View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago

Business
Conditions
1965

Fe b ru a ry

Contents
Banks, too, post collateral

2

Common Market policy expected
to restrict U. S. farm exports

6

Crosscurrents in savings deposit
flows— some recent evidence
W o rld sources and uses of gold

11
13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Banks, too, post collateral
M o s t people think of collateral as some­
thing that a bank requires a borrower to
furnish as security for a loan. Such collateral
may be in the form of a lien upon a physical
asset or it may be a financial asset such as a
Government or corporate bond, which itself
is an evidence of indebtedness. A bank will
accept as collateral, of course, only those
assets which it judges to be sufficiently sound
and liquid to provide protection against loss
in case the borrower should be unable to
repay his loan at maturity. Acceptable col­
lateral is typically something easily identified,
readily marketable and of fairly stable value.
A loan applicant possessing such high-grade
assets (and who otherwise meets minimum
standards of credit worthiness) normally has
little trouble getting credit accommodation.
Not so well understood is that banks
themselves must often post collateral against
certain of their liabilities. Just as individual
or business borrowers pledge houses, stock,
bonds, inventory, cattle or equipment as
security for bank loans, member banks must
pledge specific assets as collateral when they
find it necessary to obtain temporary accom­
modation from their Federal Reserve Banks.
There are two methods by which member
banks can obtain credit from their Federal
Reserve Banks. One is by endorsing and dis­

counting “eligible” paper at the Reserve
Bank. This was the method commonly used
in the early days of the Federal Reserve Sys­
tem, and it was this process which gave rise
to the term “discount window” and “discount
rate.” The statute provides that short-term
negotiable notes and drafts drawn for speci­
fied purposes related to the working capital
needs of commercial, agricultural or indus­
trial borrowers are eligible for discount. Such
paper constituted a large share of bank assets
in the early days of the System, and it was
contemplated in the Federal Reserve Act that
the provision for discounting this selfliquidating paper would automatically result
in the proper amount of money to accommo­
date the needs of business—in short, an elas­
tic currency.
The second method of extending Federal
Reserve credit to a member bank is through
advances on the member’s own note, secured
either by eligible paper (as described above)
or by U. S. Government securities. Such col­
lateral must be delivered and held in custody
accounts at the Reserve Bank; in practice,
Government securities are often already held
there for safekeeping.
In addition, at a premium of Vi of 1 per
cent above the discount rate, member banks
can borrow on any other asset judged to be

BUSINESS CONDITIONS is published monthly by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Dorothy M. Nichols was primarily
responsible for the article "Banks, Too, Post Collateral," Charlotte H. Scott for "Crosscurrents in Savings Deposit Flows—
Some Recent Evidence" and George G. Kaufman for "W orld Sources and Uses of Gold."
Subscriptions to Business Conditions are available to the public without charge. For information concerning bulk mail­
ings, address inquiries to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.

2

Articles may be reprinted provided source is credited.




Business Conditions, February 1965

sound by the Reserve Bank even if it does
not meet the requirements for eligible paper.1
For a good many years member banks
have borrowed from Federal Reserve Banks
mainly through advances secured by Gov­
ernment securities. This practice reflects the
great convenience of such securities for use
as collateral because of their unquestioned
credit rating, widespread availability and
variety of denominations.

Ba n k s' U. S. securities
have shrunk in relation
to collateralized liabilities
billion dollars

W h y b a n k s b o rro w

When a member bank borrows at the dis­
count window, it receives credit in its deposit
balance at the Reserve Bank. These deposits
serve as clearing balances and the legal re­
serves member banks are required to hold
against their deposits. While the growth and
variation in the aggregate volume of bank
reserves are governed mainly by Federal
Reserve System open market operations, the
distribution of these reserves is determined
by the forces of the marketplace. Deposits
of individual banks fluctuate widely from day
to day and week to week as a result of trans­
actions by the public and the Treasury and
even by System open market operations,
which have their initial impact on the cen­
tral money market. Individual banks are sub­
ject to frequent, substantial and often totally
unexpected deposit drains which, although
temporary, force them to take action to mainJA proposed amendment to the Federal Reserve
Act (S.2076, H.R.8505, 88th Congress) is designed
to change the provisions with respect to collateral
for member bank borrowings in recognition of the
changes that have occurred in banking practices
and the composition of bank assets. This amend­
ment would remove the present eligibility rules and
permit banks to borrow at the regular discount rate
on any assets satisfactory to the Federal Reserve
Banks, subject to such regulations as the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System might
prescribe.




