View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

JULY 2009
NUMBER 264a

Chicago Fed Letter
Risks and Resolutions: The ‘Day After’ for Financial Institutions—
A conference summary
by Carl R. Tannenbaum, vice president, Supervision and Regulation, and Steven VanBever, lead supervision analyst, Supervision
and Regulation

The Chicago Fed’s Supervision and Regulation Department, in conjunction with DePaul
University’s Center for Financial Services, sponsored its second annual Financial Institutions
Risk Management Conference on April 14–15, 2009. The conference focused on risk
management, headline issues, and recent financial innovations.

This year’s risk conference focused on
how the rapidly shifting financial and
economic environment is changing the
way risk is being managed. This Chicago
Fed Letter provides a summary of the relevant research presented and discussions
held by the bankers, supervisors, and
academics in attendance.

Materials presented at the
conference are available at
www.chicagofed.org/news_
and_conferences/conferences_
and_events/2009_sr_risk_
regulation.cfm.

Opening the conference, Ali Fatemi,
DePaul University, described how rapid
growth in the U.S. financial sector in
recent decades led to deregulation, increased leverage,1 and overconfidence
in the industry’s ability to manage risks.
As we enter a new period of stricter regulation, he said, there is concern that the
best and brightest workers will depart
the industry in significant numbers.
Carl R. Tannenbaum, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, noted that the U.S.
financial landscape has changed dramatically in just the past six months.
The U.S. Department of the Treasury
and the Federal Reserve have been
exceptionally active over this period.
He said that we will be identifying and
debating the lessons learned for years
to come. These include lessons about the
assumptions and applications of financial risk-management models, as well as
lessons about linkages between credit
risk and liquidity risk.

Amplifying Tannenbaum’s assessment,
Charles L. Evans, president and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, outlined how an abrupt swing from extreme
risk tolerance to extreme risk aversion
had brought the financial system to its
current state. Financial stress is also taking a toll on the “real” economy during
this business cycle; i.e., the turmoil on
Wall Street is affecting what’s happening on Main Street. This has not always
been the case historically. Gross domestic product continues to contract, and
unemployment is likely to continue to
rise until 2010.
Evans predicted that a number of reforms
could figure into the resolution of this
crisis. These include identifying systemically important institutions, rethinking
how to price the safety net, and requiring
higher capital—whether “exogenously”
through higher regulatory minimums
for capital balances or “endogenously”
through putting debt holders at risk
and exerting market discipline.
CEO and chief risk officer perspectives

William Downe, CEO, Bank of Montreal
(BMO), argued that BMO has benefited
from the diversity of its businesses, the
strength of its risk infrastructure, the
sound judgment of its staff, and its conservative risk culture (especially regarding

credit risk). BMO’s most important lessons learned concerned liquidity and interdependencies among products and
markets, especially the vulnerabilities
of asset securitization.
Under BMO’s risk-management program, business lines own the risks, but
additional lines of defense are provided
by the corporate risk-management and
audit functions. BMO has historically
had strong risk functions for individual risks, but has been working recently
to strengthen communication across
these functions.

and bottom-up framework, in which both
the “tone from the top” and “escalation
from staff and officers” are critical to
success. The board has shown its support
by establishing a dedicated board-level
ERM committee.
The “biggest shocks” of the financial crisis
cited by these panelists were the speed at
which liquidity problems grew, the rapid
decline in collateral values supporting
loans, and the abrupt change in the public’s perception of bankers (from positive
to negative). Their most difficult decisions
were recognizing higher nonperforming

