View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Using Stock Returns to Identify
Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP 2009-03

Using Stock Returns to Identify
Government Spending Shocks∗
Jonas D.M. Fisher
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
jfisher@frbchi.org
Ryan Peters
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
ryan.peters@chi.frb.org
August 24, 2009

Abstract
This paper explores a new approach to identifying government spending
shocks which avoids many of the shortcomings of existing approaches. The
new approach is to identify government spending shocks with statistical innovations to the accumulated excess returns of large US military contractors.
This strategy is used to estimate the dynamic responses of output, hours, consumption and real wages to a government spending shock. We find that positive
government spending shocks are associated with increases in output, hours, and
consumption. Real wages initially decline after a government spending shock
and then rise after a year. We estimate the government spending multiplier
associated with increases in military spending to be about 0.6 over a horizon
of 5 years.
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: E0, E30, E60
Keywords: Government spending shocks, fiscal policy, stock returns

∗

The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. Without implicating, we thank
Marco Bassetto, Jeff Campbell, Valerie Ramey, Chris Sleet, François Velde and Sevin Yeltekin for
helpful conversations.

1

Introduction

A classic question in macroeconomics is: How does the economy respond to a change
in government spending? The answer to this question clearly is important from
a public policy perspective, particularly given current events. It is also important
because competing macroeconomic models make different predictions, and hence answering the question is helpful for choosing between these models. The magnitude
of the stakes has stoked much research. Yet, there is surprisingly little consensus on
what the answer to the question is. The lack of consensus derives from the fact that
the two main approaches to identifying government spending shocks lead to different
answers and that both have important shortcomings. This paper seeks to avoid the
shortcomings of the existing approaches and contribute to the debate in the literature
by developing and applying a new measure of government spending shocks based on
defense contractor stock returns.
One of the two main ways of identifying government spending shocks, often called
the narrative approach, was developed by Ramey and Shapiro (1997). These authors
argue that there are three dates when persistent increases in US military spending
were anticipated. By viewing the events precipitating the spending as exogenous,
these dates can be used to identify government spending shocks. Ramey and Shapiro
(1997) find that output and hours rise and consumption and real wages fall after
a spending shock, supporting the simple neoclassical view of the effects of government spending. These findings have been confirmed in subsequent work by Burnside,
Eichenbaum, and Fisher (2004), Cavallo (2005), Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher
(1999) and Eichenbaum and Fisher (2005). The principle advantages of the narrative
approach are the likely exogeneity of the spending episodes and that it takes into
account the anticipated nature of the government spending. However, there are some
clear shortcomings. These include the small number of observations, that the episodes
only involve spending increases, the need to assume that the spending is known with
certainty, and that the selection of the dates is inherently subjective. Recently Ramey
(2008) has expanded the set of dates, mitigating the first two shortcomings, but there
is little that can be done about the other two.
The second main way of identifying government spending is associated with Blanchard and Perotti (2002). Essentially, this involves identifying a government spending
2

shock with the Choleski innovation to government spending in a vector-autoregression
(VAR) with government spending ordered first. Many other papers have used this approach, including Berndt, Lustig, and Yeltekin (2009), Fatas and Mihov (2001), Gali,
Lopez Salido, and Valles (2007), Mountford and Uhlig (2002), Perotti (2002), and
Perotti (2007). The government spending innovations approach typically finds that
output, hours, consumption and real wages all rise after a positive government spending innovation. These findings are usually interpreted as supporting models where
sticky-prices play an important role. The principle advantages of this approach are
that there are many observations, both positive and negative shocks, and it is not as
subjective as the narrative approach. However, there is one important shortcoming.
This is that, as the narrative approach highlights, there are many cases where patterns
of government spending are anticipated before they are recorded in the data. Ramey
(2008) shows how failure to take into account the anticipated nature of changes in
government spending can lead to estimates of the response of consumption that are
of the wrong sign.
The identification strategy explored in this paper avoids the shortcomings of both
the narrative approach and the government spending innovation approach, at least in
principle. The idea is simple, intuitive and builds on the existing approaches. Like the
narrative approach, the starting premise is that there are intermittent disturbances to
current and expected future US military spending that can be treated as exogenous.
In the event of such a disturbance, current and expected future earnings of firms which
specialize in producing services and equipment for the military will change. Forward
looking agents incorporate expectations of sales into their valuation of the stocks of
these firms, thereby affecting the returns to holding these stocks. This suggests it may
be useful to use surprises in the returns of military contractors to identify government
spending shocks.
Of course, not all variation in military contractor stock returns is due to changing
expectations about military spending. Military contractors sell to the private sector
and so are influenced by the state of the economy. There is also idiosyncratic variation
in the stock of any single contractor due to success or failure in winning particular US
or foreign military contracts. These issues are addressed in several ways. First, we
identify innovations in government spending with innovations in military contractor
stock returns in excess of the market as a whole. We assume these innovations are
3

orthogonal to variables representing the state of the economy. Second, we use the
combined stock returns of multiple contractors. Third, we emphasize the returns of
large contractors that specialize in producing for the military. The stock returns of
these firms should be less driven by idiosyncratic contracting outcomes compared to
small contractors.
While this identification strategy certainly has some drawbacks, which we discuss
below, it should avoid the shortcomings of the existing approaches. Like the government spending innovation approach it increases the number of observations, includes
increases and decreases in defense spending and is less subjective than the narrative
approach. Importantly it is also immune to the Ramey critique of the government
spending innovation approach. Finally, unlike the narrative approach it incorporates
the inherent uncertainty involved in predicting the future path of defense spending.
These advantages suggest that it is worth investigating the implications of using contractor stock returns to address the government spending question.1
Our main results are based on the stock returns of military contractors that have
ever appeared in an annual listing of the top 3 military contractors by value of primary
contracts awarded in US government fiscal years from 1958 to 2007. A primary military contract is a contract directly with the military. The value of primary contracts
in any given year is an imperfect measure of the defense business of a firm since firms
will sub-contract pieces of a primary contract, and they will undertake sub-contract
work from primary contracts of other firms. Still, they are a useful indicator of the
magnitude of the defense business of any given contractor. To find our group of
contractors we have compiled listings of the top 100 primary military contractors
from 1958-2007 using a variety of government and private sources. The total sales of
contractors ever in the top 3 follow the contours of aggregate defense spending and
excess returns of these firms have superior explanatory power for defense spending
and government spending as a whole.
We find that after a positive excess return innovation, output, hours and consumption initially are roughly constant for several quarters, and then all rise in a
1

