View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS O N ISSUES

T H E FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
O F C H IC A G O

JU N E 1992
N U M B E R 58

Chicago Fed Letter
Capitalism and change in
the Commonwealth o f
Independent States
The dramatic change resulting in the
dissolution of the Soviet Union and
the formation of the Commonwealth
of Independent States (CIS) has
excited much discussion among
economists concerning the problems
and opportunities involved in mov­
ing from a planned economy to a
market economy. Of particular im­
portance are questions concerning
the form Western aid to the CIS
should take, as well as what opportu­
nities will exist for Western entrepre­
neurs and investors. This discussion
has often focused on so-called macroeconomic problems such as control­
ling inflation, stabilizing the ruble,
decreasing budget deficits, and so
forth. However, it is also important
to focus on microeconomic prob­
lems, that is, the problems involved
in developing the institutions and
mechanisms whereby a planned
economy can be transformed into a
market economy.
During a recent trip to the CIS in
conjuntion with the International
Monetary Fund, I had a chance to
observe first hand the status and
moves for change in the CIS repub­
lics. In this Chicago Fed Letter l discuss
the current economic situation in the
CIS in order to provide some insights
into some of the problems involved
in moving from a planned economy
to a market economy.
The profit motive and privatization

Currently in the CIS, most compa­
nies are government owned, as they
were in the old, planned economy.
However, in an effort to make firms

more profitable, legal restrictions have
been relaxed in order to give manag­
ers more control over firm resources.
In any system in which the managers
of a firm are not the owners there will
likely be “agency problems,” that is,
managers will be inclined to pursue
their own self interest rather than
maximize firm value. In a market
economy, publicly held firms are
owned by the shareholders who have a
variety of methods for putting pres­
sure on management to maximize
firm value. For example, shareholders
can sell their shares, causing share
prices to decrease and signaling to
capital suppliers that investment in the
firm is not a good idea. They can vote
for directors on the board who can
discipline or replace top management.
In actual market economies there are
problems in the system for pressuring
management, however, the important
point is that firm owners—the share­
holders—have the right incentives to
discipline firm management: they
benefit if firm value increases and lose
if firm value decreases.
The problem in the CIS is that the
government officials who are sup­
posed to regulate firm managers do
not have the right incentives to ensure
that managers maximize firm value.
The officials do not profit if firm value
increases or lose if firm value decreas­
es. Government firms in the CIS are
owned by everyone; this means that
nobody benefits directly by increases
in firm value. Thus, the result of re­
laxing restrictions on managers’ con­
trol of firm resources has been an
increase in agency problems rather
than firm profits. For example, man­
agers from several firms have used the
combined cash flow from their firms
as capital to start a private bank. Prob­
lems with regulating firm manage­

ment are exacerbated by the fact that
the republics’ governments do not
have sufficient resources or manpower
to oversee managers of all government
owned firms.
One obvious solution to the agency
problem is to privatize government
owned companies, for example, by
selling shares in the company. One
difficulty for this idea is the lack of
capital in private hands. Some repub­
lics plan to solve the capital problem
by issuing vouchers to citizens. These
vouchers could be used to purchase
only either shares in newly privatized
companies or dwellings. Once compa­
nies are privatized, a capital market
could emerge. Market forces could
then function as they do in Western
countries, to discipline firm managers,
thus relieving government of some of
the regulatory responsibility.
Some republics have moved further
towards privatization than others. One
area of success is in agriculture: in
most of the republics, much of the
agricultural land is owned by private
citizens. Farmers sell their produce in
markets in nearly every city in the CIS.
These produce markets existed even
before the break up of the Soviet
Union and are the most successful
examples of the move towards a mar­
ket economy in the CIS.
A separate problem concerning firm
profitability and manager incentives
arises from the price instability cur­
rently in the CIS. Ideally, managers
should be rewarded for increasing the
value of the firm. In fact, in the CIS, as
in many other economies, manager
performance is evaluated on the basis
of profits, that is, on firm earnings
after expenses. The problem with this
type of incentive structure is that man­
agers can manipulate profits by, for