ratio

tain their reserves at legally required levels.
A great deal of flexibility in adjusting to
these developments is provided by the sale
or maturity of liquid assets and, especially
for larger banks, the ability to borrow re­
serves for a day at a time from other banks
through the Federal funds market. Never­
theless, it is often appropriate for individual
banks to obtain needed funds at the discount
window to meet a temporary reserve defi­
ciency.
In many cases the need to borrow results
from the bank’s efforts to serve unusual credit
needs of its customers promptly and ade­
quately. Just as businesses need bank credit
to tide them over periods when their re-

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

sources are out of phase with their outlays,
so banks must sometimes borrow when the
loan demands of their customers are not per­
fectly coordinated with the growth in their
deposits or with adjustments that could rea­
sonably be expected to be made by dispos­
ing of liquid assets. The guiding principles
relating to access to the discount facilities
are stated in the foreword to Regulation A,
which sets forth the rules governing discounts
and advances by Federal Reserve Banks, as
follows:
Federal Reserve credit is generally ex­
tended on a short-term basis to a member
bank in order to enable it to adjust its asset
position when necessary because of develop­
ments such as a sudden withdrawal of de­
posits or seasonal requirements for credit
beyond those which can reasonably be met
by use of the bank’s own resources. Federal
Reserve credit is also available for longer
periods when necessary in order to assist
member banks in meeting unusual situations,
such as may result from national, regional or
local difficulties or from exceptional circum­
stances involving only particular member
banks.

This statement suggests the circumstances
under which borrowing by member banks is
considered appropriate. Outstanding borrow­
ings at any given time are relatively small—
rarely exceeding a billion dollars, or roughly
5 per cent of total member bank reserves—
and this is distributed among a constantly
changing group of borrowers. But while the
aggregates are small, for an individual bank
a particular situation may call for a large
amount of borrowing in relation to its re­
serves and, likewise, relatively large amounts
of collateral.

required are the laws providing that certain
assets must be pledged as security against
deposits of the U. S. Government—mainly
Treasury tax and loan accounts—in excess of
the amounts insured by the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation. Acceptable collateral
for deposits of public moneys under the Sec­
ond Liberty Bond Act, as amended, encom­
passes a wider range of assets than those
acceptable as security for borrowing at the
discount rate. Included are U. S. Government
securities, state and municipal issues, corpo­
rate securities, short-term commercial and
industrial paper and other designated obli­
gations with specific provisions as to the valu­
ation of these instruments for collateral pur­
poses.2 The law further provides that such
collateral must be held in custody at the
Federal Reserve Bank, or in a depository
designated by that Bank.
In addition, the laws of most states and
political subdivisions require the pledge of
specific assets of generally similar types
against their funds with custody usually in
the hands of a correspondent bank or another
legally designated agent. It might be noted
that while state and Federal laws require spe­
cific collateral against public moneys, banks
are generally prohibited from granting prior
claims on any segment of their assets to other
classes of depositors.
Governmental units are, for many banks,
important deposit customers. At mid-1964
total U. S. Treasury and state and local de­
posits in commercial banks throughout the
nation amounted to almost 32 billion dollars,
or more than 10 per cent of all commercial
bank deposits. Short-run variations in these
totals are wide, due mainly to the uneven

S e c u rity fo r “ public d e p o sits”

4

Of much greater importance from the
standpoint of the total amount of collateral




2See Treasury Department Circular No. 92
(Revised) for detailed description of acceptable
collateral and valuation requirements.

Business Conditions, February 1965

Loan to deposit ratio
of commercial banks reaches
level of early Thirties
per cent

*Loans excluding interbank loans; deposits net of cash
items in process of collection.

impact of Federal tax receipts and expendi­
ture patterns. For individual banks, more­
over, fluctuations in state and local balances
are also large. With the growing volume of
state and local deposits combined with the
steady uptrend in the ratio of loans to de­
posits (and the related decline in holdings of
Government securities), the margin of Gov­
ernments over collateral needs has shrunk
and individual banks occasionally find them­
selves faced with a severe “shortage” of Gov­
ernment securities which may be used as
collateral for borrowings. Such shortages
occur at times when a high level of public
deposits happens to coincide with reserve
drains due to adverse clearing on private bal­
ances or other temporary needs.
C u sto m er p a p e r a s c o lla te ra l

