View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SPECIAL ISSUE

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

AUGUST 1999
NUMBER 144b

Chicago Fed Letter
Global financial crisis and
economic development
On May 23, 1999, the Department of
Economics and the George J. Stigler
Center for the Study of the Economy
and the State of the University of Chicago and the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago cosponsored a conference
titled Global Financial Crisis and
Economic Development. The conference drew prestigious representatives
from academic, business, and policy
circles. Nobel laureates Gary Becker
and Robert Lucas participated, and international financier George Soros gave
the keynote address. This Chicago Fed
Letter summarizes the ideas presented
at the conference.
Asian financial crisis: A tale
of two countries
Robert M. Townsend, the Charles E.
Merriam Distinguished Professor of
Economics at the University of Chicago,
discussed the role of Thailand in the
Asian financial crisis. Since 1970,
Thailand had been characterized by
tremendous economic growth and
high saving and investment rates. The
government was fiscally responsible,
producing surpluses of 6% of gross
domestic product (GDP) and a negative current account balance. However,
there were signs of weakness in Thailand’s financial system. Most deposits
and financial credit were centered in
commercial banks and finance companies in urban areas such as Bangkok.
Seeds of the crisis were planted with
misguided investment in these institutions. Investment decisions in areas
such as real estate were often based
upon a non-market rationale rather
than on supply and demand. Finance
companies had a large fraction of their
portfolio in real estate and, while official figures state that commercial lending was primarily in manufacturing,

Townsend suspects that many of these
loans were also in real estate. In addition, financial institutions had substantial foreign exchange exposure and
were dependent on foreign capital.
The onset of the financial crisis saw
depleted reserves, a fall in real activity
and imports, and high fiscal deficits.
Given the poor investment decisions,
where had the phenomenal GDP
growth come from? Townsend discussed several models of growth, and
argued that growth was fostered
through capital deepening rather
than total factor productivity. Capital
accumulation was fostered by an initial
scarcity of capital. Capital drew high
rates of return, attracting investment
from abroad and from within Thailand.
Townsend finds that a substantial portion of credit within Thailand was
provided through informal relationships. Thus, growth in Thailand was
in large part self-financed. This theory
is supported by evidence that unemployment was low in rural areas during
the crisis. Household income from
wages and remittances fell, but business income increased. Small businesses were likely supported through
informal rather than institutional credit, which may explain why demand for
institutional credit was low during the
crisis. The success of small enterprises suggests that the Thai government
should have focused on long-term improvements in the financial system
rather than on unemployment, which
was likely overstated.
Next, James Tsuen-Hua Shih, Central
Bank of China, Taiwan (CBC), discussed why Taiwan was spared the fate
of other troubled Asian tigers during
the crisis. Shih believes that a combination of sound governmental policies,
high-quality human resources, strong
entrepreneurial spirit, and a favorable
external environment allowed Taiwan

to flourish with high growth and low
inflation. Taiwan is known for its stability as a net creditor country, with
consistent current account surpluses.
It has been able to maintain large foreign reserves ($90.3 billion at yearend
1998) and carry virtually no external
government debt. Other strong economic fundamentals, such as a high
savings rate and near fiscal balance,
have also contributed to Taiwan’s superior record. However, even Taiwan’s
impressive economic fundamentals
could not protect it completely from
the effects of the Asian crisis. The new
Taiwanese dollar (NTD) depreciated
and stock index volatility increased,
but Taiwan suffered little in comparison with other countries. Shih credits
sound monetary policy for Taiwan’s
success. The CBC intervened heavily
in the beginning, expecting that the
strong economic fundamentals would
prevent much speculation. However,
after several billion dollars had been
lost in the defense of the NTD, the
CBC followed a managed float of the
exchange rate to stem further losses.
The success of the float has allowed
Taiwan to continue on a path of economic growth and financial restructuring. Along with sound economic
fundamentals and monetary policy,
Shih also credited the resilience and
flexibility of Taiwanese enterprise for
weathering the financial storm. In addition, the Taiwanese people benefited
from their experience with a major asset bubble during the 1980s. As a
result, investors were better prepared
to deal with asset volatility during the
Asian crisis.
Crisis in Latin America
The conference then examined two
case studies of financial crisis in Latin
America. Jose Scheinkman, the Alvin
H. Baum Distinguished Service Professor of Economics at the University

