R e d u c e d la b o r r e q u ire m e n ts in s e m is k ille d a s s e m b ly o p e r a tio n s , a nd in c re a s e d need f o r m a c h in e m a in te n a n c e p e rs o n n e l. M a c h in e a s s e m b ly has e x p e rie n c e d c o n s id e ra b le d e v e lo p m e n t o v e r th e p a s t d e c a d e , a n d is e x p e c te d to c o n tin u e to g r o w in use. N e w m a te ria ls P la stic m a te ria ls o f f e r a d v a n tages o v e r ste e l a n d ca st m e ta l m a te r ia ls in w e ig h t savings a n d , o fte n , fe w e r p ro ce s s in g o p e ra tio n s . P a rts can be f a b r i c a te d fr o m m e ta l p o w d e r in to c o m p le x s h a p e s and w it h fe w e r m a c h in in g o p e ra tio n s . M o re w id e s p re a d use o f a lu m i n u m a nd sp e cia l steels also is a n tic ip a te d . S o m e re d u c tio n in s e m is k ille d s h e e t-m e ta l w o r k e r s a nd m a c h in e t o o l o p e ra to rs . Use o f p la s tic s a nd a lu m in u m c o n tin u e to g ro w . N u m e ric a l c o n t r o l A u to m a tic o p e r a tio n o f m a c h in e to o ls b y e le c tr o n ic c o n t r o l d e vice s a n d c o d e d ta p e in s tru c tio n s can re d u c e m a c h in in g tim e and la b o r costs. D e c lin e in th e n u m b e r o f m a c h in e t o o l o p e ra to rs n e e d e d , a nd p o s s i b ly s o m e incre a se in m a c h in e m a in te n a n c e p e rs o n n e l. N u m e ri'c a l c o n t r o l in lim ite d use a t p re s e n t. A p p lic a tio n s e x p e c te d to g ro w in fu t u r e , w it h e m p h a s is o n n e w s o lid - s ta te p ro g r a m m a b le c o n tr o lle r s a n d d ir e c t c o m p u te r c o n t r o l. Im p r o v e d tra n s fe r lin e s T ra n s fe r lin e p r o d u c t iv it y and f l e x ib i li t y have been incre a se d b y th e in t r o d u c t io n o f m u lt i- ; p u rp o s e m a c h in e s , in t e r ch a n g e a b le m a c h in e m o d u le s , sto ra g e b a n k s f o r p a rts a t in te rv a ls in th e m a c h in e lin e , and an incre a se in th e n u m b e r o f a u to m a tic o p e ra tio n s . R e d u c tio n in th e n u m b e r o f m a c h in e to o l o p e ra to rs a n d in s p e c to rs . E q u ip m e n t d e s ig n e d t o in cre a se tr a n s fe r m a c h in e f l e x i b i l i t y is in lim ite d use, a n d s h o u ld in cre a se as tra n s fe r lin e s are m o d ifie d o r re p la c e d in th e fu tu r e . T e c h n o lo g y body parts. The .computer translates the design into mathe matical coordinates thaf can operate automatic drafting ma chines and numerically controlled (N/C) machine tools. En gineering, drafting work, and tool production operations can be more closely integrated, thereby speeding pp the work flow. Computer use in design may affect labor re quirements in tfye industry in several ways. First, th§ com plex programming required may increase the need for com puter programmers. The need for drafters however, should decline. Such computer-aided design is expected to increase in the years ahead. Engineering research and product development. Using com puters, engineers can analyze large quantities of data—some times from computer simulation of real situations—to solve design or production problems in remarkably short periods of time. An auto parts manufacturer, for example, saved 9 months to 1 year of development time by using its com 191 w ill puter capacities to perform preliminary design calculations on a new long-life piston ring.2 Computer application t o ' research and development operations is not yet common place, but it is a frequently used tool that will probably become commonplace in the future. Computer control. The application of computers to the control of production operations is a major step in the evolution of computer technology. Computers are being used to keep track of parts and production materials and to forecast potential shortages that could disrupt production. Computer control can aid in attaining uniformity and qual ity control in machining. It also can aid in work scheduling and production line balancing to increase productivity by directing the proper materials to the worker at his place on the assembly line. Computers can be applied to a group of such operations, tying them together in such a manner as to provide computerized control over an entire manufacturing or assembly process. The computer system also can make available large quantities of current data to management to aid decisionmaking. The major auto manufacturing firms are using most of these applications but there are no data on the extent of their use. Several machine tool manufacturers market computer ized control systems for machine operations. One system links a small computer directly (no tapes are used) to four machine tool controllers. The system requires only one op erator to load stock and oversee the operation of the sys tem, and it can perform the work of ten conventional ma chines and operations.3 Another system uses a small multi purpose computer, memory drum, and a teletypewriter input/output unit to operate simultaneously a combination (up to 16 units) of N/C machines, special purpose ma chines, and transfer machines. One operator can control the entire system.4 Numerical control Numerical control is a process of operating machine tools through a series of electronic control devices and coded tape instructions. It is a process that is particularly suitable for the manufacture of metal parts in small volume because it eliminates the many expensive fixtures, jigs, and templates otherwise necessary. As such, numerical control techniques are in limited,'but increasing, use for the fabrica tion of the tools and dies needed to operate the industry’s many high-volume production machines. Extensive use is being made of numerical control in fabricating sheet-metal parts—a development which ranks among the major applica tions of numerical control techniques in the United States. Increased use of numerical control techniques should, as has occurred in other industries, reduce the need for ma chine tool operators. Applications of numerical control and direct computer control (discussed elsewhere in this chapter) can be ex pected to grow. This is one of several methods the auto industry can use to improve the flexibility and utilization of its basic production machines. Transfer lines Transfer lines—highly mechanized production lines—are becoming more flexible. Traditionally, transfer lines have been custom built to do one job. Any significant change in the job to be done has generally necessitated a significant change in the construction of the transfer line itself—an expensive and time-consuming process. Flexibility is being increased by the use of “building block” , or “modular” , transfer lines, constructed from ma chinery and equipment consisting of interchangeable, stan dardized units. These lines can accommodate changes in parts design or retooling for new car models with delays and retooling costs minimized. 192 The inclusion of storage banks for parts at intervals along a transfer line provides a further increase in flexi bility. These storage banks allow a line to continue in oper ation even if a station in the line stops. Although not a new concept, the use of storage banks has yet to be fully imple mented. Computer simulation is being used by at least one manufacturer to predict optimum locations and sizes for storage banks within the transfer lines. The number of auto matic operations performed on transfer lines also is increas ing, especially time-consuming gaging and inspection opera tions, which allows a reduction in labor requirements and an improvement in quality control. The new transfer lines are mechanically more complex, requiring more highly skilled maintenance crews. The development of solid-state programmable machine controllers also contributes to transfer line flexibility. These controllers operate faster and more reliably than the older magnetic-relay controllers they are replacing. It is their programmability that makes them important. Chang ing the application of a conventional magnetic-relay con troller involves changing the physical wiring in the con troller, and each such change can take an hour or more to make. The programmable controller needs only to be repro grammed, which can be accomplished in minutes, rather than hours. Furthermore, it is possible that the use of pro grammable controllers will lead to more widespread use of computer control. Machine assembly Machine assembly (where it can be used) reduces the high labor content of assembly operations, which