Such occasions have prompted a number
of banks to renew their acquaintance with



the use of other acceptable collateral in ob­
taining Reserve Bank credit and in securing
their public deposits as well. On the other
hand, despite the fact that the discount facili­
ties were set up for this specific purpose,
many banks appear to be hesitant either to
discount eligible customer paper or to offer
it as collateral for Federal Reserve advances,
perhaps in part because of uncertain cus­
tomer reactions. Since, for many years now,
the amount of U. S. Government securities
held by banks has been more than ample to
provide for collateral needs as well as shortrun liquidity, bank loan customers have be­
come accustomed to seeing no endorsements
on their matured notes.
Endorsement — once fairly common —
shows that the notes have been discounted
or used as collateral for borrowing by the
lender. Bank customers may again see such
endorsements on their notes with somewhat
greater regularity as banks more closely ap­
proach the loan ratios that were more com­
mon in the years prior to the depressed
period of the Thirties and the acquisition of
the huge portfolios of Governments during
World War II. This development would sim­
ply reflect a continuation of the postwar
trend for banks to use their resources less
for investment in liquid assets and more for
the accommodation of business and industry.
Given an appropriate reason for a member
bank to borrow, in principle it is of no conse­
quence what type of collateral is used in the
implementation of such borrowing. The rela­
tive convenience of alternatives is the de­
termining factor.
The banking system as a whole still ap­
pears to have ample holdings of Govern­
ments to meet its collateral requirements. At
the end of 1964 commercial banks held about
60 billion dollars of these securities—nearly
twice the total volume of public deposits and

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

borrowings from the Federal Reserve com­
bined. Part of this, however, represents se­
curities in trading positions of large banks
that have dealer departments. It has been
mainly at the large city institutions which
have been aggressive in serving their loan
customers over the past few years and whose
Government deposit and borrowing needs
fluctuate widely from day to day that the ade­
quacy of Government security collateral has
posed problems. Member banks in New York
and Chicago now have only one-third the
amount of Governments they held at the end
of World War II, while for all other com­
mercial banks Governments are still 75 per
cent of the 1945 level.
As indicated earlier, many types of securi­
ties, including state and approved municipal
obligations, are acceptable at specified valu­
ations as collateral for the deposits of most
governmental units, but eligible collateral for
borrowing at the discount rate is much more
limited. Substitution of other acceptable col­

lateral as security for public deposits would,
of course, free Governments not only for use
as security against borrowings but also for
other purposes—market transactions, liquid­
ity and generally greater flexibility in reserve
management. However, a limiting factor in
the use of some assets, particularly munici­
pals, is their unit size. Any paper denomi­
nated in small units is inconvenient for col­
lateral purposes due to both the physical
problems of transport and storage and the
necessity to examine each item to determine
its acceptability.
For the most part, banks will continue to
pledge U. S. Government securities as col­
lateral for both public deposits and borrow­
ings from Federal Reserve Banks. However,
some flexibility is required, and it seems
likely that the most practical and appropriate
alternative would be to resort to the well
established precedent but nearly forgotten
practice of using prime customer paper to
serve banks’ collateral needs.

Common M arket policy expected
to restrict U. S. farm exports

6

T h e tariff negotiations which began in
Geneva last May are providing a test of the
possible impact of the trade liberalizing
features of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962.
The purpose of this act was to achieve, if
possible, further worldwide reduction of man­
made barriers to the international exchange
of goods, including agricultural products.
The United States, with a large and per­




sistent deficit in its balance of international
payments and capacity to produce larger
quantities of agricultural commodities is
vitally interested in enlarging its foreign ship­
ments of farm products. In the year ended
June 1964, United States agricultural exports
exceeded 6 billion dollars. This nation is a
leading exporter of wheat, feed grains, soy­
beans, cotton, tobacco, lard and tallow.

Business Conditions, February 1965

U n ite d Sta te s exports to EEC—1963

Commodity

Total
United States
agricultural
exports

Feed grains
W heat and flour
Oilseeds and products
Animals and products
Cotton, excluding linters
Tobacco, unmanufactured
Fruits, vegetables and nuts
Others

794
1,330
827
709
576
403
449
496

TOTAL

5,584*

Exports
for
dollars
(million dollars)
720
359
719
551
420
367
447
371
3,954

United States
exports
to EEC

EEC as
per cent of
total

EEC as
per cent of
dollar sales

276
73
247
152
132
104
102
85

35
5
30
21
23
26
23
17

38
20
34
28
31
28
23
23

1,171

21

30

‘ Includes exports under Government programs of grants and sales for inconvertible currencies.

But agricultural protectionism is deeply
entrenched in the laws and tradition of many
countries, including the United States. With
governments deeply committed to farm aid
programs, negotiators face a difficult task in
moving toward freer trade in agricultural
commodities on a mutually acceptable basis.
The EEC