of Chicago, discussed the situation in
Brazil, and Roque Fernandez, Minister
of the Economy and Public Works and
Services of Argentina, followed with
perspectives from Argentina. Scheinkman began by depicting a grim picture
of Brazil during the eighties. Brazil
had no per capita income growth, and
was the “world champion of inflation.”
The economy was characterized by
government intervention, with state
monopolies and restriction of entry in
industries, controls on prices, wages,
and interest rates, and high labor taxes. High labor taxation encouraged a
high degree of informality within the
labor force, as workers avoided official
jobs in favor of jobs within the underground economy. Such informality
can be costly since these enterprises
are often restricted to a smaller, inefficient scale. The closed nature of
Brazil’s economy created distortions
with investment. The cost of an investment good was nearly twice that of an
investment good in the U.S. In this
regard, Brazil proved a sharp contrast
to the capital deepening that occurred
in Thailand, since investors had little
incentive to invest in Brazil.
However, Brazil began to improve. The
real plan proved effective at reducing
inflation. Deregulation occurred, as
well as privatization in many industries.
Barriers were lowered to foreign investment and trade. In seven years, productivity doubled in steel, banking, telecommunications, and automobiles.
Privatization of state banks led to a
healthy banking system. However, a
crucial element was missing: the control of fiscal deficits. Brazil was stymied
by high government expenditures,
and further problems were created
by the government’s inflation-fighting
policies. The resulting high interest
rates raised the cost of debt servicing,
creating a vicious cycle. The government
borrowed to follow a tight monetary
policy, but then had to pay restrictive
interest rates (15% to 20%) to finance
the government debt. Scheinkman
reflected that raising interest rates to
solve what was basically a fiscal problem
was misguided. The fiscal situation
deteriorated and left Brazil vulnerable
to financial crisis. Although Brazil
suffered substantially, the crisis was

short-lived, largely owing to favorable
external conditions and International
Monetary Fund (IMF) recommendations and the fact that the crisis was
expected. While Brazil now shows positive signs of recovery, Scheinkman believes that only expanded investment
in human and physical capital combined with more openness will guarantee its future economic success.
Roque Fernandez discussed Argentina’s experience with globalization. In
contrast to the relatively closed nature
of Brazil’s economy, Argentina maintains a high degree of openness, with
a currency board and no restrictions
on international capital flows. Argentina’s future depends on balancing
the rewards and perils of globalization.
The rewards include high GDP growth
and foreign investment. On the other
hand, Argentina is subject to a large
amount of volatility from foreign markets and open capital markets. Crises
within the country closely follow fluctuations in capital flows and GDP.
This imposes a form of discipline
on policymakers. Financial markets
appraise the consistency and appropriateness of government policies, rewarding successes and penalizing failures.
Fernandez proposed that there were
other consequences to such openness,
as “innocent” countries may be susceptible to financial contagion from countries with ineffective policies. Should
international scrutiny simply be accepted as a constraint on domestic policy?
He argued that market perceptions
are typically correct in their valuations.
When markets suspect that a banking
system is weak, evidence after the crisis
tends to confirm the perceptions.
Fernandez expressed positive expectations given the domestic and international reforms taking place, such
as Argentinian private deposit insurance and the IMF’s new contingent
credit lines.
The Lucas critique
Robert E. Lucas, Jr., the John Dewey
Distinguished Service Professor of
Economics and Nobel laureate from
the University of Chicago, shared his
views on monetary policy and the

prospects for world economic growth.
He began with a thorough critique of
fixed exchange rate regimes. Since
the dissolution of the Bretton Woods
system in 1971, most countries have
abandoned fixed exchange rates in
favor of flexible exchange regimes.
Countries typically adopt fixed exchange rate regimes either as a commitment against inflationary monetary
policy or to facilitate capital flows.
Lucas argues that the costs of such an
exchange rate policy outweigh the
benefits. His review of the data shows
that the largest recessions since Bretton Woods have been due to the defense of exchange rate regimes. For
example, Mexico’s defense of its
exchange rate through restrictive
monetary policy precipitated a costly
recession in 1994, and devaluation
occurred anyway. Lucas attributed the
improvement in world living standards
to the effectiveness of postwar institutions and central banks’ efforts to control inflation. Therefore, he argued
that countries should adopt monetary
policies that target inflation, rather
than maintain fixed exchange rates
and fiscal fine-tuning.
Lucas views capital allocation as the
most important issue facing economics. In order to maximize production,
resources should be directed where
they are most efficient. Lucas illustrated
the potential waste of resources by
sketching a simple model of the inefficient allocation of capital. His rough
estimates suggest a $4 trillion waste
due to lack of training and physical
capital. To address this waste, Lucas
advocated policy innovations that encourage efficient aggregation of labor
and capital, such as immigration, and
liberalized capital flows.
Soros calls for reform in the IMF
George Soros, chairman of the Soros
Fund Management LLC, discussed
reform of the international financial
system during the keynote luncheon
address. Soros believes that the current infrastructure is inherently unstable and contributes to the advent of
global crises. He identified the IMF
as the focal point of reform. He blamed
many policy decisions of the IMF for

