View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

APRIL 2000
NUMBER 152

Chicago Fed Letter
Should we be concerned
about the current account?
By the time this article hits your desk
you will have seen headlines announcing that the U.S. current account deficit
(the amount by which national investment exceeds national savings) has
widened to a new record annual level.
During 1999 it took just nine months
to equal the previous record annual
level of $221 billion set in 1998. Record
nominal trade and income deficits in
the fourth quarter raised the 1999 current account deficit to $339 billion. The
magnitude of these recent increases has
prompted policymakers and the press
to express concern about the economic consequences of sustaining large
current account deficits and to propose
restrictive trade policies to reduce
them.1 Congress has gone so far as to
establish a bipartisan commission, the
U.S. Trade Deficit Review Commission
(USTDRC), to look into the perceived
current account problem.2 This Chicago
Fed Letter examines the merits of this
debate by analyzing the data to see if
recent changes in the current account
balance were a temporary response to
a short-lived economic event, the Asian
financial crisis, or the persistent byproduct of recent U.S. trade agreements.

Guide to international transactions
The current account has three parts.
The first part is the familiar trade account. The balance of the trade account is the difference between the
value of U.S. exports and imports of
goods and services. A trade deficit occurs when the value of imports exceeds
the value of exports. The second part
of the current account is the less familiar income account, which records
income payments made to foreigners
and income received from foreigners.
International income flows largely
reflect interest payments made by the
U.S. on its foreign debt and interest
received from its foreign assets.

Income flows also reflect labor income
received by U.S. residents from overseas and labor income paid to foreign
residents. An income deficit occurs
when the value of income payments
to foreigners exceeds the value of income receipts from abroad. The final
part of the current account is transfers.
The balance of the transfer account is
the difference in the value of private
and official transfers to and from other
countries, the largest of which is foreign aid. The balance of the current
account is the sum of the trade, income, and transfer account balances.

so it should have no problem meeting
its foreign debt obligations.

Assessing the current account for any
one year is difficult because past current accounts influence future current
accounts through the income account.
Holding other things constant, a current account deficit this year would
automatically lead to a smaller income
balance and larger current account
deficit next year. The annual change
in the stock of a country’s net foreign
assets (foreign assets less foreign debt)
is determined by the country’s annual
current account balance.3 For example, an annual current account deficit
of $100 billion would mean that the
stock of net foreign assets decreased
by $100 billion over the year. Other
things being equal, the smaller stock
of net foreign assets this year would
lead to relatively higher interest payments to foreigners next year, implying a smaller income balance and
an increased current account deficit
next year.

The driving force behind these record
deficits has been large increases in the
trade deficit. Fluctuations in the trade
balance over the 1980s and 1990s
changed the current account balance
by as much as 1 percent of GDP in a
single calendar year, while the combined income and transfer accounts
have slowly added about 0.5 percent of
GDP to the current account deficit
over the last 40 years.

Thus, the nominal current account
appears to be inherently unstable.
However, focusing on just the current
account ignores the fact that a country’s ability to meet its foreign obligations is tied to gross domestic product
(GDP). Economists overcome this
problem by expressing the current account as a ratio to GDP. Even in deficit,
a country that has a stable current
account to GDP ratio would also have
a stable net foreign debt to GDP ratio,

History of U.S. current account
Figure 1 plots the current account (and
its three components) as a percentage
of nominal GDP. Looking through this
lens we see that the current account
deficit of 1999 loses some of its alarm.
At 3.66 percent of nominal GDP it is
still a record deficit, but it is only marginally higher than the current account
deficit to GDP percentages of 1986
and 1987.

Figure 1 shows that the U.S. has only
been running a deficit on the income
account since 1998. Figure 2 reveals
that over time the accumulated value
of U.S. current account deficits has
outweighed the accumulated value of
surpluses so that the stock of U.S. foreign debt exceeds the stock of U.S.
foreign assets. In other words, the U.S.
is an international net debtor. The U.S.
has been an international net debtor
since 1986. U.S. net foreign debt currently represents 16 percent of GDP.
This should have led to an income
deficit back in 1986. It did not because
the ex-post rate of return on U.S. foreign assets has consistently exceeded
the ex-post rate of return foreigners
enjoy on their U.S. assets (i.e., U.S.
foreign debt).
In contrast to the income account, figure 1 shows that with the exception of
1991, the U.S. has consistently recorded
a transfer deficit, a consequence of large
foreign aid payments to developing

countries. The surplus in 1991 came
about because of net transfer payments
to the U.S. associated with the war in
the Persian Gulf.