One of the more important developments
in the sphere of foreign trade in recent years
has been the formation of the European Eco­
nomic Community or Common Market.
While fostering freer trade within the area,
this group of countries has not moved aggres­
sively toward freer trade with countries out­
side the area.
The European Economic Community’s
Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), adopt­
ed by its six member countries in January
1962, constitutes a plan for the unification of
the six members’ agricultural sectors. In
essence, it calls for the achievement by the
end of the Sixties of a system of unified
“target” prices throughout the community for
every important agricultural commodity pro­




duced in the area—notably grains, livestock,
dairy products and poultry. Imports from
outside the community are to be subject to a
“variable levy” which will be the difference
between the target price and “the most fav­
orable buying terms on the external market.”
In other words, the variable levy is designed
to offset the difference between world prices
of commodities and desired price objectives
in the Common Market. This system could
promote a policy of protection and selfsufficiency in the Common Market countries.
With high internal prices and protection
against imports afforded by the variable lev­
ies, EEC farmers would have the incentive to
expand uneconomic production. EEC in­
ternal price levels, therefore, are the key to
the effects of the variable levies on trade with
outside countries.
R e ce n t m o ves b y th e EEC

Members of the European Economic
Community recently agreed on a common
price for grains, generally accepting basic
price levels previously proposed, and set July
1, 1967, as the date on which these common

7

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

8

prices are to be applied in all six member
countries. Adoption of the common grain
prices makes possible the future establish­
ment of common prices for many other farm
products as pork, poultry, eggs, dairy prod­
ucts, beef and veal.
While the adoption of the common grain
prices should facilitate current trade nego­
tiations, the agreed upon price levels indicate
that imports by Common Market countries
will be subjected to more restrictive levies if
production in those countries is substantially
stimulated. The target price for soft wheat
was set at $106.25 per metric ton or about
$2.89 per bushel—a compromise between
the community’s highest price of $118.90 per
ton in Germany and its lowest price in France
of $100.20. This is more than $1 per bushel
above the United States landed price in West
Germany.
Price levels for other grains were also set
considerably higher than the equivalent
United States delivered prices. The target
price for rye was placed at about $2.38 per
bushel compared with about $1.50 for Amer­
ican rye. In response to a request by Italy,
which imports a large part of its feed grain
supply, prices for barley and corn, $1.98 and
$2.30, respectively, were set lower than ori­
ginally proposed but are still well above the
United States delivered level. Furthermore,
the community adopted a system of subsidies
and levies, with compensatory payments to
be made to German, Italian and Luxembourg
farmers to offset farm income declines due
to the new target prices.
Under the arrangements, no amount of
price reduction, whether it reflects export
subsidization by foreign governments or nor­
mal developments in the world market, is
likely to assist foreign producers to penetrate
the EEC market. France is the community’s
largest grain producer and exporter. Many




U nite d Sta te s sha re
of world trade has grown

observers feel that the established grain price
levels, that are well above the present French
levels, will stimulate production in France
and in other low cost producing areas in the
Common Market countries.
During the five-year period from 1956
through 1960, domestic production in the
Common Market countries relative to total
domestic utilization averaged 89 per cent for
wheat and 75 per cent for feed grains. Al­
though weather conditions have held produc­
tion down in recent years, further strides by
EEC countries toward self-sufficiency will
probably be made.
Wheat imports to the EEC, while expected
to decline, may continue larger than might be
indicated by the output relative to utilization
in these countries. This would reflect the de­
mand for high-protein wheat (which cannot
be produced in significant quantities in EEC
countries) for blending with low-protein
locally produced wheat. Also, with rising em­
ployment and incomes in the European coun­
tries bringing increased consumption of live­
stock products, annual feed grain consump-

Business Conditions, February 1965

tion is expected to rise, possibly slowing the
expected decline in imported feed grain re­
quirements.
Nevertheless, it is expected that many
foreign products sold in competition with
domestic output will be displaced from West­
ern European markets. At the least, the
EEC’s system of variable import levies
against foreign products will tend to stimu­
late high-cost domestic production, thus po­
tentially displacing imports from traditional
outside suppliers in both developed and de­
veloping countries.
As the Common Market’s largest tradi­
tional supplier, the United States is espe­
cially interested in Western Europe’s policies
affecting agricultural imports. In 1963 coun­
tries in the EEC imported about 1.2 billion
dollars in agricultural products from the
United States— about one-fifth of all United
States farm exports. Furthermore, EEC
countries are by far the leading importers of
American agricultural products paid for in
dollars or convertible currencies.

EEC important United States
customer
Total United States exports
Country

1953

1963
(per cent)

C om m on M a rk e t (E E C )1

23

21

Ja p a n

13

12

9

11

10

7

In d ia

2

6

P a k ista n

3

3

U A R - Eg yp t1

1

3

39

37

Canada
United King dom

O th e r

’Includes countries comprising respective areas.