We are not the first to consider stock returns of the defense industry in the context of government
spending. Berndt et al. (2009) use the Fama-French “Guns” portfolio to help forecast government
spending. We discuss this below. In private correspondence Valerie Ramey describes preliminary
research into using defense industry stock returns to predict government spending. We call the
portfolio of stocks used by Ramey “Guns+” and discuss it below as well.

4

hump-shaped pattern. The results for wages are less clear cut. There is an initial
decline during the period when the other variables are essentially unchanged. After
this initial decline, wages rise persistently over the period when output, hours and
consumption are following their hump-shaped paths. We estimate the government
spending multiplier associated with increases in military spending to be about 0.6
over a horizon of 5 years. Overall, the results are closer to the government spending
innovation based findings than those based on the narrative approach, and they point
toward models that depart from the simple neoclassical paradigm.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. The next section describes the
dynamics of sales and stock returns of the military contractors which underlie the
analysis. In section three we describe and defend our identification strategy. Section
four contains the main results, compares them to findings based on the narrative
and government spending innovation approaches, and quantifies the contribution of
government spending shocks to macroeconomic fluctuations. Section five contains
some concluding remarks.

2

The Military Contractor Data

The stock returns used in this analysis are those for firms which specialize in munitions
and related equipment, and which are ever ranked in the top 3 in value of primary
contracts awarded in a given year. A prerequisite for determining these firms is to
compile lists of top contractors. The first sub-section describes how we do this. This
is followed by a description of the sales and stock returns of the firms which satisfy
the top 3 criterion. The third sub-section briefly relates the excess returns to the
military shocks described in Ramey (2008).

2.1

Compiling the Top 3 Military Contractors, 1958-2007

The main source for compiling the top contractor lists is the report “100 Companies
Receiving the Largest Dollar Volume of Prime Contract Awards” published by the
Department of Defense Directorate for Information Operations and Reports. The report presents summary data on the 100 companies and their subsidiaries receiving the
5

largest dollar volume of Department of Defense (DoD) prime contract awards during
the fiscal year for each year, starting in fiscal year 1958 and continuing until 1995.
These reports have been archived at the web site for the Defense Technical Information Center (www.dtic.mil). Unfortunately, not all of these reports are available.
The missing years are 1980, 1984-1987. Starting in 1996, the reports are available
online from the Department of Defense Personnel and Procurement Statistics web
site (siadapp.dmdc.osd.mil). The reports have been produced from individual prime
contracts, specifically DoD form DD350. Electronic copies of these forms are also
available from the Department of Defense Personnel and Procurement Statistics.
For the missing years 1984-1987 we used lists published in Defense Magazine. Each
year from 1983 to 1996 this publication contains an annual supplement documenting
the structure and finances of the DoD. This supplement includes an extract of the
“100 Largest Companies” report with just the parent company name and the volume
of prime contracts for the company and its subsidiaries. This is enough information
for our purposes.
For the missing year 1980 there is no summary data available. Fortunately, we
can go to the primary source – the DD350 forms originally used to produce the “100
Largest Companies” reports. The 1981 report has a list of companies that have
dropped off of the top 100 list since 1980 as well as a list of firms that are on the
list in 1981 but not 1980. Using these lists, it is trivial to construct the top 100 list
for 1980. Filling out the procurement numbers is only a matter of referencing the
subsidiary lists from 1979 and 1981 and adding up sales from all subsidiaries. There is
a chance that some subsidiaries have changed over the course of a year, but generally
subsidiaries do not change that often and are not that large a share of total military
sales.
On the top 100 lists are companies for which military contracts are not the main
source of revenue. For example, AT&T was a major military contractor for many
years, but this was a small portion of its business. We used two procedures to cull
firms from the list to avoid including firms whose stocks returns may be strongly
influenced by idiosyncratic industry developments with nothing to do with military
spending. First, we study just those firms in the lists which have a clear military

6

focus as determined by their SIC code.2 In practice this has little impact on the top 3,
eliminating just one firm, an automobile parts manufacturer named Tenneco. Second,
we exclude Boeing from the list. About half of Boeing’s business is commercial aircraft
and this business has its own low frequency movements that have a significant impact
on its sales and stock price, reducing its predictive power for future government
spending.3
The list of companies that appear in the top 3 of our refined listings for at least
one year, along with their SIC industry classification, and the years they appear in
the top 3, is reported in Table 1. The table indicates that fourteen companies have
been in the top 3 at one time or another. Due to mergers over the years these fourteen
companies are currently just five. Martin and Marietta (which is not listed in the
table) merged in 1961, and then the combined company merged with Lockheed in
1995. Grumman and Northrop merged in 1994. McDonnell Douglas merged with
Boeing (and so drops from our top 3) in 1996. We refer to the list of firms in Table
1 as the Top 3 firms.
A significant fraction of revenues for all these firms derives from military contracting, but, as the SIC descriptions suggest, they are also involved in the US space
program. Indeed many of these firms also appear at the top of listings of the value
of space contracts awarded. For example, Lockheed Martin, Raytheon and Northrop
Grumman are second, third and fourth on a listing of the top 50 space companies by
sales in 2002 published by Space News (Boeing is first on this list.) This is convenient
given that Ramey (2008) has used spending on the space program to augment the
original Ramey-Shapiro war dates. So the stock returns of these companies should
reflect anticipated space program spending as well and can be compared to the “space
dates” compiled by Ramey (2008).
2

