View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE 1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF
THE PRESIDENT

Mt

HEARINGS
BEFORE THE

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
NINETY-SIXTH CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION

PART 3
FEBRUARY 22, 23, 28, AND MARCH 2 AND 8, 1979

Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee

0

,

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
47-977 0

WASHINGTON: 1979

For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20402

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
LLOYD BENTSEN, Texas, Chairman
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri, Vice Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

SENATE
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
EDWARD M. KENNEDY, Massachusetts
GEORGE McGOVERN, South Dakota
PAUL S. SARBANES, Maryland
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
WILLIAM V. ROTH, JR., Delaware
JAMES A. McCLURE, Idaho
ROGER W. JEPSEN, Iowa

HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
LEE H. HAMILTON, Indiana
GILLIS W. LONG, Louisiana
PARREN J. MITCHELL, Maryland
CLARENCE J. BROWN, Ohio
MARGARET M. HECKLER, Massachusetts
JOHN H. ROUSSELOT, California
CHALMERS P. WYLIE, Ohio

JOHN R. STARK, Executive Director
Louts C. KRAUTHOFF II, Assistant Director-Director,SSEC
RICHARD F. KAUFMAN, Assistant Director-GeneralCounsel
CHARLES H. BRADFORD, Minority Counsel

(11)

CONTENTS
WITNESSES AND STATEMENTS
THURSDAY, FEBRUARY

22, 1979

Mitchell, Hon. Parren J., member of the Joint Economic Committee, presiding:
Opening statement.......................................................................................................
Byrom, Fletcher L., chairman, board of trustees, Committee for Economic
Development, and chairman, Koppers Co., Inc ......................................................
Jenkins, George P., chairman of the board, Metropolitan Life Insurance Co .....
Schott, Francis H., chairman, Finance and Currency Committee, New York
Chamber of Commerce and Industry ................................................................
FRIDAY, FEBRUARY

WEDNESDAY, FEBRUARY

2
11
14

39
40
48
61
73

28, 1979

Bentsen, Hon. Lloyd, chairman of the Joint Economic Committee: Opening
statement......................................................................................................................
Thompson, Hon. James R., Governor, State of Illinois .............................................
Snelling, Hon. Richard A., Governor, State of Vermont ..........................................
Hunt, Hon. James B., Jr., Governor, State of North Carolina .............
..................

101
121
208
217

2, 1979

Bolling, Hon. Richard, vice chairman of the Joint Economic Committee: Opening statement ...............................................................
Oswald, Rudolph, research director, American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organizations, accompanied by Kenneth Young, director,
legislative department ..............
.................................................
Young, Howard, special consultant to the president, UAW, accompanied by
Jerry Tucker, legislative office .........................
......................................
THURDSAY, MARCH

241
243
308

8, 1979

Mitchell, Hon. Parren J., member of the Joint Economic Committee, presiding:
Opening statement.......................................................................................................
Brown, Hon. Clarence J., member of the Joint Economic Committee: Opening
statement......................................................................................................................
Kreps, Hon. Juanita M., Secretary of Commerce .....................................................
Marshall, Hon. Ray, Secretary of Labor ..............................
Brown, Ronald H., vice president, National Urban League, on behalf of the Full
Employment Action Council ....................
(I11)

1

23, 1979

Bentsen, Hon. Lloyd, chairman of the Joint Economic Committee: Opening
statement......................................................................................................................
Bosworth, Barry P., Director, Council on Wage and Price Stability ....... :.............
Keyserling, Leon H., former Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers, and
president, Conference on Economic Progress .........................................................
Mitchell, Daniel J. B., senior fellow, the Brookings Institution, and professor,
Graduate School of Management, UCLA ...............................................................
Weintraub, Sidney, professor of economics, University of Pennsylvania .............

FRIDAY, MARCH

Page

365
366
367
387
430

IV
SUBMISSIONS FOR THE RECORD
THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 22, 1979
Page

Byrom, Fletcher L.: Prepared statement.....................................................................
Jenkins, George P.: Prepared statement ................................................................
Schott, Francis H.: Prepared statement......................................................................
23, 1979

FRIDAY, FEBRUARY

Bosworth, Barry P.:
..................................................
Prepared statement ..............
Response to additional written questions posed by Representative Hamilton ...............................................................
Keyserling, Leon H.: Prepared statement...................................................................
Mitchell, Daniel J. B.: Prepared statement................................................................
Weintraub, Sidney: Prepared statement, together with an appendix ...................
WEDNESDAY, FEBRUARY

45
97
52
63
77

28, 1979

Bentsen, Hon. Lloyd:
Charts:
State government fiscal condition, fiscal years 1977-79 ...........................
State government expenditures, 1977-79 .....................................................
Federal expenditures, 1977-79 ...............................................................
State-Own source tax revenues, 1975-78 ...................................................
Memorandum from the National Governors' Association, dated November
28,1978, to Hon. James T. McIntyre, Jr., Director, Office of Management
and Budget, suggesting criteria for curbing spending in a way that
.........
minimizes the adverse effect on State and local governments ..........
Hunt, Hon. James B., Jr.: Prepared statement ..........................................................
Snelling, Hon. Richard A.: Prepared statement ........................................................
Thompson, Hon. James R.:
.................................................
Prepared statement ..............
Analysis of the President's budget prepared by the National Governors'
Association entitled "The Proposed Fiscal '80 Federal Budget: Impact on
the States ...............................................................
FRIDAY, MARCH

3
12
15

104
105
105
105

106
222
212
127
133

2, 1979

Oswald, Rudolph, et al.: Prepared statement, together with appendix
material .249
Reuss, Hon. Henry S.: Table presenting fiscal 1980 budget allocation for the
proposed National Development Bank ................................................................
Young, Howard, et al.:
...............
Prepared statement of Douglas A. Fraser, president, UAW ............
Letter to Senator Bentsen from Howard Young, dated March 6, 1979, in
response to Representative Rousselot's query regarding the cost of
proposed "full employment communities" demonstration projects recom..............................................
mended by the UAW .................
THURSDAY, MARCH

302
315

360

8, 1979

Kreps, Hon. Juanita M.:

372
.................................................
Prepared statement ..............
Paper entitled "The Productivity Decline: Its Causes and Effects".. ..............379
Response to additional written questions posed by Representatives Mitchell
416
and Brown ................................................................

Marshall, Hon. Ray:
Prepared statement .............

..................................................

White paper entitled "The New Comprehensive Employment and Training
Program".................................................................................................................
Response to Senator Sarbanes' request to supply additional information on
the joint labor-management committees .........................................................
Response to Representative Mitchell's query regarding the use of public
service employment funds for the private sector initiatives program ......
Response to additional written questions posed by Senator Javits ......... ......

389
392

410
429
430

THE 1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE
PRESIDENT
THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 22, 1979

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,
Washington, D.C.
The committee met, pursuant to recess, at 10:15 a.m., in room
6226, Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Parren J. Mitchell
(member of the committee) presiding.
Present: -Representatives Mitchell and Brown; and Senator
Javits.
Also present: David W. Allen and William R. Buechner, professional staff members; Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; and
Mark R. Policinski, minority professional staff member.
OPENING STATEMENT OF REPRESENTATIVE MITCHELL, PRESIDING

Representative MITCHELL. This hearing will now come to order.

I want to apologize to everyone for being late. Traffic is just
about impossible. I drove in from Baltimore for the first time since
the blizzard of 1979.
We are very pleased to have as our scheduled witnesses this
morning three distinguished members of the business communityMr. Fletcher Byrom; chairman of the Koppers Co., Inc., and chairman of the board of trustees of the Committee for Economic Development; Mr. George P. Jenkins, chairman of the board of Metropolitan Life Insurance Co.; and Mr. Francis H. Schott, chairman of
the Finance and Currency Committee of the New York Chamber of
Commerce and Industry.
Gentlemen, I welcome all three of you. Again, I apologize for my
delay and I thank you for taking the time to get here.
We have stressed throughout this year's annual hearings that
inflation is a problem of major concern. In 1978, the consumer
price index rose by 9 percent. There is nothing in the winds to
indicate that inflation will slow down substantially in 1979, unless
President Carter's anti-inflation program proves to be successful.
Much of the success of that program will depend on the ability of
the Government and the business sector to work together to make
it a success. We are very concerned about what the Government
can do to help business move in the direction of solving some of the
underlying causes of inflation.
First, we have the recent slowdown in productivity. In 1978,
productivity in the nonfarm business sector rose by only 0.4 percent. This is just unacceptable, since it means that almost all of the
wage increases in 1978 were passed on to consumers in the form of
(1)

2

higher prices. An increase in productivity will require more capital
spending by business and more spending on research and development. I hope you will be able to give the committee some ideas as
to how we can do this.
Second, we have the problem of increased Government regulation. While most regulation is designed to achieve very important
social goals, too much regulation is excessive and unnecessary.
These costs get passed on to consumers in higher prices.
If we can make some progress on regulatory reform, we can have
a substantial impact on inflation. There, again, I hope all three of
you gentlemen will give us some advice, counsel, and some sense of
direction.
Third, we will need to talk about the wage and price guidelines,
and how well they are working. Guidelines alone can't control
inflation-but guidelines can be a useful part of an overall program to reduce inflation, if business and labor cooperate. So far,
everyone says they want the guidelines to work. I hope they will
work, and I want to get your ideas and prognosis of the workability
of the guidelines.
Finally, I hope you will help us on the problem of structural
unemployment. Since the bottom of the recession, the economy has
created a record 12.1 million new jobs, and the unemployment rate
has fallen from almost 9 percent to less than 6 percent.
However, the threat of worse inflation would make it foolhardy
to use stimulative policies at this time to further reduce unemployment, especially since much unemployment today seems to be
structural. We must turn our attention from cyclical unemployment to structural unemployment.
Last year, Congress enacted two new measures to alleviate structural unemployment, including a targeted jobs tax credit and a
private industry program under CETA. We need to know what
more we can do to create private sector jobs for the structurally
unemployed.
Again, Mr. Byrom, Mr. Jenkins, Mr. Schott, I welcome you and I
look forward to your testimony.
I would not dare suggest who should be the leadoff witness. Why
don't you settle that among yourselves. It is a fait accompli, Mr.
Byrom. Also we have copies of your prepared statement. You may
submit the entire prepared statement for the record and simply
excerpt from that portions that you want to read or you may
submit the entire statement. It's entirely up to you.
Mr. Byrom, thank you for being our leadoff witness.
STATEMENT OF FLETCHER L. BYROM,. CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF
TRUSTEES, COMMITTEE FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, AND
CHAIRMAN, KOPPERS CO., INC.

Mr. BYROM. Thank you very much, Congressman Mitchell.
I certainly don't intend to read my prepared statement. I would
like to submit the prepared statement for the record.
Representative MITCHELL. Without objection, it will be submitted
in its entirety for the record.
Mr. BYROM. Today is a rather interesting day in that it is the
100th anniversary of the first 5-and-10-cent store of Woolworth Co.
in Utica, N.Y. It seems to me, maybe, that underlines our problem

3

as well as anything does. It has been a long time since anyone has
thought of buying anything for 5 or 10 cents.
As chairman of the Committee for Economic Development, I
welcome the opportunity to meet with this committee and to give
some, hopefully, constructive comments regarding the President's
economic message and where we are in the economy today.
First, I would like to say we very much applauded the President's budget balancing schedule which anticipates a balanced
budget by 1981, hopefully.
Restraint in fiscal policy is extremely important because it
makes possible a more effective monetary policy that does not of
itself have to be expansionary.
The thing that concerns me probably more than anything else
going on at the present time is the rapid liquidation of the capital
base of our capital-intensive industry in this country. I am not
satisfied that we are dealing with this question with sufficient
attention to priorities.
I am also concerned with the fact that regulatory intervention
uses too much command and control and does not use the possible
incentives which could be employed to bring market considerations
back into judgments related to pollution control devices and to the
implementation of other socially mandated goals.
I am also concerned about the effect of those who advocate
intervention to achieve zero-risk standards without recognizing the
importance and value of acceptable risk standards.
I certainly subscribe to your remarks about structural unemployment. I think that we must move forward rapidly with the kind of
things that are contemplated by title VII in the Comprehensive
Employment and Training Act. I feel we should get on with the
funding of this program.
I hope that you feel that these very cursory remarks are sufficient as an introduction. What I am trying to do is to save time to
answer whatever questions you may have. I would rather be responsive to your concerns than try to make a speech.
Thank you, Congressman Mitchell.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Byrom follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF FLETCHER

L.

BYROM

Mr. Chairman, members of the Joint Economic Commitee, I welcome the opportunity, on behalf of the Committee for Economic Development, to comment before this
Committee on the President's Economic Report to Congress and related matters. I
am especially pleased to see you in the chair, Senator Bentsen. As a former CED
trustee, you are familiar with our work, and you are aware that our views have
been expressed here annually since these hearings were initiated.
In my opening statement, which I am pleased to submit for the record, I should
like to offer some praise, some cautions, and several specific recommendations.
First, the kind words. I applaud the basic thrust of the anti-inflation fiscal,
monetary and regulatory policy changes outlined in the President's Economic
Report. Further, they have earned broad support among the American public on the
part of earners, producers, investors, and especially inflation-burdened consumers.
This is not because wringing inflation out of the economy is going to be easy or riskfree, but because fighting inflation is increasingly recognized as essential to the
general welfare and the survival of our economy as we have known it. We have all
watched the building of this broad national consensus that has now made controlling inflation the nation's top economic priority.
To have continued to do too little would have insured economic disaster; to have
done too much, by imposing wage-price controls, would simply have compounded
and postponed the inevitable consequences until the controls were lifted. Even the

4
present system of so-called voluntary wage and price guidelines stirs little enthusiasm in me, though my company is complying with them. While these guidelines
may have some temporary braking effect on inflationary momentum, they are
basically a short-term treatment of the symptoms of inflation that breed distortions
the longer they are continued. There is no quick fix to the underlying, long-term
problem.
My colleagues and I fully endorse the President's admonition that "we must act
forcefully and effectively to combat inflation, and we must persist until the battle is
won." We particularly share the widely-held conviction of the American public that
this battle cannot be won unless the Federal Government sets the first example by
imposing much stricter discipline on its own performance. It is a commendable goal
to hold the budget deficit to $29 billion in the 1980 fiscal year, and to move
progressively toward a budgetary balance, by 1981 if possible, but in any event no
later than 1982.
That budgetary restraint needs to be accompanied by a firm monetary policy with
no more than moderate growth in the monetary aggregates. I am glad to see we
finally seem to have slowed monetary expansion, and trimming the budget deficit
will make a continuation of that performance much easier to achieve.
Holding firmly to this budgetary goal will do more than any other word or deed of
the Executive Branch and the Congress to restore public confidence that price
stability can be regained in the American economy. If, however, this proclaimed
budgetary restraint is cast aside by Administration or Congressional action for
whatever high motives, the resulting expectations will cause more inflation.
Of course, if overall demand should show much more weakening than the Economic Report projects, some flexibility must be allowed for countermeasures. But
the first line of defense against such weakening should be monetary policy-as has
recently been suggested by Chairman Miller-not a sudden opening up of the
floodgates to permanent additions to expenditure totals.
The needed disciplines will not be easy. In the budgetary trimming and wastecutting process, one man's fat is another man's muscle. Moreover, it would be
immoral to allow the heaviest burdens of the anti-inflationary campaign to fall on
the backs of those hardest hit by inflation and least able to cope: the poor, the
elderly, the handicapped and the structurally unemployed. It is also bad economics
and bad social policy to treat our unemployed youth, especially minority youth, and
our underskilled adults, as unusable in our economy. As CED points out in its
recent study, "Jobs for the Hard-To-Employ," leaving these human resources idle is
not only inhumane, it also deprives the economy of their productive output and
inflates our social costs.
CED recommends meeting the problem, -not by paying people not to work, nor by
creating many more costly and futureless jobs outside the real job market, but by
on-the-job and close-to-the-job training programs in the mainstream economy,
through vigorously expanded public-private partnership efforts. This approach is in
the long run both anti-inflationary and deeply humane.
A good many of the problems of Federal budget trimming require sharper distinctions between what government alone can do and what the private sector, given the
incentive and the opportunity, can do better, more efficiently, and with less inflationary consequences. We have to scrutinize long-established government practices
which are not only expensive, but are often also counterproductive as well as
inflationary.
This is a field to which CED has addressed a whole series of policy statements
over more than a decade, and their broad recommendations have never been more
relevant than they are right now. Civil Service reform-a concept CED supportedis a most salutary development. Improving productivity at all levels of government
is one of the important goals of the popular tax revolt that has been gathering
momentum in recent months. Other goals including reversing excessive growth of
government bureaucracy, and the decent burial of bureaus, programs and budgets
that have ceased to perform any defensible public service.
In the public eye, reducing the burden of bloated government is not only a matter
of overcoming fiscal drag; it is also a matter of improving governmental responsiveness, efficiency and effectiveness, and getting government out of those areas where
its intrusion is economically destructive.
I can think of no better examrple than Mr. Kahn's success in deregulating commercial aviation in this country, with resulting lower air fares, increased air travel,
healthier airline profits, and a scramble for new routes and services by what had
been a troubled industry. Regulation is no substitute for the self-correcting processes of a market economy.

5
There are denser thickets to the regulatory mess, however. In recent decades, we
have added to the costs of both government and industry-and have thereby fueled
inflation-by proliferating regulatory regimes ostensibly aimed at broad social goals
which, on their merits, are perfectly reasonable. The fault is less with the goals
than with the means.
I recognize that socially mandated values require some form of government intervention in the market to do such things as the establishment of minimum standards
affecting public health and safety, environmental quality, and fair employment
opportunities. The trick is to define our standards realistically, and to provide the
incentives and disincentives which will insure the efficient production of these goods
through the competitive dynamics of the market system.
Instead, we have created a vast superstructure of autonomous regulatory bodies,
and a maze of intricate and often contradictory regulations, which substitute command and control for the market process. Instead of placing a money cost on, for
example, undesirable levels of pollution, and thus giving industry the incentive to
solve the problem creatively and efficiently as a competitive business challenge, we
have empowered a remote and expensive bureaucracy to dictate and enforce precisely how each step of the job is to be done. Time and again, this latter method of
pursuing social objectives has shown itself to be both inefficient and inflationary.
Yet there are alternative ways of achieving the goals of regulation, and improving
the trade-off between real income and quality of life. These ways, because they use
the allocative efficiencies of the marketplace, involve less prospect of raising the
costs of production, reducing employment opportunities, and adding to inflation.
They include substituting incentives and disincentives for command-and-control
systems, setting performance goals for industry instead of imposing detailed instructions concerning the methods to be employed in reaching such objectives, and
abandoning the insistence on zero-risk goals in favor of the more realistic approach
of minimum acceptable risk. In its forthcoming policy statement, CED will offer a
number of recommendations on improving government regulatory intervention in
the market.
I have commented on some of the more obvious ways in which we have legislated
and institutionalized inflation as a new way of life. There are others. We have
indexed inflation into labor contracts, social security benefits and pension plans,
and may soon do the same with mortgages. We have built inflationary expectations
into our purchasing and investment decisions, as individuals and as business enterprises. Worse, we are undermining our ability to expand our productive capacityan expansion which is essential in order to counter the long-term nature of this
inflation. To be blunt, we are rapidly liquidating the capital base of the core of the
nation's economic system. This is happening because of the combination of high
fixed costs of new physical capital; the long lead time needed to expand or modernize capacity, or to launch a new product; the unpredictability of possible added costs
created by regulatory uncertainties; outmoded accounting practices and taxing policies; and antigrowth depreciation policies.
When allowable depreciation and real return on investment are inadequate, the
incentive disappears-whether for a large corporation, a small entrepreneur or an
individual shareholder-to invest in growth. Unless we improve the incentives for
investment in new capital plant, in research and development, and in the application of technologies which reduce unit costs and lead to better products and more
efficient manufacturing processes, the United States will continue to lag in productivity gains and international competitiveness, and we can continue to expect to lose
market shares, abroad and at home, to our more innovative and productive foreign
competitors and trading partners. Our record trade deficits of the last two years
have been the result, not merely of abnormal growth in the cost of imports, but of
our inability to achieve a vigorous export growth.
The economic condition we find outselves in, domestically and internationally, is
both cause apd effect of inflation-and of the public as well as private choices we
have made to institutionalize that inflation. Rising wages and prices are in one
sense symptoms of a more basic disorder (although they are an efficient way of
distributing inflationary pressures throughout the economy).
Correcting the fuudasmentql disorder calls for more than a treatment of symptoms. Neither mandatory wage-price controls nor a Constitutional prohibition of
budgetary deficits will do the job. The transformation called for is in our national
attitudes and habits, our expectations of government and of each other, and our selfdiscipline. We cannot legislate the good life; we are going to have to make it for
ourselves. Part of the solution is to relearn how to mobilize private interest for the
public good.

6
If I may summarize my recommendations, they comprise the following disciplines,
reforms and priorities:
1. Determined budgetary restraint, by both Congress and the Executive, in line
with the President's budget-balancing schedule. This is the most important and
most difficult discipline. Within the broad political front supporting budgetary
restraint, Congress faces a multitude of competing political demands for special
exemption from that restraint. Compassion for the neediest is essential, and help to
those outside the system to bring them into it is a wise investment for the future..
Otherwise, the pains of extricating our economy from a self-perpetuating inflationlike the costs of inflation itself-should be shared as fairly as Congress in its
wisdom can decide. But the budgetary line must be held.
2. Monetary restraint. Only with continuing fiscal responsibility will it be possible
to continue the present responsible monetary policies of the Federal Reserve in
holding the growth in demand to moderate but sustainable levels. Should demand
falter, however, presenting the prospect of a larger deficit based on a decline in
revenues, the Fed should exercise a careful degree of flexibility, and I am confident
it will.
3. Strengthening investment incentives in order to restore the depleted capital
base of the economy. It will be necessary to encourage increased and sustained
levels of investment in both physical and human resources, and in R&D, in order (a)
to strengthen overall supply and capacity in the economy, (b) to reverse the precipitous decline in productivity gains and competitiveness of the economy, (c) to rationalize the enormous increase in costs of politically mandated investment in environmental, safety and other social goods, and (d) to overcome the formidable disincentives to capital formation, especially the high fixed costs of new physical capital and
the extended lead time for expanding or modernizing capacity. More rapid depreciation allowances would, I believe, be a particularly constructive tax reform for these
purposes. CED is also exploring the possibilities for upgrading the capabilities of the
economy through public policies which promote technological innovation, and will
have recommendations to make on this issue before very long.
4. Overhaul and reform of regulatory structures and reduction of their inflationary and decapitalizing impacts on the economy. I have already expressed some
strong views on this subject, and shall elaborate only to say that I hope the
members of the Joint Economic Committee will find CED's forthcoming recommendations in this field to be a constructive framework for improvement.
5. Major investment in human resources to provide better training and jobs for
the hard-to-employ. We are pleased that the 1978 CED statement on this sensitive
subject has played a useful role in the development of the President's Private.Sector
Training and Jobs Initiative Program. However, as Frank Schiff, CED's Chief
Economist, spelled out before this committee yesterday, it is urgent that the timetable for this program be speeded up and that the business community be given real
responsibility for carrying out this new initiative.
A final word. This country has a proud record of world economic leadership. We
have not lost that lead, but we have hobbled ourselves unnecessarily in recent
decades, and we are hurting from the consequences. We do not have to look
elsewhere for blame or for solutions. We got ourselves into this bind, and we have
the knowledge and the power to get ourselves out of it. What matters is whether we
have the will.

Senator JAVITS. May I ask unanimous consent to ask the witness
two questions and may I explain why.
I am the proponent of the principal Taiwan protective amendment before the Foreign Relations Committee. I am the ranking
minority member and we are meeting at 10:30. Mr. Byrom and Mr.
Jenkins are leading citizens from my home town.
Mr. Byrom, I know my colleague, Congressman Mitchell, will ask
you some questions to bring out your point of view which you have
already started. I have two things. I will name them both and you
can address yourself to them. If Mr. Jenkins and Mr. Schott have
views other than yours, I hope they will intercede.
One, it is a popular idea that indexing is good policy. For example, a resolution passed, which I violently opposed, at a major
Republican meeting a week ago in Ashton, Md., endorsing the
indexing of tax brackets. I gather from your prepared statement,

7

that you have deep worries about indexing. I refer to your comment on how it is now built into many things. So, one, the policy of
indexing..

Two, we are deeply troubled now-it used to concern a few of us
but now it concerns a great many-by the great lag in production
by the U.S. private enterprise productivity machine.
Question. To what extent will this be helped by building up the
capital base as contrasted with raising the morale of workers? In
your opinion, how much of each in order of magnitude is cranked
into the final equation of a grave national crisis-namely, the lag
of productivity growth?
Mr. BYROM. Let me respond, Senator, and it is good to see you
sir.

Senator JAVITS. Thank you.
Mr. BYROM. In the first place, as far as I personally am concerned, I am very strongly against-violent is almost the wordanything which acknowledges inflation as being an acceptable condition in an economy. To me, indexing, in effect, says that. It
admits that you have quit, that you can't win the fight and you
just are ready to say we are going to live with it and hope that we
can contain it within reasonable bounds.
I see no reason why we have to give up the fight. I think that
inflation can be eliminated over a period of time. It is not going to
be easy. It took us, as far as I am concerned, by my way of
reckoning, from 1966 to 1979 to get to where we are. We are not
going to undo it in a matter of 6 months. But, in fact, I think
inflation can be done away with, and I certainly don't think this
will happen if we start to index things.
Second, on the matter of productivity-your second question-we
have to separate, in effect, what we are talking about. I think, on
the one hand, we have capital-intensive industries. On the other
hand, we have, in the service sector, activities that are relatively
labor intensive. I am satisfied that in the second of these areas,
productivity is essentially the result of how an individual performs
a service, of the quality of his performance, of how he reacts, how
stimulated he is, how motivated he is, how hard he tries, and I am
using the term "he," but I should be using "he" or "she." How
much a person tries can very much affect productivity in this
climate. However, the situation is different in the area I am most
concerned about: the industries which provide the primary source
of wealth in our society, wealth which makes it possible to have a
service economy, these basic wealth producing industries are
highly. capital intensive.
Very frankly, I don't think that in this sector the individual
motivation of the worker, unless it is negative, affects productivity
very much. Productivity improvements are accomplished by significant increases in the capital base that utilizes the technology that
is available to us.
I am deeply concerned, Senator, that we have all kinds of inhibitions against productivity in the capital intensive industries in our
society. They involve many kinds of questions of depreciation accounting in an inflationary economy. They involve questions of
antitrust policies which assume that we are essentially trying to

8

deal in a free-trading world when we are often actually dealing
with industries that are either State-owned or State-subsidized.
Our needs in those areas, which I think are basic to the wellbeing of this society, have to do with capital formation and not
employee motivation.
Senator JAVITS. Mr. Jenkins.
Mr. JENKINS. Thank you, Senator. I would like to echo Mr.
Byrom's comments on indexing.
I, too, am opposed to indexing as a theory. Once you index
something, everybody else wants an index, so your wind up indexing everything. I submit that you are far worse off by indexing
everything than if we stood firm and made a good fight.
I am happy to have had a very interesting experience about 3
years ago. A group of us went down to Brazil. That was just at the
height of, if I call it in quotes "relative," as they thought Brazil's
indexing was a "relative" success.
Subsequent events have proved it was not nearly as successful as
had been anticipated. We had a briefing. I came away from that
with two thoughts: No. 1, of course, was that we are entirely
different from Brazil. What went on in Brazil could never happen
here. Frankly, the only reason indexing worked in Brazil for a
while was because it came out of the hide of labor. It could not
possibly work permanently, and I think subsequent events have
shown that.
If we index, sooner or later everybody is going to demand it. I
reject it totally as a concept.
On the matter of capital investment and worker morale, our
problem, as we all know, is to stop the decline in productivity, turn
it around, and get an increase. I think there are a number of
factors that have a bearing on productivity improvement, but the
principal one is capital investment.
Unfortunately, there is just not the incentive in a great many
places to make this capital investment.
In my particular business, which is basically the lending of
money-the investment of money-we study various propositions
that are brought to us, particularly in the basic industries. When
one looks at the potential return, one would be better off to invest
the money in Goverment bonds. I think this is a sad state of
affairs.
What we need to improve productivity is more capital investment. As Mr. Byrom says, I am afraid we are liquidating our
capital base.
I think, obviously, worker morale is important; and as we get
better facilities, that should be a help. On the other hand, I believe
one of the things that does hold back capital investment is restrictive work practices. Restrictive work practices might well affect
morale, but I have always been one who believes that a person
should be paid well and work as hard as he possible can-8 hours a
day.
I would also say that many governmental regulations, unfortunately, are restricting productive investment. I am thinking particularly of some of the expenditures that should be made and
some of the things that should be done, but aren't.

9

We are competing against foreign businessmen which can get
economies of scale. We, here, are restricted by some of our, I
believe, misguided antitrust policies and are unable to get the
benefit of economies of scale so our industries can compete with
the world at large.
Senator JAVITS. Thank you, Mr. Jenkins.
Mr. Schott, is there anything you want to add? My time is very
brief.

Mr. SCHOTT. I will be very brief, I join my fellow panelists in
opposing price indexing. As long as the Government is running a
deficit, there should be no further tax relief. You might conceivably have a case for an adjustment of tax brackets, but you do not
have such a case while the Government is running a heavy deficit.
On the contrary, we should be seeking to have a larger growth in
revenue than in spending for some time until the Government
deficit is closed. That has been a heavy contribution to inflation, so
therefore I am opposed to any indexing.
With respect, to productivity, I would add that the President's
report has a very good discussion of the productivity problem. I
believe, among the items mentioned by my associates, Government
regulation should be particularly singled out. The largest productivity decline in recent years has been in mining. All of us know
there were conditions in the mine that needed to be cured and one
can land certain OSHA and EPA regulations as being meritorious
in themselves, but our chairman has already said there is a cost
attached to Government regulations.
I am afraid in the case of mining the Government regulations
have contributed to the declining productivity. After a while you
could say we shall get over that problem. We certainly need to
have a pause and some thought about any further Government
regulation of production and technology.
Then, besides that, we need capital investment and substantial
capital investment so that present production methods can be
brought in line with government regulations such as we have up to
now and, please, no additional ones, and yet continue on that new
base to improve productivity by R. & D. and capital investment.
So, we have a lot to think about as a Nation in helping to answer
those questions.
Senator JAVITS. Thank you, Mr. Schott.
If I may ask one more question, Mr. Byrom. We had a meeting of
top-flight economists and some business leaders late last fall. They
decided that between ADR, that is, accelerated depreciation and a
material reduction in the corporate tax rate, it would be a greater
stimulus to capital investment if you reduced the corporate tax
rate instead of reducing ADR. I don't agree with that, but that is
neither here nor there. I don't own a single business except my
watch. What do you think?
Mr. BYROM. As you well know, my peers are not unanimous on
this view. I support your view. I think the problem is the liquidation of the capital base. What I would like to see is the kind of
accelerated depreciation under which we would leave to the discretion of the firm to use as much of the available depreciation
allowable within a given year provided this does not exceed what

10

the firm plows back in terms of plant and equipment in that
particular year.
To me, more flexible depreciation allowances are the way in
which we can best deal with the problem we are talking about. I
feel that reduction in the corporate tax rate-obviously, any reduction in taxes-makes a positive contribution, but this type of reduction is not nearly as important as improved depreciation. The thing
that bothered me was that the corporate tax reduction was coupled
with an overall tax reduction which further accentuated the consumption bias which is the reason we are in the trouble we are in.
Senator JAVITS. We agree.
Do you have any differences of opinion, Mr. Jenkins?
Mr. JENKINS. I would just like to add one thing. I know there are
many people on both sides of the argument. I can see many good
reasons for each approach.
In my discussions with people, one thing comes through loud and
clear, that is, if they could count on continuity for a while and not
be subject to change, that would be as important as any factor in
moving along this capital investment.
Senator JAVITS. Do you have any differences, Mr. Schott?
Mr. SCHOTT. I would just like to say we should postpone further
government giveaway schemes until we hale brought inflation
under control.
Senator JAVITS. Thank you very much. You have been very
gracious.
Mr. BYROM.

I would like to indicate some degree of difference
with Mr. Schott.
My only concern, Mr. Schott, is-I understand what you are
saying: that it is very difficult at a time when you are trying to
contain inflation to do anything to increase the size of the deficit. I
agree with you on that. This is the same kind of thing which is
included in the Economic Report of the President on pages 130 and
131.
On 130, they say:
If the investment needed to reach our economic goals in 1983 is to be realized,
policy actions are required that will strengthen investment incentives and reduce
investment costs and risks.

Then, they go on to the next page and say:
Further tax reductions designed to strengthen investment incentives may well be
needed in the years ahead-

they are needed nowto encourage a high rate of investment in new plant and equipment. Given the
budgetary constraints required in the near future to reduce inflation, there is no
room for additional tax cuts now.

That is Mr. Schott's point. I understand the dilemma we are in.
Paul Tillich said we have to learn to be comfortable with ambiguity. We are dealing here with an ambiguous situation. If we are
ever to correct our problem we have to get on with the elimination
of the liquidation of the capital base that is taking place. It has to
happen now and we have to recognize that this is important.
Representative MITCHELL. Obviously, Senator Javits' questions
have invoked questions on my part. Certain key words emerged,
such as giveaway programs and problems with the President's

11

antitrust policy, and I would like to raise some questions in those
areas.
Before so doing, I think it would be better to hear from Mr.
Jenkins and Mr. Schott and then we can get into a discussion after
that.
STATEMENT OF GEORGE P. JENKINS, CHAIRMAN OF THE
BOARD, METROPOLITAN LIFE INSURANCE CO.

Mr. JENKINS. Congressman Mitchell, like the rest of the group, I
do appreciate the opportunity to appear before this committee. I
have prepared a statement here which has been submitted. Rather
than read it, it had been my intention to just highlight it. In view
of the discussion that has gone on, I think I will just highlight my
highlights by stating that we were asked particularly for our view
of the business outlook.
We see the current business cycle maturing. We have been in a
4-year expansion phase, and expect that the economy will move
this year into an adjustment period which will temporarily slow
output. To put some numbers on that, our company's economic
forecast indicates a real growth rate of somewhere between 1¾ and
2 percent.
I noticed in this morning's paper, that the Chairman of the
Federal Reserve, in his comments yesterday, indicated about the
same expectations by the Federal Reserve for 1979. Unfortunately,
the way we see it, growth in capital outlays in 1979 is likely to be
about one-half of what was achieved in each of the last 2 years.
Now, in going around the country and discussing this with the
various people with whom we do business, I find one thing: Most
businessmen are reasonably confident regarding their own industry, but are concerned about the general course of the economy and
such things as, No. 1, inflation, the value of the dollar, energy,
Government control, economic policy decisions, and so forth.
We think that business will not get particularly good growth in
real profits this year. By real profits I mean profits after consideration for inadequate depreciation and higher inventory replacement
costs.
Our projections also indicate that this will be the fourth year in
a row in which internal cash flow of nonfinancial corporations will
fail to match outlays for fixed investment.
That means that external financing needs will be large and, by
the same token, we look for long-term funds to be relatively tight.
Commercial mortgage markets are still competing for these same
long-term funds. Of course, we know that the reason commercial
and housing mortgage markets have been so active this year is
because of the 6-month certificates tied to the Treasury bill rate.
I might say that as far as the administration's anti-inflation
program, announced last October, is concerned, we support its
principles and goals. But we feel as a Nation we should not lose
sight of the fact that it is only a stopgap measure and success
against the upward price spiral will ultimately depend on the
course of fiscal and monetary policies.
We believe that more formal controls would be counterproductive and only compound other long-term problems, such as our
need to raise the level of productivity.

12
To sum it up, we see a moderate economic adjustment occurring
in 1979. We feel that fiscal and monetary policy cannot be allowed
to become stimulative. Failure to at least reverse price trends at
this juncture and to dampen inflation expectations have very serious implications for the long-run economic health and stability of
our Nation.
Thank you.
Representative MITCHELL. Thank you very much.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Jenkins follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF GEORGE P. JENKINS
Thank you for the opportunity to appear before this distinguished committee,
of
express my opnions regarding the course of the economy, and comment on some
the problems that concern members of the business community in general and the
life insurance industry in particular.
Let me turn first to the business outlook as we see it. Fourth-quarter results, as
you know, were surprisingly strong virtually across the board. However, we see
signs of maturing in the growth phase of this business cycle as the recoveryexpansion period approaches 4 years. The U.S. economy appears to be moving into
an adjustment phase which is expected to temporarily slow output. We expect the
to
adjustment to be moderate and that real gross national product will still manage
grow by almost 2 percent for the full year.
The likelihood that consumer spending will be slowing in 1979 is supported by the
significant deceleration in retail sales performance in January. In brief, we expect
consumers to adjust their spending for some excesses that have occurred over the
repaypast few years. They will improve the balance between credit extensions and rate
of
ments, adjusting spending closer to current incomes, and stepping up their
saving from the very low levels of last year. Because consumer liquidity is relatively
strong, the adjustment should be mild and of short duration.
Housing, in terms of starts, has been moving along a high plateau for about 10
months. Traditionally, housing would have been adversely affected by now through
of
disintermediation pressures. However, the introduction of savings certificates
has
deposit and more recently the 6-month certificates tied to the 6-month bill rate and
alleviated this problem, as has shrinkage in the gap between market rates
institutional portfolio yields. In addition, housing has been bolstered by low vacancy
rates and the fact that homeownership is being increasingly regarded as an "inflation hedge" by individuals. As a result, housing prices have been bid up very
rapidly, far outpacing gains in income. Home mortgage rates have moved up sharply and are now competitive with other long-term rates. Plans to buy homes have
dropped significantly in the past 2 months and it is beginning to look as if cost
factors will be the constraining influence on housing in the current cycle.
Growth in business capital outlays in 1979 is likely to be about half of that
achieved in each of the past 2 years. I find that most businessmen are reasonably
confident regarding their own industry but are very concerned about the general
course of the economy and such problems as inflation, the value of the dollar in
foreign exchange markets, energy, and government control of economic decisions.
These concerns, coupled with poor growth in real profits-that is profits after
correction for inadequate depreciation charges and higher replacement costs for
inventory-are bound to affect capital spending. Moreover, growth in nominal profits will slow up considerably this year. With relatively tight labor markets, and with
operating rates in the vicinity of 86 percent, the corporate business sector will be
expanding output on a rising cost curve. In fact, 1978 was already characterized by
a sharp slowing in productivity. Profit margins will therefore be squeezed.
This year will be the fourth in a row in which internal cash flow of nonfinancial
corporations will fail to match outlays for fixed investment. Thus, their external
financing needs will be large, but long-term bond funds may prove to be tight.
Commercial mortgage markets are competing for these same long-term funds. The
household sector, which has often acted as a pressure value in this market during
periods of peak interest rates, is unlikely to perform this role in 1979 for reasons
previously mentioned-low saving and sizable commitments in various special deposits which cannot be abrogated without strong penalties.
Some slow-up in inventory accumulation for the year is expected, but fortunately
there have been few excesses. This is a key reason why we expect only a moderate
cyclical adjustment.

13
Inflation and problems in international trade and finance will provie to be persistent and will significantly influence government policies. A number of developments-some of them very recent-reinforce our expectations for a price increase in
excess of 8Y2 percent for the full-year 1979. Among these are the price and trade
impacts from the drastic shifts in both political and economic patterns in Iran,
along with the four-step OPEC oil price decision and the necessary increases in
domestic oil and gas prices. The high food prices registered so far this year have
already added several tenths of a percent to the overall rate of inflation. In addition
to these major factors, cost pressures created by the marginal use of less efficient
productive capacity and labor, and other rising expenses will add to inflation. Price
passalongs stemming from the large increase in Social Security taxes and the lifting
of the minimum wage rate are cases in point. On the positive side, a more stable
dollar in foreign exchange markets will help to slow up the rise in the cost of
imported raw materials and other goods.
With such powerful and diverse inflationary pressures, it will take an extended
period of monetary and fiscal caution to turn the tide. Progress will be slow but we
must avoid the temptation to switch to stimulus as the economy slows. If this
happens the likelihood of a more severe economic correction and financial crunch
increases dramatically. In this regard, let me add that we do not feel the current
stance taken by the monetary authorities is overly restrictive. Money is still available for sound investment purposes and interest rates, after allowance for inflation of
recent years, are not very high.
The life insurance business has been deeply concerned over the high rates of
inflation of recent years and the need for policies to bring down these rates. In fact,
just a year ago our trade association, the American Council of Life Insurance
initiated a major study effort on anti-inflation policy which is reaching its final
stages this week in Williamsburg, Virginia. One hundred leaders from our business,
other corporate enterprise, trade union leaders, and university professors are gathered to develop a longer range approach to the solution of the inflation problem. A
summary of the outcome of this inflation study will be furnished to the Joint
Economic Committee in a statement to be developed next week.
As for the Administration's Anti-Inflation program announced last October, Metropolitan is supporting its principles and goals, but feels we as a nation should not
lose sight of the fact that this is only a stop-gap measure and that success in halting
the upward price spiral will ultimately depend upon the course of fiscal and monetary policies. More formal controls would be counterproductive and only compound
other long-run problems such as the need to raise our level of productivity.
In this respect we applaud the Administration's goal of reducing the relative size i
of government in the economy and those measures in the Revenue Act of 1978 that
were designed to bolster capital formation. A higher rate of investment in new and
more efficient plant and equipment is essential if we are to improve productivity,
enhance our competitiveness in international markets, and encourage energy conservation, exploration, and development.
Similarly, a reduction and streamlining of government regulatory systems would
be most beneficial, especially in the case of the costly paper work and red tape
involved in compliance. Moreover, a more appropriate application of antitrust legislation is necessary in a world in which U.S. industries face ever-increasing competition from many government-sheltered industries in other countries.
While job growth will continue, we expect the strong employment expansion that
characterized recent years to moderate considerably and the unemployment rate to
drift upward as the year progresses. By year end, it will be in the vicinity of 61/2
percent, reflecting less favorable employment opportunities and also somewhat
slower growth of the labor force. Efforts to mitigate unemployment must be more
directly targeted than simply returning to the broad stimulative policies of the past.
Job training, job placement services, employment counseling, and special incentive
approaches should be used to combat structural unemployment.
While several recent changes in export financing procedure and other trade
mechanisms should help us compete more effectively abroad, a more comprehensive
export policy would benefit the U.S. We need to continue working to develop greater
export credit harmony among countries, reduce major disincentives to exports
caused by federal legislation and regulation, and help firms to take advantage of the
opportunities resulting from the depreciation of the dollar by offsetting some of the
difficulties to be faced in selling in other countries. Better export performance
would spur domestic economic growth, create jobs and, by strengthening the dollar,
help fight inflation.
In summary, we foresee a moderate economic adjustment occurring in 1979.
However, fiscal and monetary policy cannot be allowed to become stimulative.

47-977 0 - 79 - 2

14
Failure to at least reverse price trends at this juncture and to dampen inflation
expectations has serious implications for the long-run health of our nation and
economic stability. Thank you.

Representative MITCHELL. Mr. Schott, please proceed.
STATEMENT OF FRANCIS H. SCHOTT, CHAIRMAN, FINANCE AND
CURRENCY COMMITTEE, NEW YORK CHAMBER OF COMMERCE AND INDUSTRY
Mr. SCHOTT. Thank you, Congressman Mitchell. I, too, will be
very brief.
In our-prepared statement we are dealing with inflation, the No.
1 economic problem. We are pointing out inflation is a socially
destructive force. We are pointing out that it had been stated that
the inflation rate of 6 percent was sort of a base rate against which
one could operate and it would not escalate regardless of demand
management. We are now witnessing a major problem and before
someone blames the whole thing on OPEC, again I would like to
point out inflation was rapidly rising in 1977 and 1978 even before
%,
the oil problems started.
We are saying inflation is a socially destructive force in our
economy; and we are convinced the reason is that each political
and social interest group, in actively seeking to protect itself
against inflation, engages in conduct that makes the general problem worse. I am echoing the problem of indexing. If everybody is
indexed, would you not be where you were before? You are pitting
one group against the other.
Real income gains, over and above the modest per capita advances the country has been making in recent years, can come only
at the expense of others.
Our real income gains are limited by productivity advances
which have been nonexistent, so we will have to distribute a roughly equal pie for a number of years from now on.
So we are emphasizing and reemphasizing over and over that
inflation is the No. 1 problem and our policy should be conditioned
by that recognition.
We are pleased that the administration is making a step toward
a more nearly balanced budget. We particularly endorse the notion
that spending increases have to be brought under control. We are
applauding this choice that has been made and support it fully.
The President's proposed expenditure increase of less than 8
percent is a step in the right direction-the first time in decadesand we hope Congress will not add a penny to spending increases
suggested by the President. In fact, we recommend to you that
every spending increase and all spending be subject to the most
vigorous examination.
We endorse the administration's desire to gradually bring back
the proportion of GNP spent by the Federal Government from 22
percent to 20 percent and tax cuts should be conditional upon the.
achievement of spending restraint.
Since the Government has run not only actual deficits, but also
high-employment-calibrated deficits throughout the current economic expansion, there is no doubt that massive deficits have
contributed to the renewed deterioration of the inflation rate since
mid-1976.

15
We point out that the Government would be in high-employment
budget deficit in fiscal 1979 and 1980, and we say this is inappropriate. Nevertheless, the thrust of the 1980 proposal goes on in the
right direction.
On monetary policy we would like to point out in particular that
interest rates, although they may seem high, are not really high
when you measure them against the inflation rate. Someone who
pays 10 percent for a mortgage loan, in view of the escalation of
house prices and the tax writeoff you get on the mortgage, and the
inflation being at 9 percent, is really paying very little more for
money, so we cannot agree that 10 percent is high.
Other rates are similarly high because inflation has risen. Therefore, we hope the Federal' Reserve will continue to pursue an
interst-rate policy that will contribute effectively toward moderation of credit demand and lower inflation in 1979, which is urgently necessary in order to bring some order into the inflation picture
while the Government's budget program is still stimulative.
We are endorsing the guidelines and for the moment we are
opposed to anything other than the voluntary guidelines.
I note our Finance and Currency Committee of the New York
Chamber of Commerce and Industry includes members from some
of the largest companies. We have expressed endorsement for the
guidelines and we intend to abide by them as near as I can tell
from the reactions in our committee. I want to put in a good word
for them. We feel special emphasis should be placed on deregulation.'

We think the example set in the airlines should be emulated.
On productivity, we feel, as Mr. Jenkins has suggested.
Finally, we have a long discussion of structural unemployment in
our prepared statement. This is for the simple reason that we
endorse the concept not only in theory. Several years ago the New
York Chamber of Commerce and Industry recognized the seriousness of this form of unemployment and, through its educational
foundation, developed a program to attack the problem.
Since 1970 we have sponsored clerical training consortia. We are
a prime contractor under CETA. We are endorsing the structural
CETA program which shifts funds toward the private sector. We
have trained several thousand people with a retention rate of 60
percent among our members.
In New York City there is an urgent need for skilled clerical,
secretarial workers. We find with proper training we can integrate
structurally unemployed people into the work force and that business urgently needs them. We have made a lot of progress and we
look forward to being able to use CETA funds within the President's budget request. We are looking forward to expanding on
that.
Thank you.
Representative MITCHELL. Thank you.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Schott follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF FRANCIS H. SCHOTT

The New York Chamber of Commerce and Industry welcomes the opportunity to
submit a statement concerning the President's Budget Message and Economic
Report for the guidance of the Joint Economic Committee. We consider the direction

16
of Government economic policy to be of crucial importance in shaping the behavior
of the economy not only during 1979 but in the period beyond.
INFLATION-THE NO. 1 ECONOMIC PROBLEM

Our Committee has repeatedly warned the Congress in previous submissions that
inflation is a mounting and socially destructive force in our economy. We are more
concerned than ever before about the problem. At recent near double-digit rates,
inflation is more virulent now than at any other period except for war, early
postwar periods and brief flurries following major outside events such as the OPEC
price rise of 1973-74. In other words, inflation has become endemic to the economic
system itself. We are out of excuses. There are no special circumstances on which to
place the blame. .
The self-reinforcing nature of inflation is also being revealed ever more clearly.
At the recent cyclical low, in mid-1976, inflation had decelerated to about 51/2
percent annual rate. The OPEC price rise and the food shortages of 1973 had spent
their initiating force, and the recession of 1974-75 materially curbed wage and price
demands. Inflation was proved capable of deceleration. When it began to pick up
so-called
steam again, in late 1976/early 1977, the argument was advanced that theaggregate
"base rate" of inflation was around 6 percent, virtually regardless of
economic policy. Recent events have proved this argument fallacious. The current
inflation has acquired upward momentum.
While inflation is by no means the only ailment afflicting our economy-low
productivity and structural unemployment among certain population groups are
others-it is, as noted, by far the dominant one at the moment. Without a concerted
anti-inflation program as the top policy priority, there is every reason to assume
that inflation will soon mount into double-digits and continue to worsen until fara
sterner measures than those currently undertaken or contemplated would become
dire necessity.
The reason is that each political and social interest group, in actively seeking to
protect itself against inflation, engages in conduct that makes the general problem
worse. Real income gains, over and above the modest per capita advances the
country has been making in recent years, can come only at the expense of others. It
is the government's obligation to stop the futile race. This is so especially because
the very old and very young as well as large segments of the unorganized labor
force are not able to protect themselves adequately against inflation, while other
groups may be able to do so. Thus, grave inequities and ever-increasing alienation of
the public from government are the likely outcome of an uninhibited inflation
f
spiral.
Aggregate demand management.-The administration has chosen to combat inflation via an array of countermeasures that will tend to reverse the rate of price
increase over an extended period, rather than by abrupt measures such as a major
recession or tight controls. We applaud this choice and support it fully.
In view of the recent rapid approach of virtually full utilization of men and
machines, the first line of attack has to be to hold back the rate of demand growth.
The administration correctly states that "to avoid creation of excess demand, economic growth needs to slow to a pace at, or somewhat below, the long-term potential rate of expansion . . . for 1979 and 1980" (Economic Report of the President, p.
79).
Fiscal policy.-The President's fiscal 1980 budget is a major step in the right
direction. The proposed expenditure increase of just under 8 percent, while still
permitting a large $37 billion expenditure increase, is less than the almost 10
percent increase taking place in fiscal 1979 and well below the far higher percentage increases of the preceding five years. Furthermore, the predicted deficit of
under $30 billion is a material improvement over the fiscal years 1974-79.
We should note that the government has run not only actual deficits but also
high-employment-calibrated deficits throughout the current economic expansion.
There is no doubt that massive deficits have contributed to the renewed deterioration of the inflation rate since mid-1976. It is therefore essential for the Congress to
refrain from adding appropriations to the administration's requests. This is not to
deny that Congress may have somewhat different priorities in expenditures, but
there should be a resolve to pare expenditures elsewhere if more is spent in some
areas than the President has proposed. In addition, Congress should subject not only
increased spending but all spending to the most stringent cost/benefit tests it is
capable of devising. We support the administration's aim to reduce federal outlays
from 22 percent of GNP to 20 percent two years hence.
We also support the Administration's stance against further general tax reductions until spending and the deficit are under better control. Savings and invest-

17
ment incentives should have the highest priority in further tax reductions when
they become appropriate. The savings rate has been unusually low for the past two
years, and the U.S. investment rate places this country near the bottom among
industrial economies. We cannot, however, foresee any likely circumstance that
would justify tax reductions of any kind in calendar 1979. Reduction of the deficit
and of the inflation rate is the highest priority. If Congress agrees to this course,
spending restraint will create the proper conditions for future tax reductions by
1981 and possibly even in 1980. We note and emphasize that the administration's
projected budget deficit for fiscal 1980, substantial as it is, depends on favorable
revenue estimates along with some spending restraint. Should the economy not
perform quite as satisfactorily as assumed, the revenue shortfall will serve as an
"automatic stabilizer" without any additional tax relief.
Monetary policy.-In view of the short-term inflexibility of the budget, monetary
policy must act as the swing factor in the government's economic stance. Since the
inflation must be dealt with even in the fact of large federal deficits and strong
wage/price push, the Federal Reserve is the "supplier of restraint of last resort."
The Federal Reserve has filled this role creditably in 1978. We endorse the
gradual approach toward an interest rate level appropriate for curbing borrowing
demand. We note that interest rates in the 9V2 percent area for long-term rates and
11 percent to 12 percent for short-term rates are hardly onerous for debtors anticipating inflation just short of these figures, especially in view of the favorable tax
treatment of interest payments. Therefore, we hope that the Federal Reserve will
continue to pursue an interest rate policy that will contribute effectively toward
moderation of credit demand and lower inflation in 1979. Such a policy cannot and
should not be defined in terms of any particular interest rate level. It is results that
count. If present interest rates will do the job, that would be a welcome but, to
many observers, a surprising result. If they do not yet curb credit and liquidity
expansion sufficiently, it is to be hoped that the Federal Reserve will not encounter
political obstacles in pursuing additional restraint. As noted, the Federal Reserve
carries the main burden of aggregate economic policy until the budget comes into
closer balance.
One of the main obstacles to the use of monetary policy has been removed with
the introduction of a variety of measures that have enhanced the competitiveness of
home mortgages in the capital market. We endorse, in particular, liberal interest
rate regulation of "consumer CDs" at thrift institutions. It is desirable, and now
very nearly a fact, that various types of financial institutions, markets and borrowers should be about equally impacted by monetary restraint.
Supplementary anti-inflation policies.-The history of price/wage controls is discouraging, especially when they have been viewed as a shield behind which expansionary fiscal and monetary policy could be pursued in disregard of the inflation
threat.
Nevertheless, on the assumption and in the hope that this mistake will not be
repeated, there may be a case for voluntary guidelines such as the administration is
now seeking to implement. It is unquestionably true that the dynamics of price/
wage decisions would benefit from mutual and simultaneous deescalation. If the
economy is poised for slower growth in 1979, as is widely believed, and if monetary
policy stays on a course that assures such a result, the guidelines may help dampen
the slowdown by reducing the inflation rate more quickly than might be the case
without them. Therefore, we favor a good-faith effort on the part of all concerned,
including business, to see whether the guidelines can be made to work during the
calendar year 1979. The guidelines should not, however, be given the force of law,
nor should they be prolonged beyond the initial period during which the inflation
rate is "turned around."
We cannot endorse the "wage insurance" plan of the administration, which seeks
to compensate workers up to specified wage and inflation rate limits if they have
accepted a 7 percent wage limitation. The plan is risky with respect to its budgetary
costs. It is certain to be highly inequitable as among family income units with
widely varying individual situations; and it leaves out of consideration, and therefore behind, many types of income recipients other than wage earners who cannot
possibly hope to get even a 7 percent increase this year (for example, savers in fixedyield instruments such as U.S. Government savings bonds).
Regulatory and productivity policies.-We endorse wholeheartedly the broadening
of the deregulation drive to industries beyond the airlines. Pro-competitive policies,
including the avoidance of import barriers, are a sound component of anti-inflation
and pro-free-market policies.
Although the discussion of regulatory policy in the President's Economic Report
(pp. 85-91) stresses commendable progress in the government's attitude toward

18
relieving excessive burdens of such regulation, we do not believe that the full extend
of the problem is as yet sufficiently comprehended. The fact is that regulation,
including especially EPA and OSHA rules, have imposed the equivalent of heavy
additional taxes on the U.S. consumer-costs that show up in the price index but
not in the government budget nor in any other explicit analysis provided by the
Government. Thus, it has been estimated that the cost of environmental regulations
for the average U.S. automobile is in excess of $600, or about 10 percent of the
present average initial price of an automobile. In addition, car owners incur additional costs for unleaded gas that can easily add 10 percent to fuel costs throughout
the lifetime of the car.
The poor productivity performance of the U.S. economy is amply discussed in the
President's Report (pp. 67-72), but the explanations of the difficulties leave much to
be desired. Yet, we endorse the conclusion that "The magnitude of the productivity
effects does highlight two facts: regulation is very costly; and benefits should be
closely compared with costs in the design of regulatory legislation and specific
regulations" (p. 69).
In view of the urgent need to support anti-inflation policies in every reasonable
way, there is a strong case for a moratorium on new cost-increasing regulations and
a mandate for the review of existing regulations. The absorptive capacity of industry and of the public of regulatory activity has clearly been strained to the limit.
STRUCTURAL UNEMPLOYMENT

Structural unemployment persists through strong and weak periods in the labor
market. Discrimination, lack of education and therefore lack of skills, poor motivation-most typically some combination of the foregoing-account for this persistent
aggravation of the unemployment problem, even in periods of intense strain in
skilled-labor markets. It is a national responsibility to alleviate the problem.
Several years ago, the New York Chamber of Commerce and Industry recognized
the seriousness of this form of unemployment and, through its Educational Foundation, developed a program to attack the problem. Since 1970, the NYCC Educational
Foundation has run eleven clerical training programs. In the "consortia" (groups of
participating companies) approximately 1,500 people have been trained to fill jobs as
clerks, typists, stenographers, secretaries and bookkeeper's assistants in 39 companies in New York.
Clerical consortia programs have been "hire-first" programs. After being screened
for eligibility by Neighborhood Manpower centers, trainees have been assessed for
academic achievement and desire for clerical training by experienced staff. They
have been hired by participating companies, but immediately referred to the training agency for about three months' classroom training while on the payroll of the
employing company. Participants have studied basic office procedures, business
math and English, typing, and stenography or bookkeeping.
Upon successful completion of the course work and upon passage of the employer's entrance examinations, trainees have begun a 15-week on-job-training. During
the classroom period, salaries for trainees have been totally subsidized by the New
York City Department Of Employment; on-job-training salaries have been 50 percent subsidized. The average retention rate of trainees following training during
these eleven consortia has been about 60 percent.
Now the Chamber is sponsoring a Skill Training Improvement Program under
CETA Title III. This is a "train-first" program-unemployed persons without marketable skills will be prepared to take jobs as secretaries and bookkeepers. There
are now 32 trainees involved in a 30-week classroom, 15-week on-job-training program, subcontracted to Con Ed. With the aid of two job marketers, they will gain
employment in the private sector at salaries of $4.25 per hour or better.
Encouraged by the success of its training program, the Chamber embarked on a
new pilot program in the summer of 1978. The Chamber holds that the original
Comprehensive Employment Training Act (CETA) had not directly addressed the
structural unemployment problem. Although four out of five jobs are in the private
sector, more than 90 percent of CETA funds have been spent on short-term public
service employment positions. To deal with this pressing issue, the Chamber's
Educational Foundation, in cooperation with the New York Metro Chapter of the
National Alliance of Business, launched the Private Industry Council with the sole
objective of offering real training and long-term employment in the private sector.
The training programs will be flexible enough to train people for existing job
openings in hundreds of occupations.
The Private Industry Council will give small and large employers the chance to
deal directly with a business-oriented group, thus saving them from the delays
connected with securing government training contracts directly through public

19
agencies. The Chamber found that many large firms that had embarked on training
programs with the use of CETA funds had quickly become disillusioned with the red
tape and delays caused by governmental agencies. In addition, many medium-sized
and smaller firms have neither the financial resources not manpower available to
launch and administer government-funded training programs.
Currently the Chamber's Private Industry Council is operating under $3.5 million
in contracts with the New York City Department of Employment and the U.S.
Department of Labor. It is estimated that it will cost between $2,000 and $3,000 in
CETA funds to train one person. For this small investment the graduating trainees
will earn between $8,000 and $9,000 during the first jear on the job. Reduced
structural unemployment will generate tax revenues for the City, State and Federal
Governments.
Looking to the future, the Chamber's Education Foundation will expand its training program. The new Title VII of the CETA Act, passed by the 95th Session of
Congress, should provide between $10 million and $20 million in private sector
training funds for New York City. Our Chamber has been designated as the vehicle
to carry out the mandate of the CETA Title VII legislation in New York City. The
current momentum generated by the pilot program must be maintained. Therefore
we urge approval by the Congress of the Administration's fiscal 1979 budget request
of $400 million for the CETA Private Sector Initiative Program, which is included in
the budget as it now stands.
The President's fiscal 1980 budget proposes a $729 million reduction in total
CETA outlays. The drop in total outlays is mainly the result of a phased-in reduction in public service jobs. Outlays for private sector programs can rise because Title
VII is only gradually becoming operational. The Chamber supports the Administration's proposed private sector CETA program for fiscal 1980. -

Representative MITCHELL. I guess we should start out with trying
to wrestle with the beast, and that is where we are in terms of
inflation.
Having served on the House Budget Committee and having
worked with the Senate Budget Committee, I know how we arrive
at a projected inflation figure. I am certain the President uses the
same method. We go through a lot of econometric figures and
arrive at a number.
The President says he expects the inflation rate for this year to
be about 7.5 percent.
I will put this question to all three gentlemen: From your perspective is that realistic and is that the size and nature of the beast
we will be dealing with this year, 7.5 percent?
Mr. BYROM. My feeling is that that is a very optimistic forecast.
In all fairness it was made before the difficulties in the Mideast,
but I think it fails to recognize a lot of built-in factors.
Representative MITCHELL. What is your educated guess on figures?
Mr. BYROM. I think it would be closer to 9 percent rather than
7.5 percent.
Mr. JENKINS. A minimum of 8.5 percent and likely tending
toward 9 percent.
Mr. SCHOTT. I remain a little more optimistic than that.
I believe the important thing is the trend of the inflation during
the year. Early in the year, clearly we are going to be running at 9
percent or more. I still hope that toward the end of the year we
might be in the President's ball park, having an inflation rate of 7
or 7.5 percent.
You see the slowdown in the economy that we are projecting and
hoping for, to put it bluntly to you, will help in creating an alleviation of the shortage problems that are beginning to emerge. We
think if the scenario is played out according to Mr. Jenkins-1.75
to 2 percent real growth-then the inflation rate should decline

20
somewhat by the end of the year. So I feel, for the year, if you take
an average of 1979 over 1978, we might be in the 8 to 8.5 percent
ballpark, but toward the end of the year we might be at a 7-to 7.5percent inflation rate rather than a 9-percent inflation rate.
Representative MITCHELL. I am inclined to disagree with you and
agree with Mr. Jenkins and Mr. Byrom. I think we will have a
slightly higher inflation rate than the President projects.
One of the methods that has been referred to for fighting inflation this year is attempting to hold wage settlements to a given
level. The President has proposed a real wage insurance effort.
Let me put two or three questions to all of you gentlemen for
response.
No. 1, do you think the President's proposed real wage insurance
will indeed help to hold down wage demands during this year?
No. 2, and I think one or two of you alluded to this, with
reference to the companies that you own or companies with which
you deal, do you think your companies' wage settlements for this
year will be within the guidelines proposed by the President?
Mr. BYROM. I guess we might as well stay in the same order.
I am very much concerned about wage insurance because it has
the connotation of indexing. It isn't, I know, but it implies that
although the administration is asking labor to be responsible in its
settlements, it implies -that it is really not very sure that the
efforts on anti-inflation are going to be successful and, therefore, it
says to labor: "we will protect you." It very honestly is being stated
as being a hoped for encouragement on the part of labor to accept
what could be harmful settlements for themselves if, in fact, the
inflation is not contained.
I understand and recognize the thought behind it. I guess I would
like to say that I am encouraged by what has been happening so
far in the way of wage settlements. I am not in favor of wage and
price controls, sir, but I think the guidelines at very best, very
temporarily deal with the symptoms of a disease. They don't really
get at the problem.
But the thing that they are accomplishing very temporarily in a
voluntary sense is making everybody think twice before they proceed to make a price increase or before they proceed to ask for a
wage increase that maybe would be excessive.
I would like to believe that, in fact, as a strictly temporary kind
of thing, as a cosmetic almost, the guidelines are performing a
useful purpose, they may give enough time for us to cause people
to believe that, in fact, the administration and the Congress intend
to do something about inflation. Really, that is what is needed.
We need to perceive that somebody is really going to do something about it. My only support for wage and price guidelines is
that it gives a temporary kind of thoughtful second look that may
give us time for you gentlemen-and the President-and the executive branch to prove you mean what you are saying.
I would hope- wage insurance is not necessary, if only because of
the complications that would be involved in its administration.
This is an additional and entirely different disadvantage.
Now I have talked too long and I have forgotten your second
point.

21

Representative MITCHELL. Do you think in this instance your
company will be able to hold to the guidelines and wage settlements?
Mr. BYROM. We have told the President we intend to try. So far,
we have no reason to believe we wouldn't be able to live within the
guidelines.
Representative MITCHELL. Let me put one more question to you.
Obviously you don't support price controls, but you are going to
try to stay within the wage guidelines. In the real world, suppose
one of your suppliers said, "I am going to up my prices" and they
will exceed the guidelines suggested by the President. What could
you do about that?
Mr. BYROM. Very little and if he is the sole supplier or if I don't
have other materials that I can use, but normally if I find a pricing
situation to be oppressive, I immediately look for another supplier
or I look for another material that can be used as a substitute.
One of the things I would personally do, I would go and look at
his profit and loss statement and see, in fact, what kind of money
he is making. I would like to see if he is showing a return on
investment that allows him to continue in business. If it is not-as
is the case with many utilities-I would ask our people not to move
in and argue against a rate increase because I would like to have
some energy available.
I know if people are denied a return on investment that justifies
their continuation in business, they will go out of business and
then I wouldn't have a supplier.
Again, it is a very complex kind of thing, but when you ask me
do I have alternatives, I say yes, I do, plenty of them.
The other thing is that -if, in fact, somebody is producing something where I decide I wouldn't buy it at his price, that is the way
the market is supposed to work. Maybe he is supposed to go out of
business.
Representative MITCHELL. I am glad you said "maybe." That is
the way the market is supposed to work. Obviously that has not
been my experience. I am digressing a bit, but I attempted to get
breakthroughs for minority businesses to supply various corporations. I get the same answer over and over again-"We have been
dealing with this supplier for years. Why should we change?"
Mr. BYROM. That is not what I meant, sir.
The way the market system works is that society has a chance to
vote on whether it wants a product or does not. If, in fact, there
are alternative products, alternatives that can serve the same purpose, and this particular person cannot produce the product at a
price that makes me want to buy it, I find no justification for
holding an umbrella over that person's head to stay in business.
I don't think that is the same thing at all with minority businesses. I understand what you are talking about. That is a different
question.
Representative MITCHELL. I want to come back to this because I
think we are in serious philosophical differences.
Mr. BYROM. I don't think we are.
Representative MITCHELL. I think we are. I am not sure at this
stage of our economic development in this country that we really

22
have a free-flowing, pure market demand kind of economy working.

Mr. BYROM. I agree.
Representative MITCHELL. I will make one other statement and
then I will get to the other gentlemen.
There are some things which are basic to this country. We have
seen a rise in the price of steel. Obviously there are reasons for
that price rise, but I think any economist would be hard put to
explain the rise in terms of demand in this country.
Mr. Jenkins and Mr. Schott, would you comment on the two
questions?
Mr. JENKINS. As far as real wage insurance is concerned, one can
say it is an ingenious idea. There is much to be said for it, much
against it, but I would have to say that in theory I don't believe I
would be for it. Second, although not on that same question, how it
would be administered and implemented would be a monstrosity.
Our company has gone on record that we will live within the
wage guidelines. As of today I see no reason why we cannot. There
is nothing on the horizon that indicates we cannot.
If I might make another remark, you asked Mr. Byrom about
prices. I think the industry that I represent-the life-insurance
industry-can make a rather unique, if generalized, statement:
take the price of an insurance policy for an individual, say aged 35,
with a whole life policy for 20 years or whatever, the cost of that
insurance today is no more, and may even be a little less, than it
was 25 years ago, for the same person in the same circumstances.
Representative MITCHELL. That is unique.
Mr. JENKINS. In that respect, we have not raised prices.
Mr. SCHOTT. Congressman, you asked where are we actually
going on real-wage insurance, and what if a supplier raises his
price more than the guidelines?
The real-wage insurance is the only one directly covered in our
prepared statement, therefore representing 24 large companies, our
committee, New York Chamber of Commerce and Industry as a
whole, in that statement we are opposed to real-wage insurance.
I share the notion that it is an ingenious idea. I guess I have two
basic problems with it. No. 1 is technical difficulties. If you have
one man earning $22,000 a year, presumably he would be outside
the real-wage insurance. If you have two members of the same
family earning $11,000 each, those two would be covered.
So you could have the result one family with an income of
$22,000 would be covered by the real-wage insurance and the other
would not. We find it extremely difficult technically to deal with
this.
On a more general point, we would like to say that any openended commitment by the Government to a new program, where
you really don't know what the costs of it are going to be, has the
potential of aggravating the budget deficit because it might substantially add to outlays. All of the estimates ,made for the real
cost of that wage insurance program-well, fantasy is perhaps too
strong a word, but "estimate" is already giving it too much credit,
so they are "guesses."

23
We don't like any new Government spending program that
amounts to a guess at a time when there is a serious Government
deficit.

Where are we actually going on wage-price settlements? I think
the next 6 months are going to be crucial. If you can hold wage
settlements-which are the basic component of the cost-price
push-within the guidelines over the next 6 months or so and
thereby get inflation to decelerate, I think you have a fair fighting
chance.
As far as I know, practically all big businesses have agreed to
abide by the guidelines and will do so if they are not confronted
with the situation you describe in your third question. What if the
supplier raises prices by more than the guidelines? .
I know that in most large businesses there are established procedures for taking competitive bids on anything of large size. Everything, possible would be explored before one would agree to pay
more than the price guideline, or for that matter, whatever the
high bids are, one would look for the lowest bid. But if the lowest
bid does exceed the guidelines and you need the material, then I
would agree with Mr. Byrom there is not very much you can do
about it.
Your own inflation forecast, Congressman Mitchell, suggests you
are not going to be able to hold to the wage-price guidelines. I am
not prepared to give up. I think they should be given a good, hard
try for 6 months with a lot of jawboning to see if that can be made
to work within the context of a more conservative fiscal and monetary policy which we and the President advocate.
Representative MITCHELL. Thank you.
All three of you gentlemen have indicated a concern for the rate
of spending and the number of projects for which we spend money.
Mr. Schott, I believe you referred to giveaway programs. Bear with
me for just a moment and, if you will, let your nightmares come
true.
Let's assume that all three of you are Members of Congress and
all three of you are on the Budget Committee. You have a budget
figure, a budget figure which contains uncontrollable programs; 76
percent of that budget is uncontrollable-76 percent of it. As a
Member of Congress holding to the present ideas about budget
cutting and exercising fiscal restraint, where would you begin to
cut in those uncontrollables? Would you cut old-age and survivors
insurance? That is an uncontrollable item in the budget, based on
people, and you are having to pay into the trust fund. Would you
begin to cut employment compensation benefits? Is that logical
when we still have a 6 percent or better unemployment and the
forecast is suggesting that in our efforts to fight inflation unemployment will slightly increase?.
Mr. Congressman, will you give me your advice as a Member of
Congress on this nightmare? Where would you start planning, just
dealing with uncontrollable parts?
Don't deal with that part that says "no new programs." I will
hold that separately. How do you start cutting and reducing the
cost of uncontrollable items in the budget?
Mr. JENKINS. I think we are all faced with that problem in our
businesses as well as in the Congress.

24
In direct answer to your question, I would say that if we couldif the Congress could-hold to the $29 billion deficit figure for the
coming fiscal year-sure, all of us would like to see it less-but if
we could hold to that and not wind up with a deficit in the middle
$30 billions, that would be an accomplishment. We would look to
further reduction in the deficit each year thereafter. We don't
minimiize the situation. We in business are faced with the same
problems.
Representative MITCHELL. Let me make sure I am understanding
you correctly. You are assuming the President's budget is different
for the next year. You are assuming that was not perfectly uncontrollable and I agree with you there, but then you go on to refer to
a balanced budget.
My question that still remains: Once you start moving toward
that balanced budget, with 76 percent of the items in the budget
uncontrollable, you come four-square with the problem of where do
you cut uncontrollable programs, those mandated programs? right
Mr. JENKINS. If I understand my colleague here to the
correctly, there are two ways to get this budget balanced. One is to
cut expenses and the other is to increase revenues.
The thrust of what we have to say is increase the tax base. If
some of these things were done, the governmental revenues would
get
be increased to take care of that. We could get things moving,basic
these
of
some
and
programs
expenditure
capital
these
of
some
industries we have, moving along.
I am a great believer in the marketplace. I know the market has
certain restrictions-there is no doubt about that-but I am inof
clined to believe the marketplace involving hundres of thousands
There
have.
could
we
people making decisions is the best regulator
are specific reasons what the market has not been allowed to work,
but we have a sound economy, and if we can just unleash it, we can
have a balanced budget.
Representative MITCHELL. I am glad you mentioned the area of
loss of revenues.
Based on the President's budget and law, in effect there is substantial loss in revenues or tax expenditures.
What troubles me is how could all of you argue for some further
tax relief for investment when I am sure you are all aware of the
fact that the loss of revenues from current incentives have contributed to our current deficit.
Mr. BYROM. I think you and I are thinking very much alike, but
I think we have to understand that a society which wishes to
improve the quality of its lifestyle cannot do that unless there is
wealth available to distribute beyond what was necessary to maintain equilibrium at the former level. I don't have to tell you that.
So, it is essential that that society organize itself in such a way
as to give incentives to the wealth-creation process, not your
wealth or mine, but the wealth that is available for society to
distribute as it will.
As I perceive myself, you just cast me more or less as a private
predator.
Representative MITCHELL. I certainly did not mean that. You are
much too pleasant. I would not dare do that.