In o th e r co u n trie s a s w e ll

Common Market countries, however, are
not alone in fostering policies that result in
high-cost agriculture production internally
and the restriction of competition from for­
eign producers.
In nearly all countries the market for agri­
cultural products is influenced extensively by
government programs or those of govern­
ment-sponsored producers’ associations. Out­
put is conditioned or directed by financial
inducements and penalties, and marketing
processes are “controlled”—usually for the
purpose of boosting prices and income of the
agriculture sector.
The typical pattern of government support
of domestic agriculture comprises tariffs,
quantitative import restrictions (including
sanitation and disease controls), govern­
ment-guaranteed minimum prices, subsidies
(including subsidized credit), financial assist­
ance on favorable terms for making specified
farm improvements and control of market­
ing. A key element in such programs is the
import quota, which can be used to deny
access of imports unless it is evident that the
domestically produced supply of a commod­
ity will sell at the established price.
In some countries (for example, Switzer­
land and Norway), price support is provided
for virtually every important agricultural
product. By contrast, in the United Kingdom
the prices of most agricultural commodities
are allowed to fluctuate, but the producers
are guaranteed a specified price, and if the
average market price (greatly influenced by
imports) is below this level, farmers receive
a “deficiency payment.”
Achieving some specified level of prices is
more difficult for countries (like the United
States) with surplus output than for those
(like Germany) whose production is not suf-

9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

ficient to meet the domestic demand at
“normal” prices. The former, by one means
or another, often establish two prices for the
same product, a higher price for domestic
sales and a lower one for foreign sales.
Such conditions are often a source of in­
ternational friction. For example, sales of
wheat by the United States abroad at prices
below those in the domestic market may ap­
pear to non-American producers as “unfair
competition.” Anti-dumping laws provide for
the protection of United States producers
from similar actions by other countries.
Price supports, direct or indirect, are not
the only subsidies to agriculture. Other aids
often extended are designed to raise farm
output per worker, per unit of land area, or
both, in the expectation that increased output
per farm will make farming more profitable
or less dependent on price-support actions.
The benefits of such programs often flow
largely to consumers since total output tends
to rise and to depress prices, in turn com­
plicating the efforts to support prices and
boost sales abroad.
In addition to subsidies for research and
experimentation in agriculture and dissemi­
nation of the results to the agricultural popu­
lation, governments often make large invest­
ments in programs for land improvement and
control of pests and diseases affecting plants
and livestock. For example, in the Nether­
lands, where these expenditures are highest
in relation to both population and area of
cultivated land, investment in reclamation is
done largely at public expense.

ever-present danger of war with its potential
disruption of foreign supply lines. In addi­
tion, in nearly all countries, agricultural in­
terests have strong political leverage, and—
at least in the Western world— a view that a
rural way of life is favorable in contrast to
the rapidly growing urban populations with
their widely publicized restlessness, tension
and crime. It is likely, therefore, that agricul­
ture will continue to be regarded as a favored
sector of each economy and to be deeply en­
meshed in various governmental programs
designed to support the domestic industry.
The success of the Trade Expansion Act
and other efforts to move into the sphere of
unencumbered world trade will depend
largely upon the ability of governments to
rationalize the interests of domestic agricul­
ture with the availability of supplies from
outside sources and the alternative uses of
domestic labor and capital. The immediate
prospects for a substantial reduction in trade
restrictions and the achievement of freer in­
ternational trade in these commodities must
be viewed at best with limited optimism.

A nnual R e p o rt
The 1964 Annual Report of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago contains the Bank's financial
statements, brief reviews of last year's develop­
ments in business, agriculture and banking, and
an illustrated feature article "Steel Begins Its
Second Century." The study discusses historical
trends and future prospects of the steel indus­

Conclusion

Few governments leave the direction of
their agriculture entirely or even largely to
the market forces, in part because of the

10



try from the standpoint of technology, location,
markets and finance. Copies of the Annual Re­
port may be obtained by writing to the Bank.

Business Conditions, February 1965

Crosscurrents in savings deposit
flows— some recent evidence
^ ^h an g es in commercial bank savings de­
posits are, of course, the net result of amounts
added to and withdrawn from accounts. Since
inflows may respond differently than with­
drawals to changes in income, interest rates
and other factors, it sometimes is helpful in
evaluating savings trends to analyze these
measures separately as well as in terms of
their combined effect on balances.
Statistics on savings deposit inflow and
withdrawals are available for banks located
in urban areas of the Seventh Federal Reserve
District.1 As the accompanying chart indi­
cates, amounts added to savings accounts at
these banks generally have increased, as have
amounts withdrawn. These gains in gross
flows, like those in balances, mainly reflect
growth in population and personal incomes.
Savings deposits at the District banks have
increased at a faster rate during recent busi­
ness recessions than during the immediately
preceding years of rising economic activity.
In the recession year of 1958, for example,
savings deposits at District banks rose 5 per
cent, compared with a 4 per cent increase
during 1957 and 3 per cent in 1956. Growth
in savings deposits remained at 5 per cent
during 1959 but rose—to 7 per cent—during
the recession year of 1960.
The gains in the growth rate of savings
’Savings deposits refer to individuals’ combined
holdings of “passbook” savings accounts and time
certificates of deposit. Except as otherwise indi­
cated, data refer to commercial banks in 51 metro­
politan and smaller urban centers in the Seventh
District.