The SIC codes we use are: 3482 – Small Arms Ammunition, 3483 – Ammunition, Except
for Small Arms, 3484 – Small Arms, 3489 – Ordinance and Accessories, Not Elsewhere Classified
(NEC), 3720 – Aircraft and Parts, 3721 – Aircraft, 3724 – Aircraft Engines and Engine Parts, 3728
– Aircraft Parts and Auxiliary Equipment NEC, 3730 – Ship and Boat Building and Repairing, 3760
– Guided Missiles and Space Vehicles and Parts, 3761 – Guided Missiles and Space Vehicles, 3764
– Guided Missile and Space Vehicle Propulsion Units and Propulsion Unit Parts, 3769 – Guided
Missile Space Vehicle Parts and Auxiliary Equipment NEC, 3795 – Tanks and tank components,
and 3812 – Search, Detection, Navigation, Guidance, Aeronautical Systems.
3
United Technologies also has a large non-defense business. However, this business is closely
aligned with the overall state of the economy which is accounted for by focusing on excess returns.

7

2.2

Top 3 Contractor Sales and Stock Returns

For the stock returns of our list of military contractors to be credible indicators of
total military spending their sales should line up well with the total. To examine
whether this is the case, consider Figure 1. This figure displays linearly detrended
real military spending and three measures of defense industry sales. These measures
are for ‘Top 3’, the firms in Table 1, ‘Guns,’ the firms in a subset of the industries
listed in footnote 2, and ‘Guns+’, the firms in all the industries listed in footnote 2.
The excluded industries in ‘Guns’ are 3720-3728, 3795 and 3812. We have included the
sales of Guns and Guns+ since they are plausible alternative portfolios to identify
government spending shocks with. The Guns category corresponds to the FamaFrench definition of the ‘Guns industry’ in their 48 industry portfolio. Berndt et al.
(2009) have used excess returns of these firms to help forecast future government
spending. The Guns+ variable includes additional defense-like industries and seems
to be a plausible perturbation to Guns. We obtain the sales data from COMPUSTAT.
Figure 1 indicates that Top 3 sales lines up very well with the main undulations
of military spending, but Guns and Guns+ sales do less well. The contemporaneous
correlation between sales and spending is .92, .34 and .43 for Top 3, Guns and Guns+
sales, respectively. The relatively poor alignment with military spending of Guns and
Guns+ is because using SIC codes alone to select a defense industry portfolio leads
to including firms having non-military businesses that dominate the overall dynamics
of the firm. For example, Guns includes Brunswick, a large maker of recreational
products including boats, and Taser, a maker of personal security devices. The very
high degree of co-movement with military spending of Top 3 sales emerges because
the military businesses dominate the dynamics of these firms. This strongly suggests
stock returns for the Top 3 portfolio will be a better indicator of expectations about
defense spending compared to stock returns for Guns or Guns+.
Now we describe the stock return series we use. Here we focus on the stock returns
of the Top 3 firms. Our measure of contractor stock returns is simply the marketvalue-weighted sum of total returns on the individual stocks. By total returns we
mean the return from both capital gains and dividends. We use the market value at
the beginning of the quarter to weight monthly holding period returns and accumulate
these returns over each quarter. Our overall market return indicator is the market8

value-weighted sum of total returns of all publicly traded firms. The source for these
data is CRSP. We define excess returns as the difference between the Top 3 returns
and the overall market return. Excess returns are very noisy and it is difficult to
discern low frequency movements with them. Consequently, we focus on accumulated
excess returns.
Before discussing the returns of the Top 3 as a whole, it is worth briefly considering the returns of the individual firms. These are displayed in Figure 2 along with
vertical lines indicating the Ramey-Shapiro war dates. The Ramey-Shapiro war dates
correspond to the Korean War (1950:3), the escalation of the Vietnam War (1965:1),
and the Carter-Reagan military build-up (1980:1). There is also a vertical line corresponding to the quarter of the 9/11 terrorist attacks, which has been considered
as a “war date” by Eichenbaum and Fisher (2005) and Ramey (2008). Accumulated
excess returns are normalized to unity in the first year the firm is listed in CRSP so
that values above unity reflect holding period returns in excess of the market from
the first date of returns.
Two observations on Figure 2 are worth making. First, the dynamics of the
individual returns are quite different, reflecting the idiosyncratic nature of defense
contracting and the differences in behavior of the firms’ other business lines. Second,
some of the firms make large excess returns over the sample. General Dynamics
has almost always fluctuated above break-even returns, and since 1990 has done
exceptionally well, so that the return from holding General Dynamics stock from
1947 to 2007 is more than 8 times the market. Northrop-Grumman has also done
very well, with holding period returns exceeding 10 over many periods. Most of the
other returns also do well.
Figure 3 displays accumulated excess returns of the Top 3 portfolio along with
real military spending and the war dates. Accumulated excess returns are normalized
to unity in 1947:1. The returns prior to 1958 are calculated using the list of firms in
Table 1 since we have no information prior to 1958 to add to the list. We make four
points about Figure 1.
First, as anticipated by Figure 2, the accumulated excess returns for the portfolio
of Top 3 firms are large. Had one followed the investment strategy of buy and hold
on the stocks of the firms in Table 1 starting in 1947:1 the accumulated excess return
9