25
Mr. BYROM. I see my function is creating wealth that society can
then distribute. In other words, I have a specific function to perform. The function of profits in my context is that necessary thing
that allows me to continue to perform that function for society.
I frequently refer to profits of corporations as breathing is to life.
You and I would agree we don't live to breathe, but it is very
difficult to function without it. So, the profits of a corporation are
its breath of life.
That is not the reason I exist. I exist to create that wealth. You
and other people are trying to figure out the priorities.
The difficulty in our society is that we have lost the ability to
choose between difficult alternatives. We have a pluralistic society
where each advocacy group can make a very strong pitch that its
particular need is paramount. You and I would not deny the idea
that what they are after is important. I know of none of these socalled interest groups which are not espousing something which
would be important if we could try to satisfy their goals in an
orderly way.
When you ask me how do you deal with uncontrollables, it is a
little bit like asking "have you stopped beating your wife?"
Representative MITCHELL. If it sounds like that, the question is
obviously based upon statements that the witnesses at the table
have given.
Mr. BYROM. Let's look at medicare. I suppose you could argue
that it is uncontrollable, but it involves a very large amount of
funds. For example, HEW published a study in 1973 which found
that 21.6 percent of total medicare reimbursements in 1967 was for
persons who died during that year-the study also notes that 60
percent of the persons who died in 1967 were hospital inpatients at
some time during the year.
Representative MITCHELL. You had better go ahead. I drew an
inference that frightens me.
Mr. BYROM. I am sure it does. You are going to think I am very
callous. For example, I don't believe that we can afford renal
dialysis for everybody who has kidney disease when it costs $17,000
to $20,000 per person, especially when it does not cure the person.
We do not have the wealth to do everything you and I would agree
would be the humanistic thing to do. Just to be sure you understand what I am saying, I made this remark to the deans of the
medical schools at their annual convention, and six of them just
said you have told me a complete contradiction of what I have been
taught.
There is no price on human life. We have insisted that we had to
have caps on medicines so the children couldn't get to that medicine. I have been told that the cost of that program was $100
million and it was anticipated that the total deaths avoided would
be 100.
Now, again, you are going to say you are a very callous individual. Are you saying that we the United States can't afford $100
million to save 100 children. I am not sure the occasion of death is
necessarily limited to the medicine.
What I am saying is this, and then I will be quiet: Some people
say to me, "How can you claim to be a Christian and a chief
executive officer?" The implication is how can I shut down a plant

26
which will change the well-being of a town, of a community, of
families, of people? The answer is that fundamentally my responsibility is to maintain the viability of an economic institution which,
if it survives, will create the wealth that allows us over a period of
time to eliminate proverty.
I am not callous. We can have everything we want, but not all at
the same time. We have failed as a society to understand that.
Representative MITCHELL. My question would have been believability now. I would find it difficult to say, "Pull the plug." I have
never been more humanistic.
Mr. SCHoTT. I would like to deal with the questions of giving
away revenue under circumstances in which the Government
budget is unbalanced and then the question of uncontrollable
expenditures.
I am afraid there was a misunderstanding about the revenue
being given away. I would not be in favor of that. On the contrary,
our prepared statement says very plainly under the present circumstances there should be no further tax cuts at this time. We
are flatly against tax cuts until the Government budget is more
nearly in balance.
I would not want to be thought of as voting for a giveaway
program.
I would also point out if it were not for the tax cut of 1979, that
is the tax cut that became effective January 1, the Government
budget for fiscal 1980 would be much more nearly in balance than
it is likely to be. The revenues of the Government are rising quite
rapidly-for fiscal 1978, $402 billion; for fiscal 1979, $456 billion, an
increase of about 12 percent. And revenues for fiscal 1980 rise to a
projected $503 billion, that is about a 10-percent increase even with
the tax cut. So, obviously there is more money to do something
with each year.
If it were not for the tax cuts, we would be in the position of
being at a nearly balanced budget. I am not in favor of a balanced
budget at all times, only in times of high employment.
I happen to believe, Congressman Mitchell, that there are no
such things as uncontrollable expenditures provided that you give
us a little time frame within which to operate. To be sure, once you
have enacted a program, and have committed yourself open-ended
to, say, give such-and-such to all eligible under such-and-such criteria, that is uncontrollable. You can no longer control how much
you would spend.
Yet that becomes controllable. If you took a 3- or 5-year timeframe, every funding program should be subject to your review.
You should start out with the old budget considerations, each time
around on each spending program. You would find there are very
few uncontrollable expenditures.
Take the military expenditures. Are they uncontrollable? I say
they are not, Congressman. The expenditures are uncontrollable
only after you build yourself the box you are already in.
Representative MITCHELL. I would like to put one other question
to all three of the witnesses.
We have heard testimony from Mr. Jenkins and Mr. Schott to
indicate that so far as the private sector is concerned, there is a

27
possibility of real growth being at around a rate of 1.75 to 2
percent for 1979. I believe that is what you answered.
Again there was testimony to the effect that capital outlays in
your mind over this next year will be about one-half that of the
last 2 years; is that correct? If these are true projections, it seems
to me they are not moving toward a moderate slowdown in the
economy. It seems to me we are really moving toward some type of
recessionary period based upon reductions in investment for this
year and based upon your real growth rate.
Now add to those two factors, the monetary policies that Chairman Miller has suggested he is going to pursue. I suppose this year
he will hold monetary growth within the guidelines of M, and M2 ,
the guidelines he presents to the Congress. I suppose he will hold
within them.
I would further assume those guidelines are a little tight, that
the ceiling would be a little tighter. It seems to me there are three
factors involved which operationally suggest a recessionary trend.
May I have your comment? Am I misinterpreting the facts?
Mr. JENKINS. No I don't think you are misinterpreting the facts.
A recession by definition is to have two successive quarters at zero
or minus growth in real GNP, as I understand it. Our projections
are that there might be two quarters this year that will approach
that, but with a pickup toward the end of the year, and a further
pick up in 1980.
Now, it is true that this could get out of phase time-wise. I
believe all of us were rather pleasantly surprised with the robustness of the figures for the fourth quarter of 1978-I would prefer to
call this an adjustment. We expect in the following year, 1980, real
GNP and business capital outlays should turn around and increase.
But I get back to the horse that I ride all the time, which is that if
we had a better investment environment we could get these, capital
expenditures we need.
Representative MITCHELL. Including regulations and all the other
things you alluded to.
Mr. JENKINS. Yes.
Representative MITCHELL. Are there any further comments?
Mr. SCHOTT. As I stated in the prepared statement,-we endorse
the Federal Reserve's restraint. Growth targets are hard to define,
but I would like to note it is the growth not the mechanical
measurement of interest rates.
It could be that with the monetary, aggregate targets that the
Federal Reserve has now established, it could be that with those
you will have a moderation in economic growth and in inflation. If
that is not sufficient, then you have to have more emphatic restraint.

If a major recession should occur, then I believe the targets
should be liberalized. I don't feel you should feel nailed to the wall,
and I would hope there is flexibility in Federal Reserve policy.
I think their targets are reasonable for the presently foreseeable
future. They should be permitted to do their thing until further
notice. I do say this too, Congressman, if you did not have the
Government deficit, then monetary policy could be more expansive.
People complaining about interest rates should look in the mirrors. One of the main credit demands that has to be financed in the

28
market is Treasury notes, bills, and bonds. If the Treasury itself
would not be such a demander of additional funds, chances are
interest rates would not be as high as they are now.
So, within that context, the Federal Reserve has been performing
a creditable job.
Mr. BYROM. I agree that some of the actions we are taking are
probably going to tend to move away from what I referred to
earlier as a consumption bias. I would be hopeful that there would
be a tendency toward savings. I would hope that that savings
would end up in investment, but that is a big hope. I understand
that.
I am concerned about capital spending certainly in the near
term. I am satisfied that in a reasonably short period, and by near,
I am talking 4 or 5 years and-in terms of the history of civilization that is not very long-this Nation has to some way or other do
something about turning around the liquidation of its capital base.
It may fundamentally change the nature of the way we carry out
our production in primary areas of the country. As a pessimist,
about the way things are going, I feel the whole concept in private
industry is under great siege, and there may be reason to believe
that it is not going to survive.
In the long run we will build more plants and we will begin to
introduce the technology that is available to us to increase the
productivity of our society. Until we do, we are going to be in deep,
deep trouble. We have less and less wealth and we continue to
demand more and more from that base.
I am not worried about the Fed showing monetary restraint. I
think that is helpful at the present time. If and when we do move
toward recessionary tendencies, I would hope monetary policies
would be the mechanism with which we try to deal with this
problem, not fiscal policy.
I would rather see an easier monetary policy trying to deal with
a situation than I would building, in the future, uncontroll'ables
into our fiscal base. I think that could very well happen.
I don't think that we can anticipate that any of us are smart
enough to sit down and say exactly what we will do when things
start to happen that way.
At the present time, we are not in a recession and frankly I don't
see any signs of moving to one. We are just worried about the fact
that we probably will move toward one. We are in an inflationary
spiral which I don't think we have seen the end of.
One of the reasons I am pessimistic, is that I believe the wholesale price index has yet to appear on the decline. We must find a
way of answering the problem and learn to be flexible-for instance, some feel the President should have the option available
whereby he could move taxes up or down for a limited period of
time, subject to congressional veto. I think we need some flexibility.
We don't have it with our fiscal policy.
Representative MITCHELL. I would say I see both fiscal and monetary policies involved and needing flexibility. Thank you.
Congressman Brown, please take over, I have to leave.
Representative BROWN [presiding]. I want to thank you for your
discussion.

29
Mr. Byrom, I do want to give an appropriate reason for asking
some of the questions I am going to ask. I have to make a speech to
a steel group shortly.
I understand you are in a unique position to comment on the
steel industry. You are a metallurgist by trade, and your firm is
one of the major manufacturers for the steel industry. You are one
of the leading industrialists in the country.
Would you share with me your view as to the prospects for the
national economy.
Mr. BYROM. If I may first say I am not sure I am as qualified as
you give me credit for but that is fine. It is true I was a metallurgist by training, but I have not been working at metallurgy since I
was 2 years out of college.
Representative BROWN. I am not sure the metallurgist will save
the steel industry.
Mr. BYROM. I am very, very worried about the steel industry. In
fact I am so much of a pessimist, I honestly believe within 5 years
we could be at the point of no return as to whether it will be
necessary to inject public funding in order to keep the industry
from going down the drain.
We have in the United States a series of steel plants which, for
the most part, are obsolete in terms of today's technology. We have
a highly fragmented industry in which no component has an incremental share of the market available to it which justifies the use of
the scale economies that are possible on.the basis of the available
technologies.
We, in fact, have had de facto price control in the industry for 15
years or more. The return on investment in the industry is unacceptable on the basis of reported earnings and the reported earnings don't tell the true story.
Due to the shortfall in depreciation allowances, due to unfunded
pension liabilities, I honestly know of no steel company today
which is showing a return on its investment. It is not that capital
is not available to build the plants. It is that the economics of the
project do not justify investing money in it.
Interesting enough, the United Kingdom went through this same
situation and came to the point where it was impossible, using
private funds, to nationalize the industry. So they went ahead and
proceeded to create the British Steel Co. with the intention of
nationalizing the industry and using economies of scale. That was
brilliant.
The only problem with it was, once they did it, then Parliament
stepped in. Parliament was pushed by certain political forces, if
you will, when they tried to shut down the obsolete plant, the
representatives from those districts said, "You can't do fthat, you
will put my people out of work." So they have kept the old plants
operating, but it has been denied the new plant.
Could the new plant operate at capacity?
The British Steel Co. is losing a billion dollars a year 'all from
public funds.
If you go around the world, you can see situations where the
steel industry if being used as a public-works program or for socialpolitical purposes as viewed by that particular sovereign nation,

47-977 0 - 79 - 3

30

and almost everywhere the steel companies are owned or subsidized by public funds.
We are asking our industry to compete in a world with that kind
of competition.
The problem is we are imposing on top of this competition requirements for environmental control and requirements for improvements in the occupational safety and health conditions in the
plant. We are in a situation where, fundamentally, the reported
revenues of the United States Steel Corp., where 78 percent of
their sales came from the steel industry to less than 12 percent of
their earnings-and this was without recognizing the shortfall in
depreciation or the unfunded pension liability.
What I am saying to you is that the steel industry today is losing
money, and we are not going to be able to do the things we need to
do. A large part of the problem is antitrust policy. We are not
allowing them to do the aggregations that are necessary to allow
them to utilize the technology available to us.
Does that respond to your question?
Representative BROWN. It does, and I share some of your concerns and agree with some of your suggestions about actions that
might be taken. I sit as a member of the board of visitors of the
Harvard Business School. At our last meeting, they gave us a very
interesting case to look at, the miracle of modern Japan from the
mid-fifties to the year 1971. They have gotten into some troubles
since then, but it bespoke the Japanese policy decision at the end
of World War II to undertake world competition as a national
matter, in some of the most difficult and highly technical areas
which many other countries were decidedly far superior.
*They decided not to go back to making toys and paper parasols,
but to take on the world steel industry, to take on the world
automobile industry, the electronics and computer industry, and
other industries of similar nature. They have done very well, but
they have done it as a national policy with the ramifications of
national monopolies in these areas. Shipbuilding was another of
these industries, and in most instances that decision has been
directed pretty much at us.
I think the steel industry would certainly suggest it is directed at
us, and the automobile industry, and they have done very well.
Now, some of the things they have done would perhaps be in the
range of national subsidization that you suggested might be necessary in the steel industry.
It seems to me there are some steps we could take therefore;
first, those related to our antitrust procedures, and second, those
related to the writeoff or depreciation of equipment.
I have some economic statistics put together by the staff on the
minority side of this committee looking at the profits of the steel
industry since about 1958, the time the Japanese started their
effort, as you suggested-frankly, your years are a little understated-for 20 years, or a little longer, during which we have had
wage-price controls, to some extent wage controls, and certainly
profit controls-you have to go back to the time that Harry
Truman suggested he was going to nationalize the steel industry
after World War II.

31

The upshot was, given the profits and depreciation of steelmill
capital, profits have not been sufficient to modernize the industry.
So the net result of about 20 years of operation of the industry is a
negative figure.
That certainly bodes ill for us as a society.
We in Ohio are going through struggles such as the Youngstown
problem. We are talking about a plant which had its last major
modification in 1915 or 1916. They are almost ancient history, and
I am almost ancient history myself. But the upshot is that we do
have a very bad steel policy. Because of the under appreciation,
there was a taxing of the industry which is another factor. This
could be resolved if we had a higher replacement writeoff.
It seems to me that is a first step before we decide to subsidize
the industry from other producers of wealth in this society. Would
you agree with this?
Mr. BYROM. I certainly would, and, having been as pessimistic as
I sounded, there are some alternatives. I was talking to Mr. Jenkins before the hearing. Several years ago my company made the
proposition that we get financial institutions to underwrite a
modern plant which would be operated by an operating company to
produce ingots.
In other words, it would be coke, blast furnace, basic oxygen
furnace, and continuous casting. It would be a continuing water
port, expending between 8 to 10 million tons. It might be down in
the gulf coast, you would barge the ingots upriver to various rolling
facilities elsewhere.
The operating company would have a lease, a hell-or-high-water
lease, with a financial institution which would be guaranteed by
take or pay contracts with credit-worthy steel corporations.
Now, the thing did not fly. One of the reasons it did not fly was
people were worried about antitrust policy. This would be a case of
three or four companies, no one of which had need for more than 1
million or 2 million tons of steel-in effect working in an indirect
way, in a way to produce an economically sized plant. That is one
way of doing it.
Mr. JENKINS. Let me interrupt to say that we are inconsistent
here. Business is allowed to do it with raw materials. The iron ore
projects are consortiums. If we could do something like this as an
institution-and we have looked at this many times-to let's say
get the economy of scale of a major blast furnace through a consortium, as Mr. Byrom said, we would finance it, just as we have done
with the raw materials.
Why is it against policy to do this for, say, a blast furnace? One
of the things that came home to me the other day is that we have
not built a new large blast furnace in this country for so long that
when one of the major steel companies was considering it and went
to the drawing boards, they felt they had to go to Japan for the
technology. To illustrate how times have changed, Japan got the
original technology from us post-World War II. Now we have to go
back to them for the technology.
Representative BROWN. You have stimulated my interest.
My c4her interest is in the Subcommittee on Energy. Not very
many new "refijierie4, have been built in this country in recent
years. One of the protlems w6 have l4ad, is the development of

32
nuclear power. Now we see as a national policy the White House
has turned its back on it. In recent testimony of one of the science
committees on the House side, an Assistant Secretary of the Department of Energy is supposed to have said that he is not particularly worried about our delay of nuclear power in this country;
other countries were developing it; namely, the French, and if they
came up with anything really good, we could buy the technology
later on.
That had two assumptions. One is the assumption that they
would sell it to us, and the other is that we would have the money
to buy it with.
I am not sure if it were the dollar which now seems to be
becoming old-fashioned and not as valuable as it once was, or, if
there were some other method of purchasing.
Mr. BYROM. I don't know if you know that the steel industry is
importing coke from Germany at a level which is equivalent to
about 20 percent of their requirements.
The difficulty is, when the Germans run out of the surplus of
coke they have, we are not going to have in this country coke
which is available to produce the iron that we need to make the
steel.
The amount of coke-Representative BROWN. As a matter of technological development or a matter of resources?
Mr. BYROM. About 40 percent of the coke ovens, and we build
them, and this may sound self-serving, but 40 percent are over 25
years old. The normal life of a coke oven is about 30 years. These
ovens are for the most part nonconforming as far as OSHA and
EPA requirements. From the time you get a given order to the
Koppers to build a coke plant, it takes us the better part of 36 to 40
months to build it. The amount of coke we are importing annually
would require about 10 economically sized batteries to produce
today. The refractories industry can only make enough brick to
handle three or four of these projects at a time.
What I am saying is, right now we are short of about 20 percent
of capacity to satisfy our requirements at a 90-percent operation of
the steel industry. That is going to get worse before it gets better.
There is no way a company can justify a new coke plant. We are
going to end up in a situation where we are going to have to
import a significant portion of our steel, not because we want to,
but we will have no choice.
Mr. JENKINS. We could be in the same position in the steel
industry 3 or 4 years out as we are in the oil industry todaydependent on foreign sources.
Mr. BYROM. The problem is it does not stop in steel. It is true in
the nonferrous industries, it is true in copper smelting. You can
just go down the line in capital-intensive industries in the United
States where we are liquidating our productive base.
Representative BROWN. I am told it is also true in the utility
field. You may talk to your friend and neighbor-Mr. BYROM. I think we are past the point of no return in the
utility field.
Mr. SCHOTr. We point out in our statement that we endorse
essentially the President's Economic Report when it comes to regu-

33
latory and productivity policy, but we think it does not go far
enough. It is just the beginning of a vague recognition of the
problem. The President has made some gestures in that direction,
such as the Intergovernmental Council on Regulation, which is
now supposed to bring some order to the chaotic situation in which
one agency after another issues contradictory orders depending on
its own criteria.
We are saying, as a minimum, there should be a moratorium on
additional regulatory orders preventing modernization and productivity improving measures in basic industry so that industry can
adjust to existing regulations and gradually come up with technology that would take account of existing regulations, not be hit with
additional regulations, but 6an adjust it so that on the basis you
can then make productivity advances. That seems to be the
rational way of getting out of that.
Mr. BYROM. Right.
Representative BROWN. Let me make a comment, which is not to
disparage your company. Senator Bentsen and I have proposed
joint legislation addressing the regulatory problem. You mentioned
contradictory regulations. We would address that by making the
Office of Management and Budget resolve those contradictions and
eliminate one regulation or the other. Nonetheless, this results in
OMB trying to be the traffic cop for terminating the contradictions
within regulations.
We have also tried to encourage, in writing this legislation, the
establishment of a productivity test of the regulations so we are
not spending $5 to get a 20-cent improvement in some areas, and
similarly that we have a regulatory budget so that the budget
enforcing private expenditures would be considered in the same
way one would consider the budget of taxation. But when the local
utility company is obliged to put on a scrubber-and that embraces
almost everyone-it is almost like the tax that goes on every
citizen at the requirement of the Federal Government in our interests to clean up the environment.
It seems to me one of the problems we face in trade, for instance,
is that while the Japanese have been resolving to take over the
steel industry of the world, the United States has been resolving to
clean up the air of at least our corner of the world. Perhaps those
are noble motives and should not be taken facetiously in and of
themselves. If the Japanese gave thought to any environment,
maybe we would be not in the position we are in, and the Japanese
would not be as far ahead of us as they are in steel.
Mr. BYROM. They would have a significant advantage because
their concept of the use of technology is much more intelligent
than ours is as a nation. As I am sure you know, when they get to
a certain level of demand below their supply capabilities, they set
up what they call a recession cartel where they agree that they
will eliminate the least efficient production operation for an 8month period and will concentrate production in the most efficient,
so they take their most efficient production and concentrate that
production on those plants which operate at 100 percent of capacity
during that period.
Our system distributes uniformly across the board.

34
Representative BROWN. The IRS taxing arrangement makes it
more economical to use the older plant.
Mr. BYROM. There is another thing that happens and I am sure
you know this. They do not use a very significant amount of equity
in their capital structure. They are 80- to 85-percent debt.
Now, this would be frowned on by my friend, Mr. Jenkins. If the
Koppers Co. operated with 85 percent, he would not be one of the
people willing to lend me any money.
The reason it works in Japan is that the Bank of Japan guarantees the debt so the commercial bank is all taken care of and there
is no concern about it.
When you can operate your company on the basis where all you
have to do is service the interest on the debt but you never have to
pay off the principals this changes the economics of your production significantly. That is what we are asking our private steel
industry to compete with and all the rest of our industry to compete with.
We are saying to the steel industry that it should act as though
the rest of the world does not exist, as though the United States is
an island, that it is an isolated market and we have to maintain
competition between us. Our antitrust policy refuses to recognize
that aluminum is an alternative to steel and that plastics are an
alternative to both of them.
It refuses to recognize that there are producers throughout the
rest of the world who are prepared to invade our market at the
drop of a hat. We are forcing ourselves into a protectionist stance
which could be a disaster for the world. It is obvious to me why.
I am not very smart.
Representative BROWN. The antitrust laws were written shortly
after the McKinley-Harris legislation and you had a different concept of what you were trying to do with the protection of developing industry in the United States than you have now.
Mr. BYROM. What can we do about it now?
Representative BROWN. One thing you might try to do about it is
educate Members of Congress. I am trying to do that on the inside,
but I am having even less success.
Mr. BYROM. Imagine how difficult it would be for me to do it.
Representative BROWN. People in the private sector have some
influence over the way people vote in their own bailiwick. Even
people like Mr. Jenkins live and vote in precincts someplace and
perhaps might get involved in the political process. I know these
multinational and large organizations are really considered floating crap games in terms of their local and parochial interests and,
therefore, have no home, but I still think it would be nice if you
took advantage of the locality which you do live in and got interested politically in a much more progressive way than you are, because that is where the game is and Congress has been doing this
and will continue to do it, whether wisely or unwisely.
I would like to take time to lecture you about something else
that I think you are all wrong on.
Considering the fact I am so outnumbered, I don't know whether
I will get into it or not. That has to do with your limited view of
indexing the tax system. I would like to suggest to you that the
Canadian experience has been that the people who are most un-

35
happy with it are first, the budget-makers who must try to reduce
Federal spending in Canada and the next most unhappy people are
the politicians, who can't offer tax cuts every year.
Giving it now doesn't get the political benefit of cutting taxes.
When those two groups are unhappy, it seems to me it is probably
a pretty good system. The test is whether or not the Canadians will
learn the restraint required by the budget requirements that they
have automatically placed upon themselves.
We have no limits that we place upon ourselves in terms of tax
revenues because we are now benefitting from inflation and, therefore, have learned no restraint whatsoever. It is a little bit like the
problems created by the bill. You know, when money has become
so free and easy through the inflation bonus that the Federal
Government gets because of increased revenues as a result of the
inflation they create, that we just simply spend money will-nilly
without any concern about where it must come from, because it all
comes automatically without raising taxes.
They raise automatically.
Mr. BYROM. I admit my objection to it may have a touch of
idealism. The thing that bothers me about indexing is that it
recognizes inflation as being something that is going to be with us.
I am just unwilling to quit yet.
I don't think that has to be the truth. What you are saying is a
very pragmatic response to a condition and you may very well be
right. I just hate to give in at this point. I keep hoping that
somehow or other people will be able to recognize that inflation
does not have to be with us and that it is caused by excesses and
our unwillingness to deal with the inability to choose.
Representative BROWN. When my constituents write me-and I
think the same is true with my colleagues-about inflation, they
don't write about the inflation of taxes. They write to me about the
inflation of grocery costs or gasoline or something that they deal
with every other day or two, and that is the area that they are
afflicted by.
I can't think that people will get less inflation-conscious if we put
the skids on one aspect which may be fairly fundamental so that
some of the others may continue to be concerned about it.
Mr. SCHOTr. May I comment on that?
Representative BROWN. Certainly, Mr. Schott.
Mr. SCHOrr. I believe the basic responsibility of Congress is to
restrain spending directly. You can restrain by cutting taxes and
hope to make the Government deficit less, but that strikes me as
being second best.
Representative BROWN. We have this Draculian effect-cut off
the blood supply and maybe the monster will die.
Mr. SCHOTT. As regards Canada, it does not work. Canada has
had a higher rate of government spending and higher rate of
inflation and higher rate of unemployment than the United States.
People are fed up with the workings of that system. Of course, tax
indexing is just one small aspect of the total picture. Their spending restraints have not worked; therefore, their printing presses
have been more active yet.
If you were to try to go at this directly, I suggest that you should
try in conjunction with your colleagues to systematically limit the

36
rate of increase of Federal spending. In this way you will build a
case for stabilization and eventual reduction of tax rates that is
much sounder than to rely on the notion that Congress will not
approve of the budget deficit that would result from taxcutting
before you restrain spending.
Representative BROWN. That is like trying to catch AA members
at Beatty's Bar. You don't really have a very good audience for
cutting Federal spending when you start talking about the Members of Congress. We do seem to have some outside sources that are
pressing at us; 24 or 25 of the States have now come up with
constitutional convention calls or the approval of resolutions calling for a constitutional amendment reducing spending and suddenly they seem to have gotten the attention of Congress.
That does not indicate we have given up the bad habits. It is just
that they have gotten our attention. We are trying to figure how to
frustrate the restraining influences these people want to put on us
and how we can avoid the constitutional convention or the constitutional amendment, but nobody seems quite ready to take the
pledge of temperance in the spending game.
They talked a good game in 1978 in the campaigns, but I am not
sure whether that is a Damascus Road conversion or just a conversion for the benefit of the election campaign.
Mr. SCHOTT. Mr. Congressman, just for the record, I would like to
note in fiscal 1978 the increased Federal Government spending was
12.2 percent; fiscal 1979 now has an estimated 9.5 percent. The
President's proposal for fiscal 1980 is an increase of 7.7 percent in
outlays.
I suggest to you, Mr. Congressman, that your focus of attention
should be on making these figures come true and, if at all possible,
improve upon them. There is no reason why the Government outlays in 1980 have to go up the full 7.7 percent.
Representative BROWN. We have had proposals to cut back on
impact aid to schools, among other things. Every President of the
United States since Dwight Eisenhower has tried that, and that is
when the program began. They have been trying to cut a foot or
tail off that monster and nobody has been successful.
On that hinges a great deal of the deficit, to the $30 billion level.
I suggest there has been cosmetic conservatism in that budget
that is not real. We are not forced to make decisions in some of the
harder areas. I have some difficulty in whether or not we are going
to get those cuts. I think there has to be a great deal more aggressiveness about those things than has been evident up to now.
Mr. SCHorr. I don't see how you would help that situation by
cutting taxes.
Representative BROWN. I don't think I ever mentioned cutting
taxes, but I think we would have some difficulty making progress
in the basic industries if we don't in some way cut taxes or at least
if we don't in some way make a realistic adjustment like the
depreciation rate. This has an impact on the nature of what government takes from productive industry in the form of taxes because that depreciation rate is not realistic and therefore increases
the tax take rather than reducing it.
Mr. BYROM. I ran into trouble with Congressman Mitchell, who I
think has concluded that basically I am an inhuman kind of person

37
in that, in my presentation on that, I am saying fundamentally
what we have to do is move the bias of our tax revenues away from
a consumption bias and incentives toward consumption and get it
to at least where there is a removal of obstructions to investments.
Representative BROWN. I know you are a businessman and politician, but I am a businessman, too. I think it should be inflation
bias. We have inflation bias in our system because the tax system
was devised during the great recession to get the money out of the
mattress and into circulation.
Mr. BYROM. That is much better, but the problem is until we get
our productive base improved to the point where it can start to
create wealth to the degree that it has in the past and can again,
we must limit our desires and aspirations for doing everything that
will bring the quality of life up to the highest level that we perceive ourselves.
We can't afford to do it until we are creating the wealth.
Representative BROWN. I want to leave the group on a harmonious note. Let me just conclude perhaps by suggesting that all of us,
Mr. Schott, Mr. Jenkins, and Mr. Byrom want to balance the
budget. Speaking for myself, I would like to balance the budget at
a relatively low level of tax taken out of our system so that the
money could be left among those people who produce.
I think that will have the impact of making the pie larger and
therefore ultimately increasing the amount of money that the Federal Government or State and local governments have to build
social organizations and structures that have been so beneficial to
our society.
I just want to suggest one other idea for the CED to look at. I am
not sure we had a CED representative here when I suggested this.
Perhaps we need a Department of Foreign Trade in this country or
at least something within the Department of Commerce that elevates our interest in trade, because it has now become not 6 percent of our economy as it was just 6 years ago when I got on the
Joint Economic Committee, but now 20 percent of our total GNP
revolves around the whole trade issue.
If we are to be competitive and not victims in the foreign trade
programs of our country, then it seems to me we have to have
somebody who will have the stature, with all due respect to the
President, to speak about the importance of approaching the steel
industry from the standpoint of a national asset rather than as a
bunch of parochial mom and pop competitors operating entirely
within the structure of the geographic United States.
We may be able to rationalize our sudden move away from high
tariffs to low tariffs with the Sherman Antitrust Act and a few of
the other pieces of legislation that now make our regulators think
in terms of busting up our competitive ability rather than enhancing it.
Nobody in our society today wants to speak in favor of monopolies because we have such a national bias against them. On the
other hand, when we deal with the Japanese, the Germans, the
French, the British, and all the other competitors, not to mention
the Communist bloc which, of course, is a nationalized monopoly,
we are dealing with people who are competing with us from the

38
economies of scale of a monopoly which their national private or
public interest represents.
It seems to me that we have to recognize this in terms of where
we head in foreign trade and maybe one way to do that is to set up
a Department of Foreign Trade. I am sure in this administration,
the first secretary will be Mr. Strauss and he might even be the
first one under a Republican administration if he could get his act
together in some other ways.
With that I think we had better close the hearing or I will be
accused of taking advantage of Congressman Mitchell's geniality.
We are adjourned until tomorrow.
Thank you very much.
[Whereupon, at 12:28 p.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene
at 10 a.m., Friday, February 23, 1979.]

THE 1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE
PRESIDENT
FRIDAY, FEBRUARY 23, 1979
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,

Washington, D.C.

The committee met, pursuant to recess, at 10:05 a.m., in room
1202, Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Lloyd Bentsen (chairman of the committee) presiding.
Present: Senators Bentsen and Javits; and Representatives
Brown and Heckler.
Also present: Louis C. Krauthoff II, assistant director-director,
SSEC; Lloyd C. Atkinson, William R. Buechner, Kent H. Hughes,
L. Douglas Lee, and M. Catherine Miller, professional staff members; Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; and Charles H.
Bradford, minority counsel.
OPENING STATEMENT OF SENATOR BENTSEN, CHAIRMAN

Senator BENTSEN. This hearing will come to order.
The U.S. economy continued its upward expansion in 1978 for
the fourth year in a row.
Real GNP grew at the healthy clip of 4.3 percent. Employment

rose by 3.3 million and the unemployment rate dropped by more
than a full percentage point. Corporate profits rose in 1978, and
this combined with the continued rise in capacity utilization helped
to spur a much needed increase in real nonresidential fixed investment. Despite sharply increasing interest rates, the housing
market showed continued resiliency.
These good news developments, however, were marred by an
acceleration of inflation in 1978, and its apparent continued acceleration in the first month of this year as reflected in the whopping
1.3 percent January increase in the wholesale price index.
Part of the deteriorating inflation picture can be explained by
the rapid increase in food prices in the early part of the year, by
the extreme poor showing of productivity growth, and by the substantial depreciation of the dollar on foreign exchange markets.
However, the accelerating rate of inflation was not due to these
factors alone. On the contrary, during 1978 there was a marked
increase in our underlying rate of inflation of perhaps 2 percent or

more.
As a result of our deteriorating inflation picture, reducing inflation has become the top priority policy for 1979 and 1980. The
demand restraint program proposed by the administration and the
Federal Reserve clearly reflects their concern with inflation. The
(39)

40

trick, of course, is to achieve overall restraint without, at the same
time, triggering a recession.
In my view, the administration's anti-inflation program provides
too little in the way of incentives for capital formation. A high rate
of capital formation is needed if we are to reverse the disastrous
course of productivity growth in the American economy which, in
turn, is essential to the success of our longrun goal of significantly
slowing inflation.
The need for additional capital incentives is clear. The problem
is that inflation itself significantly retards investment spending if
for no other reason than that the "historic cost" basis of depreciation lowers real corporate after-tax profits and therefore the real
after-tax rate of return to investment.
We have before us today a very distinguished panel of economists, starting with Barry Bosworth.
Mr. Bosworth, it is very timely having you here this morning,
what with the recent court decision in Nashville and some announcements this afternoon on the CPI at 2:30, as I understand it.
Mr. Bosworth is Director of the Council on Wage and Price
Stability, who will discuss the progress being made with the administration's voluntary wage and price program and the overall antiinflation program.
Mr. Bosworth, we will start with your testimony, and we will
proceed without interruption to let each of the witnesses make
their comments before responding to questions.
I will want you, in your statement, to respond to this court
decision concerning the TVA.
STATEMENT OF BARRY P. BOSWORTH, DIRECTOR, COUNCIL ON
WAGE AND PRICE STABILITY

Mr. BOSWORTH. All right.
I will submit my prepared statement for the record, and make a
few introductory remarks.
I will first outline what I think the basic question is in the
development of the administration's anti-inflation program and
then comment about our progress and difficulties that we have
encountered.
First of all, although I realize that there are a wide variety of
factors responsible for inflation and that there is a wide amount of
disagreement in the country on exactly what factors should be
emphasized, I do think that some sense could be made out of the
problem of inflation if we try to place it into two fundamental
areas.
No. 1, it is a problem that has grown out of the last decade of the
continuing momentum of inflation which has built up in the economy because of the price increases and expectation that those price
increases are going to continue.
I think that basic underlying process of inflation is not tied that
much to excess demand. It is not inflation of a historical type with
demands for goods and services higher than the supply.
Instead, it is basically an inflation which most people in the
economy are operating in a purely defensive fashion, trying to
protect themselves. Most wage increases are justified simply on the

41

basis that prices have risen and people expect them to continue.
Most business firms are behaving about the same way.
The first problem is that this momentum that has so deeply
drained the economy and built up over the last several years, and
we have to brake it.
The second problem concerns government actions. In particular,
some foreign developments have tended to exacerbate that momentum of the inflation.
Also, the chairman referred to another one of them, the very
sharp decline in productivity which occurred over the last decade.
In the 1950's to 1960's, we averaging productivity growth near 3
percent a year. In the last 10 years, the economy has been capable
of generating a rate of productivity of less than 2 percent a year. In
the last 2 years, despite a very strong economic expansion program,
productivity has grown less than 1 percent a year.
I think the factors responsible for that productivity slowdown are
considerably more important than capital formation.
Senator BENTSEN. I agree with that, Mr. Bosworth. You are
talking about the administration's projection. It is, as I recall it,
four-tenths of 1 percent of productivity growth again for next year;
isn't that right?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I think that the Congressional Budget Office
projection is usually slightly more than the administration's. The
administration's forecast anticipates only about a six-tenths percent growth in producivity over the next year, so it is a little bit
better.
I think that there is a variety of factors responsible for that
productivity slowdown that we have to address.
One of the problems is that we do not completely understand
why producitivy has slowed down the economy to the extent it has
in the last decade. We can only list some of the major factors.
In the first part of the period, I think it is difficult to argue that
it was caused by capital formation, because of its historical peaks
in 1974. Yet the slowdown in productivity growth can be traced
well before that period.
We have had a very rapid growth in the labor force over the last
decade that has tended to give us a young and inexperienced work
force. We expect that to be a sort of transitory factor as we look
forward to the 1980's as these workers reach their more productive
years, and it should result in some improvement in productivity.
Since 1974, however, I think capital formation has been a poor
factor. It has not been strong, particularly, in the area of the
development of the new plants to be disposed of, or existing plants
since large productivity tends to occur principally when you have a
new plant being constructed.
Another major factor that we should identify has been the rapid
growth in U.S. Government regulations dealing with such objectives as improving the environment and worker health and safety.
These regulations have had a lot of noneconomic benefits, but their
costs show up in terms of the economy as a decline in the measured rate of growth for productivity.
If I were to put numbers on it, I would think some were around
three-tenths to four-tenths in our studies of the productivity
growths, due to the capital formation, something on the order of

42
magnitude of about four-tenths, due to the shift in the composition
of the work force, and some were around three-quarters of 1 percent for currently occurring conditions, because of the impacts
under the Federal regulation.
The second problem that has to be addressed is to find a way to
accelerate that productivity, if we are to do something about inflation.
Another area closely related to such regulatory costs lies in the
responsibility of Government. All the special legilsation that has
been passed in recent years, such as the actions being taken to
protect individual groups from both foreign and domestic competition, the attempts to guarantee minimum wages in all these actions, has been adding very considerably to the inflationary pressure in recent years, and adding to that momentum of inflation
that has built up over the last decade.
The administration's program has been designed to try to deal
with all of this. First, however, I want to discuss how that program
can be successful in braking the momentum of the private sector.
I think there are two approaches that we can all agree would
work. One is extreme fiscal and monetary restraint, which will
succeed in braking this inflationary momentum. The other option
would be wage and price controls. However, we have not adopted
either policy because of the tremendous costs that they bring to
society as a whole.
First of all, with respect to fiscal and monetary policies all you
have to do is look back at the past recessions. They were extremely
expensive in terms of unemployment.
Trying to break the current inflation by sole reliance on the
fiscal and monetary restraints to put the economy into a severe
recession would raise unemployment costs to an unacceptable level.
Our own indications are that we would like to try to reduce the
current rate of inflation to one-half of its current level in the next
2 or 3 years.
Another way of looking at it is on the basis of past historical
experience; it would cost the country about 1 million people unemployed for about a 2-year period to bring inflation down 1 percentage point. That cost is too high.
At the same time, I think that wage and price controls could deal
with inflation. But again, I think the cost of those policies are far
too high. We would create distortion and other problems in the
economic system that made people so mad about inflation to begin
with.
I don't think the Government has the technical expertise to set
prices in an economy as complicated as ours, and I think that both
equity and political considerations say the Federal Government
should never get involved in the business of trying to set individual
wages.
The problem with wage and price controls is simply that they
are too complicated. We have no mechanism to apply them in a
fair and equitable fashion. Therefore, I think we are forced to
something in between.
It seems to me the current policy combines two approaches to
brake the momentum. First, fiscal and monetary restraints to slow
the inflation, but not a fiscal and monetary restraint so severe as

43
to reverse the progress that has been made in reducing unemployment in current years. The intent of this fiscal and monetary
policy is to relieve inflationary pressures by holding the economy
at the current levels of operation. We do not want to go backwards,
but at the same time we admit that we cannot continue to expand
the way we have been expanding in recent years.
Second, we are adding to that some voluntary measures to see if
that fiscal and monetary policy can be translated in a greater
amount at less cost in terms of unemployment than would be the
case in the absence of those standards.
I think the combination of those two policies can gradually, but
certainly not overnight, result in substantial moderation of wage
and price inflation. At the same time, though, we must begin to
deal with the longer term problems of trying to accelerate productivity growth in the economy to offset wage increases and find a
means to deal with special interest legislation.
The impact of that program at present, and all the economic
forecasts agree, is that our economy will be slow for substantially
the rest of this year. Most of the foreign economists also seem to
agree, although they may quarrel about whether or not to call it a
recession.

It is far too early to see success or failures in any of the price
indexes of that program, but I think today's announcement of the
CPI reinforces the concern that the administration has had with
inflation and how serious a problem it is.
For the next several months, I think we will see very rapid
increases before this program can expect to have a bite. Some of
the problems in the current months are because of the very strong
and unanticipated rate of growth of the economy with real GNP on
annual rates.
That should moderate later in the year, but certainly in the last
couple of months excess demands pressures have added to the
current inflationary pressures. I think it will be noted. in the very
high level of corporate profits for the first quarter of 1979. There
are three areas that lie somewhat outside the standards that present special problems. First of all, we have had extremely rapid,
almost explosive increases in food prices. Meat prices, in particular,
and even more particularly than that, beef prices, have been going
up at a remarkably rapid rate. Our estimates show those prices are
more than 40 percent above corresponding levels a year ago.
We are also going to continue with the serious excess demand
problem in the housing area, with prices rising over 11 percent a
year. In that kind of an excess demand situation, there is almost
nothing the Government can do in the short run to relieve the
current shortages of housing that have accumulated over the last
decade.
Third, the Iranian oil situation exacerbates the tremendous problem we will face in the next year with sharp substantial increases
in energy prices.
All three of these mean that even if the average American
worker does cooperate with this program, he is going to be faced
with large and substantial increases in the basic necessities that
make up such a large proportion of his budget. That is the reason I
think if we are going to ask workers to go along and take a chance

44
on this voluntary program to cooperate to the extent that they so
far have, the administration's real wage insurance proposal is extremely important to the effectiveness of this program. We want to
get some protection to those workers who are going to have to go
first, and are going to have to take the hard actions to restrain
their wages. There is a sharp difference between the risk that
workers are exposed to in trying to moderate inflation than a
business firm is. American business firms can say they will go
along with this program, and if it does not work out 6 months from
now, they can raise their prices. When American workers sign
labor contracts and say they will go along, however, they don't
have the option to negotiate in 6 months if inflation doesn't fall. If
we expect them to cooperate, I think we must address that issue.
The program has come under attack in several areas; one, as the
chairman mentioned earlier, is with the use of the Federal procurement policy. This is not directly the responsibility of the Council on
Wage and Price Stability. The issue was raised by the AFL-CIO
yesterday, and it has been raised repeatedly by various groups who
say they will take it to court. I only point out that the administration has received a legal opinion from the Justice Department. The
program is being done because it is good for Federal procurement,
and the Federal Government should try to aim its purchases away
from areas of the economy where prices are rising rapidly. That is
the intent of that program.
It can have enormous benefits for the Federal procurement in
future years, because one of the reasons the Federal budget is
rising as rapidly as it is is the enormous inflation that has been
occurring in recent years by government.
Anything that we can do in the Government to moderate that
inflation of those goods will hold down future procurement costs.
I think this issue will be tested in court. Ultimately the court
will have to resolve the issue. This same approach was taken with
equal employment opportunity back in the 1960's, and the same
challenges were made. The courts have upheld the legality of the
measure, that under the Federal procurement program the Federal
administration does have the authority to use it as long as it
applies it in an equitable and fair fashion.
Second, the January wholesale price index indicates another
problem with this program that has developed on the price side. I
would evaluate our success so far in trying to get people to go
along as good, despite the deep concern of a lot of labor leaders
about whether or not this program will work. On the price side, I
think we have received a great deal of cooperation and support for
the program by the largest of American industrial firms. Our
reading of the January wholesale price index shows that two factors contributed to that sharp increase: One, some notable excess
demand pressure; and, second, it appears that some smaller companies and intermediate sized companies have taken advantage of the
current situation, and have moved some of their price increases
forward that they would normally take later in the year, either
because they expect controls or because of other concerns. We have
a problem in getting smaller and intermediate firms to accept this
program.

45

I think the administration's response to that has to be to set up
and implement more rapidly than previously planned the monitoring efforts by the Council on Wage and Price Stability.
We are trying to move more rapidly to implement that part of
the program to identify those components of the price index that
will be released today. We will show the most rapid increases,
identify the companies who are producing those products, andicontact those companies to inquire whether or not their overall pricing policies are consistent with the administration's program.
It will take a couple of more months, I think, to get a reading on
whether or not this monitoring effort can be successful in the
smaller and intermediate companies. However, our own check on
prices at present indicates that the difficulty is not due to the
larger corporations. Those companies that pledged earlier this year
to comply with the program have tried to go along with it.
Thank you.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much, Mr. Bosworth.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Bosworth follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF BARRY P. BOSWORTH

Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am glad to discuss with you the
broad policies that the Council on Wage and Price Stability intends to pursue over
the next nine months in carrying out the President's anti-inflation program, and
what we have accomplished during the first 3 months. I will keep my prepared
remarks brief, so I can answer any questions you may have.
We've almost finished the first stage of the program. After receiving and analyzing the numerous comments from the public on the initial standards and after
many meetings with both business and labor groups, we have issued the final wage
and price standards. In addition, we've issued special guidelines for retailing, food
processing, professional fees, insurance, petroleum refining and for Federal, State
and local governments. These standards were tailored to meet the special characteristics and problems of these sectors of the economy. We expect to issue standards
shortly on utilities generally and electric utilities in particular. I will be glad to
discuss with you any of these particular problems.
The regulatory review process the President promised in his message of last
October 25, has been set in motion. The Regulatory Council, which is, of course, not
part of our operations, has been organized to assume first-level responsibility for
this effort. Its first task is the preparation of a regulatory calendar, which will, I
understand, be issued this month. This will provide the Council on Wage and Price
Stability with a systematic basis for planning an orderly review of pending regulations. We will be able to meet, more effectively than we have in the past, our
statutory obligations to intervene in regulatory proceedings, both on our own behalf
and on behalf of the Regulatory Analysis Review Group.
Regulations have been issued governing the use of Federal procurement policies
to encourage compliance with the wage-price standards. While enforcement of this
policy is the responsibility of the Office of Federal Procurement Policy, the Council
on Wage and Price Stability will be directly involved in certifying compliance.
Although the procurement aspect of the program is not the Council's responsibility, there are a couple of observations I'd like to make for the record. First, the
Department of Justice has advised us that the policy is legal. Second, the policy
makes sense. To the extent that we succeed in using procurement to encourage
business to hold down its prices in compliance with the standards, we advance the
cause of reducing inflation, and at the same time realize savings in Federal expenditures over the long term. Twenty-two of the country's top 25 contractors have
already pledged compliance with the standards; and we are now discussing with the
remaining three the problems they may have.
THE STANDARDS

I'd like now to discuss the Council's main role in the anti-inflation program: the
implementation and the monitoring of the voluntary wage and price standards.
The anti-inflation program was developed on the premise that monitoring efforts
will concentrate heavily on those sectors of the economy dominated by large firms

4 7-977

0 - 79 - 4

46
and large employee groups, that have the greatest discretion in wage and price
decisions.
Firms with annual net sales or revenues of more than $500 million have been
asked to file data relating to base period price changes, along with information
pertaining to profit margins, in case they should later argue that they are unable to
meet the price deceleration standards.
There are about 750 firms in this category
From our contacts with individual firms thus far, there is every reason to believe
that the overwhelming majority of these companies will comply with the objectives
of the program. Next month we will begin to publish a regular report on the extent
of compliance with the price and pay standards. Since the first six months of the
program year will be completed in March, we will also be able to begin to identify
specific situations of noncompliance with the standards and to identify any individual firms that fall into that category.
In addition to the reporting requirements for the largest firms, companies with
annual net sales or revenues of between $250 and $500 million are asked to file with
the Council their organizational structure for compliance purposes and the revenues
of major lines of business for each company treated separately. There are approximately 600 firms in this category.
The reporting requirement for companies with sales or revenues between $250
and $500 million serves three purposes. First, it is a signal that smaller companies
are aware of the anti-inflation program. Second, it provides a basic reference for
monitoring any suspected violation of the pay and price standards by smaller firms.
Finally, it requires a company to make basic organizational decisions in advance of
the monitoring period and discourages later organizational decisions that would
serve as a subterfuge to noncompliance.
Organizations with more than 5,000 employees have been asked to indicate the
method they will use for computing pay-rate changes during the program year or, in
the case of government entities, to make a statement that they will comply with the
program. About 850 firms, governmental units and organizations are expected to be
in this category.
Beyond this, the Council will carefully follow developments in major collective
bargaining agreements and provide public analyses of how those agreements square
with the anti-inflation program's pay standard.
I am aware that there has been criticism that these procedures will place enormous reporting burdens on firms and that the Council staff will be swallowed up in
paper work. I am confident that this will not be the case.
The data that the Council has requested is designed to satisfy several basic needs.
First, if these firms do intend to comply with the program, they will need to
establish an organizational structure for purposes of measuring their compliance
and compute their base period rate of price increase. Since they should be doing this
in any case, the Council's request should involve no extra work and only verifies
that they have set up a system to measure their compliance. Also the Council must
know the base period rate of price change if it is to evaluate a firm's performance.
In addition, the Council has asked for information on the firms' major product lines
(in a form that would correspond generally to the Standard Industrial Classification). Since CWPS' monitoring efforts are focused on market prices, it is necessary
to have a list of individual companies that are active in those markets. Finally, the
Council has asked for information on profit margins since some firms may resort to
that exception as the year progresses. We have tried to adhere to well-known
accounting definitions of the SEC to minimize the reporting burden.
The pay and price standards are explicit. In keeping with the voluntary nature of
the program, however, there is a measure of flexibility to meet the differing needs
of specific situations. And there are, of course, necessary exceptions.
Raw farm commodities, the first sale of imported goods, interest rates, and crude
oil and natural gas, are exempt from the price deceleration standard for individual
firms. We do not believe that individual farmers set farm prices, for example. This
is not to say, however, that they will not be affected by the overall anti-inflation
program; farm prices will be monitored on a market-wide basis. If price increases in
excess of the overall inflation rate are not justified by cost increases, we will seek to
find appropriate government action to expand supply and thus moderate price
increases. As we succeed in reducing the rate of inflation, the price of imported
goods will fall. Fiscal and monetary restraint, as it reduces aggregate demand,
should reduce pressure on interest rates.
Refining and distribution of crude oil are covered by the standards. The prices at
which crude petroleum and natural gas are sold are already controlled by the
Department of Energy.

47
I am convinced that widespread adherence to the price and pay. standards will
have a very significant effect on the rate of inflation this year. If every company in
the U.S. economy were to adhere precisely to the price deceleration standard, we
estimate that the program year inflation rate would be about 5¾ percent. This
figure is obtained by deducting one-half a percentage point from the 6¼4 annual rate
of increase of the Consumer Price Index, excluding food, during the 1976-1977 base
period. Because of raw material price increases and other factors, however, not all
firms will be able to achieve price deceleration. To comply, these firms will have to
use the profit-margin exception, which allows cost increases to be passed through on
a percentage basis up to 6½2 percent on a dollar-for-dollar basis thereafter. Given
full compliance with the price standard, including application of the profit margin
exception, our estimate is that inflation would be about 6½2 percent for the year.
This figure assumes full compliance with the pay standard and an adjustment for
productivity growth.
With full compliance with the pay standard, the Council estimates actual private
hourly compensation costs will rise about 73/4 percent over the year. When mandated Social Security cost increases are included, total compensation per hour will rise
about 8¼4 percent.
But when 1¾ percent for productivity increases is deducted, unit labor costs will
rise about 6Y2 percent and result in a 6V2 percent increase in prices. This is not
meant to be an inflation forecast, but rather a statement of the program-year
inflation objective assuming full compliance with the standard.
At this point in time, I am really encouraged by the response we have received.
The overwhelming majority of business firms has indicated a willingness to support
the program. Whether this will translate into actual price deceleration, we will
have to wait and see. My judgment is that it will. There has been a lot of rhetoric,
in addition, about how labor groups do not like the program and will not cooperate
with it. No one likes to be asked to reduce wage demands in our present economic
atmosphere. But as we monitor wage changes around the country, we find that
almost everyone is cooperating with this program. One of the most visible developments in the past few weeks was the settlement with the Oil, Chemical and Atomic
Workers. The two-year contract signed reflected pay increases averaging less than 7
percent per year. This settlement was reached and without a strike. I think we will
find that most workers want the program to work. But, understandably, they need
to be convinced that others are cooperating and that they are not going to be left
holding the bag.
The difficulty of providing such assurances must be faced by any voluntary
program of pay and price restraint. Workers are particularly vulnerable, since their
pay rates are determined once a year, or in the case of collective bargaining
agreements, once every several years. Yet firms can adjust their prices very quickly
to changing economic conditions. I believe that the real wage insurance proposal is
an important response to this concern and, as such, is an important element of the
anit-inflation program.
Quite obviously we are not going to solve overnight a problem that has been
gaining momentum for 10 years. It is equally obvious that to attempt to solve it
quickly by throwing a lot of people out of work would not be the answer.
Because the reduction of inflation will require an effort that stretches over
several years, there will be a need to reduce the standards in future years as the
inflation abates. The selection of specific targets for future years must await an
assessment of the performance of prices and pay rates during the first year. Several
characteristics of those future changes should be indicated now, however, if the
anticipation of such actions is not to have a perverse impact on current prices and
pay actions. First, the base period will not be extended forward to include the
current program year since such an action would penalize those who achieve the
greatest deceleration in the current year. Second, the standard for price changes
will be a cumulative one that includes the results for the first year of the program.
This is a comprehensive program that will require the contribution of everyone
and will require several years to succeed. But, if the Congress will join with the
Administration in providing strong leadership, I believe it can succeed.

Senator BENTSEN. Our next witness is Leon Keyserling, former
Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers. We are pleased to
have you and your testimony this morning. If you will limit your
oral remarks to 15 minutes, we would appreciate it. Your
testimony provokes some questions that we want to get answered.

48
STATEMENT OF LEON H. KEYSERLING, FORMER CHAIRMAN,
COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS, AND PRESIDENT, CONFERENCE ON ECONOMIC PROGRESS
Mr. KEYSERLING. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I
would like to have my prepared statement inserted in the record.
Senator BENTSEN. We will take it in its entirety.
Mr. KEYSERLING. I will certainly try to confine myself to 15
minutes.
I must say, first, that the views I will express here today are not
the majority view among economists, but I have always had confidence in the judgment of this committee to weigh what is said and
not to count noses.
I must also say, not pridefully, that I have had more than a little
experience in this subject. I was very active in the economic program during World War II, which accomplished miracles in the
production and employment, and contained inflation.
Stabilized prices have not been mainly in consequence of pricewage controls but due to maximizing production and employment,
and never fall into the trap of thinking that we can reduce inflation by striking hammer blows at the basic performance of the
American economy in terms of production and use of goods and
services.
During 7 years under President Truman, we faced more difficulties of all kinds than at any time since, and we brought inflation
down to 0.8 percent and employment down to 2.9 percent, again, by
rejecting the tradeoff and by calling forth huge increases in employment and availability of goods and services.
Since then I have watched the situation continuously, and before
this committee and elsewhere I have evaluated each of the efforts
to avert or reduce inflation.
Each time I have made the same criticism as I am making now,
each time against the policies which are being followed now, and
each time these policies failed their avowed objectives.
On the basis of this experience, I have some general conclusions
and I am sorry to have to state them. The policies advanced by
President Carter fill me with trepidation about our country's
future-they will make inflation worse than it would otherwise be,
weaken the dollar and worsen our international balances; strike
hammer blows at real economic growth, production and employment, and aggravate unemployment; stifle productivity growth.
Such policies are defeatist; they sell America short, and, if perpetuated, they would reduce us to a second-rate economic power
and third rate in our attention to human and social needs.
Now, I cannot discuss the problems of inflation without discuss-

ing the other damage done to the economy by the current anti-

inflationary program, if for no other reason than it is my thorough

proposition, supported by all the empirical evidence, that this other
damage has been before and will be again the predominant cause
of the inflation itself.
In the first place, the President is endeavoring to stop inflation
by driving unemployment upward substantially, by cutting the real
economic growth rate in half and by projecting a real economic
growth rate of 3.8 percent over the next 5 years.

49

The first trouble with this is that the President cannot reach his
goal of 4-percent unemployment by 1983 with his policies and
programs, and I have much material in my prepared statement
and in my charts attached to it to that effect.
In the second place, his program is unsatisfactory because the
policies and programs which he presents cannot possibly attain
even his own goals, and I trace the consequences of that and I
estimate that his program will lead us to 6.5-percent unemployment rather than 4-percent unemployment by 1983.
The President's proposals are avowedly designed to raise the rate
of unemployment to 6.2 percent during 1979 and 1980, while it
needs to be reduced to 5.6 percent in 1979 and 5.1 percent in 1980,
to get to 4 percent by 1980. For 1979-83 inclusive, I estimate that
the President's proposals would mean 7.8 million more unemployment and 16.7 million less employment than the administration's
policies and programs in accord with the mandated 4-percent unemployment by 1980 in accord with the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
The difference between the unemployment and employment estimates is that the civilian labor force grows much more rapidly
when the economy is moving forward at a satisfactory pace.
The second point I want to talk specifically on is the matter
which the chairman raised a question about.
I agree with the administration's goal that investment over the
next 2 years has to grow much faster than other sectors. This is
always true in a period of sound recovery. But the ratio between
the investment goals which the President sets and practically no
growth in consumption, an acutal decline in real wages, a 1-percent
growth in Federal purchases, a repressionary tax policy and so
forth and so on, and a repressive monetary policy, cannot activate
nor sustain the 4-percent growth rate in investment which the
President projects.
It has never happened that way; it can never happen that way.
There is no way to get a good and sustained increase in investment in the face of the cutting of the economic growth rate in half,
in the face of the contrived economic stagnation, in the face of
business recognition with which most economists agree that an
absolute recession is probably on the way, and in the face of a
demand for products being held to one-fourth the rate at which the
administration expects investment to advance.
This is a death knell for investment growth.
If the economic development is as most economists expect under
the President's program, there will be a sharp decline in investment because investment is the most volatile part of the economy
and that is the way it always happens.
I have not heard this morning, nor have I frequently heard, any
recognition of the basic reasons for the productivity decline.
Of course, we should be concerned about this, and I have repeatedly called attention to it.
The basic cause of the decline in productivity is not the availability of capital, nor is it unskilled labor. The basic cause of the
decline in productivity is that productivity always declines to 2
percent or 1 percent or zero when we have a large slack in the
economy in terms of high unemployment and low utilization of
plant capacity.

50

The reason for that is very simple but I don't have to give any of
the reasons because the empirical evidence is there and a pound of
history is worth a pound of logic.
In an index of 100 represents plants operating at 92 percent of
capacity or full utilization, and actual utilization is only 82 percent,
you have an 11-percent slack in the use of capacity, but fortunately
you don't fire 11 percent of the workers. You may fire 6 percent, so
the index of labor utilization falls from 100 to 94.
With a 94-percent index of employment and an 82-percent index
of plant utilization, the division of one into the other shows a short
decline in the productivity performance.
Technologically, the productivity potential is advancing all the
time. The productivity potential over the years has accelerated and
this is attributed to the genius of the American economy so the
reason that the actual productivity growth rate is so low is because
the utilization of labor in the plant is so slack, not the quality of
the labor.
The quality of the labor does not change much when the index of
the use of employed labor rises, but the productivity growth rate
shoots up under such conditions.
Thus, cutting the real economic growth rate in half deliberately,
which reduces the utilization of employed labor, is going to reduce
the productivity growth rate far below the low figures of today.
I have charts in my prepared statements on this. I cannot understand, in the face of the unanswerable evidence, that the official
economists never turn to a simple explanation which every businessman I talk to recognizes as to why productivity is so low.
Now I come to the matter of the battle against inflation. We
have to talk a little history.
We came into early 1953, as I have said, with 2.9 percent unemployment and 0.8 percent inflation.
When Arthur Burns then came in as my successor-I do not
criticize him personally-he was worried that the inflation rate
was too high and the unemployment rate was too high, and
through fiscal monetary policies which he influenced on the theory
of the "tradeoff" the unemployment rate rose from 2.9 in 1953 to
7.6 in 1961 and the inflation rate multiplied 2½/2 times.
I am not talking politics-I am now criticizing a Democratic
President.
During 1961-66, under KennedyJohnson and Walter Heller, the
inflation rate was held to 1½/2 percent a year, and unemployment
was reduced from 7.6 to 3.8, and then another set of policies came
in and we know the history since.
It has not been the Arabs, it has not been "special favors" that
have made the underlying rate of inflation so very high. Economic
slack has been two or three times as high as when we had reasonable price stability.
My charts trace that all the way through.
Now I want to give a few of the reasons for this, and I want to
read them from my testimony because the reasons make clearer
the empirical evidence.
Reason No. 1 is that we have a largely administrative price
economy, and I am not saying this critically.

51

When sales are slack the effort to reach profit targets without an
adequate volume of sales leads to faster increases in prices in basic
industry than when volume is high.
I have traced this through in almost every major industry over
20 years, and it is true.
In the second place, the economic slack drops productivity
growth, which correspondingly raises the per unit labor costs, so
you have to have a higher price to cover those higher labor costs.
In the third place-and this is dramatically illustrated by the
President's program-the philosophy of economic scarcity which
leads to slack use of resources is evoked in those very areas where
the biggest inflation is.
Take housing. The President's reports predict that housing starts
may go as low as 1.1 million by the end of next year, and Government policy is a very important factor in that.
I wrote a book on "The Coming Crisis in Housing" just before the
1974 recession and predicted exactly what would happen and what
it would do to the economy and to inflation. Just that happened.
It is going to do it again. There is nothing more inflationary
under the present circumstances than the cutting in half of the
rate of housing production.
The same thing is true with other areas of the economy.
Energy-I represented the utilities for many years when I was a
private economist.
I forecast the shortage long before we heard of the Arabs because
the high interest rates-claimed to check inflation-were costing so
much there was not much left over to invest in exploration and
facilities.
If you run across every area of the economy, you find an intimate connection or the umbilical cord tie between the contrived
shortages of the economy and the increased rate of inflation.
Now, what should we do? It is obvious. We have to alter national
economic policies drastically. The current policy in its major ingredients-money policy, housing policy, tax and spending policies,
guidelines policy-is an almost exact replica, with slight adjustments, of the policies used before each period of stagnation or
recession. It happened five times, and we have learned nothing.
The Government needs a new "department of experience."
Reversing the course, we have got to get some congressional
influence toward changes in the money policy-lower interest
rates, and through the selective use of credit which we have had
before, pinpointing the points where credit is needed most instead
of making it most easily available where it is needed least.
We need to have a rearrangement in the spending policy, more
adjustment to servicing the national priorities. We need to point
Federal outlays to where the shortages are and so forth, and so on.
Well, thank you very much for your attention. I am sorry to
have been so critical.
Senator BENTSEN. Well, you will be counted and there is no
reason to regret it.
We are glad to hear your comments.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Keyserling follows:]

52
PREPARED STATEMENT OF LEON H. KEYSERLING'

Why the President's Anti-Inflationary Policy Won't Work
Mr. Chairman and Members of the committee, the policies advanced by President
Carter in his January Economic Report and Budget Message fill me with trepidation about our country's future. They will make inflation worse than it would
otherwise be; weaken the dollar and worsen our international balances; deliberately
strike hammer blows at real economic growth, production, and employment and
aggravate unemployment; and stifle productivity growth. Such policies are defeatist,
sell America short, and if long perpetuated would reduce us to a second rate
economic power and third rate in attention to human and social needs.
The President's core purpose is to reduce inflation, but the means chosen are so
inimical to that purpose and so calamitous in themselves that they should be
treated first. The short range goal is deliberately to reduce the rate of real economic
growth from 4.3 percent in 1978 to an average of about 2.7 percent for 1979 and
1980, and to lift unemployment from 5.8 percent in December 1978 to 6.2 percent in
1979 and 1980. Thereafter, it is claimed, the growth rate will average 4.4 percent for
the next three years, or 3.8 percent during 1978-1983, thus reducing unemployment
to 4.0 percent by 1983.
These Administration goals are egregiously too low, because empirical evidence
since World War II demonstrates that an average annual real economic growth rate
of 3.8 percent cannot bring us anywhere near to 4 percent unemployment by 1983.
The average would need to be about 5.5 percent, which in terms of relevant experience is moderate and practical from so high a base of unemployment and unused
capacity.
The Administration's goals are also unattainable in practical terms because of
deficiencies in policies and programs which I shall discuss in detail. Alice Rivlin
testified before a House Subcommittee on February 13 that unemployment in both
fourth quarter 1979 and fourth quarter 1980 might be as high as 7.2 percent under
the Administration's policies and programs. And even if the Administration
achieved its growth rate averaging about 2.7 percent from 1979 to 1981, the empirical evidence is that a 7.2 percent rather than 4.4 percent average would be needed
during the next three years to reach the 4 percent 1983 unemployment goal. That 7
percent rate has never been approximated for even one year during the past quarter

and programs diametrically opposed to those
century, and would require policies
2
which the Administration projects.
My estimates are that actual gorwth under the Administration's policies, which
will be considerably lower than its deficient goals, will lift unemployment from 6.2
percent at least in 1979 and 1980 to 6.5 percent in 1983 (barring intervening
recessions). To get unemployment down to 4 percent by 1983 in orderly fashion
would require reducing unemployment to 5.6 percent in 1979 and 5.1 percent in
1980. In absolutes, I estimate that the Administration's policies and programs would
lift unemployment to 6.9 million in 1983, while 4.4 million would be consistent with
4 percent unemployment. The differentials in the amounts of unemployment between the two. courses would rise from 500 thousand in 1979 to 2.5 million in 1983,
would
for a five-year difference of about 7.8 million; the differentials in employment
3
rise from 1.4 million to 5 million, or about 16.7 million over the five years. The fiveyear difference in GNP would be almost 820 billion 1977 dollars.

These are losses neither our economy nor our people can stand, coming on top of
a roller coaster performance from 1953 to 1978 which caused us to forfeit about 6

trillion 1977 dollars in GNP and more than 76 million man- woman- and teenageryears of employment opportunity.'
Although my estimates of needs and potentials are supported by the empirical
record, while the Administration's goals seem to me and many others pie in the sky
under its policies and programs recommended, sheer common sense also comes in.
The proposition that the economy will be made better off in the long run by making
it worse off in the short run, that business confidence will be augmented by a long
period of economic stagnation with likelihood of recession, that the rescue of people
struggling in deep water should begin by keeping more of them under for two years
longer, violates every rule of reason and experience. Each of the five stagnations
'Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers under President Truman. President, Conference on
Economic Progress.
2See chart 1.

I Differences in size of differentials due to greater growth in civilian labor force under more
favorable economic conditions.
4 See chart 2.

53
since 1953 has led into recession, and usually progressively severe recessions, before
the upturns commenced.
Further, the Administration's entire policy is in flagrant violation of the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, recently enacted by a majority of 105 in the House and 4 to 1 division in the Senate, and then
signed by the President with the promise to implement it vigorously and forthrightly. No competent lawyer in America can, and I think no Member of the Congress
whose vote indicated support for the objectives of the Humphrey-Hawkins legislation will, find anything in the legislation itself, or the legislative history in hearings, Committee Reports and floor debates, to support the proposition that efforts by
the Administration to reduce unemployment should avowedly commence in the
third year rather than the first year or that the best way to get from Chicago to San
Francisco is to start by moving for two years from Chicago to New York. Nothing
could more undermine economic and business conficence than to blare forth that
comprehensive economic legislation enacted in 1978 becomes meaningless in early
1979.
The President's economists claim that a very subnormal economic growth rate
can reduce unemployment to 4 percent by 1983 because of a chronic or permanent
collapse in the rate of productivity gr6wth. But the data conclusively demonstrate
that the productivity growth rate has been very high when plant and labor force
utilization has been moving vigorously toward, or near to full use, and vice versa.
Defeatist about the real capabilities of our great economy, and apparently unaware
that in a technological sense the productivity potential has been and still is advancing at an accelerating rate, the official economists are trying to deal with the
productivity problem by forcing in aggravated form a recurrence of the very types
of economic slowdowns which have always brought the productivity growth rate
down toward zero or even made it negative. I have never witnessed anything more
ridiculous than this, if it were not so tragic.5
The goals which the official documents set for balanced growth-a balance essential to sustained growth-have no credibility whatsoever. The goals for 1979 contemplate a real growth rate at a mid-point of about 2 percent for consumer expenditures, a mid-point of about one percent for Federal purchases, and a mid-point of
about 4.25 percent for nonresidential fixed investment. There are also the official
forecasts that housing starts could decline from 2.1 million in fourth quarter 1978 to
as low as 1.1 million in fourth quarter 1979, and that State and local outlays could
show a real growth rate declining from 3.5 percent in 1978 to as low as 1.75 percent
in 1979. This crazy quilt of irreconcilable developments cannot possibly add up to
even the very inadequate real growth rates in GNP projected officially for the first
two years, much less for the five years as a whole. Fixed nonresidential investment
growing two to four times as fast as the two other main components is hard to
imagine and, if it happened, the results would be the same as when it happened
before each of the four previous stagnations and then recessions since 1953.
More on the imbalances. The tax policy enacted in 1978, now relied upon by the
Administration, is both regressive and repressive in its economic effects, especially
when social security taxes increases get fully underway. The money policy is continuing along lines which five times helped bring on recessions, stunted economic
growth, and enlarged unemployment. The wage-price guidelines, if effective, will
have consequences stated so well by Business Week of February 19, 1979: "Even
though weekly earnings are about 9 percent ahead of a year earlier, so are prices,
balancing out any real gains for the individual worker. This pattern will worsen at
least for the rest of the winter and into early spring", and 'to the extent that the
wage guidelines are effective, the change in real buying power will turn negative in
coming months."
The President projects only a 1.4 percent average annual growth rate in the total
Federal Budget in real terms from fiscal 1979 through fiscal 1983. I estimate the
needed figure at about 4.7 percent, which is so much smaller than the needed GNP
growth rate of 5.5 percent that it would reduce the ratio of the Federal Budget to
the gross national product and would balanace the Federal Budget by 1983. It is
incomprehensible to me that the official economists have failed to note the glaring
correlation between the size of the GNP gap and the size of the Federal deficit. Few
economists now believe the President's goal of a $29 billion deficit in fiscal 1980 can
be reached under his policies. I estimate that these policies will result in an average
annual Federal deficit of $25.6 billion during fiscal 1980-1983 inclusive and $13.6
billion in 1983 alone, while the economic growth policies which I recommend would
mean an average annual deficit or $14.3 billion during these years, a balanaced
budget in fiscal 1983, and a $2.4 billion surplus in calendar 1983. Even more
I See chart 3.

54
important, the President's policies forget that the primary purpose of the Budget is
not to help stabilize the economy nor to balance itself, but rather to provide those
priority goods and services which the economy and the people need but which,
paraphrasing Lincoln, they cannot accomplish or accomplish so well in their separate and individual capacities. Current policies threaten to make us in due course a
second rate nation in terms of economic strength, and a third rate nation in terms
of exercise of basic human and social responsibilities.
Even if all the costs and tribulations set forth above purchased some gains against
inflation, the price would be too high. We in the past have found means of controlling inflation by more sensible methods, under pressures far more serious than
those which now exist.
But the President's program can do little against inflation, and is likely to make
it worse than it would otherwise be. Alice Rivlin, in earlier referred to testimony,
estimated that the Administration's policies would reduce inflation below the 7.2
percent rate in fourth quarter 1978 by only 0.1 percentage points in fourth quarter
1979 and only 0.2 percentage points in fourth quarter 1980. With meticulous regularity, experience since 1947 to date has demonstrated almost definitively that, in
the main, there is an inverse correlation between the rate of inflation and the rate
of unemployment., This is because the widest departures from full resource use (1)
foment faster administered price increases, to compensate for low volume sales and
to reach profit targets nonetheless, (2) bring higher per unit cost resulting from
depressed productivity growth, (3) have induced "anti-inflationary" tight money
policies which are inflationary per se, particularly in their impacts upon housing,
fuel suppliers, and farm production and credit costs (these being areas where
inflation is most severe), (4) have been accompanied by failure to use pinpointed
public outlays to overcome other inflationary shortages, such as in medical care, (5)
have a disuasive effect upon private investment, and (6) general lack of confidence
flows from a roller coaster economic performance.
These are all reasons why the Humphrey-Hawkins law mandates specifically that
"policies and programs for reducing the rate of inflation shall be designed so as not
to impede achievement of the goals and timetables specified in clause (1) for the
reduction of unemployment." I The Congress realized that the so-called "trade-off",
thoroughly discredited by experience, was an economic flop and a moral monstrosity.
Today, the attempt of the President and his advisors to make the "trade-off" the main
implement of national economic policy for five years ahead again flaunts the
expressed will and intent of the Congress.
The lack of confidence in the dollar overseas, the deficits in our balance of
payments and trade accounts, the competitive inroads upon our own markets, and
the excessive flow of American capital abroad through multinationals and otherwise, are all based upon the fact that we are losing ground, both in economic terms
and opinions of others based upon our social policies. Comparisons of our real
average annual economic growth rates with those of such nations as Germany and
Japan, since 1953 or since 1969, show what our international economic difficulties
really stem from. And nothing could do more to decrease confidence in us overseas
than cutting our own real economic growth rate in half and risking a sixth recession.'