In te re st rate changes affect
growth of savings deposit
balances at District banks
per cent per annum

*
-

*

sovings deposit rate—
weighted average

yield on 3 month
treasury bills
1_____1_____ 1
_____ 1
__ 1 ___ 1
_____ 1_
_____ I_____ 1
1956 1957 1958 1959 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964
per cent change from previous month at annual rate

thousand dollars

#■ business recession

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

12

balances during the recession years were
mostly the result of slower growth or out­
right decreases in deposit withdrawals. In­
deed, inflow actually declined during 1958.
It rose during 1960 but at a slower pace than
in 1959.
Accelerated growth of savings deposits
during recession years, therefore, is explained
largely in terms of forces affecting with­
drawals rather than forces affecting inflows of
savings. Individuals may be reluctant to draw
down their balances for the purpose of sup­
porting current spending during business re­
cession. Also, the relative improvement in
the yield on savings deposits—since rates
paid to savings depositors tend to remain un­
changed while market rates of interest de­
cline—may reduce the incentive to move
funds from savings deposits into other assets
and thereby reduce withdrawals.
Savings deposit flows during periods of
business expansion have been greatly affected
at times by deposit interest rate increases; in­
deed, increases in payments to savings de­
positors characteristically occur during peri­
ods of business expansion. In the Seventh
District, rate increases were especially wide­
spread during the 1956 third quarter, 1957
first quarter, 1959 third quarter and 1962
first quarter. The proportion of District banks
posting higher rates was comparatively large
also in the first quarters of 1960 and 1964,
reflecting increases at Indiana banks immedi­
ately following revision in the state regula­
tion governing maximum rates. The effect of
higher interest rates on savings deposits is
both to boost inflow and to reduce with­
drawals.
The growth of savings deposits at the Dis­
trict’s banks accelerated during 1961 and has
remained at a higher rate during the current
upswing in activity than in earlier periods of
business expansion. This strong rise in sav­




ings deposit balances is largely attributable
to the rise of inflow. Growth in balances
picked up during both 1961 and 1962 as the
expansion of inflow more than offset the
growth in withdrawals. Savings inflow re-

To ta l tim e deposits and personal
savings component compared
annual rate of change

Note: The increased ownership of time deposits by
corporations since 1961 has made the series for savings
deposits and total time deposits of individuals and busi­
nesses more divergent in recent years than earlier.
The Seventh District series on savings deposits can be
taken as a proxy for national data, at least in a broad
sense, without substantial error. Comparisons of savings
deposits at District banks with total time deposits at all
commercial banks in the United States, excluding inter­
bank, U. S. Treasurer's open account and postal savings
deposits, reveals a rise each quarter in both series, except
in the first quarter of 1960 when time balances at all
commercial banks in the United States declined. The rate
of increase in both series was higher at the cyclical
trough of the first quarter of 1958 than during any of
the 1956 and 1957 quarters. A sharp upturn in growth
occurred in both series around mid-1960. Rates of growth
remained relatively high during the 1960-1961 recession.
Also the first quarter 1962 peak was identical in both
series.

Business Conditions, February 1965

mains at a relatively high level, in contrast
with its performance after the first stages of
the last two preceding business expansions of
1954-57 and 1958-60. Furthermore, with
some additional increases in interest rates on

savings deposits effective the beginning of the
year and prospects that personal income will
continue to rise, there is no indication that a
slowing of the current rise in savings balances
is imminent.

W o rld sources and uses of gold

U

ncertainties in international financial
conditions in the closing months of 1964,
stemming primarily from the pound sterling
crisis, probably prevented Western central
banks from achieving a record increase in
their gold holdings during the year. Official
gold holdings of international institutions and
Western central banks rose 705 million dol­
lars in the first nine months of 1964 com­
pared with 430 million in the same period in
1963 and only 325 million in all of 1962.
Purchases by official institutions account
for only a portion of total purchases of new
gold each year. The remainder is purchased
either for use in industry and the arts or by
private sources as a store of value and hedge
against devaluation of national currencies.
The distribution of gold among these pur­
chasers is dependent, in large measure, upon
changes in confidence in political and eco­
nomic conditions both at home and abroad.
Changes in official gold holdings tend to
move inversely with changes in private hold­
ings. When international tensions are low,
official gold holdings expand faster than pri­
vate holdings. When confidence is disturbed
by either the threat of war or serious deteri­
oration in a major country’s balance of pay­
ments, fear arises about the future value of
national currencies and private sources tend