would have been more than five times the overall market return by the end of 2007.4
Second, the excess returns closely match the Vietnam War date and the 9/11
date, but not the Korean War or Carter-Reagan dates. In the case of the Korean
War we see that military spending increased sixfold between 1950 and 1953. Yet
it was not until 1953 that excess return started to accumulate significantly. This
delayed response of Top 3 stock returns is not puzzling after one realizes that, as was
the case in World Wars I and II, excess profits tax legislation was enacted during the
Korean War. This legislation was effective from July 1 1950 to December 31 1953.
To the extent that “excess profits” were accurately determined by the legislation, the
absence of significant excess returns is understandable. This kind of legislation has
not been enacted since the Korean War, although there was an attempt during the
first Iraq War.
Third, movements in excess returns correctly forecast the persistent declines in
spending at the end of the Vietnam War and the end of the Carter-Reagan build-up.
It also appears that agents were anticipating a persistent rise in military spending
before the Carter-Reagan build-up was fully underway.
Fourth, there are some large movements in excess returns which are not followed
by future changes in spending which would rationalize the movements. The best example of this is dynamics of excess returns in the 1990s and early 2000s. Following
the first Iraq war, agents expected increases in military spending due to the success
of certain weapons systems during that war. This counteracted expectations of diminished spending following the end of the Cold War. When the new spending failed
to materialize there was a sharp drop in excess returns in the latter part of the 1990s,
reflecting a general perception that post Cold War military spending would not rise
to levels seen during the Reagan years. Anticipation of military spending under a
George W. Bush administration partially offset these declines in returns, before 9/11
and then the second Iraq War led to widespread expectations of increased military
spending that are reflected in large excess returns.
The last two points highlight key benefits, relative to the narrative approach, of
4

A regression of the Top 3 returns on a constant and the overall market return over the sample
1947:1 2007:4 yields a constant equal to .012 (robust standard error .006) and slope coefficient equal
to .98 (.09). Over the sample period beginning in 1957:3 we focus on below, the estimates are .009
(.006) and .95 (.09).

10

using military contractor stock returns to measure expectations of future military
spending. The stock returns capture expectations of declines in spending, which the
original narrative approach does not. They also incorporate unrealized expectations,
which are largely ignored in the narrative approach.

2.3

Excess Returns and Ramey’s Military Shocks

To gain more insight into how contractor excess returns and the narrative approach
are related, Figure 4 displays accumulated Top 3 excess returns along with the new
military shock series described in Ramey (2008). This series is the result of a careful
analysis of the historical record to determine when revisions to expectations of future
military and space program spending may have occurred, and by how much those
expectations changed. The series is zero on all dates except those determined to
correspond to revisions in expectations. The series on these dates equals the expected
present value of the revision in spending scaled by the nominal value of government
spending in the previous period. Each plot in the figure displays a window of dates
over the sample 1947-2007 where the windows encompass the entire sample.
The top-left plot shows the failure of excess returns to respond to the onset of the
Korean War we have already discussed. The remainder of the plots indicate there are
few examples where the stock returns obviously reflect the military shocks compiled
in Ramey (2008) and in no case is there the sharp, persistent change in stock returns
expected with discrete revisions to expectations. One case where the stock returns
match the shock is 1980:1 (top-right), when excess returns and the shock series both
spike. Still, there were movements in stock returns prior to 1980:1 which suggest
the information that military spending would be rising was revealed over several
quarters. In addition returns fall in the quarter after 1980:1. This suggests there was
uncertainty about the magnitude of the future spending. There are spikes in returns
on the dates corresponding to the two space program shocks in the Ramey (2008)
series, 1957:4 (Sputnik) and 1961:2 (Moon mission), middle-left plot. But, these are
also followed by subsequent declines, and, as evident in the other plots as well, the
variation in the excess returns is just as large on dates where the shock series is zero
as it is when the shock series is non-zero. In many cases, for example the two middle
plots, excess returns do not qualitatively match the magnitude of the military shock
11

- smaller shocks have similar or greater excess returns associated with them than
nearby larger shocks. Finally, there are examples where the timing in the shock series
appears to be off. In the top-right plot the shock in 1981:1 appears to be anticipated
by a quarter. In the lower-right plot the 2001:3 shock appears to be one quarter too
early.
The overall impression from Figure 4 is that the shock series and the excess returns
do not correspond well. This could reflect that the excess returns are a poor measure
of expected future military spending. In our view it reflects the fact that the process
of information revelation by which expectations about future military spending evolve
is more nuanced than the stark determination indicative of the narrative approach.
This is not to say one approach is definitively superior to the other, but that there is
a strong case to be made for considering using excess returns to identify government
spending shocks.

3

Identifying Government Spending Shocks with
Stock Return Data

In this section we build a case for using the stock returns of firms on our top 3 military
contractor list to identify government spending shocks and then describe how we go
about doing so.

3.1

The Explanatory Power of Top 3 Excess Returns

A key test of whether our excess returns measure is useful for identifying government
spending shocks is its explanatory power for government spending and other macro
variables. Our procedure for evaluating explanatory power follows Ramey (2008).
In particular, we regress variables to be predicted on current and lagged values of
the indicator variable in question. Table 2 reports R2 for these regressions using five
indicator variables to predict military spending, overall government spending, GDP
and non-durable and services consumption. The top panel is based on the sample
1948:1–2007:4 and the second panel on the sample 1957:3-2007:4, which corresponds
to the sample we have data for compiling our Top 3 list. All the predicted variables
12

are log first differences after first dividing by population.
The five indicator variables include three log accumulated excess return series
and two narrative based series. The excess return series correspond to portfolios of
Top 3, Guns and Guns+ firms as defined above. We include the additional excess
return series because they are natural stock return based alternatives to Top 3. The
narrative series are the Ramey-Shapiro war dates plus the 9/11 date, ‘War Dates,’
and the new military shock series introduced in Ramey (2008), ‘Shocks.’
Consider the top panel of Figure 2. This shows the clear superiority in explanatory
power of the narrative variables. The explanatory power of the Shock series for
military and overall government spending is particularly striking. The stock return
variables perform substantially worse over this sample period. This performance was
anticipated by our discussion of the Korean War episode and the role played by the
excess profits tax during that time.
In the bottom panel of Figure 2 we see that the explanatory power of Top 3, Guns,
and Guns+ for military and total government spending is greater in the later subsample. It is substantially greater for Top 3 and Guns, and Top 3 is has somewhat
better explanatory power for military spending compared to Guns+. There is only
a slight improvement in the explanatory power for Guns. All three stock return
indicators show modest improvements in explanatory power for the other variables
in the table. The narrative series perform much worse once the Korean War episode
is excluded. Both series have very poor explanatory power for military and overall
government spending compared to the stock return indicators. The explanatory power
for output and consumption of the war date variable is somewhat better than the stock
variables, but it is worse for Shocks.
We conclude that for military and total government spending, Top 3 and Guns+
are clearly superior to Guns and the two narrative variables over the sample period
we think the stock return series have a chance of being useful for identifying shocks
to government spending. The Top 3 returns are marginally better than the Guns+
returns at explaining the government spending variables. This motivates our focus
on the Top 3 returns for identifying government spending shocks.