The needed changes in national economic policies are really explicit in which I
have said. We must fight inflation by building production and employment, not
tearing them down. We must set more realistic goals; adjust policies more sensibly
to their attainment; stop trying to balance the budget at the expense of the economy; improve the priority list for Federal spending; make the tax system more
progressive by starting with cancelling out the social security tax increases; utilize
Congressional pressures to reduce interest rates and revive selective monetary
policies; stimulate more housing starts instead of allowing them to decline precipitately; and develop real budgets of needs and supplies for energy, food, and some
other items. Practically all of these programs are listed in the Humphrey-Hawkins
legislation, but the Administration has hardly touched them. By not doing these
things, the Administration is shadow boxing against inflation, not punching away.
Most important of all, we must regain a sense of what America can and must do
instead of do without, of what we need rather than what we cannot afford. Austerity and sacrifice are good things in their time and place, such as during World War
II when every resource was overstrained. But what place do they really have, when
almost all of our economic problems and social problems result fundamentally, not
from economic overstrain, but from failing to use the available resources which are
pleading to be used. The Administration's policies, in their current form, represent
a shortsighted, small-minded, defeated, and deflated frame of mind and loss of
nerve. This Committee and the Congress can help to change all that.
6See charts 4 and 5.
,Section 4(bX2) of the Employment Act of 1946 as amended by section 104 of the H-H Act.
I See chart 6.

THE "ROLLER-COASTER" ECONOM ICPLERORUANCE:
ECONOM.IC GROWTH R!CrES, 1922-1929, 19tU-1945, AND 1947-1970'
(Uniform Dollars)

Up

87% Up

1948 194595

1954- 955 195
191-1949
1952
1947990-1981970"
19ss155
1so9511952 1955 D
1.3%

4.1% 3.8%
i4%
39%.?./
1922-96-

194 1-

1929

1945 1

1752

141953-9 11-947-

1978

1978

1%~~

.8%.P

up

.8%6

I/f978 estimated

970- 1971- 192
sg9 1968 96l 1962- 965- 96- 1965- 1966- 1967- 1968- 190
1958 15
959 1965 196 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 Sawn1971 1972 1973

1947- 6-

::349;LggL.>fw

1953

1949

~~25
1949-

.

19531964
9,-:

Lg

1953

1961

3
U

r

91-

1,966-97
V

1966

Z:/Recessinn during pazrtof perlod.There werefiverecesclons,1953-1978.but somewornentirelywithinoneyearandbeganandendedIn different yea~rs.

1969

1975- 1976- 7-tJ
1876 1977 1978
S
D
1U41L 1u3P

Oft

12%
42.8%
1969

1976- 1977
39%

C

1978

-

1977

1978

COST OF DEPARTURES FROM FULL ECONOMY. 1953-1978"Lj
2,800
2,300
ss ""]'%ERENCE 5,9375
=

FULL ECONOMY PERFORMANCE

ACTUAL PERFORMANCE

.S.....

953 '54

'55

,

'57

'58,

'59
,

'60
,

'61

'62

'63

'64

'65,

'66I

'67

618

'A69
I

170
I

I
'71

'72

'56

'57

'58

'59

'60

'6f

62

'63

'64

'65

'66

'67

'68

'69

'70

'71

'72

'56

'57

'58

'59

'60

'61

'62

'63

'64

'56

t978
1/ estimated.
2/Real averageannualgrowthrate ot 4,4 percent.
'IReal averageannual growthrate at3.3 percent.tho 1953-1978 average.
ot 4.1 percent, or 2.9 percentutll-time unemployment.
4/Average true tvel otunemptoyment
of 7.8 percent,or 5.2 percentfuI -time unemployment.
A/Average true level of unemployment
Dept.of Labor
BasicData: Dept.ot Commerce;

I

'

'73

I

'74

'75

'76

'77

'78

57
Chart,

j

S4NV2;3WAC7

viF
V
iCOIN,36 '; ^

oG20VT

T

*1

UP3ON PRODUC71V7, ' G.ROW TH

I

93%

~~~~~~~

m

,

3S%

__

._

40 1975- 101976101976
401977
(ann.
rate) (anmrole)

~~~..__
._
407740'789/

7.6%

3.8%
4

26%
2.6%

FTI

!
1947-1953' 1-195 0

3.8%
1

3.1%

44
4

.1

;c
1.7%
g~t

E~~~~an

M

I

%t

SL60-19661966-1970 1970-1972 1972-1978/

I

9 i978 and40'78 estimated.
Source:
DeptofLabor,Deptof Commerce

0-5%
40 1975- 101976101976
401977
(ranrrote)

4C77
40789

~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~(aan

1:

EC'i")1K'CROcTf RKAWES EL.`FL0Y' tET (:i UNELrLoY`RNIG NINFLATIO i
AND FFDL',RAL EJUDGET CONDITIONS.lJRlNC3VW.RIOUS PaRIODS. 1947-1978-"
Real Ave. Ann.
Econ. Growth Rate

Ave. Annual
Unemployment
(full-time)

4.8%

4.0%

Unemployment
First Yr. Last Yr.

Inflation Rate
First Yr. Last Yr.
(C.R 1.)

Ave. Annual
Inflation

Ave. Ann. Surplus
or Deficit
Fed. Budget
(Fiscal Years, Billions)

7.8%
3.9%

3.0%+1.

2.9%

N

1947-1953

0.8%

6.7 %
2

1953--1961 |

~~~~~~5.1% 2.9%
67%

5_2%

514%

3.2%

1966-1969

3.

1969 1978

2.8%
2 %

~~~~3.7%

3.8%

6.0%

-7.0%

0.8%

1.6%

1.2 %

3 5%

4.1%

6.0%

6.6 %

IP8¶6

Il~13.5%
0%20
6.5%

3.8%

1.4%

6.0%

L-

2.9%

7.4%

|
7%6.5

- 2

-$4.4

2.9%

2 9 %iL

i

1977-1978
/'1978esirmont;d Tooltowfor momentun eftecTsofprt les.thefirst ycorofo
ReportsofthePresident,nd EconomniIndicotors
Source.Economic

1.2 %

.

-2
M1

%

$277_
perbd.
periodisalso trcoted osthe lo-l yeorotthe prcceding

_____

-5469

59
Choul

RELATIVE TREENDS IN ECONOMIC GROWTH
UNEMPLOYMENT, A PRICES, 1952-1978
i=
jZ

Io=

I

Total National Production in Constant Dollars. Average Annual Rates of Change

M

Industrial ProductionAveroge Annual Rates of Change

M

Unemployment as Percent of Civilian Labor Force. Annual Averages*
ga4%

= Consumer Prices

All Finished I

4.1%

1

n0%

-an%

1952-1955 1955-1958 1958-1966 1966-1969 1969-1978 1Q74-10'754Q'7-lQ764Q77-4078
Average Annual Rates of Change
(anare teI
cnnual
afThese
avereges(cs
differentiated from theannual
ratesotchange)
arebased
aonfull-time officially
reported unemployment
measured
oaginst theofficially reported Civilian Labor Forne.
SourceDept.
of Lebor.
Deptof Commerce,
a Federal
Reserve
System

60
ch i

..

COMPARATIVE REAL ECONOMIC GROWTH RATES
VARIOUS COUNTRIES. 1953-1977AND 1969-1977
Avecge Armal Rates of Growlh

_

I

product
for ollothercountries.
AsG.N.P.for
U.S.,Japan,& Gennrny. Grossdnmestic

61
Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Mitchell, we are pleased to have you this
morning. We are pleased to have your testimony.
STATEMENT OF DANIEL J. B. MITCHELL, SENIOR FELLOW,
THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION, AND PROFESSOR, GRADUATE
SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT, UCLA
Mr. MITCHELL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
My name is Daniel J. B. Mitchell, I am a senior fellow at the
Brookings Institution and a professor at the Graduate School of
Management, UCLA. I would like to thank the committee for
inviting me to express my views on current anti-inflation policies. I
have provided the committee a 35-page prepared statement, detailing these views.
Senator BENTSEN. We will take that in its entirety and you can
summarize it.
Mr. MITCHELL. Thank you.
My remarks today will be a brief summary of that statement.
Inflation has become the single most important economic issue
facing the Federal Government. The general public is clearly distressed at the seeming inability of Government to overcome the
problem. While economists can cite statistics showing that the
average person has kept up with inflation, such figures miss the
point. Inflation has created a climate of uncertainty. Long-term
planning has become difficult. The investment outlook has become
clouded. It is hard for anyone to plan for retirement or make any
saving decisions.
Knowledge that inflation can induce Government to follow restrictive policies which will slow. economic growth simply increases
the uncertainty.
In this climate, the political leadership of this country will be
tested. The public is looking for miracle remedies: proposition 13's
and balanced budget amendments. Yet, there are no miracle remedies; if there were, they would surely have been implemented long
ago. The most we can hope for is a gradual tapering off of inflation
over a period of years. And such tapering could easily be offset or
overwhelmed by such "exogenous" disturbances as the cutoff of
Iranian oil and its resultant effects on energy prices.
Inflation has become rooted in the psychology of the American
economy. There was a time-in the late 1940's and early 1950'swhen the glimmer of recession could induce an actual fall in prices.
There were many people at that time who remembered the Great
Depression with its dramatic price declines. Perhaps they reasoned
that it could happen again. But few people today believe that there
will be much relief from inflation, whether or not there is a recession this year. Our current system of wage and price determination
tends to perpetuate inflation, once it has begun. There is no way of
setting the clock back to the 1940's or the 1950's. And that is why
the guidelines efforts-if properly managed-can be an important
element in a program designed to bring about a gradual reduction
in inflation.
Both monetary and fiscal policy have moved toward a restrictive
posture. The budget proposals of the Carter administration represent a cut in the ongoing rate of expenditures, a difficult-to-accomplish feat in the context of a system of outlays which is so heavily

47-977 0 - 79 - 5

62
''uncontrollable." Despite the heavy emphasis in public discussions
on the deficit, fiscal policy in the near term is primarily a matter
of controlling expenditures.
In theory, the size of the Federal deficit might cause the Federal
Reserve to expand the money supply in an effort to "fund the
debt." But, in fact, the Fed has been tightening monetary policy in
order to defend the dollar exchange rate against other currencies
and to resist inflation.
The current difficulty with monetary policy is that we don't
know how tight is tight enough, given changes in financial institutions. Because of this uncertainty, the Fed has been cautious in
responding to short-term developments, and rightly so.
Monetary and fiscal policy can influence the rate of inflation.
But their impact falls mainly on real economic activity. It takes a
considerable rise in unemployment to produce a small reduction in
price increases. That is why the administration has added wageprice guidelines to its anti-inflation program. The idea is to take
advantage of the expected increase in economic slack and to promote a larger-than-expected reduction in the rate of inflation.
Unlike some earlier efforts at direct-wage price intervention, the
new program will not be operated in the face of strong economic
expansion.
Public discussion of the guidelines has often centered on the
issue of whether they would be turned into formal, mandatory
controls. I find this issue rather empty: For larger firms and Government contractors, there is little distinction between so-called
voluntary guidelines and controls. The new program is imposing
obligations on the private sector.
It must be operated with those obligations in mind. In practice,
this means that it must be adequately staffed so that questions can
be answered and appeals can be heard. In practice, this means
resolving the contradiction between a desire to deal only with large
firms and unions and a program which nominally covers firms and
bargaining units of all sizes. In practice, this means operating the
program in a flexible manner so that economic reality penetrates
the rules.
The last point is especially important. It is generally conceded
that the key to the program is labor cooperation, whether tacit or
explicit. If it turns out that inflation in sectors beyond the reach of
guidelines-food prices, oil prices, and imports-is accelerating,
consideration must be given to adjusting the wage standard.
The Kennedy-Johnson wage guideline passed into oblivion when
it failed to recognize an acceleration of inflation. And the 5.5percent standard of the Nixon administration controls went the
same way, although perhaps with a little more grace.
We should learn from the past about the perils of a rigid stance
in the face of altered circumstance.
Originally, the administration appeared to believe that its proposal for "real wage insurance" wourd permit a rigid guideline
administered by tiny staff to weather any changes in economiccircumstance. In testimony before the Senate Banking Committee
last November, I warned that real wage insurance was not capable
of such a role and that it was a complicated and ill-conceived plan.

63
On February 5, in testimony before the House Ways and Means
Committee, I backed that warning with a detailed analysis of the
real wage insurance plan. The plan is complex and filled with
anomalies. Its rules differ from the guidelines so that it is possible
to qualify for one program but not the other. It involves the IRS in
assessing productivity bargaining and tandem relationships. It diverts resources to the small employer sector where wage pressures
are not expected to be a major problem. And it draws Congress into
ongoing collective bargaining negotiations.
Already, Congress has become an unwilling participant in the
sensitive trucking and automobile negotiations. The budgetary
costs of real wage insurance are uncertain and its incentive effects
for bargainers are marginal at best. Over 4 months of the program
year to which the proposal applies have already passed. Even the
strongest proponents of the concept have never claimed that it
would have retroactive effects.
* A quick death for the real wage insurance proposal would be the
optimum outcome. But, paradoxically, the second best outcome
would be a quick birth with the plan put into effect essentially as
proposed. The worst outcomes would be a slow death or a prolonged labor. We need to get on with the business of managing the
guidelines.
Congress could be more profitably discussing the adequacy of the
size of the staff of the guidelines program, the extremely comprehensive nature of the program, and the bridges to organized labor.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much, Mr. Mitchell.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Mitchell follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF DANIEL J. B. MITCHELLI

Current Anti-Inflation Policies
1. INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY

The current inflation problem has persisted for over a decade., If there were an
easy miracle cure for inflation, common sense suggests that it would already have
been implemented. Thus, the theme of this paper is that while policy is generally
moving in the right direction to fight inflation, the most that can be expected is
gradual relief. Furthermore, it is quite possible that even with the right trend in
policy, short-term problems-such as the Iranian oil shutdown-can overwhelm the
effort at deceleration.
In Sections II and III, it will be argued that much of the research and discussion
on inflation has been misplaced. The emphasis has often been on finding the initial
cause of inflation, i.e., the spark that started the current era of inflation back in the
1960's. But the spark is a matter of historical interest. The current dilemma is the
perpetuation of inflation and the need to break into the wage/price spiral. How
much effort should be expended on decelerating the inflation process is really a
political question. As discussed in Section IV, some economists in the 1960's were
relatively sanguine about the impact of inflation because the costs of inflation are
hard to measure or even define. But political pressures to resist inflation have
mounted. That rising pressure is the best available measure of the costs, and it is
clear that the costs are severe.
Sections V-IX deal with specific anti-inflationary policies. These are monetary and
fiscal policies, the new wage/price guidelines, controlling the costs of regulation,
XDaniel J. B. Mitchell is a senior fellow at the Brookings Institution and a professor at the
Graduate School of Management, University of California, Los Angeles. He was Chief Economist
of the U.S. Pay Board during Phase II of the Controls Program begun in 1971. The views
expressed in this statement do not necessarily reflect those of other Brookings staff members or
the officers and trustees of the Brookings Institution.
Parts of this paper are based on an upcoming Brookings study on anti-inflation policy in
w
which several Brookings colleagues are involved. The opinions expressed, however, are my own.

64
and real wage insurance. Fiscal policy in the near term is primarily expenditure
policy. And there are heavy constraints on what may be accomplished. However,
fiscal policy has moved toward a more restrictive stance. Monetary policy is less
constrained, but is beset with new institutional structures that make policy actions
difficult to interpret. The possibility of monetary overreaction, based on imperfect
information, suggests a need for caution. Each bit of bad news on inflation should
not call forth an automatic tightening of monetary policy. Finally, it is important to
note that both monetary and fiscal policy will have their primary effects on real
growth, not on inflation. Especially in the short run, restrictive demand policy will
produce only a mild slowdown of inflation.
The new wage/price guidelines can make a contribution to deceleration. Virtually
all economic forecasts suggest a growth slowdown and a rise in unemployment
during 1979. Thus, the guidelines will be operating in a different climate than that
which accompanied the Kennedy/Johnson guideposts of the 1960s or the Nixon
controls program. Unlike those earlier programs, the new guidelines will not have
to face rising demand pressures. On the other hand, the new guidelines may have to
cope with food-fuel price pressures similar to those of 1973. Such pressures will
require flexible administration of the guidelines. In particular, it may be necessary
to loosen the wage guideline if price inflation picks up substantially.
Real wage insurance will not remove the need for flexible guidelines administration. Indeed, real wage insurance may never become law. And while it is debated in
Congress, the proposal could have a disruptive effect on ongoing labor-management
negotiations. Real wage insurance is excessively complex and can have only a
marginal effect at best. It deserves a quick burial. But if that is not possible, a quick
birth would be the second-best option. The worst outcome would be a prolonged
debate and an attempt to tinker with the plan.
Regulatory reform is surely one of the most important long-term issues before the
Congress. It could produce some significant cost savings which can only help in the
anti-inflation effort. But the issues raised by proposals for deregulation and regulatory restraint are complicated and are not amenable to quick solutions. In the
interim, Congress ought to be cautious and conservative about any new proposals
which raise the price level.
11. THE CAUSES OF INFLATION

In the 1960's, economic textbooks debated the causes of inflation in terms of two
polar models. The "demand-pull" theory suggested that inflation had its cause in an
overheating of the economy provoked by excessively-expansionary monetary and
fiscal policy. Alternatively, the "cost-push" model attributed inflation to upward
pressure on wage and prices from groups seeking to maintain or enlarge their share
of available income. Inflation was seen as a competitive struggle for income which
vented itself in rising prices because the claims on income exceeded its availability
in real terms.
Neither model is entirely satisfactory as a complete explanation for current
inflationary pressures. Most economists would agree that the inflation which built
up in the late 1960s was caused by classic demand-pull pressures. Indeed, it would
be difficult to point to any substantial cost-push pressures in the early 1960's that
could have sparked the inflation, especially if "cost" is a code word for "wages." If
one is searching for an "initiating cause" of the inflation of the late 1960's, monetary and fiscal policies are good candidates. A limited form of cost-push explanation
could be added to account for the 1973-74 episode of dollar devaluation, world farm
increasesrice increases. However, that episode was not the
price increases,price
product of a domestic struggle for income; much of the impetus was international.
In any case, the search for the initial cause is misleading. The key issue today is not
what started inflation but what is perpetuating it.
III. THE PERPETUATION

OF INFLATION

Once inflation has occurred for a long period, it tends to continue. The mechanism is primarily a wage/price spiral. Prices reflect the cost of labor; wages reflect
the cost of living. Inflation that has occurred in the past comes to be expected and is
pushed into present. In some cases where long-term contracts are utilized, it is
pushed into the future.
The wage/price spiral is not completely self contained; if it were the inflation rate
would never vary. It carl be influenced somewhat by monetary and fiscal restraint,
for example. An increase in the unemployment rate tends to produce a small
decrease in the rate of wage change. In turn, this will tend to affect price changes
which will affect later wage changes. Thus, the cumulative effect of a "softened"

65
economy is greater than the initial effect. But the speed of the adjustment appears
to be slow.
Part of the difficulty in using traditional demand restraint policies is that a
slowdown in the economy is less effective as an anti-inflationary device than it once
was. In the late 1940's and the mid 1950's, there were two episodes in which
recessions induced actual drops in the price level. Perhaps in those periods, many
people still remembered the Great Depression of the 1930s when prices fell by
almost 25 percent. Possibly they thought that the recessions might herald a return
to depression levels of output and a fall in prices. Recessions may have acted as a
"signal" at that time which produced a self-fulfilling reaction of prices.
It has been argued that if the government were now to announce a tough,
inflexible, and long-term policy of demand restraint, the announcement itself would
have a dramatic effect on inflationary expectations. Effectively, according to this
view, such an announcement would restore the signaling effect of recession. Inflation would cease to be self-perpetuating; people would again act as they did in the
1940s and 1950s. But it is not clear how a representative government can make such
a commitment credibly, since it amounts to stating that government will ignore
whatever pressures arise to restimulate the economy. And there is no way of
knowing whether such a commitment-if it were made-would have a substantial
anti-inflation effect.
IV. THE COSTS OF INFLATION

Economists have had a hard time trying to measure the costs of inflation or even
define the costs. Some economists in the 1960s were tempted to believe that the
gains to some people and the losses to others induced by inflation would cancel out,
leaving no net public discontent. This view is not widely held any more. Inflation is
a generator of uncertainty. It makes long-term planning difficult. It means that
even if nominal wages are not cut, real wages can fall appreciably. And it "politicizes" the income distribution by forcing reopening of the redistributive features of
the tax system and by inducing direct government involvement in wage/price
decisions.
Such costs cannot be totaled into a dollar aggregate. They are strains in the social
fabric for which the index is the political channel. That index is currently registering considerable public unhappiness over the lack of progress in slowing inflation.
V. AGGREGATE-DEMAND

POLICY IN THE SHORT TERM

By the end of 1978, virtually all economic forecasters were expecting a slowdown
in economic growth, despite the fact that no such slowdown was yet evident. A
sample of such forecasts-all made at about the time the Carter Administration was
preparing its forecast-is shown on Table 1. It is clear from this table that the
Carter Administration is relatively "bullish" on economic growth compared to private forecasters. But even the Administration forecast suggests some increase in
unemployment. In part because the Administration was optimistic on growth, its
inflation forecast was at the pessimistic end of the range.
Evaluation of current and proposed aggregate-demand policies must be made
within the context of considerable uncertainty about the economic outlook. However, it is clear that monetary policy has definitely moved toward a tighter stance
than was anticipated, even 6 months ago. And the Carter Administration's new
budgetary proposals also represent a tightening. These shifts in direction are the
consequence of fears of accelerating inflation and the related concern over the value
of the dollar in international exchange markets.
TABLE 1.-SELECTED ECONOMIC FORECASTS,
LATE
1979 AND EARLY 1979
[topeoznt]

Source
anddate

Data Resources, Inc., Jan. 1979 ............................Manufacturers Hanover Trust, winter 1978-79
UCLA
business forecast, Dec. 1918
Wharton, Dec.1978 .6.9
See footnote
at endoftabte.

GNP
dettato
inflation
rate

Growth
of
real GNP

1978-V to

1978tV to

1979-4

7.4
7.2
6.2

Peak
UnernpiMnent
rate, 179'

1979-t

0.5
.2
.9
1.4

7.1
7.2
7.1
6.1

66
FORECASTS,
LATE
1979 AND EARLY 1979-Continued
TABLE 1.-SELECTED ECONOMIC
[Inpercent]

Source
anddate

George Perry, Brookings, Jan. 1979 ..........................
Carter administration, Jan. 1979 ...........................

GNP
deflator
inflation
rate
1978-IV
to
1979-IV

6.8
7.4

of
Growth
realGNP
to
1978-tV
1979-4V

.8
2.2

Peak
uneorplymueot
rate,1979'

6.4
6.2

1979-IV.

(i) Fiscal policy.-Fiscal policy could affect the rate of inflation in three ways.
First, there is the standard analysis which suggests that a decrease in spending or
an increase in tax rates is contractionary. The problem in the past has been that
much of the contractionary effects associated with a tightening of fiscal policy have
fallen on real output rather than inflation. In the short term, say over a period of a
year, a 1 percentage point increase in unemployment might slow the inflation rate
by 0.5 percent. (Some would say that is an optimistic estimate.) To obtain that
increase in unemployment, real GNP would have to drop by perhaps 3 percent
relative to its trend. Thus, for a 1 percentage point reduction in the inflation rate,
the economy must sacrifice 6 percent of real GNP, if not more. At current levels of
production, this is equivalent to a cost in real output of about $130 billion.2 And,
obviously, the burden of that cost is not going to fall on the population in an
equitable manner.
A second type of fiscal policy relates to taxes that have a direct influence on
prices. The most obvious examples of such taxes are state and local sales taxes. A
substitution of income taxes for such sales and excise taxes would directly lower the
price level as it is conventionally measured. Unfortunately, the importance of excise
taxes to federal receipts is small, leaving little room for such adjustments by the
federal government. Unless the federal government is prepared to compensate state
and local governments for lost sales or property tax revenue, the only major tax cut
available for direct price effects would be a cut in Social Security payroll taxes.
However, such cuts would raise significant questions about Social Security financing, questions that Congress is unlikely to wish to face during the coming year.
Thus, the chance for any direct fiscal exercise on the price level in the near term is
remote.
A third possible influence of fiscal policy on inflation could operate through an
induced effect on monetary policy. It is sometimes argued that large budget deficits
"force" the Federal Reserve to finance the debt through monetary expansion. Were
the Fed to feel obligated to buy a substantial fraction of the net issues of Treasury
obligations, large deficits would indeed have substantial monetary implications.
However, there are no legal or institutional obligations of the Fed to finance the
debt. And, as Table 2 illustrates, the statistical evidence does not show any close
linkage between Fed purchases of Treasury obligations and Treasury issuances of
such obligations. Deficits do not automatically call the shots for an independent
Federal Reserve, nor should they.
The alleged monetary effect of fiscal policy is really the only channel by which
the budget deficit itself-as opposed to spending and tax decisions-could play an
important role in aggregate demand policy. Thus, the recent concentration by the
public on the deficit as the source of inflation is misplaced. The deficit does have
significance over the long term for the rate of national saving and investment. But
even from that perspective, it is necessary to have an expanding economy with good
prospects for investors as a precondition for a high rate of investment.
I The cost estimates are highly sensitive to the assumed impact of economic slack on inflation.
Arthur M. Okun, using a lower estimate of the response (0.3 percentage points off the inflation
rate per point of additional unemployment), set the real output cost at $200 billion per point of
inflation. See his "Efficient Disinflationary Policies," American Economic Review, Vol. 68 (May
1979), p. 348.

67
TABLE 2.-CHANGES INFEDERAL
DEBT
HELD BY PUBLIC AND BY FEDERAL
RESERVE
[Dollars
in tillionss

Fez!ar

1955 ..........................
1956 ..........................
1957 ..........................
1958 ..........................
1959 ..........................
1960 ..........................
1961 ..........................
1962 ..........................
1963 ..........................
1964 ..........................
1965 ..........................
1966 ..........................
1967 .
1968 .
1969 ..........................
1970 ..........................
1971 ..........................
1972 ..........................
1973 ..........................
1974 ..........................
1975 ..........................
1976 ..........................
1977 ..........................

Fdeal=
heldbypublic
(1)

$2.1
-4.3
-2.8
6.9
8.6
2.2
1.4
9.8
6.1
3.1
4.1
3.1
2.8
23.1
- 11.1
5.4
19.4
19.4
19.3
3.0
50.9
83.4
157.2

Netanby
FeeralReerve
(2)

Ratio(2)(1)
(peceet
(3)

-$1.4
.2
-. 8
2.4
.6
.5
.8
2.4
.2
2.8
4.3
3.1
4.6
5.5
1.9
3.6
7.8
5.9
3.8
5.5
4.3
9.7

'18.2

-66.2
-4.6
28.5
34.6
6.9
23.0
56.1
24.6
38.2
89.5
106.0
99.8
160.3
23.9
- 16.7
67.1
40.1
30.4
19.5
181.7
8.5
11.7
14.4

Figures
forfiscalyear1977
reflect
anextra
"transitional"
quarter.
Data
have
been
adjusted
bymultiplying
them
byfour-fifths.

For the present, therefore, federal fiscal policy is largely a matter of spending
decisions. Tax policy has already been laid out, and there is little sentiment for
major tax changes at this time. A substantial portion of federal spending is considered to be "uncontrollable" because it follows previously-established formulas. The
Administration estimates that a simple continuation of existing federal government
services would have cost $12.5 billion more than the proposed level of outlays in
fiscal 1980.3 But the budget reduction by itself can have only a small effect on
inflation in the short term, perhaps a reduction of one or two tenths from the
inflation rate.
(ii) Monetary policy.-Monetary policy is currently in a paradoxical position. On
one hand, it is the more flexible of the two aggregate demand policies because it can
be changed quickly in response to economic developments. But on the other,
changes in the institutions surrounding the financial sector have made the response
of the economy to monetary policy uncertain. In particular, a major element in the
responsiveness of the economy to monetary contractions was through disintermediation in the savings institutions, a shortage of funds to the housing industry, and a
resultant construction crunch. The disintermediation occurred as market interest
rates surpassed legal ceilings on interest rates paid on deposits in savings institutions, thus enticing savers to move into such assets as Treasury bills. However, the
introduction last June of new certificates geared to Treasury bill interest rates
appears to have sheltered the housing industry from the impact of disintermediation. Savings institutions have retained their deposits-although at-considerable
cost-and borrowers have been able to obtain mortgage loans, except in states with
restrictive usury ceilings. This development is somewhat ironic,,since housing prices
have been a clear area of overheated speculation. A cooling off of such speculation
would have been especially desirable.
Whether one prefers interest rates or monetary aggregates as measures of monetary policy, it is clear that in the last quarter of 1978, a dramatic shift occurred.
;

Office of Management and Budget, "Special Analyses,/Budget\of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1980" (Government Printing Office, 1979), p. 13.

68
During the first half of 1978, the Fed appeared to be in a reactive posture: Growth
in the monetary aggregates tended to exceed the targets established by the Fed for
the year, a process which continued into the third quarter. As Table 3 shows, M-2
was rising at an annual rate of over 10 percent during that quarter. But by that
time, the Fed had moved toward a more activist position, pushing up interest rates,
partly in response to depreciation of the dollar.
International considerations produced a dramatic policy reaction in the fourth
quarter, when it became apparent that foreign-exchange traders were not satisfied
with the prospects of the newvly-outlined anti-inflation program. Growth in the
monetary aggregates slowed substantially, and interest rates reached new peaks.
This tighter stance has continued into 1979.
TABLE 3.-INDEXES OFMONETARY POLICY
[In percent]
Annualized
rateof
growth
ofmoney
supply
Period

M-1

Dec.1976 to Dec.1977
.
................
Dec. 1977 to June 1978
.
................
June 1978 to Sept. 1978 ........................
Sept. 1978 to Dec.1979 ........................

8.0
8.6
9.5
.2

M-2

End-of-periodDiscount
M-3

9.3
7.8
10.8
4.5

Federal
funds

11.3
8.0
12.4
7.4

rate

6.56
7.60
8.45
10.03

rate

(NewYork)

6.0
7.0
8.0
9.5

M-l = circulating
currency
plusdemand
deposits
(excluding
domestic
interbank
andU.S.
Government
deposits).
M-2= M-fplus
bank
timeandsavings
deposits
other
thanlarge
negotiable
certificates
ofdeposit.
M-3= M-2plus
deposits
atmutual
savings
banks,
savings
andloanassociations,
andcredit
unions.
Source:
U.S.
President,
"Economic
Report
ofthePresident,
1979,"
(Government
Printing
Office,
1979),pp.251,259.

Given the uncertainties over monetary policy, it would be most unwise f6r the
Fed to react to each month's inflation news with a further tightening of monetary
policy. The short-term response through the housing industry and disintermediation
has been substantially attenuated, so that the monetary mechanism can be expected
to work only gradually through the effect of interest rates on investment decisions.
Because of the lags involved in this mechanism, the Fed could easily overshoot,
pushing the economy into a deeper recession or slowdown than intended. A cautious
approach is warranted until a clearer trend in economic activity emerges over the
next 2-3 months.
Finally, it is important to note that the channels through which monetary policy
affects inflation are much the same as those of fiscal policy. That is, monetary
policy restrictions will primarily slow the growth of real output, producing only a
small anti-inflation dividend, especially in the short run. The current boom in
agricultural prices and the effects of the OPEC oil price increase and the Iranian
production shortfall are not likely to respond to monetary policy. And, perversely,
the impact of increased mortgage interest rates has a dramatic worsening effect on
inflation as measured by the consumer price index.
Vi. INTERNATIONAL CONSIDERATIONS

A variety of special measures designed to support the dollar were announced last
November 1. These measures, which were the outcome of earlier policy conclusions,
signaled the end to the position that such interventions in the exchange market
could be avoided through the use of floating exchange rates. The dollar exchange
rate affects the domestic inflation rate; it is estimated that a 10 percent devaluation
of the dollar produces an eventual 1.5 percent increase in the consumer price index.
Devaluation raises the prices of imports, exports, and other substitute goods. And
inflation affects the dollar exchange rate; a perception of a faster pace of inflation
in the U.S. relative to inflation abroad puts downward pressure on the dollar. The
timing by which this process occurs is not precise. And it is quite possible for "runs"
on the dollar to occur due to the intangible loss of "confidence' in the currency.
The decision to defend the dollar carries risks, however. Unless intervention is
accompanied by a slowdown in inflation, downward pressures on the dollar will
resume and the government will suffer capital losses on the liabilities it has incurred. With hindsight, it appears that the deterioration in the net export balance
in recent years was indicating an increasingly overvalued dollar. It could be argued,

69
therefore, that the United States should have acted to slow its domestic expansion
well before mid 1978. This step would have reduced the rate at which imports were
sucked into the domestic economy and might also have increased exports. The lack
of a policy response in the past has required a more abrupt change in policy now.
Even with floating exchange xrates, individual nations must coordinate policies
and must consider international developments in formulating policies. One area in
which international cooperation will be needed is the so-called dollar "overhang,"
recently estimated at $60 billion.4 These dollars represent the holdings of official
foreigners which exceed what they would normally wish to have in their portfolios
for investment and reserve purposes. The-overhang was acquired during a period in
which foreigners acted to support the dollar. A quick release of these dollars in the
exchange markets could depress the dollar. Moreover, knowledge that official foreigners have a pool of dollars which they wish to unload is itself destabilizing.
VII. THE WAGE/PRICE GUIDELINES

Because of the limited response of inflation to demand-restraining policies, governments in all industrialized countries have sought other means to influence wage
and price decisions directly. The diagnosis of a wage/price spiral suggests that
inflation will perpetuate itself unless some outside force changes inflationary psychology and puts downward pressure on a large number of wage and price setters
simultaneously. This type of diagnosis ultimately led to the guidelines program
announced last October.
The new guidelines program is nominally voluntary; it is not backed by the force
of law. Pains are taken to distinguish the program from mandatory controls. Yet
the distinction is one of degree. Under the program larger government contractors
are required to certify that they have complied with the standards. The legality of
this aspect of the program has been challenged. But even without it, large firms and
contractors would probably feel compelled to comply. Although the program is
nominally voluntary, the Council on Wage and Price Stability has filled the Federal
Register with rules that are hard to distinguish from regulations. Larger companies
are also being "requested" to send in reports to the Council, just as they would be
required to do under controls.'
It is important to avoid dogmatism in assessing the new program. A common
response to the effort has been the assertion that "controls don't work." Yet the
evidence is mixed. During the Korean War, wage/price controls were accompanied
by relatively stable prices and there was no "bubble" of repressed inflation when
the controls were lifted. During the period since the mid 1960s, there have been
episodes of controls, other forms of direct wage/price intervention, monetary restraint, and fiscal restraint. It is hard to say which policy "didn't work" in recent
years. No policy was highly effective. This time, however, the odds for success are
improved by the prospect for decreased demand pressure.
(i) The specifics of the rules.-The new guidelines have been altered since their
original announcement. But the basic outlines are as follows. Firms must decelerate
their rate of price increase by 0.5 percent relative to the increase experienced in the
base period 1976-77. Under the deceleration rule-which is a carryover from the
now-defunct deceleration program announced a year ago-a maximum increase of
9.5 percent is allowed. In addition, a minimum increase of 1.5 percent is permitted
without question. Firms which cannot comply with the deceleration standard due to
uncontrollable cost increases are allowed cost-justified price increases. Under cost
justification, firms are required to limit their profit markups to the margin experienced during the best two of the last three fiscal years prior to October 2, 1978.
However, their profits per unit of output are not to rise more than 6.5 percent.
Special rules apply to certain industries and to state and local agencies.
On the wage side, 'pay adjustments are limited to 7 percent unless they were set
forth in contracts or pay practices prior to the guidelines announcement. Union
contracts can include 8 percent wage increases in the first year of multi-year
contracts averaging 7 percent per annum. Maintenance of benefits due to factors
such as rising insurance premiums is chargeable only up to 7 percent. Certain costs
of maintaining pension benefits are not charged at all. And union escalator clauses
are charged as if the inflation rate were 6 percent, regardless of the actual experience.
Both the pay and price standards provide for exceptions due to "gross inequity."
But the pay standard also provides exceptions for pre-guidelines tandem relations,
Lawrence B. Krause, "The 1979 International Business Outlook," Economic Research (February 1979), p. 6. (A publication of Goldman Sachs.)
regulations appear in the Federal Registers of Dec. 28, 1978, Jan. 4, 1979, and Jan.
5COWPS

25, 1979.

70
post-guidelines tandem relationships, productivity bargaining, and labor shortages.
In addition, low-wage workers (those earning $4 per hour or less) are exempt from
the 7 percent standard. Special rules are provided for certain types of executive
compensation such as stock options. Professional fees are limited to an average
increase of 6.5 percent.
(ii) Administration of the rules.-The new guidelines program is a very ambitious
one. It is apparent that the program's administrators really wish to concentrate on
larger firms and wage-determining units. But the rules nominally apply to firms
and units of all sizes, including governments. The Council on Wage and Price
Stability is requesting funding for an additional 90 staff members, which would
of Phase II (late
bring the total up to 233. By comparison, the wage/price controls
6
1971 to early 1973) involved a staff of about 4,000 persons. And the Phase II
controls exempted small businesses of 60 or fewer workers in most industries.
COWPS faces a dilemma under the current arrangements. Even with 233 staff
members, the Council will be swamped with business. And even if there were a
desire to increase the staff further, there are limits to the speed at which an agency
can expand. The new program is imposing obligations on wage and price setters,
despite its voluntary label. Thus, COWPS must be prepared to answer questions,
hear appeals, and generally regularize procedures. If regularization does not prove
to be possible, given the staff size and workload, then a reduction in coverage of the
program must be seriously considered.
Obvious areas for program coverage reduction are small businesses, public utility
prices, and rents. A small business exemption would have been carefully worded to
avoid exempting small firms covered by major union contracts involving many
employers. But in general, small businesses are not likely to be sources of strong
wage or price pressures. (And if they do become sources of such pressures, there is
little COWPS can do about it.) Public utility rates are already regulated by governmental agencies on a cost-markup basis. Additional regulation is superfluous. And
rent coverage is meaningless. There are simply too many rental housing units for
COWPS to undertake meaningful rent controls. And such controls would probably
have undesirable consequences, even if they were possible. Rent complaints took up
an inordinate amount of time and resources during Phase II.
Prior to the announcement of the guidelines, COWPS had an ongoing program of
review of regulatory decisions and general research into cost problems of certain
industries. This aspect of the COWPS operation ought not to be lost in the crush of
work related to the guidelines. Moreover, there is a certain tension between the
guidelines operation and the regulatory activities. COWPS may find itself asking for
guidelines cooperation from firms and unions with which it has a disagreement
concerning regulatory policy. It would be useful to insulate the regulatory and
guidelines components of COWPS activities from each other.
(iii) Monitoring of inflation and monitoring of the program.-COWPS plans to use
conventional data sources-such as the wholesale price indices-for compliance
monitoring, along with reports received from larger firms and units. However, these
same data sources will be used by the public to monitor COWPS program. It is
important, therefore, that a public information program be undertaken to interpret
available price and wage data. If price indexes are rising due to sectors exempt from
the program (such as imports), this fact should be put forward.
Wage data are already becoming available which require some explanation. As
shown on Table 4, surveys by the Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. have reported
that median first-year wage gains since the guidelines went into effect have averaged about 8 percent. The standard for multi-year contracts (probably more than 90
percent of the sample) is 8 percent, but the data suggest that about half of the
contracts surveyed have been running above the standard. It is possible that these
contracts all qualify for the tandem or other exceptions, but if that is the case, it
ought to be publicized. As time goes on, COWPS will have to deal with reports on
wage changes and union settlements from other sources, especially the Bureau of
Labor Statistics. These reports may also require interpretation, or they may suggest
sectors in which the guidelines are being ignored.
Finally, COWPS will be receiving a variety of reports from larger firms and units.
It is possible that useful public reports-aggregated to avoid disclosing confidential
information-could be made available so that the public could be kept aware of the
progress being made by the program. Information should also be made available
concerning the appeals activities. How many exception requests are being received?
I Statement of Dr. John T. Dunlop, Director, Cost of Living Council, before the Subcommittee
on Production and Stabilization of the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban
Affairs, Feb. 6, 1974 (GPO, 1974), p. A-107.

71
What types of exceptions are being requested? What is the disposition of these
appeals?
TABLE 4.-MEDIAN FIRST-YEAR
UNION WAGE SETTLEMENTS
[In percent]

Perio

Allindustrejs

Third quarter 1978 .
..........................
.
Oct. 31 to Nov. 13, 1978
.
...............
Nov. 14 to Nov.-27, 1978 .
.......................... .
Nov. 28 to Dec.11, 1978 .
.......................... .
Dec. 16 to Dec.25, 1978 .
.......................... .
Dec.26, 1978 to Jan.8, 1979 ............................
Jan. 9 to Jan. 22, 1978
.
................
Jan. 23 to Feb.9,1979
.
................
1979 through Feb.9...........................

7.8
7.5
8.7
8.0
8.4
8.3
8.0
8.7
8.3

Manufacturng

8.4
8.9
10.0
8.6
9.0
8.9
8.7
8.7
8.7

except
construction

7.7
8.4
8.0
6.9
7.5
-7.0
(2)
(2)

7.2

"Conains
a feow
construction
settlements
notshown
separately.
'Sample
toosmall
formeaningful
calculation.
Source:
Bureau
ofNatonal
Affairs,
Inc.,Daily
Labor
Report,
various
issues.

(iv) Can guidelines help?-By itself, the guidelines program is obviously not a
cure-all for inflation. But-as noted earlier-movements in demand are expected to
be in an anti-inflation direction. They will reinforce the guidelines effort. Unless
virtually all economic forecasters are seriously mistaken, 1979 will not be a repetition of 1966 and 1973 when demand forces worked against efforts at direct intervention in wage and price setting.
With good luck, the guidelines might knock a half a point or even a point off the
inflation rate. With not-so-good luck, the guidelines might at least prevent short-run
inflationary impulses from food and fuel from becoming permanently embodied in
the wage/price spiral. With bad luck, the guidelines could be blown apart by a foodfuel price explosion, leading to a rejection of the guidelines in a major union
situation or simply a loss of confidence in the programs by the public.
In short, whatever success occurs is likely to be measured in inches, not yards.
The public must be told not to expect miracles. The guidelines authorities should
avoid the temptation to grasp at food-fuel problems which are beyond their reach.
In 1973, attempts to control meat prices quickly emptied supermarket meat
counters. Attempts to prevent world oil prices from being reflected at American
service stations led to gasoline lines and informal rationing. These mistakes should
not be repeated.
The guidelines must be operated flexibly. In particular, if a new plateau of price
inflation is reached, the authorities ought to seriously consider raising the wage
standard or providing a more explicit cost-of-living exception.7 The 7 percent standard was very tight when it was first announced last October. At that time, compensation per hour was increasing at about 9 percent per annum and consumer prices
were rising at about an 8 percent rate. The recent worsening of inflation makes the
wage standard still tighter.
Basically, the key rule for the guidelines administrators is that it is better to "roll
with the punch" than "lead with the chin." A defiant stand against inflation may be
good public relations in the short run. But the longer-term prospects of the program
will suffer if the guidelines are administered in a rigid fashion. The Administration
should not count on real wage insurance to reconcile a price explosion with wage
restraint. At best, real wage insurance will have only a marginal influence. And, it
may never be passed.
' In principle, unionized units can install escalator clauses providing 100 percent protection
against inflation. However, 100 percent escalator clauses are quite rare because of the need of
employers to have advance knowledge of their wage rates. In recent years, average escalator
protection has been 57 percent in the major union sector. Escalators are extremely rare for
nonunion workers. And nonunion units cannot install escalators if wages are raised by more
than 7 percent as a result under COWPS rules. For data on major union escalators, see Victor J.
Sheifer, "Collective Bargaining and the CPI: Inflation vs. Catch-Up," Proceedings of the Industrial Relations Research Association, August 1978, forthcoming.

72
Vill.

REAL WAGE INSURANCE

The most novel feature of the guidelines program announced last October was the
proposal for "real wage insurance." Under this plan, workers in employee units
accepting wage increases of 7 percent or less would be rewarded with a potential tax
rebate. The plan would provide protection against inflation above 7 percent and up
to 10 percent, subject to certain limitations.
As part of recent testimony before the House Ways and Means Committee, I
submitted a 45-page report on real wage insurance, a report which expressed strong
doubts about the plan., That report makes clear why the initially-appealing idea of
real wage insurance has provoked considerable skepticism in the press and in
Congress. Ironically, the reasons for the skepticism can be found in last year's
Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisors. That report contained a discussion of "tax-based incomes policies"-of which real wage insurance is a variant. The
CEA concluded that such plans are inherently highly complicated, might not have
sufficient wage-restraining effects, and could turn the Internal Revenue Service into
a controls agency. Curiously, the judgments reached in January 1978 did not extend
until last October.
Originally, the real wage insurance proposal threatened to have a very detrimental effect on the guidelines program. Its designers apparently thought that real
wage insurance would have such widespread appeal, that a rigid 7 percent wage
guideline could be enforced with virtually no staff. Real wage insurance threatened
to make the program rigid so that the wage standard rules could be written into the
tax code. Fortunately, the widespread doubts which the plan evoked pushed the
Administration toward a more flexible guidelines system and a larger staff. But if
the prospects for Congressional passage of real wage insurance pick up, the Administration could fall back into the rigid rules/tiny staff model. That is one of the chief
dangers of real wage insurance.
Real wage insurance poses another danger. As long as Congress debates the issue,
there is a potentially destabilizing effect on ongoirig collective bargaining negotiations. Already, the Congress has become a party to the sensitive automobile and
trucking negotiations. Moreover, as the anomalies and peculiarities inherent in real
wage insurance become apparent, the entire anti-inflation effort could come to be
viewed as the latest version of a "WIN" button; a multi-billion dollar version.
There are many odd consequences of the real wage insurance plan. These cannot
all be enumerated in a brief summary, but the following six are especially worth
mentioning:
(1) The rules of the wage guidelines are not the same as the rules for real wage
insurance. Some of the exceptions to the 7 percent rule permitted by COWPS are
not reflected in real wage insurance. And there are differences regarding fringe
benefits and other aspects of computation. It is possible to qualify for one plan but
not the other. This is a strange outcome for a plan which is supposed to reward
compliance with the guidelines.
(2) Workers with cost-of-living escalators will be double compensated for inflation;
once from the escalator and once from the tax rebate.
(3) There will be individual workers who receive larger than 7 percent wage
increases who will be eligible for a rebate because others in their units got less. And
there will be workers who receive less than 7 percent and receive no rebate because
others in their unit received more. The problem of workers versus units becomes
especially apparent for job changers and moonlighters.
(4) The union and nonunion sectors are treated differently. They are covered by
different computation rules and timing rules. The differences involve the treatment
of fringe benefits, promotions, and employee mix. Thus, workers in units receiving
identical pay raises could be treated in a disparate fashion.
(5) The proposal appears to contain a control-year problem which could permit
wage increases of up to 15 percent in a unit to qualify for a rebate. This can occur if
workers under a union contract negotiated before the guidelines receive 7 percent
under their old contract and then negotiate a new agreement for 8 percent in the
first year.
(6) The proposal would have the IRS evaluate the savings realized from a productivity agreement in case of an audit. But evaluation of such agreements is a
complex matter over which labor and management sometimes disagree.
Despite assertions by the Administration to the contrary, the plan is complex. The
Administration assumes that the proposal by itself provides a strong incentive for
wage restraint. This is purely an assumption. According to recent testimony of the
Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors before the House Ways and Means
*The statement entitled "Real Wage Insurance and the Wage Guidelines" will appear in the
hearings record for Feb. 5, 1979. In the interim it is available from the author.

73
Committee, real wages have almost always increased on an annual basis. But this
plan proposes instead a zero increase, hardly a strong incentive, especially for the
big union situations which have experienced the greatest real gains in recent years.
Moreover, over 4 months of the control year to which this plan applies have
already passed. Can real wage insurance have a retroactive effect? It clearly did not
influence the recent oil workers' settlement. That settlement-in fact-illustrates
an important point. It is the guidelines themselves which will produce whatever
wage restraint there will be from this program, not real wage insurance. And it is
the guidelines program which should be getting the resources, resources which will
be diverted to the small employer sector where wage pressures have not been a
major problem by real wage insurance.
Paradoxically, the Administration's real wage insurance proposal is as well drafted as such a plan could be. Tinkering with that plan may correct some anomalies,
but will create new ones. Hence, Congressional leaders should look at the plan as it
is and make a quick decision. Prolonged debate would be disruptive. But it is
important that Congress look at the specifics of the proposal, the technical issues,
and the anomalies. Congress cannot pass a nice idea; it can only pass a detailed bill.
IX. REGULATORY REFORM

One of the areas singled out by the President in his guidelines announcement was
the need to reduce the costs of government regulation. The biggest success story in
deregulation has been the administrative and Congressional moves in the airline
industry. There are prospects for further cost reductions in the deregulation of
ground transportation. However, there are obvious complications as well. Regulation of railroads and trucking is interrelated, since the two industries compete with
each other. Reforms in one sector might be difficult to accomplish without reforms
in the other. Thus, further deregulation may be a prolonged process. The antiinflation consequences-especially in the near term-are also likely to be small.
Regulatory reform in some of the newer agencies, such as OSHA and EPA, will
also be complex. There have been suggestions for regulatory "budgets" which would
limit the costs an agency could impose on the private sector. However, the measurement of the costs of regulation is almost as complicated as the measurement of the
benefits. Thus, while regulatory reform is a vital issue Congress must address, its
results will be slow in coming.
X. CONCLUSIONS

With the exception of real wage insurance, the current anti-inflation efforts of the
federal government seem reasonable and desirable. Monetary and fiscal policies
have moved toward greater tightness. But both these policies have their impact
primarily on real output; their anti-inflation effects are small. The guidelines can
help in making wage and price setters more responsive to monetary/fiscal restraint.
But the guidelines must be administered flexibly and must be reviewed in the light
of changing economic conditions. In particular, if price inflation makes the wage
guideline unrealistic, the wage standard may require upward revision.
Real wage insurance will not eliminate the need for flexibility and realism. In
fact, the real wage insurance plan could impose costs on the guidelines efforts
rather than the benefits its drafters expect. The plan is filled with anomalies that
could prolong debate in Congress, and thereby disrupt ongoing collective bargaining
negotiations. A quick death would be the best outcome for the proposal. But,
paradoxically, the second best outcome would be a quick birth with the plan put
into effect essentially as proposed. The worst outcomes would be a slow death or a
prolonged labor.

Senator

BENTSEN.

Our next witness will be Sidney Weintraub,

professor of economics at the University of Pennsylvania.

STATEMENT- OF SIDNEY WEINTRAUB, PROFESSOR OF
ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA

Mr. WEINTRAUB. Thank you.
President Lincoln, until Grant emerged, lamented the "slows" of
his generals. They deferred battle despite superior numbers and
equipment.
Our stagflation bog is now 11 years old. Our policies betray a
case of the "slows."

74
The testimony just this week of the chairman of the Federal
Reserve Board, speaking of 6, 7, 8 years for fighting the inflation
trauma, I think confirms this. I have heard other remarks suggesting that we must unwind it slowly.
We do have the "slows". The double-trouble promises to linger,
sometimes more dismal on the inflation front, sometimes more
alarming in respect of the unemployment plight.
It is the inflation surge that accounts for the decline of the dollar
in foreign markets. It gives us the stock market jitters, it accounts
for the historic high interest rates.
Wherever we turn, with respect to housing, with respect to rebuilding the cities, or our transportation network, or -in trying to
exploit new energy resources, in health care, in everything, we are
told, "Now, go slow," we cannot do it for fear of inflation. I think
that controlling inflation is our first priority.
Monetary maneuvers, fiscal plans and some income policy feint
comprise the present strategy. Once again, we are relying on monetary policy. Apparently, the thought is that there is a new prescience not matched by immediate Federal Reserve predecessors. I
am skeptical of this. Words abound on recession prospects. Surely,
unless monetary policy creates a recession, or slows growth, it
stands little chance of -curbing inflation.
We talk about soft landings. Metaphors about "soft landings"
make vivid reading but spurious analysis.
It seems to me that monetary policy acts out a kind of "destroyto-revive" fantasy. We try to get the patient sick and then we seek
ways to restore health. This has been our story over the last 11
years.
We have, however, in the current inflation drama, a new growth
industry. Students of our colonial history know of early opposition
to Government expenditure and taxation; this is not exactly a new
phenomenon. Its novel status now is that it has become a vocal,
organized "industry." Insofar as popular ire contends that government budgets are the inflationmaker, the fusillades are largely
misdirected. In general, on this, government, the Federal Government particularly, has been getting a bum rap from many States,
especially in the light of the Federal Government making available
about $80 billion in grants-in-aid.
State and local budgets would be in a more dismal plight if these
moneys were not forthcoming.
With respect to Government expenditures, I would argue substantially that Government expenditures are more the consequence
of inflation than the cause. In 1963 prices, the current fiscal year
outlays of about $500 billion would be about $240 billion. Whenever
defense hardwares goes up, whenever office supplies raise in price,
when civil servant pay scales rise, then outlays rise. Pricewise,
given what is happening in the private sector, Government outlays
for exactly the same programs will be heavier. You cannot avoid
this result.
Now, this is not to condone wasteful Government expenditures.
Obviously, I, too, am opposed to waste, but if you cut all costs down
to the bone, if it were possible to eliminate every dollar of waste,
you would still find Government expenditures going up to match
the general rise in prices so long as you try to maintain roughly

75
the same programs. As I look at the Federal expenditure total, I
get a figure of about $358 billion out of this $500 billion on which it
is very hard to do any trimming. I wish you well in cutting. Of
course, I want you to trim insofar as you can. I would like to see
my own tax bill lower, but I don't think too much can be done.
I might add, I favor a tax cut.
Deficits are often condemned as the inflationmaker. However, in
the 51 budget years since 1929, we have had only 9 years of surplus
and yet, over this period, until the last 10 years in any event, the
general price level behaved rather well.
In fact, in the year of the largest deficit, in 1933, with a 55percent deficit-$4.5 billion of expenditures, about $2 billion of
revenues-the price level actually fell. Thus deficits are surely not
an automatic force for inflation. The better analysts, in using the
argument, largely tie deficits to borrowing from the banks and
increasing the money supplies. The theory is really a sister of a
monetarist position.

Inflation, in my own view, a position which I have held for many
years, is largely a result of money incomes outpacing output levels.
You can't avoid a rise in the price level if incomes, on average, go
up by 10, 15, 20 percent per annum, and productivity goes up 1, 2,
3, or 4 percent-or whatever small numbers you want to put in
there.
The void, the vacuum, between. the series will be filled with
higher prices. When we talk of money incomes advancing, inevitably we must emphasize money wages and salaries, which comprise
75 percent or so of the total income. Employee compensation is
rising currently at the rate of about $140 billion per annum. In 3
or 31/2 years, just the rise in employee compensation will exceed
the existing totals of Federal Government expenditure.
Now, how much of Government outlays can you cut in Washington? $10 billion; $20 billion; $30 billion? I don't think you can get to
those numbers, but suppose you could. Contrast this to what I am
talking about: for the same output, for the same amount of work
effort for the same amount of services, total income payments will
go up in the $140 billion range. It seems to me that when we
concentrate on Government outlays-in the light of the current
sentiment on deficits, on expenditures, on taxes-we are looking at
the smaller sized stem rather than the major factor.
I have often said we have been quilty of an assault on the laws of
arithmetic. We are trying to raise money incomes by extremely
large numbers. In England, they have been trying to raise wages,
as in 1974, by 25 percent; Australia, by the same number, and then
in both countries they are astonished that the price level rises by
approximately the same amount.
The belief that we can raise money incomes in compliance with
these numbers, and without any price consequences seems to be a
result of an urge to invent a modern Aladdin's lamp. Now, I don't
want anyone to think that I want to depress labor income. I would
like to make everyone a millionaire and I don't think we should
wait too many days to do it-today, next week, 2 weeks from now.
If we can raise money incomes, regardless of the movement of
productivity, there is every reason to raise incomes by enormous
sums. Once you say we cannot raise all incomes by 8 percent each

76
hour or 18 percent each hour, or 800 percent each hour-or even
bigger numbers-you are suggesting there is roughly a right rate, a
right pace of increase. I think we have got to focus on the right
rate.
I have a chart in my prepared statement indicating that money
wages far, far outstrip the price movement-whatever date you
wish to start with-in our history. Starting with 1929, it goes well
above productivity. If the chart included a price line, this would
fall in between the wage and productivity curves. With respect to
profit margins, those who say it is excess profits which are responsible for the price trend, if we go back to 1950, on the score of the
average price markup the average profit margin prices would be
about 12 percent lower rather than being 150 to 160 percent
higher.
This is not to suggest the unimportance of money. I have always
argued on the importance of the money supply but it seems to me
the big impact, the hammer blows of monetary policy, is on output
and employment. Whenever we have tight money we do have some
downturns in jobs.
To ignore the prewar period, in 1949, 1953, 1957, 1960, and most
of the years since 1968, whenever tighter monetary policy has been
invoked, we have had a clout or direct blow on the housing industry, and then the multiplier ramifications run through the
economy.
There have been comments here on labor productivity, on the
abysmal slow pace of productivity increases. I am one of those who
thinks this is a more durable problem.
Let me offer a small illustration. I think that the terms of trade
have been going against us, and that this will persist. Let's assume
the price of a barrel of oil is $2 and the price of an automobile
$4,000, as in the recent past. With the car selling now at $6,000,
and the barrel of oil selling at $15, it requires 5 cars for 2,000
barrels of oil. Previously, for just one automobile we could get 2,000
barrels of oil.
When we look around at the prices of sugar, coffee, cocoa,
copper, and so on, all the materials on which we are dependent on
our imports, we see substantially the same kind of phenomena. I
don't think there are any immediate remedies here, and-Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Weintraub, I must ask you to summarize.
Mr. WEINTRAUB. Thank you. I will.
On the matter of the Carter anti-inflation program, it seems to
me that this was belated by about 18 months. I applaud the fact
that he has taken the steps that he has, and that something is in
motion. I also think the Council is veering down the road to limited, though old-fashioned controls.
Further, I have some reservations on the suggestion of publishing a bad boy, or a non-complying list of firms. This sounds like a
new kind of WIN button being devised.
In brief, it seems to me that the program is designed mainly to
put a cap on inflation in the range of about 7 percent. I think this
is too high. I favor a program to stop inflation, not to slow inflation.

.,

77

A policy to slow inflation generally argues, let's not stop it
quickly, let's not hurt anyone else other than those who have been
ravished already by the 100-percent rise in the last 10 years.
In conclusion, I agree with the view of a right to a job, a right to
income-a right particularly of available work opportunities. I
regret that Thomas Jefferson did not include this in the Declaration of Independence, the unalienable right to jobs. But there is
also, as John Stuart Mill said in his essay, "On Liberty," denying
the right of anybody to act overtly to injure others. This, I think,
covers the inflation ordeal.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have attached to my prepared statement an appendix on my views on an anti-inflation package.
Thank you.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much, Mr. Weintraub.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Weintraub, together with an
appendix, follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SIDNEY WEINTRAUB
President Lincoln, until Grant emerged, lamented the "slows" of his generals.
They deferred battle despite superior numbers and equipment.
Our stagflation bog is now 11 years old. Our policies betray a case of the "slows".
The double-trouble promises to linger, sometimes more dismal on the inflation front,
sometimes more alarming in the unemployment plight.
MONETARY AND FISCAL ANTIDOTES
Monetary maneuvers, fiscal plans, and an incomes policy feint comprise the
present strategy.
Monetary policy: A destroy-to-revive fantasy
Again, we are embarked on a monetary misadventure to control inflation: the
reigning faith seems to be that what has failed before will now somehow succeed.
Players in the current drama intimate that there is new percipience not matched by
immediate Federal Reserve predecessors. I wish it were so.
Words abound on recession prospects. Surely, unless monetary policy creates a
recession or slows growth, it stands little chance of curbing inflation; only by an
employment debacle, thereby possibly blocking the wage climb, can it hope to arrest
the price splurge. Metaphors about 'soft landing" make vivid reading but spurious
analysis.
In perspective monetary policy acts out a sort of "destroy-to-revive" fantasy. Fed
policies set roadblocks to economic expansion; after the slowdown: when we think
the economy has suffered enough, steps are taken to revive it. There is an inner
irrationality in this marching up the interest rate hill preparatory to a slide down.
Tax and expenditure protests: A new growth industry?
To students of our colonial history, opposition to government expenditure and
taxation is not exactly a new phenomenon. Its novel status now is that it has
become a vocal, organized growth 'industry'. Insofar as popular ire contends that
government budgets are the inflation-maker, the fusillades are largely misdirected.
In inflation season and out, wasteful outlays by government can hardly be condoned. Nonetheless, government expenditures for any fixed programs of government
activity are more the result of inflation than the cause. The Federal 1979 budget of
about $500 billions would be about $240 billions in 1963 prices. Whenever prices of
defense hardware or office supplies surge, or when civil servant pay escalates,
government expenditures will inevitably mount.
Federal nondefense GNP outlays are not very much higher, relatively, than in
Herbert Hoover's time. (Vast transfer outlays, however, complicate the comparison.)
State and local governments far outspend Washington in GNP. Cutting expenditures will mean fewer orders in the private sector, fewer civil servants, thus fewer
jobs. Scalewise, the anti-inflation impact is likely to be small, operative indirectly
through unemployment restraints on wages and salaries.
Beset by inflation the cry for lower taxes comes on strong. Lower taxes, by and
large, should raise market expenditures and thus enhance private sector employment. For advocates of higher unemployment as the proper inflation medicine, a tax

47-977 0 - 79 - 6
7-

78
cut is hardly an ideal remedy. It tends to negate any assistance from tight money or
curtailed federal outlays.
I favor a tax cut, I might add. But this is because unemployment is edging up and
because of doubts on the efficacy of unemployment to stop inflation.
Deficits and inflation
Many hold government deficits culpable for inflation. Factually, over the past 51
budget years surpluses have popped up in only nine years, sometimes in piddling
amounts. Despite the deficit-ridden path, the price level behaved fairly well, judged
by standards of the last decade. In our 55 percent expenditure deficit in 1933, the
price level tumbled. Deficits are not an irresistible inflation-maker.
For better analysts, the deficit theory of inflation is a disguised form of monetarism. Deficits usually compel bank borrowing; money supplies increasing, the Quantity Theory then takes hold.
To eliminate deficits we will have to reduce outlays or raise taxes. I detect no
ground swell for the latter. Similarly, I doubt any great prospect for sharp pruning
of government outlays during our stagflation trauma. Our best chance to close the
deficit hole will be through budget restraints during a job and output ascent-not
under a planned recession.
THE WAGE-COST MARKUP

(WCM)

INFLATION THEORY

Inflation, in my view, in an economy where money wages and salaries comprise
the bulk of business costs, and the lion's share of consumer demand, is attributable
to an excessive rise in money incomes compared to labor productivity.
Employee Compensation is now rising at about $140 billions per annum. In under
four years merely the sum of cumulative additions to the total will outweigh
current Federal government expenditures.
The assault on the laws of arithmetic
Recent years have witnessed a precipitate assault on the laws of arithmetic.
Productivity inches up, say by 1 plus percent per annum, and we rush pell-mell to
raise money incomes-meaning wages and salaries mainly-by 8, 10, 12 percent or
more (as in England) per annum. Then we profess astonishment that prices lunge to
fill the productivity and money income gap.
The myth that money incomes can lurch steeply without generating inflation
reflects an urge to invent a modern Aladdin's lamp: make everyone a millionaire.
When labor announces for a general 8 percent advance we should protest the
modesty and insist on 80, 800 percent more. After all, the Fed-in the recital of its
eternal vigilance-can ward off inflation.
With outsized pay grants through the economy, my conviction is that the Fed's
monetary gestures will resemble the seven maids with seven brooms flailing at the
seven seas.
The WCM theory
The price level equation for the private sector can be written as: Price level
equals average price markup times average money wage divided by average Labor
Productivity.
Eschewing deeper analysis here, the accompanying chart depicts the slight down
drift in the markup (k) since 1950: the price level should have scored about 12
percent lower rather than steaming by about 160 percent. Average money wages (w)
have far outstripped productivity gains (A). A price level plotted on the same chart
field would sit about midway between w and A.
The price level emerges as literally a tug-of-war between w and A developments.
The consumer price level formulation is more complex; nonetheless, after conceding
that other factors can explain mild price bumps and wiggles, the practical doubling
of the price level since 1967 would stress the heavy wage-salary and productivity
imbalance.

79
-

T

.i
I
I

I

i
I

I

I

I

I

iI I

I

Iuidir\ trmidl'rr

it,

t
ivk, A,

"'-1

a

i

i

i
I

80
Money in the WCM theory
The importance of the money supply is not belittled in the WCM theory. Operative effects, however, are almost entirely confined to production and employment
directly, and the price level indirectly. If tight money knocks people out of jobs, or
deters growth so that unemployment swells, thereby containing average pay hikes,
the price level will be reined.
The price level pressure thus comes on the roundabout as by some recession.
Parenthetically, the adoption of a steady 3-4-5 percent "rule" for annual money
growth would not work too badly if the price level was once stabilized by first
aligning average pay to average productivity.
Note the major reservations: "ifl' the price level was stabilized by an effective
incomes policy, the rule could then prevail, almost mechanistically. Monetarists too
often assume the price level would be stabilized regardless of the average payproductivity trend.
The productivity creep
Dismay is widespread at the miniscule productivity creep.
A typical prescription is to urge a tax cut to favor investment, even by some who
opt for tight money and budget slashes, and thus some recession which would
negate any investment splurge.
I, too, favor judicious tax cuts-once we have an Incomes Policy in place, thus
allowing the easing of monetary policy without inflation alarms.
Still, the productivity problem is likely to be more obdurate without new technological triumphs because of rising raw material costs. For example, not many years
ago we were able to exchange about one automobile for 2,000 barrels of oil. That is,
assume the auto price was $4,000 and a barrel of oil $2. With an auto selling at
$6,000 and a barrel of oil at $15, it requires five cars for the same quantity of oil.
Through OPEC, the higher cost of extracting minerals, higher prices of coffee,
sugar, cocoa, copper, etc., we realize smaller domestic quantities of these items for
the same amount of work-hours.
Instant remedies are precluded. Productivity jumps from 1 to 2 percent, or 2 to 3
percent, are enormous when compounded over time. If spectacular productivity
surges could be captured there would' be no poor or underdeveloped countries.
A better inflation record would strengthen the dollar, lower import costs, and
facilitate faster growth through sugmented investment. Conversely, until productivity returns to historic norms, a tighter incomes policy will be indispensable to a
sidewise price path.
THE CARTER ANTI-INFLATION PROGRAM

The President, in his October 24 and November 1, 1978 pronouncements, finally
set an anti-inflation course after the more casual approach of last spring. Regrettably, the action was about 18 months belated. It is still too tentative and there is a
long road to travel.
The announcement-effects of Fed policy, and the international stabilization measures, have imparted some buoyancy to the dollar. Fed policy, however, will require,
as remarked, some economic slowdown to be effective against prices. Monetary
policy is capable of aggravating our unemployment ordeal without yielding much
inflation surcease. The stagflation double-trouble promises to persist.
The President's budget aims to reduce, slightly, the scale of government in GNP.
On inflation it is unlikely to dent the sorry price trend.
Incomes policy measures consist of a plea to hold average pay hikes to about a 7
percent norm, accompanied by price standards just short of the pay guides. Sanctions for violators involve a denial of government procurement, a trial balloon call
for boycotts-quickly disavowed by the President-and intimation of the publication
of a "bad boy' roll-a new kind of public enemy listing as against the earlier WIN
button merit badge. The news media reports staff recruitment and the issuance of
directives attesting to the functioning of the Council on Wage and Price Stability.
Too, there is the 'real-income insurance" now before Congress. (A comment on a
related approach appears as point 3 in the Appendix.)
A brief critique
The Council seems to be veering down the road to limited old-fashioned controls,
poking its way into pricing and wage decisions, forging exceptions to fit special
cases. It is still too early to judge the agency, whether it will be a mouse or a lion,
despite the four months that have elapsed.
The pay and price norms, I think, have been set too high: the 7 percent pay norm,
and the roughly 6½2 percent price move originally promulgated, hardly ends infla-

81
tion; it caps it at a jagged height. Prices at this peak will double in a decade; some
supporters are skeptical that even this tier will hold.
In promoting the numbers the pervading philosophy concurred that inflation
must be unwound gently, otherwise many who counted on inflation will be hurt; the
judgment then has been to bleed those who have been ravaged already.
This is distressing. A strategy to stop inflation should target to stop it. The
President will reap as much flak for this tentative inflation-oriented anti-inflation
step as from a more precipitous price and wage-salary drop. Better to face the
acrimony and to promote public education now, rather than to drain our energies
into 1980 and beyond. The October inflation message assures us that there is a
stagflation dialogue in our future. Our inflation-unemployment affliction is not over.
Beyond the high numbers, and the bureaucratic overtones of controls tempered by
new types of sanctions, the current environment begs to minimize government
intervention in the economy. Government should not exacerbate conflicts in the
economy. Firms that want to pay more than the noninflation pay rate should be
free to do so-it was childish bureaucratic bungling to utter even a one-day reproof
on Pete Rose's baseball contract. Cost deterrents, not a procurement scramble nor a
social offender (or public enemy) list should be evoked on those who puncture the
pay norms; for monopoly-type price markup excesses we do have an Anti-Trust
Division.
In all this I maintain, therefore, my predilection for the Wallich-Weintraub TIP,
modified in some details. (See Appendix.)
CONCLUSION

The inflation "slows" still beset us; the problem is finally being attacked-slowly.
Assessment of its critical severity is belated and inadequate; its blot on our
economic performance and national well-being is still dimly apprehended.
Simultaneously, we are backward in creating an environment for maximum employment. There is an "unalienable" right to jobs, to income and human dignity, at
roughly current real wages. A pity that Thomas Jefferson, with what John Adams
called a "peculiar felicity of expression," did not inject a right-to-work clause in the
Declaration of Independence. Too, John Stuart Mill's observation, in his celebrated
essay On Liberty, denying the right of anybody to act overtly to injure otherswhich covers the inflation ordeal-remains apt for a democratic society.
Socialist economies, obviously, control money incomes. Some with market economy features, such as Hungary, have an enviable price level record. We will have to
learn to gear money incomes, on average, to productivity norms while, at the same
time, avoid jeopardizing the basic freedoms of the market economy.
I remain an optimist despite our long frustration.
Appendix
[Excerpted from Challenge, September-October 1978]
PROPOSAL FOR AN ANTI-INFLATION PACKAGE

On the premise that the "carrot" and the "stick" will both influence conduct, the
following package reflects my own concept of the proper legislative design for TIP.
1. Amend the Davis-Bacon Act. According to law, prevailing wages must be paid
on current government or government-assisted construction. The government is
thus already operating an incomes policy. Labor and business now lobby for contracts which create jobs, and shortly thereafter there are strikes for higher pay,
involving raids on the public purse. A new clause, however, can require that, over
the life of the contract, average pay increases for all personnel are not to exceed 5
percent per annum.
A construction authorization incomes policy (CAIP), should help hold the line on
construction excesses. Penalties can include disallowing overpayments on the corporate income tax form, and remanding sums equal to the excess above 5 percent to
the government.
2. Amend government procurement contracts. CAIP can be applied to government
procurement generally, especially to defense contracts, where pay increases are paid
for by the public.
3. Reduce personal income taxes. Reduce the personal income tax by a credit of 2
percent on employee compensation, with a minimum tax reduction of 2 percent on
employee compensation, with a minimum tax reduction of $200 and a maximum of
$300 on all incomes rising by 5 percent or less per annum. This borrows from the
original Okun proposal. Largest percentage benefits would redound to wage earners'
advantage and help induce wage restraint.