Sill

s; ■mm m

mm

example, cutting back on discretionary
expenses such as advertising or capital
spending. Also, firm profits are affect­
ed by things other than management
skill, such as general economic condi­
tions. This latter problem is particular­
ly acute in the CIS because of price
instability. Frequent, drastic price
changes mean that reported profits are
a very poor indicator of true economic
gains or losses and therefore of man­
agement skill. For example, energy
prices are expected to increase ten fold
in September. After the price change,
energy producing industries will likely
show very high profits while energy
consuming firms may show sharply
declining profits. Obviously, these
changes in profitability would not show
that managers of energy producing
firms are doing a good job while man­
agers of energy consuming firms are
doing a poor job.
M onopoly power

Under a planned economy, it may be
easier and more economical to build
one plant or factory rather than several
plants in order to produce a particular
type of good. As a result, there are a
large number of firms in the CIS with
monopoly power. In a market econo­
my, a monopoly can restrict output and
raise prices. Because buyers have little
power, a monopoly producer has little
incentive to increase product quality.
Because of the lack of competition,
monopolies have little incentive to
increase production efficiency. Conse­
quently, in the U.S., for example, gov­
ernm ent regulation restricts monopo­
lies in order to avoid these problems
and protect consumers.
In the CIS a number of factors inhibit
the government from reducing monop­
oly power. Local government officials
fear that restricting prices may result in
the demise or downsizing of a large
plant. The resulting worker layoffs
might cause social unrest.
One of the main impediments to reduc­
ing the power of CIS monopolies is that
the managers of many of these large
plants have developed close personal
ties with government officials. Conse­
quently, they are able to influence

government policy to favor continuing
monopoly power and higher prices.
The relationship between firm manag­
ers and government officials devel­
oped in the old, planned economy. In
that system the central government
appointed managers of firms and
supervised the distribution of supplies,
products, and capital. Thus, managers
depended on government offices
called ministries for supplies, capital,
and markets for their products. The
ministries in turn depended upon
managers to keep the distribution
system running smoothly. This distri­
bution system is largely still in place.
In particular, the same government
ministries still control distribution
both within and between republics
and the same managers run the mo­
nopolies. Both of these groups want
to retain monopoly power and keep
control of distribution, thus, they resist
movement toward market determined
prices and distribution. This situation
is complicated by the fact that the
ministries controlling distribution
were part of the central government,
not the local republic governments.
Now they are controlled by the repub­
lic governments, however, these gov­
ernments have no experience control­
ling the distribution of goods. Thus,
they can not simply dismantle the
present distribution system because
there is nothing to take its place.
Continuing monopoly power as well
as the ministry control of distribution
and trade create powerful barriers to
entry for new firms, allowing the exist­
ing monopolies to remain entrenched.
Western countries contemplating aid
to the CIS countries should keep the
distribution situation in mind in deter­
mining how to administer financial
assistance. If, for example, aid given
to the republic governments ends up
in the hands of the ministries, then it
may well help maintain the present
system. If Western countries wish to
encourage the move towards a market
economy, in particular, to reduce
monopoly power and encourage the
creation of a market distribution sys­
tem, a better idea might be to give
grants to entrepreneurs trying to start
new firms rather than aid to govern­
ment agencies.