13

3.2

Identification of Government Spending Shocks

We identify government spending shocks with the Choleski innovation to the log of
the accumulated Top 3 excess return series in VARs including several macroeconomic
variables representing the state of the economy, where the excess return variable is
ordered last. Thus innovations to government spending are identified with innovations
to Top 3 excess returns which are orthogonal to the state of the economy. Assuming
that the macroeconomic variables in the VARs are a good representation of the state
of the economy, this strategy should identify shocks to government spending well if
(i) technological progress in production (costs) at the Top 3 firms evolves in the same
way as in the rest of the economy, (ii) Top 3 mark-ups do not behave differently than
in the rest of the economy, (iii) variation in sales of the Top 3 firms are dominated
by shocks to defense spending. The third condition is verified by Figure 1.
The second two conditions are more questionable. One concern about condition (i)
may be that the Top 3 firms are largely involved in producing capital equipment. Since
relative prices of capital equipment have been declining over the sample, this suggests
the production technology in the defense industry may be improving at a faster rate
compared to the rest of economy. Condition (ii) might also be viewed as problematic
given the large excess returns of the Top 3 and of political considerations which may
have boosted profits in the defense industry. We address these concerns about (i) and
(ii) by including linear trends in the VAR. By doing this we are essentially hoping that
any remaining idiosyncratic variation in stock returns is overwhelmingly dominated
by (exogenous) variation in demand for the military products of the Top 3 firms,
rather than idiosyncratic technology or mark-up shocks.
We use quarterly data. The first left-hand-side observation in our VARs is 1959:1
and the last observation is 2007:4. In the VARs discussed below we use six lags. So
the first lagged observation is 1957:3. This corresponds to the first quarter of the
fiscal year 1958, the first year we have a listing of the top 100 primary military contractors. The starting date for the analysis represents a departure from the literature
and so deserves some discussion. Previous work uses 1947:1 or 1948:1 as the first
quarter of the analysis. We use the later starting date for several reasons. First,
the quarter 1957:3 is the first for which we have information on the top 3 military
contractors. Second, this date excludes the Korean War episode. We think this is ap14

propriate given our previous discussion of the use of the excess profits tax during this
war. We also think it is appropriate to exclude the Korean War episode because the
increase in military spending associated with this episode appears to be a permanent
shock. Military spending increases more than sixfold during the Korean War and is
maintained at elevated levels thereafter. Later waves of per capita military spending
appear to be temporary fluctuations around a permanently higher level. It therefore
seems worthwhile to assess the impact of excluding the Korean War and focusing on
a later sample.
A related argument for beginning the sample in the late 1950s is that this appears
to be a watershed period in the economic history of the US. Essentially, it marks the
beginning of the modern defense industry. President Eisenhower makes this point in
his farewell address on January 17, 1961:
Our military organization today bears little relation to that known by
any of my predecessors in peacetime, or indeed by the fighting men of
World War II or Korea. Until the latest of our world conflicts, the United
States had no armaments industry. American makers of plowshares could,
with time and as required, make swords as well. But now we can no longer
risk emergency improvisation of national defense; we have been compelled
to create a permanent armaments industry of vast proportions.
From this perspective, it seems difficult to make the case to begin the sample any
earlier than the late 1950s, if one wants to identify government spending shocks using
variables related to military spending.

4

New Estimates of the Economy’s Response to a
Government Spending Shock

This section describes our main findings. We describe the responses of output, consumption, hours and wages to an identified government spending shock. After this
we quantify the contribution of our identified shocks to macroeconomic fluctuations.
Finally, we relate our estimated responses to those obtained using alternative identifications.
15

4.1

Main Findings

The dynamic responses to the shocks are estimated in VARs which, in addition to
our Top 3 accumulated excess returns variable, include logs of per capita military
spending and GDP, the log of the nominal gross three month treasury bill rate, plus
one additional variable we wish to estimate the response of. The additional variable
is one of the following: the logs of per capita hours worked, chain weighted consumption of nondurables and services, and total government spending, and real product
wages. The population and hours measures are the ones described in Francis and
Ramey (2008). The population measure is adjusted for changes in the demographic
composition of the workforce and the hours measure is for the economy as a whole.
The wage measure is private business wages deflated by the price deflator for the
private business sector.5 The VARs include six lags and a linear time trend. We
use six lags because the impulse responses are more precisely estimated compared to
cases with fewer lags. The qualitative findings are similar with four or five lags. We
include linear trends since that is the usual practise in the literature. Similar results
also are obtained including variables in first differences. The qualitative nature of the
results are also robust to including inflation and taxes in the VAR.
Figure 5 and 6 display our main findings. The blue lines are point estimates
of responses to one standard deviation innovations to the accumulated excess return variable, that is our measure of government spending shocks. The green lines
demarcate 68% posterior probability regions which contain the true responses with
approximately 2/3 probability. This is the criteria advocated by Sims and Zha (1999)
for assessing the plausibility of estimated impulse response functions. The units of
the responses are percent deviations from the un-shocked path of the variable.
The responses in Figure 5 confirm our finding from Table 2 that the excess returns
variable is a good forecaster of future military and total government spending. If this
were not true we would have little confidence that the estimated responses for the
5

The population and hours series were obtained from Valerie Ramey’s website. The remaining
variables were obtained from the Haver Analytics Database. The series names are: real military
spending – GFDH, real total government spending – GH, real output – GDPH, nominal nondurable
consumption – CN, real nondurable consumption, – CNH, nominal services consumption – CS, real
services consumption – CSH, compensation in private business – LXBC, and deflator for private
business – LXBI.