to acquire the bulk of the new gold offered
for sale. (Although private citizens and busi­
ness firms in the United States and United
Kingdom may not own or purchase gold other
than for industrial, artistic and limited numis­
matic uses, residents of many other countries
may do so.)
The relation between changes in interna­
tional political and financial conditions and
changes in official and unofficial holdings of
gold may be seen from the table. At the end
of 1956, the concurrent Hungarian Revolt
and Suez crisis gave rise to fears of wider
international conflict. As a consequence, pri­
vate demand for gold to hoard rose sharply
at the expense of gains to official holdings.1
In 1960, concern over the size and dura­
tion of the balance of payments deficit, which
had existed every year since 1950, with the
single exception of 1957, suddenly became
widespread. Fears of a possible devaluation
of the dollar and other currencies were dra^hanges in private gold holdings are estimated
to be the residual change after increases in official
holdings and consumption by industry and the arts
are substracted from total new gold supplied. Newly
minted gold coins are included with private hold­
ings as these coins are typically not designed to,
and do not, circulate as media of exchange. Most
new coins are minted by a few countries to sell to
private holders at premium prices.

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

matically reflected in a sharp jump in the
price of gold on the free gold markets of the
world. The gold price on the important Lon­
don market rose abruptly from a few cents
above $35 per ounce—the usual selling price
—to about $40 per ounce. Although the
price quickly declined again to near $35, de­
mand from private sources remained high
and the amount of gold estimated to have
moved into private hoards during the year
rose over 700 million dollars. This was 60
per cent above the 1959 level and more than
twice the estimated additions to private hold­
ings in 1958.
Despite the Berlin crisis near the middle
of the year, firm notice of the United States
intentions to reduce its international pay­
ments deficit and maintain the official price
of gold at $35 an ounce dampened private
demands for gold in 1961. Private takings
declined nearly 20 per cent, while official gold

14

holdings rose 75 per cent more than in 1960.
During 1962 the abrupt decline in stock
prices early in the year, the Cuban missile
crisis later in the year and recurring doubts
of the United States ability and/or willing­
ness to take stronger actions to reduce its bal­
ance of payments deficit combined to give a
strong push to private demands for gold.
Additions to private holdings jumped more
than one-third, while central banks and in­
ternational institutions increased their hold­
ings only half as much as in 1961.
Reasonable world tranquility and a
marked improvement in the United States
balance of payments in the second half of
1963, following the introduction of such
stronger measures as an increase in the Fed­
eral Reserve Banks’ discount rate and presi­
dential recommendation of the interest equal­
ization tax, contributed to a slight decline in
the rate of expansion in private gold hoard­
ing and a sharp in­
crease in additions to
official holdings of
Record increase in official gold holdings in 1963
gold.
The estimated
Sources'
Uses'
smaller
addition to
Change in
Consump­
official
tion by
holdings of private
holdings2
Sales
industry
purchasers occurred
by
Produc­
United
and the
tion
USSR
W o rld
States
arts
Residual
even in the face of the
(million dollars)
record increase in gold
940
+680
1955
75
40
177
158
supplied from new
+485
454
1956
975
150
+ 305
186
production
and Rus­
+705
+ 799
222
1,015
260
1957
348
sian
sales.
The
latter
+680
283
1,050
220
-2,275
307
1958
were su b stan tially
1959
300
+750
-1,076
224
1,125
451
+345
1960
1,175
200
-1,703
316
714
greater than in any
+600
604
1961
1,215
300
- 857
311
other postwar year
+325
327
1962
1,290
200
- 890
838
and almost twice the
- 461
325b
1963“
1,350
550
+850
725b
amount in the previ­
'Gold valued at $35 per fine troy ounce. World estimates exclude USSR,
ous peak years, 1959
Other Eastern European Countries, China Mainland and North Korea.
2Holdings of central banks and international institutions.
and 1961. The jump
“ Preliminary.
bProjected.
in
sales could be at­
SOURCE: Annual Report of the Director of the Mint, Annual Report of the
tributed in large part
Bank for International Settlements and IMF, International Financial Statistics.
to the USSR’s need to




Business Conditions, February 1965

acquire United States dollars to help finance
heavy purchases of Canadian and American
grain during the year.

