View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

	 THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
	 OF CHICAGO

	 MARCH 2013
	 NUMBER 308a

Chicag­ Fed Letter
o
Are local property tax breaks for businesses and
nonprofits broken?
by Richard H. Mattoon, senior economist and economic advisor

On November 30, 2012, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Metropolis Strategies, and the
Civic Federation held a workshop to explore the role of property tax incentives in supporting
business growth, as well as the tax treatment of properties owned by nonprofits.

Local governments increasingly find

Some materials presented
at the workshop are available
at www.chicagofed.org/
webpages/events/2012/
property_tax.cfm.

themselves caught in a vise. On the one
hand, they want to stimulate economic
development by attracting (and retaining)
businesses, often through the use of property tax incentives. On the other hand,
they grow concerned about the erosion
of their tax base as the number of property tax incentives for businesses—as well
as the amount of properties owned by
tax-exempt nonprofits—increases. Government officials, business owners, nonprofit leaders, and researchers gathered
at the workshop to discuss these and
related issues affecting local economic
growth and tax revenues.
Role of business property tax incentives

Daphne Kenyon, Lincoln Institute of
Land Policy, presented her recent report
on property tax incentives offered by
state and local governments to entice
businesses to move to (or stay in) their
jurisdictions.1 Kenyon noted the continued growth in the use of three major
types of incentives: 1) tax abatements,
which offer a full or partial reduction in
property tax liability for industrial and
commercial real estate over a temporary
period (most commonly, a decade); 2) tax
increment financing, or TIF, which involves earmarking future property tax
revenue gains to subsidize current improvements (often in designated blighted
geographic areas); and 3) enterprise
zones, which are designated economically

depressed areas in which tax and regulatory relief is offered to entrepreneurs
and investors to encourage business
development. In 2010, 37 states allowed
tax abatements, 49 permitted TIF programs, and 42 authorized enterprise
zones.2 Kenyon questioned the effectiveness of these incentives in developing
business activity, noting that property
taxes tend to account for a very small
share of the total costs for most businesses. On average, property taxes equal
0.3% of total costs (for a manufacturer),
whereas labor costs equal 21.8%.3 That
said, property tax incentives can be an
effective means to draw businesses into
specific parts of a metropolitan area.
By altering the relative costs of running
a business within a metro region, these
incentives can influence business location. Kenyon explained, however, that
copycat behavior by neighboring states
and jurisdictions often reduces the effectiveness of offering incentives to induce
business investment.
According to Kenyon, the use of these
incentives lacks transparency and independent evaluation. While 44 states produce tax expenditure reports, only 18
include property taxes—with merely
eight estimating forgone local property
tax revenues due to incentives.4 To highlight the importance of independent
evaluation, Kenyon cited two reviews of
Minnesota’s Job Opportunity Building

Zone (JOBZ) program. The state agency’s
report stated that about 5,500 jobs had
been created by the JOBZ initiative; in
contrast, an independent evaluation later
found that the number was closer to
1,000, at a cost that was about five times
greater than the agency’s estimate.
Given such concerns, Kenyon recommended alternative strategies, local policy
reforms, and state policy reforms. Her
favored alternatives involved several nontax policies, such as job training customized to individual firms’ specifications,

potential economic benefits. And finally,
they should use incentives in cooperation with other local governments to
prevent inefficient bidding wars for
business investment.
Kenyon argued that state-level policy
should limit the number of local governments permitted to use property tax incentives for businesses and restrict the
use of such incentives to communities
with the greatest need. Additionally,
Kenyon contended states should require
these tax incentives be approved by all

Because local tax bases remain stressed, property tax incentives
for businesses and the tax treatment of nonprofits’ properties
will remain prominent in public policy discussions.
labor market intermediaries (programs
that help workers match with firms), and
regulatory assistance (to help resolve
problems with state or federal agencies).
Kenyon’s other nontax policies included
business incubators for start-ups and
business improvement districts, where
property owners agree to pay for expanded public services, such as more
police patrols and street cleaning, which
may raise property values.
For local governments, Kenyon suggested
five policy reforms. First, local governments should set explicit criteria for
granting incentives that account for not
only the probability of the firms locating
elsewhere with or without the incentives,
but also the impact that successfully
drawing the firms to their jurisdictions
will have on local fiscal health. Second,
they should limit incentives to firms that
export goods and services out of the
region, since such firms create greater
economic value for local areas than nonexporting firms (like retailers). Third,
they should limit the number or the total
dollar value of incentives, treating them
more like direct expenditures subject
to annual appropriations, which would
make granting incentives more selective.
Fourth, they should use an open process
for deciding on incentives, involving not
only politicians and economic development officials but also tax administrators
and taxpayer groups, to better ensure
forgone tax revenues do not outweigh