may in turn lower manufacturing costs. In addition, stricter safety standards and increased emphasis on product performance and quality can often be better met by machine assembly than by manual methods. The potential impact of automatic assembly operations on labor requirements is considerable because assembly op erations are the most labor intensive in the manufacture of autos. There are many simple, repetitive, and monotonous assembly operations that are candidates for machine assem bly. Similarly, machine assembly can be applied to some operations that are physically difficult and fatiguing. Job skills for assemblers tend to shift toward machine monitor ing and materials handling. The demand and skill require ments for machine maintenance personnel could increase considerably; these can be met by retraining machinists who might otherwise be displaced by the new process. The diversity and productivity potential of automatic assembly machines are illustrated by the following example obtained by BLS staff during plant visits: One manufac turer uses both an automatic and a manual line to assemble and test torque converters used in automatic transmissions. When the automatic line is in full operation, a crew of 8 people per shift is expected to produce as much as is pres ently done by a crew of 13 people on the manual line. One part of the automatic line already in operation inserts blades into slots in the body of the torque converter—a process in which two people per shift (one attendant and one parts loader) on the automatic line can do as much work as four people per shift inserting blades by hand. Several major automakers utilize industrial robots to per form many of the welding operations required on a pas senger car body, including those that are the most difficult for employees to accomplish. The robots are programmed to make a particular type of weld on a specific body style. The first robot in the line is supplied computer data on the sequence of body styles forthcoming on the assembly line. The first robot also contains a master program for control ling the succeeding robots on the welding line. Each robot reportedly can do work equal to U4 welders, thereby reduc ing the number of welders needed. This is, however, some what counterbalanced by the need for a larger and more highly trained maintenance crew. Although there may be little or no labor savings, the quality of the weld is more consistent than is possible with manual welding. New materials and processes The use of plastic materials has grown considerably as improvements in both the plastic materials and the plastic working technology have become available. Advantages of plastics over steel (in those cases where plastics meet rigid ity and strength requirements) include lower weight and generally lower tooling costs. Increased use of plastics may reduce labor requirements because plastic parts often re quire fewer finishing operations than comparable metal parts and large, one-piece molded plastic panels (such as dash panels or front-end body panels) can often replace an assemblage of sheet-metal parts, reducing assembly time. Plastics (especially fiber-reinforced composites using glass or other filaments) are expected to grow considerably in use because of the increased emphasis on lowering vehicle weight to improve fuel economy. Aluminum and special steels also will be used more widely for a growing number of auto components to reduce weight. The fabrication of metal parts from metal powder is more widely used in the automotive field than in any other industry, and may become even more important due to recent improvements in materials and manufacturing pro cesses. Powder metallurgy parts can be made in complex shapes, of high strength, and to such close tolerances that many secondary machining operations and inspection pro cedures can be reduced or eliminated, thereby reducing labor requirements. ©ytpyft sod ©ytS@@k O utp u t Industry output increased at an average annual rate of 4.8 percent between 1960 and 1975. The growth rate was higher 193 during 1960-67 period—averaging 7.9 percent a year—than it was during the more recent 1967-75 period, when it averaged 3.2 percent a year. The lower growth rate of recent years reflects several negative economic factors: There was a moderate recession and a major industry strike in 1970, followed—from late 1973 to 1975—by an oil embargo, a period of high inflation, and a severe recession. What tends to be obscured in this growth rate figure is that output rose to record levels in 1971, 1972, and 1973. Auto sales began to rise in late 1975. and continued strong during 1976. Historically, “regular” size passenger cars have been the mainstay of U.S. auto manufacturers. During the late 1960’s, however, smaller passenger cars—intermediates, compacts, and subcompacts, both domestic and foreign— became more important in the marketplace at the expense of regular size and large cars. According to Ward’s Automo tive Yearbook, intermediate and small cars accounted for almost 40 percent of new car registrations in 1966. By 1975 this figure had grown to 77 percent. The trend toward smaller cars will continue in response to the present Federal Government regulations for fuel economy (27.5 miles per gallon by 1985) set in the Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975. To meet such a fuel economy goal with current automotive technology will re quire a rather large shift to small cars. The popularity of such a shift among car buyers remains to be seen. During the energy crisis from late 1973 to early 1974 the demand for small, fuel-efficient cars was strong. But as fears of gaso line shortages declined, so did some of the enthusiasm for the smallest cars. The strongest sales for 1975-76, according to industry sources, were of the intermediate and larger autos, although sales of the smaller cars did not decline. As of late 1976, however, some dealers were offering discounts on some subcompact models in an effort to improve their sales. The most likely market structure over the next 5 to 10 years will be a general reduction in size in all categories. Passenger cars presently considered to be of “intermediate” size may well become the standard size. A demand for “full size” cars is expected to continue if production of such cars remains possible under the fuel economy regulations. Sev eral domestic manufacturers have expressed concern that the various Federal regulations on fuel economy, exhaust pollution, and safety standards could affect the size, perfor mance, and general desirability of future passenger cars. Demand for light trucks and vans (less than 14,000 pounds gross vehicle weight) has been strong since the late 1960’s as recreational vehicles gained in popularity. During 1973, demand for heavy trucks (which had increased stead ily after a 1970 slump) also grew sharply. Truck production peaked at a record level in 1973, then dropped slightly, but surged to a new record in the 1976 model year. Truck trailer production dropped sharply in 1975, in part because of heavy purchases in late 1974 as customers sought to avoid purchasing 1975 units that were required by law to have expensive anti-skid braking equipment. Productivity Output per employee-hour increased at an average an nual rate of 3.2 percent from 1960 to 1975. The in crease averaged 3.6 percent annually during 1960-67, slightly higher than the 3.2-percent productivity growth rate achieved during 1967-75. Growth in output per employee-hour was particularly strong in 1971 and 1972 as output rose sharply from 1970 in response to a very strong demand for new cars and trucks. Productivity continued to grow in 1973 as manu facturers reported a third year of record new car and truck sales; however, by the fourth quarter of 1973, retail sales had begun to fall, causing a final-quarter decline in both output and productivity levels. The decline in productivity continued through 1974, during which there was a sharp drop in output and in employee hours, but a considerably smaller drop in the number of people employed. Appar ently the manufacturers chose to cut working hours (espe cially overtime) and keep their work force intact. The year 1975 was unusual for the industry in terms of output and productivity. Output continued to decline (for the second year in a row) due in part to the recession and in part to higher auto prices. Although output declined, pro ductivity increased substantially. In this instance, both em ployee hours and total employment declined at about the same rate—and both dropped considerably more