To reduce systemic risk, policymakers are taking a hard look
at “too-big-to-fail” and other regulatory policies, including
capital requirements.
Richard Cahill, Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, moderated a panel of three
chief risk officers: Joyce M. St. Clair,
Northern Trust Corporation; Dominic
Monastiere, Chemical Bank; and Kevin
Van Solkema, The Private Bank. The panelists discussed their organizations’ riskmanagement structure and how they are
responding to the global financial crisis.
St. Clair said that at Northern Trust,
risk policies, tolerances, and reporting
flow through an extensive committee
structure at the business-line and executive levels to the board of directors. In
the current economic and political climate, the bank has institutionalized and
globalized its incident management
process, is focusing more on emerging
risks, and is paying more attention to
scenario analysis and stress testing to
determine capital adequacy.
According to Monastiere, Chemical Bank
has a decentralized service delivery
system and a local decision-making structure but also centralized procedures,
operations, and controls. Monastiere’s
responsibilities include 15 major functions covering the full range of financial
and compliance risks.
Van Solkema explained that The Private
Bank began to implement enterprise risk
management (ERM) relatively recently,
in the summer of 2008. Consequently,
ERM has rapidly evolved into a top-down

loans and charge-offs, developing action
plans for problem loans, and changing
business strategies for reputational reasons.
Supervisory lessons learned

Tannenbaum also led a panel on the
lessons learned thus far through the
bank supervision process. It featured
Jon D. Greenlee, Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System; Kathryn
Dick, Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency (OCC); and Mark J. Flannery,
University of Florida.
Greenlee reviewed indexes of stress in
financial markets, as well as those of deleveraging (i.e., reducing leverage, whether at the level of the individual, the firm,
or the financial system). The “originateto-distribute” model, where the originator of a loan sells it to various third
parties, has largely been abandoned for
the present. It may involve simpler structures once it returns. In addition, given
the complexity of the financial system,
and the nature of the “shadow” banking
system (comprising nonbank financial
institutions, which are less regulated than
banks), risks originated in unforeseen
places and were transformed in unforeseen ways. Finally, Greenlee noted that
incentives play a critical role in both
risk-taking and risk management.
Dick recounted key lessons learned at
the OCC. They are as follows:

• Underwriting standards matter;
• Risk concentrations accumulate and
need to be controlled;
• Asset-based liquidity matters;
• Systemically important firms need
“state-of-the-art” infrastructure; and
• Capital issues (including quantity,
quality, planning, and procyclicality
issues2) are paramount.
She also covered an array of risk-management topics being explored by the
OCC, including greater transparency of
disclosures and the need to address
excessive complexity of both structured
products and organizational structures.
Flannery emphasized the impediments
to risk management and risk supervision.
Risk assessments differ across observers
at any point in time. In addition, risk
managers must identify outcomes that
are unlikely to happen; therefore, they
are wrong much more often than they
are right. Expanding on Greenlee’s
earlier point about incentives, Flannery
said that power within a firm flows to
those who are making money; i.e., it goes
to risk takers rather than risk managers.
Supervisors face all these challenges, plus
political pressure if they try to limit
currently profitable activities.
The too-big-to-fail problem

Gary H. Stern, president and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
concentrated on the too-big-to-fail (TBTF)
problem3 in his remarks. He indicated
that the current financial crisis has reaffirmed four lessons learned from earlier crises: 1) the need to put uninsured
creditors of TBTF firms at risk; 2) the
value of preparing in good times; 3) the
limitations of a resolution regime based
on FDICIA (the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation Improvement Act of 1991);4
and 4) the limitations of traditional
supervision and regulation.
In order to reduce expectations of bailouts and reestablish market discipline,
Stern said, policymakers must convince
uninsured creditors that they will bear
losses when their financial institution gets
into trouble. In addition, a credible commitment to imposing losses must be built