16

other variables reflect the effects of government spending shocks. A one standard
deviation shock to excess returns is associated with hump-shaped positive spending
responses, peaking after about three years. The peak response of military spending
is about 2% and of total government spending is about 3/4%.
Figure 6 indicates that the hump-shaped government spending paths are associated with delayed hump-shaped positive responses of output, hours and consumption.
In all three cases it takes about a little over a year before economic activity starts to
rise. The response of wages is quite different. During the period when the activity
variables are essentially unchanged, real wages drop by about .2%. Just prior to the
expansion in activity, wages start to rise until after about two years the response is
positive for the remainder of the response horizon of five years. However, given the
probability bands encompass zero after six quarters, it is hard to rule out that the
real wage returns to its pre-shock path, rather than rising above it.

4.2

Quantifying the Effects of Government Spending Shocks

There are three ways we quantify the effects of our identified government spending
shocks. We focus on output, but the magnitudes are similar for consumption and
hours. The first approach is to consider government spending multipliers. For this we
calculate the accumulated responses of military spending, total government spending
and output over the five year horizon used for the impulse responses. These are 30%,
10% and 3%, respectively. The average values over our estimation sample of military
and total government spending’s nominal shares of output are 6.7% and 20%. It
follows that the military spending multiplier is about (.03/.3) × (1/.067) = 1.5. That
is, one dollar of extra military spending translates to 1.5 dollars of output. Using
total government spending the multiplier is .6.
The second way we quantify the effects of government spending is to consider
forecast error decompositions. Since the responses in Figure 6 are relatively small,
the identified spending shocks explain under 10% of the forecast error variance of
output, hours and consumption over a 5 year horizon.
Still, there is the possibility that spending shocks have larger effects in particular periods. The third way we quantify the effects of spending shocks is to consider
17

historical decompositions during the three war date episodes in our sample, the Vietnam War, the Carter-Reagan build-up and post 9/11. Figure 7 displays the actual
log levels of total government spending and output and the values of these variables
predicted by assuming only the estimated excess return shocks are realized. In both
cases the paths predicted as of the information one period prior to the last date before
the plots begin have been subtracted out.
Figure 7 shows that during the Vietnam War the contribution of government
spending to the deviation from output was quite substantial for about three years.
During the “growth recession” of 1967 it appears as if government spending prevented
the economy from entering a full-blown recession. The impact of the Carter-Reagan
build-up was relatively small, raising the level of output by a maximum of just .68%,
as output was tumbling by over 5% relative to trend. After 9/11 the effects of the
increase in spending appear more significant, having a noticeable impact during the
nascent recovery in 2003 and 2004.

4.3

Comparison with Alternative Identification Strategies

We now address how our findings compare to those obtained using the main alternative identification strategies. Since our sample period begins later than is typical in
the literature, we need to re-estimate the impulse responses of interest with the alternative identifications. We focus on the original war date and statistical innovation
based approaches, and omit from the analysis estimates based on the military shock
series created by Ramey (2008). With our sample period we were unable to obtain
estimates of the responses of output and hours which are significantly different from
zero with the military shock series. For the two alternative identification strategies
we do consider, we study specifications we view to be representative of how these
approaches have been applied in the literature.
For the narrative approach, we use the estimation procedure described in Eichenbaum and Fisher (2005). They estimate VARs with current and lagged values of a
dummy variable equal to zero everywhere except the war dates. Impulse responses
are identified as the simulated response of the system to the onset of a war episode.
Eichenbaum and Fisher (2005) weight the war dates by their eventual magnitude. We
assign a value of 1 for the Vietnam War date and 1/3 to the Carter-Reagan date and
18

the 9/11 date. These values are consistent with the ones considered by Eichenbaum
and Fisher (2005) and Ramey (2008). The variables in the VAR are the same as in
our baseline specification, except we drop the excess return variable. As in recent
applications of this approach, for example Perotti (2007), we use four lags of the
endogenous variables and six lags of the war dummy.
For the government spending innovation based approach we consider a single VAR
ordered as total government spending, output, consumption, hours, wages and the
interest rate. We identify the government spending shock with the Choleski innovation
to government spending. As in recent applications of this approach we estimate the
VAR using four lags, c.f. Perotti (2007) and Ramey (2008).6
The results we obtain are displayed in Figures 8 and 9. These are formatted in
the same way as Figures 5 and 6. The striking feature of these figures is how closely
the responses resemble our baseline estimates, at least qualitatively. Output, hours
and consumption all rise, after a delay. Wages initially fall during the delay in the
responses of the quantity variables and rise thereafter, eventually turning positive.
The main departure from the baseline is that the decline in wages is very short-lived
with the government spending innovation approach. Another difference is the timing
of the delay in the sustained increases in output, consumption and hours. Still, when
viewed overall these estimates line up quite well with our baseline responses.
The findings for the innovation-based approach are not that different from previous
results reported in the literature. So these findings do not appear to be sensitive to the
inclusion of the Korean War period. However, the results for the narrative approach
are different from those emphasized in the literature. The narrative approach is
usually associated with declines in both consumption and wages. An obvious question
is whether our particular implementation of the narrative approach underlies the
differences in our findings. It does not. We have confirmed that if we extend our
sample back to 1948 then consumption and wages fall.7
That our findings can be reconciled with the narrative approach suggests that
6

Unlike our baseline VARs, including six lags of the endogenous variables with the alternative
identifications lowers the precision of the estimates. The qualitative features of the responses are
similar with six lags.
7
We are not the first to notice this sensitivity to sample period selection. Perotti (2007) finds the
sign of the response of consumption under the narrative approach depends on whether the Korean
War date is in the sample.