than did output. Thus, the productivity increase resulted, for the year as a whole, from a large drop in the industry’s work force and a much smaller drop in output. In fact, output actually increased in two quarters during the year, while employee hours remained at low levels during all four quar ters. Investment Capital expenditures Expenditures for new plant and equipment, in current dollars, increased from $790 million in 1960 to $2.1 billion in 1975, an average of 7.4 percent per year. An estimated $2.4 billion was spent in 1976. Since current-dollar figures do not take into account price increases over the years, real capital outlays were less than these figures indicate. The rate of increase in capital expenditures was significantly higher between 1960 and 1967, when,the industry was ex panding its productive capacity, than during the more re cent 1967-75 period. The average annual rates of growth were 16.0 percent in 1960-67 and 6.9 percent in 1967-75. As shown in table 6, the rate of increase in capital ex penditures per production worker was also greater during the first half of the 1960-75 period. Plant and equipment expenditures per production worker in 1974 reached a peak of $4,266, or triple the 1960 total of approximately $1,400 per production worker, and then declined to $3,460 per production worker in’ 1975. 194 Capital spending is expected to increase strongly over the next several years. A recent McGraw-Hill survey of capi tal spending plans5 indicates that planned expenditures for 1977 will jump to $4.15 billion, followed by an increase to $4.36 billion in 1978. One manufacturer plans to invest $15 billion by 1980 for new, redesigned, smaller passenger cars, while another manufacturer plans to spend almost $2 billion (worldwide) in 1977, and over $2 billion a year in 1978, 1979, and 1980.6 This high level of capital spending is necessary to design and produce car models that will meet Federal Government standards for safety requirements, exhaust pollution levels, and—most especially—fuel economy. While funds will be invested in all of the production phases, the emphasis will be on new tooling for updated car models. The increasing importance of capital relative to labor is reflected in a decline in the ratio of payroll to value added, from 0.451 in 1960 to 0.419 in 1972, an annual average rate of decline of 0.1 percent. (See table 6.) Funds for research and development Expenditures for research and development (R&D) in the industry group of motor vehicles and other transporta tion equipment except aircraft7 increased from $884 mil lion in 1960 to a planned level of $2.4 billion in 1974, or at an average rate of 7.2 percent a year. Company R&D ex penditures were 2.3 percent of net sales in 1960, increasing to a planned level of 2.8 percent in 1974. R&D expendi tures are expected to rise to $3.1 billion by 1977.8 Research is underway to develop new automobile power plants that meet exhaust emission standards and provide improved fuel economy. Alternative types of power plants being considered range from modified conventional piston engines to alternative engine concepts including the rotary engine, diesel engine, and turbine, Stirling cycle, and electric engines. The approach found most feasible by most major Table 6. Indicators of change in the motor vehicle and equipment industry, 1960-75 In d ic a t o r C a p ita l e x p e n d itu r e s p er p r o d u c tio n w o r k e r .............. P a y ro ll p e r u n it o f va lu e a d d e d ......................................... R esearch a n d d e v e lo p m e n t e x p e n d itu r e s 3 ...................... A v e ra g e a n n u a l ra te o f c h a n g e 1 1 9 6 0 -7 5 1 9 6 0 -6 7 1 9 6 7 -7 5 5 .9 1 1 .8 7 .4 2- 0 . 1 - 0 .5 2- 0 . 5 4 7 .2 6 .8 4 9.1 1 L in e a r lea st sq ua re s tr e n d s m e th o d . 2 F in a l y e a r = 1 9 7 2 . 3 D a ta are f o r m o to r v e h ic le s a n d a ll o th e r t r a n s p o r t a t io n e q u ip m e n t e x c e p t a ir c r a ft , a n d a re based o n e x p e n d itu r e s o f m a n u fa c tu r in g c o m p a n ie s in th e t r a n s p o r t a t io n in d u s tr y (e x c e p t a ir c r a ft c o m p a n ie s ) th a t have re sea rch a n d d e v e lo p m e n t p ro g ra m s . 1 9 7 4 fig u re s are based o n c o r p o r a te s p e n d in g p la n s as r e p o r te d b y M c G r a w - H ill. 4 F in a l y e a r = 1 9 7 4 . S O U R C E : B u re a u o f L a b o r S ta tis tic s , B u re a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is , B u re a u o f th e C ensus, N a tio n a l S c ie n c e F o u n d a tio n , a n d M c G r a w - H ill. automobile manufacturers starting with 1975 models is modification of the piston engine through application of catalytic converters—a device attached to the exhaust sys tem which uses platinum and palladium as catalytic agents to convert noxious auto exhaust emissions into water vapor and carbon dioxide. The “stratified charge” engine, a conventional piston engine with an unconventional cylinder head, reportedly has the capability to meet most of the strict emission standards to be implemented after 1978 and may, according to some experts, become more widely used in the early 1980’s. While some improvements in fuel economy may result from refinements in engine design, reducing automobile weight is probably the best way to improve fuel economy. Building smaller cars and substituting lightweight materials (such as aluminum and plastic) are two of the more obvious ways to reduce weight. One manufacturer has already intro duced some new car models that are smaller and lighter than the corresponding models of previous years-and this trend will continue. Employment and Oasypationa! Trends Employment Employment in this industry rose from 724,100 in 1960 to a peak of 955,300 in 1973 and then dropped sharply as economic conditions turned downward and auto sales fell, to 774,100 in 1975. This pattern represents an average growth rate of only 1.6 percent a year between 1960 and 1975. During the first half of this period, 1960 to 1967, employment grew at an average annual rate of 3.6 percent. Between 1967 and 1975, however, employment declined by an average of 0.2 percent a year. As sales and production rose again in 1976, employment increased to 850,600. The long-term trend, however, is for a decline in employ ment. The BLS projections for 1973-85, indicate a parti cularly sharp decline from 1973, when employment was at an all-time high. Employment in the motor vehicle and equipment indus try is concentrated in two industry sectors: Motor vehicles (SIC 3711), and parts and accessories (SIC 3714). The motor vehicles sector employed 41 percent of the indus try’s work force in 1960 and 42 percent in 1975. Employ ment in the parts and accessories component of the indus^ try accounted for 43 percent of the work force in 1960 and 45 percent in 1975. The ratio of production workers to total employment has remained fairly stable; production workers accounted for 78 percent of total employment in 1960 and 77 percent in 1975. The rate of employment growth for production workers during 1960-75 was 2 percent-about the same as the all-employee growth rate indicated earlier. The rates of growth in employment of production workers during the 195 shorter term 1960-67 and 1967-75 periods closely parallel trends for total employment. Occupations Technological and other changes are expected to alter the occupational structure of the motor vehicle industry by 1985. Employment is expected to increase in only three of the eight major occupational groups—managers, officials, and proprietors; sales workers; and operatives. In the other major occupational groups employment is expected to decline, ment is expected to decline. Increased use of computers in design, engineering, and production applications should bring about several changes among professional and technical workers and clerical workers. The number of computer specialists (primarily sys tems analysts and programmers) is expected to increase by 8 percent. Greater use of computer terminals should in crease the productivity of drafting technicians and engi neers, although the effect of this on employment is unclear. If the volume of work were to remain unchanged, employ ment might decline. But there is a strong possibility that computer techniques will be used more intensively to im prove vehicle design and weight optimization—new analyti cal work which could absorb people who might otherwise not be needed. An increase of 34 percent is expected for computer peripheral equipment operators. Keypunch oper ators are