on reforms that directly reduce the incentives that lead policymakers to bail
out uninsured creditors (i.e., provide
significant protection for them).
Stern suggested that, without sufficient
preparations, policymakers—even under
a FDICIA regime—will end up supporting
uninsured creditors of financial institutions perceived to pose systemic risk.
Similarly, bank supervision has proven
slow to identify risks and is prone to
forbearance, as shown by its failure to
prevent excessive lending to commercial
real estate ventures.
The TBTF problem was also the subject
of a panel moderated by Elijah Brewer III,
DePaul University. The panel featured
David R. Casper, BMO Capital Markets;
Ron J. Feldman, Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis; and Robert A. Eisenbeis,
Cumberland Advisers. Brewer began by
raising the question of whether it would
be truly catastrophic to allow large firms
to fail, indicating that it had never really
been tried.
Casper listed the potential adverse repercussions of allowing a systemically
important institution to fail. However,
preventing such failures also has a number of negative impacts, such as moral
hazard (by seeming to reward irresponsible behavior), distortions in competition, artificial incentives for growth, and
costs to taxpayers. He recommended several measures to limit TBTF: maintaining
uncertainty around government intervention (i.e., not stating explicitly the
circumstances under which a government bailout will be forthcoming); enhancing capital requirements and board/
senior management accountability; improving supervision; creating a systemic
risk regulator; improving transparency
in credit default swaps and other over-thecounter (OTC) markets;5 and improving
resolution processes.
Feldman outlined the characteristics of
an effective “macro-prudential” supervisor. Such an entity would likely need,
for instance, practical, hands-on knowledge of institutions. In addition, to complement its own monitoring, it should
use firms’ own analyses of their exposures
to counterparties and other spillover

factors, as well as market assessments of
risk, to the extent possible. Since it is hard
to predict specific events that could precipitate a failure, more time should be
spent on determining appropriate responses in the event of a failure.
Eisenbeis argued that the concept of systemic risk has become broader and vaguer
over time. There is no workable definition of “systemically important” that could
be applied to a firm before an actual failure. In addition, creating a systemic risk
regulator may not be a panacea and could
produce conflicts of interest and other
incentive problems. To limit systemic
risk and TBTF, Eisenbeis recommended,
among other measures, limiting excessive
leverage and complexity and considering unwinding scenarios as part of the
bank supervision process.
Regulation and capital

The future of regulation, including capital requirements, was considered by a
panel moderated by Brian D. Gordon,
senior professional, Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The panelists were Anil K
Kashyap, University of Chicago; Edward F.
Greene, of Cleary Gottlieb Steen and
Hamilton LLP; and David Palmer,
Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.
Kashyap focused on capital regulation.
He proposed that, other things being
equal, capital requirements should be
higher for banks that pose greater potential systemic risk (i.e., larger banks
and banks with a higher proportion of
illiquid assets or of short-term debt).
He also proposed that failing institutions
should be forced to recapitalize, rather
than depending on large amounts of
government resources to prop them up.
This could be done through “contingent
equity,” a long-term debt instrument that
converts to equity under specific conditions. Banks would issue these bonds to
private investors before a crisis. If triggered, the automatic conversion of these
bonds into equity would keep a weakened
bank solvent at no cost to taxpayers.
Greene addressed likely changes in the
regulation of key markets and instruments,
as well as the concept of a systemic risk
regulator. He expressed concerns about

the effects of short selling6 during the
current crisis. He also predicted changes
in derivatives markets,7 such as increased
use of central counterparty clearing.
For securitization markets to come back,
key issues are better allocation of risk
to, and licensing of, loan originators,
as well as enhanced disclosures. While
endorsing the goals of having a systemic
risk regulator, Greene emphasized the
difficulties of implementing such a concept in the current highly fragmented
U.S. regulatory system.
Palmer concentrated on banks’ internal
assessments of capital adequacy. Banks
face a number of challenges in this area,
including the need for fundamental
processes to identify and measure risks.
Stress testing is also important in estimating capital needs and evaluating
available capital resources. It should be
used to challenge assumptions in existing
models and to look at potential outcomes
not captured in them. Given the inevitable
uncertainties surrounding the capital
assessment process, banks need to maintain strong capital buffers and have an
overall sense of humility about what they
understand and what they can measure.
The future of financial innovation