Impediments to trade
between republics

Under the old Soviet planned econo­
my, the government determined how
much each factory would produce and
distributed the goods from the pro­
ducers to consumers. In particular,
the government determined what, and
how many, goods and services each
republic would receive, as well as the
price. Thus the government deter­
mined how big the total “pie” of goods
and services would be as well as how to
slice it—that is, how many of the goods
and services would go to each repub­
lic. As a result, each republic would
try to acquire as large a slice of the
total pie as possible both by receiving
goods produced in other republics
and by keeping locally produced
goods and services for consumption in
the republic. Thus, in the old planned
economy it was in each republic’s
interest to maximize imports into the
republic and minimize exports.
In a market economy, by contrast,
exports and prices are determined by
external demand for a region’s goods.
Higher levels of exports increase the
inflow of payments into a region and
increase economic activity. Conse­
quently, increased exports are general­
ly beneficial for a region’s economy.
Of course, countries in the process of
developing a market economy may
have to increase imports in the effort
to obtain resources needed for eco­
nomic development. However, the
status of trade in the CIS is more the
result of trade barriers enacted to
preserve the old system in which the
government controlled trade between
republics.
Currently in the CIS, trade between
republics is controlled by the same
ministries, discussed above, who con­
trol trade within republics. In many
cases, to export goods from republic A
to republic B, producers in A must sell
their goods to the government of A,
who sells them to the government of
B, who in turn sells them to consumers
in B. This process is less efficient than
allowing producers in A to contract
directly with consumers in B. Trade
between republics is similar to a barter

system, although the transactions in­
clude the exchange of rubles. For
example, republic A may agree to sell
wheat to republic B if B agrees to sell
oil to A. Republic A may agree to sell
wheat at a lower price than it could get
elsewhere, in order to get the oil. This
is similar to a barter system because it
is the exchange of goods which deter­
mines which transactions will take
place, rather than the price of the
goods involved. Trade agreements
may also be independent of demand.
Suppose, for example, that republic A
has a good that all the other republics
want. Then ministers from the other
republics will all come to A to try to
negotiate a trade. One would think
that A could then get a very high price
for its good, or at least the best barter.
However, what may actually happen is
that A will agree to trade with B be­
cause the ministers controlling trade
in A and B are friends. This happens
because the ministers do not gain
from selling goods at a higher price or
bartering for better goods.1You might
say that demand for a republic’s goods
does not increase prices, it only in­
creases ministers!
The implicit barter arrangements
between republics explains why many
prices in the CIS countries are below
world market prices in spite of price
liberalization. Government restric­
tions on most price movements were
eliminated in January 1992, except for
a few food items for low income fami­
lies and medical, educational, and
some other services. Nevertheless, the
price of natural gas in Turkmenistan,
for example, is 40 times lower than the
price in the world market. Such low
prices are the result of voluntary price
controls between republics. Each
republic views extreme price increases
as a threat to its economic survival.
Since the minimum price for one
republic’s output depends on the
input prices of other goods from other
republics, each republic fears a chain
reaction triggered by increases in any
input good. Consequently, the repub­
lics conspire to control prices. These
voluntary controls are possible only
because trade with foreign countries is
even more restricted than trade be­
tween republics.

Government control over trade be­
tween republics means that disputes
between republics have serious conse­
quences for trade. For example, no
trade takes place between the CIS
republics of Azerbaijan and Armenia
because of a territorial dispute. In
contrast, the citizens of Arab countries
can obtain Israeli goods so long as
they are willing to pay a high enough
price, in spite of the disputes between
Israel and her Arab neighbors.
The ministries claim that control over
trading is necessary in order to ensure
that the republics have a supply of the
necessary commodities. They argue
that the producers of goods are too
inexperienced to conduct trade. Of
course, the government officials also
don’t want to give up their positions of
power in the trading network. Like
the monopoly situation, the trade
situation is the result of a vicious circle.
The ministries preserve their control
over distribution both within and
between republics because there is no
other distribution system to replace it.
But so long as the ministries maintain
their control, a market system cannot
develop.
Conclusion