expected to decline*by 58 percent as punchcard data entry is supplanted by more sophisticated forms of data entry. Operatives (semiskilled workers) will continue to be the largest occupational category in the motor vehicle industry, making up about 50 percent of the work force. Many of these workers are engaged in production operations that are relatively labor intensive and have potential for further automation. Semiskilled metal workers (drill press opera tors, lathe operators, welders, etc.) are expected to decline by 20 percent in response to more widespread use of nu merically controlled machines, industrial robots for welding and inspection operations, and more automatic transfer lines. Although some advances are anticipated in automatic (or machine) assembly operations, the job category of assem blers is expected to grow by 34 percent to employ almost 168,000 people by 1985—by far the largest single occupa tion in the industry. The general increase in automated pro duction and inspection operations should serve to limit any increase in the number of inspectors needed. Training for many of the semiskilled jobs is relatively brief, consisting primarily of on-the-job instruction for periods of several days to several weeks. Hence, shifting semiskilled workers from one position to another generally should not cause great dislocations. The impact of advanced production machines on occu pational skills was discussed with officials from several auto manufacturers visited by BLS staff. In general, a shift to ward skilled workers is expected—especially in computerrelated occupations—with a decline in unskilled workers and semiskilled machine operators. Maintenance workers would be the occupation most greatly affected, with de mand for these workers rising in step with increases in the use of N/C machines, industrial robots, and other auto mated machines. Skilled machinists who are displaced by automated machines can be retrained to maintain the new equipment. Adjustment of workers to technological change The impact of technology on jobs is probably not as critical in the auto industry as it is in many other industries. A substantial proportion of blue-collar jobs are in semi skilled occupations, and operators displaced from one job can be retrained for other jobs more easily than in indus tries with high skill level requirements. Also, there are areas in auto production (such as final assembly) that are fairly labor intensive, and will continue to be so in the foreseeable future. Approximately two-thirds of the industry’s employees are covered by collective bargaining contracts. All of the contracts contain general provisions pertaining to seniority, layoffs, grievances, retirement, and supplementary unem ployment benefits that could be applied to job losses result ing from technological change. Additionally, contracts with two manufacturers contain specific statements con cerning technological change. In both cases, the contracts have provisions that require advance notice to the union of planned technological changes, create training programs for qualified employees within the bargaining unit, and allow problems not otherwise resolved to be submitted through the regular grievance procedures. The recession of 1974 and 1975 caused considerable tur moil in the auto industry. Employment dropped substan tially and some plants were shut down sufficiently long for a number of laid-off employees to exhaust their unemploy ment benefits. By the time new labor contracts were due to be negotiated in late 1976, production and employment had returned to healthy levels—but the recession probably left its imprint on the contract negotiations. In a 4-week strike at one manufacturer, the United Auto Workers won a shorter work year. Employees will receive a total of 13 additional days off over the 3-year contract period, which will serve to create new jobs over the short run and preserve job security in the future. The other manufacturers have since agreed to this pattern. 5Preliminary Plans for Capital Spending in 1977-78, McGrawHill Fall Survey, Fall 1976. 1These data exclude employees in a number o f industries which produce components for the motor vehicle industry. According to estimates o f the Motor Vehicle Manufacturers Association, more than 517,000 workers are engaged in producing motor vehicle com ponents and thus are classified in industries other than SIC 371, motor vehicles and equipment. 6 “Capital Spending to Set Record in ’77,” Autom otive. Indus tries, October 1, 1976, pp. 14-15. 7 Motor vehicles and other transportation equipment except air craft consists o f SIC’s 371, 373, 374, 375, and 379. Separate data for the motor vehicle industry, SIC 371, were not available until 1972. The importance o f motor vehicles within this industry group is illustrated by the fact that the motor vehicle segment accounted for over 98 percent o f the industry group’s R&D funds in 1972 and 1973. 2 “Computer Speeds Design Production of Piston Rings,” A u to m otive Industries, November 15, 1968, pp. 79-85. 3 “N/C and C/C, New Keys to Productivity,’’'A u to m o tive Indus tries, O ctober 15, 1972, pp. 33-36. 4 “Computer Controlled Machining,” A u tom otive Industries, July 15, 1970, pp. 51-52. 8 R&D expenditures for 1960, National Science Foundation; planned R&D expenditures for 1974 and 1977, McGraw-Hill. SELECTED “Computer Controlled M a c h in in g A u tom otive Industries, July 15, 1970, pp. 51-52. “ Lordstown Plant: GM’s New Mark o f Excellence?,” Iron Age, March 11, 1971, pp. 39-40. “Computer Speeds Design Production o f Piston Rings ''A u to m o tive Industries, November 15, 1968, pp. 79-85. “ Machine Assembly . . . Industry’s Last Change for Increasing Pro ductivity,” A u tom otive Industries, April l , 1972, pp. 35^4-1. “ Detroit’s Frantic Hunt for a Cleaner Engine,” Business Week, December 9, 1972, pp. 60-70. “ Materials: New Marriages in Design,” A u tom otive Industries, December 15, 1973, pp. 37-47. “Gage-Assemble-Test Warms Up Again.” A utom otive Industries, C)ctober 15, 1976, pp. 24-27. “N/C and, C /C -N ew Keys to Productivity,” A u tom otive Industries, October 15, 1972, pp. 33-36. “ How Computers Unify Manufacturing,” A u tom otive Industries, June 1, 1974, pp. 31-36. “ Powder Metallurgy: Phase II,” A u tom otive Industries,. July J , 1972, pp. 25-28. 196 T@(g[h[n)®S@gf and Labor in Petroleum (Refining Rose N. Zeisel and Micheal D. Dymmel S y m m a ry Technological changes in the refining industry are being made in response to shifts in crude oil supply, changing demand for petroleum products, and envi ronmental and energy considerations, in addition to the usual incentives of greater productivity and low er costs. These changes are primarily in the areas of cracking, hydrotreating, and reforming, in associa tion with advanced instrumentation and computer control. The outlook is for greater emphasis on pro cesses for desulfurization and octane improvement. Because the industry is capital intensive, the shortrun effects on labor are likely to be minimal, but in the longer run they will alter job content and may reduce employment growth. Productivity rose sharply from 1960 to 1977, at an average rate of 4.3 percent annually compared with 2.6 percent in ail manufacturing. From 1967 to 1977, the rate was 3.0 percent. The outlook to 1985 is for productivity to rise but at a slower rate than in the last decade. Many uncertain variables affect the out look including crude imports, gas supplies, and gov ernment environmental and energy policies. But for the most pari, the industry’s productivity in the next decade will depend on the Nation’s economic growth and consequent energy needs. Changes in govern ment policies or in the international situation are not dealt with in this chapter. Capital investments have been increasing almost steadily since the 1960’s. By January 1977, operable capacity had risen 50 percent over the decade and 20 percent since January 1973, reversing concerns about capacity shortages. Due to uncertainties of supply and demand and rapidly rising costs, howev er, there is no general agreement on future capital outlays for capacity expansion. But large invest ments are anticipated to accommodate changing demand for the industry’s products and government environmental and energy policies. About 160,000 people were employed in the indus try in 1977, the largest number since 1962. Following a sharp decline in the first half of the !960’s reflect ing very rapid productivity growth, employment was Reprinted from BLS Bulletin 2005 (1979), Technological Change and its L abor