A panel on financial innovation, which
was moderated by John W. Labuszewski,

Charles L. Evans, President; Daniel G. Sullivan, Senior
Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas D. Evanoff,
Vice President, financial studies; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Daniel
Aaronson, Vice President, microeconomic policy research;
William A. Testa, Vice President, regional programs,
and Economics Editor; Helen O’D. Koshy and
Han Y. Choi, Editors; Rita Molloy and Julia Baker,
Production Editors.
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2009 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

Chicago Mercantile Exchange, featured
David Marshall, senior vice president,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and
Gerald A. Beeson, Citadel Investment
Group LLC. Labuszewski detailed how
his firm continues to innovate in a distressed economy, with particular emphasis
on bringing central counterparty clearing to the OTC derivatives market.

Beeson noted that much needed innovation had occurred within the derivatives
market in recent years. However, many of
these innovations, in risk transfer and
funding, have been shut down, perhaps
permanently. In addition, continued impairment of the securitization market will
hinder risk transfer between providers
of credit and pools of available capital.

Marshall analyzed the underlying causes
of the financial crisis and related policy
issues. A massive inflow of capital from
abroad led to low interest rates, underpricing of tail risk,8 overprovision of housing loans to nontraditional borrowers
(e.g., those with poor credit histories),
and overpricing of residential real estate.
Financial innovation is always potentially
disruptive, changing the distribution of
returns in unpredictable ways and making
tail risk events more likely. Marshall suggested that policymakers take a serious
look at this “dark side” of financial innovation, as well as managerial incentives,
the disruptive effects of housing mispricing, and (especially) measurement
and containment of tail risk.

Past crises

1

Leverage refers to the proportion of debt
to equity (also assets to equity and assets
to capital). Leverage can be built up by
borrowing (on-balance-sheet leverage) or
by using off-balance-sheet transactions.

2

Procyclicality refers to features that amplify the swings in the business cycle.

3

TBTF refers to the provision of discretionary government support to the uninsured
creditors of financial institutions perceived to pose systemic risk.

William M. Isaac, The Secura Group,
played a key role at the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) during the
banking crises of the 1980s. He said that
the current financial crisis is much less
severe than the earlier ones. The 1980s
saw massive problems in the economy and
thousands of bank and thrift failures. In
the current crisis, however, a relatively
manageable amount of potential losses on
subprime mortgages has been amplified
by misguided regulatory policies, he said.
Isaac identified several such policies. One
is fair value accounting, which has caused
assets to be marked to unrealistic, fire-sale
prices in the absence of a functioning
4

FDICIA mandated a least-cost resolution method but allowed a “systemic
risk exception.”

5

An OTC market is a decentralized market
of securities not listed on an exchange.

6

Short selling is the selling of securities or
commodities that the seller does not yet
have but expects to cover at a lower price.

7

A derivative is a financial instrument whose
characteristics and value depend upon

market and thereby destroyed hundreds
of billions of dollars of capital. Also misguided, Isaac said, were decisions by the
Securities and Exchange Commission to
allow “naked selling” (selling a financial
instrument short without first borrowing
it or ensuring that it can be borrowed)
and to eliminate the requirement that
short sellers could sell only on an uptick
in the market. Isaac also criticized the
Basel capital rules for exacerbating cyclical problems through the use of backwardlooking models. Loan-loss reserving
policies and FDIC insurance premiums
have also had highly procyclical effects.
Finally, Isaac argued that policymakers
created a crisis atmosphere by the way
large failures were handled and by using
inflammatory rhetoric when requesting
emergency taxpayer funds.
Conclusion

Overall, the conference built effectively
on last year’s meeting and reflected the
new directions both risks and policy responses have taken since that time. The
sponsors were gratified by the enthusiastic
response to this event.
those of an underlier—typically a commodity, bond, equity, or currency. Futures
and options are examples of derivatives.
8

Tail risk is a form of portfolio risk that
arises when the possibility that an investment will move more than three standard
deviations from the mean is greater than
what is shown by a normal distribution.