affected governments (e.g., those of the
municipality, county, school district, and
special-purpose district)—and not by just
the government offering the incentives.
In line with Kenyon’s analysis, Richard
Dye, Institute of Government & Public
Affairs at the University of Illinois, said
that a key problem with property tax
incentives is the inability of governments
(and independent third parties) to measure their effectiveness because of a lack
of sharply defined goals. Dye suggested
that as a starting point, each community
should establish what it has to offer to
businesses and what it wants from
business development.
Dye explained that TIF strategies often
produce hidden debt, taxes, and governance. For example, while the incremental property tax revenues produced by a
TIF program should be used for economic development, they also can be
shifted to other budgetary needs. In addition, TIF and other incentives can provide
public aid to economic development that
would have occurred anyway. Dye argued
for more rigorous analysis to ensure that
incentives are only granted in cases where
business investments would not have
otherwise occurred. Finally, Dye warned
of “incentive creep,” i.e., firms expecting
or demanding tax incentives beyond the
initial property tax incentive granted.
William Stafford, who serves as chief
financial officer of the Evanston Township

High School District 202 in Illinois,
agreed that the tools for evaluating the
effectiveness of providing business property tax incentives could be better, and
argued that state governments are the
most appropriate parties to improve these
tools. As Stafford pointed out, some
communities lack the financial tools to
do sophisticated pro forma analysis, particularly if strategies affecting multiple
taxes are involved. In addition, some local
governments lack the capabilities to do
credit and risk analyses and to structure
“clawback” provisions if economic development targets are not met by the
businesses granted incentives.
Moreover, Stafford countered many traditional notions about the use of property tax incentives to draw businesses.
First, in response to the negative views
on TIF, he highlighted Evanston, where
four TIF developments were used. All
four led to significant incremental increases in tax revenues; and the ones
that matured came back on the general
tax rolls, providing significant new revenues to the school district and other
governments. Second, he questioned
whether policy should restrict the use
of such incentives to low-income communities. He contended that developers
require a vibrant market before making
investments and that business property
tax incentives will often not be large
enough to generate investments in communities lacking good market conditions.
Similarly, he questioned the wisdom of
limiting these incentives to only manufacturing and other export firms, since
retailers make up such a large segment
of the business base of most communities. Finally, Stafford pointed out that
most communities in Illinois are classified
by state law as non-home-rule, meaning
that their municipal legislative authority,
including their ability to adopt local taxes,
is limited by the state. Given such limitations, Stafford said he is against states
placing restrictions on non-home-rule
communities’ use of property tax incentives for businesses, since doing so hinders their ability to manage their own
economic development.
Thomas Cafcas, Good Jobs First, noted
some recurring problems in using property tax incentives to spur economic

development. For instance, many local
development strategies are not well targeted because localities often favor large
firms; indeed, small firms usually lack the
economic clout to get business property
tax incentives, although their business
investment could also help local economic
development. Additionally, the provision
of tax incentives frequently amounts to
a zero-sum game, where jobs and economic activity are simply reallocated
from one location to another without
creating new value. Finally, Cafcas also
pointed out the lack of fiscal transparency and systematic evaluation of outcomes from offering such incentives.
Cafcas suggested several remedies to
these problems. First, he endorsed collaboration among communities in these
matters. For example, early warning systems should be created to alert communities in proximity of one another about
firms possibly relocating; such systems
would also allow communities to focus
on retaining current businesses. Second,
he encouraged greater online disclosure
of incentive awards and outcomes. Good
Jobs First has created a database tracking
the use of incentives, but Cafcas argued
that broad disclosures by local governments and firms themselves would benefit everyone. More specifically, when
incentives are given, local governments
and firms should report the resulting job
creation, including information on wages
and benefits of new employees (relative
to the market) and the ability for jobs to
be maintained over the subsidy period
(and beyond).  All the disclosed results
should be verified independently. Finally,
Cafcas said that the cost of incentives
should be printed on local property tax
bills and that neighboring jurisdictions
should work toward producing a unified economic development budget
to avoid bidding wars and eliminate
redundant efforts.
Tax treatment of nonprofits’ properties