82
4. The (modified) Wallich-Weintraub TIP. All business firms employing 500 or
more employees or having an annual wage and salary bill of five million or more,
are subject to the following tax provisos:
a. For average employee wages that increase by not less than 3 percent nor more
than 5 percent per annum, the firm's tax rate will be lowered by (at least) 2 percent
below the standard corporate tax rate.
b. If the average annual pay increase exceeds 5 percent, the firm will be subject to
progressive penalty tax rates.
Essentially, (b) is the original Wallich-Weintraub TIP. Proviso (a) is inserted (from
Dr. Seidman) with the 3 percent floor intended to preclude greater rewards to firms
that beat down pay levels; it dispels any possible allegation that TIP is a plan to
"create slave labor." It should also encourage pay moderation to foster price stability. Restriction to large firms should render the proposal administratively feasible.
Others may prefer to include only firms that are even larger in size.
5. TIP-CAP: A productivity bonus. Firms reporting average value-added per employee surpassing the economywide 2-3 percent trend of the past might be granted
a pay prerogative above the 5 percent norm. Calculations would have to be made for
average product corrected for price level inflation (CAP, or Corrected Average
Product). This would be a bit more complicated than TIP calculations, but would
involve only simple subtractions (of cost of materials from sales receipts) and applying standard price level indexes as a deflator.
This would be a productivity bonus. Perhaps one-third of the superior productivity
increase above 6 percent might be added to the 5 percent standard increase. Not all
of the productivity gain should be commanded by employees, however, for the firms
should be motivated to reduce prices.
6. TIP supplements. Various supplements can be attached to TIP-CAP to assure
compliance. For example, certain firms might be in cash-flow financial straits if
their 5 percent settlement offer were rejected by labor, resulting in a strike. Such
firms might be cleared for a government-guaranteed loan to meet fixed charges.
Clearly, loan availability would have to be monitored to prevent collusion.
Labor, in rejecting a settlement at 5 percent (or a trifle more) might be subject to
penalties ranging from mild to stringent, depending on strike duration and the
(vague) national interest. Labor specialists should promote this discussion.
7. Amending the anti-trust laws. To allay objections that prices are absolved from
sanctions, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) might be mandated to report quarterly on trends and profit margins, especially among the 2,000 largest firms, measured in terms of sales or employment.
Firms reporting extra productivity improvement should be expected to lower
prices. Where there is evidence that they are not doing so, the FTC might be
empowered to report and to seek remedial policies.
Profit margins have been declining. Until contrary evidence emerges, further
action can be deferred.
8. Government employees. Average pay increases for federal employees would be
limited to 5 percent per annum, with corrections every two or three years if the
private sector trend exceeds this norm. State and local employees would be brought
under the same 5 percent tent through the leverage of federal grants or other
federal aid programs.
CONCLUSIONS

These appear to be the essential legislative provisos to accomplish a firmer matchup of money, wage and salary trends to the productivity norms. None of them does
violence to the market economy; mostly, they invoke the tax laws and, confining
them to the largest firms, they spell only minor complications. They are modest by
way of intervention in the market system. If successful, they ought to capture the
big prize of full employment without inflation. Over the past decade a workable
policy of price level stabilization would have enhanced GNP by $50 to $150 billion
per annum. Inflation drift will inflict equal or greater annual losses in the future.

Senator BENTSEN. I will limit the members to 10 minutes per
round on the questions. I will exercise the prerogative of the chairman by starting.
Mr. Bosworth, the CPI index for January will not be released, I
understand, until 2:30 this afternoon, so I don't have it to discuss
at the present time. Perhaps you can give us some idea of where it
is headed. We are looking at some awfully rapid price increases

83
over the next several months. We have had no testimony on that
one.
With that in mind, how can you possibly achieve the President's
7/-percent inflation goal? Are you still holding to that?
Mr. BOSWORTH. First, I am not going to try a couple of hours
ahead of time to predict what the CPI increase is, because I could
easily be proved wrong. There are two things that I am reasonably
sure will show problems.
Senator BENTSEN. Let me interrupt, for a moment, to talk about
the productivity number because we were talking from memory,
both of us, on what the productivity increase would be for 1979.
The staff has researched it for me. I had correctly said 0.4
percent, and you quoted something higher than that.
Mr. BOSWORTH. I stand corrected on the 0.4 percent.
I think that the CPI will show a very high rate of increase this
afternoon. We know that there will be very substantial increases in
food prices in January.
Also, there will be dramatic increases in the dairy area, which
have been up very sharply over the last year. I would emphasize
that we believe that the rise in beef prices is almost exclusively
due to the rise in farm prices. The margin, the difference between
the retail value and the farm valuerhas been less than 6 percent.
January will show again that the margins have been held down
fairly well, but there will be very big increases at the farm level in
food prices. In other words, I would guess that the rate of increase
in food prices will be well over a 1 percentage point increase.
In the housing area, there is no reason to think that the rapid
escalation of housing prices will not continue for the next couple
months. That is what I would label as our second major problem.
In housing, I really think that it is a classic excess-demand
situation, in part, having to do with demographics, the fact that
the postwar baby boom is at the house-buying age.
Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Bosworth, I just have 10 minutes. The
question I have is: Do you still believe that with all of those factors
that you continue to go along with a projected 7 1/2-percent inflation?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I think we can get down very close to 7 1/2-percent
inflation. After the first quarter is over and we get into the spring
months with better weather, we believe there will be a substantial
amount of moderation in food price increases.
I think my uncertainty in answering your question explicitly
depends almost exclusively on energy. If the Iranian oil supply is
restored soon and the world prices don't rise rapidly, I think you
are talking around 71/2 percent.

Senator BENTSEN. I hope you are right on that.
Now, this morning, I read that a U.S. district judge in Nashville
has not approved the TVA settlement on pollution abatement and
that was partially because of your intervention. What is your comment concerning that? What do you think will be the result of
that?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I saw the same article in the paper. We had
regarded the issue as pretty much settled. TVA had attempted to
get an out-of-court settlement under the environmental protection
laws with respect to local coal, way back last summer. The Council

84
made an effort to discuss the issue with TVA because we are
* concerned about trying to find the least costly way to cut down on
the pollution that comes from powerplants.
The problem basically is that western coal is low sulfur coal. The
use of western coal will mean lower pollution, but it will also mean
there will be a drop in the local regional use of coal; thus some
requirements to use local coal could be passed. That is more costly
because that will then require more equipment to cut pollution.
We wanted those issues investigated. TVA declined to do so last
fall. A company wrote and asked us about the issue. I wrote them
that the issue was settled as far as we were concerned; the Council's involvement was some months ago. Now, we find that this
letter that we wrote to the company has been put before the court.
But the Council has not been involved since last summer.
Senator BENTSEN. Is it true that prices have been raised in
anticipation of the possible mandatory wage and price controls? Is
that part of what we are seeing? You have spoken principally of
food, but are there parts of the industry where decisions have been
made suggesting a pattern that might have been instigated by
management feeling that wage and price controls are not in the
offing?

Mr. BOSWORTH. Yes. Our concern is not only in the food area, it
is also in the nonfood area. What is startling in the January
producer price index is the wide range of price increases that have
occurred.
It seems not to have been a problem with the larger companies.
The automobile industry is not one of those, the steel industry is
not one of those, the aluminum industry is not one of those, et
cetera.
It seems to be much more broadly spread in those categories of
the economy dominated by smaller producers. We are still trying to
contact some of these companies and see what the reasons were for
the price increases, so I cannot give you a complete answer to that
question yet.

Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Keyserling, I recognize the fact that productivity goes downhill every time there is a lessened use of capacity, since businessmen keep on supervisory personnel; you cited
that. But has this been happening in our economy? Have we actually had such a reduction in the utilization of capacity in this
country that it would lead to such a substantial lowering of productivity?
Mr. KEYSERLING. We certainly have. Of course, it depends on
what period you start your comparisons with. My whole objection
to much of what is looked at is that it assumes systematically that
we have a very short-range problem. What has been happening
since 1953, with some undulations, is a chronic and increasing
secular or long-term increase in unused capacity, increased unemployment, and increased inflation all at the same time, and unless
we take a long enough view, we are flying blind.
Now, I do have a chart here which shows what I am talking
about. It is chart No. 3 in my prepared statement. Chart No. 3
traces over various substantial periods of time, beginning with 1947
and running through 1978, the relationship between productivity

85
growth and real economic growth, which correlates closely with
unused plant capacity.
It shows a very strong and positive correlation between the rate
of real economic growth-which correlates very closely with the
degree of utilization of plant and human power, and other productive resources-and the rate of productivity growth, so I think it is
all there.
Senator BENTSEN. Well, let me ask you about these numbers. We
have also heard, and it seems to me, as compared to the rest of the
world, we have an aging manufacturing capacity. I often wonder
about the percentages of capacity utilization that are recorded.
When they talk about 85 percent utilization of capacity, the part
that is not utilized normally consists of the older plants or the
older parts of the plants or those parts that are not as productive.
Are those not usually brought onstream when you get to even
higher percentages of utilization? Isn't that perhaps distorting the
numbers some?
Mr. KEYSERLING. It is not distorting my numbers. I think it is
refuting the official reasoning because the official reasoning is just
as defective in its examination of our overseas problems as in its
examination of our domestic problem.
Let me get, just for a minute, into your question about the
overseas situation. The weakening of the dollar, increasingly unfavorable trends in our trade and balance of payments, our failure to
be competitive which is bringing too many goods from overseas into
the United States, and the excessive flow of American capital
overseas through multilaterals and otherwise-developments that
are all due primarily to the relatively weaker performance of the
American economy.
I have a chart 6 here which shows that, during the last 10 years,
the Japanese and German economies have been growing two to
three times as fast as ours in real terms.
Also, on previous occasions, I presented to this and other committees, charts showing that those countries also tried to reduce inflation by cutting economic growth and higher unemployment and
every time they did that, the inflation went up, and when they
abandoned that approach, the inflation went down. I have drawn
up a chart within the last couple days, showing that this is true
even until now, but I have not yet had time to reproduce it.
Why are we not getting enough business investment, nor getting
rid of old plants rapidly enough to be more competitive? It is just
because demand for and sales of what industry produces are not
expanding enough.
So, the high inflation in the United States, the lower productivity growth rate, the lower real economic growth rate, and the
selective and inflationary shortages-deliberately c'ontrived stagnations and recessions-are all one ball of wax. And these all contribute to the increasing competitive advantage of these other countries who have, for these very same reasons-relatively more in->vestment, a higher ratio of investment to GNP, relatively more
new plant and so forth-is all part of one picture.
IJ
Let me read my last paragraph, because it bears so directly on
this. I am not going to try to answer what some of my friends have
developed in the laboratories of their own minds. I would like to

86
look at the great laboratory of the American economy in action.
What worries me more than any single thing is this. There is no
planning-and Senator Javits will be interested in this as a sponsor of the Humphrey-Hawkins legislation related to this. There is
almost no planning in what the administration is doing; its own
programs are in conflict. It is listening to the advice of six contending top economists and I can never tell who is "top," and the
President does not decide who is "top".
What worries me most of all, as I state in my prepared statement:
We must regain a sense of what America can and must do instead of do without,
of what we need rather than what we "cannot afford." Austerity and sacrifice are
good things in their time and place, such as during World War II when every
resource was overstrained. But what place do they really have, when almost all of
our economic problems and social problems result fundamentally, not from economic overstrain, but from failing to use the available resources which are pleading to
be used. The administration's policies, in their current form, represent a shortsighted, smallminded, defeated, and deflated frame of mind and loss of nerve. This
committee and the Congress can help to change all that.

As to productivity, it almost makes me cry to see an administration, with the kind of technological potential that we have, with
the enormous growth rate in it, which is going to cause more and
more unemployment if allowances are not made for employment
action, yielding and bowing to the idea that we have really suffered
an irretrievable loss in our ability to increase productivity growth.
The administration is not doing anything much about the causes of
the decline, and until they start doing that by a reversal of policies,
it is never going to get productivity up.
Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Keyserling, I agree that there are things
we can do, and have to do, but my time has expired and I want to
yield to my distinguished colleague, Senator Javits.
Senator JAVITS. Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
First, I would like to join our colleague from Texas and thank
him for being with us. It is all very helpful and very helpful to the
country.
Mr. Bosworth, one thing that you have said puzzles me. As I
gather from your statement-and please correct me; I am just
trying to summarize what I have gathered from the testimonyyou feel the administration should go right on doing what it is
doing and that it will result in an inflation rate of 7 to 8 percent,
notwithstanding current evidence that invalidates that proposition;
is that correct?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I don't think the program is locked in concrete. I
think that there will have to be some changes made.
Housing, for example, has continued to rise and we have to find
something to do about it.
The standards have been in place basically in the last couple of
months. We can't say on the basis of the WPI report a month prior
to that, "Now we will switch course and go to something else."
I think the administration has been careful to emphasize that
you cannot get overnight success out of this program; it will take
some time to have some impact.
There are, however, two thoughts that have been going on in
recent months-the problem of food and the problem of housing.

. 87
Standards of wage and price limitations do not directly address
these issues, when there are farm price increases or when aggregate demand exceeds supply.
Just .because the inflation rate has continued high for the first
month of 1979 I don't think that the forecast of 7 to 8 percent
inflation has to be invalidated.
Senator JAVITS. Well, in other words, what I said is correct. I am
not disagreeing with you. I just wanted to get it clear.
You say what the captains of ships say, "Steady as we go"; right?
Mr. BOSWORTH. Basically, I think you are correct.
Senator JAVITS. Well, I mean, we have our choice as to whether
we agree or not, but I think it is very important to get it clear.
The other thing that you said that interested me greatly was
that you don't have so much trouble in the "voluntary" guideline
situation with big business as you have-I suppose it is impliedwith small business; is that correct?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I think we have much more visibility and awareness of the program, and efforts to comply with it on the part of
the large firms.
Right now some of the smaller firms seem to feel that the program does not apply to them; we will have to overcome this attitude.
Senator JAVITS. Now; do you have any plans for overcoming it
and if so what are they?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I think basically the task of the Council on Wage
and Price Stability is to get the monitoring up and running and to
begin to contact some of these firms where we see sharp price
increases.
I think the most effective means of driving home to these intermediate companies-those with less than $500 million in sales-is
to bring some of them in and ask them about their price actions.
This program applies to them just as much as it applies to General
Motors.
Senator JAVITS. Well, to me, that is very big news. This is one of
the first times I have ever heard a Government official, Republican
or Democrat, say that you could get compliance out of big business,
but you are having some with small business.
I think that is a very important point because it is so popular in
our country to make big business the whipping boy. Often it de-

serves to be bitterly criticized; but just to take for granted that it is
big business that is at fault is not good for the country.
I think it is a very fair statement and I am glad you made it.
Now, turning to one other aspect-our time is rather limited, so

it is hard to ask too much.
Turning now to the issue of productivity which has concerned
very deeply Professor Weintraub and also by implication Mr. Keyserling, who happens to be a very old and dear friend of mine-this
has been not only a matter of great concern, but of great activity
as far as I am concerned and a few others here, including our
chairman.
The thing that puzzles me is this: I would like to reconcile the

two points of view again as I understand.
As I understood Professor Weintraub's point, he really said that
unless you can improve the rate of productivity from its present

88
catastrophically lower state, you have to reduce the American
standard of living.
Again, these are very hard words for politicians, just like what
Mr. Bosworth said about big and small business, but it is. a fact
because what he says is the wage bill is going to eat you up alive.
Now, what Mr. Keyserling says is this, don't worry about raising
the productivity by tightening your belt; just increase the output of
goods and services and that will raise productivity.
Now the question that bothers me is this, Mr. Keyserling: It is a
fact that the theory behind your theory is that business then
makes enough to modernize, but it may also be true that statutory
policies of depreciation give us a completely distorted view of busi-.
ness's ability to do that because it does not deal with replacement
cost nor does it deal with modernization, it takes the standpat, old
American plant and depreciates it at "normal" rates.
Is that the hole in your theory?
In other words, is your theory invalidated because unless we are
realistic so that more production in volume does produce truly
greater ability to modernize and thus replace the theory in balance?
Let's ask Professor Weintraub and see if he agrees with me.
Mr. WEINTRAUB. Senator Javits, might I state, as you know, that
a long time ago we had Kenneth Galbraith as a price controller.
He always insisted that it was much easier to control the large
firms than the small ones. I think that the reported recent facts
bears this out.
On the productivity issue, in general, you can write down a set of
statistics. But these apply to the yesterdays. Where are we getting
the new technological breakthroughs currently?
Largely, when they evolve, they represent a help; if they come
along, we will be in pretty good shape in the inflation struggle. We
probably could get productivity up a little bit-maybe by one-half
percent; 1 percent; or even 11/2 percent-by fuller employment. But
you are not going to get fuller employment unless you first resolve
the inflation issue.
You cannot get businessmen to go ahead with modernization
investment as readily at 10 and 12 percent, and even higher rates
of interest, as you can get them to act at interest rates about half
those numbers.
Further, the general contraction in economic activity by fighting
inflation through monetary policy does lead to unemployment and
militates against putting new capacity in place. So I tend to think
that we just won't get ahead on the production front unless we first
cope with inflation.
There I come back to: How to do it? Monetary policy has the
great drawback of trying to move-unsuccessfully-against the one
illness, inflation, by putting us in unemployment jeopardy.
One further point you mentioned-Senator JAVITS. Professor Weintraub, I must interrupt. My time
has expired.
Mr. WEINTRAUB. I want to agree with you, Senator.
Senator BENTSEN. Let Mr. Weintraub finish the answer to your
question.

89
Mr. WEINTRAUB. I agree with almost everything Senator Javits
said and I am not in conflict with much of it, and none of this
surprises me on the basis of past experience.
Let me try to reconcile this.
Point 1. Let's, for the moment, say that productivity is the big
problem.
The question is: How do you get it up? I admit it is a problem.
You say that inflation is the big problem. I admit that. The question is: How do you get it down?
Productivity is increased by two things: Full utilization and more
investment. You need both.
Full utilization depends on more markets. Business is not going
to invest more when the growth rate is cut in half or when recession is on the way, even if business has the capital.
Therefore, I think the first step is to supply the essential basic
ingredient to the encouragement of business to invest more. This is
more markets, more ultimate demand, with more consumer buying
and more public outlays in proper proportions.
If you find, as you start, the business still needs more capital to
invest, on which a lot could be said, then we should have pinpointed improvements in the tax cuts to bring that about.
We should not have the kind of broadcast tax reductions that we
have had over the last years which have gone willy-nilly to almost
everybody whether they have needed it or not.
I led the way to pinpoint the tax reductions during the Korean
war, and this was very effective. So you have to do both of those
things; you cannot leave out either of the important ingredients.
Now a word and what was said about labor and wages. I will
merely quote from what Business Week said a week or two ago.
It said a week or two ago that, during the past year there has
been a 9-percent increase in prices and a 9-percent average increase in wages. I don't know where the "800 percent" comes from.
So, labor made no gains in buying power per worker. And then,
Business Week said that, if the guidelines are effective, labor's
buying power would absolutely decrease.
Now, wage-earner buying power is two-thirds of all consumer
demand and consumer demand is two-thirds of the whole economy.
You cannot get an increase, you get, rather, a decrease in output
and employment of the whole economy if these kinds of policies on
guidelines, spending, taxation, and monetary policy are followedwith more, not less inflation. This has happened five times since
1953. Why is the administration trying the same things again?
Senator JAVITS. Thank you very much.
Senator BENTSEN. Congresswoman Heckler.
Representative HECKLER. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to say to Mr. Bosworth that you recommend a stable
course as Senator Javits described it.
Let me say that I think the ball is in your court as Director of
the Council on Wage and Price Stability.
If you succeed, we will have a stable course. If you fail, then the
public pressure against the increase in prices will cause and force
the Congress to take another course and that will back us into
wage and price controls which I do not favor.
So, I feel that those are the options.

90
You will succeed or, based on your achievements, there will be
few options available to the Congress which cannot be avoided.
I would like to ask at the outset, Mr. Bosworth, do you speak to
the President?
Mr. BOSWORTH. Occasionally.
Representative HECKLER. I think it is disappointing that it is
only occasionally.
Did you have an opportunity to speak to him about his announcing his support of an increase in the price of sugar from 15 to 15.8
percent?
Have you spoken to the President about that?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I, personally? No. That would normally go
through Mr. Schultze, Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, or Alfred Kahn, the Chairman of the Council on Wage and
Price Stability.
Usually, I don't give advice directly to the President.
Representative HECKLER. In other words, you monitor the price
increases in the private sector, but if the President initiates the
price increase, you have no voice in that?
Mr. BOSWORTH. We will usually make an analysis for the administration on those types of issues. That is forwarded to the President by either Alfred Kahn or Charlie Schultze.
A few months ago it was mainly Mr. Schultze because he was
Chairman of the Council on Wage and Price Stability.
Representative HECKLER. It is my understanding that the average American consumed 92.7 pounds of sugar last year and that an
increase in the price of sugar will virtually affect costs in almost
every product line since the American taste becomes sweeter and
sweeter.
Now, the end result of all this has to be an increase in food
prices, which is the runaway factor aside from energy, which has
some rational basis.
The increase in food prices is the runaway factor in your scenario as you, yourself, admit. How can this Government then not deal
with the inflationary impact of an increase in sugar prices which
will affect so many food items and the food budget itself?
How can the President, on the one hand, say that we are going
to fight inflation and on the other hand propose an increase in
sugar prices that creates food inflation in the most sensitive area of
the whole economy where the inflation is already out of hand?
How can you justify these inconsistent and contradictory policies?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I think in terms of national policy you cannot.
Even the administration's proposal to Congress on the sugar
situation is inflationary. There is no doubt that it will raise sugar
prices.
This issue has a long history between the administration and the
Congress. The administration last year tried to get a much lower
sugar price.
The administration's interest in the issue principally has to do
with the International Sugar Agreement. The administration has
been unable to get the Congress to consider this agreement unless
it would first agree to a sugar bill.

91
Sugar is very important to some people in the Congress who
have a strong say in what our program is going to be. If you are
trying to work out an agreement to resolve this issue of sugar, the
industry and many of its congressional proponents are talking of
introducing a bill calling for 17 or 18 cents for sugar.
The administration had earlier sought a much lower price for
sugar. We tried to resolve that difference through compromise.
The latest proposal by the President is inflationary in and of
itself. But it comes down to the action that is taken in terms of the
alternatives available to the administration, and I don't see that
they have much choice. It depends on what they can get through
the Congress.
Representative HECKLER. If I might interject, it seems to me that
in view of the enormous impact of inflation on the American
consumer and taxpayer, inflation should be the No. 1 priority. Is
the implementation or the future of a sugar agreement more important than fighting food price inflation for the consumer of
America?
Mr. BOSWORTH. I would remind you that about 4 years ago for a
short period of time we had 80 cents a pound sugar because of a
sharp world shortage. The purpose of the International Sugar
Agreement is to work out an agreement between the producers and
the consumer nations to establish a reserve to meet such needs.
Domestically, only about 15,000 producers, but they are 15,000
very influential producers up here on Capitol Hill. The domestic
cost of producing sugar in the United States is currently about 15
cents to 16 cents a pound if you made a full allowance for the price
of land.
The question basically is whether or not the United States will
have a domestic sugar industry. The argument made by some
people in the Congress is that there is too much exposure if the
United States becomes completely dependent on the world market.
The domestic producers say that they need a sugar price of at least
16 or 17 cents.
Representative HECKLER. Are you saying that the sugar agreement is more important than food price inflation for Americans?
Mr. BOSWORTH. It is part of the food price inflation. If we do not
have some sort of international agreement to stabilize the sugar
market, we will get more inflation the next time around. We are
trying to avoid the large swings in sugar prices.
You are absolutely right, however, that the implication in the
short fall is that the price of sugar will be higher than it otherwise
would be for the next year or two. What the implications of this
agreement will be over the next 10 years can very well be that, on
average, sugar prices will increase less.
Representative HECKLER. Well, we are dealing with the problem
of inflation today as the No. 1 problem in America.
Mr. BOSWORTH. Right.
Representative HECKLER. Now, in terms of going from the question of the President's supporting an inflationary increase in the
price of sugar which affects the commodities across the spectrum
and foods across the marketplace, the fact of the matter is that I
question how really effective you are, even how effectively you are
approaching this whole question of food prices. I am really sur-

92
prised to have you testify today that what happens is the traditional answer, or the reason for increases in food prices, whereas in
Boston one of our leading supermarkets, the Star Market, itself
recognized the increase in pricing of all food products and initiated
a new labeling system in which it made the consumer aware that
the new goods were exceeding your guidelines.
This was happening on such a flagrant basis-I think in anticipation of a wage freeze or a price freeze later-that this supermarket
took it upon itself to inform the consumer that the prices were
exceeding the guidelines.
Now, this is not a question of whether we are looking at cattle or
at traditional elements of the boom-or-bust farm cycle problem; we
are looking at a policy of many companies that indicates to meand I don't know their size, whether they are within the large,
medium, or small range-that they are virtually ignoring your
guidelines.
While we don't expect overnight success, if you have passive
acceptance and this increase in sugar which will affect hundreds of
products, you are going to produce inflation yourself.
Now, what are you doing in terms of this food inflation that goes
beyond farm factors which are not necessarily the pivotal questions
or the questions of current and runaway food prices? What monitoring system have you instituted?
Mr. BOSWORTH. No. 1, I guess I would disagree a little bit. I think
that the problem in the last few months and over the last year has
been farm prices.
Farm prices are 30 percent of the consumer's food bill.
While that is only one-third, it has been increasing at very rapid
rates. In the food marketing area the Council does have standards
to control the margins with respect to the amount of increase in
price over and above the farm prices.
For the first 3 months ending in December the average annual
rate of increase in those margins has been less than 6 percent.
We do have a standard. We are trying to monitor these food
processors to make sure that the increase in the cost of goods they
purchase does not bring them more than 61/2 percent in additional
profits over the next year.
So far, the industry appears to be cooperating with the program.
I would also say that the next 3 months is not over yet and we will
have to wait and see what develops further.
In sugar, I think that you are right. In the short run it is
absolutely inflationary.
It is an issue of long-range effect because we cannot be concerned
about inflation in the next few months; we have to be concerned
only about next year as well.
Basically, this conflict is over whether or not the United States
should have a domestic sugar industry. The conflicts are not going
to be limited to sugar. We are going to have basic questions in the
next year from the energy area too.
Representative HECKLER. Mr. Bosworth, let me raise another
subject just briefly. I think there must be some misunderstanding,
but I did not hear your testimony.
I understand that one of the causes that you attributed for the
lack of productivity in the American wage force was the introduc-

93
tion of more minority individuals and women into the wage force;
is that correct?
I cannot believe that you think that women are less productive
in the wage force than men.
Mr. BOSWORTH. Let me be clear. What we have is a very rapid
growth of new entrants into the work force, partly of women and
partly because of the postwar baby group.
When people first come in to work for the first couple of years,
until they develop job skills, they tend to be less productive.
Now, the demographics in the 1980's will go in our favor because
then these people who entered now, women and teenagers, will be
experienced workers and their productivity should increase.
We argue that it has been a factor holding down current rates of
productivity but it has nothing to do with their sex, or their age
per se. Rather, it is the fact that there is rapid new entry to our
labor force.
Representative HECKLER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you, Congresswoman Heckler.
I am committed to let you gentlemen finish at noon, so I now call
on Congressman Brown.
Representative BROWN. Thank you.
It is nice to see you here and we appreciate your views.
Let me ask a fundamental economic question. Given the situation in which we find ourselves now, is this the time to stimulate
demand or supply in our system?
Mr. Keyserling, maybe I had better. start with you as the senior
officer present.
Mr. KEYSERLING. It is now the time to stimulate both, through
selective programs that deal with both.
There is nothing more damaging to national economic policy
than the fallacy of the thinking which concentrates on one point to
the neglect of most others, and this is the trouble that I find in this
administration, in contrast with those administrations which were
successful in dealing with all of these problems. That is what
planning under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act means.
When we hear people coming up here and saying that they have
not talked to the President, that may be all right but they ought to
talk with the President.
In other words, the President has to have the command to get a
unified economic policy and he is doing an injustice to the Congress
when they can't find out from his representatives where he really
stands.
This is the essence of a unified economic policy.
Now, during the Truman administration we had Mr. Charles E.
Wilson as an aid to mobilization during the Korean war. I was not
subordinate to him; I worked for the President.
But President Truman insisted not only that I sit with the
Wilson group but that I brief them every week so that we had a
unified economic policy-covering demand, supply, production,
wages, prices, and all basic elements of national economic policy.
Now, let me answer part of this question by Congresswoman
Heckler, because I believe she is right on everything she says and I
agree with her on everything she says.
In the first place, as to the women entering the labor force-47-977 0 - 79 - 7

94
Representative BROWN. Wait a minute. Congresswoman Heckler
has had her time. You are perfectly welcome to do that but not on
my time.
I asked you if you think we need to stimulate demand or supply,
one more than the other. Now your answer was, I guess, that we
ought to stimulate both.
Mr. KEYSERLING. All right.
Let me continue to answer that. This was my intent, I am sorry
to have caused you to infer otherwise.
Representative BROWN. I want to get the other gentlemen's
answer, too, and we only have 10 minutes.
Mr. KEYSERLING. Fine.
This is one of the problems. We have to stimulate both supply
and demand, and the President's program is trying to cut back on
both. He is trying to cut back on housing; he is trying to cut back
on other sources of supply; he is trying to cut back on demand.
This is inimical to the whole American economy, and it is the
worst thing that we can do with respect to inflation because stagnation and recession always produce more inflation.
An automobile running 30 miles an hour burns more gas per
mile than one running 50. It also burns more gas per mile at 90
miles per hour than at 50.
The official economists think if we get it to 30, it burns less than
at 50. They found that an economy running at a real economic
growth rate of 9 percent generated more inflation pressures than
at a 5-percent rate. So they are now trying to reduce the growth
rate to a 2.7-percent average during 1979 and 1980 to reduce inflation. They are as wrong as they can be.
Representative BROWN. All right.
Mr. Weintraub.
Mr. WEINTRAUB. On the question you raise, I would distinguish
between stimulating money demand-for output-from real
demand and money-oriented supply and real supply.
The question involves rates of pay. Are we going to pay $500 a
week or $200 a week or $800 a week? So, I would say that the time
is long past for stimulating both real demand and real supply, but
not money demand and money supply market output schedules.
Money supply, money demand refers, in my arguments, to money
income aggregates.
Representative BROWN. Mr. Mitchell.
Mr. MITCHELL. I guess I have a problem in responding. I don't
think that we really have instruments currently that turn supply
on and off.
We have instruments of monetary fiscal policy but unless you
were talking about some very thoroughgoing system of national
planning, something of that type, it does not seem to me that we
really can talk about a supply policy except in some very specific
areas.
Possibly in the farm or agriculture area we have some instruments.
Representative BROWN. Let me comment.
It seems to me that we can sell more farm goods abroad at
anywhere close to reasonable prices and that we therefore in a
year's time very quickly stimulate the supply of those goods pro-

95
duced in this country which reduces for the American consumer
the cost of those goods. This occurs because we are proliferating
our market, reducing our unit costs to production and winding up
with our domestic consumers better off because of the drop in that
unit cost of production.
Also, we are dealing with the farmer and his perceptions of his
needs in terms of total economic return. I guess the first step in
that, then, is to institute the policy that might stimulate foreign
demand for American products but the reduction in price or rather
the stabilization in price-the reduction probably is too optimistic-comes from the stimulation of the supply; does it not?
Mr. MITCHELL. I think the agriculture area is one where the
Federal Government can influence supply.
I think most economists would agree that you could increase
output and that would be beneficial.
Representative BROWN. Now, I have expressed this concern to
people like Chairman Miller of the Federal Reserve Board.
As a small businessman, we are finishing our fiscal year about
now and I have begun to look a the cost of replacement of the
products with which we try to make money, I mean, the machinery
with which we try to make money.
I discovered that with respect to the tax policy; under which I
can deduct depreciation as related to machinery, if I could take a
higher depreciation rate reflecting real cost of replacement of those
producing pieces of equipment, then my taxes are reduced. However, the tax policy does not allow me to take a real cost of
replacement as my depreciation rate; it allows me to take something that is outdated by maybe one-third or two-thirds of the real
cost of replacement.
So, I paid a higher tax in my company so a profit could be made
and yet when it comes time for me to replace that equipment or
expand, I don't have the resources unless I go out and borrow
money to do that because I have not made the money from profits
because the profits have been taxed away because of the depreciation rate.
When I get to the bank to try to get the additional money I need,
I find that my competitor is the Federal Government which is
borrowing that money or using it up in some form to meet its
deficits and its expenditures.
The interest rate is high and the availability of market funds for
my whole business is quite low.
Do you understand my problem and where that puts me with
reference to the effort to increase supply and thus reduce the cost
of the product that we produce?
Mr. MITCHELL. I understand your concern.
Representative BROWN. About what?
Mr. MITCHELL. I think there would be some problems at this
point on generalized tax cuts of large amounts for business or
anybody else.
Representative BROWN. I never mentioned tax cuts in all that;
did I?
Mr. MITCHELL. Pardon me.
Representative BROWN. Did I mention tax cuts?
Mr. MITCHELL. You mentioned some form of tax--

96
Representative BROWN. Well, an increased depreciation rate,
something that the IRS says merely reflects the real cost of replacement.
We were told yesterday we are going to draft the steel legislation. We have had pricing ills for a long time on steel-de facto,
not de jure.
So, the profit from the steel industry has not gone back into the
replacement of those steel plants.
What do we do about that? I mean, is there some other method
by which we get relief?
Should we nationalize that industry and subsidize it rather than
tax-cut it?
Are you following my concerns here?
Mr. MITCHELL. I am following your concerns but I think you have
me out of my element.
Representative BROWN. In the steel industry?
Mr. MITCHELL. Yes.
Representative BROWN. I don't know what your element is but
maybe Professor Weintraub can help us.
Mr. WEINTRAUB. Could I go back a bit, Congressman? On your
farm illustration, I would say the exports do tend to improve our
foreign balance through some strengthening of the dollar. That
would be fine.
On the other hand, if we have the unchanged domestic spending
without the exports, it would seem to me that would lower the
price level here. But then the question is what you have-Representative BROWN. My time is up, but if we had an -expansion of both supply and foreign demand, wouldn't the unit cost of
production tend to come down?
Mr. WEINTRAUB. That plus the augmented output by and of
itself, and with the same amount of income to do the purchasing.
Representative BROWN. Did you want to pursue it further?
Mr. WEINTRAUB. With respect to plant modernization, I think
this gets us to an enormous issue. We should be all out for modernizing our plants. The calamity is that Japan and Germany have
outstripped us in modernization, in steel and in autos where we
have enjoyed this enormous technological lead, and where we have
been having complaints about imports.
The whys and wherefores are the issues. It would seem to me
that we must do something to get back that lead once again.
We have been derelict on this problem in many ways. Words
such as "tax cuts," "subsidies," and so on, are met with abuse even
without examining the proposal.
Yes, we should be in the van of technology in all of those fields,
in steel and electronics. Why not? We have the engineers, we have
the know-how. In altering our laws, there can be some differences
in approach. But this is a major problem. It would seem to me
deserving of the highest priority.
Representative BROWN. Let me conclude with a comment. It
seems to me in the past we have had the very heavy investment in
the development of plant in the United States starting with the
period before we set the tax rates and the tax methods that we now
have. During that period of time the rate of inflation in this
country was relatively low and the rate of new job development

97
was relatively high, and now these are the things that are afflicting us in the society.
It seems to me that in our total policy area-not just this tempo-.
rary means of trying to deal with the inflation until the next
election-that there has got to be some answer for the future of
our society.
The Japanese are outstripping us in growth; the Germans are
outstripping us in growth; and now the French and the British are
also outstripping us in growth. I am a little concerned about what
that implies for the United States in the year 2000.
I don't like to be a second-class power, and I sure don't want to
be a third-class power.
Mr. WEINTRAUB. I agree. It is, I think, all closely tied to productivity and to the inflation issue.
We have invited stagflation through our monetary policies. These
have created the economic downturn in housing and in investment.
Yes; I do feel that these questions are bound together. Yes, this is
the economic calamity that has befallen us. Where we once were in
the technological forefront, we are now lagging.
Representative BROWN. Thank you.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you, Congressman Brown. You have
expressed the concerns of all of us on that.
I think the diversity of the comments and the so-called proposed
solutions are an aid to the problem.
I am appreciative of the strong views that were expressed and
the comments that you have made. It has been helpful to us.
Thank you very much for your attendance.
[Whereupon, at 12:05 p.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene
at 10 a.m., Wednesday, February 28, 1978.]
[The following questions and answers were subsequently supplied
for the record:]
BARRY P. BOSWORTH TO ADDITIONAL WRITTEN QUESTIONS POSED BY
REPRESENTATIVE HAMILTON
by Alan Blinder and William Newton, for the National
study
recent
Question 1. A
Bureau of Economic Research, demonstrated that after the 1971-74 wage-price
controls were removed, prices rose so fast that they were actually about one percent
higher than the level which would have prevailed if there had been no controls at
all. Based on the results of this study, Blinder said, "The Carter controls program
should be scrapped. There's not much of a short-run payoff, and in the long run,
prices end up higher than in the absence of controls." What is your own evaluation
of the Blinder-Newton study?
Answer. In the 1971-74 period, wage and price controls were substituted for
responsible fiscal and monetary policy. Pressures created by expansionary monetary
and fiscal policies during the control period caused rapid price increases when
controls were lifted. In contrast, prudently restrictive monetary and fiscal policies
are the essential foundation of the President's anti-inflation program. Under these
policies, future removal of voluntary wage and price standards should not result in
escalating prices.
Question 2. You and Chairman Schultze have repeatedly stated that in the early
1970's mandatory wage and price controls were a failure. At the end of 1972,
approximately 4,000 people in the Federal government were employed to administer
the program.
Under the President's proposed budget for fiscal year 1980, the total size of the
CWPS staff should be increased to approximately 150. But at the February 23rd
Joint Economic Committee hearing, you announced your intention to step up monitoring of intermediate and small companies. Admittedly, President Carter's standards are voluntary while President Nixon's were mandatory; but on the other hand,
inflation is much worse today than it was in the early 1970 s.
RESPONSE

OF

98
In short, how can 150 succeed if 4,000 failed?
Answer. During the 1971-74 period of wage-price controls, prices were contained
despite expansionary monetary and fiscal policies and a fourfold increase in the
price of OPEC oil. Wage-price controls were a failure because underlying inflationary forces, created by stimulative monetary and fiscal policies, quickly came to the
fore when controls were lifted. In addition, the approach to wage-price controls,
which attempted to control each and every price in the economy and which did not
allow relative prices to adjust, created serious inefficiencies and market distortions,
some of which, like beef, we are still experiencing. However, 4,000 people were able
to control individual prices in the economy during the control period.
The current wage and price standards are easier to administer than the Nixon
controls for a number of reasons. The standards apply to average prices rather than
individual product prices. The price standard is aimed at decelerating rates of price
increase and thereby avoids the great difficulties associated with administering
controlled prices based on cost-pass-through considerations. Finally, the current
monitoring effort is focused on larger companies and on industries in the excessively high rates of price increase. The President's fiscal year 1980 budget requests a
total of 233 staff for the Council on Wage and Price Stability. These staff will be
assisted by staff of certain other executive agencies in the price monitoring effort.
We believe that the projected effort will be equal to the task.
Question 3. Wage and price controls: Many commentators have suggested that
labor and business still expect that we will have mandatory wage and price controls,
in spite of President Carter's statements to the contrary; as a result of this expectation, they may attempt to obtain large wage settlements and price increases now,
defeating the President's program. Alan Greenspan has suggested that in order to
end this speculation about controls, President Carter should state in advance that
he would veto any legislation which would give him the power to impose controls.
Do you agree with Mr. Greenspan that the President should take this step?
Answer. I would hope that the Congress would not take unilateral action to
provide such authority or to impose mandatory controls and I expect that Congress
will not.
Question 4. Mr. C. Jackson Grayson, Jr., Chairman of the American Productivity
Center, has charged that the anti-inflation wage-price guidelines "could seriously
curtail some of the most effective productivity improvement programs in America"
because productivity gains may be counted as offsets to pay increases for labor
under union contract only. What is your response to this allegation?
Answer. The voluntary pay and price standards were designed to be consistent with
the goals of increased economic efficiency and improved productivity. These standards
are not counterproductive as often claimed. They have been designed to encourage
efficiency and avoid the dampening of investment incentives. This is evident in
several aspects of the standards.
First, the notion of a price standard based on a cost-passthrough principle was
rejected at the outset. Under the 1971-1973 program of price controls-administered
by Mr. Grayson, Chairman of the American Productivity Center-price limitations
were based on a percentage passthrough of costs. This approach provided no incentive for firms to search for cost efficiencies, since any decrease in costs would have
to be reflected in reduced prices. In contrast, under the present price standard, if
the price deceleration goal is achieved, no limitations are placed on profits. This
encourages firms to take cost-reducing actions, with the resultant profits available
for investment and capital accumulation-a major determinant of productivity
growth.
Second, the price controls of the early 1970's applied to individual product prices,
and this approach tied companies into a pricing straight-jacket that prevented them
from reacting rationally to changing cost and market conditions. In contrast, the
current price standard applies to the average rate of price change across all product
lines of a company. Companies are free to adjust relative prices in response to
changing market conditions so long as they meet the overall deceleration objective.
Third, the standards do not limit dividend payments. These payments, which were
limited during the earlier controls program, help companies attract funds needed
for capital investment.
We intentionally rejected the notion of a differential pay standard for differing
rates of productivity growth at the firm level. In designing and revising the pay
standard, we received outside advice and comments from numerous compensation
experts and labor-relations experts, and these individuals overwhelmingly recommended against such a general productivity-adjustment clause. Their primary concern was that, since productivity is extremely difficult to measure, the existence of a
general adjustment would create a significant loophole, preventing the placement of

99
any effective limitation on pay-rate increases. The experience of the Cost of Living
Council during the controls period bears out this belief.
However, there is a more ,-n-idamental objection to a general productivity-adjustment clause. There is no theoretical, empirical, or ethical.justification for the notion
that wage-rate increases should be directly linked to productivity growth at the firm
level. The disparities between productivity growth rates across industries are not
attributable to differences in the diligence of the workers; rather, they are due to
the fact that there is more potential for productivity-improving innovations in some
industries (for example, manufacturing) than in others (for example, services). Rapid
productivity growth in some industries is primarily the result of the embodiment of
new, more advanced technologies, which can in turn be traced back to general
scientific progress. The productivity growth rate for the economy as a whole determine the rate at which real wages can increase on average, but there is no reason
why the distribution of real-wage increases across industries should correspond to
the distribution of productivity increases across industries. Rather, disparities in
productivity growth rates across industries are reflected in divergent price trends;
price increases are relatively low in high-productivity-growth sectors and relatively
high in low-productivity-growth sectors.
The pay standard does not afford special treatment to firm-level productivity
incentive plans. There are economists who would argue that these plans have any
significant value in increasing aggregate productivity or in prompting individual
workers to work hard. Under these plans, all workers benefit when performance
improves, including those who make no extra effort; thus, these plans provide little
individual incentive. Further, the performance criterion under these plans (for
example, under Scanlon plans) is most often measured in dollars rather than units
of output. Thus, an increase in price is often called a "productivity increase" under
these. plans. The absence of these plans is not a cause of our long-term decline in
productivity, and they should be given no special treatment under the pay standard.
The pay standard has given special treatment to productivity only where it is
clearly and directly measurable and only where it is clearly tied to a demonstrable
improvement in the diligence of the individual workers.
This occurs in two cases:
Pay-rate increses that are traded for work-rule changes that result in demonstrable improvements in productivity are not counted against the 7-percent
standard. This exception applies only to collective-bargaining situations, in
which a company has no alternative means of eliminating outdated work-rule
restrictions other than a buy-out using additional wage-rate increases.
In cases in which an individual's pay is directly linked to physical measures
of his or her own industriousness, such as piece-work pay and sales commissions, the 7-percent standard does not apply to-pay increases related to increased physicial output per hour worked.-_
The Council appreciates your concern about this important matter; we hope our
explanation and suggested course of action will be helpful to you.

toI.

THE 1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE
PRESIDENT
WEDNESDAY, FEBRUARY 28, 1979
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,

Washington, D.C.

The committee met, pursuant to recess, at 10 a.m., in room 1202,
Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Lloyd Bentsen (chairman of
the committee) presiding.
Present: Senators Bentsen and Javits; and Representative Brown.
Also present: Richard F. Kaufman, assistant director-general
counsel; John M. Albertine and Deborah Norelli Matz, professional
staff members; Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; Katie MacArthur, press assistant; and Mark R. Policinski and Stephen J.
Entin, minority professional staff members.
OPENING STATEMENT OF SENATOR BENTSEN, CHAIRMAN

Senator BENTSEN. Gentlemen, this hearing will come to order.

Gentlemen, we are very pleased to have you here this morning.
We will get started, although some members of the committee will
not be here for awhile.,
Governor Snelling, when he was discussing this issue with me
earlier this week, said that he felt that the Governors should have
a chance to express their points of views publicly in hearings
before the Congress, and we are reciprocating. Fortunately, we
already had this hearing planned, but we are delighted to let them
present their side of the issue.
I would like to say that the President, as part of his anti-inflation program, has proposed a rather austere budget. Yet, it would
still result in a $29 billion deficit in fiscal year 1980, if we accomplish what he. has called for. At its 1978 annual meeting, the
National Governors' Association (NGA) called for a balanced Federal budget, and this sentiment was affirmed at the Governors' meeting yesterday, so I assume that our witnesses today will be prepared to recommend additional budget cuts.
I have had some of them say the reason I proposed a curtailment
or cut off in the Federal revenue sharing to States was in response
to the Governors' calling for a balanced budget. That simply is not
the case. I have a long record of voting against revenue sharing; I
opposed it from the very beginning.
Let me also say that our system of Federal intergovernmental
aid has grown at an extraordinary pace in recent years. In 1960,
the Federal Treasury disbursed $7 billion to State and local governments. This figure has soared to $82.9 billion in the fiscal year 1980
(101)

102
budget. Thus, while State and local governments are giving consideration to reducing their local taxes and expenditures, they are
more dependent than ever on the Federal Government. In fact, in
1977, for each dollar of revenue raised by State governments,
States received 46 cents from the Federal Treasury.
What is more, State expenditures, according to the National
Governors' Association data, increased by an astounding 25 percent
between 1977 and 1978, and are expected to increase another 14
percent between 1978 and 1979.
We have some charts attached to my opening statement for
reference on that.
Thus, it appears that the deficit-ridden Federal Government is
assisting States to hold the line on local taxes, while increasing
local expenditures greatly. I realize that these expenditure increases are in part caused by inflationary pressures over which
State officials have little control, but these excessive expenditure
increases are also fueling the national inflation, and though it
might be painful, must be curtailed.
That is why I introduced legislation to prohibit State governments from receiving general revenue sharing (GRS) funds. At this
point in time, no State is projected to incur a budget deficit and, in
fact, according to NGA data, States will realize a $4.3 billion surplus in fiscal year 1979. It simply makes no sense to me for the
Federal Government to be providing $2.3 billion to the State government sector which is in relatively healthy fiscal condition. I
hasten to add that State tax revenue between the years of 1975 and
1978 increased by 42 percent; well outpacing the combination of
inflation and population growth. In fact, between 1977 and 1978,
State governments realized a 14-percent increase in per capita tax
revenue without even counting the revenue from tax-rate increases.
If we are to balance the Federal budget, additional cuts are
essential. You just can't have it both ways. You can't call for a
balanced Federal budget, yet oppose efforts to curtail Federal outlays to State governments.
I realize that many Governors believe that categorical grants
rather than general revenue sharing funds should be cut. However,
I have yet to see a list of which programs and how much should be
trimmed.
In the past, when I have made this comment, I have been referred to a National Governors' Association memorandum to Jim
McIntye. As far as I am concerned, that memorandum offers little
more than platitudes calling for elimination of waste through program consolidations. I am still awaiting, and anxious to review, a
list agreed upon by our Nation's Governors which recommends
actual categorical program cuts.
Instead of a list of cuts, however, the NGA has endorsed the
administration's proposal to provide a new $150 million energy
impact assistance program to assist States suffering from economic
boom.
I am certainly not adverse to cutting categorical grants. Last
year, I voted for over $24 billion in budget cuts. But I do not
believe the choice is whether general revenue sharing or categorical programs should be cut. I think they both ought to be cut. With

103
the pressure on State and local governments to reduce taxes and
pressure on the Federal Government to balance its budget, the
bottom line is that general revenue sharing as well as categorical
grants must be reduced.
I turn to you, our Nation's Governors, for suggestions on which
programs and how much should be cut.
[The charts and the National Governors' Association memorandum referred to in Senator Bentsen's opening statement follow:]

State Government Fiscal Condition
Fiscal Years 1977-1979
DOLLARS INBILLIONS

1977

1978
ESTIMATED

1979

ACTUAL

ESTIMATE
CZ

I Fotal Funds Available
EExpenditure

Surplus

C

\

$88.5

$946

$113.0

$123.0

83.6

92.5

104.1

118.7

4.1

8.9

4.3

4.9

Source: NGA & NASBO Fiscal Survey of the States.

State Government
Expenditures
1977

DOLLARS
IN BILLIONS

PERCENT
CHANGE

$ 83.6

-

State -Own Source
.Tax Revenues
STATE TAX
REVENUE
PER CAPITA
1975

$375.

1975

1978

104.1

25

1979

118.7

14

(Estimate)

ADJUSTED
PER CAPITA
INCREASE'

$3 75.

-

1976

4 15.

8.1

1977

4 66.

10.4

1978

5 32,2

14.2

Source: NGA & NASBO Fiscal Survey of the States.

Federal Expenditures
DOLLARS
IN BILLIONS

PERCENT
CHANGE

1977

$401.9

1978

450.8

12

1979

493.4

9

-

1Adjusted

changes.

for population growth and tax rate
-

For year ending September, 1978.

Sources: Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Relations; Bureau of the Census.

0o

Wn

106
National Governors' Association

National Conference of State Legislatures

November 28, 1978
ME MO R A N D U 1

TO JAMES T. McINTYRE.

JR.

members of the National Governors' Association and the National
Conference of State Legislatures have given careful consideration to the
Review of the federal budget is certain to continue
federal EY 1980 budget.
within our organizations, and our views will be made available to you on a
basis.
continuing
Traditionally, NrA and 3CSL committees have made program by program
spending recommendations without indicating any order of priority. This
document reflects an early attempt to add a new element to our recooenndasuggesting criteria for curbing spending in a way that minimizes
tions:
the adverse effect on state and local governments.
Three points should be made at the outset:
1.

We strongly support the President's determination to restrain
inflation, and we are working closely with the Administration
A
to undertake joint efforts to achieve this objective.
necessary element of the overall strategy to curb inflation
is fiscal prudence in the development of the FY 1980 federal
budget.

2.

We believe that the state-federal programs noted in this report
are of the highest priority. Other key state-federal program
reconmendatlons which have already been made to you (or will
be made shortly) by NGA and NCSL should also receive strong
support in the budget process.

3.

We consider it essential to terminate the myth of a large state
Such a surplus
"surplus" which has been widespread during 1978.
does not exist and should not be permitted to confuse consideration of the EY 1980 budget.

There are a number of issues on which our groups do not have a
document is silent on broad priorities (such as
Where tis
position.
reported Administration proposals to increase defense spending, for
intend to indicate tacit support for these prioritIes.
way
no
we
in
example)
We urge you to ensure that the FT 1980 budget proposed by the
AdinistatIzn incorporates the policy and program racomeendations we have
outlined in this docernt.

HAL Cf fi S-AIfS

"A.

,*Ced Se

CA 2ct%'2±_S"'!

wand,

/ qs'r

cC:=Ool .
'-±s±

107
I.

BALANCED FEDERAL BUDGET

The National Governors' Association and the National Conference of State
Legislatures support the President's efforts to balance the federal budget by
FY 1981.
NGA has emphasized its
support by renewing its
call for a balanced
budget at the 1978 NGA annual meeting.
While NCSL has not taken formal action,
a poll of the NCSL membership taken in February showed that 68 percene of those
responding felt
that the federal budget should be balanced if unemployment did
not rise.
The details of the FY 1980 budget and the proposals which the President will
make to Congress on how to achieve significant reductions in the deficit next year
are of immediate concern to both organizations.
We have convened a joint working
group to consider the issue and have given it considerable thought.
As a result,
we have developed policy and program recommendations which we urge you to incorporate
in the proposals you make to the President.
The extent to which these policies are
reflected in the budget will determine the level of active support which NGA and
NCSL can commit to the President's proposals for achieving a balanced budget.

II.

RECODENDATIONS
A.

Overall Budget Policy
1.

2.

Budeet savings in intergovernmental Programs should be accomDaniid by
increased administrative flexibility for state and local governments.
Program reductions should be accompanied by major administrative
reforms, such as program consolidation, reducing
mandates on
state and local governments, and streamlining procedures and paperwork.
Between 1975 and 1978, the number of separate federal
categorical programs has increased from 442 to 492, and the last
major block grant program was enacted in 1974.
The Administration
should recognize that program consolidation, reduced mandates, and
other administrative reforms are responsive to the public's concerns
about inflation and government inefficiency, duplication, and wastt.
Funding decisions should result in real savings to taxDavers.
Cut-backs in programs administered by state and local governments
cannot be equated with cuts in other sectors of the budget.
A
reduction by the federal government in a program area of exclusive
federal responsibility is virtually certain to result in reduced
government spending.
A cut by the federal government in an
area of joint federal, state and local responsibility--such
as welfare or education-may simply result in the transfer of costs
-from the federal government to state and local governments.
The
effect may be nt\ a reduction in the overall level of government
spending but a transfer of the burden from the federal income tax to
a state sales or income tax or even to the local vroperty tax.
Such
a cut at the federal level is not really anti-inflationary; in fact,
it may be the reverse.

108
Funding reductions in federal programs that are unaccompanied
by administrative reforms are likely to have an adverse impact on
the productivity of state and local government delivery systems,
in effect driving up the per unit cost of services. Therefore,
in considering reductions below current service levels in any
program, the Administration should ensure that the reduction will
result in real economies and will have the least adverse impact on
the recipients of services and on state and local taxpayers.
3.

Fiscal constraints should not delav the development of authorizing
legislation for high priority programs which will have a limited
impact on FY 1980 budget projections. A welfare reform proposal and
a stand-by program of economic assistance to state and local governments
are key examples here. A commitment by the Administration to action in
these two areas are top state priorities.

4.

techniques which preserve
The Administration should use budget-making
the fiscal choices of the states. In general, we will oppose federal
cutbacks which are made by shifting funding responsibilities to state
and local governments through reduced federal matching rates. Appropriation reductions, in spite of the dislocations they cause, maintain
the states' option to reduce their participation in programs proportion-.
ate to the federal reduction, to retain a funding commitment equivalent
to previous years'- funding, or to increase their contributions to the
program:.

5.

Intergovernmental assistance should not bear a disproportionate
share of funding reductions below current services.

6.

The impact of federal policies on state and local government should
be determined before these policies are adopted. The President should
ensure that no legislation or regulation will be supported by the
Administration unless determination has been made of the impact it
will have on state and local government.
The federal government has been criticized for placing unfunded
mandates on state and local governments.
Requirements for specific
tests for safe drinking water, for specific state actions to ensure
air quality, for special education, and for accessibility of programs
and facilities to the handicapped are recent examples of mandates
promulgated without adequate assessment of cost.
Unfunded mandates placed on state and local governments are a
current point of intergovernmental conflict, but they are not the
only issues of major concern between states and the federal government. The relationship of federal programs to existing state and
local efforts is another important recurring question, and so is
the amount of paperwork which the federal government requires of its
grantees.

109
There have been notable attempts at the federal level
to ensure
more careful assessment of the impact of administrative requirements.
Nevertheless, there are two areas where additional improvements could
be made:
a.

OMB Legislative Analvsis Checklist - The Office of Management
and Budget should review its
procedures for analyzing
congressional and agency legislative initiatives to ensure
that a determination is made of the effect legislation would
have on state and local government before Administration support
is extended.
As with the urban impact analyses, the OMB state and local
impact analyses should be brief.
They should cover the following
points:
*

effect of the 'initiative on present and future
costs to state and local government;

*

methods for financing these costs;

*

timetable for implementation;

*

the relationship of the proposed federal initiative
to existing state and local programs and management
practices;

*

the method for ensuring that where overlap, duplication, or a potential conflict exists between the
proposed federal initiative and state programs, adequate
provision is made for coordination between the levels of
government; and

*

the paperwork implications of the administrative requirements of the proposed statute.

Any potential problems which appear during the course of
this analysis should be resolved before Administration support
is recommended for any legislation.
b.

Congressional Cost Analysis - Section 403 of the Congressional
Budget Act of 1974 requires the Congressional Budget Office
to review the cost of implementing any legislation which is
reported by a congressional committee.
This section has been
interpreted by the Congress to require an assessment of the
cost to the federal government; costs to state and local governments are deemed not to be covered by the statute.
In the last
session of Congress, an attempt was made to require C30 to assess
the cost to state and local government as well as to the federal
government.
In light of the demands of citizens that government
spending at all levels be controlled, and in light of the
President's anti-inflation initiatives, the Administration should
support such a rule change.

47-977 0 - 79 - 8

110
7.

Prescriptive federal regulations should be revised to permit
increased flexibility for states and improved targeting
State officials
according to state and locally defined needs.
and others who have studied federal program administration have
found that detailed regulations add significantly to the cost of
running federally funded programs and hamper the targeting of
In general, we support the President's
-funds to local needs.
strategy to reduce prescriptive regulations through executive
reorganization, improvement in federal planning requirements,
and reforms in the joint funding simplification program.
The federal government is now undertaking a variety of
demonstrations under which prescriptive regulations are revised
to allow increased state and local flexibility. These demonstrations
should be expanded to more sites and programs.
Among the demonstration projects we refer to here ate:
* HEW Planning Grants. The Department of Health, Education
and Welfare will be working with five states this year to
determine whether existing state planning and budgeting
systems can be substituted for federal plan requirements.
HEWcurrently requires about 55 annual plans. The
success of this project would mean major paperwork reductions
and better targeting of federal funds to meet state priorities.
* Farmers Home Administration Coordinated Investment Strategy.
FmHA and North Carolina have reached an agreement to work together to implement the state's balanced growth policy.
The agency, which spends some $500 million in North Carolina,
has made a commitment to spend a portion of the funding for
each of its programs in accordance with the state-developed
strategy. FmHA has also promised to work with other federal
agencies to assure their cooperation in funding projects which
have been designated as top priorities by the state.
* HUD Rural Housing and Community Development Initiative.
HUD will be working in two states (Washington and North Carolina)
to simplify forms, provide special technical assistance, and
develop a streamlined decisions process to make it easier for
rural areas to obtain federal housing and community development
aid. The aim of the pilot project is to ensure that the funding
allocated to rural communities in the two states will be used
in accordance with local needs.

8.

The President should make public his Dosition on some of the technical
details of his alan to balance the budget before increased nublic
Among the issues on which a position
pressure limits his choices.
should be developed are how capital expenditures should be budgeted
and what provisions should be made to allow for decisive federal
action during times of economic downturn or rising unemployment.
The President could ensure that these questions are addressed in a
neutral public forum by requesting that they be examined by a Presidentixl
task force.

ill
B.

Program Recommendations
1.

General Revenue Sharine should be reauthorized with little
change. _
For more than a decade, Governors and State Legislators have strongly

supported the concept of General Revenue Sharing. It is viewed as a
centerpiece in the federal-state-local system of shared powers and
responsibilities.
In light of the increased pressure on state and
local budgets, continuation of the current program is of the highest
priority to state elected officials.
Failure to fund the program
would result either in the discontinuation of many state and local
services or the shift of additional burdens to the very taxes which
the nation's taxpayers appear to like least. NGA and NCSL view the
General Revenue Sharing program as an indispensable element of the
federal-state-local partnership. We do not endorse any major changes
in the revenue sharing program.
2.

Welfare reform should be addressed in the President's budget. The
Administration should renew its commitment to welfare reform in the
1980 budget. This commitment could have a much reduced budgetary
impact than that of the original Administration proposal and still
make badly-needed and extensive changes in the existing welfare program.
The programmatic alterations to be made under reform legislation should
be implemented only after adequate lead time for all administering
governments.
In

keeping with recent Administration pledges,

such legislation

should provide interim fiscal relief which precedes implementation
of the programmatic alterations. Therefore, the changes in the
rate of federal matching for the welfare programs should take effect
-in 1980. This would have an approximate additional federal cost of
$21billion. However, most programmatic alterations should be made
effective in federal Fiscal Year 1981, with the result that no additionalprogrammatic costs will be incurred in FY 1980.
NGA and NCSL will pursue legislation modeled on some of the
provisions of the 1978 compromise proposal developed by the New
Coalition.
These components, with an estimated annual cost of
$7-8 billion, include;
*

establishing a national minimum benefit of $4200 for eligible

recipients;
* providing transitional cash assistance in
parent families as they seek work;
*

all states to two-

providing supplemental cash assistance to all working two-

parent families whose incomes do not reach levels where
assistance benefits are provided to families eligible for
welfare;

112
* moving toward greater uniformity of rules and eligibility
standards;
* simplified administration;
* strong assistance to all unemployed or underemployed
recipients able to work in finding suitable employment;
and
* fiscal relief of approximately $2.0 billion to state and
local governments

3.

for welfare expenses.

A Permanent stand-by Program of economic assistance to state and
local governments should be enacted for use during recessions.

Such a program need not involve major budget expenditures in the
If current economic projections are accurate, a
FY 1980 budget.
If
stand-by program should entail only nominal expenditures.
economic conditions deteriorate, however, states.and localities
will need economic assistance to avoid laying off public employees
The Administration
and curtailing services or increasing taxes.
should propose a program of stand-by economic assistance in the
FY 1980 budget.
C.

Recommendations

Improvement,
1.

for Efforts Which Can Produce Savings.

Administrative

and Increased Effectiveness in the Intergovernmental System

The Administration should propose major Drogram consolidations as
Dare of the FY 1980 budget. The National Conference of State Legislatures and the National Governors' Association support extensive
grant consolidation to provide more efficient use of state and federal

The following are
resources and to create administrative savings.
three program consolidation proposals which we urge the Administration
to consider; they are illustrative of the consolidation initiatives
we support.
a.

NGA has developed an economic development
Economic Develooment'block grant proposal which would cover the following programs:
Grants and Loans for Public Works (Title I,

PWEDA)

Business Development Assistance (Title III)
Technical Assistance (Title III)
Public Works Impact Projects (Title IV)
Special Economic Assistance and Economic Adjustment
Emergency Financial Assistance (Title X)
Local Public Works

(Title IX)

Excluding the Local Public Works Program, the categoricals proposed
for consolidation are authorized at a level of 2.5 billion;
Attached is a
appropriations have been about $750 million.
copy of the legislation we have drafted to impLement this block grant.

113
b.

Environmental Program Grants - EPA is developing a proposal which
would allow states to apply for consolidated program grants
specially tailored to their needs. Grants to states for air and
water pollution control, safe drinking water, and solid waste
planning could be included in consolidation proposals submitted

by states.

c.

Airport Development Aid Program (ADAP) - The seven categorical
programs of the ADAP program are candidates for consolidation.
We suggest that the states be given authority to set priorities
and spend funds for all airport construction and improvement
projects except for those affecting the largest airports. These
large facilities would continue to deal directly with the federal
government.

The consolidation plan should create significant savings. A
Federal Aviation Administration study in 1974 compared the cost
of federally funded airport construction projects with projects
funded by other sources and found non-federal projects to be 30
percent cheaper. The added expense is attributed to poor coordination of federal resources with state and local funding and inflationary increases which occur while federal approval is being sought.
In addition, the drop in the number of grantees under the
consolidation plan from over 4,000 to about 100 may create the
possibility of staff reductions in FAA by as many as 40 people.
Using OMDBguidelines (which set the average cost of each federal

position at about $25,000) the administrative savings from staff
reductions-alone would be $1 million.
In addition to the three consolidation grants proposed above,
we support block grants in healkh, enerev conservation, and olanning
programs.
We urge the Administration to consider the block grants we have
identified and to develop additional consolidation proposals.
As a
starting point to this effort, we have attached a list
describing
the consolidations mentioned in the paragraph above and consolidation

proposals made by the Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations
in 1977.
Although some program changes have been made by Congress since
the time the ACIR list
was compiled, particularly in the areas of
vocational rehabilitation, programs for older Americans, and transportation, the list
is still
valid and deserves consideration.
ACIR might
be asked to update it to take into account changes which have occurred.

2.

Hosoital cost containment leeislation should be re-introduced bv
the Administration.
In light of recent efforts to combat inflation,
hospital cost containment should be one of the highest priorities
presented in t-e budget message.
Rapidly rising medical costs have

114
placed a major strain on the federal budget; federal outlays for
health care have grown at an annual rate of 20 percent since 1967.
Hospital costs have been among the major sources of health care
Over the past ten years, total hospital expenditures
cost inflation.
have quadrupled, rising at an annual rate of more than 15 percent-about 2.4 times the average increase in the CPI.
In response to the problem of hospital cost inflation,
which
passed a compromise bill
*

the Senate

established a voluntary hospital cost containment program to be

backed up'by a mandatory system if

the voluntary effort fails;

*

insured that the mandatory program, if triggered, would apply
equitably to all costs and all payers; and

*

assured that the federal program would not preempt ongoing
state cost containment systems.

Estimates indicate that the bill would have saved between $30 and
$35 billion over the next five years, of which $11 to $12 billion would
have been federal savings and $1.5 to $2 billion would have been savings
for state and local governments.
3.

The FY 1980 budget should contain proposals for advance appropriations
As part of his anti-inflation effort, the
of federal program funds.
President should support advance appropriations for major construction

programs. One area where advance appropriation is most needed is in
the $4 billion program for construction of wastewater treatment facilities.
Uncertainty about funding levels delays the lengthy planning and
and these delays result
construction process for treatment facilities,
The FY 1980 budget should
in significant inflationary cost increases.
contain a proposal for advance appropriation of the wastewater treatment
construction grant program.

In addition, the President should renew proposals he made last
year for providing advance appropriations for vocational rehabilitation,
maternal and child health, and programs for the aging.
III.

CONCLUSION

The National Governors' Association and the National Conference of State
Legislatures support the Administration's effort to balance the federal budget.
We have prepared 'the material in this report to alert you in advance to our

major concerns and to the criteria by which we will be measuring your specific
budget proposals.

Attachments

115
ATTACLMENT:

1.

OPTIONS FOR GRANTCONSOLIDATION

Health
At the time the "Federal Assistance for Health Care" block grant
was introduced, some state officials expressed interest in
the consolidation if medicaid were excluded. The other programs
that were included in the proposal were:

Community Health Centers

Maternal and Child Health

Alcohol Project and
State Formula Grants

Family Planning

Veneral Disease

Migrant Health

Immunization

Emergency Medical Services

Rat Control

Health Planning

Lead Paint Poisoning
Prevention

Medical Facilities Construction

Community Health Centers

Developmental Disabilities

State Health Grants (314d)
These fifteen programs, which have a combined budget authority level of about $2
billion, are potential candidates for consolidation.
ACIR has suggested that a similar, but not identical list of health programs be
consolidated. Categoricals on the ACIR list which were not included in earlier
presidential proposals are:
Narcotic Addiction, Drug
Abuse and Drug Dependency
Prevention and Rehabilitation: Drug Abuse
Education

Communicable and Other Disease
Programs: Other Diseases

Communicable and Other
Disease Programs:
Tuberculosis

Drug Abuse Prevention and Treatment: Basic Grants

Communicable and Other
Disease Programs:
Measles Control
Obligations for these programs in FT 1977 were about $84 million.

116
2. Energy Conservation: State Energy Management Program
The Department of Energy has developed a consolidation proposal for
The proposal would fold tothe core energy conservation programs.
gether the following programs:
State Energy Conservation Programs (EPCA)
Supplemental Program (ECPA)
Energy Extension Service
The proposed authorization for the program is $105 million, approximately
$30 million below the authorization level of the three programs. States
have opposed the $105 million figure because it is lower than current
authorizations and because new responsibilities (including data collection
and capacity building) would be required of consolidated grant recipients.
The program provides that two years after the grants are consolidated states
may submit requests to consolidate additionalenergy programs which are
either in existence at the time the block grant goes into effect or are
created by future legislation.
3.

Planning/Capacity Building

Duplicative, overlapping planning requirements have been the subject
One block grant option is to create a
of increasing criticism.
package of planning aid out of programs like the following:
Comprehensive Planning and Management Assistance (Sec. 701)
State Economic Development Planning (Sec. 302)
Substate Economic Development District Planning
Rural Development Planning (Sec. 111)
Intergovernmental Personnel Act
State Science, Engineering and Technology
4.