worsening crises; examples include
underestimation of the financial contagion and misguided macroeconomic
recommendations to troubled countries. He also expressed concern about
the structure of the IMF. First, its very
nature as an international lender limits its role in preventing crises as it
must wait for requests of assistance
before it can take action. Second, the
IMF creates moral hazard as a result of
its lending policies. The fund’s structural deficiencies when taken together
exacerbate crises. Soros cited the similarities between Thailand, Indonesia,
and Korea, where costly devaluation,
followed by IMF assistance requiring
high interest rates and fiscal austerity,
ended in prolonged recession. The
IMF has responded to criticisms by
introducing new reforms such as its
contingent credit line. The new mechanism provides funds to countries
experiencing financial contagion,
but only to those that have met specific
fiscal requirements. Soros agrees with
the reforms, but argued that they must
work in tandem to be effective. He also
pushed for explicit enforceable standards as a condition for lending.
Models of crisis
David Marshall, senior economist from
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
and Raguram Rajan, the Joseph L.
Gidwitz Professor of Finance from the
Graduate School of Business at the
University of Chicago, presented their
research on the Asian crisis. Marshall
examined the role of coordination
failure in financial crisis. He cited
foreign investors’ behavior during the
Asian crisis as an example of coordination failure. An investor individually
may find it optimal to withdraw funds
from a troubled country, but all investors would be better off if they maintained their investment in that country.
He developed a model to illustrate
how coordination failures can occur.
Such a model is useful for understanding financial panics and developing
corresponding policy responses. For
example, in a fractional reserve banking system, the possibility of a coordination failure exists, as investors fearing
losses withdraw their funds, resulting
in a bank run. While requiring banks to

maintain 100% of deposits in reserves
would offset the risk of coordination
failure, such a requirement would
eliminate an important role of banks.
Banks convert short-term liabilities
like individual deposits into longterm assets such as mortgage loans.
This welfare trade-off between reduction of coordination failure and
banking efficiency may warrant the
provision of liquidity by an international organization, like the IMF, to
avoid this trade-off. Marshall concluded that models of coordination
failure offer a way of rationalizing extreme shifts in economic performance
which accompany financial crisis, but
are currently inadequate to provide a
complete explanation.
Rajan provided an alternative framework to understand the underpinnings of the Asian crisis. He proposed
that the financial infrastructure of
troubled countries in Asia was to
blame rather than a financial panic.
These countries have very fragile banking sectors with poor governance, inadequate laws and enforcement, and
weak bankruptcy provisions. Under
such a system, credit must be intermediated by institutions with overlapping
ownership, multimarket contacts, and
specialized information and skills.
Only institutions with these attributes
can recover loans in such a system.
Rajan argued that a fragile banking
system requires a high level of shortterm debt. Banks commit to investors
by paying out what they collect on
short-term debt. Fragility is necessary
as a lever for outsiders to punish banks
in the case of failure. Unfortunately,
such a system requires continued
high growth or monopoly returns to
prevail. In addition, such a system
suppresses market signals, which
leads to inefficient resource allocation. Eventually, deteriorating investment creates problems of repayment.
Rajan argued this occurred in the
Asian crisis. Banks were being run
because of solvency concerns rather
than for liquidity reasons. Why does
this matter? During a liquidity-based
crisis, confidence-building measures
would work and foreign lenders and
new banks would replace insolvent
domestic institutions. In addition,