Im pact in Five Engergy Industries. S97 relatively stable until 1973. Since 1973, however, employment has been moving up as technology changes require more unit labor and as the number of very small refineries increases. The outlook to 1985 is for a resumption of the decline. Technology in the 1970’s Petroleum refining is a series of processes of phys ical separations and chemical reactions, it involves three major groups of processes: Separation, conver sion, and treating. First the hydrocarbon compounds in the crude oils are separated through heating and distillation to recover the lighter products such as gasoline, kerosene, and distillate fuels. Some com pounds heavier than gasoline may be “ cracked” or chemically converted into higher quality products. Desired products may also be built up by chemical reactions such as alkylation. Others are chemically rearranged, by catalytic reforming, for example. In addition, at some stage of manufacture the products may be treated to remove impurities such as sulfur or metals. In the past, the objective of U. S. refineries was to maximize gasoline production rather than the out put of heavier fuels. Consistent with this objective, they were geared, primarily, to producing high-oc tane gasoline from low sulfur (sweet) crude petro leum. Moreover, in general, there were no restric tions on levels of sulfur and other impurities in pe troleum products. However, the picture is changing. First, there appears to be a long-term shift in emphasis from gasoline to heavy fuels based on a projected slow down in gasoline demand and an increase in the market for heavy fuels as a result of the natural gas shortage. Second, environmental protection regula tions encourage or require low-sulfur, low-lead prod ucts, as well as the reduction of noxious wastes from the refining process itself. At the same time, however, the availability of low-sulfur varieties is declining. As a result of these conditions, refineries must make adjustments to accommodate product changes. In addition, changes are taking place in the struc ture of the industry. Although a number of small refineries are being built, in general, process units are becoming larger, and functions are being consoli dated to increase productivity. Average capacity has increased very sharply to over 60,000 barrels per day (as of January 1977), and the labor implications (dis cussed in the employment section) are significant. Capacity varies considerably among refineries, how-, ever, ranging from 500 to 640,000 barrels per day. Sn general, the smaller plants consist of a crude oil dis tillation unit plus the necessary auxiliary units, while the larger refineries are considerably more complex. They include, in addition to distillation facilities, Tab!© 4. cracking, reforming, coking, hydrogen-treating, alky lation, fuel desulfurization, and other processing un its. Key advances in the basic refining processes in the last decade, their labor impact, and their rate of difusion are presented in table 4 and discussed in greater detail below. Computer control High-speed digital computers improve production efficiency and raise quality through - more precise control of the production process. Other benefits also are often cited, such as better technical and operating data and improved plant safety. tectaology ebsnges in petroleym srafmiing Technology Description Labor implications Diffusion C om puter control H igh-speed digital com puters, in association with highly com plex instrum entation, m onitor and/or control various refinery process es; th e y .a re used in testing and research laboratories and for m anagem ent inform ation. Use minimizes co sts and im proves product quality. A ffects o p e ra to r’s duties prim ari ly, assum ing earlier installation of sophisticated instrum entation; requires com puter-related techni cians. Installation in one-fourth of refin eries constituting m ore than twothirds of industry crude capacity. Im proved cracking Improved riser-cracking tech- • niques use cataly sts with more tolerance to fe ed sto cks of higher metal content to provide greater yields o f desired products and higher octane ratings. Im proved hydrocracking provides more feedstock flexibility. Increased labor productivity; di rect effects are minimal. R iser m ethod constitutes approxi m ately 40 percent of U .S. c ra ck ing capacity. H ydrocracking ca pacity is equal to 16 percent of the total. Diffusion is expected to be relatively slow. D esulfurization ad v an ces H igh-activity catalysts and other advances efficiently reduce sulfur content. H ydrogen-based process es enable refineries to process so u r crude, to m ake low -sulfar feed sto ck s for m odern </.<aiytic reform ing units, to produce resid uals and distillates to environm en tal specifications, and to meet pollutant em ission controls. Additional processing, increases unit labor requirem ents for tech nicians and m aintenance person nel. Process units being built into new refineries. Diffusion will depend on environm ental protection re quirem ents and type of crude available. H ydroprocessing capac ity increased 30 percent betw een 1975 and 1.978, and is expected to increase another 5 percent by 1980. O ctane-im proving processes C atalytic reform ing, alkylation, and isom erization increase gaso line octane ratings w ithout lead additives. N ew bim etallic cata lysts are im proving all reform ing m ethods. C ontinuous reform ing elim inates periodic shutdow ns for catalyst regeneration. Direct labor effects depend on refinery com plexity. Small plants may need additional operators and m aintenance w orkers. In all cases, productivity would be ad versely affected. By !978, reform ing accounted for 22 percent of crude capacity; isom erization, 2 percent; alkyla tion, 5 percent. Low -lead require m ents suggest increased im por tance of octane-im proving proc esses. E nergy conservation m ethods Increased use of heat exchangers, furnace air preh eaters, therm al insulation, gas and hydraulic tur bines, w aste-heat steam genera tion, process im provem ents. j Increases m aintenance labor, par ticularly in older refineries; also increases dem and for engineering skills. By early 1976, energy use was cut !0 p ercent below 1972. E xpecta tions are fo r an additional 15-per cent cut by 1985. Preventive m aintenance technologies U se of ultrasonic testing. X-ray testing, infrared cam eras, m agnet ic particle testing, and corrosion probes to determ ine equipm ent reliability. N ew er sophisticated preventive m aintenance equipm ent requires highly trained personnel, but may require few er unit em ployee hours as dow ntim e is reduced. M aintenance craft consolidation also reduces unit labor require m ents. N ew testing m ethods are widely used; use depends on com plexity and age of equipm ent. 198 In process control, digital computers are applied to various refining processes ranging from crude dis tillation to on-line gasoline blending. Open-loop con trol is most common: data received from plant wide on-stream sensors are monitored and the operator is notified when machine changes are required. Howev er, closed-loop control is increasing in use in the newest installations. The trend is toward use of minsor microcomputers which, while linked to a central control center, control separate functions. Required adjustments in the production process are made au tomatically, thus eliminating some of the operator’s functions. Digital computer use is generally more common in large complex plants. Approximately one-fourth of American refineries use digital computers in various applications,1 but these plants constitute more than two-thirds of total U.S. capacity.12* With current trends towards the construction’ of larger, more complex plants, it is expected that practically all future refineries will incorporate one or more pro cess control digital computer systems. The use of very sophisticated instrumentation generally precedes or accompanies computer instal lation, and so the labor implications of the computer cannot be easily sorted out. In a refinery visited by the BLS staff, the computer monitored information from more than I,(XX) electronic instruments, such as chromatographs, mass spectrometers, and octane analyzers, that are located at the process unit and continuously measure product qualify. Their import ance lies in the speed with which problems can be corrected, and also in1 their tie-in to computer con trol. All U.S. refineries use analyzers, but the num ber and sophistication of the instruments vary with the size and complexity of the plant. The effect on employment is associated largely with the degree of sophistication of the refinery’s instrumentation. For example, fewer analyzer repair ers, operators, and lab technicians may be required where on-line monitoring is possible.3 In a modern plant, one technician may take the place of three or four technicians or operators in an older plant which still maintains sample testing and manual recording. On the otfier hand, jobs such as programmers and systems analysts increase with the installation of computers. A BLS study4 shows, however, that the number of some computer-related jobs in a plant may decrease after the initial phases of installation and programming are completed. 