Kenyon presented her other recent research, which analyzes payments in lieu
of taxes (PILOTs) voluntarily made by
tax-exempt private nonprofit organizations.5 This research surveys the wide
range of tax-exempt nonprofits, including
universities and hospitals, that make

PILOTs to their local governments and
describes the terms under which the contributions are negotiated. Kenyon noted
that interest in PILOTs has become heightened since the early 1990s on account of
growing revenue pressures on municipalities (particularly those with significant amounts of tax-exempt properties
within their borders) and increasing
scrutiny of the nonprofit sector. In addition, Governing magazine reports
that compared with five years earlier, the
assessed value of tax-exempt properties
makes up a higher share of the assessed
value of all taxable and tax-exempt
properties combined (for either 2011
or 2012) in 16 of the 20 most populous
U.S. cities with available data; however,
this share’s variation from city to city is
quite large today.6

•	 PILOTs are often ad hoc, secretive,
and contentious.

Among nonprofits making PILOTs,
higher education and health care organizations lead the pack, Kenyon said;
combined, these two types of organizations account for 46% of all nonprofits
making PILOTs. Additionally, the postsecondary education and health care
sectors account for 92% of all PILOT
revenues—with universities and colleges
alone contributing over two-thirds of
all such revenues. That said, Kenyon
stressed that PILOT revenues typically
form a very small share of the general
revenues of localities collecting them.
Of the ten communities receiving the
most PILOT revenues in recent years,
seven of them received nearly 1% or less
of their general revenues from PILOTs.7

Michael Pagano, University of Illinois at
Chicago, said that PILOTs are an important policy option for local governments with a high reliance on property
taxes. However, he noted that some
municipalities have access to sales and
income taxes, which may offset or obviate
the need to use PILOTs or raise property
taxes. Like Kenyon, Pagano suggested
levying fees from nonprofits for services
like water. In addition, Pagano promoted

Kenyon presented arguments both in
favor and against PILOTs. In support
of PILOTs, some might argue that nonprofits should pay for the public services
they consume. Indeed, some say that
PILOTs help address the imprecise nature of a nonprofit subsidy, i.e., when its
value is not directly related to the fiscal
impact that the nonprofit places on the
municipality. The arguments against
PILOTs include the following:
•	 PILOTs might lead nonprofits to
raise fees or cut services.
•	 Given that PILOTs are often negotiated, they can be a limited and unreliable revenue source.

•	 Inequities may arise when similar institutions negotiate different PILOTs.
In conclusion, Kenyon offered three
alternatives to PILOTs for communities
interested in raising revenues from
nonprofits—namely, user fees, special
assessments, and municipal service fees.
User fees are fees that may be charged
to nonprofits for services such as water,
sewer, and garbage collection. Special
assessments may be appropriate in cases
where the government provided improvements to a specific area in which the
nonprofit is located. Finally, municipal
service fees may be collected from nonprofits to fund a public good, such as
street maintenance.

Charles L. Evans, President  Daniel G. Sullivan,
;
Executive Vice President and Director of Research;
Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic
Advisor ; David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial
markets group  Daniel Aaronson, Vice President,
;
microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Richard
Heckinger,Vice President, markets team; Anna L.
Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A. Testa,
Vice President, regional programs, and Economics Editor ;
Helen O’D. Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors  ;
Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors 
;
Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2013 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

four practices for revenue-strapped
municipalities, especially those with a
large share of nonprofit properties:
•	 Use audits to ensure that nonprofits
are in compliance with their 501(c)(3)
tax-exempt, charitable status.
•	 Reconfigure fiscal systems so that users
(including nonprofits) of city services
pay for them commensurately.
•	 Redesign fiscal systems to be less reliant
on property taxes and more reliant on
earnings, income, and payroll taxes.
•	 Consider innovative alternative fees
or taxes—such as a university tuition
tax, which reflects the costs associated
with hosting a large (mostly transient)
student population.
Sarah Wetmore, Civic Federation, presented a case study of the tax treatment
of a nonprofit hospital in Urbana,
Illinois—namely, Provena Covenant
Medical Center—which failed to meet
the standard for charitable (free and
discounted) care according to the
Champaign County Board of Review and
the Illinois Department of Revenue. The
hospital disputed their assessment; however, the Illinois Supreme Court eventually ruled against the hospital in 2010
after a series of hearings in lower courts.8
This particular ruling prompted the revenue department to revoke tax-exempt
status for three other hospitals in 2011. In
response, the Civic Federation launched
a task force to clarify standards for hospitals to gain and retain tax-exempt status.
Based on the task force’s analysis, the
Civic Federation first recommended that
the Illinois General Assembly establish
a clear quantitative threshold of public
1	 Daphne A. Kenyon, Adam H. Langley,