Problems with the microeconomic
institutions and mechanisms of the
CIS countries are inhibiting the move
toward capitalism. Neither the manag­
ers nor the government officials in
charge of regulation have the incen­
tives to increase profits of government
owned firms. Efforts toward privatiza­
tion have been hampered by the lack
of capital, the existence of monopo­
lies, and restrictions on trade within
and between republics. In particular,
change has been slowed by govern­
ment control of the distribution of
supplies and finished goods.
Creating smaller privately owned firms
and breaking up large firms would
help the move towards privatization
and reduce monopoly power. Increas­
ing the number of independent firms
would also encourage the develop­
ment of an independent distribution
system. Reducing monopoly power is
the first step in reducing government

control of distribution and encouraging
the development of a market system for
the distribution of goods.
Western countries could support the
creation of small and medium sized
firms through loan guaranties to entre­
preneurs willing to develop joint ven­
tures with CIS businesses. Western
countries could also make loans to
employees of CIS firms in order to en­
able employee buyouts of government
owned firms. Lower import tariffs
and fewer restrictions on CIS products
would encourage CIS governments to
move toward free trade. Free trade and
the development of a market economy
in the CIS countries will benefit Western
countries by providing new markets for
Western products in the CIS.
—Philip Israelevich
Philip Israelevich was bom in Riga, Latvia.
He received his masters in mathematical eco­
nomics from Novosibirsk University in Rus­
sia before emigrating to the U.S., where he
received his Ph.D. in economicsfrom the
University of Pennsylvania.
1The fact that trade between republics
often takes the form of barter does not
mean that the ruble has no market power,
as some economists have concluded. Rather,
as I have explained, the barter system is
the result of government officials adhering
to the old planned economy. Transactions
such as the payment of wages and trade
between individual producers and consum­
ers take place in rubles.

Karl A. S cheld, S enior Vice P re sid en t a n d
D irecto r o f R esearch; David R. A llardice, Vice
P re sid en t a n d A ssistant D irecto r o f R esearch;
C arolyn M cM ullen, E ditor.
Chicago Fed Letter is p u b lish ed m o n th ly by th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t o f th e F ed eral Reserve
B ank o f C hicago. T h e views ex p ressed are th e
a u th o rs ’ a n d are n o t necessarily th o se o f th e
F ederal Reserve B ank o f C hicago o r th e F ederal
Reserve System. A rticles m ay b e re p rin te d if
th e source is c re d ite d a n d th e R esearch
D e p a rtm e n t is pro v id ed with copies o f th e
rep rin ts.
Chicago Fed Letter is available w ith o u t ch arg e
from th e Public In fo rm atio n C e n te r, F ederal
Reserve B ank o f C hicago, P.O . Box 834,
C hicago, Illinois, 60690, (312) 322-5111.
ISSN 0895-0164

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

Midwest manufacturing activity in February staged its first significant increase
(up 1.2%) since September of last year. While gains were widespread, much of
the strength was centered in the metalworking and transportation sectors. In
addition, the labor component (hours worked) of the index led the capital com­
ponent (electrical power usage), offering encouragement that producers may be
gearing up for further production increases in the months ahead.
After lagging the nation in recent months, the MMI slightly outperformed the
national average (up 1.1%). The region benefitted from doing well in those
sectors, especially auto-related industries, where much of the growth nationally
was concentrated.

1990

1991

1992

N O TE: T h e MMI a n d th e USMI are co m p o site
indexes o f 17 m a n u fa c tu rin g in d u stries a n d are
d erived fro m e c o n o m etric m odels th a t estim ate
o u tp u t from m o n th ly h o u rs w orked a n d
kilow att h o u rs data. F or a discussion o f th e
m ethodology, see “R eco n sid erin g th e R egional
M an u factu rin g In d e x e s,” Economic Perspectives,
F ederal Reserve B ank o f C hicago, Vol. XIII,
No. 4, Ju ly /A u g u st 1989.

1115"S££ (£I£)
h£80“06909

o u i\\\ ‘o S e a iq s

F£8 x o g O d
j a i u a ^ u opeuL io ju j a ijq n j

OOVOIHO TO NNVH 3A33STH TV33Q33

4 T f P r]

p p j

( X o T 4 1 l |r )