ACIR Consolidation Recommendations

The following list was compiled by the Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations in 1977. Although some program changes have
been made by Congress since the list was put together, particularly
in the areas of vocational rehabilitation, programs for older Americans,
and transportation, the list is still
a valuable resource.
In addition to the health bock grant mentioned earlier, ACIR has
recommended that the following categorical programs be consolidated
into block grants:
CFunding levels provided are FY 1977 obligations)

I

117
a)

b)

Child Nutrition and School Meals:

$2.8 billion

Child Nutrition Programs:
Conodity Distribution Differential
Payments

Child Nutrition Programs: Special
Assistance for Free and Reduced
Price Lunches

Child Nutrition Programs:
Assistance

Non-food

Child Nutrition Programs: Special
Food Service for Children in Service
Institutions

Child Nutrition Programs:
Breakfast Program

School

Child Nutrition Programs:
Lunch Food Assistance

School

Vocational Rehabilitation:

Child Nutrition Programs:
Milk Program

Special

Child Nutrition Programs:
Administrative Expenses

State

$769 million

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Special
Federal Responsibilities:
Rehabilitation Facilities Construction
Grants

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Special
Federal Responsibilit
: Training
Services for the Handicapped

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Special
Federal Responsibilities: Initial.
Staffing Grants

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Vocational
Rehabilitation Services: Basic Grants
to States

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Special
Federal Responsibilities: Facilities
Planning Grants

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Vocational
Rehabilitation Services: Innovation
and Expansion Grants

Vocational Rehabilitation and Other
Rehabilitation Services: Special
Federal Responsibilities: Facility
Improvement Grants
c)

Proerams for Older Americans :