and Bethany P. Paquin, 2012, Rethinking
Property Tax Incentives for Business, Cambridge,
MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy,
available at https://www.lincolninst.edu/
pubs/dl/2024_1423_Rethinking%20
Property%20Tax%20Incentives%20for
%20Business.pdf.

2	 Ibid., p. 5.
3	 Ibid., pp. 23  24.
–
	 Ibid., p. 46.

4

benefits that a hospital must provide in
order to get a property tax exemption,
said Wetmore. This threshold should be
equal to the estimated tax bill for the hospital property (based on the local property tax rate and the property’s assessed
value) had it not received a tax exemption. Given this standard, the administrators of a hospital would know how
much charitable care the hospital would
need to deliver annually in order to
qualify for tax exemption. The Civic
Federation also recommended that the
Illinois General Assembly consider certain additional expenditures made by a
hospital beyond the value of charitable
care when determining which types of
activities and expenditures should count
toward the quantitative threshold. Specifically, the federation advised the following
items be counted: unreimbursed expenses for Medicaid and other similar
programs, unreimbursed Medicare expenses, and a portion of bad debt (from
patients who did not disclose their inability to pay when admitted but who
would have otherwise qualified for
charitable care). These expenses are
often incurred when a hospital serves
low-income and uninsured patients; however, by legal definition, such expenses
do not count as charitable care.9
Providing an economist’s perspective,
Woods Bowman, DePaul University, explained that economic theory offers three
primary positions regarding the tax
treatment of nonprofit properties:
•	 Every property owner, including
governments and nonprofits, should
pay property taxes, since they all
benefit from government services.

	 Adam H. Langley, Daphne A. Kenyon, and

5

Patricia C. Bailin, 2012, “Payments in lieu
of taxes by nonprofits: Which nonprofits
make PILOTs and which localities receive
them,” Lincoln Institute of Land Policy,
working paper, No. WP12AL1, available at
https://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/
2143_1469_Langley_WP12AL1.pdf; and
Daphne A. Kenyon and Adam H. Langley,
2010, Payments in Lieu of Taxes: Balancing
Municipal and Nonprofit Interests, Cambridge,
MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy,
available at https://www.lincolninst.edu/
pubs/dl/1853_1174_PILOTs%20PFR%
20final.pdf.

•	 All (not just some) nonprofits should
be exempt from the property tax.
Also, given that nonprofits are incorporated by the state, the state
should pay localities for the lost property tax revenues if an exemption is
granted by the state.
•	 If the first two positions are politically
unacceptable, then recognize that
consumer surplus from property
taxes gets capitalized into property
values. If this is correct, old property
tax exemptions have little or no economic effects on current taxpayers,
since their effects have already been
fully capitalized. The issue then becomes the treatment of new property
tax exemptions, and concerns about
such exemptions can be neutralized
by one-time “impact fees” levied on
the nonprofits.
As a possible alternative to PILOTs,
Bowman discussed the “quid pro quo”
property tax treatment of nonprofits, or
“services in lieu of taxes.” Under this type
of property tax treatment, nonprofits must
provide charitable services whose value
matches that of the property tax exemption, but only the charitable services
provided to local residents would count.
Conclusion

Because local tax bases remain stressed,
property tax incentives for businesses
and the tax treatment of nonprofits’
properties will remain prominent in
public policy discussions. Communities
need to understand the potential impacts
of both issues on economic development,
as well as on the collection of tax revenues to provide public services.

6	

Mike Maciag, 2012, “Tax-exempt properties
rise as cities cope with shrinking tax bases,”
Governing, November, available at www.
governing.com/topics/finance/gov-taxexempt-properties-rise.html.

	 Langley, Kenyon, and Bailin (2012, p. 5).

7

	 For details, see www.state.il.us/court/

8

Opinions/SupremeCourt/2010/March/
107328.pdf.

9	

For more details, see www.civicfed.org/
civic-federation/publications/positionstatement-charitable-property-tax-exemptions.