19

the critique of the government spending innovation approach made by Ramey (2008)
may not be serious in practise. This is consistent with recent work by Ravn and
Mertens (2009). These authors develop an empirical procedure for handling anticipated government spending shocks in a VAR setting and show that results based
on the government spending innovation identification strategy are not substantially
affected by implementing their procedure.

5

Conclusion

In this paper we have introduced a new way to measure shocks to government spending
and have used it to revisit the question of how the US economy responds to such a
shock. We have emphasized that our new measure, based on the stock returns of
large military contractors, avoids the main shortcomings of the available alternatives.
Our new measure predicts that, after a delay, output, hours and consumption all
rise following an identified positive shock to government spending. Real wages fall
during the period of delayed response of the quantity variables and then start to
rise. We have confirmed the most widely used alternative approaches to identifying
government spending shocks lead to quite similar responses, once the sample period
is restricted to exclude the Korean War.
We are encouraged by the fact that the three different approaches, which involve
different identifying assumptions, lead to similar answers once the Korean War is
excluded from the sample, since we think there are good reasons for doing so. Therefore, it seems reasonable to conclude that the weight of the evidence is starting to
point to the view that the response of the economy to a government spending shock is
inconsistent with the simple neoclassical growth model. The exact set of assumptions
needed to reconcile theory with findings such as those reported in this paper is an
important task for future research.
We conclude by emphasizing the kind of lesson we think readers should take
from an empirical analysis of government spending shocks which focuses on military
spending. As we emphasize in the introduction, there are two reasons to be interested
in the findings reported here. One reason is that it is interesting from a public policy
perspective to know how government spending, including military spending, affects
20

the economy. The second reason is that knowledge of the response of the economy to
a particular kind of shock is useful for distinguishing between alternative economic
models.
In our view, the main advantage of focusing on military spending is that it addresses a very specific kind of fiscal experiment that is easy to replicate in a model:
an exogenous change in government spending where that spending is a pure drain on
production. While advantageous in this respect, it does mean the analysis is probably not useful for understanding other, policy relevant, kinds of government spending
shocks. So it is important to keep in mind that the empirical findings of this paper should not be used to understand how the economy responds to, among other
possibilities, shocks to spending on transfers, education, health, or infrastructure.

21

References
Berndt, A., H. N. Lustig, and S. Yeltekin (2009). Does the us government hedge
against fiscal risk? Carnegie-Mellon University manuscript.
Blanchard, O. and R. Perotti (2002). An empirical characterization of the dynamic
effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal
of Economics November, 1329–1368.
Burnside, C., M. Eichenbaum, and J. D. Fisher (2004). Fiscal shocks and their
consequences. Journal of Economic Theory 115, 89–117.
Cavallo, M. (2005). Government employment expenditure and the effects of fiscal
policy shocks. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper 2005-16.
Edelberg, W., M. Eichenbaum, and J. D. Fisher (1999). Understanding the effects of
a shock to government purchases. Review of Economic Dynamics 2 (1), 166–206.
Eichenbaum, M. and J. D. Fisher (2005). Fiscal policy in the aftermath of 9/11.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37 (1), 1–22.
Fatas, A. and I. Mihov (2001). The effects of fiscal policy on consumption and
employment: Theory and evidence. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2760.
Francis, N. and V. A. Ramey (2008). A century of work and leisure. American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. Forthcoming.
Gali, J., D. Lopez Salido, and J. Valles (2007). Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 5,
227–270.
Mountford, A. and H. Uhlig (2002). What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks.
CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3380.
Perotti, R. (2002). Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in oecd countries. CEPR
Discussion Paper No. 3380.
Perotti, R. (2007). In search of the transmission mechanism of fiscal policy. NBER
Macroeconomics Annual .
22

Ramey, V. (2008). Identifying government spending shocks: It’s all in the timing.
University of California, San Diego Manuscript.
Ramey, V. A. and M. Shapiro (1997). Costly capital reallocation and the effects of
government spending. Carnegie Rochester Conference on Public Policy.
Ravn, M. O. and K. Mertens (2009). Anticipation of fiscal policy. University of
Southampto manuscript.
Sims, C. A. and T. Zha (1999). Error bands for impulse responses. Econometrica 67 (5).

23

Table 1: Firms that are Ever Among the Top 3 US Military Contractors
Primary Contractor

SIC Industry

Years in Top 3

General Dynamics

Ship and Boat Building,
Repairing

1958 -1962, 1965 -1971,
1974 -1974, 1978 -1992

Grumman

Aircraft

1970 -1972

Lockheed Aircraft,
Lockheed (1977 -1994),
Lockheed Martin (1995 -)

Guided Missiles,
Space Vehicle, Parts

1958 -1977, 1983 -1987,
1992 -2007

Martin,
Martin Marietta (1961 -1993)

Guided Missiles,
Space Vehicle, Parts

1959 -1962, 1993

McDonnell Aircraft,
Aircraft
McDonnell Douglas (1966 -1996)

1963 -1964, 1966,
1968 -1969, 1971 -1996

Northrop,
Northrop Grumman (1994 -)

Search, Detection,
Navigation, Guidance,
Aeronautical Systems

1975, 1992,
1994 -2007

Raytheon

Search, Detection,
Navigation, Guidance
Aeronautical Systems

1988 -1991, 1996,
1998 -2000

United Aircraft,
United Technologies (1969 -)