1International Petroleum Encyclopedia, 1977, pp. 443 - 44. 2 Ibid., op. 316 -2 0 . 1 “ Process Computers— They Do Pay Off in Refineries,” Oil and Gas Journal, Dec. 3, 1973, p. 62. 4 Computer Manpower Outlook, Bulletin 1826 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1974), pp. 36-37. With the installation of computer process control, changes are necessary in the operator’s duties. One example is clearly shown in a BLS survey of em ployment implications of computer process control.-5 The duties of an operator of a fluid catalytic crack ing unit before computer control were to manually adjust automatic analog controllers at the control console and to monitor automatic data logging equip ment. After installation, the computer controls and monitors a large part of the process and automatical ly logs the data, although the operator still performs manual control. In case of emergency, the operator can take control of any part or all of the process. improved eemiking Fluid catalytic cracking is a refining process that converts heavier oils into lighter, more valuable products such as gasoline, primarily by chemical reaction in the presence of a catalyst. The.--technique of riser cracking was developed concurrently with a new generation of highly active catalysts in the early 1960’s. Considered more efficient than older tech niques, this method presently is in use in over 40 percent of U.S. cracking capacity. Hydrocracking, an older, but greatly improved method of cracking, has several advantages over the conventional “ cat-cracker.” These include the capa bility to meet environmental specifications of low sulfur and nitrogen more efficiently and flexibility to handle variations in crude stock and in products de sired. Currently, however, hydrocracking accounts for only about 16 percent of cracking capacity, and the diffusion is expected to be slow, due primarily to the very high investment and energy usage required for this process. For both types of cracking, continually improved catalysts and regeneration methods enable more efficient processing of oils with high contents of sul fur and metals. To meet new product specifications and increased use of high-sulfur crudes, refineries with older cat-crackers may need to change over to the more efficient processing methods. Sn general, the effect on labor utilization of im proved cracking procedures in place of older crack ing methods is minimal. 0®sylfyrizati©n advances Hydroprocessing to reduce impurities, particularly sulfur, will become increasingly important as de mand increases for low-sulfur residual and distillate fuels. In addition, stricter environmental protection regulations and greater utilization of high-sulfur crudes due to dwindling supplies of sweet crudes 5 Outlook for Computer Process Control: Manpower Implica tions in Process Industries, Bulletin 1658 (Bureau of Labor Statis tics, 1970), p.29. 19® tane ratings over those possible with conventional catalysts. In addition, the process of continuous re forming eliminates periodic shutdowns because, un like other reforming methods, it continuously rege nerates the catalyst. To meet the low-lead requirements, refiners in creased their reforming capacity by roughly 19 per cent between 1972 and 1978. In that period, the use of bimetallic catalysts more than doubled, to over 60 percent<of total reforming capacity. At the start of 1978, continuous reforming accounted for 4 percent of total catalytic reforming capacity compared with about 69 percent for semi-regenerative reforming, and almost 27 percent for the older process of cyclic reforming.7 In addition to reforming, the processes of alkyla tion and isomerization provide increased octane rat ings in gasoline. Developed in' the early 1940’s to produce aviation fuels, these processes are not wide ly used now, representing only about 5 percent and 2 percent, respectively, of crude capacity (compared to 22 percent for reforming). However, they will become increasingly important as leaded gasoline is phased out. Although the phasedown of leaded gasoline may not be as severe for the large refineries capable of wide process adjustment, it will be particularly diffi cult for smaller, older refineries, geared primarily to producing leaded gasoline: Some of these smaller refineries may have problems associated with capital acquisition or procurement and construction of the needed equipment. In addition, more operators may be needed in refineries lacking process control sys tems. More maintenance labor may also be required by the small plant. In all cases, however, productivi ty would be adversely affected by the additional processes required to increase octane ratings. will lead to strong growth in desulfurization capaci ty. Desulfurization is an important factor in better enabling refineries to process sour crudes. For this purpose, sulfur removal may follow initial crude dis tillation. Desulfurization is also performed down stream to meet the stringent requirements of cataly tic reformers and to control pollutant emissions from the catalytic cracking process. Residual and heavy gas-oil desulfurization, the smallest but most rapidly growing segment of hydroprocessing capacity in the United States, is performed as the last step in the production of those fuels. New refineries are being designed to produce low-sulfur products from highsulfur crudes, and existing plants are revamping their process units when changes become necessary. Various hydrogen-based processes (hydrodesulfurization, hydrorefining, hydrotreating) are used for sulfur removal. All are based on chemical reactions between oil and hydrogen in the presence of a cata lyst. Advances involving separate demetallization processes and new high activity catalysts are reduc ing problems related to metals accumulation and need for frequent catalyst regeneration. However, the costs are still quite high. With some desulfuriza tion processes, off-site regeneration of catalysts by specialized companies is increasing as an economical solution to catalyst-related problems. The trend is clearly toward an increasing capabili ty of refineries to process sour crudes. Total hydro processing capacity increased 30 percent between 1975 and the start of 1978 and is expected- to in crease an additional 5 percent by 1980. Residual and heavy gas oil desulfurization capacity more than tri pled from 1975 to |978 6 Since additional processing is required for desul furization and demetallization, unit labor require ments for operations and maintenance personnel may increase. These increases may be temporary, however, as the processes become integrated into the overall operation of the refinery, Oetasie improvement Catalytic reforming, a process which. improves the octane rating of gasoline or fuels, is particularly important today in 'view of: the Federal Govern ment’s requirements for lower lead and lead-free gasoline. To increase yields of high-octane gasoline without lead, low-sulfur feedstock is necessary. The desulfurization of feedstock, discussed in the pre vious section, is therefore necessary. New bimetallic catalysts are making all reforming processes more efficient, increasing yields and oc-6 7lbid. 6 “ Federals Shape U.S. Refining Industry,” Oil and Gas Jour nal, Mar. 20, 1978, pp. 6 3 -6 6 . Energy co n serv atio n Because of the high costs of new refining technol ogies, particular emphasis is bei/ig placed on reduc ing costs through energy conservation—the more efficient utilization and generation of fuel and pow er. 8 Current technologies such as heat exchangers, furnace air preheaters, gas and hydraulic turbines, waste-heat steam generation, and thermal insulation are* now being improved. Minor process adjust ments, automatic instrumentation, increased mainte nance, and intensified surveillance of operations are also important in reducing refinery energy consump tion. The labor implications