Why are policymakers concerned?
By definition, the current account balance is the outcome of consumption
and investment decisions made by U.S.
and foreign residents, who presumably
act in their best interest subject to various constraints (including government
policy), so from their standpoint the
current account balance is optimal.
This means that the size of the deficit
should not be a concern for public policy unless there is evidence of poorly
functioning markets (in goods or capital) and/or inappropriate government
policies (fiscal, monetary, or trade).
While the policy debate surrounding
the persistent current account deficits
of many emerging countries has included discussions about imperfect domestic capital markets and inappropriate
domestic government policies, the U.S.
debate has been limited to questioning

government policies, most recently
free trade agreements.
For example, the record current account deficits of the mid-1980s coincided
with large fiscal deficits, which led to
the popular view that current account
imbalances are byproducts of fiscal
imbalances—the twin-deficits theory.
According to this theory increases in
the government’s fiscal deficit should
be matched by similar increases in the
current account deficit. The idea is
that the current account balance reflects the difference between national
saving and investment, so reductions
in national saving such as a large fiscal
deficit would directly increase the current account deficit. Obstfeld and
Rogoff (1995) and others find no empirical support for this theory in the
long term.4 Its apparent weakness is
also reflected by the fact that the U.S.
reduced its fiscal deficit over the latter
half of the 1990s and is currently running a surplus.
In contrast to the 1980s, today’s policy
debate over the appropriate size of

the U.S. current account deficit has
focused on the ballooning trade deficit. This is the primary focus of the
USTDRC. Commentators argue that
the trade deficit is the necessary
byproduct of restrictive trade practices
in other countries and the ongoing liberalization of U.S. international trade.
This has led to calls for limiting the
entry of foreign goods into the U.S.
Another feature of the current debate
is that commentators have raised fears
about the dynamic consequences of
sustaining large trade deficits. They
argue that the situation is more acute
than it was in the 1980s because the
U.S. is now an international debtor
with an income deficit. The concern
is that the U.S. will soon be in a debt
trap as larger income deficits lead to
higher net debt levels that in turn lead
to even larger income deficits. Witnesses testifying before the USTDRC
have argued that the stock of U.S. net
foreign debt could reach 50 percent
of GDP by 2011 if the U.S. and world
economies continue to expand at
present rates and returns on assets remain at current levels.5

1. Components of current account

2. Net international investment position

percent of GDP
2

value at current cost, percent of GDP
80

Stock of U.S.
foreign debt

Income account
balance
0

40

Transfer
balance

Stock of U.S.
foreign assets
Trade balance

-2

0

Current

-4
1960 ’63 ’66 ’69 ’72 ’75 ’78 ’81 ’84 ’87 ’90 ’93 ’96 ’99

3. Exports vs. imports
percent of GDP
16

Net foreign assets
-40
1984

’87

’90

’96

’99

4. Goods trade vs. service trade
Imports of goods
and services

percent of GDP
2

Service trade
balance

12
0
8
4

’93

Exports of goods
and services
Trade balance

-2

0
-4
1960 ’63 ’66 ’69 ’72 ’75 ’78 ’81 ’84 ’87 ’90 ’93 ’96 ’99

Trade
balance

Goods trade
balance
-4
1960 ’63 ’66 ’69 ’72 ’75 ’78 ’81 ’84 ’87 ’90 ’93 ’96 ’99

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis,
National Income and Product Accounts and U.S. International Transactions.