$351 million

-

Older American Programs: Area
Planning and Social Services

Older American Programs:
Program

Older American Programs:
Projects
-

Older American Programs: Planning,
Coordination, Evaluation, and

Model

~~~~~~~Administration

Nutrition

118
d)

Child Welfare Services:

$83 million

Child Abuse and Neglect Prevention
and Treatment: Assistance to
States for Developing, Strengthening
and Conducting Programs
e)

Domestic Volunteer Services:

$57 milli.on

Domestic Volunteer Services:
Grandparents Program

Foster

Child Welfare Services:

Basic Grants

Developing Local Facilities for
Runaway Youth

Domestic Volunteer Services:
Health Aides

Senior

Domestic Volunteer Services:
Retired Senior Volunteer Programs
(RSVP)
f)

Forest Lands Management:

$33 million

Assistance to States for Tree
Planting and Reforestation

Cooperative Production and Distribution
of Tree Planting Stock

Cooperative Forest Fire Control

Promott g Research in Forestry

Cooperative Forest Insect and
Disease Control
g)

h)

Highway Beautification:

Funding Level N/A

Highway Beautification:
of Junkyards

Control

Highway Beautification:
of Outdoor Advertising

Control

Transoortation Safetv:
Highway Safety:

*,

Highway Beautification:
and Scenic Enhancement

Landscaping

Funding Level N/A
Highway Safety: Projects for High
Hazard Locations

Basic Grants

Highway Saf ety: Eliminating
Railroad Crossing Hazards

>

Highway Safety: Incentive Grants:
Reduced Traffic Fatalities
Highway Safety: Elimination of
Roadside Obstacles
Highway Safety: Incentive Grants:
Seatbel: Law

Highway Safety:
Replacement

Special Bridge

Motor Vehicle Diagnostic
Inspection Demonstrations

119
i)

Comprehensive Urban Transportation:

Funding Level N/A

Highways: Federal Aid Primary and
Secondary Extensions Within Urban
Areas

Urban Mass Trasnportation Basic Grants

Federal Aid Urban Systems

Urban Mass Transportation Grants For
Managerial Training

Carpool Demonstration Proj ects in
Urban Areas
Special Urban High Density Traffic
Program
Transportation Planning in Urban
Areas

Urban Mass Transportation:
Technical Studies

Grants for

Urban Mass Transportation:
and Equipment

Facilities-

Urban Area Traffic Operations
Improvement
j)

Comorehensive State Transportation:

Funding Level N/A

Education and Training Programs for

Highway Personnel
Highways:

Interstate System

Highways:

Priority Pr-imary Routes

Highways: Federal Aid Primary
System in Rural Areas

Highways:

Public Land Highways

Highways: Federal Aid Secondary
System in Rural Areas

Surveys, Research, Planning and
Development for Highways

Highways:
k)

Emergency Relief

Highways:

Forest Highways

Water Pollution Prevention and Control:

Funding Level N/A

Safety of Public Water Systems; Special
Studies and Demonstration Programs

Water Pollution Prevention and Control:
Pollution Control Programs

Solid Waste Disposal:
State, Interstate and Local planning

Water Pollution Prevention and Control:
Waste Treatment Works Construction

Water Pollution Prevention and Control:
Areawide Waste Treatment Management and
Planning Grants

Preparation of Plans for Rural Water
and Waste Disposal

Water Pollution Prevention and Control:
Planning Agency Adainistrative Expenses

120
1)

Public Library Aid:

Funding Level N/A

Public Library Programs:
Construct ion
Public Library Programs:
Library Cooperation

Inter-

Public Library Programs:
Services

Library

Strengthening Instruction in Science,
Math, Languages, and Other Critical
Subjects: Expansion and Improvement
of Supervisory Services and Administration
School Library Resources and Textbooks

Strengthening Instruction in
Science, Math, Languages, and Other
Critical Subjects: Equipment and
Minor Remodeling
m)

State Education Assistance:

Funding L4evel N/A

Vocational Education:
Romemaking Education

Consumer and

Vocational Education: Exemplary
Programs: Basic Grants

Vocational Education:
Programs

Cooperative

Vocational Education: Special
Programs for the Disadvantaged

Vocational Education:
Development

Curriculum

Vocational Education:
Councils

Vocational Education: Research
and Training: Basic Grants
Vocational Education:
Programs

Work-study

State Advisory

Vocational Education: State
Vocational Education Programs

121
Senator BENTSEN. We have three very able and eloquent Governors before us this morning, and I am delighted to now turn the
testimony over to Governor Thompson.
STATEMENT OF HON. JAMES R. THOMPSON, GOVERNOR, STATE
OF ILLINOIS
Governor THOMPSON. Thank you,.Mr. Chairman. I wonder if I
might, at the outset, respond just for a moment to the concerns you
have expressed, because I think they are not only relevant, but
pointed.
I speak now just for myself as Governor of the State of Illinois,
and I will attempt to illustrate how we in Illinois, for the last 2
years during my administration, have been trying to do just what
you would have us do, and why it is important to us that at least
for the moment Federal revenue sharing be kept. I will limit these
introductory remarks to just that one subject.
When I became the Governor in January of 1977, we forecast
that a yearend balance in our general revenue fund, our bank
accounts, our surplus, would be just $52 million. That had to be one
of the lowest, if not the lowest, surpluses in any State in the
Nation. It had been spent down from half a billion to $52 million,
so I inherited a State that was literally on the edge of bankruptcy.
By holding my requests for spending increases in the next full
fiscal year to an average of one-third the size of those over the past
decade, we were able to improve the surplus position of the State
and avoid cash flow problems. I did not want to say Illinois was a
deadbeat when it came to paying bills of citizens for services and
goods. I have held to ,that budget line each year, and my budget
submission for next year will be for spending less than the growth
of inflation in this coming fiscal year.
If all goes well with our spending plans this year, and we enter
no recessionary mode that drives up the cost of public aid and
related medicaid spending and drives down tax revenues, we will
end this fiscal year with a surplus of $136 million. I don't intend to
let it go beyond that. Even that surplus was fueled in significant
part by the receipt this year of one-time entitlement revenues that
won't be repeated in the next fiscal year.
This year, Illinois will receive about $115 million of general.
revenue sharing funds. If that $115 million were to be subtracted
from the $136 million in surplus that we will have at the end of
the year, we would be worse off than when I began our careful
budgeting program 2 years ago and we would be near bankruptcy.
We are bringing down the growth of capital spending in Illinois.
We are being very conservative. But it is not correct to include
Illinois as one of those States that has massive surpluses. Although
there are hues and cries all over the State for tax relief, we simply
cannot afford it, and I refuse to promise people something as
illusory as tax relief, when there is no revenue to support it.
I might begin by saying that in the interest of the committee's
time and in the interest of my two fellow Governors, I have shortened my prepared statement, which is available to the committee,
as is this analysis of the President's budget prepared by the National Governors' Association which I will submit for the record.

122
In my view, this committee has an important role to play in this
most critical year, for this committee-alone in this Congress-has
the mandate to take the broadest possible view of the Federal
budget for what it is: The economic and programmatic game plan
for how this nation intends to conduct the business of the people
next year.
I'm sure I speak for most Governors in expressing the hope that
you will use that mandate to encourage other committees to look
beyond the nuts and bolts of this document and focus on the
premises on which it is based-and in particular on how it views
the Federal-State-local service delivery system.
To judge by the tone and content of the meeting of the Nation's
Governors over the past 3 &ays, we will not be beating on your
doors this year to plead poverty. But we will be pleading for
rationality in Federal policy.
Whether you as Senators and Congressmen, or I as a Governor,
like it or not, Federal aid is, in fact, the lifeblood of the FederalState-local system. When you cut, we bleed. If you cut crudely, we
bleed badly. But if the incision is clean-and sewn up properly-we
can survive.
Also whether we like it or not, we-the States and their localities-are junior partners in the Federal system. And we are concerned that our senior partner is not providing the leadership, or
the wherewithal, or the freedom-and that's most important to
us-to show our stuff, to prove that we can carry out our role
effectively for the greater good of the firm.
The state of the Union may well be basically sound, as the
President has suggested. But the state of the States is nervous.
Mr. Chairman, when we met with the President late last year to
talk about the preparation of the budget, he told us that we were
the only group that had come to see him that day, and perhaps
even that week, maybe even that year, that was not asking for
more, that in fact said we will take a little less if we can get some
programmatic improvements that will allow us to survive the cutting of our funds somewhat. He was most grateful for our attitude.
I would like to repeat that for the committee today, and the
Congress. We are not saying, "Give us more." We are not saying,
"Don't cut us." What we are saying is that there are some tradeoffs
that Congress can make, that make programmatic sense, which I
will try to demonstrate in a minute.
To this end, there are five giant steps that Congress could takeand we believe should take now. Their enactment would at once
improve services to people, help stop the inflationary trend in
Government spending at all levels, and bolster the private sector
economy.
None of these suggestions is based on bold, new ideas. But all of
them are long overdue. And if ever the time was right for the
Congress to take a new look at them-and to act-it is now, in this
era of the taxpayer revolt.
I apologize for a litany that has been offered too often in the
halls of this building, and will be forever more on behalf of Governors. We deeply believe in it.
First, consolidate more Federal-State-local categorical programs
into single-purpose block grants.

123
Time and again, Governors, mayors, the Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations and others have put forward laundry
lists of proposed consolidations for programs embracing every facet
of governmental activity-in health, transportation, planning,
social services, vocational rehabilitation, jobs, water and air pollution control, and more.
Not only have we been turned down, we've seen no fewer than 50
more narrow categorical programs added in the last 3 years alone.
Governors and mayors now have 492 different sources of Federal
funding among which to window shop-and sometimes get lostwhen we come to Washington for help.
When Governors and mayors besiege the Congress for yet more
categorical grant programs, it isn't because we like the system. It's
because we're realists. If that's the only way we can get Washington's ear, that's the way we'll ask for Washington's help.
Meanwhile, back home, Governors try to practice what they
preach in Washington. Two-thirds of all State budget expenditures
are for locally oriented functions. And in the last 12 years, the
proportion of State-generated funds given out to localities in the
form of general-purpose block grants has risen by almost 50 percent. It would no doubt be much higher if we didn't have to tie up
so-many State dollars in Federal redtape before sending them on
their way to meeting people's needs at the local level.
To consolidate Federal categorical grants would be to shift power
away from the unelected bureaucracy and toward elected officials
at all levels of government-including the Congress. And I don't
say that in any perjorative sense, because most of my time in
public service, now exceeding almost 20 years, has been in appointed positions.
To continue to go the other way-as we have been in recent
decades-would be to perpetuate the myth that Washington has a
monopoly on integrity, expertise, and concern for the problems
that Governors and mayors must grapple with every day. And it
would be to say that Governors and mayors don't have priorities,
don't have commonsense, and aren't in touch with the concerns
and needs of their people.
The cost of general revenue sharing has risen at an average
annual rate of only 3 percent since the program began, while
categorical grant spending has jumped nearly 15 percent annually
over that same time. If nothing else, these figures demonstrate the
power of special interests-and the inability of the 300 committees
and subcommittees of this Congress to say no to them.
There's something wrong with a system that supports so many
lobbyists in Washington that there is a need for an association of
associations and a market for a newsletter on newsletters.
If Congress is to control spending, it's obvious that it must at
least simplify the ways public dollars are spent. General revenue
sharing has proven that point, and shown the way Congress should
be going.
To argue,. as many do, that not all States and localities need
their fare share of general revenue sharing funds is to miss the
point of the program-and to miss the point of the argument over
categorical grant funding. Revenue sharing funds are the only
Federal moneys States and cities can use as they see fit-in ways

124
they deem appropriate-to meet needs they identify, which can
shift from year to year. It can be education one year, it can be the
cries of abused and neglected children next year. It can be relief
for the elderly the third year. Revenue sharing gives the States the
flexibility they need to meet programmatic priorities that they find
whether it is in a prison system in revolt, or the need to do more
for those who cannot help themselves, like children and the aged.
For example, consider the priorities of the 16 States represented
on this committee which together receive about half of the $2.28
billion in general revenue sharing funds going directly to State
governments.
Nine of your States have decided to pass all or a large part of
these funds directly on to local governments. The other seven use
most of these funds to offset State costs in such areas as transportation, education, capital spending, and similar programs which
directly or indirectly benefit local governments. Nationally, at least
40 percent of the States' share of these funds are passed through to
the local level.
Thus to cut the State share of revenue sharing would have a
direct local impact in virtually every State-or result in pressures
for increased State taxes to make up the difference.
Our second proposal, which complements the first, is to give
States and localities more latitude to do things their way under
existing Federal categorical grant programs.
The Federal Register last year brought us over 61,000 pages of
new rules-more than 90 million words telling State and local
government and private service providers and businesses precisely
what they can and cannot do.
You have heard time and again of the havoc these words can
create-and you will keep hearing it until there's no reason for
Washington to print the equivalent of a daily Bible.
Time and again, States and cities have demonstrated to Washington that they can have a better idea. In Illinois, for example, we've
started a "no frills" job program that we expect will place welfare
recipients in private sector jobs at a much higher rate than any
federally inspired-and profusely regulated-program.
We seldom get Federal help for such projects-and we rarely
seem to get Federal attention to the better ideas we prove workable. In this demonstration project, we're showing that our caseworkers don't need a 4-foot shelf of rules and rubrics to get someone off the rolls and into the economy. They need a will to work at
it-and time to do it right. They don't need to squander that time
on Federal formalities.
In my view, Washington's role should be to set broad national
goals and general policies designed to meet them. Our role should
be to work within'those policies to fashion the ways and means of
programs best suited to the particular needs of our people.
Our third suggestion is for the administration and the Congress
to give States a more direct role in coordinating programs and
funds now flowing directly to our cities and towns from Washington.
A major disappointment in this budget is the lack of a cohesive
urban policy in general-and of a new mechanism for State involvement in urban policy in particular.

125
The Governors had high hopes last year that Washington was
going to get more serious about putting some sense into programs
affecting our cities and towns. We still have hopes that Congress
will see the need for such a 'thrust and meet it in the coming year.
Local governments are, after all, creatures of their States, and I
don't say that in the 19th century way in which perhaps that
phrase is thought. We have gone beyond the old common law rules
that municipalities are creatures of the State and serve at will of
the State government. The balance of power has shifted much in
the last 100 years. Philosophies of home rule and metropolitan
government have chipped away at the old notions that cities don't
count for anything without the say so of the State, but there are
programmatic reasons why the Congress should reexamine programs through which significant Federal funds flow to municipal
forms of government without significant State input.
Economies don't end at city borders. Roads don't end at city
borders. There is a massive movement of people between cities and
suburbs and rural areas. Industries cut across lines. Tax structures
of municipalities are dependent on State law so the relationship is
still significant, even if it has lost many of its 19th century vestiges. And yet Washington likes to leapfrog State capitals and deal
directly with local governments-even with neighborhoods. Governors have little or nothing to say-and therefore can't dovetail
State programs with Federal activities-in crucial program areas
like economic development, community development, and jobs programs.
We're not asking for the power of the purse. We are asking for
the power of preview and persuasion-to give States a coordinating
role in what's going on within their own borders.
Our fourth suggestion speaks for itself: Washington should be
forced by law to weigh the fiscal impact of.its actions on States and
local governments and the private sector.
Here, I am talking about a philosophy that goes between the
fiscal note process we have in some of our States, including Illinois,
and a rule that the Congress fund mandated programs fully. I am
not quite sure what the acceptable mechanism is. I know the
Congress will want to weigh this kind of suggestion very carefully,
because of the magnitude. What I am speaking mostly toward is a
philosophy that stems the Congress. I confess we have been guilty
of this on the State level for many years towards our local units of
governments, setting into being broad new social programs-entirely worthy social programs, ones that no fair person would quarrel
with-access to public facilities by the handicapped, for examplewithout Oany idea on anybody's part-Congress, the administration,
the State and local governments or the taxpayers-as to how much
it will cost and who is going to bear the financial burden. Now we
find ourselves with mandated programs not only in those areas,
but others. We are very uneasy. In fact, we are more than uneasy
about our ability and the ability of the Federal Government to pay
the costs of funding those programs as quickly as the law suggests
they should be implemented.
Government at all levels is already devouring two-fifths of this
Nation's income and employing 1 in 5 of its work force. It's also
47-977 0 - 79 - 9

126
placing a sometimes necessary-but too often frivolous-array of
burdens on the private service and business sectors.
Commonsense suggests, for example, that we don't need every
one of the 2,100 reporting regulations the General Accounting
Office has found imposed on businesses. Commonsense suggests
that hospital administrators are right in questioning why more
than 100 Federal, State, and local regulatory agencies may be
looking over their shoulders at any time. Commonsense suggests
that we're demanding too much of an Illinois businessman if he
has to be put through 6 months to 1 year of bureaucratic hoops
before he can certify his product as eligible for bidding on a Government procurement contract. And commonsense suggests that
the State of Illinois should not have to send every one of the 100
State plans to Washington to spell out what it's doing for children
and families.
Before a law is enacted, or a rule is written that will mandate'
someone, somewhere to do something, someone in Washington
should be forced to demonstrate that the real cost, the ultimate
cost, balances with the real benefit. When something must be done
as a matter of public policy-like cleaning up our water and air or
opening access to facilities and services for the handicapped-no
one will argue the merits of the goal. Where there is room for
argument is in how the goal is to be reached, when it must be
reached-and who is to bear the cost.
These arguments should be settled up front, before the statute or
rule becomes the law of the land.
Finally, our fifth suggestion, which also speaks for itself. Pass
"sunset' legislation to force periodic hard looks-and hard
choices-the same hard choices you spoke of in your opening statement, Mr. Chairman, on laws and rules already on the books.
We think this is an idea whose time has long since come. More
and more States are doing it-we hope to enact it in Illinois this
year-and the Congress came close to accepting it last year.
Over the past half-century, we've seen variations on the zerobased budgeting theme come and go. None has made an impact, for
none has had the help that Congress could give, were it to force the
bureaucracy-and itself-to occasionally rethink what seemed to
be good ideas at the time they became Federal policy.
We're confident that a "'sunset" policy would ultimately lead the
national administration to accept the Governors' arguments for a
more effective State role in a more productive Federal-State
system.
The Nation's Governors will, of course, be talking with other
committees of this Congress, and with their own delegations in the
months to come, about the line-by-line concerns we have with this
budget proposal. And we have many such concerns, in addition to
the broad issues I have outlined here.
I suppose the last point I would like to leave the committee with
is to please remember that States are not only partners with the
Federal Government, but are the original sources of the powers of
both the Federal Government and local governments. Sometimes
we are made to feel like we are foreign nations, and not the
founding source power in this Nation, on the dole instead of asking
for rationality of programs which return not the Federal Govern-

127

ment's dollars or our dollars, but our citizens' dollars to them in
the form of services.
I have a very fundamental belief in the commonsenee of the
citizens of the United States. Even with all the current clamor over
balanced budgets and constitutional amendments and constitutional conventions, I suspect that our citizens share a deep-seated
knowledge that won't be easily overturned about what they get in
return for their taxpayers' dollars.
We had an election in Chicago yesterday that, in the end, turned
more on the delivery of services to people than it did on any
clamor currently in vogue as it may be for tax cuts. That is an
interesting thing to reflect upon.
The Governors in conference this week, despite great pressures,
not only rejected a call for a constitutional convention, but rejected
any resolutions that would have proposed a constitutional amendment to force Congress to balance the budget. Despite our occasional harsh rhetoric, especially when we all get together, we retain a
deep-seated belief in the wisdom and the ability of this Congress to
set its priorities and to make the hard choices that we have to
make on the State level every day, and to legislate the balanced
budget through the process which brings you here as our representatives.

I think if we approach it in that spirit and if the Congress will
give a genuine look at the concerns I have expressed this morning,
we can be more effective partners with you. We can help you and
the President get that budget down, and we can achieve a balance
between what people pay for in terms of 'taxes, and what they
receive in the form of services, to leave them with a decent feeling
toward Government and its elected representatives. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much. I agree with much of
what you have said, and appreciate your statement. I, too, feel that
Benjamin Franklin and Thomas Jefferson did a pretty good job on
the Constitution, a constitutional convention would have every interest group in the country trying to rewrite the Constitution. Our
Constitution has brought us to this point very effectively and I
believe the present system works very well.
[The prepared statement of Governor Thompson and the analysis
of the President's budget prepared by the National Governors'
Association follow:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HON. JAMES R. THOMPSON

This Committee-alone in this Congress-has the mandate to take the broadest
possible view of the Federal budget for what it is: the economic and programmatic
game plan for how this Nation intends to conduct the business of the people next
year.
I'm sure I speak for most Governors in expressing the hope that you will use that
mandate to encourage other Committees to look beyond the nuts and bolts of this
document and focus on the premises on which it is based-and in particular on how
it views the Federal-State-local service delivery system.
To save time-and to spare you a litany of complaints and caveats that I and
other Governors have with individual items in this budget proposal-I will limit my
remarks to the most general of our concerns. And I will offer some specific suggestions from the Nation's governors for actions the Congress might consider to meet
those concerns.

128
For the record, I offer a detailed analysis of the budget prepared by the NGA
which I believe will be helpful to Members of the Joint Economic Committee in
understanding the States' point of view.
To judge by the tone and content of the meeting of the Nation's governors over
the past three days, we will not be beating on your doors this year to plead poverty.
But we will be pleading for rationality in Federal policy.
Whether you as Senators and Congressmen or I as a Governor like it or not,
Federal aid is, in fact, the lifeblood of the Federal-State-local system. When you cut,
we bleed. If you cut crudely, we bleed badly. But if the incision is clean-and sewn
up properly-we can survive.
Also whether we like it or not, we-the States and their localities-are junior
partners in the Federal system. And we are concerned that our senior partner is not
providing the leadership, or the wherewithal, or the freedom-and that's most
important to us-to show our stuff, to prove that we can carry out our role
effectively for the greater good of the firm.
The State of the Union may well be basically sound, as the President has suggested. But the State of the States is nervous.
We are on the front lines of the tax-and-spending cut battle. Governors and
mayors are the first targets of the.general malaise our people are feeling toward
government at all levels-because we're closest to home.
In State after State-and Illinois is one of them-the people are demanding that
more be done with less, that taxes and spending be stabilized or cut, that government stop promising more than it can deliver, and that it deliver what it promises.
Next week, I will be presenting my administration's proposed budget for what will
be-if the General Assembly makes it so-a watershed year in the history of Illinois
State and local government.
We will not only balance our budget for the third year in a row, we will also be
grappling with the question of how to clamp a ceiling on taxes and spending at the
State and local level.
This will not be easy-as Members of this Committee well know. No one in the
world is against balancing income with outgo and controlling spending in principle.
But no two will agree on precisely how to put that principle into practice.
Part of the problem for us in Illinois-and for every other State and local
government in this Nation-is related to the fact that nearly a quarter of our
spending, and much more than a quarter of the laws and rules that govern all of
our spending, flow from Washington.
Thus if we are to have true reforms and efficiencies in government programs back
home, we have to look for reforms in Washington to trickle down to us before we
can make much more sense of the dollars we spend to meet people's needs.
I was one of a delegation of Governors who met with the President last December
to press this point.
We said the States are ready and willing to help the national administration and
the Congress cut deficit spending and cure some of the ills of the Federal-State-local
system that lead to waste and contribute to inflation. But to do our part, we said,
Washington must give the States a stronger role in the Federal system.
We offered several suggested steps to this end, which I will elaborate on in a few
moments. Among these steps:
Consolidate scores of categorical aid programs into block grants;
Give States a central role in major grant programs now sending funds directly to
local governments; and,
Ease the timetables on some of the monstrously expensive mandates that Washington has imposed on States and their localities.
No one of these steps is being taken, and no one of these issues is addressed to
any meaningful degree in the budget proposal now before Congress. The President
has said, again, that his administration will consider some consolidations, some
reduction in red tape and some review of Federal mandates. But not this year. In
effect, States and local governments are being told-in this document-that the
administration expects us to do the people's business as usual, but with less help
from our senior partner.
To add insult to injury, some officials of the administration and some Members of
the Congress are pointing to State and local governments as primary causes, rather
than victims, of what ails the Federal-State-local system.
We are told, for example, that we can survive major cuts in Federal aid because
the 50 States are running a cumulative budget surplus of $4.3 billion this year.
That argument is nonsense. It ignores the fact that States are constitutionally
bound to balance their budgets. It ignores the fact that the combined surplus is only

129
3.6 per cent of all State spending. It ignores the fact that more than half of it is
sitting in the treasuries of three States-California, Texas and Alaska.
It also ignores the fact that the 50 States have long term capital debts of nearly
$90 billion, that they have unfunded pension liabilities of as much as $175 billion,
and that they owe $5.4 billion to the Federal unemployment compenstaion trust
fund.
In Illinois-with total appropriations of more than $11 billion-our "surplus" will
be only $136 million, or just over one per cent this year.
For cash flow purposes alone, an operating surplus of one per cent is less than a
corner grocery store would need in the till every morning to make change for its
customers. For emergencies, there should be more.
No government should be run on a basis that generates massive surplus revenues.
A government that does is taxing too much, and should put that cash back in the
people's pockets-or, better still, not take it out in the first place. But no State
government can run responsibly without some extra cash in the till. We can't print
it-any more than we can foresee what crisis it may be needed for.
We are also being blamed in some quarters for the failure of social services
programs in general-and for the failure of delivery systems to make sense in
particular.
We will, of course, accept our fair share of the blame. But to a very large degree,
we are what Washington makes us when it comes to delivering services to the
people.
If Washington says it has 492 categorical ways to help-as it now does-States
and localities have to organize 492 ways to get their fair share. That's one big
reason why our workforces have grown-and the primary reason why we have to
send people in need from pillar to post to get help.
When States try to reorganize-as my administration has been moving to do over
the past two years-we run time and again into solid walls built of minutiae by the
Federal bureaucracy dictating the who, what, where, and when and how of human
service programs and spending.
One example from our experience in Illinois. Last year, Members of the Senate
Budget Committee suggested that we develop a block grant proposal to show how h
State like Illinois would organize services for children-if it had a free hand to use
Federal funds and its own matching funds any way it saw fit.
In the process of drawing up this proposal-which is proving vastly more difficult
than we imagined-we'refinding some startling symptoms of what's wrong with the
Federal-State-local system.
For example, eleven of our agencies find they must draw Federal funds from a
total of 171 distinct sources, all aimed at some distinct target population among
children and families in Illinois.
To apply for and keep track of those funds, these agencies have to pay more than
1,000 employees nearly $20 million each year to write more than 100 separate
"State plans" to tell Washington how they intend to spend not only the Federal aid,
but also State money used to match it.
Any taxpayer could suggest far more productive ways for us to use the time and
talents-and the salaries-of those employees.
Which brings us to the heart of the question before this Committee and this
Congress.
Most of the Nation's Governors, as I noted earlier, are more concerned this year
with the quality of the Federal-State relationship than with the quantity of Federal
funds flowing into their States and localities.
We told the President-and we'll repeat it to the Congress: We want to help curb
spending and improve government services. But we can't be expected to survive
massive cuts in the flow of Federal funds into our programs until and unless
Washington acts to restore the States to their rightful places as full and effective
partners in the Federal system.
To this end, there are five giant steps the Congress could take-and we believe
should take now. Their enactment would at once improve services to people, help
stop the inflationary trend in government spending at all levels, and bolster the
private sector economy.
None of these suggestions is based on bold, new ideas. But all of them are long
overdue. And if ever the time was right for the Congress to take a new look at
them-and to act-it is now, in this era of the taxpayer revolt.
First, consolidate more Federal-State-local categorical programs into single-purpose block grants.
Time and again, Governors, Mayors, and Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations and others have put forward laundry lists of proposed consolida-

130
tions for programs embracing every facet of governmental activity-in health,
transportation, planning, social services, vocational rehabilitation, jobs, water and
air pollution control, and more.
Not only have we been turned down, we've seen no fewer than 50 more narrow
categorical programs added in the last three years alone. Governors and Mayors
now have 492 different sources of Federal funding among which to window-shopand sometimes get lost-when we come to Washington for help.
When Governors and Mayors besiege the Congress for yet more categorical grant
programs, it isn't because we like the system. It's because we're realists. If that's the
only way we can get Washington's ear, that's the way we'll ask for Washington's
help.
Back home, Governors try to practice what they preach in Washington. Twothirds of all State budget expenditures are for locally oriented functions. And in the
last twelve years, the proportion of State-generated funds given out to localities in
the form of general-purpose block grants has risen by almost 50 per cent. It would
no doubt be much higher if we didn't have to tie up so many State dollars in
Federal red tape before sending them on their way to meeting people's needs at the
local level.
To consolidate Federal categorical grants would be to shift power away from the
unelected bureaucracy and toward elected officials at all levels of governmentincluding the Congress.
To continue to go the other way-and we have been in recent decades-would be
to perpetuate the myth that Washington has a monopoly on integrity, expertise and
concern for the problems that Governors and Mayors must grapple with every day.
And it would be to say that Governors and Mayors don't have priorities, don't have
common sense, and aren't in touch with the concerns and needs of their people.
The cost of General Revenue Sharing has risen at an average annual rate of only
3 per cent since the program began, while categorical grant spending has jumped
nearly 15 per cent annually over that same time. If nothing else, these figures
demonstrate the power of special interests-and the inability of the 300 committees
and subcommittees of this Congress to say no to them.
There's something wrong with a system that supports so many lobbyists in Washington that there's a need for an association of associations and a market for a
newsletter on newsletters.
If Congress is to control spending, it's obvious that it must simplify the ways.
public dollars are spent. General Revenue Sharing has proven that point, and
shown the way Congress should be going.
To argue, as many do, that not all States and localities need their fair share of
General Revenue Sharing funds is to miss the point of the program-and to miss
the point of the argument over categorical grant funding. Revenue sharing funds
are the only Federal monies States and cities can use as they see fit-in ways they
deem appropriate-to meet needs they identify.
For example, consider the priorities of the 16 States represented on this Committee which together receive about half of the $2.28 billion in General Revenue
Sharing funds going directly to State governments.
Nine of your States have decided to pass all or a large part of these funds directly
on to local governments. The other seven use most of these funds to offset State
costs in such areas as transportation, education, capital spending and similar programs which directly or indirectly benefit local governments. Nationally, at least 40
percent of the States' share of these funds are passed through to the local level.
Thus to cut the State share of revenue sharing would have a direct local impact
in virtually every State-or result in pressures for increased State taxes to make up
the difference.
Our second proposal, which complements the first, is to give States and localities
more latitude to do things their way under existing Federal categorical grant
programs.
The Federal Register last year brought us over 61,000 pages of new rules-more
than 90 million words telling State and local government and private service providers and businesses precisely what they can and cannot do.
You have heard time and again of the havoc these words can create-and you will
keep hearing it until there's no reason for Washington to print the equivalent of a
daily Bible.
Time and again States and cities have demonstrated to Washington that they can
have a better idea. In Illinois, for example, we've started a "no frills" job program
that we expect will place welfare recipients in private sector jobs at a much higher
rate than any Federally-inspired-and profusely regulated-program.

131
We seldom get Federal help for such projects-and we rarely seem to get Federal
attention to the better ideas we prove workable. In this demonstration project, we're
showing that our caseworkers don't need a four-foot shelf of rules and rubrics to get
someone off the rolls and into the economy. They need a will to work at it-and
time to do it right. They don't need to squander that time on Federal formalities.
Washington's role should be to set broad national goals and general policies
designed to meet them. Our role should be to work within those policies to fashion
the ways and means of programs best suited to the particular needs of our people.
Our third suggestion is for the administration and the Congress to give States a
more direct role in coordinating programs and funds now flowing directly to our
cities and towns from Washington.
A major disappointment in this budget is the lack of a cohesive urban policy in
general-and of a new mechanism for State involvement in urban policy in particular.
The Governors had high hopes last year that Washington was going to get more
serious about putting some sense into programs affecting our cities and towns. We
still have hopes that Congress will see the need for such a thrust and meet it in the
coming year.
Local governments are, after all, creatures of their States. They don't exist in a
vaccuum. Their roads and rails don't stop at their borders. Their local industries
affect the economy at large. Their tax structures are dependent upon State law.
And yet, Washington likes to leapfrog State capitals and deal directly with local
governments-even with neighborhoods. Governors have little or nothing to sayand therefore can't dovetail State programs with Federal activities-in crucial
program areas like economic development, community development and jobs programs.
We're not asking for the power of the purse. We are asking for the power of
preview and persuasion-to give States a coordinating role in what's going on
within their own borders.
Our fourth suggestion speaks for itself: Washington should be forced by law to
weigh the fiscal impact of its actions on States and local governments and the
private sector.
Too often, laws and rules are put on the books without a long look down the road
to see if their end result will be to send States or cities or businesses down the fiscal
drain.
Government at all levels is already devouring two-fifths of this Nation's income
and employing one in five of its workforce. It's also placing a sometimes necessarybut too often frivolous-array of burdens on the private service and business sectors.
Common sense suggests, for example, that we don't need every one of the 2,100
reporting regulations the General Accounting Office has found imposed on businesses. Common sense suggests that hospital administrators are right in questioning
why more than 100 Federal, State and local regulatory agencies may be looking
over their shoulders at any time. Common sense suggests that we're demanding too
much of an Illinois businessman if he has to be put through six months to a year of
bureaucratic hoops before he can certify his product as eligible for bidding on a
government procurement contract. And common sense suggests that the State of
Illinois should not have to send every one of those 100 State plans to Washington to
spell out what it's doing for children and families.
Before a law is enacted or a rule is written that will mandate someone, somewhere to do something, someone in Washington should be forced to demonstrate
that the real cost balances with the real benefit.
When something. must be done as a matter of public policy -like cleaning up our
water and air or opening access to facilities and services for the handicapped-no
one will argue the merits of the goal. Where there is room for argument is in how
the goal is to be reached, when it must be reached-and who is to bear the cost.
Those arguments should be settled up front, before the statute or rule becomes
the law of the land.
Finally, our fifth suggestion, which also speaks for itself. Pass "Sunset" legislation
to force periodic hard looks-and hard choices-on laws and rules already on the
books.
This is an idea whose time has long since come. More and more States are doing
it-we hope to enact it in Illinois this year-and the Congress came close to
accepting it last year.
Over the past half-century, we've seen variations on the zero-based budgeting
theme come and go. None has made an impact for none has had the help that
Congress could give were it to force the bureaucracy, and itself, to occasionally rethink what seemed to be good ideas at the time they became Federal policy.

132
We're confident that a "Sunset" policy would ultimately lead the national administration to accept the Governors' arguments for a more effective State role in a
more productive Federal-State system.
The Nation's Governors will, of course, be talking with other Committees of this
Congress and with their own delegations in the months to come about the line-byline concerns we have with this budget proposal. And we have many such concerns,
in addition to the broad issues I have outlined here.
For many Governors, this is a back-track budget-on urban and rural policy, on
jobs programs, on law enforcement, on energy in general, and on coal technology
development in particular
We may differ among ourselves over some particulars, but we are agreed on the
larger concerns I have cited here.
The States are not foreign governments. Federal aid for our programs is not a
dole handed out to help us along. The billions at issue here came straight from the
pockets of the people who elected all of us-Senators, Representatives, Governors,
and Mayors-the same people who depend on all of us to use those dollars rationally and equitably for the services they demand.

133

The Poposed
~Fiscl

'180

Federd Budget
Impact on the Stotes

National Governors' Associon
Washington, D.C. *

*.

134
THE NATIONAL GOVERNORS' ASSOCIATION, founded in 1908 as the

National Governors' Conference, is the instrument through which the
governors of the fifty states and the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico, the
Virgin Islands, Guam, American Samoa, and the Northern Mariana
Islands collectively influence the development and implementation of
national policy and apply creative leadership to state problems. The National Governors' Association membership is organized into eight standing committees on major issues: Agriculture; Criminal Justice and Public
Protection; Executive Management and Fiscal Affairs; International Trade
and Foreign Relations; Human Resources; Natural Resources and Environmgental Management; Community and Economic Development; and
Transportation, Commerce, and Technology. Subcommittees which focus
on principal concerns of the governors operate within this framework. The
Association works closely with the Administration and the Congress on
state-federal policy issues from its offices in theHall of the States in
Washington, D.C. Through its Center for Policy Research, the Association
also serves as a vehicle for sharing knowledge of innovative programs
among the states and provides technical assistance to governors on a wide
range of issues.
1978-79 EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE

Governor
Governor
Governor
Governor
Governor
Governor
Governor
Governor
Governor

Julian M. Carroll, Kentucky, Chairman
Otis R. Bowen, Indiana
John N. Dalton, Virginia
Thomas L. Judge, Montana
William G.-Milliken, Michigan
Dixy Lee Ray, Washington
Robert D. Ray, Iowa
John D. Rockefeller IV, West Virginia
James R. Thompson, Jr., Illinois

1978-79 STANDING COMMITTEE CHAIRMEN

Governor George Busbee, Georgia, InternationalTrade and Foreign
Relations
Governor Brendan T. Byrne, New Jersey, Transportation,Commerce, and
Technology
Governor Pierre S. du Pont IV, Delaware, Community and Economic
Development
Governor J. Joseph Garrahy, Rhode Island, Human Resources
Governor James B. Hunt, Jr., North Carolina, CriminalJustice and
Public Protection
Governor Richard D. Lamm, Colorado, NaturalResources and
Environmental Management
Governor Arthur A. Link, North Dakota, Agriculture
Governor Richard A. Snelling, Vermont, Executive Management and
FiscalAffairs
Stephen B. Farber, Director
PROGRAM DIRECTORS

Jack A. Brizius, Policy Research
T. Scott Bunton, Human Resources
Philip R. Davis, Community and Economic Development
Edward L. Helminski, Energy and Natural Resources
David W. Johnson, Environmental Management
Nolan E: Jones, CriminalJustice and Public Protection
John P. Lagomarcino, Legislative Affairs
Joseph P. McLaughlin, Jr., Public Affairs
James L. Martin, State-Local Relations
Deirdre Riemer, Executive Management and FiscalAffairs
Richard R. Rodgers, Administration and Finance
Bud Thar, Transportation,Commerce, and Technology
Joan L. Wills, Employment and Vocational Training

135
FOREWORD

Presenting the views of the Governors on the fiscal year 1980 federal
budget to the administration has been a major project of the Committee
on Executive Management and Fiscal Affairs this year. Representatives of
the National Governors' Association have met with the President and the
Director of the Office of Management and Budget to urge that the budget
contain major initiatives to consolidate federal programs and to achieve
other reforms in the grant-in-aid system. The points we have raised are
summarized in part four of this document.
The analysis that follows examines domestic programs of significant
concern to Governors and presents information that each Governor needs to
judge the impact of the budget proposals on his or her state.
The entire NGApolicy staff contributed to the analysis. Their work
was coordinated by Deirdre Riemer, staff director for the Committee on
Executive Management and Fiscal Affairs.
I hope that you will find this budget analysis a valuable reference
tool.

Governor Richard A. Snelling
Chairman, Committee on Executive
Management and Fiscal Affairs

136
CONTENTS

Summary ...
1.
II.
III.
IV.
V.

1

Overview of the Budget.

3

Economic Outlook

9

Congressional Outlook .11
Administration Response to the Governors'
Recommendations .13
Selected Program Highlights .18
Revenue Sharing and Fiscal Assistance .18
Natural Resources and Environmental Protection.... 19
Community and Economic Development .26
Law Enforcement and Justice .30
Transportation .31
Health .34
Income Maintenance, Social Services, and
Nutrition Programs .38
Employment and Training .46

Education .
Energy ....................

5
,.....................

Emergency Management ..............................

55
62

Agriculture .63
Other Programs .64
VI.
VII.

Glossary .66
Appendix..s.......................................... 68

137
SUMMARY
-President Carter's FY 1980 budget reduces the federal deficit by
$8.4 billion to $29 billion and proposes cuts in current services of
$12.5 billion when all programs are fully adjusted for inflation. If
the economic assumptions underlying the budget prove accurate and if
Congress follows the president's recommendations, outlays would rise
to $532 billion from $493 billion, up 7.7 percent, and receipts would
rise to $503 billion from $456 billion, up 11 percent. As a percentage
of gross national product, federal expenditures would decrease from 22.1
percent in fiscal 1978 to 21.2 percent in fiscal 1980.
In real dollars, grants to state and local governments would decline significantly. Outlays for grants-in-aid would rise to $82.9
billion from $82.1 billion, but this 1 percent increase clearly does
not accommodate the administration's projected 7.4 percent rate of
inflation. As a percentage of state and local expenditures, federal
grants would decline in one year to 23.6 percent from 25.4 percent. This
trend--a major reversal from the pattern of the last 20 years, when
grants increased at an annual rate of almost 14.6 percent--is projected
to continue in the future.
The president's budget does not respond to the recommendation of
the Governors that cuts in spending be accompanied by comprehensive reforms in the federal aid system. Although the budget proposes some consolidation of federal grants, the trend is toward categorical spending.
Other major aspects of grants reform--such as review of mandates and a
stronger state role in intergovernmental programs--are not addressed.
The administration has committed itself, however, to include more reforms along the lines recommended by the Governors in the 1981 budget.
The response of the budget to the specific program recommendations
of the Governors is excellent. The budget provides for welfare reform
and hospital cost containment legislation, proposes a stand-by program
of economic assistance, and funds the general revenue sharing program,
although it also indicates that no decision has yet been made on continuing
the program beyond 1980.
The budget is austere for federal domestic spending generally and
for grants to state and local governments in particular. It reflects
decisions to cover inevitable increases (caused by factors such as previous commitments and automatic cost increases); to phase out most of
the economic stimulus programs (such as some public service jobs and local
public works); and to freeze the remainder, allowing for a few new initiatives to be offset by cutbacks in other programs.
Among the spending reductions which will be of particular concern to
Governors are those made in the CETAprogram, wastewater treatment construction grants, housing programs, health professions education, rural
development, and planning/technical assistance. Requests for the state
incentive and soft public works proposals, key portions of last year's
urban policy, were not renewed.
l

138
New policy and program proposals of interest (in addition to those already.
mentioned) include targeted fiscal relief, changes in the administration and
funding of the food stamp program, consolidations in environmental, mental health,
and transportation programs, expansion of coverage in the Medicaid program, and
the national development bank.

139
1. OVERVIEW OF THE BUDGET

President Carter's FY 1980 budget proposes a real decrease in federal
assistance to state and local governments. Grant outlays of $82.1 billion
in the current fiscal year would have to grow to $87.8 billion just to
reflect the cost of 7.4 percent inflation. Instead of this increase of
$5.7 billion, the budget provides for an increase of $0.8 billion for state
and local assistance. Put another way, state and local governments would, under
the budget proposals, be required to absorb 100 percent of the costs of inflation for their share of various programs and also put up about 85 percent of the
inflation impacts on costs previously paid by the federal government.
The low growth in spending recommended for grant programs and the decline
in real purchasing power of federal grant dollars stem from a number of causes,
including:
* phasing out of some economic stimulus programs, such as some
public service job slots and local public works;
*

assumed cost-saving effects of administration initiatives on
health care and welfare costs;

* selective real increases in a few grant programs and sharp
reductions in a relatively small number of others; and
* decisions to freeze virtually everything else at about the
same dollar levels as FY 1979.
,The president's proposal would reverse a trend of growth in federal grant
programs.
Over the past ten years, federal assistance to state and local government has grown more rapidly than the federal budget as a whole and more rapidly
than the rate of inflation. This expansion has resulted from:
a

sharply increasing costs for such services as welfare (AFDC) and
Medicaid;

a

continuing expansion of grant programs in some areas such as education
and health;

a

the recent use of grant programs (such as CETA and countercyclical
revenue sharing) to stimulate the economy; and

a

the use of grants to pursue other national goals through state and
local governments rather than through direct federal programs.

In the FY 1980 budget, grant programs show an increase of 1 percent over
FY 1979.
This is markedly lower than the increase between 1965 and 1978 when
the average annual increase in grants was 16.0 percent.

3

140
There are very few changes in grant outlays that account for the slight
increase in funding between FY 1979 and FY 1980. These are shown in the
table below.
CHANGES
IN GRANTOUTLAYS BETWEEN
FY 1980 ANDFY 1979
Change
Total grants, 1979 estimate
Payments for individuals:
Medicaid
Housing Programs
Other
Subtotal
Economic stimulus grants:
Local public works
Temporary employment assistance
Anti-recession fiscal assistance
Subtotal
Other:
Sewage treatment plant construction
Community development block grants
Office of Education
Social services- retroactive claims
Other
Subtotal
Total grants, 1980 estimate

1

Amount ($ billion)
82.1
.6
.5
.1
1.3
-1.7
- .6
- *
-2.3
.5
.4
.5
-.
5
1.0
1.9
82.9

*$50 million or less
The decreases are concentrated in economic stimulus programs that the
president-feels are no longer necessary because of the state of the economy.
They include the effect of spending most of the local public works money in
or before FY 1979 and reductions in CETA job slots. The negative entry for
social service reimbursements reflects that it will not be necessary for the
federal government in FY 1980 to repeat the one-time social service reimbursements made in FY 1979.
Many of the increases are the result of factors not under the administration's
control, such as increasing health care costs, rather than deliberate decisions
to expand programs.
For example, outlays for sewage treatment plant construction
go up because of commitments of prior year appropriations, while budget authority
to make new commitments is recommended for reduction.

In this and other tables in this analysis and in the budget documents themselves,detail may not add precisely to totals because numbers are rounded
in detail but totals are added without rounding.
4

141
The near freeze in the growth of federal grant spending can be seen from
the distribution of changes from FY 1979 as shown in the table below.
GRANTOUTLAYS BY MAJORFUNCTION
(S billion)
Function

FY 1979

FY 1980

Change

4.0

4.6

+15%

9.9

10.3

+ 4%

6.4

5.4

-16%

Education, Training, Employment and
Social Services

22.7

22.3

-

Health

13.8

14.5

+ 5%

Income Security

Natural Resources and Environment
Transportation
Community and Regional Development

2%

14.7

15.3

+ 4%

General Purpose Fiscal Assistance

8.8

8.7

- 1%

All Other Functions

1.8

1.8

0

82.1

82.9

+ 1%

TOTAL

The increase in natural resources shown on the table is attributable primarily
to spending funds that have already been committed. Spending increases in
health and income maintenance result principally from cost increases that the
federal government cannot control rather than from decisions to spend more.
The sharp drop in community and regional development reflects the ending of
local public works spending.
In the FY 1980 budget, the administration has presented estimates for
grants for FY 1981 and FY 1982 that provide detailed back-up for tables showing
that the budget can be balanced in FY 1981.
These estimates suggest that the
administration, if it retains its balanced budget target, will be proposing
decreases in real grant spending for the next several years. The projections
are shown below,along with recent history which provides a sharp contrast.
GROWTH
OF FEDERAL GRANTSTO STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
($ billions)
Year

Total

Increase

1976

59.1

19%

1977

68.4

16%

1978

77.9

14%

1979 estimated

82.1

1980 recommended

82.9

5%
1%

1981 forecast

88.0

6%

1982 forecast

91 .9

4%

S

47-977 0 - 79 - 10

;

;

142
This projection of slow growth in grants is not a result of slow growthin overall federal spending. For example, between 1981 and 1982, while grants would
be held to a 4 percent increase, overall spending would increase by 7 percent
Several points in the budget, including a new section dealing with population change, suggest that the population is aging rapidly, with a reduction
in the numbers of children to be educated'and a higher ratio of retired persons
to active workers. This development, the budget indicates, will tend to relieve fiscal pressures on state and local government while increasing pressures
on the federal government, suggesting that continued rapid growth in federal
assistance to state and local governments would be inappropriate.
The main problem is that the principal outlays of the federal government for
aging programs are social security payments from a trust fund to which most
state and local governments are contributing increasing amounts of money and to
(Federal contributions are
which federal general revenues contribute little.
made only for military employees.) The federal government faces increasing retirement costs for its own employees, but so do state and local governments.
The Budget and State and Local Fiscal Situations
If the president's budget is enacted as proposed, the proportion of state
and local spending that is financed by the federal government will drop in 1980.
The figures in the table below show how important federal support has been to
state and local governments in the past several years and the situation projected
in the budget for 1980.
GRANTS AS A PERCENTAGE
OF STATE AND LOCAL SPENDING
Year

Percent

1976

24.5

1977

26.4

1978

26.7

1979 est.

25.4

1980 est.

23.6

How much impact this reduction will have on the percentage of state and
local udoets financed by federal funds is dependent upon the actions taken by state
and local governments in spending for specific functional areas and on their overall fiscal situation. Assuming no recession between now and the end of FY 1980,
the state/local sector is unlikely to have either large balances or major deficits
during that period. During the recession of the mid-1970's, the fiscal position
of state and local governments deteriorated substantially. This triggered responses
such as lower spending, higher taxes, and expanded federal assistance which, along
with recovery from recession, improved the state and local financial situation
considerably in 1976-78. However, the Fiscal Survey just completed by the
National Governors' Association and the National Association of State Budget Officers

143
indicates that state unobligated balances are likely to decrease dramatically in
1979. As a percentage of general fund expenditures, state balances are Projected
to decline from 8.5 percent in fiscal 1978 to 3.6 percent in fiscal 1979.
Defense and International Spending
One of the critical issues that dominated the debate within the administration
during the preparation of the budget was the inherent conflict i'ntrying to
maintain current services on the domestic front, provide the real increases in
defense spending to which the president was committed, and, at the same time,
shrink the deficit and seek to reduce the share of the gross national product
taken by the federal government.
Domestic programs clearly came up the loser in this debate. The total
federal budget (measured by outlays) increased by 7.7 percent. However, fixed
commitment programs (social security, federal employee retirement, interest on the
national debt, and Medicare) increased by 11.2 percent, reducing the amount available for either defense or domestic outlays. If what remained available, given
the president's decision on the size of the total budget, had been equally divided
between the remaining domestic programs and defense and international programs,
each would have increased by 5.2 percent.
Instead, the president's budget
recommends an increase of 11.2 percent in outlays for the defense and international
programs and 1.6 percent for domestic programs.
Tax Policy
Last year Congress enacted major changes in the tax code.
In his budget,
the president chose not to make proposals for a fundamental overhaul of the
tax system or for changes in tax rates.
The president, as expected, did recommend a "real wage insurance" proposal
which the budget estimates would cost about $2.5 billion. The insurance would
provide a tax credit for persons whose wages increased at or below the wage-price
guideline rate of 7 percent. The wage insurance plan basically would hold such
persons harmless from increases in the Consumer Price Index of more than 7 percent.
The administration is having difficulty
drafting details of this proDosal to
cover complex situations, such as when a person held more than one job in a year,
was unemployed for Part of the year, and the like. Some congressional sources
have suggested that the plan is unlikely to pass.
The president also proposed a number of initiatives under the rubric of
"cash management."
The substance of these changes is to move money into the
federal treasury faster (thereby increasing revenues) at the expense of whoever
would otherwise be holding the money--a category that includes state governments.
One proposal, which the administration is attempting to implement by regulation,
is to accelerate the payment of state and local deposits of social security taxes.
The plan to accelerate the payment of individual income taxes by the employers who
withhold them from employees will also affect state and local governments. Other
changes would affect individuals and corporations filing estimated taxes.
7

144
The budget indicates that the administration will seek legislation to
prevent programs in which state and/or local governments act as intermediaries
in providing mortgage credit for middle and higher income families. Such programs
involve use of the tax-exempt borrowing authority of states or cities to provide
mortgage money that, because of the lower rate on tax-exempts, can be provided at
significantly lower cost than regular home mortage money. A number of states
have been considering such a program.
Urban Policy
The president made a number of urban policy proposals in March of 1978.
These included a new state incentive program to induce states to participate
more heavily in dealing with the problems of distressed areas, continuation of
the counter-cyclical revenue sharing program as supplemental fiscal assistance,
and a new national development bank. Congress did not pass these initiatives
during 1978 although it did pass other elements of the president's program.
In the FY 1980 budget, the president:
* dropped the state incentive program completely;
* dropped the so-called "soft public works" program;
a

scaled back the size of the supplemental fiscal assistance
program and indicated that it would be targeted more toward
very distressed areas; and

a

renewed his call for enactment of the national development bank.

The budget indicates that consideration is being given to having the bank included
as part of a cabinet department rather than as a new free-standing agency and that
it might be given responsibility for some programs now administered elsewhere.

8

145
11. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

The economy is one of the strongest forces that shape the federal
budget. When the economy is healthy, costly federal programs triggered
by high unemployment and undesirably low investment levels consume fewer
resources, and the budget has more room for new spending initiatives and
reduction of the deficit. When the economy weakens, the need for remedial
programs limits a president's ability to propose new programs other than
those designed to temporarily stimulate the economy.
Fundamental budget decisions hinge on economic projections, and one
of the most heated debates throughout the budget process revolves around
which federal spending policies seem most appropriate in light of differing
projections of economic conditions.
The 1979 debate is already under way. A number of private economists
are forecasting a slowdown in economic growth or even a recession (two consecutive quarters of decline in real gross national product) sometime in
1979. Others are less sure that a recession will come this quickly, given
the strong growth in the economy in late 1978, but argue that growth in
1979 would simply postpone a recession until 1980 rather than prevent it.
As shown in the table below, the administration's estimates do reflect an
economic slowdown in 1979 but an upturn in 1980. The unemployment rate is
expected to increase somewhat, which is consistent with the slowdown forecast for real growth.

THE ADMINISTRATION'S ECONOMIC
ASSUMPTIONS
Calendar Year

(percents)

1978

1979

1980

Real Gross National Product Growth Rate

4.0

2.2

3.2

Inflation (December over December Consumer
Price Index)

9.2

7.4

6.3

Unemployment Rate

5.8

6.2

6.2

(fourth quarter)

Compared to many private projections, the administration's forecast
presumes a somewhat lower rate of inflation, reflecting more confidence
within the administration than outside about the probable success of the
voluntary wage and price guidelines.
A higher-than-expected inflation rate would help the budgetary picture
by increasing revenues faster than expenditures, but it would increase
9

146
pressures to strengthen the wage-price guidelines and to follow monetary
policies that would cause interest rates to rise.
A lower-than-expected growth rate or an unusually high unemnloyment
rate would likely cause the administration to consider policies to stimulate
If such economic weakness apneared while Congress was conthe economy.
sidering the budget in 1979, it could increase the likelihood that Congress
would continue countercyclical programs (such as Dart of CETA)at current
levels and would accept a larger deficit than that proposed by the president.
High inflation rates also spell trouble for the many state and local governments whose revenues are tied to taxes (such as property taxes and cents-per-gallon gasoline taxes) that do not respond as rapidly or as completely
to inflation as their expenditures do.

10

147
111. CONGRESSIONAL OUTLOOK

Fiscal austerity is expected to be the major force shaping the budoet
that Congress approves for FY 1980. If economic conditions worsen, budgetcutting sentiments may be tempered by counter-pressure to stimulate the economy,
by traditional coalitions orotecting popular programs, and by inflationary
increases in revenues which permit increased spending without enlarging the
deficit. Congress, however, is likely to accent the general outline of the
Carter budget, if not the specific proposals the administration has made.
The Influence Exerted by the Congressional Budget Process
In this climate, the budget committees of both houses will play key
roles in congressional spending decisions. The committees, which recommend
spending levels for each major functional category in the budget, have priority-setting responsibility that is of central importance when there is pressure
not to fund'all of the orograms that the authorizing committees wish to enact.
The congressional process is explained in the appendix to this report.
Although Congress cut President Carter's proposed fiscal 1979 deficit
by $10 billion, most observers agree that this was accomplished largely by
revising the president's tax reform package and by using lower estimates for
the outlays of federal agencies. (See appendix table for a comparison between
the administration's budget and Congress's budget.) The budget committees
did present Congress with some authentic budget-cutting decisions, however.
The victories won as a result of the relatively new budget process point to
greater influence for the budget committees in FY 1980 when many members may
see a need for even more reductions in order to keep their camnaign promises.
The Influence Exerted by Economic Conditions
An economic downturn could cause Congress to reevaluate its spending
policy, however. The current pattern of continuing growth in employment,
production, and personal income represents oneof the longest expansionary
periods in the peace-time history of the United States economy. Nearly all
economic observers seem to agree that this expansion will slow and perhaps
end in a period of economic decline. The unknown factors are when the slowdown will begin, how long it will last, and how serious it will be.
Congressional action on the budge; will be heavily influenced by the
economic situation in the spring and summer. Continuing growth would strengthen the president's initiatives to reduce the size of the deficit. If the
economy slows and unemployment rises, however, the budget deficit is likely
to grow for two reasons:
(I)

slowed growth is likely to reduce estimated revenues and thus increase the deficit even without any suending increases; and

(2)

signs of economic distress will create pressure in Congress for
costly economic stimulus measures.
11

148
Still another scenario could develop if inflation exceeds the projecIn that case, Congress will have the tempting
tionsby a significant margin.
option of both holding the deficit at or below the president's figure and expanding spending beyond the levels recommended by the President. This possibility would result from the substantial imDact that high inflation has on
increasing revenues from the progressive income tax.
If decisions by the 95th Congress indicate a trend, even severe economic
problems are unlikely to lead to substantial new aid to state and local governments in FY 1980. Last year, Congress rejected proposals for supplemental
fiscal assistance, welfare reform, and public works programs which would have
funneled increased funds to states and localities. Congress preferred tax
It seems likely that
reductions as the method to stimulate the economy.
measures taken this year in response to any signs of economic weakness will
federal spending
using
of
reflect this skepticism toward the effectiveness
to increase economic growth.
The Influence Exerted by Key Rules Changes
Last year, across-the-board reduction measures were proposed for budget
resolutions and appropriations bills. In a tight budget year, with Proposition 13 sentiment high, some members might be tempted to resort to acrossthe-board reductions in budget resolutions without specifying exactly where
This approach avoids deciding where to make the
such cuts should be made.
cyts, while requiring that the cuts do get made. Such an approach is critleaders involved in the budget process because
some
congressional
icized by
it sidesteos hard decisions and transfers power from Congress to the executive branch, if the executive branch is given the responsibility for making
the reductions.
convened this month, the House, but not the Senate,
When Congress
made a change in rules so that amendments to cut budget resolutions will also
have to specify the detailed cuts that add up to the proposed change in total.
Conclusion
Some informed observers speculate that Congress will decrease the president's defense request and increase other categories of spending for FY 1980.
Others believe that anti-spending sentiment will preclude increases for any
programs.
The competition
including the budget
will be fierce. The
The general outlines
the compromise.

among some of the major forces shaping the budget -process itself, the economy, and program advocates -complicated dynamics seem to point to a middle ground.
of the budget submitted by the president may define

12

149
IV. ADMINISTRATION RESPONSE TO THE
GOVERNORS' RECOMMENDATIONS

During the fall and winter of 1978, Governors met with President
Carter and his budget director to present their recommendations on the
FY 1980 budget. The suggestions of the Governors were divided into two
broad categories: overall budget policy recommendations and specific
program recommendati ons.
The administration's budget incorporates the Governors' specific
program recommendations virtually intact. However, the responsiveness
of the budget to the overall policy recommendations is limited.
The recommendations of the Governors are listed in this section and
underlined. The response provided in the budget is listed below each
recommendati on.
I.

OVERALL POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

1. NGA supports the president's efforts to balance the federal budget
by 1981. The deficit proposed by the administration is $29 billion, almost
IO-Mbi7lion less than the deficit for FY 1979. Projections provided by
the president show the deficit shrinking to $1 billion in FY 1981 and turning into a surplus in FY 1982.
2. Budget savings in intergovernmental programs should be accompanied
by increased administrative flexibility for state and local governments.

In particular, major program consolidations should be pursued.

Although the

president has proposed several small grant consolidations that reflect
the Governors' recommendations, major grant consolidations are noticeably
lacking in the budget. There is a possibility, however, that a consolidation
of some economic development programs will be recommended at a later date.
Some consolidation of surface transportation is also taking place, along
with the merger of subunits dealing with highways and mass transit in the
Department of Transportation.
On balance, however, the consolidations (energy management, environmental regulatory and planning activities, and certain mental health
in transportation, and the possibility of
programs, some initiatives
consolidation in economic development)do not add up to a major move in the
direction the Governors suggested.

13

150
In addition, the budget reflects greater reliance on categorical
grants rather than broad-based ones. Broad-based and general purpose
grants (basically, block grants and revenue sharing), which are much more
flexible and less expensive to administer, have declined as a proportion
of federal grants to state and local governments by 15 percent since
President Carter took office. (In 1977, such grants totaled 26.1 percent
of intergovernmental aid; in 1980, they are estimated at 21.9 percent,
a relative decline of 16 percent.) This is shown in the table below.
GRANT
OUTLAYS BY TYPE OF FEDERAL
Percent of Total
Type of Grant

1977

1978

1979

19B0

General Purpose Grants

13.9

12.3

10.9

10.6
11.3
7B.1

Broad-Based Grants

12.2

14.7

13.9

Other Grants

73.9

73.0

75.2

By failing to include substantial program consolidations, the administration has not pursued an opportunity to ensure that substantial portions
of the reductions in federal spending come out of administrative overhead
costs, as the Governors recommended. Because the level of service provided
by the proposed budget would decrease while only limited efforts are being
made to reduce administrative costs through consolidation, the budget may
actually raise the costs of delivering services on a per-unit basis.
In his budget message, the president refers to future proposals for
reorganization and consolidation in economic development, natural resource
management, and surface transportation. Since the administration has not
yet settled upon plans for economic development and natural resources, it
is impossible to tell whether such proposals will involve consolidation
of federal agencies, federal programs, or both. In the message, the
president also makes a general reference to further consolidations.
In a briefing on January 20, OM Director James McIntyre was asked
how the proposed budget responded to the recommendations of the Governors.
McIntyre said the budget contains "some small program consolidations" and
'one major consolidation," referring to a proposal that some business
loans and grants which are shown in the budget as administered by other
agencies might be consolidatedunder the administration's proposed national
development bank. McIntyre said the Governors' recommendations were

14

151
meritorious and worthy of pursuing" but would affect "some groups, congressional committees and federal agencies" with whom the administration
would want to consult before undertaking a major consolidation effort.
McIntyre went on to say that the Governors' proposals "have a lot of
thought put behind them" and that "we will pursue them in developing the
1981 budget."
Some of the specific consolidation proposals that are referenced in
the budget have some excellent features that would be useful in other
consolidation legislation. For example, participation in the proposed
environmental management consolidation would be voluntary, and participants would be able to combine the included categorical programs in whatever way best meets their needs. Participants would have the flexibility
to shift funds among priorities, and the role of the state relative to
local governments is well-defined.
3. Funding decisions should result in real savings to taxpayers.
Some of the administration's budget reductions are clearly designed to
decrease actual spending of both the federal government and state and
local governments that share costs with the federal government. The
health cost containment proposal is an example of this approach. In other
cases, however, the effect of the federal decision to cut spending, or to cut
purchasing power-by holding the FY 1980 spending to prior year levels,
would be to inflict costs on state and local government. For example,
the administration recommendations would prevent the scheduled increase
in the federal share of costs for education of the handicapped that
federal legislation mandates for state and local government. Other
federal savings, such as having the FBI leave investigation of bank
robberies to state and local government, represents a transfer of costs,
not savings.
4. The administration should use budget-making techniques that preserve the fiscal choices of the states. In general, federal cutbacks
should not be made by shifting funding responsibilities to state and
local governments through reduced federal matching rates. In general,
the budget does not change matching rates for existing programs.
One
exception is the support of state economic opportunity offices, where
the state share would increase from 20 percent to 50 percent.
5. Intergovernmental assistance should not bear a disproportionate
share of funding reductions. This criterion was not met by t e budget.
The total outlays are recommended to increase by over 7 percent while
outlays for intergovernmental assistance will increase by only 1 percent.
Defense outlays increase by about 11.2 percent.

15

152
6. The impact of federal policies on state and local government
should be determined before these policies are adopted. The budget
fails to discuss the impact of federal spending and legislative proposals
For the Medicaid program, for example,
on state and local government.
new coverage is proposed for up to 2 million people. The impact of
this major expansion on state governments is not discussed. No explanation is provided in the budget to suggest that the administration will
do more to gauge the impact of its proposals on state and local governments than it has in the past, although the urban impact statement
procedure started by the president last year could be helpful if applied
in the context of the budget. The budget document contains no proposals
to review or revise mandates that have been imposed on state and local
governments in the past.
7. The budget should contain proposals for advance appropriation
of federal programs. The administration was not responsive to the
Governors' general desire for advance appropriations as a means to produce
more certainty about future federal program levels. Such appropriations
are continued for a few transportation programs, but were not requested
by the administration for other programs, despite a major recommendation
from the Governors that wastewater treatment grants be advance funded
and despite legislative authority for such appropriations for a number
Some of the education programs are
of nutrition and education programs.
forward funded in the budget, as they have been in the past.
II. PROGRAM
RECOMMENDATIONS
The Governors recommended that:
*

Full funding for the general revenue sharing program be included in the budget
It was, although the administration has not yet made recommendations on the program's renewal.

•

Welfare reform be addressed in the budget.
It was, although the amounts upon implementation
are less than would be required under many of the earlier
reform proposals. No fiscal relief was projected for FY 1980.

16

153
* A permanent stand-by program of economic assistance be

proposed.
It was.

* Hospital cost containment be included in the budget.
It was.

17

154
V. SELECTED PROGRAM HIGHLIGHTS

Revenue Sharing and Fiscal Assistance

REVENUE
SHARING
GENERAL
The proposed budget recommends the full entitlement ($6.9 billion) for
The current authorization for the program exthe revenue sharing program.
pires at the end of FY 1980, and the budget states that "no final decisions
have been made on the desirability of extending general revenue sharing...
beyond September 30, 1980."
ECONOMIC ASSISTANCE
The proposed budget contains $150 million in outlays for a targeted
program of assistance to jurisdictions in economic distress. The president
proposes to request a supplemental appropriation of $250 million in order to
begin the program this year. The legislation for this budget item has not
been developed, but the aid is expected to be highly targeted. The proposal
is expected to exclude states from eligibility in the program.
The president will also propose a stand-by
ance, to be triggered when the economy weakens.
that the economy will remain relatively healthy
program will not have to be implemented, so the
Both state and local governments would
for it.
participate in this program.

program of economic assistThe administration assumes
in FY 1980 and that the
budget contains no funding
probably be eligible to

Congressional approval of these two economic assistance programs is
viewed by many observers as difficult to achieve.

18

155
Natural Resources and Environmental Protection

-

ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
The major characteristics of the FY 1980 Environmental Protection
Agency budget requests are (1) temporary slowdown in the funding of new
sewage treatment facilities construction; (2) increased research efforts
to identify the health effects of environmental pollution; (3) significant increases for the agency's premarketino review and testing program
for toxic substances; and, (4) selected changes in funding levels for
various state grant programs.
FY 1979 and FY 1980 Budget Authority and Outlays
for Grants to State and Local Governments for Pollution Control
and Abatement
($ millions)
FY'1979 (Est.)

FY 1980

Budget Authority

7.1

7.1

Outlays

6.2

6.2

Water/Sewer Construction Grants
The administration is requesting $3.8 billion for construction of
municipal sewage treatment facilties, down from FY 1979 appropriations
of $4.2 billion. The administration argues that slowing the pace of
new project planning is needed to integrate recent statutory changes
in the 1977 Clean Water Amendments into EPA's management system and to
phase in new state management capacities authorized by the law.
In its budget proposals, the administration reemphasizes its longterm commitment to the program and suggests that this slowdown will result
insubstantial carryover funds to augment FY 1981 funding levels.
The administration did not request advance appropriations for the
construction grant program, despite the strong urging of the NGAand
local government officials. The administration cited the lack of
congressional support and OMBconcern over future program outlays as the
reasons for not seeking advance funding.

19

156
FY 1979 and FY 1980 Budget Authority and Outlays for Sewage
Treatment Construction Grants
($ billions)

Budget Authority
Outlays

FY 1979 Est.

FY 1980

$4.2

3.8

3.1

3.6

EPAcontemplates two legislative initiatives in connection with the
First, a one-year extension of the current
construction grant program.
reallotment period for previously-allocated construction funds will be
requested, starting with FY 1978 funds. Various program delays, resulting from the 1977 Clean Water Amendments, may cause up toD30 states to
lose a portion of their current funds to reallotment under current
requirements. EPAfears that without this proposed extension, states
may commit funds to lower priority projects rather than lose them through
real lotment.
The second proposal, currently
ment assistance grants to a maximum
authorization levels rather than to
the case. This would stabilize the
construction appropriations occur.

under study, would tie state manageof 2 percent of construction grant
appropriation levels, as is currently
funding when decreased levels of

In addition, the administration proposed $75 million in FY 1980 budget
authority for a rural technical and financial assistance program under
Section 35 of the Clean Water Act. This program is designed to assist
landowners controlling the most critical non-point sources of water
pollution in rural areas. Under this initiative, USDAwould share pollution
control and conservation costs required by state water quality plans developed under the Federal Water Pollution Control Act.
State Grants
Selected highlights of proposed funding for state and local grant
programs are:
* funding for state air quality programs will increase by $5.6
million, but grants to local government for required air
quality planning have been eliminated from EPA's budget and
would be funded through the Department of Transportation's
planning program under the Urban Mass Transit Authority.
However, no specific earmark of these funds (which totaled
$50 million in FY 1979) appears in DOT's budget.

20

157
a

Increased funding is requested for states' hazardous waste
management activities but a significant reduction in state
solid waste management activities is proposed as part of a
planned five-year phase-out of Subtitles C and 0 grant funding
under the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act.

Consolidated Environmental Assistance
In response to the Governors' expressed support for categorical
program consolidation initiatives, the administration will submit
legislation to Congress that would authorize interested states, on a
voluntary basis,.to combine two or more of EPA's categorical programs
into a single integrated environmental plan. The bill would incorporate
current categorical funding formulae, establish a supplemental
authorization to provide incentive funding of $25 million for FY 1980,
and permit applicants' flexibility to shift funds among covered
programs by to 20 percent of the level provided under the catergorical
approach. Funding could be used for any activity within EPA's mandate
except construction grants, even in the absence of currently authorized
funding for some of those programs.
Local governments would be eligible
for state pass-through to encourage consolidated environmental planning,
where appropriate. The proposal, according to the administration, would
provide increased flexibility at the state and local level in determining environmental protection priorities and allocating resources;
encourage integrated planning, implementation, and management across
media program lines; and improve and simplify the administration of
state and local grants by reducing paperwork, duplication of effort, and
reporting requirements.
The bill probably will be referred to the Senate Committees on Public
Works, Agriculture, and Government Affairs, and to House Committees on
Public Works, Commerce, Agriculture, and Government Operations. The
congressional outlook is uncertain. Opposition can be expected from those
who view the proposal as a threat to existing categorical arrangements.
States that support the thrust of the proposal must develop arguments
that would highlight potential cost-savings and better management capabilities that would result from the consolidated approach.

21

47-977 0 - 79 - 11

Environmental Protection Agency
State Grant Programs
Budget Authority
(i in millions)
1979
Air
Section 105 .....................
Section 175
Water Quality
Section 106 .....................
Section 208 ...............
Clean Lakes .....................
,

$80.0
$85.6
5 .0.....................
.
...

; .....

Drinking Water
Public Water Systems
Program Grants .................
Underground Injection
Control Program ................
Special Studies & Demos .........
Solid Waste
Solid Waste Management ..........
Hazardous Waste
Management
Resource Recovery
Pesticides
Pesticides Enf Grants ...........
Interdisciplinary
Consolidated Grants .............
TOTAL .......................

1980

52.4
41.0
14.7

48.7
40.0
15.0

26.4

29.5

7.6
2.0

7.8
1.4

VI

15.2

10.0

l.10.....................
l.
10...............

18.6
14.0

8.8

8.8

...

25.0

$328.2

$304.3

X

159
WATERRESOURCES
Bureau of Reclamation budget authority for water resources planning,
development and operations programs in the 17 western states would increase
by $170 million under the president's budget request of $757,461,000.
The administration is requesting $510 million to continue construction
of 70 western water projects previously authorized for which Congress
appropriated $401 million for FY 1979.
The FY 1980 budget requests funding for only one new Bureau of
Reclamation construction start, in line with President Carter's water
policy proposals to provide full funding for such projects. This proposal
is certain to provoke continuing congressional opposition to the water
policy proposals in view of the traditional congressional approach of
funding a larger number of new water projects on an annual, piecemeal
basis.
FY 1979 and FY 1980 Budget Authority and Outlays for Bureau
of Reclamation
($ millions)
FY 1979 Est.

Fv 1980 Est.

Budget Authority

598.3

757.5

Budget Outlays

624.3

638.1

Budget authority for construction activities of the Corps of Engineers
is expected to increase from $1.3 billion in FY 1979 to almost $1.8 billion in
FY 1980, primarily to maintain a reasonable construction pace on projects that
have previously been started. Limited new starts are also contemplated for the
Corps.
St1;-t Water Management Plans
The administration proposes to increase state matching grants under
Title III of the Water Resources Planning Act from $3 million to $50
million as part of the Carter water policy proposals. The increased
grants would help states develop comprehensive water management programs
that would emphasize conservation, integration of water quanity and water
quality planning, and technical assistance to local governments for more
efficient water use. The congressional outlook is uncertain, given the
continuing debate over proposed national water policy reforms.
Land and Water Conservation
While a significant overall reduction is proposed for the land and
water conservation fund, the bulk of the cut would come from federal
land acquisitions. Matching grants to states would be reduced from the
FY 1979 outlay level of $369.7 million to $359.3 million for state out-

23

160
door recreation planning, land acquisition, and outdoor recreation facilities development.
Urban Parks
A supplemental 1979 appropriation of $37.5 million, plus FY 1980
funding of $150 million, will be requested for 70 percent federal - 30
percent local matching grants to urban governments for the rehabilitation
of existing urban recreation facilities under 1978 urban parks legislation (PL 95-625).
Historic Preservation
A 25 percent reduction in matching grants-in-aid is requested for state
planning and individual projects under the Historic Preservation Fund.
Although this reduction would be spread equally among states under
current distribution guidelines, smaller state programs would have greater
difficulty absorbing the 25 percent reduction.
FY 1979 and FY 1980 Budget Outlays for the Heritage
Conservation and Recreation Service (KCRS)
-$ milMlons)

Salaries & Expenses

1979

1980

$ 15.3

$ 18.5

Land and Water Conservation
Fund
,

737.02

Historic Preservation Fund

60.0

45.0

Urban Park and Recreation

37.5

150.0

$850.0

$824.0

TOTAL

24

610.0

Increaase (+) or
Decrease (-)
$+

3.1

- 127.0
-

15.0

+ 112.5
$ -

26.3

161
Coastal Zone Management
Since the planning phase of the Coastal Zone Management Program is,
for the most part, completed, the FY 1980 budget request for program
development grants is significantly reduced ($8.5 million in FY 1979,
$2.6 million in FY 1980). The overall budget authority request, however,
is increased from $57.3 million in 1979 to $66 million in FY 1980.
Major increases are proposed for program administration and management
grants.

25

162
Community and Economic Development

LCQBGs) AND
BLOCK GRANTS
COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT
ACTION GRANTS(UDAGs
URBANDEVELOPMENT
For FY 1980, the administration is requesting $3.9 billion in budget
authority for the community development block grant program, a $150 million
increase in the budget authority provided for FY 1979. FY 1980 outlays for
CDBGsare expected to be $3.3 billion, about $400 million more than the $2.9
billion anticipated during FY 1979.
For urban development action grants (UDAGs), the administration is
requesting $400 million in budget authority for FY 1980. This amount is
identical to that requested and received from Congress for FY 1979. Outlays
for UDAGs,however, are expected to increase from $44 million in FY 1979 to
$162 million in FY 1980.
State governments have indicated to the administration that they are
able and willing to Participate extensively in the administration of the
small cities CDBGprogram. Budget authority in FY 1980 for this program is
$690 million. At the present time, the administration does not intend to
submit legislation to Congress permitting states to olay a significant role
in the administration of this program (e.d., assisting HUDin establishing
funding priorities for the small communities).
DEVELOPMENT ADMINISTRATION (EDA)
ECONOMIC
The administration is submitting a request of $759 million in budget
authority for the Economic Development Administration inFY 1980, a substantial increase, $210 million, in FY 1979 budget authority of $549 million.
During FY 1980, EDA's outlays are expected to decrease from those of FY 1979.
Outlavs for FY 1980 are anticipated to be $832 million, $1.6billion less than
the FY 1979 total of $2.43 billion. The principal reasun for this significant
decrease is the completion of Rounds I and II of the local public works program.
EDA's proposed budget for FY 1980 is something of a mixed bag for
state governments. On the one hand, the administration intends to request
$150 million in budget authority for an energy impact assistance program long
sought by states. On the other hand, the 301 and 302 programs are being cut
by about $9 million. States, sub-state districts, and municipal governments are
the beneficiaries of these planning and technical assistance programs. Further,
the administration's reactions to the NGAeconomic program consolidation leoislation, which would consolidate a number of EDA's categorical programs
and distribute economic development grant funds on a state-by-state formula
basis, are not yet clear.

26

163
HOUSING (HUD)
The Department of Housing and Urban Development's proposed budget for
FY 1980 provides $27 billion in budget authority for subsidized housing
This
programs, particularly the Section 8 and public housing programs.
amount represents a $3.9 billion decrease in budget authority from the $30.9
billion provided in FY 1979. The administration estimates that the FY.1380
budget will permit production of 250,000 units of Section 8 rental assistance
housing and 50,000 units of public housing. This total of up to 300,000
units would be a decrease of 60,000 units of housing permissible under
the FY 1979 budget. Outlays for subsidized housing programs in FY 1980 are
expected to total $5.3 billion, nearly $870 million more than in FY 1979.
State governments do not do particularly well in the administration's
FY 1980 housing budget. For example, it is expected that the number of
Section 8 rental assistance housing units allocated to state housing finance
agencies will be reduced from 53,000 for FY 1979 to 40,000 for FY 1980.
In addition, the administration apparently does not intend to permit financially troubled state public housing projects to be eligible for the $91
million in assistance funds requested for FY 1980. The administration's
stance seems to contradict commitments made to state housing authorities
last year that states would be able to participate in the troubled projects
program.
As part of its tax policy recommendations, the administration has decided
to press for legislation that would limit the ability of states or cities.
to use tax-exempt bonds to finance mortgages for middle and higher income
persons. Use of tax-exempt financing for low and moderate income housing
would continue to be permitted.
NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT
BANK
The administration intends to reintroduce legislation creating a
national development bank.
The bank would use financial incentives to
encourage private businesses to locate in distressed and declining communities. These incentives would include direct grants, guarantees of
loans made by financial institutions, interest rate subsidies, and a secondary marketing facility for loans made by financial institutions to firms
locating in distressed areas.
The administration intends to request $3.5 billion in budget authority
for the national development bank in FY 1980. Outlays for FY 1980 are expected
to be $195 million.
The administration has not yet decided whether the bank should be an
independent agency or an entity within an existing department and whether
The role of state
some existing programs should be administered by the bank.
governments in the operation of the bank's programs also remains undecided.
PLANNING AND TECHNICAL ASSISTANCE PROGRAMS
For FY 1980, the administration is requesting $40 million in budget
authority for the HUD701 planning Drogram, no money at all for the Farmers
Home Administration Section III planning orogram, and $6.5 million for the
27

I

164
EDA301 and 302 planning programs.
The table given below compares these and
other planning and management budgets for FY 1979 and 1980.

BUDGETAUTHORITY FOR PLANNING ANDMANAGEMENT
($ millions)
FY 1979

FY 1980

53.0

40.0

FmHARural Development Planning (111)

5.0

0.0

EDA Economic Development Planning
(301 and 302 state portions)

6.5

6.5

20.0

20.0

HUDComprehensive Planning (701)

Intergovernmental Personnel Act (IGA)
NSF State Science, Engineering,
Technology
Total

and

2.5
87.0

.

0.0
66.5

This proposed reduction of $20.5 million in planning and technical assistance funds could have severe implications for Governors and their planning
staffs, which are major recipients of these funds. The administration's
argument for cutting these planning programs is that state and local governments have already developed the capacity to engage in comprehensive community
and economic developmental planning. Consequently, fewer federal dollars are
necessary. Further, because state and local governments now have the ability
to prepare comprehensive plans and to administer complex programs, the federal
government argues that they should use their own funds for these purposes.
However, during a time of fiscal stringency at the state and local governmental
levels as well as at the federal level, it is questionable whether states and
localities will accept a $20.5 million reduction in federal planning and capacity building programs.
REGIONAL COMMISSIONS
The administration is seeking reauthorization of the Appalachian Regional
Commission (ARC) and the eleven regional commissions established under Title V
of the Public Works and Economic Development Act of 1965. For FY 1980, the
administration is requesting $359 million in budget authority for ARC and $74
million in budget authority for the Title V commissions. These amounts represent
a $10 million reduction for ARC and a $11.2 million increase for Title V commissions. The increased budget for Title V commissions reflects the provision of
start-up funds for the Mid-Atlantic, Mid-America, and 11id-South Commissions and
greater funding of the Southwest Border Commission.
During FY 1980, budget outlays
for ARCwill increase from $281 million in FY 1979 to $296 million. Outlays for
the Title V commissions will increase from $68 million in FY 1979 (including funds
carried over from previous fiscal years) to $70 million in FY 1980.
28

165
RURALDEVELOPMENT
The administration's FY 1980 budget proposes $275 million in budget
authority for Farmers Home Administration water and sewer and rural
develppment grants, an $18 million decrease from the FY 1979 level.
The
administration also is requesting $950 million in water, sewer, and community facilities loans and $1 billion in business and industrial loans
administered by FmHA. These amounts represent reductions of $200 million
and $100 million respectively from obligations in FY 1979.
For rural housing programs, the administration has requested $1.65
billion in budget authority for FY 1980. This is a $175 million reduction
from the $1.82 billion provided in FY 1979. However, reflecting spending
from prior commitments, outlays for rural housing programs are expected to
increase from $218 million in FY 1979 to $362 million in FY 1980.

29

166
Law Enforcement and Justice

LAWENFORCEMENT
ASSISTANCE ACT
The administration has proposed $2.4 billion in budget authority for the
Department of Justice, a reduction of $111.6 million from FY 1979 levels. State
and local programs within the Justice Department are scheduled for a reduction
of $122 million. LEM, which has suffered budget cuts of $248 million from
FY 1975 to FY 1979, is slated for another reduction of $100.1 million in FY 1980.
Approximately $87 million of this reduction will come from state and local
programs.
This decrease in federal funds will have an impact on most state criminal
justice programs.
For example, funds for planning and administration will be
cut by $15-million, criminal justice formula grants will be reduced by $39 million,
and the juvenile justice formula program will receive a 50 percent reduction from
its present level of funding, to $33 million. Overall, the direct assistance
programs controlled by the state and local units of government were reduced by
$87.0 million, or over 21 percent. However, collateral assistance programs
(those programs controlled and operated in Washington) decreased by only 10
percent.
It should be remembered that LEAA must be reauthorized by statute this year,
and the administration will again propose legislation that would create a new
Office of Justice Assistance, Research and Statistics (OJARS).
LEAA would be
a part of this office, along with a Bureau of Justice Statistics and the National
Institute of Justice. Funding under this structure would be as follows: LEAA
would receive $497,936,000 and the Bureau and the Institute together would
receive $48,411,000 The legislation proposes to reduce "red tape" and paperwork
by requiring (among other things) the submission of state plans every three years
rather than annually.
The community anti-crime program, currently a function of LFAA, will. be
funded at $10 million, an increase of $3 million over FY 1979.
In addition,
$10 million is requested to implement the president's urban crime initiative.
The $20 million for these programs will be subtracted from the LEM portion
($497,936,000) of the overall OJARS budget ($546,347,000).

30

167
Transportation

The president's transportation budget, overall and in programs of
particular interest to state governments, recommends funding increases
that fail to keep pace with inflation. Using the Department of Transportation'smeasure of activity, the program level of the department will increase by about 5 percent. Actual outlays will increase more slowly.
The budget reflects an overall tone of austerity, regulatory reform,
and applying user charges to defray mony transportation costs. The budget
contains the comment:
"...the federal government cannot continue to subsidize inefficiencies within the transportation sector that lower productivity
and cause a constant drain on national resources. These inefficiencies
are caused in part by outdated regulations and in part by poor management or an inability to respond to changing transportation patterns.
Federal operating subsidies to private firms and local governments
sometimes make it too easy to continue these inefficiencies."
The budget indicates that the president intends to submit legislation in
1979 to deregulate rail and bus lines.
In addition to reflecting the president's austerity approach to FY 1980,
the Department of Transportation budget does reflect some concepts of the
type that the Governors presented to the president in late 1978. Where choices
could be made, the administration consistently has favored assistance programs
to state and local government that are considerably more flexible than
narrower categorical approaches. To facilitate state and local planning,
advance appropriations are provided in mass transit. Changes in legislation
in 1978 and in organization in 1979 are designed to make it easier to consider
mass transit and highway policy in an integrated fashion.
In almost every transportation function, basically level funding by the
administration will trigger some reductions in construction activity and/or
service levels unless state and local governments are prepared to meet inflationary costs with their own funds. Maintaining funding for highways at
last year's ceiling in the face of costs for highway construction that have
been increasing more rapidly than the overall rate of inflation is expected
to reduce construction activities. Level subsidies for mass transit probably
will slow construction activities and shift the higher operating costs onto
some combination of transit users and state and local governments. Constant
rail subsidies are expected to force consideration of reductions in Amtrak's
long-distance routes and possible elimination of unprofitable Conrail routes.
This, in turn, is likely to increase pressures on states to provide funds to
continue some of these services.

31

168
HIGHWAYS
Budget authority for highway improvement and construction is expected
to increase by about 2.5 percent while outlays will actually drop slightly.
The administration has decided to continue the FY 1979 ceiling on federalaid highway programs at $8.5 billion.
Within this funding level, the budget proposes to omit funding for
"a series of smaller highway programs that can be funded within existing
federal-aid highway authorities or that can be supported satisfactorily by
states and localities." Funds affected by this decision include those used
for some highway beautification activity, construction of roads not listed
on any federal-aid highway system and "most aid identified for soecifically
identified highway projects." No funds are requested for the highway beautification program pending a departmental review of it.
The Department of Transportation proposes funding for continued work
with the states in motor carrier safety.
MASSTRANSIT
While mass transit outlays will rise substantially, reflecting spending
related to prior-year programs, budget authority for mass transit is expected
to be $2.5 billion, an increase of 2 percent from the FY 1979 level. Under
the Surface Transportation Assistance Act of 1978, the administration of
highway and mass transit programs will be more closely linked. To facilitate
this program linkage, the Department of Transportation is planning to combine
its Urban Mass Transportation Administration and the Federal Highway Administration. Consistent with its "same as last year" approach to transit funding.
the administration does not request funds for several new categorical grant
programs established by the Surface Transportation Act, such as bus terminal
construction.
RAILROADS
Proposed funding for railroads reflects a reduction in both budget
authority and outlays. The budget justifies the level of funding proposed
for railroads as follows: "We cannot continue to ask the general taxoayer
to pay the cost of an uneconomic railroad system, a system largely sustained
by outdated federal regulatory policies." The funding levels recommended
for both Amtrak ($760 million) and Conrail (outlays of $440 million in FY 1980
under a supplemental appropriation) are explicitly designed to force each to
make reductions in service. The same level of funding as in FY 1979, $67
million, was recommended for the Rail Service Assistance Program, a program
of aid to states to prevent abandonment of essential rail lines.
AIR TRANSPORTATION
The administration plans to offer legislation to continue the airport
and airway trust fund by which many federal aviation activities are funded
through charges to the users. The budget appears to contemplate some reductions
in airport development grants to small airports in FY 1980 but spending is
expected to increase to about £800 million a year in FY 1981, which is consistent with
the new trust fund legislation. Within a context of little change in funding,
32

169
the Federal Aviation Administration will implement a variety of steps to
reduce the likelihood of mid-air collisions. The budget also contemplates
a shifting of service to smaller communities from larger carriers to commuter
airlines.
There is no provision for the consolidation of the Airport
Development Aid program, as the Governors had recommended in the fall.

33

170
Health

The president's budget proposes to spend $52.2 billion on health programs
administered by the Department of Health, Education and Welfare. This represents an increase of S4.1 billion (8.5 percent) over the estimated expenditures
for FY 1979.

HEALTH PROGRAM
OUTLAYS FY 1979 AND FY 1980
DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH, EDUCATION ANDWELFARE

($ in Millions)

Public Health Service

FY 1979

FY 1980

$ 7,157

$ 7,683

Change
+ 7.3%

Health Care Financing Administration
Total HCFA

41 .005

44,553

+ 8.7%

Medicare

(29,149)

(32,080)

(+10. IS)

Medicaid

(11,751 )

(12 ,354)

(+ 5.1%)

Other HCFA

(

(

119)

(+13.3%)

$52,236

+ 8.5%

Total HEWHealth

105)

$48,162

The bulk of the increases in HEWhealth outlays will occur in entitlement
programs (Medicare and Medicaid).
In the portion of the budget in which more
discretion can be exercised by the president and Congress (the Public Health
Service), there is an overall increase which is relatively smaller (7.3 percent)
than that for the entitlement programs (8.7 percent). The budget figures for
a number of health programs of interest to the Governors are summarized in the
table on the next page.

34

171
BUDGET
AUTHORITY FY 1979 AND FY 1980
SELECTED HEALTH PROGRAMS
(S in Millions)

Program

FY 1979

FY 1980

Percent
Change

1

Medicaid" )
11 842.0
Maternal and Child Health
345. 5
Community Health Centers
351.0
Community Mental Health Centers
278.3
Health Planning
152.5
Health Maintenance Organizations
39.5
Drug Abuse Formula Grants*
40.0
Alcoholism Formula Grants*
56.8
Public Health Grants (314(d))*
90.0
Mental Health Block Grant
Prevention Formula Grants
Family Planning
145.0
Migrant Health
34.5
Immunization
50.0
Adolescent Pregnancy Prevention
7.0
Health Professions Education (Capitation)**
144.0
Hospital Closure/Conversion
Home Health Services
6.0

$12,696.0
357.4
381.0
241.1
154.5
73.6
-0-052.0
99.0
18.0
145.0
41.4
33.5
60.0
-030.0
.8

+ 7.2X
+ 3.4
+ 8.5
-13.4
+ 1.3
+86.3
-100
-100
-42.2
proposed
new
-0+20.0
-33.0
new
-100
proposed
-86.7

See discussion of grant consolidation.
** See discussion of education budget.

(1) Reflects proposed legislation.

HEALTH GRANTCONSOLIDATION
The budget proposes major changes in the health block grant authorized by
Section 314 (d) of the Public Health Service Act and in the formula grants for
state drug abuse and alcoholism programs.
The block grant appropriation would
be decreased by more than 42 percent, and the formula grants would not be funded.
In place of the formula grants and a portion of the 314 (d) program, the
administration will propose legislation to create a mental health block grant.
The overall effect of the consolidation will be to decrease funds 10 percent
below the level available last year. The reduction will be felt more deeply
than the figures suggest because the program spending levels have not been
adjusted for inflation.

35

g

172
AUTHORITY FY 1979 AND FY 1980
BUDGET
MENTALHEALTH BLOCKGRANTAND CONSOLIDATED PROGRAMS
(S in Millions)
FY 1980

Change

Program

FY 1979

Health Block Grant

$ 13.5

--

abolished

Drug Abuse Formula Grants

40.0

--

abolished

Alcoholism Formula Grants

56.8

--

abolished

Mental Health Block Grant

--

99.0

Consolidated Programs

110.3

99.0

new
-10.2%

15 percent ($13.5 million) of the Section 314 (d) grant
to each state is allocated to the state mental health authority.

* Under present law,

As a result of the consolidation of existing formula and block grants, the
(The public
budget proposes a net decrease of $36 million in these programs.
health block grant will decrease by $24.5 million, and the mental health and
substance abuse programs will be $11.3 million lower than the FY 1979 budget
authority.) The president's budget also proposes budget authority of $18
million to implement a program of state formula grants for preventive health
services. This program was authorized by P.L. 95-626, which also authorized an
expansion of the Section 314 (d) block grant program.
MEDICAID
The estimated outlays for Medicaid will increase significantly during
FY 1980, and the president will seek legislation to slow the rate of increase.
In addition to new hospital cost containment legislation (see below), the
budget assumes the passage of legislation limiting reimbursement for hospitalbased physicians (saving $7 million), disallowing reimbursement for chiropractic
services ($1 million), and requiring common Medicare and Medicaid audits ($28
million). Administrative changes will also be undertaken to increase provider
efficiency (saving $8 million) and to limit the payment through Medicaid for
hospital malpractice insurance premiums ($40 million).
The budget also includes S288 million to cover the cost of a Child Health
This program, to be introduced in the 96th Congress,
Assessment Program (CHAP).
will require states to expand Medicaid eligibility to more than 2 million
pregnant women. The CHAPlegislation will
to
100,000
low-income
children and
establish a national income standard for eligibility (the higher of the state's
AFDCstandard or 55 percent of the national poverty threshold) and would require
states to provide dental, hearing, prescription drug, and ambulatory mental
health benefits to all Medicaid-eligible children.

36

173
HOSPITAL COST-CONTAINMENT AND HEALTH PLANNING
The president's budget assumes significant savings to the Medicare and
Medicaid programs from the enactment of hospital cost-containment legislation
during 1979.
Following up on the guidelines under the anti-inflation program,
the administration will propose federal legislation establishing voluntary
goals for hospital expenditures and standby controls if the goals are exceeded.
The voluntary goals established under the anti-inflation program suggest that
hospital expenditures be held to a 9.7 percent increase between 1978 and 1979.
The administration would write the anti-inflation program goals into its
hospital cost-containment legislation for introduction in the 96th Congress.
The major existing program focused on medical care cost containment -- the
health planning program -- is slated for a small increase in the FY 1980 budget
($2 million). The president proposes no funding for the regional health
planning technical assistance centers but will propose legislation to aid in
the conversion or closure of excess hospital capacity. The new program would
include $30 million in new budget authority and would be designed to demonstrate the efficiencies that would result from the removal of unneeded hospitaT
beds from the system.
CONGRESSIONAL OUTLOOK
The hospital cost containment and child health initiatives will probably
receive the majority of the administration's attention. A hospital cost bill,
similar to the one that will be-proposed this year, made its way through the
Senate in the closing days of the 95th Congress. Opposition from the hospital
industry has not abated, and the imposition of a voluntary goal significantly
lower than the industry's own goal of 11.6 percent is likely to increase the
pressure against passage. The fiscal mood of the new Congress and a more flexible approach by the administration may help to secure enactment of a hospital
cost-containment statute.
The new CHAPproposal will probably receive early and favorable action in
the 96th Congress. Many of the modifications made in this year's proposal
reflect amendments to the administration's proposal which were attached by
committees of the 95th Congress. There is no strong or organized opposition
to the program. Somecould develop if it is expanded radically, causing a
significant increase in costs.
The proposal to consolidate the mental health and substance abuse grants is
likely to stimulate some opposition as it is considered in the 96th Congress.
Advocates of each program have traditionally opposed consolidation, and the net
reduction in funds will not help to garner support from other groups.
The proposal to eliminate capitation grants to health professional schools
will stimulate vigorous opposition from a number of quarters. The debate will
probably result in a compromise which should set the stage for the reauthorization of the health manpower legislation scheduled for the second session of
the 96th Congress.

37

47-977 0 - 79 - 12

Income Maintenance, Social Services, and Nutrition Programs

WELFARE/PUBLIC ASSISTANCE
Federal costs of benefits under the two major cash assistance programs, the
Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) state-federal program and the
federalized Supplemental Security Income (SSI) program (which many states
supplement), are expected to rise in FY 1980. AFDCexpenditures will increase
by about $350 million to $6.3 billionand SSI spending will increase $400
million to $5.6 billion in FY 1980.
As is the case with all individual entitlement programs, the president's
budget is of importance when it contains proposals to alter the
terms of the programs, or it proposes to change the way in which state administrative expenses are computed.
There are only a few such proposals in the
1980 budget, none of which should be significantly troubling to state and
local governments.
Several of the proposals have considerable appeal.
The
proposals are as follows:
AFDC
1. Although current plans call for incorporation of AFOCinto the welfare
reform proposal the administration plans to submit to Congress, the administration will likely propose an effective date of FY 1980 for a provision to simplify and standardize the AFDCwork expense allowance within the earned income
disregard. It is expected that the administration's proposal will be modeled
after the provision in the Food Stamp Amendments of 1977. The administration
estimates that this provision will save $81 million in federal outlays in 1980.
States will also realize savings.
2. Legislation will be proposed to revise the calculation of AFDCbenefits
in cases where a stepparent lives with an eligible AFDCfamily unit, so that a
stepparent's income in excess of an amount reserved for his own support (and
that of any of his dependents) will be counted in determining AFDCeligibility
and benefits for stepchildren. This oroposal, if enacted, will reduce federal
outlays by $100 million in FY 1980 and will also provide savings for states.
3. The administration will propose that Congress make permanent the
increased federal participation and limit the reimbursement ceilings to $52
million for public assistance programs in Guam, Puerto Rico, and the Virgin
Islands established for one year by the 95th Congress. This measure would
result in $29 million in additional FY 1980 outlays.
SSI
Legislation will be proposed to:
* shift the accounting system from quarterly prospective to
monthly retrospective (no FY 1980 outlay impact);
*

prohibit the disposal of assets to qualify for benefits ($6
million reduction in FY 1980 outlays);
38

175
e

eliminate windfall benefits when an applicant receives
retroactive Title II Social Security benefits for the same
time period ($19 million reduction in FY 1980 outlays);

* increase the legal responsibility of sponsors of legally
admitted aliens who become dependent on SSI ($2 million
reduction in FY 1980 outlays); and
e

improve equity and simplify the SSI program (,7 million increase
in FY 1980 outlays).

States supplementing SSI benefits may also realize some savings if the
proposals are enacted. However, several of the OASDI cost reduction proposals
will increase SSI FY 1980 outlays by $20 million.
Child Support Enforcement Program
Through the Child Support Enforcement program, states (with 75 percent of
their costs assumed by the federal government) locate absent parents, establish paternity, and obtain child support payments from delinquent parents.
Currently, state and federal administrative costs are approximately three-fifths
of the total child support collections resulting from the program.
FY 1980