of energy conservation in the refinery are considerable. Some companies have 8 Oil and Gas Journal, Mar. 29, 1976, p. 74. zm set up energy systems departments whose managers closely control energy use. In addition to managerial and engineering skills, more employee hours of skilled craft and maintenance workers may he re quired for efficient energy utilization, particularly in the older refineries. There is no general agreement on the level of domestic demand for refinery products in 1985JO Many observers expect gasoline demand to peak out in the next few years, while demand for distillate and residual fuels is expected to increase as utility! and industrial users substitute fuel oil for natural gas. Imports Preventive msiomferaanc® Special emphasis is being placed on preventive maintenance, particularly the use of electronic in struments to locate defects in and measure the deter ioration of equipment before problems arise. Through the use of ultrasonics, X-rays, and electri cal corrosion probes, wear and corrosion in pipes and vessels can be measured on- or off-stream, sonic testers can detect high-frequency sounds generated by gas leaks from valves and fittings, and magnetic particle tests and infrared cameras can also pinpoint structural defects in some equipment. Preventive maintenance reduces downtime and maintenance costs, but the effect on labor is difficult to assess. Maintenance labor requirements vary with the complexity and age of the refinery, the sulfur in the crude, and the extent to which maintenance is subcontracted. Newer refineries may have less maintenance because modem materials, e.g., corro sion resistant, are more fully utilized. In general, however, important changes are occurring which are reducing unit labor requirements for maintenance personnel. These are discussed in the section on employment and occupational trends. Production add Pr®du<eiw% ©ytloolk Gytjpyt The steady growth in petroleum refining output since World War II was interrupted only by small declines in 1949 and 1958 and again in 1974 and 1975. Overall, from I960 to 1976, output rose at an average rate of 2.9 percent annually.9 The growth rate, however, was considerably more rapid in the strong economy of 1960-66 (3.2 percent) than in the 1966-67 period (2.4 percent). The latter period included the em bargo and the 1974-75 production cutback associated with the economic recession and energy conservation. But in 1976 and 1977, output jumped to peak levels, recording the most rapid annual rates of growth since 1955. Until the early 1960’s, the United States was ...selfsufficient in refined petroleum. Even in the first half of the 196Q’s, domestic refining capacity could sup ply more than nine-tenths of domestic demand; product imports consisted almost entirely of residual fuel. But in the 1965—73 period, demand for petro leum products expanded considerably more rapidly than capacity, and by January 1973 operable capaci ty could supply less than 80 percent of the demand. Thus, the gap between domestic demand and supply had been growing for years when the crude oil em bargo and price increases intensified the problem. Product imports rose to peak levels in 1973, averag ing 3 million barrels daily." Residual fuel was still the major refined product imported but other imports had also risen substantially. However, the demand/supply situation reversed itself following the crude oil embargo when concern rose sharply about our self-sufficiency. Capacity in creased as plants were expanded and new plants were built, while demand declined after three de cades of continuous growth. Consequently, the gap between refining capacity and demand greatly nar rowed, and our dependence on imported irefined products in 1975 dropped back to roughly that of the mid-1960’s. Although demand has been rising, capac ity increases continue to hold down the gap filled by product imports. In 1976, im ports of .refined prod ucts averaged 2 million barrels daily, It 1/2 percent of domestic demand, the lowest proportion since 1967. But crude distillation capacity alone is not a mea sure of tj\e industry’s capability to provide for domestic demand, even assuming available crude supplies. Residual fuel has been and continues to be our major import because,. (as discussed' earlier,, domestic refineries have not been interested in or geared to processing residuals. The problem is now complicated by government regulations which re quire Sow-suSfur residuals, sometimes necessitating changes in technology. Nevertheless econom ic in centives and the outlook for rising demand have re10 See P ro jectio n s o f E n erg y S u p p ly a n d D em a n d an d 'Their Im p a cts: A nn ual R e p o rt to C on gress. Vol. II, 1977 ( U.S. Department 9 P ro d u c tiv ity In d exes fo r S e le c te d In dustries, 1977 E dition Bulletin 1983 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1977). Output measure based on Bureau of Mines data. 201 of Energy, Energy Information Administration, 1977), ch. 6, pp. 127-53. ’ 11 Bureau of Mines data. Table 5. suited in more domestic processing of residual fuel— from 30 percent of domestic demand in 1973 to about 56 percent in 1977. Imports of residua! fuel hit a low of 1.2 million barrels a day in 1975 and have not increased greatly since then, in spite of a sizable increase in demand. The outlook for imports of refined products is not clear. Opinions differ as to domestic capacity growth and shifts in demand, aside from the avaiSa-, biJity. of crude supplies or, in. the longer, run, the possibility that oil-producing countries will move into refining. Average annual percent change1 Indicator 1960-75 1960-66 1966-75 Payroll per unit of value added .. -3.2 -6.3 -1.0 Capital expenditures per produc tion worker ............................. 13.4 9.1 10.7 1 Linear least squares trends method. SOURCE: Bureau of the Census. Productivity doff@r©pc©s Data on productivity differences among establish ments in an industry with a high degree of speciali zation may provide some insight into the faqtors associated with high productivity performance within the industry. In a study of 1967 Census d a ta ,14 pe troleum refineries w eres ranked by value added per production worker hour to provide a rough indica tion of the range of productivity differences. In this industry, average value added per production worker hour in the highest quartile was almost 11 times greater than in the lowest quartile. Wide productivity differences in the refining indus try may reflect differences in size, management, complexity (type of processing), labor, capital out lays,-etc., but the limited data preclude general con clusions. Nevertheless, the 1967 data suggest that size may be important (table 6). Establishments in the highest quartile had an average employment almost four times greater than those in the lowest quartile. This is verified by studies15 which show that labor productivity increases with capacity and with employment, up to a point. Small plants must maintain a minimum staff of operators and mainte nance and technical personnel to run the refinery; as capacity increases, the number of production work ers needed per thousand barrels of output declines sharply. But at some point, the advantages of size may be offset by duplication of process units. Productivity Productivity in refining rose sharply in the postWorld War SI period. From 1960 to 1977, output per employee hour in the refining industry increased at an average rate of 4.3 percent annually, compared with 2.6 percent in all manufacturing. 