Aircraft, Parts

24

1958, 1966 -1968,
1975 -1982

Table 2: Explanatory Power (R2 ) of Indicators of Government Spending
Variable

Military Spending
Government Spending
Output
Consumption

Military Spending
Government Spending
Output
Consumption

Top 3

.07
.08
.03
.05

.21
.11
.08
.05

Guns Guns+ War Dates Shocks

.05
.02
.03
.06

1948:1–2007:4
.06
.26
.03
.24
.03
.08
.06
.08

.58
.56
.07
.12

.07
.04
.06
.06

1957:3–2007:4
.17
.06
.11
.02
.06
.09
.05
.09

.09
.06
.03
.03

Note: The reported R2 ’s are based on regressions of the predicted variable on the
current value and six lags of the indicator variable. Variables are log first differences
after first dividing by population. The first three indicators are log accumulated
excess returns. ‘Top 3’ corresponds to the firms in Table 1, ‘Guns’ corresponds to
firms with SIC codes included in footnote 2 excluding 3720-3728, 3795 and 3812, and
‘Guns+’ is the returns of all the firms with SIC codes listed in footnote 2. The war
dates are the original Ramey-Shapiro dates plus the 9/11 date. The ‘Shocks’ is the
Ramey (2008) military shocks variable described in the text.

25

100

20

50

10

0

0

-50

-10

-100

Sales

Spending

Figure 1: Detrended Defense Industry Sales and Military Spending, 1958-2007

-20
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

Military Spending

1990

1995

2000

2005

Top 3 Sales

100
6
2

0

-2

-50
-100

-6
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

Military Spending

1990

1995

2000

2005

Guns Sales

100

40

50

20

0

0

-50

-20

-100

-40
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

Military Spending

26

1985

1990

1995

Guns+ Sales

2000

2005

Sales

Spending

Sales

Spending

50

Figure 2: Accumulated Excess Returns of the Top 3 Contractors, 1947-2007
General Dynamics

McDonnell/McDonnell Douglas

8

8

8

6

6

8

6

6

4

4

4

4

2

2

2

2

0

0

0

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

0
1950

Grumman
6

4

4

2

2

0

0
1960

1970

1980

1970

1980

1990

2000

Northrop/Northrop Grumman

6

1950

1960

1990

30

30

25

25

20

20

15

15

10

10

5

5

0

2000

0
1950

1960

Lockheed/Lockheed Martin

1970

1980

1990

2000

Raytheon

6

6

5

5

5

5

4

4

4

4

3

3

3

3

2

2

2

2

1

1

1

1

0

0

0

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

0
1950

1960

1970

Martin/Martin Marietta

1980

1990

2000

United

1.2

1.2

1.0

1.0

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.0

0.0
1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

8

8

6

6

4

4

2

2

0

2000

0
1950

27

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Figure 3: Accumulated Excess Returns and Military Spending, 1947-2007
400

6

350
5

4
250

200

3

150
2
100
1
50

0

0
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
Military Spending

Accumulated Excess Returns

28

Excess Returns

Military Spending, $2000

300

Figure 4: Excess Returns and Ramey (2008)’s Government Spending Shocks, 19472007
5
2.75

4

2.25

3
2

1.75

1
1.25

0

0.75

-1

4.4
4.2
4.0
3.8
3.6
3.4
3.2
3.0
2.8

1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954
0.30

5.0

3.25

0.25

4.5

0.20

4.0

0.15

3.5

0.10

3.0

0.05

2.5

0.00

2.0

4.0

0.3

3.5

0.2

3.0

0.1

6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0

2.75
2.50
2.25
2.00
1.75
1955

1957

1959

1961

1963

0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.2
0.1
-0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
1986

2.5

0.0

2.0

-0.1

1.5

-0.2

1.0

0.30

1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985

3.50
3.00

0.35

-0.3
1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976

1988 1990 1992 1994 1996

1998
0.200
0.150
0.100
0.050
0.000

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

Note: Blue Line (left scale) is accumulated excess returns, Green Line (right scale) is
Ramey (2008) Military Shocks.

29

Figure 5: Effects of Government Spending Shocks Using Excess Returns
Military Spending
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
5

10

15

20

Total Government Spending
1.2
0.8
0.4
0.0
5

10

15

20

Note: Blue lines – point estimates, green lines – 68% posterior probability bands.

30

Figure 6: Effects Of Government Spending Shocks Using Excess Returns
Output

Hours

0.6

0.5

0.5

0.4

0.4
0.3

0.3
0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.0
0.0

-0.1
-0.2

-0.1
5

10

15

20

5

Private Consumption

10

15

20

15

20

Product Wage

0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10
-0.15

0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
5

10

15

20

5

10

Note: Blue Lines – Point Estimates, Green Lines – 68% Posterior Probability Bands.

31

Figure 7: Historical Effects of Government Spending Shocks
Total Government Spending

Output

15.0
12.5
10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
-2.5

6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
1965

1966

1967

1968

1965

1969

2

1966

1967

1968

1969

1

1

-1

0
-1

-3

-2

-5

-3
-4

-7
1980

1981

1982

1983

2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0

1984

1980

1981

1982

1983

1984

2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
2002

2003

2004

2005

2002

2003

2004

2005

Note: Blue Lines – Actual deviation from trend, Green Lines – Deviation from trend
predicted by spending shocks.

32

Figure 8: Effects of Government Spending Shocks Using War Dates
Output

Hours

7

5

6

4

5

3

4

2

3

1

2
1

0

0

-1

-1

-2
5

10

15

20

5

Private Consumption

10

15

20

15

20

Product Wages

3.0

3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5

2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
5

10

15

20

5

10

Note: Blue lines – point estimates, green lines – 68% posterior probability bands.

33

Figure 9: Effects of Government Spending Shocks Using Spending Innovations
Output

Hours

0.6

0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10

0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
5

10

15

20

5

Private Consumption

10

15

20

15

20

Product Wages

0.5

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.0

0.0

-0.1

-0.1

-0.2
5

10

15

20

5

10

Note: Blue lines – point estimates, green lines – 68% posterior probability bands.

34

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan
Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-18

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

WP-08-08

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

5