administrative costs and child support collections are proposed to increase to
$541 million and $925 million, respectively. Several legislative amendments
will be proposed. None of these are expected to have a profound program
impact, although each is designed to increase collections and reduce administrative costs; none of the proposals are inconsistent with state interests. The
administration expects these measures to reduce FY 1980 outlays by $60 million.
Refugee Assistance Programs
Under current policy, assistance varies for each of the different refugee
groups:
e

Assistance under the Cuban program will be gradually phased
out -- the 1980 budget would pay 75 percent of assistance
costs, and the program would end after 1983.

* Assistance for refugees who entered from Indo-China in 1975-1977
will be phased out in the 1980 budget. However, legislation
will be proposed to extend this program to provide assistance
for the first 3 years after a refugee's entry into the U.S. Costs
of cash and medical support for refugees'who entered after 1977
are financed at 100 percent.
*

Under the Soviet and Other Refugee program, in the FY 1979 and
1980 budgets the federal government would pay 50 percent of
support costs, while voluntary agencies would pay the remaining
50 percent.

39

176
The administration's budget (and its estimated expenditures for 1979) are
based upon the estimates of new refugees entering the United States shown in
the table below. No provision is made for the implications of providing
assistance to new groups of refugees or higher entrance levels for currentlyassisted groups of refugees.
Complete phase-out of assistance for the Cuban and Indo-Chinese Refugee
Assistance programs will place a burden on states, particularly where concentrations of refugees are highest, and in those cases where assimilation into
the culture has proceeded more slowly than anticipated. States have held that
where presence of refugees results from a large-scale federal refugee policy,
the full cost of that presence, until the refugees are fully self-supporting,
must be borne by the federal government, regardless of the length of time for
which assistance must be provided.
Budget proposals for the refugee assistance programs are summarized in
the chart below.

FY 1978, FY 1979 AND FY 1980 BUDGET
AUTHORITY
REFUGEE
ASSISTANCE PROGRAMS
(S in Millions)
1978

1979

1980

Cuban Programs
(new refugees)

$ 71
(--)

$ 57
(--)

$ 53

Indo-China Program
(new refugees)

$122
(--)

Soviet/Other Program
(new refugees)

--

()

$148
(65,000)

$ 90
(25,000)

$ 20
(20,000)

$ 20
(20,000)

Welfare Reform
The president's FY 1980 budget makes concrete his commitment to develop
and propose legislation to pursue meaningful reforms of the welfare system.
Although the description of the reform proposal is sketchy, the FY 1980 budget
documents do make clear that the-reform legislation will:
*

be fully implemented in FY 1982 at a federal cost of $5.5
billion above that of current programs projections to that
date. Sufficient room is left in projections for FY 1981
to allow for additional expenditures of $1.5 billion resulting
from reforms implemented in that year;

40

177
* standardize and simplify the work expense deduction component
of the earned income disregard for AFDC, which will become
effective for FY 1980 (see commentary under Welfare/Public
Assistance -- AFDCYY
* switch the method of computing AFDCeligibility and benefits
from prospective accounting to mandatory one-month retrospective accounting;
a

establish a national minimum benefit level for the AFDCprogram;

* make alterations in eligibility criteria (e.g., assets test
and income definitions) in the AFDCprogram to make them
uniform with the food stamp program;
* transform the unemployed father component of the AFDCprogram
into assistance for unemployed parents, and extend it to all
states;
* attempt to provide an employment and training opportunity for
the principal earner in AFDCfamilies for whom a private sector
job cannot be found;
* maximize reliance on the enacted resources for the most severely
disadvantaged under the CETA program and tax credits;
a

further expand the earned income tax credit to increase
incomes of working poor families and thereby strengthen work
incentives and reduce welfare costs; and

* provide additional fiscal relief to state and local governments.
This is largely an encouraging and welcome pronouncement by the administration. During the coming weeks and months, careful attention must be given to
the final design of the administration's proposal to ensure that it is acceptable
and helpful to state governments and politically viable.
Despite frequent, continuing messages to the administration from the nation's
Governors, particularly those from states with high welfare caseloads, that it
is essential that state and local governments be provided with some immediate
relief from the excessive and growing fiscal burden of welfare expenditures,the
administration has made no provision in the FY 1980 budget for such relief. Although $1.5 billion is includedin projections for "welfare reform" in FY 1981, it is
not specified whether part or all of this amount will be used to fund substitution
of federal expenditures for state expenditures in the AFDCprogram.
Relief from

41

178
the growing financial burden of.welfare is essential for state and local governments.
The Governors continue to take seriously earlier commitments by administration representatives that the administration supports immediate fiscal
relief upon the passage of programmatic reform legislation and would include
such a provision in its legislation. That relief must be available in both
FY 1980 and FY 1981.
FOODAND NUTRITION PROGRAMS
The administration proposed an $800 million increase in food and nutrition
programs in FY 1980. This request reflects proposed legislation which will
provide for $.35 billion in reductions from the levels that would otherwise be
needed.
Food Stamp Program
As is the-case with other entitlement programs, the budget projections are
important to the degree they reflect legislative initiatives or possible effects
on the entitlement nature of the program. This year, there are two such circumstances which will be of significant concern to state governments.
1. Public Law 95-113 established a ceiling of approximately $6.2 billion
for FY 1980 appropriations for food stamps.
The Department of Agriculture
estimates that, with no changes in current legislation (except for removal of
this cap), normal expenditures would reach S6.9 billion or more. Under the
terms of P.L. 95-113, unless this cap is raised above the level of program need,
food stamp benefits would be reduced across the board to account for the shortfall. Therefore, the expendable income of low-income individuals and families
will drop accordingly, with state and local governments finding themselves on the
firing line in local welfare offices when such reductions occur. The department
will seek legislation to remove the cap or eliminate its impact in 1980.
Final
disposition of this matter will rest with Congress.
The administration's proposal to eliminate the cap is consistent with the interests of state
governments seeking to reduce, rather than increase, the welfare burden they
carry.
2. The administration also will propose legislation to establish a quality
control program with fiscal sanctions directed at state government administration of the food stamp program.
Important decisions remain to be made concerning
the details of this program and its sanctions. Virtually every state would be
affected, however, under the program being considered. USDAis projecting federal
savings of $150 million. At this time, discussion is concentrating on instituting a quality control program resembling that which HEWwiill formally institute
in the AFDCand Medicaid programs within the next 60 days. A target error rate
will be set independently for each state, with sanctions imposed for failure to
perform at, or better than, the established target. This proposal is particularly worrisome in view of the expected results from implementation during
calendar year 1979 of food stamp program changes mandated by the 95th Congress,
especially elimination of the purchase requirement, which both federal and
state officials believe will lead to higher error rates.

42

179
School Lunch and Other Nutrition Programs
Outlays for the school lunch program and other nutrition programs that
financially assist states are estimated to increase by only. S68 million, or
1.8 percent, over the FY 1979 level of $3.831 billion. The administration expects
to save $358 million through proposed legislation that would better target
these resources to needy children. This legislation would:
* reduce lunch and breakfast subsidies by 5 cents for
children from families with incomes above $13,845;
* revise eligibility requirements for free and reducedprice meals:
* end subsidies for special milk programs in schools in
which the federal government already pays for milK; and
* prohibit private sponsors of summer food programs from using
private food vendors.
State administrative
1979 level of S32 million
However, funding would be
million in FY 1979 to S20

costs for FY 1980 would be increased from the FY
to 534.9 million for child nutrition programs.
reduced for equipment assistance to states from S24
million in FY 1980.

The budget for the Women, Infants
increase by $200 million in FY 1980 to
requested additional FY 1980 funds for
The FY 1980 budget for this program is
of $202.5 million over FY 1979.

and Children program is estimated to
S750 million.I The administration also
the commodity supplemental food program.
proposed a' S21.5 million, an increase

SOCIAL SERVICES
The FY 1980 social services budoet, including Title XX, aging, child
welfare services, and rehabilitation services, is basically a current-services
budget that allows for neither expansion nor the impact of inflation on programs
that, because of their "labor intensive" nature, are peculiarly sensitive to
increases in the cost of livino. Cuts have been made primarily in research and
demonstration projects and in training. See the chart at the end of this section
for a summary of the president's spending decisions.
Title XX Grants to States
The president's budget would increase the permanent entitlement ceiling for
Title XX to S2.9 billion from the current lid of $2.5 billion. This represents
no real increase above current services since Conoress approved funding at the
$2.9 billion level for FY 1979. It is expected that Congress will make this
amount permanent early in the session. In addition, the budget eliminates the
$200 million "earmark" for child day care services which has existed for the past
two years. This will become part of the S2.9 billion ceiling and revert from
its special 100 percent fundinc level to the 75 percent/25 percent match

43

180
(90 percent/10 percent for family planning) required under Title XX. For some
states, this will mean an increase in expenditures to maintain services previously
funded under their allotment of the 100 percent "day care" monies. The administration also will propose legislation to provide a separate fundino authority
of $16.1 million for the territories so they can plan more adequately for their
service programs.
Currently, the territories can spend up to that amount but
the funds must come out of whatever is left under the ceiling after all state
programs have been funded.
Title XX Training
Over the past two years, states have sought modification of regulations
limiting their ability to adequately develop Title XX training programs to meet
a number of objectives. These objectives include retraining personnel as
a resultof: deinstitutionalization programs; a reallocation of resources and
services resulting from the implementation of the Title XX planning process;
increased demands for greater accountability;and changes in client populations.
The states have therefore identified training as an integral component of efforts
to move toward more rational, comprehensive social services systems.
In FY
1980, however, the oresident is proposing a "cap" on training funds (currently
funded outside the Title XX ceiling) of 3 mercent of the state's total allotment. This figure is based on the level of training over the past few years
and would allow for no growth to respond to the added flexibility called for
by the states.
In fact, for over a dozen states this would represent a cutback
from current services. The administration justifies this cap on the basis of
"the unprecedentedly rapidly growing state and local training program."
Funding for Title XX training has grown only from $60 million in FY 1976 to $72
million in FY 1978. The administration estimates, however, that costs could reach
over S100 million in FY 1980 and therefore is requesting $26 million less than
the projected need.Child Welfare Services
The president is calling for increased spending of almost $85 million for
child welfare services, up from the current level of S56.5 million to a total of
$141 million in FY 1980. The administration will propose legislation similar tothe
bill it introduced in the last Congress and with provisions similar to those
contained in the child welfare services/adoption subsidy sections of HR 7200.
Last year's administration bill would have increased the funding for child
welfare services from its current level to its fully authorized level of $266
million over a period of years, provided that states make improvements in their
reporting and tracking systems and use additional funding to expand protection
for children in foster care. Although the last Congress did not act, there is a
great deal of interest in Pushing a child welfare services bill early in this
Congress.
Programs for the Aging
The FY 1980 budget calls for no increases in programs for the aging, except
for a $23 million increase in nutrition programs (consistent with the thrust of
the reauthorization of the Older Americans Act passed last year) and $15 million
for long-term care projects (see below).

44

181
Rehabilitation Services
The FY 1980 budget calls for no increase in basic state grants, although
it does call for a $2 million supplemental appropriation for FY 1979 and $10
million for FY 1980 to fund the new independent living section of the
Rehabilitation Amendments of 1978 for services to persons not capable of
employment.
Long -Term Ca re
The president is calling for $15 million to be spent by the Administration
on Aging for long-term care projects. Under the proposal, projects in ten
states will examine, improve, and develop state and community information and
referral networks for identifying the long-term care service needs of aged,
blind, or disabled persons and for streamlining services to meet those needs.
The projects are to be developed jointly by ACA, the Rehabilitation Services
Administration, the Social Security Administration, and the Public Health
Service. In addition, an increase of another $15 million is proposed for
research and demonstrations, funded by the Health Care Financing Administration,
that would focus on alternative methods of financing and delivering services
and on alternative reimbursement and utilization review systems.

The following chart summarizes the major items in the president's social
services budget.
FY 1978, FY 1979 AND FY 1980 BUDGET
AUTHORITY
SELECTED SOCIAL SERVICES PROGRAMS
(S in Millions)
FY 1978

FY 1979

FY 1980

Change

$2,500

$2,7D0

$2,900

+200

--

-200

Title XX
Basic Services
Child Day Care
(P.L. 94-401)

200

Terri tories

--

Training
Total
Child Welfare Services
(Title IV-B)

200
--

72

72

$2,772

$2,972

56.5

56.5

16

+ 16

751

+ 31

$2,991

+ 19

141

+ 8A.5

Programs for the Aging

509

521

559

Rehabilitation Services

875

929

919

+ 38
- 7

1.

The Administration estimates that states will spend $101 million in 1980;
therefore, the budget request represents a cut of $26-million.
45

182
Employment and Training

The administration is continuing to rely heavily on targeted job creation and training programs to ease unemployment. While there is a projected
phase-down of the counter-cyclical public service employment component of the
CETA program, the administration projects this will be partially offset by
the private employers' increased use of the recently enacted jobs tax credit.
Two special youth programs reflect a major retaroeting within the budget.
The first is the phase-out of a congressionally mandated job entitlement experiment and has no major impact on the formula grants to state and local
governments. The second cut is the proposed reduction by one-half of funding
for the Young Adult Conservation Corps, of which the states are guaranteed
30 percent of the total for state-administered projects. The administration
said it is reducing this program because it prefers to target job creation
efforts on programs that serve the economically disadvantaged. This program
has no income criteria attached to eligibility and therefore has not received
the administration's support for maintenance of current levels of expansion.
The projected increase in the unemployment insurance program is consistent
with the expectation of a downturn in the economy in the next year and the
interaction of various program changes.
The chart below summarizes spending levels for federal employment and
training programs projected for FY 1979 and proposed for FY 1980.

SUMMARY
CHART
AND TRAINING
EMPLOYMENT
($ millions)
FY 1979
Budget Authority
CETA

1 0 ,6 5 2 -/

FY 1980
Outlays
10,292

Budget Authority
9,154/

Outlays
9,563

Older Americans

221

210

235

219

WIN

385

372

385

378

Fed/State ESb/

745

745

762

762

91

90

86

79

12,094

11,710'

10,623

11,002

Program Support
Total

a/ includes reappropriated funds of $7 million in FY 1979 and $122 million in FY 1980.
Total direct program costs for grants to states for UI and ES is $1,797 million
in FY 1980.

183
COMPREHENSIVE EMPLOYMENT
ANDTRAINING ACT (CETA)
CETA FUNiDIW1

($ millions)
FY 1979
Budget Authority
Title II ABC
Title III
Public Service
Employment
Title II D

FY 1980
Outlays

Budget Authority

Outlays

1914

1875

2054

1948

372

659

326

404

2517

2284

2536.5

2359

Title VI

3475

3181

2190.5

2571

Total Youth (Titles
IV and VIII)
Job Corps

1967

2243

1925

2131

(296)

(375)

(416)

(400)

Summer Youth

(740)

(681)

(411a/')

(545)

YCCIP

(107)

(140)

(134)

(140)

YIEPP

(107)

(148)

-

(43)

YETP

(500)

(592)

(798)

(850)

YACC(VIII)

(217)

(307)

(166)

(153)

Title VII
Total CETA

.

400

50

10,645

10,292

9,032

150
9,563

a/ An additional $122 million will be requested to keep the program at current
levels through FY 1980, bringing total CETA budget authority to $9.1 billion.
Total CETAoutlays under the budget request would decline by 7 percent
in FY 1980. Most of the reduction comes from a decrease in Title VI from
the current level of 358,000 PSEslots to 200,000 by the end of FY 1980.
Title VI authorized funding for 20 percent of the number of unemployed over
4 percent nationally, which in FY 1980, with an unemployment rate of around
6.1 percent, would call for about 400,000 job slots. The 200,000 jobs represent only about one-half of the congressional authorization. Title II-D,
the structural unemployment PSEprogram, is expected to remain at current
levels, 267,000 job slots. Also included in FY 1980 funding request for II-D
is $175 million for 17,000 welfare reform demonstration job slots.
The youth employment programs are projected at about the same level as
FY 1979, but have been re-targeted to the most "cost-effective" programs.
The Youth Incentive Entitlement Pilot Projects program will be phased out in
FY 1980, and outlays for Summer Youth and Young Adult Conservation Corps have
been reduced by $136 million and $154 million respectively. These funds are

47

184
transferred to the Youth Employment and Training Program ($258 million in
outlays) and Job Corns ($25 million increase in outlays). Total job slots
for youth programs will decline by 228,700 from the current level of 1,224,000,
reflecting, among other things, the 250,000 loss in Summer Youth slots. However, the Department of Labor has requested that $122 million in FY 1979 unobligated
funds be deferred for spending in FY 1980 for the Summer Youth Program.
Also reflected in the totals is an expected supplemental request by
DOLfor $400 million in budget authority for Title VII, the private sector
initiative program. This request will provide $50 million in outlays in
FY 1979, $150 million in each of FY 1980 and FY 1981, and $50 million in
FY 1982. DOL expects that Title VII will provide 80,000 jobs by the end of
FY 1980.
OTHEREMPLOYMENT
AND TRAINING PROGRAMS
FY 1979
Budget Authority

FY 1980
Outlays

Budget Authority

Outlays

Older Workers

221

210

235

219

WIN

385

372

385

378

The request for the Older Workers programs would maintain the current
level of 47,500 job opportunities under Title V of the Older Americans Act
(OAA).
The 1978 amendments to OAAauthorized an expansion in funding of um
to $400 million in FY 1980. The Work Incentive program is expected to remain
at the FY 1979 level in FY 1980.
The $20 million increase appropriated in FY 1979
over the FY 1978 level of $365 million, and again requested
FY 1980, will
be used to improve employment and training strategies and for welfare reform
model s.
EMPLOYMENT
SECURITY GRANTS TO STATES
Grants to states for the administration of unemployment insurance and
employment service orograms will increase by 4.7 percent, from $1.715 billion
in FY 1979 to $1.796 billion in FY 1980. State administrative expenses for
the UI program are projected to increase from S996 billion in FY 1979 to
$1.055 billion in FY 1980. This figure reflects an increase of 560 staff
yedrs for state UI programs (a 1.2 percent increase in staffing). At the same
time, the volume of UI claims is projected to rise from 2.2 million workers
per week to 2.6 million workers per week (an 18 percent increase in claims
volume).
State employment service programs are recommended to increase from
5719.6 million in FY 1979 to S742 million in FY 1980 (a 3.1 increase),
although ES staffing levels will be held constant at the 30,000 staff year
ceiling, which has remained relatively constant over the past 14 years. Not
less than $80 million of the overall ES budget (10.8 percent) is to be earmarked for services to veterans.
48

185
Of the total budget for employment security grants to states, S22.3
million is paid for out of general revenues; the balance of funding is provided
by the federal unemployment trust fund.
UNEMPLOYMENT
INSURANCE BENEFITS TO WORKERS
The economic projections for calendar year 1980 show the total unemployment rate averaging 6.2 percent for the year. Insured unemployment
(that is, unemployment among workers covered by state unemployment insurance
laws) is expected to increase from 3.1 percent in calendar year 1979 to
3.2 percent in calendar year 1980. Consistent with this change in unemployment,
higher wages, and added coverage, total outlays for unemployment compensation
benefits are projected to increase from $9.3 billion in FY 1979 to $11.3
billion in FY 1980 (a 21.5 percent increase). Of these total outlay figures,
Ul benefits paid under state laws are expected to amount to $8.2 billion in
FY 1979 and S10.1 billion in FY 1980.
Although revenue projections show that the federal share of UI benefits
can be financed without additional advances from general revenues to the
federal trust fund, some states may be forced to draw on federal general
revenue advances to meet the state portion of these increased benefit costs.
Some 20 states continue to carry outstanding UI debts, totaling nearly S4.5
billion, to the federal treasury from the 1975-76 recession.
CONGRESSIONAL OUTLOOK
Welfare reform will.provide the backdrop for the legislative debate on
employment and training this year. Although the 1980 budget does not reflect
any outlays for a revised welfare reform program, it is known that the administration is planning to submit to Congress this year a revised welfare reform
proposal containing a strong commitment to job creation. The administration
is projecting a need for approximately 700,000 jobs and/or training opportunities
for the "expected to work" welfare population. The administration estimates
that almost half of this demand can be met by current CETAresources. Much
of the debate will focus on how best to guarantee that CETA resources will be
used for the welfare eligible population. This is important to the states
who bear the cash cost of welfare reform but have no control over local CETA
decisions or recipients of PSE jobs.
The congressional debate also will focus on the economic assumptions and
appropriate program mixes of the counter-cyclical jobs program (CETATitle.VI)
and its adequacy to meet the goals of the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment Act.
A major part of that debate will be on how much funding should be made available for programs serving the economically disadvantaged through direct job
creation versus other types of grant-in-aid, such as counter-cyclical revenue
sharing.
Congress may restore the proposed cuts in the Young Adult Conservation
Corps since the program has always been Popular on Capitol Hill.

49

186
Education

The education community will reel the president's move toward a balanced
federal budget. FY 1980 budget authority for education is proposed at $14.335
billion, or $276 million below the FY 1979 level. FY 1980 budget authority
for education orograms within HEWis $12.338 billion, $382 million below the
FY 1979 level. The budget reflects an overall commitment to:
*

maintain the current level of funding for programs;

*

make modest increases in selected programs to implement
pre-announced policies; and

* cut or eliminate funding for certain programs previously
opposed by the administration.
The impact of the president's budget on states will not be negative in
the aggregate except that maintenance of current funding levels means a real
cut in funding levels when inflation is taken into account. The negative
impact, if any, will be felt by selected states, state agencies, or programs
directly affected by selected budget proposals. The following are highlights
of the budget for HEW's education programs.
ESEA
The largest part of this request is for Title I of the Elementary and
Secondary Education Act, designed to serve low-income, low-achieving students.
The administration is requesting that the basic Title I state grant program be
continued at the FY 1979 level of $3.1 billion in budget authority and outlays.
Title I funds are for use in school year 1980-81. The actual amount available
for basic grants, $2.6 billion, is due to increased funding taken "off the top"
for state programs and the increased cost of state administration. Additional
funds of $400 million are proposed for a new program authorized in the Education Amendments of 1978 to provide funding for areas with high concentrations
of low-income students. A supplemental appropriation of $258 million has been
The Education Amendments authorized
requested for this purpose in 1979.
a new program to provide additional Title I funds to schools in states participating in an incentive matching program for state compensatory education
No funds, however, are requested for either FY 1979 or FY 1980 to
programs.
implement this program,which was authorized at a $200 million level by Congress.

50

187
Education for the Handicapped
The president's budget proposes funding for FY 1980 of $1.028 billion for
programs for the education of handicapped children, an increase of $51 million
from FY 1979. Funding for state grants under P.L. 94-142, the Education for
All Handicapped Children Act, would be $862 million, an increase of only $58
million from the FY 1979 appropriations level. This funding level falls far
short of the amount authorized for FY 1980, which would provide 30 percent of
the average per-pupil expenditure for the. costs of special programs for handicapped children (approximately $1,700 per child) multiplied by the estimated
3.95 million handicapped children HEWanticipates being served in FY 1980.
Based on the above figures, the total authorization should be somewhere around
$2.0 billion in FY 1980. The $862 million proposed by the president represents
slightly more than 10 percent of the costs, per pupil, thus shifting the
additional costs to the states. States are faced with the requirement under
P.L. 94-142 that, as of September 1978, they must be serving and providing
full services to all handicapped children as a condition for receiving-assistance
under P.L. 94-142. With the exceptions of Pre-school Incentive Grants (-$3
million), Early Childhood Education (-$2 million), and Special Education Manpower
Development (-$2 million), funding for other programs benefitting handicapped
children is requested at FY 1979 levels.
Impact Aid
The administration is requesting a cut of $288 million in FY 1980 budget
authority from FY 1979 levels for impact aid. The program provides assistance
to local education agencies for the operating costs of educating children in
areas in which local school costs are affected by federal activity. No budget
authority is requested for payments for "B" children, children whose parents
work or live, but not both, on federal property. States having a significant
number of "B" children may need to generate additional state and/or local
revenues to replace this portion of impact aid funding.
Other Elementary and Secondary Education Programs
Support and innovation grants to state and local education agencies will
decrease by $25.5 million to a FY 1980 level of $197.4 million. Follow Through
and environmental education funding are proposed at FY 1979 levels of $59
million and $3.5 million, respectively. The administration has requested that
funds for bilingual education, basic skills improvement, and alcohol and drug
abuse education programs be increased. Funds for bilingual education would be
$23.6 million above the FY 1979 level of $150 million. Basic skills improvement, which represents a major transformation of the Right to Read Program, has
been proposed to increase by $8 million to $35 million in FY 1980, with an
additional $2 million earmarked for a new program of Achievement Testing
assistance. The administration's FY 1980 request of $3 million for drug and
alcohol abuse education is 50 percent greater than the FY 1978 amount. Indian
education programs are proposed to be funded at $4 million more than FY 1979
levels.

51

188
An increase of $13 million in budget authority for FY 1979 to assist
school districts engaged in Desegregation is also proposed. Some $700 million
is proposed in FY 1980 budget authority for Headstart, with a supplemental
appropriation of $155 million for FY 1979.
VOCATIONAL ANDADULT EDUCATION
The administration has proposed FY 1980 budget authority for occupational,
vocational, and adult education of $772 million, $10 million below FY 1979.
HIGHER EDUCATION
The FY 1930 administration request for higher education programs reflects
an increase of $14 million in budget outlays, but a decrease of $307 million
in budget authority relative to FY 1979. Of the requested FY 1980 budget
authority of $5 billion, $2.4 billion is proposed to fully fund the basic
opportunity grant program, for which families with incomes up to $25,000 are
eligible (a decrease from the FY 1979 level of $2.6 billion). FY 1979 levels
of $340 million, $77 million, and $550 million for supplemental education
opportunity grants, state student incentive grants, and the college work-study
program, respectively, are also proposed. An additional $960 million is
requested to provide $2.5 billion in loans under the guaranteed student loan
program authorized by the Middle Income Student-Assistance Act. The administration requested $220 million for federal capital contributions to institutional
loan funds under the National Direct Student Loan Program. This represents
a $94 million reduction in new budget authority from FY 1979. This is consistent with previous administration positions and reflects the administration's
interest in proposing major changes in federal loan programs during the reauthorization of the Higher Education Act in 1979-80.
The FY 1980 budget request also includes $130 million in budget authority
for Talent Search, Upward Bound, and Special Services programs and for educational opportunities centers. This represents a $15 million increase from the
FY 1979 request, but $10 million below the FY 1979 appropriation. Additional
budget authority of $18 million is proposed to assist minority students under
the bio-medical sciences and the graduate professions opportunities program.
Programs proposed for no funding include: educational information centers,
university community services and continuing education, and state postsecondary
education commissions. Additional funding is proposed for activities such as
international education and foreign language studies.
HEALTH PROFESSIONS EDUCATION
The president's budget continues previous administration policy of proposing
substantial cuts in funding of health professions education programs, especially
capitation grants to medical schools and other health professions institutions.

52

189
These changes are reflected in both rescissions of FY 1979 appropriations and
elimination of funding for FY 1980 for several programs within the Health
Resources Administration budget.
* Institutional assistance for the health professions (medicine,
osteopathy, dentistry, veterinary medicine, podiatry, pharmacy
and public health) is cut in half for FY 1979 and eliminated in
FY 1980. The actual FY 1979 appropriation for capitation grants
for these institutions is $144 million. The budget calls for
rescission of $76.7 million of the FY 1979 funding and then zero
funding for FY 1980. Approximately 55 percent of these funds go
to public institutions. Because these funds currently provide
basic support for the institutions, the cuts in the federal
budget are likely to lead to the need for replacement of the
funds by the states. This would mean additional state expenditures of approximately $42.2 million in FY 1979 and $37.0 million
in FY 1980 if the proposed cuts are approved.
* Support for allied health education is maintained at $13 million
for FY 1979 but eliminated in FYl1980.
* Support for nursing education is reduced from $37.9 million in
F' 1979 to $14.7 million in FY 1980, a cut of $23.2 million.
Assuming that approximately 55 percent of the funds for allied health
and nursing programs go to public institutions, the proposed health professions education cuts could mean a transfer of approximately $100 million
in costs to the states.
The table on the next page summarizes changes in education programs.

53

47-977 0 - 79 - 13

nS1979

and Ft 1980 Bodant Authboity and Bodget
All Federa i doati..n Progrran

nS1979
Elenentary. Secondary and
Voconlonat Educatnon
Elmn.tnary and Sneondany
Indian Edn-atian
Is pnt Aid
Edu-ction far the llandioapped
SccapatioI, V..o.ational
nnd Adult Edu..ti1n
Other
Caild DB-ulopnent
SObtotal

Badget
Atuthnrinv

Budget
Outlays

Ft 1980
Badget
Budget
OntlaYs
AuthoritY

uStlays for

Change in Budget Authoritty

In Oudget Outlayn

dan

3,779
335
816
977
782

3,034
302
800
525
S08

3,953
339
528
1,028
772

3,447
301
619
814
840

+174
4*4
-288
+51
-10

4.6S
1.2
35.3
5.2
1.3

+413
-i
-181
+289
+32

13.61
0.3
22.6
55.0
4.0

365
731
7.765

349
699
6,517

358
751
7,730

326
758
7,106

+13
+20
-35

3.8
2.3
0.5

-23
+59
+589

6.6
8.4
9.0

5.332

4,696

5,013

.4,702

-319

6.0

+6

0.1

175
5,507

177
4,873

188
5,200

185
4,887

+13
-307

7.6
5.6

+8
+14

5
4.5
0.3

101
89

118
98

104
90

-5
-6

4.4
6.5

+3
+1

3.0
1.1

29
530
523
15272

33
638
518
1 405

26
592
518
1_330

0
+79
-23
+66

0
14.1
4.3
4.9

-3
+62
-14
+58

10.3
11.7
2.7
4.6

12,662

14,335

13,323

-276

1.9

+661

5.2

Higher Education
Student Aid 6 I.stitatinnal
aSupport
l Inetitatlons
+> Specit
Shbt tal

Rgsau.ch &Gener-l Educ-tional Aide
Special Proecte a.d Training
National Institute of Edaoatwion
Other Edutigioal R6esearch
Cultural AI tieitiea
t ..
Other
Shbtot.l
TOTAL

113
92
33
359
5491
1,339
14,611

Onculudec cone education plrogroec ct

Ed-.cation Dlv]nun aithin IEW.
bdelo
itered by

191
Energy

Overall, energy program outlays are scheduled to drop in FY 1980 to $7.9
billion from $8.6 billion. This results from the interaction of four factors:
(1) increases in outlays of over $100 million each for solar research
and technology, other energy supply technology, and conservation
grants;
(2) reductions in outlays of over $100 million each for nuclear fission
research, uranium enrichment, power marketing, and costs characterized
as administrative expenses;
(3) major increases in petroleum reserve receipts which are an offset to
expenditures; and
(4) other smaller increases and decreases in outlays.
Items of particular interest to the states in the FY 1980 budget include:
o

establishment of the State Energy Management and Planning program, which
restructures several existing grant activities and provides more flexibility for states;

° a significant increase in funding to develop technology to manage safely
both commercial and defense-generated nuclear wastes;
° a realignment of the fossil energy development program to deemphasize
large single technology demonstration facilities and to focus funding
on most promising technologies; and
O

additional emphasis on environmental assessment of emerging energy
technologies at each stage of development.

SOLAR ENERGY
Solar energy receives considerable emphasis in the FY 1980 budget. Total
outlays of all federal departments for solar energy are budgeted to rise by over
thirty percent. Total costs of solar energy development (including tax expenditures) exceed $800 million in FY 1980. These costs are to be distributed as
shown on the next page.

55

o

192
.

FY 1980 COSTS(OUTLAYS ANDTAX EXPENDITURES)

($ millions)
Activity
Solar research and technology development
Solar demonstration and applications
Solar tax credits (revenue loss)
Total Costs

FY 1979

FY 1980

$333

$465

218

265

88

74

$639

$804

ENERGY
CONSERVATION
The Administration has requested a total budget authority of $555 million
for conservation research and development and grant programs. This represents
a substantial reduction in budget authority, but outlays are expected to increase
by 35 percent. Included is a 17 percent reduction from last year's funding for
Delayed passage
the Department of Energy's (DOE) conservation orograms.
of the National Energy Act caused many of the programs involved to get underway
slowly so considerable budget authority from prior years can support increased
outlays in FY 1980 despite a budget authority cut in FY 1980.
Weatherization programs are to be continued at the same level as in
FY 1979 in terms of budget authority, but outlays will rise. Budget authority
for schools, hospitals and other local government activities will drop sharply,
but prior appropriations will fund increasing outlays.
Funds made available last year for the state energy conservation program,
supplemental program, and energy extension service have been consolidated into
The legisone budget request for State Energy Management and Planning (SEMP).
lative proposal for SEMPwill restructure existing grant programs and consolidate
grant administration procedures for other state energy conservation programs
administered by DOE. The table on the next page illustrates the distribution
of energy conservation funds to selected state programs.

56

193
SELECTED STATE ENERGY
CONSERVATION PROGRAMS

($ millions)
FY 1979 est.
Authority
Outlays
Schools and Hospitals Grant
Programs

100.1

Other Local Government
Buildings Grant Program
Weatherization

59.7

FY 1980 est.
Autho
y
Outlays
2.5

138.71/

29.8

18.0

0.2

17.0

199.0

128.5

199.0

174.0

78.6

110.0

96.4

State Enerqv Management

82.82/

1/ Carry-over funding from FY 1979 is expected to provide funding for this
program in FY 1980.
2/ This figure represents the total budget authority for EPCA, ECPA, and
the Energy Extension Service grant programs which will be merged into
SEMPin FY 1980.
The administration's recommendation to consolidate the conservation programs
is responsive to the Governors' recommendations to the president that broad grants
are more effective than narrow categorical programs.
FOSSIL ENERGY
PROGRAMS
The level of support provided for fossil energy programs suggests that the
administration has reduced the budget from the level that would have supported
all of the research efforts sought by the Department of Energy.
Requests for
synthetic gas demonstrations and petroleum research and development appear to
have suffered the most significant cuts. Highlights of the fossil energy
budget include:
° increases in research on fuel gas desulfurization and other environmental control techniques;
° a new initiative to test four industrial atmospheric fluidized beds; and
o

completion of construction of pilot coal liquefaction plants in Texas
and Kentucky.

The budget for the environmental program of the Department of Energy also
contains funds for additional studies on coal combustion and conversion and
expansion of research and assessment studies on the effects of increasing carbon
dioxide in the atmosphere.

57

194
MINING
SURFACE
Budget authority for surface mining programs is requested at a level that
will sharply increase the overall level of funding for those programs in 1980.
Outlays will nearly double to $148 million in FY 1980.
The budget requests made by the Office of Surface Mining were not cut by
OMB,with the exception of funding for the abandoned land reclamation program.
If state regulatory programs are approved more quickly than is expected, there
is a possibility that these funds could be restored through a FY 1980 supplemental appropriation.
Budget authority for the Office of Surface I;ning programs is shown below:

MINING ACTIVITIES
SURFACE
(S millions)
Budget Authority
FY 1980
FY 1979

Fund/Activity
General Fund
State Regulatory Program Grants

$ 20.9

$ 22.7
37.8

Federal Regulatory Programs

28.5

Mineral Institutes

10.7

5.8

4.0

15.0

$ 64.1

$ 81.3

$ 8.0

$ 27.0

55.7
12.5

51.5

$ 76.2

$ 93.5

Small Operator Assistance Payments
Total Budget Authority, General Fund
Abandoned Mine Reclamation Fund (excluding
funding adjustments)
State Reclamation Program Grants
Federal Reclamation Program
Small Operator Assistance Payments
Total (excluding funding adjustments)
Abandoned Mine Fund

15.0

The regulatory program grant levels will continue activities in the
interim regulatory program and are expected to cover funding for the permanent programs which are supposed to be established by June 1980. The
abandoned mines grant level anticipates that 27 states will have their programs
for the use of these funds approved by the end of the fiscal year.

58

195
NUCLEAR WASTEMANAGEMENT
The Department of Energy's nuclear waste efforts are to be increased
significantly in two areas in FY 1980:
(1) the Spent Fuel Storage program for implementation of the president's
October 1977 commitment to provide,interim storage for commercially
generated spent nuclear fuel; and
(2) increased efforts in Defense Waste Management aimed at long-term solutions for defense nuclear waste disposal.
Separate legislation will be proposed in early 1979 to authorize the
department to acquire and operate by 1983 spent fuel storage facilities for
commercial nuclear fuel. This legislation also will authorize DOEto make a
one-time spent fuel storage charge on users sufficient to cover all costs of
storage and disposal incurred by the government. Some $300 million will be requested in separate enabling legislation with FY 1980 estimated offsetting
revenues of $100 million.
The $115 million increase in Defense Waste Management includes funding for
handling storage and transfer of high-level and transuranic waste forms, continuation of design work for the Waste Isolation Pilot Plant (WIPP), operation of
Waste Calcining Facilities, transportation R&D and related studies, which are all
activities geared toward optimum long-temr disposition of spent fuel.
Commercial waste management, with proposed funding of $199 million, will
continue work on a deep geologic nuclear waste repository for commercially generated waste, with expanded efforts in the evaluation of various geological
environments, including non-salt media.
The decontamination and decommissioning program will shift its emphasis
from planning, engineering studies, and cleanup of DOE-owned facilities to
cleanup operations for remedial action at several former Manhattan Engineer
District/Atomic Energy Commission facilities.
DOENUCLEAR
WASTEMANAGEMENT
PROGRAMS
(S in Millions)
FY 1979
Defense Waste Management
Commercial Waste Management
Spent Fuel Storage
Decontamination &-Decommissioning
TOTAL NUCLEAR WASTE

FY 1980_

BA
S257.0
190.7
11.4
25.4

BO
5277.9
166.9
7.4
23.9

BA
$371.9
199.4
320.5
32.6

BO
S406.2
193.6
27.3
28.4

S484.5

$476.1

$924.4

$655.5

59

196
ENERGY
IMPACT ASSISTANCE
The budget includes a request (which is shown in community and economic
development rather than energy totals) for $150 million for FY 1980 for the
Economic Development Administration (EDA) to make grants to states and Indian
tribes to aid communities facing the adverse impacts of rapid energy development. For each of five years beginning in 1980 the program would provide
$15 million for planning grants and $135 million for implementation grants,
primarily to capitalize state revolving funds that would make grants and loans
to local areas for infrastructure improvements.
Matching contributions of state
and tribal funds for the implementation of impact mitigation strategies would
be required. The basic principles of this proposed program were presented to
Congress last session and were contained in the Inland Energy Impact Assistance
proposal (S1493) introduced by Senators Hart and Randolph.
The administration did not request any funding for the new Section 601
energy impact assistance program, which was authorized last year in the
National Energy Act. However, should the administration's new energy impact
bill encounter resistance in the Congress, it is understood that the administration might support funding through Section 601 rather than the new bill.
The Coastal Energy Impact Program is proposed for no funding in FY 1980
for the loan program because an estimated $130 million will be available in
that fiscal year from prior year appropriations. Outlays in the program are
expected to rise from $11 million in FY 1979 to $54 million in FY 1980.
OVERVIEW OF THE ENERGY
BUDGET
The energy budget reflects continuing increases in support of solar
energy and conservation, and, overall, attempts to constrain the growth of the
budget.

60

197
BUDGETAUTHORITY FORTHEDEPARTMENT
OF ENERGY
($ millions)
Activity

FY 1979

FY 1980

3,010

2,999

( 522
( 723
( 1,100
( 1,614
(- 959

589

Energy Supply
Solar Research and Technology Development
Fossil Research and Technology Development
Nuclear Fission Research and Technology
Other Energy Supply Activities
Offsetting Energy Supply Receipts

772
937
1,882
-1,181

Energy Conservation

659

555

Energy Information, Policy and Regulation

980

1,003

Offsetting Receipts

-

Total Regular Activities
Special Appropriation for TVA Capital Outlays
Emergency Energy Preparedness (stockpile)
Grand Total

96

-

84

4,553

4,473

0

15,000

3,007
7,560

8
19,482

Budget authority fluctuates sharply between FY 1979 and FY 1980 for two major
reasons. The FY 1980 budget includes $15 billion in authority for the Tennessee
Valley Authority to borrow funds to support power plant construction. Also,
much of the authority provided for purchases of petroleum for the stockpile
has not yet been used, so substantial added authority is not needed in FY 1980
to support the stockpile program.

61

198
Emergency Management

The creation of the Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA), to be
formally activated on March 25, 1979, consolidates in one agency the activities formerly carried out by numerous federal agencies and offices. The
most prominent agencies to be consoldiated are: the Defense Civil Preparedness Agency, the Federal Preparedness Agency, the United States Fire Administration, the Federal Insurance Administration, and the Federal Disaster
Assistance Administration.
In addition, FEMAwill administer activities of
the National Insurance Development Fund and the National Flood Insurance
Fund.
The budget calls for an FY 1980 spending level of $259 million, down
slightly from the $263 million estimated outlays for FY 1979. The decrease
represents expected savings derived from the consolidation into one agency of
the activities of numerous programs formerly administered by several departments and independent agencies. The budget figure for the new agency essentially represents level funding for the component parts of FEMA.
The new agency will continue to carry out a number of state-related
activities. These fall into three areas:
a

Civil Defense: matching grants to state and local governments
to develop and operate civil defense programs and to design,
construct, equip, and operate state emergency operations centers;

* Disaster Mitigation:
funds to support hazard mitigation programs
and activities, such as flood insurance, flood studies and
surveys, planning assistance to states for natural disaster preparedness and mitigation programs, and training and education
programs to upgrade fire service personnel; and
* Disaster Relief: grants to states for preparedness planning for
natural and man-made disasters, and a wide range of disaster
relief aid and assistance.

62

199
Agriculture

The FY 1980 budget for agriculture proposes a major reduction from FY 1979
levels. Total budget authority drops from $8.3 billion in FY 1979 to $4.9

billion in FY 1980.

This reduction is caused primarily by assumptions of substantially lower
costs for agricultural price supports and export credits. Whether these reductions will be realized in practice will depend on world market conditions
and prices. The administration'sbudget is based on the assumption of strong
international demand and lower domestic production of such commodities as feed
grains.
Outlays for the agricultural research and service functions of the Department of Agriculture are expected to decline from $1.3 billion in FY 1979 to
$1.2 billion in FY 1980. Within the research program, funds are being redirected
from other areas of research to permit increases in research for food safety,
human nutrition, conservation and natural resources, pest management, and basic
plant research activities.
The budget calls for a reduction of personnel in the Department of Agriculture from an estimated 85,000 in FY 1979 to 82,700 in FY 1980, with major
reductions in the Soil Conservation Service, Forest Service, and in-house
research capabilities.
Food safety and marketing systems programs would remain at the FY 1979 level
of $411 million with a $1.6 million decrease in grants to state marketing agencies,
under the administration's proposal.
Some key programs of the Department of Agriculture are discussed in other
portions of this analysis. Following the format of the budget, food stamps
are discussed in connection with income maintenance programs, and rural development and housing are considered with economic and community development
programs of other agencies.

63

200
OTHERPROGRAMS
STATE ARTS PROGRAMS

National Endo-ment for the Arts
While there is a $5 million increase in the total proposed budget for the
National Endowment for the Arts for FY 1980, the increase is in matching funds
which are more readily available to institutions than to states and communities.
The proposed budget for program and administration decreases slightly from the
FY 1979 level. State grants are earmarked at 20 percent of the program budget.

Arts Funding
($ millions)

Salaries and Expenses
Admi nistration
Program

FY 1979

FY 1980

111.9

107.5

9.8

10.5

102.2

97.0

Matching Grants
Treasury Funds

73.5

30.0

Challenge Grants

20.0
26.9

Livable Cities
The proposed budget contains $5 million for the livable cities program
passed by the 95th Congress as one of the urban policy initiatives. The
program has an FY 1980 authorizatianof $10 million, to be expended in grants
made by HUDto states and communities for artistic or cultural projects aimed
at revitalizing communities and neighborhoods. This is a new program which
had no FY 1979 appropriation but may receive a $5 million supplemental
appropriation for FY 1979.

64

201
International Trade and Foreign Relations
The president proposes to commit $14 million to the export development
initiatives recommended in his National Export Policy. The bulk of these
funds will come from savings realized as the result of closing six tourism
development centers abroad and five trade oromotion facilities in foreign
locations.
The administration's program calls for comprehensive trade promotion,
including the collection of international tourism data to provide policy
recommendations, technical assistance, and coordination of governmental
organizations.
The Agency for International Development programs for basic needs in
poor countries to aid in the promotion of economic growth are estimated to
rise from $1.2 billion in 1979 to $1.3 billion in 1980. P.L. 480, food aid
for humanitarian relief, is proposed for FY 1980 outlays of $1 billion,
which would permit shipment of 6.7 million tons of food. This level meets
two-thirds of the worldwide food aid target of 10 million needed tons.

65

202
VI. GLOSSARY
APPROPRIATION--The spending limit set by Congress for each federal
program.
AUTHORIZATION--Basic legislation enacted by Congress that sets up or
continues the legal operation of a federal program or agency.
Such legislation is normally a prerequisite for subsequent
appropriations, but does not usually provide budget authority
(see below).
AUTHORITY (BA)--Authority provided by law which permits federal
BUDGET
agencies to spend or to make loans.
BUDGETRECEIPTS--Money collected from the public by the federal government through taxes, premiums paid by voluntary participants in
federal social insurance programs and gifts apd contributions.
BUDGET-SURPLUS (+) OR DEFICIT (-)--The difference between budget receipts
and outlays for any given period.
RESOLUTION ON THE BUDGET--A resolution passed by both houses
CONCURRENT
of Congress, but not requiring the signature of the president,
setting forth, reaffirming, or revising specified congressional
budget totals for the federal government for a fiscal year.
CONTINUING RESOLUTION--Legislation enacted by Congress to provide budget
authority for specific ongoing activities when a regular appropriation for such activities has not been enacted by the beginning of
the fiscal year.
CONTRnLLABILITY--In the president's budget this refers to the ability of
the president to control budget authority or outlays during a fiscal
year without changing existing substantive law. The concept "relatively uncontrollable" includes outlays for open-ended programs and
fixed costs, such as interest on the public debt, and social security
and veterans benefits, as well as outlays to liquidate prior-year
obligations.
CURRENT SERVICES ESTIMATES--Projections of the amount it would cost during
the coming fiscal year to continue programs at the same level as
during the fiscal year in progress. The Congressional Budget and
Impoundment Control Act of 1974 requires that the president transmit
current-services estimates to Congress.
DEFERRAL--Any action or inaction by a federal agency to temporarily withhold
or delay expenditure of funds. Deferrals may not extend beyond the end
of-the fiscal year and may be overturned at any time by either house
of Congress.

66

203FISCAL YEAR--The yearly accounting period for the federal government
which begins on October 1 and ends on September 30. The fiscal
year is designated by the calendar year in which it ends. e.g.,
fiscal year 1980 is the fiscal year ending September 30, 1980.
(Prior to fiscal year 1977 the fiscal year began on July 1 and
ended on June 30.)
OBLIGATIONS--Commitments made by federal agencies during a given period or
that will require outlays during the same of some future period.
OFF-BUDGET FEDERALENTITIES--Organizational entities, federally owned
in whole or in part, whose transactions belong in the budget under
current budget accounting concepts but which have been excluded
from the budget totals under provisions of law. While these
transactions are not included in the budget totals, information on
these entities is presented in various places in the budget documents.
OFFSETTING RECEIPTS--Collections deposited in receipt accounts that are
offset against budget authority and outlays rather than counted
as budget receipts. These are collections from other government
accounts or from transactions with the public that are of a
business-type or market-oriented nature (such as sales, interest.
or loans).
OUTLAYS--Checks issued, interest accrued on the public debt, or other
payments made, net of refunds and reimbursements.
RESCISSION--Enacted legislation canceling budget authority previously
provided by Congress.
SUPPLEMENTAL APPROPRIATION--An appropriation enacted as an addition to
a regular annual appropriation act. Supplemental appropriation
acts provide additional budget authority beyond original estimates
for programs or activities (including new programs authorized after
the date of the original appropriation act) for which the need for
funds is too urgent to be postponed until the next regular appropriation.
TAX EXPENDITURES--Losses of tax revenue attributable to provisions of the
federal tax law that allow a special exclusion, exemption, or
deduction from gross income or provide a special credit, preferential
rate of tax, or a deferral of tax liability.

NOTE:

The sources for this glossary are "Budgetary Definitions" published
by the General Accounting Office in July 1977 and the Budget of
the United States Government, 1979.
67

204
VII. APPENDIX
Congressional Budget Process
Congressional consideration of the President's budget has, since 1975, been
governed by the procedural requirements of the Congressional Budget Act.
The initial step in the process is the submission of the president's budget
in mid-January. Shortly after the budget is submitted, the budget committees in
the House and Senate hold hearings on the budget and the economic assumptions
on which it is based.
A number of separate actions then take place in preparation for budget
committee action. The standing committees advise the budget committees on likely
programs and outlays to be authorized during the year. The Joint Economic Committee advises on the economic outlook and appropriate fiscal policy. The Congressional Budget Office reviews the budget, makes economic projections, and then
files a report dealing with national economic policy, alternative total budget
levels and national budget priorities.
Based on these materials and the results of its own hearings, the budget
committees recommend a first concurrent resolution on the budget to their respective houses by April 15. This resolution covers the recommended levels of
budget authority and outlays in total and for each of the major functions in
the budget (but not for individual programs), the deficit, the total levels of
revenues and expenditures, and the changes in federal debt implied by the other
decisions. The first budget resolution establishes targets for budget authority
and outlays. These budget targets, which represent a congressional determination
of appropriate fiscal policy and national budget priorities, guide Congress in
its subsequent spending and revenue decisions. However, the allocations for
each function are not binding on Congress at this stage. Using the normal procedures for enacting a resolution, including a conference committee to reconcile
differences between the two houses, Congress approves the first resolution by
May 15.
The May 15 date is also important because it is the deadline for reporting
legislation authorizing new budget authority. Authorizing bills reported after
that date, with a few exceptions, are subject to a point of order unless an
emergency waiver is granted.
In a statement which accompanies the first budget resolution, the totals
for functions (e.g.,community and economic development) are divided up among
the committees of the House and Senate, so that each committee is working
against a known, but non-binding, ceiling.
Under the budget process, Congress comDletes action on bills and resolutions
providing new budget authority and new spending authority by one week after
Labor Day.
Exceptions are made for appropriation bills that cannot proceed
until authorizing bills are passed. Exceptions also arise when Congress is
unable to agree on particular bills, as when an issue such as abortion holds
up appropriation bills.

68

205
The Congress is scheduled to mass a second budget resolution by September
15. Thi resolution covers the same subjects as the first one, but is binding.
It reflects updating estimates of both expenditures and revenues as well as any
program decisions that have changed since the first resolution. Based on this
resolution, the schedule calls for the Congress to complete action on "reconciliation" bills and resolutions by September 25. These measures are used to alter
previously passed appropriations legislation to conform to the totals of the
second resolution. Reconciliation action must be completed by October 1, when
the federal government begins its new fiscal year.

For information on how the budget process worked last year, see the chart on
page 71.

69

47-977 0 - 79 - 14

206
NOTESON THE TABLE

In considering what Congress might do to the president's FY 1980 recommendations, it is interesting to examine what changes Congress made in the
This is shown in the table on the next page.
FY 1979 recommendations.
The table clearly indicates that Congress followed the president's recommendations on total revenues (although the president's tax package was changed
substantially in its details) and made major reductions in outlays, concentrating on defense and energy while providing for significant increases in veterans
programs and agriculture. However, not all of the reductions made by Congress
necessarily reduce final outlays, though increases usually do increase outlays.
When reductions are made in programs whose costs are determined by uncontrollable
factors (e.g., price supports and interest), outlays may rise above original
For example, the
estimates through the supplemental appropriations process.
total outlays shown for FY 1979 (the current fiscal year) in the "Congress"
president's
FY
1980 budget suggests
billion.
The
table
are
$487.5
column of the
that this figure will be $493.4 billion, a number much closer to what is shown
as the presidential recommendation than to what is shown as the congressional
figure.

70

207
COMPARISON
OF PRESIDENTIALNUDGErI
ACTION2 FOR FISCAL YEAR 1979
AND CONGRESSIONAL
OUTLAYS
(in billions of dollars)
O-tlays

President
496.6

CODZI
Ere48787.5

S Chance
- 9.1

440.2

4413.7

+0.5

Reveoe s

48.5

Deficit

3138.8

- 9.7

Fuoction
Nanionol Snenesn

114.6

112.4

7.4

7.1

- 0.3

5. 1

Intornai.onal Affairs
Coneral Science, Spanc,
and Tenhrology

- 2.2

5.0

- 0.1

10.4

8.1

- 2.3

11.8

11.5

5.6

7.5

+ 1.9

3.0

2.8

- 0.2

17.3

17.3

9.4

9.6

+ 0.2

Nacrorl Sosoornesand
Environr ent
Agricaltore

Cou-erne
-

Noosing Credit

Transportoni.n
Cor-unicy

&
Rgionol

Developrnoe

- 0.3

0

Educ.tion. Tr-Ining, REploynent,
and Social Services

31.4

30.3

- 1.1

Health

49.8

48.1

- 1.7

159.6

159.3

- 8.3

19.8

20.7

+ 0.9

Incose Sen.rity
Votone.

Bonefitte &
Seices

kdncolsnrarton of J.ntice

4.4

4.2

-0.2

General Covernenc

4.2

4.0

- 0.2

General Pnrpn-e Fis-l Adsistnee

9.5

8.8

- 0.7

49.0

48.0

- 1.0

1.1

.8

- 0.3

Allowances
Undistribnted Offortting Rece.its

-16. 6

-10.0

+ 1.4

Tonal Budgni Ontlayn

*96.6

487.5

- 9.1

Foo-nte.
1. 71idoessios Revies of the FY 1979 Bodget
2

Second Concorrent Reen.laio.

for FY 1979

71

Joly 6, 1978

208
Senator

BENTSEN.

Governor Snelling, please proceed.

STATEMENT OF HON. RICHARD A. SNELLING, GOVERNOR,
STATE OF VERMONT
Governor SNELLING. With your indulgence, Mr. Chairman, I will
not read the prepared statement I brought with me today. It is, of
course, available to you and to your staff, and it does represent the
point of view which I bring here as a representative and as authorized spokesman of the National Governors' Association. My decision not to read it is simply in the interest of time.
I would like to address, very specifically, your opening statement.
I am sure they must deal with the hard philosophic concerns that
undoubtedly you and the other members of the committee have.
Your concern is, as I understand it, that the States are in good
financial position, that they are coming to the Congress-Senator BENTSEN. In comparison.

Governor SNELLING [continuing]. In comparison, through resolu-

tions of their State legislatures, and are giving people back home to
believe that Congress should deal with the problem of excessive
Government spending.
At the same time, they are failing to show the Congress just how
specific savings can be made.
I would like to respond to that philosophy in the vein in which
you spoke, by saying that I think that historic circumstances that
have led to these circumstances absolutely must be considered.
Prior to 1916, the Federal Government took the position that its
task was to render only those services which could not be effectively rendered in the States. It has become almost a joke in this part
of the century to talk about the days in which the role of the
Federal Government was perceived as being national defense and
the post office, but prior to 1916, the vast majority of the funds
collected in the States for the support of the Federal Government
were used for solely Federal purposes.
For 60 years now, there has been a massive change in attitude
which I don't think the Congress can now ignore. For more than 60
years, the Federal Government has taken the position that its task,
in large part, was to tell the folks in the States what they ought to
be doing for the people in the States, telling the people what was
not being done adequately in the judgment of the Federal Congress
by programs implemented at the State or local level. So, over a
period of time, a very substantial number of programs have been
enacted by the Congress, some of them fully paid for by taxes
taken to the Federal level, but a substantial number of other
programs have been partially paid for by Federal funds. In principle and philosophy, I. hope you will agree that the Congress, for
many years, has pointed the way toward the expansion of service
at the local level to give incentive to local and State governments
to render services which they had not initiated, and many, many
programs have started out by providing full funding or 80-percent
funding or 50-percent funding in order to encourage spending, to
encourage the expansion of programs.
Now, the financial circumstances to wrhich you refer are that the
States and the local governments have heeded the advice, instructions, and the prodding of the Congress, and have built up a huge

209
establishment for providing services. They have accomplished that
in large part by increasing their tax rates, and I might say, by
doing so with greater rate of acceleration than that of the Federal
Government.
Now, at exactly the same time when the public has decided that
expenditures are too great at the Federal level, the States and local
governments have come to the point where they have built up
very, very high tax rates, very high burdens. The figures you cited
earlier do show, in addition to the relative liquidity of the States,
that the tax rates have been increasing more rapidly at the local
level, that the adjusted per capita increase is more rapid in tax
revenues at the State level than at the Federal level. I would just
ask you, sir, not to mistake liquidity for burden. Your argument, as
I understand it, is that we are more liquid than the Federal Government, because we show a surplus. Well, it was destined to be so,
since we don't print money, since we had an absolute obligation to
pay for every burden thrust upon us by our own legislators or the
U.S. Congress over a period of years.
If there were two families living side by side and both of them
had the same income, both of them belonged to some neighborhood
association, and one of them ended the year with a balanced
budget and the other overspent and ended with a deficit, I don't
think it would be equitable to say that the dues to the association
paid by the family which had ended the fiscal year in balance
should be increased, or that the dues of the family which had
overspent and, therefore, was not liquid, should be reduced.
Senator BENTSEN. I think the family that overspent would be a
fool to spend the money that they had collected from the taxpayers
for that family that happened to have a balanced budget.
Governor SNELLING. Maybe the people I am talking about have
been foolish for a period of time, and maybe they are about to
rectify that failure.
Nevertheless, the statement that the States are liquid and that
the Federal Government has a deficit, I would hope, sir, would be
considered in the light of what programs are being implemented at
the State level, and at whose instigation those programs were
implemented.
What I am really arguing for, and what I think the Governors
are arguing for, is that deceleration take place cautiously and that
if now the thrust of Federal policy has changed and the Federal
Government is no longer intent on telling the States what they
should do, and encouraging them to add new programs, perhaps
will come the recognition of how painful it is when programs
undertaken at the Federal initiative and tax rates to support those
programs at the local level have been built up as high as they have
are suddenly and dramatically turned around.
Now the position of the States, I believe, is not at all that the
Federal Government should accept the responsibility for all of this
decompression. I believe we have been specific. If one makes a
statement that an automobile with a low horsepower that is not
designed for rapid acceleration will provide more mileage to the
gallon, I would say that is not a generality. That is a specificity.
What we have said is that there are savings to be had in increasing
the administrative flexibility of the programs for the States.

210
We are saying the categorical grants are expensive, and that, in
the last few years, the number of categorical grants increased from
472 to 492. For the same period, 1972, we don't know of new block
grants. We are saying we can take less money from the Federal
Government and perform the services which we have mandated
and you have mandated, if, indeed, we are allowed to do so with
less regulation.
We are saying that the Federal mandates that have come down
from the Congress for which no money has been provided are
eating up our capacity at the local level, and that the Congress, at
the same time as it addresses the concerns for reducing the Federal
Government's expenditures, can put us in a position to pick up
more of the slack and do more of these programs, if it will remove
from us the burden of mandated programs for which it has provided no money.
We have offered to the President and to the Congress a bargain.
What we have said is that we will accept less money in exchange
for grant reform. It seems that at the moment there are some who
will pick up the part that says less money, but the pace of picking
up the part that provides for grant reform is not in the environment.
Senator BENTSEN. Governor, I am in concurrence with that statement and in fact have mandated the first major study on the effect
of State spending of federally mandated programs, because I am in
concurrence with that statement. I think we ought to understand
what we are mandating, and that study will be conducted by this
committee to try to find the full extent of what we are mandating.
I totally agree with that part of your statement, but I still need
specifics from you. When you talk about categorical grants and the
ones you want cut, I want to know which ones. I really want your
counsel and advice. I am going to be supporting a lot of those cuts,
and did last time. If there are some programs that are not working,
tell us about it, but don't, on the one hand, tell us to have a
balanced budget and that you want your revenue sharing, and not
tell us where we are going to make the cuts.
Governor SNELLING. I appreciate that, and the National Governors' Association is now deep into a program which, if it is to have
value and the kind of specificity that you are talking about, will
require a little time to complete. The Governors have all been
asked to write to the National Governors' Association and outline
priorities of Federal programs and show specifically which categorical grants we think are less valuable than others, and which can
be brought together.
We have already provided to Mr. McIntye a list of 100 or more
categorical grants which we think can operate more effectively if
they are consolidated. I believe that within 4 or 5 months we will
be able to be considerably more specific than we have been in the
past, and that is the direction that you are requiring.
Let me just finish, Mr. Chairman, by a reference to something
which I know is a sore point. There are those who are coming to
the Congress from the States and saying, "Well, States balance
their budgets and why can't the Congress balance the budget?"
There are those within Congress who are saying really almost
the same thing. They are just putting it a little differently. What

211
they are saying is, "Since you are in balance back home, the first
step in achieving Federal balance or, at least, the thrust of the
steps at the Federal level should be to reduce the funds which go to
the local level."
I ask you to recognize, Mr. Chairman, that there is really not a
perfect analogy between the financial balance in the States and
that of the Federal Government. State governments do have deficits quite frequently, in that they spend more money than they
take in in a particular year. For example, our own fiscal surveys
indicate that in fiscal 1979, State governments will, in their general revenue funds alone, spend about $5 billion more than their
revenue.
Most of this is attributable to a single State-California-for
fiscal 1979 spending will exceed receipts in that year by almost $3
billion. Additionally, many States differ, and significantly, from the
Federal Government in the way that they handle capital expenditures. Federal budget outlays for capitol expenditures are found in
the operating budget. In many State budgets, we treat some capital
expenditures as off budget item to be financed by bonds, including
only debt service in our operating budgets. If one were to reform
the Federal budget to do this, which I would hope would not
happen, the Federal budget would disappear or be reduced, depending on the capital. Forty-eight States have legal restraints against
deficit spending. However, what we mean when we say States are
required to have balanced budgets is not that revenues always
equal spending expenditures, but that the combination of the balances brought into the year will exceed expenditures, because State
budgets must be balanced in this sense rather than the Federal
sense. States normally maintain balances that will be built up or
drawn down in any given year, depending upon both conscious
choice of State policymakers and the fluctuation in revenue over
which those policymakers have no control.
Mr. Chariman, your position on general revenue sharing is well
known, and the position of the National Governors' Association in
this matter has been stated so clearly and so repetitively that I will
not restate it, except in the context that we believe that the one
least restrictive categorical grant offers the States a very necessary
opportunity to flex some of these multidutinous changes that are in
the 1980 and prospective 1981 budgets, where categorical grant
funds are going to be reduced.
We subscribe to the concept of a balanced budget. We subscribe
to a trend in which Federal and local expenditures are going to be
reduced. What we want to do is work with the Congress to accomplish that change over a reasonable period of time in which decompression takes place logically, and in which we try to get the
savings which are to be had. With these consolidations of grants,
simplification of grants, and the simplification and reduction of
mandates, we must recognize that for a period of time we are going
to need some flexibility to accommodate the changed Federal attitude about the role of the Federal Government in causing expenditures at the local and State levels.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you, Governor.

212
When we are finished, I have some questions for you, and I know
Senator Javits will.
[The prepared statement of Governor Snelling follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT

OF HON. RICHARD A. SNELLING

Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am pleased to appear here today
on behalf of the National Governors' Association; I am currently serving as the
Chairman of the NGA Committee on Executive Management and Fiscal Affairs.
The testimony I will give this morning reflects the consensus of the Governors as
developed through my committee and the policy-making machinery of the National
Governors' Association.
In dealing with budgets, Members of Congress and Governors have some important experiences in common. Both of us are under considerable pressure to hold
down or reduce taxes. We are also under considerable pressure from various sincere
groups, including local governments, to increase spending or, at least, to continue
existing programs. Sometimes we get the pressure to reduce taxes and increase
spending from the very same people.
Governors are like Members of Congress in another way also. When we look at
specific policy problems, we reach one set of conclusions. When we look at aggregate
budgetary impacts we begin to doubt our conclusions about the specifics. This
happens in Congress when, for instance, you ask your own authorizing committees
about budgetary recommendations and then total those recommendations and consider the implications. This also happens to Governors collectively. If you ask us, for
example, whether we think the national interest would be served by a particular
proposed new expenditure, we normally answer in terms of the benefits we see or
fail to see associated with that particular expenditure, without trying to relate that
particular position to impacts on overall spending and revenues.
The importance of a process that relates particular decisions with financial implications to overall economic policy and budget posture was recognized by the Congress in the Congressional Budget Act. My impression as an outsider is that the Act
has increased the ability of Congress to deal more rationally, and perhaps more
frugally, with federal spending issues. Within the National Governors' Association,
we too have tried to approach fiscal issues within a framework that is responsible
overall. For example:
(1) We have been more careful in developing policy positions that call for increases in the federal budget. A comparison of our new positions with those of three
years ago show that we are asking for less.
(2) We support the concept of a balanced federal budget.
(3) We recognize that one implication of moving to a balanced budget is that some
grant programs may not be maintained at current service levels. Accordingly, we
have worked with the Administration on the fiscal year 1980 budget, and we are
organizing a more intensive, detailed effort for fiscal year 1981.
BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET

I think practically every Governor, and for that matter, practically every Member
of Congress, supports the concept of a balanced federal budget. The problem is not
reaching agreement on the principle but determining how that principle can best be
implemented.
It is our responsibility as state officials and expert witness on this point to
criticize those who make simple analogies between balancing state budgets and
balancing the federal budget. Those who come to Congress to say that states balance
their budgets and to ask why the Congress cannot balance the federal budget are
not recognizing some basic differences in both the economic roles and the accounting procedures of the two levels of government. One of our policy resolutions
adopted last February called for a study of these differences.
State governments do have deficits quite frequently, in the sense that they spend
more than revenues in particular years. For example, our own fiscal survey estimates that in fiscal year 1979 state governments will, in their general revenue
funds alone, spend about $5 billion more than revenues. Most of this is attributable
to a single state, California, where fiscal year 1979 spending will exceed receipts in
that year by nearly $3 billion. Many states also differ from the federal government
in the way they handle capital expenditures. In the federal budget, outlays for
construction are found in the operating budget. In many state budgets, we treat
some capital expenditures as "off budget" to be financed by bonds and put only the
debt service in our operating budgets. If one were to reformat the federal budget to

213
do this, the federal deficit would either be reducpd 6r would disappear entirely,
depending on what one counts as capital.
Forty-eight states have legal restraints against deficit spending. However, what
we mean when we say that states are required to have balanced budgets is not that
revenues always equal or exceed expenditures, but that the Combination of revenues
and the balances brought into the year will exceedl expenditures. Because state
budgets must be balanced in this sense, rather than in the federal sense, states
normally maintain balances that will be built up or drawn down in any given year
depending both upon conscious choice of state policy-makers and fluctuations in
revenues over which those policy-makers have no control.
In general, using the federal concept of balance, our budgets tend to be in deficit
during recessions and in surplus in boom times. This is because our revenues and
expenditures are adversely affected by recession, just as are those of the federal
government. However, our balanced budget requirements do achieve one thing.
While not necessarily in balance each year, state budgets are in balance over the
business cycle.
Every Governor I know believes that there are at least some years in which the
federal budget should be in balance. Thus, we are in support of eliminating the
deficit when the economy is growing and have formally endorsed having a balanced
federal budget in 1981.
THE GOVERNORS

POSITION ON THE FISCAL YEAR 1980 BUDGET

Last fall we met with various Administration officials about the budget. Our basic
point, then and now, is that if there are going to be cuts in real spending levels, we
are willing to work with the Administration and the Congress to make sure those
cuts cause the least possible damage.
Our main approach is to try to concentrate reductions in areas of high administrative costs and lower priority smaller programs, while using a number of program
reforms to try to do a better job with available funds. We continue to advocate the
position we took this fall and continue to seek out federal policymakers who recognize that we are willing to take action that is considerably different from coming to
Washington every year and asking for money. Our basic points are these:
1. Budget savings in intergovernmental programs should be accompanied by increased administrative flexibility for state and local governments. Program reductions should be accompanied by major administrative reforms, such as program
consolidation, reducing mandates on state and local governments and streamlining
procedures and paperwork. Between 1975 and 1978, the number of separate federal
categorical programs increased from 442 to 492, and the last major block grabat
program was enacted in 1974.
,, I * 6'
Congress should recognize that program consolidation, reduced mandates, arid
other administrative reforms are responsive to the public's concerns about inflation
and government inefficiency, duplication and vaste. The reforms we are advocating
would permit improved integration' of state and federal funds, resulting in better
service delivery and better targeting of funds to areas of state and local priority.
The President's budget is disappointing in the area of program reform. Some
changes are proposed in relatively minor programs (energy management, environmental regulatory and planning activities and certain mental health programs) and
the possibility of further proposals is mentioned in the case of economic and community development. We would like to see much more than this. For example, we have
our own grant consolidation proposal in the economic development area.
The problem, of course, is that each small program has its own constituency in
the federal bureaucracy, in interest groups, in congressional subcommittees and,
indeed, in state bureaucracies. Thus, we must look to committees in the Congress,
such as the Joint Economic Committee and the Budget Committees, which have a
broad perspective and which recognize that program design is directly related to the
feasibility of holding the budget to reasonable totals.
I will come to the specifics of general revenue sharing in a moment. As a general
observation, let me note that it appears that in both the Administration and the
Congress, the programs most under attack are those that have the greatest flexibility and lowest administrative costs and the programs where sympathy for budget
increases is greatest appear to be some of the narrower categorical programs.

2. Funding decisions should result in real savings to taxpayers: Cut-backs in
programs administered by state and local governments cannot be equated with cuts
in other sectors of the budget. A reduction by the federal government in a program
area of exclusive federal responsibility is virtually certain to result in reduced
government spending. A cut by the federal government in an area of joint federalstate-local responsibility-such as welfare or education-may simply result in the

214
transfer of costs from the federal government to state and local governments. The
effect may not be a reductions in the overall level of government spending but a
transfer of the burden from the federal income tax to a state sales or income tax or
even to the local property tax.
3. The Administration should use budget-making techniques which preserve the
fiscal choices of the states. In general, we oppose federal cutbacks which are made
by shifting funding responsibilities to state and local government through reduced
federal matching rates.
4. Fiscal constraints should not delay the development of authorizing legislation
for high priority programs which will have a limited impact on fiscal year 1980
budget projections. A welfare reform proposal and a stand-by program of economic
assistance to state and local governments are key examples here.
5. Intergovernmental assistance should not bear a disproportionate share of funding reductions below current services.
6. The impact of federal policies on state and local government should be determined before those policies are adopted.
The federal government has been criticized for placing unfunded mandates on
state and local governments. Requirements for specific tests for safe drinking water,
for specific state actions to ensure air quality, and for special education are recent
examples of mandates promulgated without adequate assessment of cost.
Unfunded mandates placed on state and local governments are a current point of
intergovernmental conflict, but they are not the only issues of major concern
between states and the federal government. The relationship of federal programs to
existing state and local efforts is another important recurring question, and so is
the amount of paperwork which the federal government requires of its grantees.
Congress, in considering new legislation and appropriations, should be as conscious of the financial impacts on state and local governments as of the financial
impact on the federal government. Representative Elizabeth Holtzman is preparing
legislation to be considered by the House of Representatives which would meet our
concerns on this point, and I hope that the Senate will take up a similar proposal.
7. Prescriptive federal regulations should be revised to permit increased flexibility
for states and improved targeting according to state and locally defined needs. State
officials and others who have studied federal program administration have found
that detailed regulations add significantly to the cost of running federally funded
programs and hamper the targeting of funds to local needs. In general, we support
the President's strategy to reduce-prescriptive regulations through executive reorganization, improvement in federal planning requirements, and reforms in the joint
funding simplification program. In many cases, these efforts will require the cooperation of the Congress and, in some cases, congressional leadership may be necessary
to get the Administration to act. There are several examples of what can be done,
including the HEW planning grants demonstration in five states, a coordinated
investment strategy demonstration involving North Carolina and the Farmers
Home Administration and HUD's work with two states on rural housing and
community development cooperation. Governor Hunt will cover these points in
more detail in his testimony.
THE PRESIDENT S RESPONSE TO THE BUDGET RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE GOVERNORS

The fiscal year 1980 budget proposals that are pending before you reflect some of
our views, but not all of them.
The fiscal year 1980 budget is submitted by the President permits grant outlays to
increase by about 1 percent, which, of course, is a reduction in real (inflationadjusted) spending of 6 to 8 percent depending on which inflation assumption one
uses. If real spending is to be maintained in the federally-assisted domestic programs and the federal government will not fund inflation-driven cost increases for
its share of the costs, then state and local governments can either cut back the
programs or fund the cost increases for the federal, as well as the state and local
share.
In general, grants felt the ax in the budget process more than practically any
other category of federal spending. Partially offsetting this are a few program

consolidations (including one for energy management/and one for environmental
regulatory and planning activities.) However, the Administration has not made any
major grant consolidation proposals, although serious consideration is being given to
one in the economic and community development area.
In addition, the budget reflects greater reliance on categorical grants rather than
broad-based ones. Broad-based and general purpose grants (basically block grants
and revenue sharing), which are much more flexible and less expensive to administer, have declined as a proportion of federal grants to state and local governments

215
since President Carter took office. They were about 26 percent of total grants in
fiscal year 1977 and are about 22 percent of the grants proposed in the fiscal year
1980 budget.
By failing to include substantial program consolidations, the Administration has
not pursued an opportunity to ensure that substantial portions of the reductions in
federal spending come out of administrative overhead costs, as the Governors recommended. Because the level of service provided by the proposed budget would decrease while only limited efforts are being made to reduce administrative costs
through consolidation, the budget may actually raise the costs of delivering services
on a per-unit basis.
Some of the administration's budget reductions are clearly designed to decrease
actual spending of both the federal government and state and local governments
that share costs with the federal government. The health cost containment proposal
is an example of this approach. In other cases, however, the effect of the federal
decision to cut spending or to cut purchasing power by holding the fiscal year 1980
spending to prior year levels, would be to inflict costs on state and local governments. For 'example, the Administration recommendations would prevent the scheduled increase in the federal share of costs for education of the handicapped that
federal legislation mandates for state and local government. Other federal savings,
such as having the FBI leave investigation of bank robberies to state and local
government, represents a transfer of costs, not savings.
The budget fails to discuss the impact of federal spending and legislative proposals on state and local government. For the Medicaid program, for example, new
coverage is proposed for up to 2 million people. The impact of this major expansion
on state and local governments is not discussed in the budget recommendations. No
explanation is provided in the budget to suggest that the Administration will do
more to gauge the impact of its proposals on state and local governments than it
has in the past,. although the urban impact statement procedure started by the
President last year could be helpful if applied in the context of the budget. The
budget document contains no proposals to review or revise mandates that have been
imposed on state governments in the past.
The Administration's recommendations were also not responsive to the Governor's general desire for advance appropriations as a means to produce more certainty about future federal program levels. Such appropriations are continued for a few
transportation programs, but were not requested by the Administration for other
programs, despite a major recommendation from the Governors that wastewater
treatment grants be advance funded and despite legislative authority for such
appropriations for a number of nutrition and education programs.
In general, we were pleased that the Administration and the Congress are at least
willing to listen to our recommendations for better management of grant programs,
but not pleased at how little action has been taken.
In some areas, such as economic development, it may be that leadership on
program consolidation and simplification will have to come from the Congress. We
would think that the Budget Committees particularly would be interested in this,
because our ability as Governors to live with declining real federal support could be
improved by such actions.
PARTICULAR GRANT PROGRAMS

From a state perspective, our highest budget priority is the General Revenue
Sharing program. The President's budget includes funds for revenue sharing, as it
should. However, changes in the authorizing legislation for the program have been
proposed for consideration by the Congress this year.
The popularity of general revenue sharing- with elected officials at the state and
local level should surprise no one. With revenue sharing, you can always do what
you could do with a particular categorical grant, merely by devoting the money to
whatever that grant would have been used for. The reverse is not true. With a
categorical grant, you must use the federal money, and often some matching money
of your own, on the particular category of activities covered by the grant-no
matter how low the priority of that program may be. In addition, the administrative
costs associated with general revenue sharing are negligible at both the federal level
and at the recipient level.
We are concerned, for a variety of reasons, with legislation that has been proposed which would take states out of the General Revenue Sharing program. Firstof all, we regret that such proposals appear to be in the form of retaliation for the
concern of many state legislatures with a balanced budget at the federal level. One
way we can guarantee never having a balanced budget is to develop a general
attitude in the Congress that everyone who wants one should be the first in line to

216
have programs cut. Hopefully, those kinds of judgments can be made on program
merits.
Second, such proposals are often made in the context of a situation in, which the
federal government is presumed to be in poor shape financially and state governments are presumed to be in particularly good shape. There are a variety of ways
that one could examine the relative positions of the two levels of government.
Clearly one is to examine deficits for the latest year on which we have comparable
data. According to our fiscal survey of the states, with 48 states reporting, state
expenditures in fiscal year 1979 (the current fiscal year) will exceed revenues by
$4.9 billion. When that deficit is compared to total revenues (and minor adjustments) of $113.8, the deficit is 4.3 percent of revenues. This is larger than the
comparable federal figure for fiscal year 1979.
One thing we all recognize about the federal budget, which is not necessarily true
about state and local budgets, is that the federal government's revenue and expenditure structures are such that, except for social insurance, federal revenues will be
sufficient so that tax cuts at the federal level can be expected periodically. There
have been tax cuts at the federal level in 1978, 1977, 1976, and 1975. The Administration's projections show the federal budget having such large surpluses of revenues over expenditures through 1984 that tax cuts clearly would be possible.
The state situation is not similar, and certainly that of the state and local sectors
together is not. State government generally do not have revenue structures that
respond as quickly or completely to inflation as the federal income tax. In addition,
many state governments are financing increasing shares of expenditures that used
to be local, particularly in education, as state decision-makers respond to crises in
cities and to increased citizen dislike for property taxes.
Thus, states are not in a particularly good position to experience a major shift in
funding responsibilities which repeal of General Revenue Sharing would entail.
More important, if there is to be some sort of a shift of costs from the federal
government to the states, it would seem more logical to make that shift by dropping
certain categorical programs rather than revenue sharing. If the states had to
choose where to take a cut of the magnitude that would be involved if General
Revenue Sharing were to be eliminated, preference would be in programs at the
federal level that involve high administrative costs and little flexibility. Revenue
sharing has none of these characteristics.
Revenue sharing should be attractive at the federal level for another reason. The
program has proven to be one of the steadiest in the history of federal programs.
There have not been major pressures to increase it above the levels of current
authorization. Assuming that some indicator of cost increases such as the consumer
price index or federal revenues, the program should operate on the same basis in
the future.
Failure to renew general revenue sharing for the states will have significant
consequences for local governments. That such consequences exist is suggested by
the support of local government officials for revenue sharing for states. Behind this
support lies the fact that state and local finances interact significantly. In some
cases, revenue sharing programs are used directly to finance a variety of local
initiatives, such as education, juvenile justice and retirement programs and county
court costs. Treasury figures indicate that 40 percent of all state revenue sharing
funds were passed through to local governments.
In other cases, the revenue sharing money is part of the overall fiscal posture of
state governments and all state activities, including local government assistance
and school aid, would likely suffer if it were cut off. The result would simply be
more fiscal pressure on local governments. This pressure should be substantial.
Census figures show that state aid to many local governments (the 74 largest
SMSA's) is four times the federal aid they receive.
One impact that revenue sharing continues to have is on the tax structure of the
United States. There is still much to be said for raising the funds used for revenue
sharing for states from the taxes to which the federal government has access rather
than sales and state income taxes. Use of the federal revenue source is equalizing
nationally, and the formula automatically responds to increases in local tax effort in
the different states and to changes in personal income (which are reflected in
relative federal tax payments that support the program).
Welfare reform is also of particular interest to Governors. We have long advocated comprehensive reform of the welfare system, both because we administer the
program and know how badly the reform is needed and because we see the need for
a greater federal role in income maintenance programs. We asked the President to
address welfare reform in the budget, which was done, but we believe that implementation should occur on a faster schedule than contemplated by the President.

217
As you know, we share with the federal government the ever-increasing costs of
Medicaid. We have supported hospital cost-containment legislation in the past and
continue to do so. We are willing to work with this Committee, and other committee
of the Congress and the Administration, in trying to find ways to contain medical
costs.
We have another proposal, also part of the President's program, that we believe
should be adopted. Hopefully, it will have no fiscal year 1980 cost implications. That
is some form of stand-by counter-cyclical assistance. Such a program should avoid
the problem everyone found with counter-cyclical assistance when last enacted.
That problem was that the enactment came too late-the money couldn't be used by
state and local governments when their spending was most needed to stimulate the
economy and when they were most pressed for revenues because the program was
not enacted and funded until later.
While we do have these recommendations for spending in excess of the President's budget, we would point out that they could be implemented in the context of
outlays that do not rise faster than the rate of inflation. Receipts are scheduled to
rise 11 percent between fiscal year 1979 and fiscal year 1980. If inter-governmental
programs were to rise by, say, 5-7 percent in fiscal year 1980 these recommendations
in real federal
could be accomplished easily within the context of a slight-declineaddress
spending
assistance to state and local governments. While not equipped to
priorities in such areas as defense, we do believe that not even asking for a
continuation of all current grant programs with increases to match inflation puts us
in a reasonable position vis-a-vis moving toward a balanced budget.
CONCLUSION

Mr. Chariman, the pressure on state and local governments to reduce expenditures has the potential for causing major shifts in current federal spending practices. It is up to the Congress to direct this pressure into constructive channels.
The federal grant-in-aid system which has developed over the last two decades is
badly in need of reform. Too many restrictions inhibit targeting funds to state and
local priorities. Too many separate programs make it difficult to link federal and
state funds effectively. Too much paperwork absorbs federal resources and diverts
the money from supporting services.
As members of the Joint Economic Committee, you have a unique opportunity to
take a broad view of the grant-in-aid system. We urge you to work with us to devise
reforms that forge an effective partnership between the federal and state governments.
Mr. Chairman, this concludes my statement. I will be happy to answer questions
from the committee.

Senator

BENTSEN.

Governor Hunt, please proceed.

STATEMENT OF HON. JAMES B. HUNT, JR., GOVERNOR, STATE
OF NORTH CAROLINA

Governor HUNT. Thank you, lOIr. Chairman. Let me first of all
express my appreciation for the opportunity of discussing the Federal budget and its impact upon us with this very important committee of Congress. I have often been impressed with the kind of
economic analysis and findings, that this committee has brought
about. I want to thank you for that.
I would like to make three points in my testimony, Mr. Chairman.
First of all, I want to express my willingness, and I think it is
the willingness of most of the Governors, to work with this Congress and with the President, to balance the budget and to accept
our fair share of any reductions that are necessary.
Senator BENTSEN. That would include revenue sharing to the
States.
Governor HUNT. Whatever it would take to balance the budget,
Mr. Chairman. I want to see the job done one way or another.
Second, I believe it is imperative that we take strong steps--

218
Senator BENTSEN. I might say that cutting out revenue sharing
to the States is my starting position.
Governor HUNT. I will tell you the end result of what it takes to
get there. I think it is imperative that we take strong Federal steps
to control spending-both to protect our economy and to maintain
the faith and confidence of our people in their Government.
The third thing I want to show is how the President's proposed
budget affects assistance for State and local governments generally,
and problems related to our major initiatives specifically.
With regard to the matter of faith and confidence, I want to
state to you, and I want to state to the members of this Congress, I
think that is a critically important thing today. I am not sure the
people here in this city are aware the extent to which that has
been diminished. Yet, I think that is perhaps the most crucial
thing facing us.
In the last 10 years, inflation in this country has increased 21/2
times faster than the 25 years after World War II. Sixty-five percent of the Federal debt was created in the last 10 years. We have
been on an unprecedented spending spree. I recognize fiscal policy
and budget deficits can be a tool for progress. Certainly that was
proved with the leadership of Franklin D. Roosevelt. Many times
during our history, and even in this decade, economic conditions
dictated fiscal stimuli to reduce unemployment.
I am afraid-and I think the people feel this way-we can't seem
to wean ourselves off of deficits. Massive deficits have continued,
even into strong recovery periods such as 1976 through 1979, and
they have fed the fires of inflation.
I know that has not been the only cause, but I think that it has
been one of the causes, a significant one that we can do something
about. I think the people are beginning to understand. I don't think
for a long time they did, but I think they do now, and are willing
to take the consequences of doing something about it. To retain
economic stability and retain the world'market we just now have a
more responsible Federal fiscal policy.
It has to do with all of these other things throughout the world,
which you know far better than I do. To do that, we must have this
more responsible Federal fiscal policy. We have to have better
management in all government, and a stronger partnership between the Federal, State, and local governments. I think we all
need to remember, all of us in government at every level, that the
American taxpayer is the one who pays the bill. I don't have to tell
you the cost of taxes to inflation.
We recently did a study in my State of North Carolina, and
learned that a North Carolina taxpayer who earns $15,000 a year,
if he got a cost-of-living pay raise in 1968, was 1.6 percent worse off
in terms of actual buying power than at the beginning of the year.
That comes about because of progressive income taxes, and the way
other taxes are levied.
But the taxpayer was actually worse off. That has contributed to
a kind of desperate, panicked feeling among so many of our people.
What is the result? It is that the taxpayers pay more, while they
see Government grow more and go deeper and deeper into debt. At
the same time, he believes too much money is wasted by redundant
programs, and I think we can literally describe the situation today

219
as one in which our people feel that at a lot of different levels, but
primarily at the Federal level, that government is literally out of
control.
I know a lot of things can be said about that, a lot of explanations can be given. I am simply saying to you, Mr. Chairman, that
that is the feeling among the people throughout the country. That
is why we in North Carolina, and a lot of responsible legislators,
feel that we may need to take dramatic steps to restore fiscal
responsibility. That is why 28 State legislators, including my own
in North Carolina, have called for a constitutional convention and
a balanced budget amendment. The strength of this support is why
the National Governors' Association last year approved my resolution calling for a balanced Federal budget by 1981. That is the
position of the National Governors' Association.
I want to reiterate that this sentiment for a balanced budget is,
of course, concerned with getting it in balance, but it runs deeper
than that. That is why it would be so disastrous to mistake it. It is
really a sign of an alienation. I think the term "estrangement" is
appropriate here. Many people in this country feel today the lack
of confidence in the ability of their Government to manage their
Nation's affairs responsibly. I don't think we can afford to ignore
those deep feelings.
I know the risk of a constitutional convention. I think those risks
have been exaggerated. It would be made up of men and women
chosen from the various States of this country, including, perhaps,
a lot of the Members of Congress. I think those fears are exaggerated, particularly by people who don't have much faith in America,
particularly those outside Washington. I do have faith in them. I
think we need to be careful to provide adequate safeguards, and I
want to point out that the North Carolina General Assembly, in its
resolution, did provide carefully developed safeguards in their resolution.
Let me enumerate some of them. First of all, our resolution
would allow 4 years from the date of ratification by the various
States for the balanced budget requirement to take effect. Second,
it recognizes the need for a safety valve to allow deficit financing
in a national or economic crisis. Third, it stipulates the convention
would be restricted to this one issue, and our call would be rescinded, if that were not the case. Finally, our resolution would no
longer be in effect, if Congress proposed a constitutional amendment on its own by January 1, 1980.
The ultimate safeguard, of course, is the fact that any amendment proposed by convention would still have to be ratified by 38
States of this Nation.
I believe that a constitutional convention should be a last resort.
I don't want one. I just want the budget balanced, and I want it put
into the laws or the Constitution in such a way that it will continue to be done unless in cases of emergency. I want the President's
economists to balance the budget. I think the President, with the
support of you and many Members of Congress, is making excellent
progress toward that goal. He promised to do that when he ran for
President. He is doing that, and we are making progress.
But Congress must recognize, and I say this with all the earnestness that I can muster, that if this is not done, the people of this

220
country are going to take whatever steps are necessary to bring
about a balanced budget in normal times. It would not be responsible for me to speak of a balanced budget without being willing to
accept the consequences of reductions in the moneys States receive
from the Federal Government. My State is willing to do that. The
Executive Committee of the National Governors' Association reaffirmed earlier this week that it is willing to do that, consistent, of
course, with a number of things that have already been set out.
Let me say to you, Mr. Chairman, that in the budget I talked to
my legislature about several weeks ago, there were two things in
there that indicated a very strong emphasis. One, in terms of
taking whatever medicine it requires on our own part, and that
had to do with cutting down the increases in personnel, and that is
where so much of the money goes at the State level.
We had a spree during fiscal period 1972 to 1976 in which personnel growth in our State per year averaged 4.8 percent-a lot
went to public schools, but every year we averaged 4.8 percent.
When I became Governor in 1976, we cut it first to 3.2, and then
to 3.1. I proposed for the next 2 years to cut it to 2 percent in the
first year and 0.9 the second year. That is the kind of step we are
prepared to take in terms of our own budget.
In terms of general revenue sharing, although I will say in a
moment I don't think we ought to totally cut it out, we did not
count on that being renewed. The budget that I took to my legislature does not have those funds from October 1980 on included.
So I say to you, Mr. Chairman, we are prepared to take the
medicine in order to get the budget balanced. I say that to indicate
that we are serious about it and we understand there are going to
be costs. We are prepared to take our share.
I do want to say this, and this has been said by my fellow
Governors here. It would not be responsible for the Congress to cut
Federal spending in a punitive way, cutting off money to the States
I
or the people throughout the States.
I can think of nothing that would do more to exacerbate the
alienation that our people feel. You spoke of that this morning.
I want to say to you that it is coming through that way to an
awful lot of people throughout this country. We have to work
together to eliminate waste in spending. We have begun to do this
in our State in a lot of different ways. We are working together
with some of the Federal agencies, and I might just say to you for
your information-because I think you would be interested-we
have developed the first plan in the country where the State is
working with the Farmers Home Administration to jointly decide
how funds ought to be used, putting together State and Federal
funds.
Again, I say the States are willing to accept their fair share of
cuts, but only if the cuts are accompanied-and I am sure the
Congress will do this, but we need to urge it-by an objective and
even-handed assesment of how we can better structure programs.
We are making a lot of progress. The Governors are very pleased
with how the Government is working with us, and the legislative
branch, in giving us input as to how we restructure these, but we
need to continue.

221
I am convinced, personally, that there are many cases where we
can cut spending without cutting services. I want to urge, Mr.
Chairman, that the Federal Government get serious about looking
at how many people are on the payroll. That is not easy to do. You
don't do it by saying, "Is there anybody who you can get along
without?"
When I became Governor of North Carolina, within the month
that I took office, knowing that there was a lot of waste, a lot of
people we could get along without, we could do a better job, we
could combine things, and so I just simply gave an order to my
cabinet secretaries that we were going to cut out 2 percent of the
personnel involved in State government. Of course, they hollered a
lot when I first did it. They said, "That is not the way to do it, and
we can't do it" but we worked on it very hard, we worked with
them, and in the course of 2 months, we cut out 2.3 percent across
the board. That many people were taken off the payroll, and I
don't think services were hurt one bit in my State because we did
it.
I think the Federal Government can do it and, gracious knows
how many tens of thousands can be found. Again, it would not be
something that would be popular.
Senator BENTSEN. Governor, I think we are trying very hard to
do this very thing. This committee-and I just became the new
chairman-presented a budget estimate to the Appropriations
Committees the other day that substantially cut the amount of
money that had been estimated in the President's budget for this
committee. This committee has not had any increase in its personnel for 3 years.
Governor HUNT. Thank you, sir. I commend you for that, and I
suggest it be done not only in this committee, but throughout the
Congress and the entire Federal Government.
Over $80 billion of the proposed budget of $493.4 billion goes
directly or indirectly to State and local governments. That is some
$30 billion more than in fiscal 1975, with sizable increases coming
in medicaid, employment and training programs, temporary employment assistance, and health care costs. The States have little
discretion with regard to an awful lot of that money, as you know.
Frequently, the Federal budget dictates increases and shifting
priorities in State and local governments. It frequently requires
more State and matching money in programs mandated by the
Federal Government. That money comes from other State and local
programs. In essence, the Federal budget mechanism undermines
the decisions and priorities that have been determined by the State
and local government.
I would want to join here with the suggestion of Governor
Thompson and many others, that the Federal Government really
make a firm move, by whatever means would be best, toward a
truth in funding principle, or whatever it might be called. I have
done this in the State of North Carolina. I have pledged to local
governments that we will not again mandate a program that they
have to carry out without providing the funds to do it with.
I can't tell you how much that has done to build relationships,
the trusts between us at those two levels.

47-977 0 - 79 - 15

222
I would strongly urge that the Federal Government do the same
kind of thing.
I mentioned this to one of the Senators over in our conference a
couple of days ago. He mentioned areas such as eliminating discrimination in civil rights. That is a tough one, and that is something we must move to do.
I know there are going to be some of those areas where, perhaps,
work cannot absolutely be begun, but there would be greater restraints in terms of funding. This should do a great deal for the
relationship between the State and Federal Governments.
Senator BENTSEN. Governor, I certainly don't want to cut you off,
but I promised one of the other Governors I would get him out
fairly early, and I do have some questions.
Governor HUNT. Mr. Chairman, I believe the great advantage of
a balanced budget is that it would force us-at whatever level it is
done, and we experience this all the time at the State and local
levels-to take the steps of getting things back in hand. It will
require tough scrutiny and harder decisions. It will require accountability and honesty in government. It will force us to find
ways to develop new approaches and be more productive with what
we have and, in particular, here in our Capital City, it would be a
counterweight to the insatiable demands of the special interest
groups.
I can certainly appreciate how they come here, because I know
what it is like in the State capital.
I would conclude by praising the President again for his leadership in working us toward a balanced budget and for all of those
who are supporting him and working with him.
I want to say again to you, Mr. Chairman, and to this committee
and to this Congress, the people of this country are serious about
fiscal responsibility in a way now that is perhaps as deep and as
strongly felt as they have been about any issue in this country in a
long, long time.
If we don't get a balanced budget, I think the people of this
country are going to take whatever action is necessary and is
provided for in that Constitution that was so well written, to assure
it comes about. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much, Governor. The people
have spoken time and time again on that specific issue, and more
so in the last few years than in a long time. I concur with that.
They do it at each election and each of us is elected by the same
constituencies.
[The prepared statement of Governor Hunt follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HON. JAMES B. HUNT, JR.

Mr. Chairman, I am deeply grateful for this opportunity to discuss the issue of the
federal budget with this committee.
I want to make three points in my testimony:
First, I want to express my willingness-and, I believe, the willingness of all
governors-to work with this Congress and with the President to balance the budget
and to accept our fair share of any reductions that are necessary.
Second, I believe it is imperative that we take strong steps to control federal
spending-both to protect our economy and to maintain the faith and confidence of
our people in their government.

223
Third, I want to show how the President's proposed 1980 budget will affect
assistance for state and local governments generally and programs related to our
major initiatives specifically.
This matter of faith and confidence is vitally important. In the last 10 years,
inflation in this country has increased two and a half times faster than in the 25
years after World War II. Sixty-five per cent of the federal debt was created during
the last 10 years. We have been on an unprecedented spending spree.
I recognize that fiscal policy-and budget deficits-can he a tool for progress.
Franklin Roosevelt proved that. Many times during our history-even in this
decade-economic conditions dictated fiscal stimuli to strengthen the economy and
to wean ourselves from deficits. Massive
seem
reduce unemployment. But we can't
deficits have continued even into strong recovery periods, such as 1976-79, they have
fed the fires of inflation.
To reattain economic stability and strength in the world market, we must have a
more responsible federal fiscal policy, better management in all government and a
stronger partnership among federal, state and local governments.
We must remember that the American taxpayer is the one who pays the bill. I
don't have to tell you the cost of taxes and inflation to the average person. I was
astonished to learn recently that a North Carolina taxpayer who earns $15,000 a
year, if he got a cost-of-living pay raise in 1978, actually was 1.6 per cent worse off
in terms of actual buying power. This is because of the combined effects of inflation
and a progressive income tax.
So the taxpayer has paid more and more while he sees government grow more
and more and go deeper and deeper in debt. At the same time, he believes that too
much money is wasted by inefficient and redundant programs. He feels that his
government is literally out of control.
That is why we in North Carolina and responsible governors and legislators in
many other states feel that we may need to take dramatic steps to restore fiscal
responsibility. This is why 28 state legislatures, including North Carolina's, have
convention and a balanced budget amendment. The
a
called for -constitutional
strength of this support is why the National Governors' Association last year
approved my resolution calling for a balanced federal budget by 1981.
We must recognize that the sentiment for a balanced budget is a sign of the
alienation that many people feel in this country today, the lack of confidence they
have in the ability of their government to manage this nation's affairs responsibly.
We cannot ignore those deep feelings.
Now I realize there are risks in the constitutional convention. I think those risks
are exaggerated by critics who don't seem to have any faith in the American people.
That is why North Carolina's General Assembly provided carefully developed safeguards in the resolution it passed on January 29, 1979 for a convention. Let me
enumerate some of those safeguards.
First, it would allow four years from the date of ratification by the various states
for the balanced budget requirement to take effect.
Second, it recognizes the need for a "safety valve" to allow deficit financing in a
national emergency or economic crisis.
Third, it stipulates that the convention would be restricted to this one issue.
North Carolina's call would be rescinded if the convention is not so limited.
Finally, the North Carolina resolution would no longer be in effect if Congress
proposed a constitutional amendment on its own by January 1, 1980.
The ultimate safeguard, of course, is that any amendment proposed by a constitutional convention would still have to be ratified by38 of the states.
I believe, though, that a constitutional convention should be a last resort. I want
the President and the Congress to balance the budget. I think this President is
making excellent progress toward that goal, as he promised the American people he
would do. I hope Congress will support him.
But Congress must recognize that, if it doesn't do it, the people of this country are
going to do it.
It would not be responsible for me to speak so strongly for a balanced budget
without being willing to accept the consequences of reductions in the money.states
receive from the federal government. My state is willing to do that. The executive
committee of the National Governors' Association reaffirmed earlier this week that