15 Productivity growth was considerably more rapid and’ steadier, however, from 1960 to 1967 (7.1 per cent) than from 1967 to 1977 (3.0 percent). Sn the last few years of the 1960’s, productivity growth leveled off at a relatively low rate. In 1972 and 1973, productivity rose very sharply; this was followed by a sizable decline in 1974. While the re covery since then has been moderate, productivity in 1977 was back to the high level of 1973. These errat ic productivity movements were associated with the embargo and the events that followed. There were erratic changes in refining output, discussed above, 'such as the unusually steep increases in output in 4973, 1976 and 1977, and the decline in 1974, the first since 1958. There were also unusual changes in employee hours. A roughly similar pattern of change in the industry since 1960 is evident in data on payroll per unit of value added, i.e., labor as a percent o f the value of shipments less materials and other costs. As shown in table 5, payroll per unit of value added fell at an average annual .rate of 3.2 percent from 1960 to 1975, compared with 1.1 percent for all manufactur ing, indicating a relatively greater increase in effi ciency. The stronger industry position in the first half of the period 1960 -6 6 is evident in the sharp decline in payroll/value added of almost 6 1/2 per cent annually. In contrast, the ratio showed only a minor change of about 1 percent'in the 1966-75 per iod, having registered sizable increases for several years.123 CapoteS expenditures Capital expenditures for refining plants increased 11.2 percent annually from 1960 to 1975 to a total of $2.2 billion—more than four and one-half times the outlay in 1960. The increase, however, was not even over those years. In the first half of the 1960’s, an nual outlays declined or remained relatively con stant; from 1965 to 1971 they rose extremely rapidly; 14 Based on unpublished data prepared by the Bureau of the Census for the National Center for Productivity and Quality of _ Working Life. 15 Studies by W .L. Nelson published in the Oil and Gas Jour nal. See “ Maintenance Material and Labor” , Jan. 13, 1975, pp. 5 7 -59. 12P rq jp ctio n s o f E n e rg y S u p p ly ar]d f b r r j ^ d , p. ,137^ 13 Productivity Indexes, 1977 Editioni plpl 7 5 -1 6 . Iradieatoirs of change in peSiroSeum refining, 1960-75 202 small refineries, 19 of these new plants had less than a 10,000-barrel daily capacity. Only one had a capac ity of more than 40,000 barrels. There is no general agreement on the outlook for capital expenditures for expansion. In addition to judgments on the need for additional capacity, capi tal outlays for expansion will be influenced by the increasingly heavy costs of new plant and equip ment. In general, however, there is agreement on the necessity to modify existing facilities to cope with changing demand and supply conditions. Even in this, there is a wide range of views relating to the future course of gasoline demand and likely develop ments in, coal gasification and liquefaction, In addi tion, future government environmental and energy policies will affect capital outlay decisions. Of great concern is the increase in environmental protection costs, which averaged 12 percent of the total petro leum industry’s outlay in 1975;18 data for the refining sector alone are not available. Table 6. Value added and employment in petroleum refin ing: Ratios of “highest quartile” to “lowest quartile” plants and to average plant, 1967 Measure Ratio of highest Ratio of highest quartile to lowest quartile to aver age quartile Value added per production worker hour.......................... 10.7 1.8 Average employment per establishment................................. 3.7 1.5 NOTE: Establishments Were ranked by the ratio of value added per production worker hour. SOURCE: Based on unpublished Census Bureau data prepared for the National Center for Productivity and Quality of Working Life. in 1972 and 1973 they declined; and in 1974 and 1975 they jumped very sharply. The average outlay in the I960—75 period was $917 million. These data, however, reflect costs unadjusted for changes in prices. Adjusting the dollar figures by the Nelson index of refinery construction costs16 reveals that real investment barely doubled from 1960 to 1975. From 1966 to 1975, real investment rose one and one-half times compared with three and one-half times for dollar outlays. However, increases in re finery costs were offset by the greater efficiency of plant and equipment. When adjusted for productivity changes by Nelson’s “ true cost” index, adjusted real capital outlays rose two and one-half times in those 9 years, and almost three and one-half times from 1960. Petroleum refining is highly and increasingly capi tal intensive. Labor costs were less than )3 percent of the value of the product in 1975 (compared with 48 percent in all manufacturing), having dropped sharply and steadily from 34 percent in, i960. As capital expenditures rose sharply and the number of production workers declined from 1960 to 1975, capi tal outlays per production worker rose almost seven fold1. After adjustment for price and productivity in crease, real outlays per production worker rose al most fivefold. These large capital expenditures resulted in addi tions to daily capacity of 3.2 million barrels, an in crease of 24 percent in the 5 years from January 1972 to January 1977. From January 1974 to January 1977, 28 “ grass roots’’ plants were built, accounting for slightly over 20 percent of the total.increase in operating capacity in those years.17 However, almost all of these were very small, of very simple design and limited flexibility. With incentives available to Employment and Occupational Trends Employment A bout 160,300 people were employed in the refining industry in 1977, the largest number since 1962. A decline starting in the late 1940’s continued unabated through the m id-1960’s, reflecting the very sharp in crease in productivity through m ost o f the period. After 1973, however, employment turned up again. In the first half of the 1960’s, the sizable employ ment decline was associated with a sharp reduction in the number of refineries and a productivity growth rate which was more than double the rate of growth of output, forom the mid-1960’s to 1973, employment was relatively stable, although it dipped to a low point of 145,(XX) in 1969. After 1973, however, sever al years of rising employment brought the level up to that of the early 1960’s. This change in the direction of employment reflected, in addition to technology changes which required more unit labor, an increase in the number of very small refineries. Overall, from 1960 to 1977, a relatively moderate annual average employment decline of 0.3 percent was registered. Refinery employment to 1985 /is projected to re sume its decline. Based on the economic assump tions stated in the introduction, the BLS projects a decline to 137,000 employees in 1985, or a drop of 1.9 percent annually from 1977 to 1985. These data reflect the technological, structural, and skill changes which have affected employment in 16 Nelson Index published in the Oil and Gas Journal. See issue of Jan. 26, 1976. *7 Trends in Refinery Capacity and Utilization (Federal Energy Administration),June 1976, pp. 4 and 7, and June 1977, p.i 14. 203 18 Data from the Bureau of the Census. might have had a ratio of 2 maintenance workers to 1 operator. Now, (excluding contract workers, the ratio of maintenance workers to operators in that refinery may be 1 to 2. the industry. A modern refinery today with an input of 100,OCX) barrels per day employs about 300-350 workers on three shifts. An older refinery with that capacity which has been modernized employs about 700 workers; that same plant would have employed almost 1,000 persons in the 1950’s. Occupations As discussed earlier, technological and structural changes are altering traditional concepts of job con tent and duties. More importantly, duties are being consolidated, as in the ca'se of maintenance crafts, or partially removed from the refinery, as in the case of contract maintenance. Maintenance craft consolidation is an important labor development of the last decade which increas es the flexibility of the work force while it reduces the number of workers required per processing unit. Under most maintenance consolidation plans, skilled workers who have attained journeyworker status in one craft are trained to handle other crafts (for ex ample, a boilermaker who learns pipefitting), thus eliminating the need for several workers, each with a specific craft duty. Such consolidation is becoming more widespread. Of 104 refineries studied by BLS in 1976, about one-fourth reported craft consolida tion plans, double the number reported in 1965.19 ln most plants, consolidation was limited to two desig nated crafts but in many plants consolidation incor porated all maintenance crafts. These skill combina tions fall into a single job classification, “ general mechanic.’’ A further development of this practice is the combination of operative and maintenance skills by one worker, who may be known as a “ running operator.” Two running operators can handle a pro cessing unit of 1(H),OCX)-barrel capacity, compared to three operators and a maintenance worker required in the average refinery of similar capacity. The trend to maintenance craft consolidation may in time contribute most importantly to revising job content and standard occupational patterns. By elim inating the lines of craft duties, craft consolidation practices generally establish new single job cla