Why we think concerns
are misplaced
The data do not support the
view that the recent surge in
the U.S. current account
deficit was caused by changes
in U.S. international trade
policy. According to trade
theory, liberalizing U.S. trade
would lead to a rise in the
relative price of foreign
goods (imports) and an outflow of capital from the U.S.,
which is inconsistent with the
facts.6 The data reveal that
there was a net capital inflow
to the U.S. and a large fall in
the relative price of foreign
goods. Based on this and
other evidence the main influence on the U.S. current
account over the last three
years appears to have been
the Asian and Latin American
financial crises and the subsequent slowdown of global
(non-U.S.) economic activity.
The U.S. was seen as a safe
haven in the wake of the

Asian, and later Latin American, financial crisis. On a risk-adjusted basis the
U.S. had higher rates of return, which
led to a large net inflow of capital.
The increased supply of funds for investment was one of the factors that
led to relatively low U.S. interest rates
in recent years,7 which helped fuel
the U.S. expansion and demand for
imports by reducing saving and raising
investment and consumption. The outflow of capital from Asia also caused a
massive depreciation of Asian, and
eventually Latin American, currencies.
This led to a significant fall in the relative price of foreign goods, thereby
raising U.S. demand for imports (and
lowering foreign demand for U.S. exports). (See figure 3.) Another consequence of the capital outflow from
Asia was high domestic interest rates in
Asia and Latin America, which caused a
severe economic slowdown. This also
lowered the demand for U.S. exports
and led to a significantly lower return
on U.S. foreign assets relative to that
on U.S. foreign debt. Overall, the data
appear to be consistent with the view
that the flow of capital from Asia and
Latin America to the U.S. following
their financial crisis caused the recent
widening of the U.S. trade and income
deficits, not trade liberalization.

Future of U.S. current account
As conditions improve abroad, we expect to see a reversal of the temporary
factors associated with the global financial crisis. As foreign risk diminishes
there should be an outflow of funds
from the U.S. This decrease in the
supply of funds available for investment
should raise the level of U.S. interest
rates. In turn, higher interest rates
should raise the level of saving and
lower the level of consumption and investment. At the same time, improved
economic conditions should raise foreign demand for U.S. goods, and the
outflow of capital should put some
downward pressure on the dollar. These
factors should lower the nominal trade
deficit through higher export and lower
import demand. The net effect of the
global recovery on the income deficit
is less clear. Higher U.S. interest rates
combined with a higher net debt level
should raise the income deficit through
higher income payments abroad, while
improvements in the relative return
on U.S. foreign assets should lower

the income deficit. Our estimates
suggest that the latter effect will dominate, so there should be an improvement in the income deficit. Overall,
undoing the temporary events surrounding the global financial crisis
should reduce the U.S. current account deficit to GDP ratio in the
short run.
The capital inflow in the wake of the
global financial crisis partly financed
the investment boom that has supported the longest U.S. economic
expansion.8 There is a widespread
belief that this investment spurt has
permanently raised the productive capacity of the U.S. and, some say, its
long-run trend growth rate. Both of
these factors have greatly improved the
U.S.’s ability to meet its foreign debt
obligations (i.e., its ability to sustain a
large current deficit in the long run).
The growing importance of services
in the U.S. economy should also help.
The so-called new economy is dominated by services, which account for
over 70 percent of GDP. Although
most economists think of services as
non-tradable goods, many are in fact
tradable. At present, services account
for a relatively small, but growing share
of U.S. trade (see figure 4). One could
reasonably expect the share of services
in trade to approach the share of services in GDP. The growing trade surplus in services indicates that U.S.
producers have a comparative advantage in this area. This suggests that
the U.S. may run trade surpluses in
the long run as trade continues to
shift from manufactured goods.

Conclusion
The current account deficit as a
share of nominal GDP is only now
approaching the record levels set in
the 1980s. Unlike the 1980s deficits,
which were driven by government
spending, today’s deficits are linked
to a favorable situation that has allowed the U.S. to expand its productive capital stock by borrowing from
abroad at relatively low interest rates.
This investment has raised the U.S.’s
productive capacity (and possibly its
long-run growth rate) and its ability
to meet its foreign financial obligations. In light of this, the current
concern about the U.S. trade and
current deficits appears to be without

merit, as are the calls for restrictive
trade policies to reverse the situation.
—Jack L. Hervey
Senior economist
—Michael A. Kouparitsas
Economist
1
See J. Khan, 2000, “Trade deficit set record in November,” New York Times, January 21, Section C, p. 1.
2
Congress established the USTDRC on October 21,
1998. See www.ustdrc.gov/index.html.
3

Foreign asset transactions are recorded in the capital
account. The balance of the capital account is the difference between the change in value of U.S. foreign
debt and assets. A capital account surplus occurs
when the value of foreign debt increases by more
than that of foreign assets. The balance of the capital
account has the opposite sign to the current account
balance so the sum of the accounts is zero.