U .S. gold transactions with
foreign countries

The gold pool

In recent years, the central banks of eight
Western countries including the United
States have combined forces to stabilize the
price of gold on the London market. The
so-called “gold pool” sells gold as the price
rises and buys gold as the price declines. As a
result, since 1962 the price of gold has fluctu­
ated within a narrow range of $35.05 and
$35.19 an ounce compared with a consid­
erably wider range in earlier years.
Pool purchases and sales are apportioned
among the participating countries according
to an agreed upon formula.
United States acquisitions from the pool
are included in the figures on gold purchases
from the United Kingdom. In 1963, almost
all of the gold purchased from Britain repre­
sented distributions by the pool. It may be
estimated that the greater share of the pur­
chases in the first nine months of 1964 also
represented such gains. The remainder was
sold by the United Kingdom to help finance
the large deficit in its balance of payments.
Because of the spurt in foreign private
speculative demands for gold near the end of
1964, the United States gold stock declined
slightly for the year as a whole. At the end
of 1964, the gold stock totaled 15,471 mil­
lion dollars, down 125 million from year-end
1963. Although 1964 was the seventh con­
secutive year in which the gold stock de­
clined, the decrease was by far the smallest,
measuring only about one-quarter as large as
the decline in 1963—the previous year of
smallest loss. In two months—July and Au­
gust—the gold stock exceeded the levels of
both year-end 1963 and the same months a
year earlier for the first time since 1957.



Purchases
Country

1962

(+ )

and sales

(—)

1964*

1963
(million dollars)

United Kingdom -387

+ 329

+493

-456

-518

-304

-130

+200
2

France
Germany

-225

Italy
Spain

-146

Switzerland

+ 102

Latin America

+ 175
-121

All others
Total

-833

+ 32

30

-105

+ 33
- 56

-392

+ 109

’‘‘First nine months of year.

G o ld r e s e r v e re q u ire m e n ts

The decline of the official United States
gold stock and the steady rise in the amount
required as reserve against deposits of Fed­
eral Reserve Banks and Federal Reserve
notes in circulation has sharply reduced the
amount of gold not required as legal reserves.
About 13.5 billion dollars of the 15.5 bil­
lion dollar United States gold stock is cur­
rently required as legal reserves. The reserve
requirement is primarily a legacy of the days
when the United States and most major for­
eign countries were on a domestic gold stand­
ard in which currency and deposits could
both be converted into gold at the holder’s
request. In today’s “managed” money econ­
omy, the requirement has had no effective
influence over the amount of money.
Presidents Eisenhower, Kennedy and
Johnson along with Chairman Martin of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

System have all stated unequivocally that the
entire United States gold stock is available to
support the international value of the dollar
and to meet foreign obligations. Recently,
President Johnson has requested Congress to
eliminate the requirement against Federal
Reserve deposits while maintaining it against
currency. In 1945, the last time the stock of
gold threatened to drop below the amount
required for reserves, Congress reduced the
requirement to its present level of 25 per
cent.
South A fric a — a m ajo r p ro d u cer

Most of the new gold produced by the
Western world is mined in South Africa.
In 1963, 71 per cent of total production was
from that country. Canada accounted for 10
per cent and the United States for 4 per cent.
If all newly mined gold and Russian sales
had been channeled into official holdings,
such holdings would have increased some­
what more than 3 per cent annually. Since
1954, however, less than half of the new sup­
ply has been added to official holdings. Al­
most as much has been acquired by private
holders, while 20 per cent was consumed by
industry and the arts. Official holdings have
risen only 1.5 per cent annually.
U nited S ta te s still la rg e s t h o ld e r

16

Although the United States has experi­
enced substantial gold losses since 1950, it
remains the single largest holder of gold. At
the end of 1949 this country’s official gold
stock was at a peak of 24.6 billion dollars,
an amount equal to 70 per cent of the esti­
mated total holdings in the Western world.
By the end of 1963, the gold stock had de­
clined more than a third to 15.6 billion dol­
lars and its share of the world’s stock dropped
nearly half to 37 per cent. However, this
amount still was almost equal to the com-




O ffic ia l gold holdings
of major countries
December 31,
1953

United States
W est Germany
France
Switzerland
United Kingdom
Italy

World total*

December 31,
1963

Billion
dollars

Per
cent
of
total

22.1
0.3
0.6
1.5
2.3
0.3

61
1
2
4
6
1

15.6
3.8
3.2
2.8
2.5
2.3

37
9
8
7
6
5

36.3

100

42.3

100

Billion
dollars

Per
cent
of
total

*lncludes international organizations but excludes SinoSoviet Bloc countries.

bined official gold holdings of the next five
largest holders and four times as great as the
amount held by West Germany, the second
largest holder.
Gold has played an important role in the
economic history of the world. While very
largely supplanted by national currencies
domestically, and to a considerable extent
internationally, gold still holds a significant
role in the international economy. Recent
events indicate that changes in the private
demand for gold continue to reflect, at least
in part, changes in world tensions and confi­
dence in national currencies. Apparently
many individuals, and official institutions as
well, feel more secure holding the non­
interest bearing yellow metal than any other
kind of asset, gilt edged though it may be.
This situation can be expected to change
only as the various countries demonstrate
further ability to maintain stable domestic
prices and international convertibility of
their “unit of exchange.”