short-term capital flows should be
restricted since they are the root of the
problem. However, under a solvencybased crisis, institutional infrastructure
is inadequate to support other forms of
lending. Liquidity is ineffective until
banks are recapitalized since investors
will withdraw their funds and leave.
Recapitalization of existing institutions
is required, since new and foreign banks
are incapable of operating in such
an environment. Under these circumstances, a ban on short-term capital
could create a massive credit crunch,
since long-term borrowing is prohibitively high for this kind of economy.
Lessons for the future
The conference concluded with a stimulating panel discussion on lessons for
financial markets and economic development. The panel comprised: Arnold
C. Harberger, professor of economics
at the University of California at Los
Angeles, William C. Hunter, senior
vice president and director of research
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Leo Melamed, chairman and CEO of
Sakura Dellsher Inc., and Michael
Mussa, economic counsellor and director of research of the IMF, and was moderated by Gary S. Becker, professor of
economics and sociology and Nobel
laureate from the University of Chicago.

Michael H. Moskow, President; William C. Hunter,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas
Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies; Charles
Evans, Vice President, macroeconomic policy research;
Daniel Sullivan, Vice President, microeconomic policy
research; William Testa, Vice President, regional
programs and economics editor; Helen O’D. Koshy,
Editor.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the
authors’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System. Articles may be reprinted if the
source is credited and the Research Department
is provided with copies of the reprints.
Chicago Fed Letter is available without charge from
the Public Information Center, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois
60690-0834, tel. 312-322-5111 or fax 312-322-5515.
Chicago Fed Letter and other Bank publications are
available on the World Wide Web at http://
www.frbchi.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

The discussion began with suggestions
for reforms within the financial sector.
Harberger proposed that banks reduce
their exposure to currency risk and
illiquidity. Banks should lend and
borrow in the same currency to eliminate foreign exchange exposure and
exit the mortgage business to avoid
the mismatch of holding assets at 30
years and liabilities at 30 days. Hunter
cautioned about rapid liberalization
without regard to banking infrastructure. A simple shock can lead to something very severe if the financial infrastructure is not robust. Fortunately, governments and international organizations are beginning to concern themselves with these issues. Becker then
addressed the role of these entities.
Is government too involved? Melamed
argued against such intervention, since
governmental bodies are unable to
prevent crises and often expedite their
occurrence. “Rescues” by the IMF are
simply redistributions, which bail out
lenders at the expense of citizens. The
Mexican crisis saw lenders being saved,
while the country suffered a costly recession. He also disagreed with Lucas
and Harberger who credited monetary policy and international institutions for favorable growth. Melamed

believes improvements in technology
that allow greater information transfer
and transparency, coupled with the
prevalence of flexible rates, have reduced global crises. For these reasons,
the international community would
be better off without the IMF.
Other panelists were not so pessimistic
about the role of government and the
IMF. Mussa proposed that the reforms
instituted since the Great Depression
have eliminated the problem of solvent institutions that are illiquid and
created a new problem of insolvent
institutions that are liquid. While the
government should remain responsible for avoiding major catastrophes,
the private sector must become more
involved, through measures such as
subordinated debt or privatized deposit
insurance, to maintain market discipline. Mussa strongly disputed claims
that the IMF was a source of moral hazard during the Asian crisis. The IMF
does not absorb countries’ losses. It
provides loans that must be repaid
with interest.
Harberger maintained that the IMF is
necessary to respond to crises. He noted that crises prompt herd behavior,
and that a level-headed international

mechanism to provide funds is required to safeguard against this irrational behavior. The IMF also serves to
reduce financial contagion; Argentina
was spared a harsher fate due to IMF
assistance afforded to Mexico. Hunter
pointed out that if the IMF were abolished, some other organization would
have to be created to take its place.
Though the IMF could use some improvement, the institution provides a
safety net that is necessary to achieve
stability of the payments system.
Melamed accepted the need for a
safety net, but proposed that no funds
should be extended until countries
meet certain requirements. However,
the feasibility of such a proposition
was subject to debate. Becker then
questioned the enforceability of such
requirements, as the specter of financial contagion makes it difficult for
the IMF to refuse to lend. Hunter concluded the panel discussion by noting
that many of the solutions for preventing crises are known, but the means of
achieving such reforms are problematic
given the political, social, and institutional impediments already in place.
—Surya Sen
Associate economist

Return service requested
Public Information Center
P.O. Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834
(312) 322-5111

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

Chicago Fed Letter

PRESORTED
FIRST-CLASS MAIL
ZIP + 4 BARCODED
U.S. POSTAGE PAID
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS
PERMIT NO. 1942