4
See M. Obstfeld and K. Rogoff, 1995, “The intertemporal approach to the current account,” in
Handbook of International Economics, G. Grossman and
K. Rogoff (eds.), Vol. 3, New York: Elsevier, North
Holland.
5
See W. Godley, 1999, “Interim report: Notes on the
U.S. trade and balance of payments deficits,” The Jerome
Levy Economic Institute, Bard College, paper.
6
See M. A. Kouparitsas, 1999, “Why do countries
pursue bilateral trade agreements? A case study of
North America,” Chicago Fed, working paper, No.
97-20, http://research.frbchi.org/WorkingPapers/
wp97_20.pdf.
7
There is a wealth of evidence suggesting that the
U.S. faces an upward sloping supply cur ve for investment funds; see M. Baxter and M. J. Crucini, 1993,
“Explaining saving-investment correlations,” American
Economic Review, Vol. 83, pp. 416–436, and references
therein.
8
There is empirical evidence that suggests large current account deficits are typically associated with investment booms; see J. D. Sachs, 1981, “The current
account and macroeconomic adjustment in the 1970s,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1, pp. 201–268.

Michael H. Moskow, President; William C. Hunter,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas
Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies; Charles
Evans, Vice President, macroeconomic policy research;
Daniel Sullivan, Vice President, microeconomic policy
research; William Testa, Vice President, regional
programs and economics editor; Helen O’D. Koshy,
Editor.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and are not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve
System. Articles may be reprinted if the source is
credited and the Research Department is
provided with copies of the reprints.
Chicago Fed Letter is available without charge from
the Public Information Center, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois
60690-0834, tel. 312-322-5111 or fax 312-322-5515.
Chicago Fed Letter and other Bank publications are
available on the World Wide Web at http://
www.frbchi.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

Tracking Midwest manufacturing activity
Purchasing managers’ surveys (production index)
72

Manufacturing output indexes
(1992=100)
CFMMI
IP

Jan.

Month ago

Year ago

136.4
146.6

135.5
145.3

130.1
138.6

Midwest

64

Motor vehicle production
(millions, seasonally adj. annual rate)
Feb.

Month ago

Year ago

Cars

5.6

5.7

5.5

Light trucks

6.9

7.1

6.8

56

U.S.

Purchasing managers’ surveys:
net % reporting production growth

48

Feb.

Month ago

MW

59.6

51.4

Year ago
54.3

U.S.

61.3

55.9

56.3
40
1997

’98

The Midwest purchasing managers’ composite index for production increased
to 59.6% in February from 51.4% in January. The purchasing managers’ index
increased in Chicago and Detroit, but decreased in Milwaukee. The national
purchasing managers’ survey for production increased from 55.9% to 61.3%
from January to February. The Chicago Fed Midwest Manufacturing Index
(CFMMI) rose 0.6% from December to January, reaching a seasonally adjusted
level of 136.4 (1992=100). In comparison, the Federal Reserve Board’s Industrial
Production Index (IP) for manufacturing increased 0.9% in January, after
rising 0.2% in December.
Light truck production decreased from 7.1 million units in January 2000 to 6.9
million units in February, and car production decreased from 5.7 million to 5.6
million units from January to February.

’99

’00

Sources: The Chicago Fed Midwest Manufacturing Index (CFMMI) is a composite index of 16
industries, based on monthly hours worked and
kilowatt hours. IP represents the Federal Reserve
Board’s Industrial Production Index for the U.S.
manufacturing sector. Autos and light trucks are
measured in annualized units, using seasonal adjustments developed by the Board. The purchasing managers’ survey data for the Midwest are
weighted averages of the seasonally adjusted production components from the Chicago, Detroit,
and Milwaukee Purchasing Managers’ Association
surveys, with assistance from Kingsbury International, LTD., Comerica, and the University of
Wisconsin–Milwaukee.

Return service requested
Public Information Center
P.O. Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834
(312) 322-5111

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

Chicago Fed Letter

PRESORTED
FIRST CLASS MAIL
US POSTAGE PAID
CHICAGO, IL
PERMIT 1942