it is willing to do that.
It would not be responsible, on the other hand, for Congress to cut federal
spending in a punitive way-cutting off money to the states simply because the
states are calling for a balanced budget. I can think of nothing that would do more
to exacerbate the alienation that our people feel.

224
What we must do is work together to eliminate, waste in spending. We have begun
to do this in North Carolina. We have signed an agreement with the Farmers Home
Administration to better coordinate what the state and federal governments are
doing. Several of our major state departments are preparing a joint funding application system that will cover the most important federally assisted policy-planning
programs. This means less paperwork, fewer overhead dollars and better coordination of planning. We have begun a centralized review of federal funding programs
in our state. These management efforts are already reducing inefficiency and waste.
The state and federal governments need to join together in more such efforts.
Again, the states are willing to accept their fair share of cuts. But only if those
cuts are accompanied by an objective, even-handed assessment of how we can better
structure these programs. I am convinced that there are many cases where we can
cut spending without reducing services.
Over $80 billion of the proposed budget of $493.4 billion goes directly or indirectly
to state and local governments. That is some $30 billion more than in fiscal 1975,
with sizeable increases coming in Medicaid, employment and training programs,
temporary employment assistance and health care costs. The states have little
discretion over most of this money.
Frequently, the federal budget dictates increases and shifting priorities in state
and local budgets. It frequently requires more state and local matching money in
programs mandated by the federal government. That money comes from other state
and local programs. In essence, the federal budget mechanism undermines the
decisions and priorities that have been determined by the state and local governments.
In addition, much of the spending is wasteful, inefficient and inflationary. We
now have over 300 separate programs, over 50 so-called comprehensive plans and
thousands of reports to meet bureaucratically mandated requirements. Too often,
they substitute the judgments and priorities of federal bureaucrats for the judgments and priorities of elected representatives in the states.
I want to caution you that elimination of general revenue-sharing to state and
local governments would be a serious mistake. It is the most responsible and least
inflationary form of federal-state spending. It avoids the waste and inefficiency of
complex, multiple planning and reporting systems. The states have used this money
to meet pressing needs-such as education and health care. Categorical spending, by
contrast, often takes place regardless of need. Eliminating revenue-sharing would
undermine the careful balancing of needs and resources that state and local governments must guarantee-in the context of a balanced budget.
I also want to urge you to maintain equity between rural and urban areas and
between the different regions of this country.
Assistance to state and local governments appears to bear a disproportionate
burden of the President's austerity program. These programs fall from a 14.8
percent share of the total budget in 1979 to 13.8 percent in 1980. The decline is even
more dramatic when state and local assistance is compared with the budget authority for domestic spending. Further, the budget authority for state and local programs
is projected to grow by only 1 percent, far less than the projected rate of inflation
(7.4 percent).
To some extent, this decline in relative share for state and local programs, reflects
the phase-out of economic stimulus assistance programs. However, the relative
decline is also apparent to a lesser degree in the program relating to North Carolina's major policy initiatives. None of the economic stimulus programs were included
in the three state policy initiatives (See Attached Tables A, B, and C at conclusion
of my remarks.)
With the exception of the Crime Control policy area, the state's policy initiatives
show a relative decline and a slower rate of growth than the total budget or
proposed domestic spending. The Balanced Growth area is the most seriously affected falling from a 4.8 percent to a 4.1 percent share of the budget. The impact is even
more severe upon programs aimed at small cities and rural areas (see attached
Table A). All of the actual dollar increase in this policy area can be-traced to
Presidential proposals that will mostly benefit large distressed cities.
We need more discretion and authority at the state level, not less. Program
managers should be rewarded for holding down costs and for being responsive to
needs. States should have greater latitude in defining needs, combining programs
and eliminating unnecessary red tape.
The great advantage of a balanced budget is that it will force us to take those
steps. It will require tough scrutiny and hard decisions. It will require accountability and honesty in government. It will force us to find waste and develop new

225
approaches and be more productive with what we already have. It will be a counterweight to the insatiable demands of the special-interest groups.
I want to conclude by praising President Carter for the progress he is making
toward the goal of a balanced budget. I hope Congress will support him. The people
of this country are looking for a sign that we are serious about fiscal responsibility.
If they don't see it, they are ready to send the loudest and clearest message they can
to Washington-in the form of a constitutional convention. I believe that we should
let them know that we have gotten the message.

226
TABLE A

Balanced Growth

State Policy Initiative:

Budget Authority (millions)

- -

Program Areas

1980

-1979

Urban/Metro National Dev. Banks *
Urban Parks
C.D. Block Grants (80%)
Urban Dev. Action Grants (75%)
Urban Mass Transit
Neighborhood Dev. Corp.
Liveable Cities

%of Budget Area
1979

1980

-

550.0
-145.0
3,120.0
300.0
2,653.8
15.0
5.0

5,986.0

6,788.8

750.0
282.5
13.0
2,250.0
100.0
76.5

780.0
265.0
10.5
1,950.0
100.0
75.0

3,472.0

3,l80.5

368.6
64.0
228.5
170.4
20.0
88.5
4,200.0
738.0
7,994.1
1,373.0

358.6
71.0
225.3
176.4
20.0
77.2
3,800.0
610.0
8,599.5
1,238.1

Sub-Total

15,245.1

15,176.1

61.7

60.4

Grand Total

24,703.1

25,145.4

100.0

100.0

24, 703. 1

2,800.0
Z7-A57T

Sub-Total
Small Cities/Rural Areas
CDBG (20F)
,FLA lWater/Sew.er
Risiness Dev.
Dev. Loans
UDAG (2Tir,)
Rural Mass. Trans.
Sub-Total

-

33.0
3,000.0
300.0
2,i53.0
-

24.2

27.0

14.]

!2.6

Ceneral

ARC
Title V Commissions
EDA - Pf
Business Dev.
Sec. 304
Title IX
EPA '201'
Iaxd/Tatcor Cons. Fund
Hihxa:,' Trust
Airport Trust

New Programs
National Developrent Bank*
*Note:

2.4
34.2
4.9

This amount reflects proposed loans, subsidies and guarantees authority the
bank would use to directly assist private organizations rather than
channeling through states and local governments.

227
TABLE B
Policy Initiative:

Raising A New Generation

Budget Authority (millions)
1979

Program Areas
Health Maternal & Child Health
Family Planning
CDC Project Grants
Child Health/Hummn Dev.
Child Nutrition
EIC
Special Milk
Sub-Ibtal

1980

%of Budget Area
1979

1980

380.5
135.0
84.7
190.1
2,697.1
:569.5
142.0
4,198.9

375.0
145.0
88.8
204.4
3,161.3
771.5
32.0
4,746.0

15.1

16.6

3,521.3
71.7
967.6
3,922.7
791.6
202.4
92.5
134.5
816.0
10,510.3

3,952.9
76.9
1,027.8
3,687.0
772.4
157.6
98.3
117.6
528.0
10,418.5

37.7

36.5

6,664.1
2,776.4
777.2
385.0
60.0
17.0
6.0
1,967.0
400.0
13,052.7

7,079.2
2,632.3
849.8
385.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
1,925.0
438.0
13,309.3

46.8

46.6

64.1
35.0
99.1

60.5
38.5
99.0

0.4

0.4

27,861.0

28,572.8

100.0

100.0

Educatidn -

ESEA
Indian Ed.
!Lindicapped Ed.
Student Assistance
Voc./Adult Ed.
Sehol Libraries
National Inst. of Ed.
SpeciaT Projects
;-Finral Impact Aid
Sub-Total
Welfare and Jobs Assistance Payments
Child Welfare
HIr=n Development
WIN
Youth Conservation Corps.
Sumer Youth
Youth Snorts
OETA - Youth
Child Support
Sub-Total

-

Jiustice -

Formula Grants
Juvenile Justice Programs
Sub-Total
Grand Total

228
TABLE C
Crime and Public Safety

Policy Initiative:

Budget Authority (millions)
Program Areas

5 of &idget Area
1979

1980

1979

1980

21.6
9.9
61.3
45.0
64.1
409.3
42.4
45.0
16.0
35.0
20.4
--770.0

21.4
9.9
10.0
30.0
60.5
185.3
19.3
30.0
28.0
38.5
19.4
497.9
950.2

75.3

129.7
133.1
252.8

139. I
119. 6
256.7

24.7

.21.4

100.0

1(O.0

Law Enforcement
Drug Fnforce Assistance
Nat. Inst. Corrections
Criminal Justice Planning
Cor-rections - Form. Grants
Juvenile Justice - "
Criminal Justice - "
Training/Manpower
Correctional Programs
Crime Prevention
Juvenile Justice Programs
Data/Statistics
*Proxnsod - WJARS
S'ub-Total

.

78.6

Disasters/Fire Prevention
Disaster Preparedness
Hazard 'iitigation/Assistance
Sab-Tocal
Grand Total
*.Note:

1,022.8

1,208.9

The President intends to transfer many of the functions now perfonrnd oy
ULAAand the National Institute of Corrections to proposed Office of Justice
Assistance, Research and Statistics (OJARS) as part of the 1979 Justice
System Improvement bill. OJARS will include several new programs, totaling
$36b.6 million and additional authority of $132.3 million for existing
LEAA programs.

229
Senator BENTSEN. Governor Thompson, you repeatedly indicate
that Federal funds should be funneled through States rather than
going directly to local governments. You also state that Congress is
subject to too much lobbying by too many interest groups. It seems
to me that the National Governors' Association is no less a lobbyist
than is the Conference of Mayors, who would probably be strenuously opposed to such a proposal. How would you counter the
mayors' arguments that they need the latitude to decide what is
best for their jurisdictions and that, in the past, most States have
not had aggressive urban policies?
I run into this also as chairman of the Transportation Subcommittee of the Environment and Public Works Committee, when it
comes to highways. I hear that fight all the time.
Governor THOMPSON. I appreciate the dilemmas and the concerns
put upon Members of Congress by the people back home. I think
that is something which, if approached by the Governors and the
mayors and the appropriate congressional committees, can be accommodated. I think there is a reasonable likelihood that those
competing interests could be balanced in trying to devise a mechanism which gives back to the States a little more authority to
reconcile competing municipal interests within their own borders,
not necessarily funneling all the moneys that now go directly to
communities back through the States as they once flowed.
I don't think we are asking for that. I don't think we are asking
that all of the dollars come back t6 our folks to be doled out. We
want to reconcile programs within our borders that are often in
disharmony in cities which are side by side.
I think we can set up a structure that would do that.
I might also say, if my reading of the press is correct, that the
Governors come and say, "Either let us keep what we have, or let
us have more latitude to use the funds we receive in more productive ways." That has been suggested this morning: a reform of
program structure. I don't think the Governors have come, as have
the mayors, for more funds-and I don't mean to put down the
mayors.
At this time, we are willing to help the Federal Government to
get the deficit under control. But I think the mayors can be accommodated, and we will work at it.
Senator BENTSEN. There has been a lot of talk of cutting categorical grants, but the response I have had this morning is for consolidation, and cutting waste, but not any specific categorical grants. If
I understood, Governor Snelling, you say you are going to be
coming up with that, but I did not get it this morning, and that is
what I had hoped to be able to hear.
Governor SNELLING. We are invited here, as I understood it, to
represent our association, and our association has only recently
undertaken the task-the obviously sensitive task-of asking its
members to identify categorical grants which they would be willing
to do without. I do respectfully suggest that cutting total expenditures can be accomplished two different ways, and will probably
require both ways.
One way is to find out how to do the things which the public has
ordered us to do, either directly, in our States, or through the
congressional representatives, and find ways to do those things

230
with less expense. Additionally, we must decide not to do as many
things. At this juncture, we do believe that consolidation of grants,
and less restrictive grants will give a greater opportunity for us to
address quite differing circumstances in our State. They do differ
enormously.
Some of us work on programs largely through counties. Some
States-Hawaii, for example-perform almost all of their public
services at the State level-welfare and almost all others. So, we
are saying that if we are given some flexibility in our States, that
an identical and, in some cases, a lesser amount of money available
for those same categorical grants will enable us to do the job, and
that is square one.
It takes a longer period of time to get the public sentiment and
some uniformity of public sentiment to entirely stop doing something. A year, or 5, or a relatively short period of time ago, we in
our States, or you in the Congress, were telling the people there
were services that absolutely had to be performed. We would like
to approach this in what we think is a uniform way.
Governor HUNT. The practical problem you run into in saying
what can be cut out, is that one assumes that you can just cut it all
out and that none of it is any good. Sometimes that is the case, but
more often the case is that this could be reduced some.
There are changes we could make, and this can take some reduction. I don't think it is going to be very realistic to expect Governors to identify a lot of programs that can be totally cut out.
Senator BENTSEN. Right now, I would settle for one.
Governor HUNT. Governor Snelling is getting responses from the
Governors, but I would just suggest they are more apt to say, "Yes,
we can make reductions." As far as I am concerned, an awful lot of
them can be cut across the board.
Senator BENTSEN. Let me make another point. State expenditures have been going up dramatically in recent years, and reliance
on Federal dollars has increased substantially. Some Governors
have been able to bring about tax cuts. Part of that seems to me to
be financed with Federal dollars. We have this incredible problem
with the dollar and the debts. I can't help but believe that every
time we collect a note, that money loses a little weight before it
gets back down to the Governors. I had just assumed you fellows
collect those taxes on your own-that that is what the State is
doing-and not sending it back to Washington.
I can't help but remember the old story Senator Long tells-he
tells it much better-about the old gentleman who addressed a
note to God and asked him to send him $100. He was in desperate
need. For some reason, they sent it to the President, and someone
in the White House said, "Let's humor the old fellow. He ought to
get by with $50. Send him the $50." He wrote another note back to
God and said, "God, I sure appreciate the $50, but the next time, I
would really appreciate it if you didn't send it through Washington. It seems to lose a little coming through Washington."
Governor SNELLING. Then there is an old story about Jeb, up in
Vermont. Jeb wasn't feeling too well, so he went to see his doctor.
The doctor said, "Jeb, if you don't stop your drinking, you are
going to lose your hearing. Why don't you stop this drinking?"

231
Jeb replied, "I like the taste of what I am drinking a lot better
than what I am hearing."
There is a sense in which this dialog, based on the question of
who is going to give up what first, is a little bit like Jeb, because it
seems to me that the States, given the tremendous number of
mandated programs and programs which have been initiated by
the Federal Government and partially funded by the Federal Government as an incentive, as an encouragement and as an instruction, literally undertake our own programs, and this gives considerable pause for the problem. Is it unfair for the States to say back to
the Federal Government, "Which of the things you instruct us to
do are you prepared to stop instructing us to do?"
In Vermont, we thought we had too many unemployed fathers on
welfare. Bear in mind that that particular program, welfare assistance to unemployed fathers, is a voluntary program. It is not
required by the Federal mandate, but it is a system, and it is
largely paid for by general fund dollars at the State level.
We designed a program which really required little else. It
meant those people tried to find employment first, and that we
assist them.
The Department of Labor, under regulations set up and sanctioned by the U.S. Congress, told us we could not do that. We had
to modify that program. We run into many, many examples of
things that you have told us to do, for example, 94-142-and I am
not speaking from a state which has any reluctance to discharge
responsibilities for the handicapped, because Vermont had completed 6 years of such plans before Congress passed 94-142.
When the Congress passes programs of that kind and gives a
year or so for compliance, and does not provide the funds to do it,
the Congress has absorbed some of the capacity of the States to use
funds raised at the local level to meet the obligations of programs
at the local level.
We, sir, are literally a catch-22.
Senator BENTSEN. Let's talk about that. I assume you are a
member of the Coalition of Northeastern Governors.
Governor SNELLING. Yes.
Senator BENTSEN. In their analysis of the President's budget,
nowhere is there a request for restraint or curtailment. They indicate several of the programs are underfunded. In addition, they
advise their members that "there are new opportunities for the
States of the region to begin to meet pressing problems through the
infusion of new Federal funds."
It appears they are talking restraints on the one side, but still
clamoring for new Federal dollars.
Governor SNELLING. I am not a spokesman for the Coalition of
Northeastern Governors. In fact, until recently, I had the interesting but disturbing status of being the only Republican member, so I
seldom speak for that group.
However, I will speak for the National Governors' Association
and our position is that we favor restraint in spending, and we
encourage reduction in Federal appropriations; we wish to provide
some asistance as to how they may be accomplished, and, as a
matter of fact, we have recently adopted a policy that we are going
to, as a result of action taken by the executive committee, require

232
fiscal notes on all policy statements of the National Governors'
Association so that we will not fall into the trap that you just
referred to with respect to that other organization.
Governor THOMPSON. May I make two brief points?
First, I think it would be very useful for both this committee and
the National Governors' Association to undertake a definitive
study of how much of the increase in State spending, or State tax
reductions, which are another form of spending, are fueled by
Federal dollars, and how much are fueled by surpluses accumulated due to progressive taxes.
Senator BENTSEN. You are absolutely right on that.
I am interested in knowing exactly how much is caused by our
mandating.
I have called for a study of this by this committee. The responsibility of this committee is a very substantial one. We analyze the
impact of the President's budget and project what we see for the
economy and indicate some of the things we think are important
and that need to be done. In addition, the effect on States by
mandated programs is a very important issue. I could not agree
with you more. I really do.
Governor THOMPSON. You asked for some examples of how you
can save money. Let me give you two illustrations of how we could
save Federal dollars, for that is what they are, or Federal and
State dollars, in two programmatic areas, by moving toward the
block grant concept.
When I was in the process of.preparing my budget to be released
next week, the man who administers the Governor's office for
manpower and development, in charge of our CETA program, came
to me and said, "You are not going to like this"-and I share
Governor Hunt's concern about head count and employees. I would
like to keep that down. I have had to add 300 case workers for
abused children, and 700 prison guards. I had no choice.
I am looking for other ways in the Government to keep that
count down. He said, "I am going to have to ask you to authorize
the addition of 100 and 200 new employees." I said, "For what?" He
said, "To monitor our CETA program."
I asked, "Are they needed to run a good program?"
He said:
No, I don't think all of them are needed to run a good program, but all of them
are required to comply with Federal mandates. If we don't comply with these
Federal mandates, we will have government auditors in here, and they will be
saying the State of Illinois was maladministering this program.

We pay and you pay for approximately 1,000 employees in the
State of Illinois, a total of $20 million to do nothing but draw 100
separate State plans to be submitted to the Federal Government by
11 State agencies to receive funding from 171 separate Federal
sources, just for programs for children and family services.
If we move away from the categorical to the block grant, we
could dispense with most, if not all, of those 1,000 employees.
Senator BENTSEN. The trouble we see with general revenue sharing is that when it was originally proposed, it was proposed as a
substitute for some of the categorical grants. That is not the way it
worked out. Revenue sharing went beyond that.

233
Since we have a time limit, I will now recognize my colleague in
the House, Congressman Brown.
Representative BROWN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
I have to say this is an area in which the Senator and I have a
relatively slight disagreement on how things should be dealt with,
but it comes from our experience level, perhaps, and also from the
global view one gets from a Senate constituency as large as Texas.
My constituency is somewhat smaller than Texas, geographically
and in numbers, but it is a little bit more like Vermont, Governor
Snelling.
We have no major metropolitan areas in my constituency, and I
find that I have a bias for revenue sharing, and against some of the
categorical programs, because somehow, they have never been able
to come up with a category that helps the folks in my district.
Mostly, what we do is pay for programs, and revenue sharing is
one of the first opportunities we really have on a per capita basis
to get some money back out from Uncle Sam.
Our folks generally don't like the idea of getting any money out
of Uncle Sam under any circumstances, because they have the
feeling they have to pay for it.
A comment was made in one of your testimonies here and I have
read them all, and they all kind of run together in my mind,
because all Governors look alike. The question I am asking is that
a comment was made about the efficiency of revenue sharing,
collections, and distributions. Do you have a statistical figure on
that? What percentage of revenue sharing, collection and distribution goes for the administrative handling of revenue-sharing funds?
Governor SNELLING. No, sir, I don't have a statistical summary
with me today, but I will say that it varies from State to State,
from darned close to zero, to perhaps some considerable sums.
There are some States that use it, I think, quite properly, as sort of
a not otherwise classified fund to make up for shortfalls in Federal
programs when a program is designed and has certain standards of
operation. Then the funding does not come through quite in that
way.
A number of States use their State shares of the general-revenue
fund for that purpose. It is an elastic fund, and that obviously
takes a considerably lower cost, but I am afraid I can't answer your
question.
Representative BROWN. Far be it from me to tell you administrators how to get your act together, but I think you should get those
statistics at the Federal level. I serve on the subcommittee dealing
with revenue sharing on the House side of the Government Operations Committee. It runs in my mind the statistic in terms of the
Federal cost, in terms of checks and distributions, is only one-tenth
of 1 percent of the cost of the funds distributed, the lowest administrative cost of any Federal program. A record with reference to
Government programs and the subcommittee dealing with revenue
sharing has that statistic.
Let me give you one other reason for my bias with regard to
categorical programs, rather in opposition to categorical programs.
The largest city in my district has 85,000 people-that is a chamber of commerce figure-it is probably closer to 80,000-but in any
event, it is one of the few cities of that size in the United States

234
that has ever, by initiative referendum, denied to the city officials
the right of eminent domain. The reason they did, and I don't know
whether it would stand up in a constitutional sense, was that for
about 3 or 4 years running, they had back in the late 1950's and
early 1960's, or perhaps it was mid-1960's, urban renewal issues to
resolve, and they came up with the plans and then found out that
their plan was not drawn according to current Federal requirements. The next year, they drew them according to the Federal
requirements, submitted the plan and found out that the money
had been expended and was not available for them at that time.
The next year, they made plans and applied for the money quite
early, and found out that the program had been altered and the
whole thing had to be scrubbed. They had to start over with a new
approach to the Federal requirements in this area, and the fourth
year, something similar in nature happened again, and the people
of the community gave the instructions to the city fathers:
You stop messing around with those people down there, and wasting our money
on all these plans and submissions. In order to assure that it will not in the future
get involved with them on renewal, we are denying you the right of eminent domain
to participate in the program.

It later took the combined efforts of the chamber of commerce,
the labor union central committee, and the city, several civic and
social groups in the city, and consumer groups and civil rights
groups, and so forth, to pass a repealer. of that eniment domain
denial.
We now are back to the Federal program business, but it left a
very bad taste in the mouths of the people in that community. I
thought it was a rather unusual response to control the city fathers
in that way.
That is one of the concerns that I have about categorical grant
programs.
I would suggest to you that there may be a couple of issues here
with reference to categorical grant programs. One is the disproportionate concern, and I mention that principally in my opening
remarks, over the disproportional Federal distribution of funds. It
seems to me that here in Washington we tend to target those funds
to certain kinds of programs, leaving other national issues unaddressed, which perhaps, at the State and local levels, particularly
with records of different States, there may be a different concern
for some things.
One, I would submit, involves potholes. A bill was distributed on
a State-by-State basis last year to resolve-Senator BENTSEN. We killed that bill in the Senate.
Representative BROWN. The House did not kill it. I voted against
it. We were unsuccessful in killing it in the House, but the State
funds distribution included funds for States like Florida to cure
potholes in that State. I had some difficulty with that. I have been
to Florida several times, but don't remember being cold enough for
potholes.
The concept of that bill was that we were going to go after a
specific problem. We had other bills of that nature that did get
passed. Maybe the rat control bill is a classic example, when we
were worried about social problems of that nature, and you got
your money or you did not get your money, depending on whether

235
or not you used it for the specific purpose that the bill was designed for.
So, I am concerned about that kind of distributional
disproportionateness, if I can use that term.
I would like to ask one other question. You may comment on
that concern of mine, if you wish, but I would like to ask one other
question, which is the number of Federal mandated programs that
require the State to make comparable or proportional spending in
a particular area. Do you have any statistics on whether the States
all use the federally mandated funds that must be matched by the
States, or is there an inability on the part of some States to
respond to that kind of Federal assistance?
I have in mind pipeline safety legislation, the meat inspection
requirements of the Federal Government, and several others which
you say you get the money if you provide certain services or
change your laws to meet the6se requirements, so that you will do it
the way the Federal Government wants you to do it.
Governor SNELLING. Mr. Congressman, the States are beginning,
more and more, not to take up, soak up all the dollars that are
made available on Federal matching programs, because you really
don't raise a critical issue when you talk about a mandate.
Let's talk about a drinking water bill, for example. The States
have to determine theoretically by voluntary sources whether they
will accept primacy, or whether primacy will continue to reside
with the Federal Government, but Congress has mandated certain
accomplishments with respect to all the States by certain years.
There are certain substantial expenditures. When you sit down
with the representatives of the Federal Government to discuss the
pros and cons of primacy, what they tell you, very disarmingly, is
that if you don't accept primacy, that you cease to get Federal
funds for projects which are absolutely necessary, and would otherwise have been available to you.
So if there is really any judgment to be made about primacy, the
States will accept primacy, and they will fulfill the mandates on
the Federal Government's time schedule for pure drinking water,
or they will lose even the capacity that they now have to address
those needs.
I don't know how it would work out economically in all other
States, but I believe that my legislature would approve, in record
time, a deal whereby we do away with all general revenue sharing,
if the Federal Government agrees to stop mandating performances
in our State for which they don't compensate us.
We would have that argument over, and we could talk about how
further savings could be made by packaging the remaining categorical grants, but I have no doubt in my mind that the cost of
mandated Federal programs not addressed by Federal funding is
enormously more than Vermont's share of general revenue sharing.
Governor HUNT. Congressman, if I follow up on what Governor
Snelling just said, I would strongly urge this committee-and this
is a long-range view of things, and has pushed toward improvements in how we manage our financing-to look toward getting
State and local governments to work together to utilize funds and,

236
furthermore, to work together with Federal agencies that have a
responsibility in this particular field.
For example, the question of housing. We generally have State
housing finance agencies or development agencies. Local people, of
course, are involved. We have the Farmers Home Administration
and HUD and all these other programs. There are various ways in
which we should have the Federal, State, and local employees
working together to combine funds in the best kind of ways, so that
we meet our needs.
We are doing that in my State. We have what we call our
balanced group policy. We don't have the problems between the
mayors and the State level, because we are working together. They
are having a voice in determining where funds are going and how
we are using them, both State and local funds.
If we develop that kind of mechanism, that kind of procedure,
you can put the money into a pot and'then you can know that both
State officials, which have a broader view, and local officials, who
want to have their own voice in things, are being involved in
making those decisions.
That is the way I think we ultimately ought to go with regard to
categorical versus revenue sharing.
Representative BROWN. My time is up, but I hope I will have an
opportunity to come and differ with some of your testimony.
Senator BENTSEN. Congressman, why don't you do that now? I
will give up my time in the interest of saving the Governors' time.
Representative BROWN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Governor Snelling, I am a little bit concerned about your comments about budget appropriations. I operate a business in real
life, and we have to do our accounting procedures, allowing for
depreciation of machinery and buildings, and so on.
You suggest that if the Federal Government would approach its
budgeting processes in the same way States do; that is, on capital
improvements, funding them as a debt and paying them off as part
of the budgetary process, then rather than including an expenditure for that item all in the budget for that 1 year, we might be
closer to a balanced budget than now shows up in the way we
handle those things in accounting procedures.
The thing that worries me is that State governments, it seems to
me, do not allow for the depreciation of the capital expenditures
that they make, and really are not keeping a good business record,
either at the State or Federal level on that basis. Would you want
to react to that comment?
Governor SNELLING. I, too, in real life am a manufacturer. I
would just have to say that any relationship between accounting
practices in the private sector and the public sector, whether it is
Federal, State, or local, is purely coincidental.
They don't even start from the same premise, so neither Federal
nor State governments capitalize from the standpoint of a capital
asset and liability of the original or remaining asset.
The concept is not known. That is why more and more States are
going to long-term capital plans so they can take into consideration
at what point they will have to consider replacement capital.
I am not saying that the Federal Government should adopt the
practice of the States' selling bonds for capital construction. The

237
argument was only comparison between the liquidity, because that
is really the argument being made by some Members of the Congress, that the States are more liquid in that they show a match
between revenues and expenditures, whereas the Federal Government does not.
I think, as a matter of fact, that the States' method of handling
.it represents some equity for current taxpayers in that the alternative to capital bonding would be current taxpayers would have to
pay for the cost of projects that last 20 or 30 years.
On the other hand, the Federal Government's method of handling things is more conservative, in that it demonstrates at once
exactly what the cost of projects is, and bonding in turn really
tends to encourage greater expenditures at a moment in time.
My statement did not suggest, nor do I think it would be a good
idea, for the Federal Government to start bonding for long-term
projects. It is merely to suggest the inequality in the comparison
made between ingo and outgo of the States and the Federal Government.
Representative BROWN. Let me turn, on that point, to the question of the States' surpluses, and the balanced budget question.
First, could you tell me how many States have constitutional
prohibitions against a deficit in current operations?
Governor SNELLING. Forty States have barriers. They are not all
constitutional. I would like to leave two booklets with you. One is a
fiscal survey of State, 1978-79, published by the National Association of State Budget Officers and the MCA, concerning fiscal
conditions of the States. The questions you are asking are covered
more specifically there. Forty-eight States have restrictions or barriers against unbalanced budgets.
Representative BROWN. It occurs to me, as a watcher of the
Federal budget process, that one of the things that happens to us
from time to time-and, df cdurse, we are discussing it in this
hearing-is that the Federal Government, from time to time, misjudges the receipts and expenditures that it has to make and, not
having the prohibitions against deficit financing, of course, frequently the budget deficit comes out much lower or much higher
than the prediction. This is because we have additional receipts
that come in on a rising economy, or a loss in receipts that come in
on a falling economy, which frequently require expenditures, or
that Congress responds to in that way.
It occurs to me that one of the responses is that there is a lot of
-surplus in State budgets these days, because we have had a rising
economy throughout the country, and the prohibition against deficit spending requires the Governors to prepare relatively conservative budgets to present to the. States. Then suddenly, there is a
surge of receipts, and you are a little better off than you anticipated being, and, therefore, show a larger receipts balance than otherwise; is that true?
Governor SNELLING. It is very true, and it is also very important
to one of the basic points of discussion as regarding general revenue sharing or the economic conditions of the States.
When the States fell into recession in 1974 and 1975, many
States had no choice but to raise taxes, because their constitutions
or other limitations called upon them to plan balanced budgets.
.

47-977 0 - 79 - 16

.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

238
The increased costs of many social programs-unemployment-type
related programs, welfare programs-caused the States to be looking at very clear deficits, and they had to raise the taxes.
When the economy recovered, the increased tax rates, together
with the buoyancy of the economy, obviously produced surpluses.
The philosophic point I want to make, and the point of justice, is to
the extent those surpluses were because of our having undertaken
the burden of taxation in bad times, the States should not be
considered overly liquid when that came as a result of having to
raise taxes in a prior bad time. The result has been that taxes have
now been reduced and that has been cited as an indication of
liquidity, but it merely restores it to the level prior to the last
recession.
Governor HUNT. Not only do we have to plan for a balanced
budget, but we have to keep it throughout the year.
In my State-and, I assume, in other States-if revenues are not
coming in at an adequate level, we just have to cut back as needed.
There is great reason for being conservative and properly so, and
this is what is needed at the Federal Government.
Representative BROWN. Let 'me press on, unless you want to
make any other comments on that issue. If not, I will go on to
another issue.
There has been a lot of talk by economists in this committee, and
elsewhere, about the prospects of a recession in the next couple of
months. The question was, what do you anticipate in your States
will happen to the surpluses? Would you anticipate you will have
enough balance to make it through without making major adjustments in the budget, or not?
I won't press that.
Governor HUNT. We are reducing the amount of growth in our
budgets, and we are anticipating that.
Governor SNELLING. These books would show you these trend
lines. If they were on a chart, they would be square, but because
the surpluses that existed in 1977 have been halved, and because of
the estimate for 1979 in my prepared statement, frankly we are
predicting a small deficit for fiscal 1980. That is allowable in our
State only because we operate on a biennial basis, but I would
anticipate the States will not have supluses in fiscal 1980 and 1981.
Representative BROWN. Do all of you favor a balanced budget
amendment, or do you have different views?
I would say, Governor Hunt, I have read your prepared statement. North Carolina is one of the States represented here that sat
in on the first Constitutional Convention. I am not so sure it is a
good idea to have a State constitutional convention, but Ohio has a
background, too.
Governor HUNT. I would much rather the Congress do it. Earlier,
there was a cry for direct elections of Senators. The people wanted
it for a long time, and the Congress did not respond. Now, almost
enough States called a convention, and the United States submitted an amendment, and it passed.
Governor SNELLING. I oppose having that, and I feel we need
fiscal restraint measured by the thoughtful actions of the Congress.
Governor THOMPSON. I do oppose the constitutional convention,
and I have not quite been persuaded that a constitutional amend4

239
ment can be drawn with sufficient care or safety or, as a matter of
discipline, needs to be drawn, or should be drawn.
I tried to make the point at the National Governors' Association
meeting the other day that if the Congress does not now have the
internal discipline to balance the budget, passing a constitutional
amendment requiring a balanced budget will not help the problem,
because all it will do is make the pie smaller and increase the
pressures on you.
Internal discipline is needed to tell the mayors and everybody
else who comes down here what is important and what is not.
Representative BROWN. You may. want to take the fifth on this. I
want. to go back to ask you if you know of specific examples,
obviously, in some other State than that which you represent,
where Federal funds were supplied for a specific purpose, and have
been accepted, and then used to accomplish what the local government felt had a priority other than for that specific purpose.
As I understand the first general revenue-sharing money distribution requirements, they prohibited the use of general revenuesharing funds to match other Federal funds but, of course, they go
into an aggregated budget and, therefore, they can be used for
something that you might have planned to use local funds for
otherwise, and the locally generated funds can be used to match. It
seems to me that that is not illegal, but a fairly clever accounting
method of meeting that requirement of the general revenue-sharing law. There are other examples, at least more of the levels than
I am aware of in my district, where good school superintendents
have taken money for distributional educational programs and
used it for repairing a gym floor or something else.
They tell me how they do that, and still feel they can live within
the law and face the taxpayers with integrity.
I think it would be helpful for those of us who feel some concern
about category assistance programs-I don't have to give them
now, I know you want to hurry along-that I cite as one of the
examples in this area and, perhaps Governor Thompson can tell us,
whether any planning funds are ignored in any way. There may be
other examples more appropriate. If you want to.supply them for
the record, I would be happy to know about them.
Governor THOMPSON. I have heard it happening in other States,
as you suggest.
Governor SNELLING. Congressmen and Governors do not have the
right to take the fifth amendment. That is not a privilege accorded
to the chief executive officers of States.
I would say to you, I don't know of any specific example of abuse
of the law, but I would say that the allocated process is susceptible
to imaginative use.
I believe people do find the most appropriate source for the funds
required, so the end-use of the Federal funds may sometimes be in
terms of the increment or the marginal performance, and may not
do what is intended, but I think that there will always be accomplishable, regardless of how strictly one would write or follow up
on special categorical grants.
Governor HUNT. I would say it is logical, if the State and local
people have a voice in the way the funds will be used, to assume
that they are more apt to be used more properly.

240
Representative BROWN. I think there is always the feeling on
both sides of the table, that there is a better idea of what should be
done with public money, and I am sure you feel that way, as
Governors. I am sure the third level of government offidials may
think that neither the States nor the Federal Government know
what should be done with the money. If they could handle it, they
could handle it better, they think. I understand that psychologically, but I also think there is one other thing that happens.
That is that we think we control from the Federal level how it is
spent, and you may think, as Governor, you are controlling it when
it goes local, with reference to its expenditures, but I think the
people who ultimately make the expenditure have more to do with
how it is spent than any of us.
Senator BENTSEN. Let me add my little bit on that. I think if we
left it to the taxpayer, he would feel he could best control it.
Thank you, gentlemen, very much, for your comments. We appreciate having them, and your point of view.
[Whereupon, at 11:57 a.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene
at 10 a.m., Friday, March 2, 1979.]

THE 1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE
PRESIDENT
FRIDAY, MARCH 2, 1979
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,

Washington, D.C.

The committee met, pursuant to recess, at 10 a.m., in room 2253,
Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Richard Bolling (vice chairman of the committee) presiding.
Present: Representatives Bolling, Reuss, and Rousselot.
OPENING STATEMENT OF REPRESENTATIVE BOLLING, VICE CHAIRMAN

Representative BOLLING. The committee will be in order.

We are very pleased to have as our witnesses this morning two
very distinguished leaders of the American labor movement. Mr.
Howard Young is special consultant to the president. He is replacing the president of the United Auto Workers, because my very
good personal friend has a bad cold, and I am glad-although I
regret he is not here-he is taking care of it, because not taking
care of a cold-can be very unpleasant.
And Mr. Rudolph Oswald, research director of the AFL-CIO, who
is accompanied by Ken Young. This, at least in my experience, is
the first time I have seen him officially since he has been head of
the legislative department of the AFL-CIO. We are delighted to
welcome you both.
The Joint Economic Committee has been considering a number
of issues during its annual hearings that are of major concern to
American workers and the American labor movement.
The first is jobs. During 1978, the employment situation improved dramatically. Between January 1978 and January 1979, 3.3
million new jobs were created. In January of this year, a record
59.3 percent of all adult Americans held jobs. Since the fall of 1977,
we have cut 1 full percentage point from the unemployment rate.
But jobs are still an important issue. Although we are rid of the
extraordinarily large unemployment caused by the 1974-1975 recession, there are still many people who are unemployed for structural reasons.
Structural unemployment is a great tragedy for this country. It
means people who have poor educations, people with inadequate
job skills, and people who have suffered from discrimination are
the people who will have a difficult time finding jobs even in better
times.
(241)

242
If we fail to attack structural unemployment with effective job
training and placement programs, we will be shunting these
Americans aside, and wasting one of our most valid resources.
Before I read on to the second and third points in this statement,
I'd like to mention that one of the concerns that many of us have
had is the whole question of productivity and capital formation.
Mr. Oswald told me some very interesting things just a few minutes ago that I hope he will work into his statement, or in answers
to questions somewhere along the line, because there is some information that is of great importance to this committee and to the
country.
The second is inflation. Despite the fact that the average worker's weekly income rose 8.7 percent during 1978, inflation actually
made many worse off with real gross weekly earnings falling 0.3
percent over the year. The Labor Department reports that the
spendable income of a worker with three dependents actually fell
3.4 percent in real terms last year. This inflation is simply eating
away at the livelihood of the American worker. It has an affect
that is not a healthy one in terms of our ability to function in this
country as a responsible participant in the world and affairs outside our borders, as well as causing difficulties within our borders.
President Carter has an anti-inflation program which includes
fiscal and monetary restraint, wage and price guidelines, and control of regulatory costs. We would like to have your thoughts on
how well this program is working, and whether there is anything
more we can do to improve the plight of the average worker.
The third problem is foreign trade. We are all for free trade as
long as our partners play by fair rules. But if we open the floodgates for foreign imports while other countries, such as Japan,
slam the door on our goods through complex regulations, artificial
standards, and administrative delays, then the game isn't being
played fairly.
For the past 30 years, our vast markets have helped to build
strong economies abroad, often to the detriment of American workers who have lost jobs to imports. If foreign countries don't reduce
some of the artificial barriers to our goods, we may have to reexamine our own trade policy.
Now, this opening statement was prepared for Senator Bentsen,
who has been very much involved in this particular issue. But
since it happens to express my own views very well, I decided to
include it.
I think we are in a very difficult situation, which is now becoming clearer and clearer and clearer. We are dealing with a variety
of countries which are described usually as free enterprise countries, but which are really led by governments. The position, the
power of government, in making the foreign trade policy of a
variety of our allies, is, I think, very much underestimated, and I
think we will have to look at our hold card, if I can put it in that
crude way, if we are going to be successful in competing. That
represents not a new discovery by me, but a realization that the
situation has become more acute, at least in my opinion, over the
last few years.
We look forward to your testimony.
Please proceed, Mr. Oswald.

243
STATEMENT OF RUDOLPH OSWALD; RESEARCH DIRECTOR,
AMERICAN FEDERATION OF LABOR AND CONGRESS OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATIONS, ACCOMPANIED BY KENNETH
YOUNG, DIRECTOR, LEGISLATIVE DEPARTMENT

Mr.

'OSWALD. .Thank you,

Mr. Vice Chairman. Mr. Lane Kirkland

had hoped to be with the committee, but he expresses his regret

that he is not able to be here this morning. Mr. Young, our director
of legislation, is accompanying me this morning.
I would like to address, first of all, the question of productivity
that you mentioned, Mr. Vice Chairman, before I get into the
formal remarks.
Representative BOLLING. Thank you.
Mr. OSWALD. I know this has been a major concern of yours, and
I think some of the headlines of the productivity gains in the past
year have failed t6 provide adequate emphasis on some of the real
improvements in productivity that have taken place in the productivity sector.
Over the past year, the nambers that are reported is 0.3 percent
gain in productivity for the total private economy.
The figures just released this week indicate a 1.1 percent gain in
productivity for nonfinancial institutions in the private sector, nonfarm sector. But I think the important figure is the growth in
productivity in the manufacturing sector over the last year, fourth
quarter to fourth quarter, which is 3.7 percent.
Now, that is a very healthy gain, and, if we look at the gain in
manufacturing for the whole period of the 1970's, the rate of
growth in productivity in manufacturing was 2.4 percent, the same
rate we had in the 1950's. The only reason that it was not substantially better in the 1970's, as good as the 3 percent rate that we
had in the 1960's, was because of the. two severe recessions that
occurred in the 1970's, and, particularly, the severe recession in
1975 when you had negative productivity growth.
The summary of the details of the other industry sectors are
attached in the background statement that is a part of the appendi' to Toy prepared statement, and it is a background to the executive cduncil's national economy statement. The discussion of productivity is at the end of that background statement.
Representative BOLLING. Your presentation will appear in full in
the record.
Mr. OSWALD. Mr. Vice Chairman, I would like to read a part of
my prepared statement, because I believe it highlights some of our
major concerns.
Representative BOLLING. Proceed as you wish.
Mr. OSWALD. The AFL-CIO is deeply concerned about today's
inflation unemployment levels and dismal outlook for the rest of
this year. Present economic policies are not curtailing inflation, but,
are pushing the economy toward a recession. A new recession
would start from a higher level of unemployment than the last
recession. Unemployment is 1 full perceptage point, or 1 million
workers, higher than 5 years ago.
To control inflation; to move the Nation faster toward full employment, decisive, effective, and prompt Government action is
essential.

244
Unfortunately, the administration's anti-inflation program is
simply not working. It cannot be successful in holding down inflation because it does nothing effectively about controlling prices
while it relies wholly upon a rigid wage control mechanism. The
program fails to address adequately the inflation pressures on the
food, housing, energy and medical care sectors-the major problem
areas.
The current prospects are that inflation may well get worse in
1979. The wholesale or producer price indexes for January portend
greater consumer price increases over the new few months, and
continued high interest rates are driving up housing costs.
The administration's predictions on inflation did not include the
recent events in Iran, which are leading to shortages and higher oil
prices. The already weak dollar cannot withstand further speculation or higher trade deficits, as reflected in the January figures.
Furthermore, the administration's restrictive budget proposals
will not reduce inflation. Cutting essential programs to meet an
arbitrary $29 billion budget deficit will have only a one-tenth of 1
percent impact on the rate of inflation, according to the Congressional Budget Office figures. However, that budget will severely
cripple a number of important Federal programs and, worst of all,
would cut job programs at a time when the administration's own
projections indicate the unemployment will go up.
In fact, the Congressional Budget Office predicts an unemployment rate for December 1979 which may be up to 1 full percentage
point higher than administration estimates. That would mean 1
million more jobless workers at the very time the administration is
cutting back on programs to create jobs.
Despite the impressive increase in the number of jobs over the
past year, little or no dent was made in the official unemployment
rate which continues to hover around 6 percent.
Black unemployment, particularly depressed, has unemployment
levels remaining over 11 percent. This is nearly double the 6 percent black unemployment levels of the late 1960's.
Unfortunately, the economic policies of the administration-as
outlined in the President's Economic Report to the Congress and in
the administration's budget proposals-fail to meet the goals set by
the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment and Balanced Economic
Growth Act of 1978.
The administration expects the unemployment level to climb to
6.2 percent in the fourth quarter of 1979 and remain at that level
through 1980. The administration assumes that the unemployment
rate will start dropping in 1981 and will get down to the required 4
percent in 1984, but sets forth no programs over the next 2 years to
reduce unemployment. Rather, its policies do just the reverse. They
aggravate the already high unemployment levels.
Unless there is substantially more stimulus to the economy than
currently projected by the administration, the Humphrey-Hawkins
goal will not be met, and, according to the CBO, the unemployment
rate will still be at the high level of 5.5 percent in 1984.
The Joint Economic Committee has major responsibilities under
the Humphrey-Hawkins legislation. This committee has the responsibility to report to the Senate and House Budget Committees on
the short-term and medium-term goals set forth in the Economic

245
Report of the President. And this committee has the opportunity
and the responsibility to present to the Senate and House Budget
Committees policies and programs to achieve the HumphreyHawkins full employment goals.
We urge this committee to make in its report and recommendations a clear statement that the administration's economic goals
and policies are not adequate nor appropriate to fulfill the full
employment mandate of the Humphrey-Hawkins law nor to control
effectively continuing high inflation.
Many of the policies and programs proposed by the administration either ignore or are contrary to the nine distinct countercyclical employment policies proposed in section 202(a) of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, and I cite these parts, and I will touch on a
few of them and leave the rest of them for the record.
The first of those countercyclical programs proposed in section
202 is accelerated public works, including development of standby
public works projects.
The previous accelerated public works program has expired and
last year Congress failed to act on the so-called "soft" public works
program proposed by the administration. This latter program, of
course, is still needed and should be enacted promptly. A new
standby public works program should be established as an essential
part of an antirecession program, which could get started quickly,
if a new recession were to occur.
With regard to public service employment, contrary to the
budget proposal, the level of funding for CETA title VI anticyclical
public service jobs should be restored to the levels already approved by Congress, and the $1 billion proposed cut in title VI
funds rejected.
Item three, State and local grant programs. A targeted, countercyclical relief program to aid areas of high unemployment should
be adopted.
Item four, the levels and duration of unemployment insurance.
The unemployment compensation law needs to be immediately
improved to provide adequate protection against the threatening
recession. Specifically, the law should establish a Federal minimum
benefit standard of two-thirds of the worker's wage up to a maximum of three-fourths of the statewide average weekly wage, extend
the present maximum 39-week duration to 65 weeks, provide Federal financing from general revenue for benefits paid to workers
after they are unemployed 39 weeks and reimburse States for
disbursements they made beyond basic payments for the period
January 1975 to January 1978, and extend coverage to all workers
now excluded.
Item five, skill training in both the private and public sectors,
both as a general remedy and as a supplement to unemployment
insurance.

Contrary to the budget proposals, skilled training under national
training and outreach programs should be continued at current or
expanded levels. The proposed $50 million cut in title III funds
should be restored.
Item six, youth employment programs. Proposed budget cuts in
the funds for the summer youth programs which reduce employment opportunitites from 1 million to 750,000 should be rejected.

246
Item seven, community development programs to provide employment in activities of value to the States, local communitiesincluding rural areas-and the Nation. The administration's proposed National Development Bank would facilitate such community development, and should be approved by Congress.
The President's budget proposal would cut that funding by over
$1 billion from that which would be necessary to provide the jobs
that are in the bill passed by Congress last year. We feel that needs
to be remedied in terms of the job needs.
I develop in detail the total of nine items that are in that section,
and I would like to point out one part of the section 202(b), the
following language in the Humphrey-Hawkins bill, which makes
reference-and I would like to quote-"In any countercyclical efforts undertaken, the President shall consider a triggering mechanism which will implement the program during a period of rising
unemployment and phase out the program when unemployment is
appropriately reduced."
The President did not recommend a triggering mechanism, and
we would hope that the Joint Economic Committee would consult
with the Budget Committees both in the Senate and in the House
to provide a type of triggering mechanism so that when the conditions worsen, as they may well do later on this year, that there
may be an automatic measure under which countercyclical programs and public works can be gotten underway without going
through the process of the third budget resolution.
There can be a contingency situation, if unemployment worsens
substantially, so that the Appropriations Committees could just act
to provide the. funds for new programs under those conditions,
without going through the specific waiver provisions or a third
budget resolution.,
In addition to the specific employment policy proposals of Humphrey-Hawkins, the AFL-CIO is also deeply concerned about inflation, and at its recent executive council meeting, set forth the
following program to curtail inflation. I would like to quote from
that council statement:
We do not like controls. We do not welcome Government operation of the marketplace: But recession is worse; runaway inflation is worse; the discriminatory application of wage controls is worse, the distorting of laws for purposes other than those
intended is worse; public scapegoating without due process is worse.
Therefore, we urge the President to draft a legislative program of full economic
controls, covering every source of income-profits, dividends, rents, interest rates,
executive compensation, professional fees, as well as wages and prices.

Supplemental policies must be designed to deal with specific
price problems in the necessities. These should curb commodity
speculation that drives up the prices of wheat and other agricultural products, regulate exports of foodstuffs and other raw materials
to prevent domestic shortages, revise restrictive agricultural policies that contribute to shortages and insure that the benefits of
price support programs be restricted to family farmers, and expand
energy supplies to relieve the OPEC stranglehold on domestic
prices.

It should also continue to regulate gasoline and petroleum prices,
contain hospital costs and control professional fees for health care,
control and allocate credit toward productive public and industrial

247
investment, expansion of housing and assistance to the family
farmer and away from nonproductive areas such as corporate acquisitions and dollar speculation.
In addition, it should expand housing programs for low- and
middle-income families to expand the housing supply and reduce
the price and rent inflation.
An excess profit tax should be instituted to insure that businesses maintain fair prices, as well as revisions in the real wage insurance proposal to correct inequities.
The AFL-CIO, of course, is very much concerned about the need
for effective economic stimulus and more rapid economic growth,
so that the U.S. economy will be creating enough jobs for the
Nation's growing labor force and so that high unemployment will
be reduced instead of going higher.
The AFL-CIO called for five specific programs to maintain this
commitment, and they are 'as follows:
The Federal budget must provide stimulus to expand the economy and to shrink unemployment.
Employment and training programs need to be expanded to provide jobs and training.
Unemployment compensation needs to be improved and expanded to protect workers and the economy.
A National Development Bank must be established to bring employment opportunities to depressed areas.
Standby programs of expanded public works should be adopted so
that they will be in place to meet worsening unemployment.
As you indicated in your opening remarks, Mr. Vice Chairman,
the international economic area is also a major concern of ours,
and we are concerned that some of these international factors fuel
inflation in the United States, as well as weakening the U.S. position in the world economy.
You indicated the very big deficits over the past 2 years. We are
very concerned that the administration itself predicts very little
decline in that trade deficit for 1980.
We would like to point out that the big change in 1978 in terms
of imports, was the jump in manufactured imports, which jumped
from $77 billion to $100 billion in 1978, while oil imports actually
declined slightly .from $44 billion to $42 billion.
The AFL-CIO welcomes the President's state of the Union pledge
to "protect American jobs threatened by unfair trade." This pledge
and this goal should be in the forefront of U.S. policy in the
multilateral trade negotiations. When the codes and the implementing legislation are completed, their impact must be fully evaluated as to whether they do actually protect American workers
and industries against unfair trade competition and assure the
maintenance of a diversified, healthy U.S. economy.
Mr. Vice Chairman, I appreciate this opportunity to present the
views of the AFL-CIO on this range of economic issues. I have
attached, as supplements to my prepared statement, a number of
the statements recently adopted by the executive council on a
number of these issues. I tKink. these documents demonstrate that
there is the ability to meet the goals of Humphrey-Hawkins and to
meet inflation as well as to promote additional employment opportunities.

248
Representative BOLLING. Thank you very much, Mr. Oswald, for
a very clear statement of the position of the AFL-CIO. As I said
earlier, all the materials in your prepared statement, including the
supplementary ones, will be included in the record, without objection.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Oswald, together with appendix
material, follows:]

249
PREPARED

Mr.

STATEMENT OF RUDOLPH OSWALD

Chairman, I appreciate this opportunity to present the views

of the AFL-CIO on the current economic situation and current economic
policies.
Let me state at the outset that we are deeply concerned about
today's inflation and unemployment levels and the dismal outlook for the
rest of this year.

Present economic policies are not curtailing

inflation but are pushing the economy towards a recession.

A new

recession would start from a higher level of unemployment than the last
recession.

Unemployment is a full percentage point or 1 million workers

higher than five years ago.
To control inflation, to move the nation faster toward full
employment, decisive, effective, and prompt government action is
essential.
Unfortunately,
simply not working.

the Administration's anti-inflation program is

It cannot be successful in holding down inflation

because it does nothing effectively about controlling prices while it
relies wholly upon a rigid wage control mechanism.

The program fails

to address adequately the inflation pressures on the food, housing,
energy and medical care sectors -- the major problem areas.
The current prospects are that inflation may well get worse in
1979.

The wholesale or producer price indexes for January portend greater

consumer price increases over the next few months, and continued high
interest rates are driving up housing costs.

250
The Administration's predictions on inflation did not include the
recent events in Iran, which are leading to shortages and higher oil
prices.

The already weak dollar cannot withstand further speculation

or higher trade deficits, as reflected in the January figures.
Furthermore,

the Administration's restrictive budget proposals

will not reduce inflation.

Cutting essential programs to meet an

arbitrary $29 billion budget deficit will have only a one-tenth of one
percent impact on the rate of inflation, according to the Congressional
Budget Office figures.

However, that budget will severely cripple a

number of important federal programs

and, worst of all, would cut job

programs at a time when even the Administration's own projections
indicate that unemployment will go up.

In fact, the Congressional

Budget Office predicts an unemployment rate for December 1979 which
may be up to one full percentage point higher than Administration
estimates.

That would mean one million more jobless workers at the

very time the Administration is cutting back on programs to create jobs.
Despite the impressive increase in the number of jobs over the
past year,

little or no dent was made in the official unemployment rate

which continues to hover around 6 percent.
Black unemployment remains particularly depressed, with unemployment
levels remaining over 11 percent.

This is nearly double the 6 percent

black unemployment levels of the late 1960's.
Unfortunately, the economic policies of this Administration -as outlined in the President's Economic Report to the Congress and in the
Administration's Budget proposals --

fail to meet the goals set by the

Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment and Balanced Economic Growth Act of 1978.

V I

251
The Administration expects the unemployment rate to climb to
6.2 percent in

the fourth quarter of 1979 and remain at that level

through 1980.

The Administration

will start dropping in
in

1984,

assumes that the unemployment

rate

1981 and will get down to the required 4 percent

but sets forth no programs over the next two years to reduce

unemployment.

Rather,

its policies do just the reverse.

the already high unemployment

levels.

Unless there is

They aggravate

substantially

more stimulus to the economy than currently projected by the Administration,
the Humphrey-Hawkins goal will not be met,
unemployment rate will still

and,

be at the high

according to the CBO,

level of 5.5 percent in

the
1984.

The Joint Economic Committee has major responsibilities under the
Humphrey-Hawkins legislation.

This Committee has the responsibility to

report to the Senate and House Budget Committees on the short-term and
medium-term goals and policies set forth in the Economic Report of the
President.

And this Committee has the opportunity and the responsibility

to present to the Senate and House Budget Committees
programs to achieve the Humphrey-Hawkins
We urge this Committee to make in

policies and

full employment goals.
its report and recommendations

a clear statement that the Administration's

economic goals and policies

are not adequate nor appropriate

the full employment mandate

to fulfill

of the Humphrey-Hawkins law nor to control effectively continuing high
inflation.

252
Many of the policies and programs proposed by the Administration
either ignore or are contrary to the nine distinct countercyclical
employment policies proposed in Section 202(a) of the Humphrey-Hawkins
Act.

These are as follows:
1.

"Accelerate public works, including the development of standby

public works projects."
The previous accelerated public works program has expired and
last year Congress failed to act on the so-called "soft" public works program
proposed by the Administration.
should be enacted promptly.

This latter program is urgently needed and

A new standby public works program, should be

established as an essential part of an anti-recession program.
2.

"Public service employment."
Contrary to the budget proposal, the level of funding for CETA

Title VI anti-cyclical public service jobs should be restored to the-levels

already approved by Congress, and the $1 billion proposed cut in Title VI funi
rejected.
3.

"State and local grant programs."
A targeted, countercyclical relief program to aid areas of high

unemployment should be adopted.
4.

"The levels and duration of unemployment insurance."
The unemployment compensation law needs to be immediately improved

to provide adequate protection against the threatening recession.
Specifically the law should: (a) establish a federal minimum benefit
standard of two-thirds of the worker's wage up to a maximum of three-fourths

253
of the statewide average weekly wage,
39-week duration to 65 weeks,

(c)

(b)

extend the present maximum

provide federal financing from general

revenue for benefits paid to workers after they are unemployed 39 weeks
and reimburse states for disbursements they made beyond basic payments
for the period January 1975 - January 1978,

and (d)

extend coverage to

all workers now excluded.
5.

"Skill training in both the private and public sectors,

as a general remedy and as a supplement to unemployment
Contrary to the Budget proposals,
national training and outreach
or expanded levels.

both

insurance."

skilled training under

programs should be continued at current

The proposed $50 million cut in Title III funds

should be restored.
6.

"Youth employment programs."
Proposed budget cuts in

the funds for the Summer Youth Programs

which reduce employment opportunities from 1 million to 750,000 should
be rejected.
7.

"Community development

of value to the States,

programs to provide employment in activities

local communities (including

rural areas),

and the

Nation."
The Administration's

proposed National Development

facilitate such community development,

47-977 0 - 79 - 17

Bank would

and should be approved by Congress.

254
8.

"Federal procurement programs which are targeted on labor surplus

areas."
In this regard, Congress should review the impact of the
Multilateral Trade Negotiation's code on "government procurement."

This

new code may interfere with government procurement policies that give
The Congress,

preference to procurement to high-unemployment areas.

should examine the MTN agreements very carefully and make sure that procurement preference for high-unemployment areas is not weakened.
9.

"Augmentation of other employment and training programs which

would help to reduce high levels of unemployment arising from cyclical
causes," and 202(b) "In any countercyclical efforts undertaken, the President
shall consider a triggering mechanism which will implement the program
during a period of rising unemployment and phase out the program when
unemployment is appropriately reduced..."
Since the President did not recommend a triggering mechanism,
the Joint Economic Committee should consult with the Senate
budget Committees to provide a triggering mechanism.

and House

Advanced budget

authority for supplemental appropriations may well be needed later this
year to fund countercyclical programs at higher levels as the economy
moves into recession and higher levels of unemployment.

Such budget

authority could provide for countercyclical contingency funds and
emergency public works.

This would simplify and shorten the procedures

necessary to offset the recession which looms later this year.

255
In addition to the specific employment policy proposals of Humphrey
Hawkins, the AFL-CIO is also deeply concerned about inflation, and at its
recent Executive Council meeting set forth the following program to curtail
inflation.

The Council stated:

"We do not like controls.
of the market place.

We do not welcome government operation

But recession is worse; runaway inflation is worse;

the discriminatory application of wage controls is worse, the distorting
of laws for purposes other than those intended is worse; public scapegoating
without due process is worse.
"Therefore, we urge the President to draft a legislative program of
full economic controls, covering every source of income -- profits,
dividends, rents, interest rates, executive compensation, professional
fees, as well as wages and prices."
The AFL-CIO Executive Council went on to lay out a comprehensive
set of anti-inflation policies as follows:
1.

The mandatory, across-the-board control program, which this

Executive Council found necessary to advocate last Octobeer and which we
reiterate today must control the cost of everything and the income of
everybody.
2.

Supplemental policies must be designed to deal with specific

price problems in the necessities.
a.

These should:

Curb commodity speculation that drives up the prices of

wheat and other agricultural products.
b.

Regulate exports of foodstuffs and other raw materials

to prevent domestic shortages.

256
c.

Revise restrictive agricultural policies that contribute

to shortages and insure that the benefits of price support programs be
restricted

to family farmers.
d.

Expand energy supplies to relieve the OPEC stranglehold

on domestic prices.
e.

Continue to regulate gasoline and petroleum prices.

f.

Contain hospital costs and control professional fees for

health care.

g. Control and allocate credit toward productive public and
industrial investment, expansion of housing and assistance to the family
farmer and away from non-productive areas such as corporate acquisitions
and dollar speculation.
h.

Expand housing programs for low- and middle-income families

to expand the housing supply and reduce the price and rent inflation.
3.

An excess profit tax to insure that businesses maintain fair

prices, as well as revisions in the real wage insurance proposal to correct
inequities.
The AFL-CIO, of course, is very much concerned about the need for
effective economic stimulus and more rapid economic growth so that the
U.S. economy will be creating enough jobs for the nation's growing labor
force and so that high unemployment will be reduced instead of going
still higher.

257
Therefore, we believe this Committee and the Congress must reject
the notion that inflation must be fought through recession and rising
unemployment.

We believe this Committee and the Congress must continue

this nation's commitment to full employment, to the eradication of
poverty, and to the kind of investment in public programs and public
services that are essential to economic progress.
The AFL-CIO Executive Council set forth the following employment
policies to maintain this commitment and we ask this Committee to support
these policies:
1.

"The federal budget must provide stimulus to expand the economy

and to shrink unemployment.
2.

"Employment and training programs need to be expanded to

provide jobs and training.
3.

"Unemployment compensation needs to be improved and expanded to

protect workers and the economy.
4.

"A National Development Bank must be established to bring

employment opportunities to depressed areas.
5.

"Stand-by programs of expanded public works should be adopted

so that they will be in place to meet worsening unemployment."
Another important area of economic concern is the international
economic arena, with its high trade deficits and declining value of the
dollar.

These factors fuel inflation in the U.S.

position in the world economy.

and weaken

the U.S.

258
The U.S.
two years.

Imports exceeded exports by $29 billion in

$31 billion in
in

trade balance dropped into sharp deficit during the last

1978.

Imports of manufactured

1977 to $100 billion in

1978,

1977 and by

goods rose from $77 billion

while oil imports actually declined from

$44 billion to $42 billion.
The dollar declined sharply against the currencies of major
industrial countries.

The decline stemmed not only from the trade deficit,

but also from speculation against the dollar.
The AFL-CIO welcomes the President's State of the Union pledge to
"protect American jobs threatened by unfair trade."
goal should be in the forefront
Negotiations.

of U.S.

This pledge and this

policy in the Multilateral Trade

When the codes and the implementing legislation are completed,

their impact must be fully evaluated as to whether they protect American
workers and industries against unfair trade competition and assure the
maintenance of a diversified,
Mr.

Chairman,

healthy U.S. economy.

I appreciate

this opportunity

the AFL-CIO on a range of economic issues.

to present the views of

I respectfully request that

the record include the appendix to my prepared testimony which contains
recent AFL-CIO statements on economic policy.

These statements demonstrate

the AFL-CIO's conviction that inflation can be attacked by programs consistent
with the full employment goals of the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment and
Balanced Economic Growth Act of 1978.

259
APPENDIX TO STATEMENT OF DR. RUDOLPH OSWALD,
DIRECTOR, AFL-CIO DEPARTMENT OF RESEARCH,
BEFORE THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
MARCH2,

1979

AFL-CIO Executive Council statements on economic policy issues
(February 1979):
The National Economy and background paper
The Federal

Budget

Unemployment Compensation
Family Farmers
Housing
Energy Prices and Supplies
Hospital Cost Containment
AFL-CIO American Federationist article
Controls:

(February 1979):

An Unfair Program Gets Worse

260
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
The National Economy
Bal Harbour, Fla.
February 19, 1979

America's economy is heading toward a recession.
Only swift,
effective government action, controlling inflation without
increasing
already-high unemployment, can prevent it.
The current prospects are that inflation will get worse in
1979. The 9 percent increase in the consumer price index during
1978 further eroded the consumer buying power essential to
economic
growth.
Yet the wholesale or producer price indexes for January
portend even greater consumer price increases.
The Administration's predictions on inflation did not include
the recent events in Iran, which are leading to shortages
and
higher oil prices.
The already weak dollar cannot withstand further
speculation or higher trade deficits.
The employment outlook is equally dismal.
Despite the impressive increase in the number of jobs over the past year, little
or
no dent was made in the official unemployment rate which continues
to hover around 6 percent.
The economic slowdown certain to result
from record interest rates will lead to higher joblessness,
particularly in the home building industry and the manufacturing
industries
dependent upon it.
At the same time, the Administration's restrictive budget proposals would deny the economy needed stimulus and cut jobs Programs.
In fact, the Congressional Budget office predicts an unemployment
rate for December 1979 of up to one percentage point higher
than
Administration estimates.
That would mean a million more jobless
workers at the very time the Administration is cutting back
on programs to create jobs.
The Administration's anti-inflation program will not be
successful in holding down inflation because it does not
have
a comprehensible, effective, enforceable system of controlling
prices.
Wage controls without price controls are not only
inequitable but compound the problem of declining consumer
buying power.

261
We repeat what we said last October:
"We do not like controls.
We do. not welcome government
operation of the market place.
But recession is worse; runaway
inflation is worse; the discriminatory application of wage
controls is worse, the distorting of laws for purposes other
than those intended is worse; public scapegoating without due
process is worse.
"Therefore, we urge the President to draft a legislative
program of full economic controls, covering every source of
income -- profits, dividends, rents, interest rates, executive
compensation, professional fees, as well as wages and prices."
While the AFL-CIO believes that inflation is now the nation's
most serious economic problem and must be effectively controlled
as soon as possible, we believe the U.S. would be making a serious
mistake if it failed to adopt programs to meet each of the nation's
economic problems.
Therefore, the AFL-CIO Executive Council urges the following
programs:
Anti-Inflation Policies
1. The mandatory, across-the-board control program-,
which this Executive Council found necessary to advocate last
October and which we reiterate today must control the cost
of everything and the income of everybody.
2. Supplemental policies must be designed to deal with specific
price problems in the necessities. These should:
a. Curb commodity speculation that drives up the prices of
wheat and other agricultural products.
b. Regulate exports of foodstuffs and other raw materials to
prevent domestic shortages and price rises.
c. Revise restrictive agricultural policies that contribute
to shortages and insure that the benefits of price support programs
be restricted to family farmers.
d. Expand energy supplies to relieve the OPEC stranglehold
on domestic prices.
e.

Continue to regulate gasoline and petroleum prices.

262
f. Contain hospital costs and control professional fees for
health care.
g. Control and allocate credit toward productive public and
industrial investment, expansion of housing and assistance to the
family farmer and away from non-productive areas such as corporate
acquisitions and dollar speculation.
h. Expand housing programs for low- and middle-income families,
to expand the housing supply and reduce the price and rent inflation.
3. An excess profit tax to insure that businesses maintain fair
prices, as well as revisions in the reaf wage insurance proposal
to correct inequities.
Employment Policies
1. The federal budget must provide stimulus to expand the
economy and to shrink unemployment.
2. Employment and training programs need to be expanded to
provide jobs and training.
3. Unemployment compensation needs to be improved and expanded
to protect workers and the economy.
4. A National Development Bank must be established to bring
employment opportunities to depressed areas.
5. Stand-by programs of expanded public works should be
adopted so that they will be in place to meet worsening unemployment.
Trade Policies
1. Fair trade policies must be adopted and enforced to assure
realistic protection of U.S. industries and jobs.
2. Speculation against the dollar by banks and multinational
corporations must be curtailed.
3. Countervailing duties must be assessed against imports
receiving foreign subsidies, and the already expired waiver of such
duties should not be extended.
4. Trade adjustment assistance must be improved to help
alleviate the immediate hardships of job loss due to imports.

* *

*

263
We hope our prediction of a recession is wrong, but a healthy
economy must be built on stronger foundations than "hopes." There
can be no substitute for effective, fair government actions to
control inflation through a program that draws the support of the
people because it is equitable, visible and enforceable. At the
same time, government must not abandon its responsibility to provide
opportunities for workers, the poor, the unemployed and the disadvantaged through necessary social programs.

0ff
f

264
Background Staterent on The National Economy
Accelerating inflation, sky-high interest rates, trade
deficits, restrictive budget policies and the erosion of
consumer buying power are pushing the economy toward another
recession. This would mean increasing unemployment starting from
the highest base rate since World War II.
In spite of impressive profits for corporations and banks
in the fourth quarter of 1978, and a 6.1 percent rate of real
growth in the national economy during this period, consumer
and business caution and pessimism about the future have
worsened.
This portends a serious slowdown in spending in
1979 that will cut sales and production and thus bring lay-offs
and increased unemployment.
Slow growth in consumer buying power as a result of the
so-called voluntary wage restraints enforced by employers will
contribute to the economic slowdown in 1979.
High interest rates adversely affect housing contruction
and home-buying, state and local government operations, small
business investment and consumer spending for durable goods.
The administration's tight budget policy reduces the government
spending stimulus needed to keep the U.S. economy expanding.

Employment and Unemployment
The civilian labor force in January 1979 included 102.2
million workers -- 96.3 million with jobs and 5.9 million
without jobs. The official unemployment rate was 5.8 percent.
But when discouraged workers and those forced to work part-time
because full-time work is unavailable are counted, the true
unemployment rate is 8.1 percent.
Although the number of workers with jobs has risen by
3.4 million over the past 12 months, unemployment has continued
to hover around the 6 percent level. In other words, there
was no improvement in the unemployment picture in 1978.
These are the unemployed:
One out of every nine black
workers, one out of every seven teenagers, one out of every
three black teenagers, one out of every 11 Hispanic-origin
workers, one out of every seven male veterans aged 20 to
24 years, and one out of 10 construction workers.

265
The administration expects the unemployment rate to climb
to 6.2 percent in the fourth quarter of 1979 and remain at
that level through 1980. To meet the requirements of the
Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act,
the administration is assuming that the unemployment rate will
start dropping in 1981 and will get down to the required
4 percent in 1984.
A more realistic view is held by the Congressional
Budget Office which suggests that the unemployment rate may
be as high as 7.2 percent by the end of 1979 and still be
there by the end of 1980. CBO also predicts the unemployment
rate will start dropping in 1981, but states that unless there
is substantially more stimulus to the economy than currently
projected by the administration, the unemployment rate will
still be at the high level of 5.5 percent in 1984.

Inflation
The Consumer Price Index went up by 9 percent from
December 1977 to December 1978.
Food costs went up 11.7
percent, housing costs 11.5 percent, medical care 8.9 percent,
and energy costs 6 percent -- or a total inflation rate for
necessities of 10.7 percent.
The outlook for inflation in 1979, on the basis of wholesale
or producer price indexes, is gloomy.
For example, unprocessed foods and feedstuffs were up
20.1 percent over the 12-month period ending January 1979;
intermediate materials for food manufacturing 15 percent, and
finished consumer foods 12.9 percent.
For the general category of crude materials for further
processing, the January-to-January price rise was 18.5 percent;
for intermediate materials, supplies, and components 8.9 percent;
for finished goods, 9.8 percent.
The price of necessities are likely to escalate substantially
in 1979. Food prices, particularly beef prices, are expected
to increase sharply.
Oil price increases, resulting from OPEC
determinations and the Iranian cutoff, will affect not only the
gasoline pump price, but the price of all items related to
petroleum and energy, including food.
Continued high interest
rates will push all costs even higher.
So the economy is heading towards another recession without
ever fully recovering from the 1973 recession. Overall
unemployment rates are a full percentage point -- or 1 million
workers higher -- and for blacks the situation is even worse -an unemployment rate 3 percentage points greater, up to
11.2 percent.

266
The Administration's Wage-Price Control Program
The administration's wage and price program is one-sided
wage control.
It pretends that wages are the cause of the
current inflation.
It fails to deal with many of the major
factors influencing inflation, particularly price inflation
in the necessities of life -- food, energy, medical care and
housing.
The administration's program exempts many types of price
changes. While it sets a precise measure for wage changes,
the standard for prices is vague.
Profits, dividends, rents
and interest rates are basically ignored.
Price guidelines do not cover all items and do not even
pretend to control the major causes of inflation.
Additionally,
they allow those who raised prices the most in the past two
years to profit further from that conduct.
For wages there is a single number -- 7 percent -- easily
remembered, widely publicized, applicable across-the-board,
enforced by every employer in the country, from multi-billion
dollar corporations to the individual firm employing only a
single worker.
The 7 percent is a maximum applicable to every employee
unit, but not every unit will receive the full 7 percent.
Wage controls are enforced by employers eager to cooperate
with the government in holding down their employees' pay.
Wage controls are particularly discriminatory against
federal employees.
The law requires that federal salaries
be comparable to those paid in the private sector. The
President in 1978 arbitrarily placed a 5.5 percent limit on
federal salary increases, and the Congress acquiesced.
In
1978, that comparability would have required an 8.4 percent
increase. That same 5.5 percent increase is projected in the
budget for 1979 without regard for what the comparability
figure would be.
This wage control figure for federal workers
is 1.5 percent below the 7 percent allowed all other workers,
is clearly unfair.
In contrast to wage guidelines, there is no single number
for prices. Coverage is not universal. There is no enforcement,
except for the government's ability to--dispense or withhold
favors through regulatory and procurement contract mechanisms.
This entire program has no basis in law and, in fact,
constitutes mandatory wage controls by indirection in the
face of explicit congressional action denying the Executive
this authority.

267
The general public has no way of knowing whether particular
price increases -- no matter how large -- are in

compliance

or not. Because allowable rates of price increase are computed
on the basis of individual company price histories, never before
compiled and not on the public record, the individual citizen
will have no means cf making an independent check on compliance.
Wide latitude is allowed for price increases on particular
product lines and particular products,

and there are alternative

methods of testing compliance other than through price
deceleration.

There are actually several price guidelines in addition
to the originally announced "price deceleration" guideline,
and there are a number of important exclusions. Additionally,
companies are allowed considerable flexibility in the choice
of their accounting methods and in whether to report as a single
company or as separate units within a single company.
Finally, and perhaps most importantly, there are certain
situations in which no restraint applies.
Essentially
excluded, for all practical purposes, are the four basic
necessities of life for the average family -- food, housing,
energy and medical costs. Thus there is little or no attempt
to hold down prices on the items no family can do without.
Inflation Problems -- the Necessities
The success of price abatement may hinge on the elements
excluded from price deceleration requirements -- raw materials,
commodity exchange items, interest rates, imports and exports.
Over the last two years the compound effects of inflation
on the cost of necessities have been particularly severe.
Specifically, food went up 20.6 percent, shelter 21 percent,
fuel and utilities 14.6 percent and medical care 18.5 percent.
These four categories make up 57 percent of the C.P.I.
and during the 1977-78 surge in prices accounted for two-thirds
of the increase.
Put another way, had the cost of necessities
stayed constant from December 1976 to December 1978, the C.P.I.
would have risen by only 5 percent over the two-year period
compared with the 16.4 percent actual increase.
The annual
average rate of increase during the two years would have been
only 2.5 percent -- 68 percent lower than the actual annual
average rate of 7.9 percent.

268
Inflation Problems -- Interest Rates
In 1978 interest rates on borrowed money rocketed upward
and by the end of the year were approaching or had surpassed
the all-time highs reached in the credit crunch of 1974.
The cost of money enters into every price in the economy
-- those paid by consumers, farmers, business and government.
Rising interest costs in themselves help fuel inflation.
Not
only do they increase the costs of short-term loans used by
business in the course of normal operations but they burden
the costs of long-term capital investment in plant and
equipment.
And they make up a large part of the cost of
housing both in the form of construction loan rates and in
mortgage loan charges to home buyers. Eventually, if money
becomes very tight and very expensive, borrowers cut back,
economic activity slows down, production is reduced, sales
drop and a recession develops. The recessions of 1970-71
and 1974-75 were both preceded by rapid and severe escalations
of interest rates.
Federal Reserve Discount Rates
The Federal Reserve Board, which directly influences
interest rates through its role as "banker for the banks,"
jacked up its discount rate seven times during 1978, starting
with its January 9 increase to 6.5 percent (from 6 percent).
By October 16, the rate had reached an all-time record of 8.5 percent -- 42 percent higher than the 6 percent rate at
the beginning of the year.
This record was again shattered
with the 9.5 percent rate announced on November 1.
Commercial Bank Prime Rates
The lending rates of commercial banks rose in similar
fashion.
At the beginning of 1978, the big bank "prime
rate," which is the minimum lending rate to large businesses,
was 7.75 percent.
This rate has been successively
increased 15 times during the year until on December 26 it
reached 11.75 percent, just short of. the record 12 percent of

July 1974.

269
Home Mortgage Rates
As of December 1978, the effective mortgage rate on
loans closed for purchasing newly-built single family homes
was 10.02 percent, up from a year earlier figure of 9.09
percent.
This was an increase of over 12 percent.
For
existing homes, the effective mortgage rate was 10.06
percent at the end of the year, more than 10 percent above
the December 1977 rate of 9.12 percent.
Financing charges for mortgage interest, property taxes,
and insurance, taken together, rose 15.2 percent in the
Consumer Price Index for Wage Earners and Clerical Workers.
Combined with rising home prices, they contributed importantly
to the overall rise of 12.5 percent in all home ownership

costs in 1978.

Credit Allocation
Credit crunches are hurting housing, and other needed
investment activities.
The Congress granted the President
and Federal Reserve Board this authority to allocate credit
under the 1969 Credit Control Act.
Allocation would
alleviate somewhat credit problems in such essential
sectors of the economy as housing, family farming, small
business and state and local public investment.
Inflation Problems -- Trade
Much of the U.S. inflation results from international
economic policies.
The devaluation of the dollar and huge
deficits in trade and international payments fuel inflation
at home and economic weakness abroad. The administration's
anti-inflation program fails to address these problems directly.
In the past two years, the dollar has dropped 16 percent
on a trade-weighted average.
The currencies of key trading
partners like Japan and West Germany have risen 50.4 percent
and 26.8 percent respectively in relation to the dollar. The
U.S. imports manufactured products of all types from these
countries -- from textiles and cars to computers and parts.
These imports are consequently more expensive and add to U.S.
inflation.

47-977 0 - 79 - 18

270
The U.S. imported $29 billion more than it exported in
1977.
In 1978, this deficit increased to $32 billion.
While
oil imports are an important element in the U.S. trade deficit,
the fact is that manufactured imports into the U.S. accounted
for the increase in the trade deficit in 1978.
The trade
surplus of $3.6 billion in manufactured goods in 1977 changed to
roughly a $6 billion deficit in 1978.
These excessive imports
cost American consumers dearly -- in higher priced foreign
currencies and in taxes to pay for the social and economic
costs of lost jobs.
But exports of food and live animals -- bought by foreigners
at a bargain with cheaper, devalued dollars -- rose almost
30 percent in 1978.
These export sales contribute to food
price inflation in the U.S.
The attempt to spur exports of
products without curbing imports at all will merely create
more shortages and put added inflationary pressures on the
U.S. economy.
The result is worse problems at home and a
weaker stance for the dollar abroad.
Trade deficits lead to inflationary speculation against
the dollar. Rather than curbing dollar speculation directly
or limiting imports, the domestic Federal Reserve Board
discount rate was raised to the unprecedented levels of 9.5
percent, creating added inflation pressures as interest costs
are pushed up.
Wages
No single statistic can be used to show what is happening
to wages because overall percentage wage increases reflect the
wage changes of many different people and many different
groups.
Employees in private non-farm industry have averaged
increases in hourly compensation of 8.3 percent in 1976, 7.6
percent in 1977, and 9.7 percent in 1978, according to the
Bureau of Labor Statistics.
This average includes executives,
professionals and all private blue-collar and white-collar
employees. BLS wage studies show that different groups of
workers have had substantial variations in wage changes.
When executive and supervisory employees are excluded,
the rates of wage increases are substantially lower as are the
wages paid such workers.
Average hourly earnings were $5.90
in December 1978 -- 8.2 percent above those of a year earlier.
The 1977 increase was 7.3 percent, identical to the 1976
increase. However, after allowing for inflation and taxes,
real earnings are actually lower than they were in 1972.

271
Chief executive officers received total compensation
increases of 12.2 percent in 1977, according to Forbes magazine.
These are chief executives of the top 800 firms and their

compensation averaged $300,000 -- so a 12 percent increase
was about $36,000 for the year.

Unions negotiating in 1978 generally settled for lower
wage increases than in the two previous years.
In 1976 firstyear increases averaged 8.4 percent; in 1977 7.8 percent,

and in 1978 7.7 percent.

For building trades unions wage and benefit increases

amounted to 7.1 percent in 1976, 6.6 percent in 1977, and
6.2 percent in 1978,
survey.

according to a special Labor Department

Union contracts with deferred wage increases in 1979
average 5.1 percent.
A number of these contracts, however,
also provide increases resulting from cost-of-living
escalator clauses.
The Squeeze on the Worker
In spite of dollar gains in the paycheck, the American
worker has lost real buying power. 'Between 1967 and 1972, the
buying power of the average non-supervisory worker's weekly
pay, after deduction of federal income and social security
taxes, rose 6.4 percent. But in 1978, the average worker's
buying power was down 4.9 percent from 1972.
Productivity
Although overall productivity measures show a slowdown
this is not true of the basic manufacturing sector.
In
fact, since manufactured goods make up a declining share of
total output, there is a serious question about the validity
of productivity measurement for the total private economy
which also includes construction, finance insurance, real
estate and personal and business services.

272
Productivity growth has not slowed in the manfacturing
sector.
In terms of output per worker hour it increased

3.5 percent in 1978.

For the 1970s,

manufacturing productivity

growth averaged 2.4 percent per year -- less than the 3 percent
average of the 1960s, but the same as the 2.4 percent average

yearly growth of the 1950s.
The respectable rate for the 1970s of manufacturing
productivity growth came despite two back-to-back recessions
and an underutilization of plant and equipment during most
of the 1970s.
The 1974 recession was so severe that it caused
a 5.2 percent drop in productivity, the largest for any year
since World War II. The recession of 1970 also caused a decline
in productivity.
The decade of the 1950s also had two recessions, but
The decade of the
neither was as severe as the 1974 recession.
1960s was a long period of continuous expansion of output with
1967.
only a slight slowing of growth in
Plant, equipment, and manpower was seriously underutilized
during the 1970s which lessened the need for expansion and
thereby slowed productivity growth. Plant and equipment
utilization averaged only 81 percent in the 1970s compared

with 85 percent in the 1960s and 84 percent in the 1950s.

Despite the severe recessions of the 1970s and the low
utilization of plant, equipment and labor, productivity
growth in manufacturing in the 1970s fared as well as that of
the 1950s.
And considering the marked difference in economic
climate, the 1970s productivity growth compared very well to

that of the 1960s.
Productivity in manufacturing is not slowing down -but manufactured goods are a declining share of total output
and manufacturing now accounts for only 29 percent of total
hours of work in the private business economy.
The slowdown in measured productivity for the total private
business economy results primarily from non-manufacturing
data which do not have the reliability of manufacturing data.
The data are so poor for construction, finance, insurance
and real estate services, and other sectors that the slowdown
in productivity may be entirely a measurement problem
rather than an actual slowdown. In fact, the government's
productivity figures in these sectors are based largely on
the flow of money rather than the number of goods and services
actually produced.

273
Construction, finance, insurance, real estate and services
account for about 23 percent of all hours used for measuring
productivity in the total private business economy.
The growth
of these sectors and relative decline of manufacturing adds
a downward bias to measurement of productivity in the total
private economy.
The inadequacies of measurement of productivity in these
sectors and the probability that productivity is vastly
understated in these sectors means that the downturn in
productivity in the 1970s may be a problem of measurement
and not reality. The lack of any decrease in the more reliably
measured manufacturing productivity despite the poor economic
climate of the 1970s strengthens this conclusion.
Concentration on doubtful statistics concerning
productivity growth and unit labor costs for the total private
economy may seriously distort an understanding of inflationary
pressures in the economy.
Productivity has been robust
in manufacturing and continues to contribute substantial real
gains to the economy.
In the non-manufacturing sectors, the
true extent of productivity growth may have been seriously
understated.

274
Productivity Growth by Industry/I
(Percent Change Per Year)

1949-59

1959-659

1969-77

Manufacturing

2.4X

3.01

2.4Z (Includes 1978)

Transportation

2.9

3.6

2.3

Communicaton

4.8

5.0

6.2

Agriculture

6.2

5.5

4.9

Electric Gas and
Sanitary Services

6.6

4.7

1.7

Services

1.3

1.9

1.2*

Finance Insurance
and Real Estate

1.6

1.2

1.2*

Retail Trade

1.8

3.0

1.3

Construction

3.0

1.9

-1.9*

Mining

4.1

4.3

-3.2

/I Data for manufacturing and agriculture are from yearly indexes.
All others are from least squares trend lines.
*BLS does not consider these data to be of sufficient quality to be
published separately.
The data are released only as a means to aid in
understanding the movements in productivity measures.
Source:

Bureau of Labor Statistics

275
CPI Increase 1976-1978
(December-December)

1977-78

Total
1976-1978

8.4X

10.7%

20.02

8.0
8.7
8.1
8.8

11.7
11.5
6.0
8.9

20.6
21.2
14.6
18.5

4.7

6.7

11.7

6.8

9.0

16.4

1976-77
Necessities
Food
Shelter
Fuel & Utilities
Medical Care

/

Other
All Items

CPI is Consumer Price Index for Wage Earners and Clerical Workers.

NOTE:

Source:

1.

"Necessities" make up 57 percent of all items in the index.
In 1977 and 1978, they accounted for over two-thirds of the
increase in the index.

2.

Had the cost of necessities stayed constant from December 1976
to December 1978, the CPI would have risen by 5.0 percent over
the 2-year period compared to the 16.4 percent actual increase.
The annual average rate of increase during the period would
have been only 2.5 percent -- 68 percent lower -- than the
actual annual average rate of 7.9 percent.

Bureau of Labor Statistics.

1/

I.

"Necessities"

index computed by AFL-CIO.

276
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
The Federal Budget
Bal Harbour, Fla.
February 19, 1979
The Administration's proposed cuts, made at the expense of
vital social programs, are too great a price for the nation to
pay in order to achieve a miniscule reduction in inflation.
In
fact, the cuts increase the risk of recession.
The proposed budget is $12.6 billion less than is necessary
simply to maintain current services.
This will result in a decline
in governmental services which will mean a reduction in the
standard of living.
The cuts are concentrated in programs designed to help retirees,
the working poor, students, the unemployed and urban residents.
In human terms, the proposed budget is a disaster: in economic terms,
it is illogical.
According to Congressional Budget Office estimates, each
$10 billion in budget cuts will reduce inflation by only one-tenth
of one percent. Thus, in order to reach an arbitrary goal of
.
bringing the deficit down to $29 billion, the Administration has
proposed a budget which could well prove counterproductive.
Indeed, if the last Congress had not given the wealthy and corporations an unnecessary tax cut, more revenue would be available.
If a recession develops, these proposed budget cuts will
actually lead to a larger budget deficit as a result of declining
tax revenues and increased social costs.
In many programs, the budget would freeze or reduce spending -especially for domestic human services and aid to state and local
governments -- at a time when inflation is accelerating. This means
that the government's buying power -- like the buying power of
workers -- will be reduced.

277
Federal Budget
We are especially troubled by the adverse impact the
proposed budget would have on programs which directly affect
people, such as those examples included in the addendum to
this statement.
Cutbacks in education weaken America's commitment to
future; cutbacks in Social Security break the government's the
word to retirees, widows, orphans and the disabled; cutbacks
in jobs programs, particularly CETA, deny the unavoidable
federal responsibility to make the unemployed taxpayers
rather than taxusers.
Additionally, the budget proposes to continue the blatantly
discriminatory practice of denying federal workers pay raises
they have earned and are due under law.
There can be no
justification for demanding a greater sacrifice in the fight
against inflation from the government's own employees than from
any other group.
The AFL-CIO believes that the federal budget must embody
more than tables of statistics, because it is through the
budget process that the nation provides opportunity to those
who have none, assistance to those in need, and services
which enrich the quality of life for all. We believe the
budget should be a commitment to the future of this country,
not a testament to antiquated economic theories.
The Executive Council calls upon the Congress to adopt
a budget which adequately and appropriately reflects the
nation's needs.
Those needs can not be calculated on a
mathematical formula based on a declining percentage of the
nation's GNP or by any other mechanical approach.
Congress must also reject the notion that inflation
must be fought through recession and rising unemployment
and it must continue this nation's commitment to full
employment, the eradication of poverty, and investment in public
programs and services essential to progress.

278
ADDENDL'M To THE STATEMENT ON THE FEDERAL BUDGET

In arriving at its "austerity" budget, the Administration
has proposed severe cutbacks in numerous programs benefitting
working people, minorities,and the poor and providing jobs for
the unemployed.
Some examples are:
*CETA -- The budget calls for a $1.5 billion decrease from
Fiscal Year 1979, a cut that is magnified by the increased costs
of inflation. Title VI, counter-cyclical public service
employment, job slots would be reduced by 240,000 by the
end of 1980. Title VI, fully funded and using the
Administration's unemployment estimate, would provide 440,000
job slots.
The summer youth program would be reduced by 250,000 slots.
National outreach and training programs would be emasculated.
Such programs include the on-the-job and apprentice programs
of the AFL-CIO and many of its affiliates, and other special
programs servicing the nation's black and Hispanic communities.
*Education -- While the Administration has proposed
increases for the educationally-disadvantaged youth attending
elementary and secondary schools, it calls for the elimination
of impact aid funds for children of federal employees who do
not live on federal property. Other elementary and secondary
education programs are maintained at 1979 levels, or, in the case
of handicapped students, funded at levels below previous commitments. The result is a cut in services because of the impact
of inflation.
In the area of higher education, while the Administration
calls for full funding of such programs as Middle Income
Student Assistance, according to the Congressional Budget
Office, it underestimates the number of eligible students
and, thus, provides insufficient funds.
*Health -- The Administration's training cuts imply a shift
from using the Federal government as a means to help increase
the supply of health professionals. Aid to nursing and
medical students is sharply cut back. No funds are proposed
for the start of any national health insurance program.

279
Addendum-Federal Budget
*Social Security -- Proposed cuts in Social Security
either eliminate or reduce existing benefits. These cuts
include:
-Abolition of benefits to deceased workers, dependent
children between the ages of 18 and 22 who are fulltime
students.
-Elimination of the $255 lump-sum death benefits which
help pay funeral costs.
-Elimination of the minimum benefit of $122 a month for
persons with low earnings under covered employment.
-The cut off of benefits to widows and widowers when the
youngest child reaches 16 instead of the present 18-year cutoff.
-Reduction in Social Security benefits for persons
receiving civil service pensions.
-Denial of disability benefits to many now eligible.
*Rousing -- The Administration proposes redycIng
Section 8 and public housing units ny OU,OCpu.
IIIb ib
insufficient funding for other housing programs.
*Child Nutrition -- Administration cuts include: reducing
subsidies to middle income students for school lunches,
eliminating the special milk program in schools operating
lunch or breakfast programs, and tightening eligibility
requirements for free and reduced-price school meals.
*Food Stamgs -- the Administration has called for a
reduction in funds below the 1979 level. Given the sharply
rising cost of food, such a reduction means a substantial cut
in benefits.
*Worker Protection -- While funds are provided for the
OSHA enforcement positions added last year by Congress,
the
Administration has suggested no additional funds for positions
necessary to provide adequate health and safety job protection.
*Pub~ic Worka -The Administration's budget includes no
additional
ds for public works -- not even the so-called
"soft" program it advocated last year or stand-by authority
for regular public works triggered to increasing unemployment.

280
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
Jnemplovment Compensation

Bal Harbour, Fla.
February 26, 1979

For more than 40 years unemployment compensation has been
the nation's first line of defense against hunger and suffering
for millions of jobless workers and their families, particularly
in times of recession.
Unfortunately,

the unemployment compensation system has

become less and less capable of doing its essential job of forestalling poverty for the unemployed and their dependents, because
it is based on an ill-matched federal-state sharing of responsibility for a national problem.

The system is inadequately financed

and provides benefits that are far too low to meet the basic
needs of the millions of Americans who must look to it for
protection.
The AFL-CIO has long urged major improvements in unemployment insurance aimed at shoring up the system.

Such action could

have been taken during the recent period of declining unemployment, but except for a much needed extension of coverage to
nearly all workers, the need for strenghtening the program was
neglected in favor of creating yet another study commission to
examine the program.

281
This commission is not scheduled to issue its final report
until March 1980.

Clearly that will be too late for millions

of Americans who will be forced to rely on unemployment insurance
in the intervening months.
Therefore, we call for the following immediate changes
in the unemployment compensation law:
1.

Establish a federal minimum benefit standard of two-thirds

of the worker's wage up to a maximum of three-fourths of the statewide average weekly wage.

This is absolutely essential to prevent

severe reductions in the incomes and living standards of workers
who lose their jobs through no fault of their own.
2.

Extend the present maximum 39-week duration to 65 weeks.

For the long-term, we call for consideration of an extended benefit
program which in good times and bad would offer jobless workers
income support and employment and training services appropriately
geared to the duration of their unemployment and labor market
conditions.

But with the prospect in the coming months of a large

increase in unemployment and many more workers jobless for long
periods, such long-term action would be too little and too late.
3.

Extend coverage to all workers now excluded.

It is

unconscionable to deny unemployment compensation protection to
any worker including those farm and domestic employees now excluded..

282
4.

Provide federal financing from general revenue for

benefits paid to workers after they are unemployed 39 weeks
and reimburse states for disbursements they made beyond basic
payments for the period January 1975 - January 1978.

Taken as

a whole, the unemployment insurance system is still in debt
resulting from the tremendous financial pressures placed on it
during the last recession.

It is certainly ill-equipped to take

on an additional financial burden now.

Massive unemployment

during an economic recession is a national problem,

and it must

be met with the financial resources of the federal government.
The emergency actions we are calling for are no substitute
for the long-term improvements we continue to recommend.

These

would include not only an effective program to meet the needs
of the long-term jobless but also federal standards which would:
* Require removal of harsh state eligibility and disqualification provisions.
* Establish minimum solvency standards

for state funds.

* Eliminate the worst abuses of the so-called experience

rating system.
* Provide for improvements in the administration of the

program.

283
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
Family Farmers
Bal Harbour, Fla.
February 26, 1979
The issues being raised by America's family farmers, through
the American Agricultural Movement and other traditional family
farm organizations, go to the heart of America's economic
problems and deserve more serious consideration and action by
the government than is evident thus far.
* The growth of corporate farming, which is driving many
farm families from agriculture, raises questions about food
monopolies and concentrations of corporate power dominating
the nation's vital food supply.
* The role of commodity speculators, who add to inflation in
food prices through paper profits, must be regulated to increase
the farmer's share of the food dollar without driving up
consumer prices.
*U.S. farm land is being purchased at alarming rates by
foreign corporations and individuals, especially from the OPEC
states.
Control of productive farm land in the hands of foreign
interests could seriously injure the nation's economic health.
* Family farmers also face serious international trade problems.
Other nations subsidize their agricultural exports heavily.
Since they do not require the health and safety standards
the U.S. imposes on domestic agriculture, we believe the same
standards should be applied to imports, and agricultural imports
labeled as to country of origin.
* Exports of agricultural commodities are presently
conducted by corporations who act in their own self interest
and usually to the detriment of family farmers. We believe a
mechanism, similar to the Canadian Wheat Board, should be
established to promote and handle foreign sales of U.S. grain.
* High interest rate policies adversely affect family farmers,
who must borrow money each year for planting and other expenses.
Since credit is not allocated to such vital needs as agriculture,
farmers are forced to compete for loans against speculators and
corporations.
This further drives up the farmer's interest
payments, increasing the cost of food.

We believe that agricultural policy should be based on the
principle of a fair return to family farmers for their labor.
Price supports and other programs should be strictly limited
to family farmers and denied to corporate farms and other absentee
owners.
If policies to help the family farmer are not quickly
adopted, consumers could be left at the mercy of corporate
monopolies, and the nation could lose the rich heritage
family farmers have provided.

284
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
Housing
Bal Harbour, Fla
February
, 1979
The drastic January decline in housing starts marks the
It will aggravate
beginning of the expected housing slump.
the already existing, major national housing crunch.
Not enough homes are being built to meet demand, forcing
up housing prices and rents.
Interest rates continue to climb,
making housing unaffordable for millions of families. The net
result of a decline in residential construction will be
increases in unemployment, starting in the construction trades
and rippling throughout the economy in industries which produce
and distribute housing materials.
Each year the nation needs 1.55 million housing units just
to accommodate new households.
In addition, more units must be
built to provide for mobility through higher vacancy rates and
to replace units lost due to demolition, fire, flood and
other disasters.
Thus, there is a total annual need for 2.4
million units, without any allowance for replacement of
substandard units which are presently occupied.
An estimated five million occupied housing units have
serious physical deficiencies and should be replaced or
rehabilitated within a reasonable time period. Thus, the
annual housing requirement is three million new or rehabilitated
units.
Since 1973, the average annual total of new housing unit
starts was less than 2 million per year, including 330,000
mobile home shipments.
The result of this shortfall of one
million housing units a year is inflationary. It is also socially
unacceptable because it forces millions of low and moderateincome families, the elderly and minorities to endure
inadequate and often substandard housing conditions.
Because a recession in the housing industry always precedes
general economic declines, the AFL-CIO urges strong actions
to boost housing production and maintain it at a high enough level
to meet current and future needs.
Specifically, we support:

285
* Releasing the $1 billion in standby authority for
emergency assistance for the Government National Mortgage
Association for single-family homes as soon as a depressed
housing market threatens.
* Reducing the 7i percent ceiling on mortgage interest
rates under tandem plan financing to 6 percent. The law -Title III of the National Housing Act, Section 313 -- only
stipulates that a mortgage interest rate of 7j percent is the
most that can be charged. Therefore, legally, there is no
reason why the interest rate could not be lowered.
* Lowering the interest rate for HUD Sectior. 235
homebuyers from the current 4 percent to the 1 percent
statutory minimum.
Such an action would enable low-income
families to buy homes, thus, stimulating the production of
tens of thousands of additional assisted homeownership units.

* Authorization by the President for the Federal Reserve
Board to implement the Credit Control Act of 1969. Under
that Act, the FRB could exercise selective credit regulation
measures for the purpose of preventing housing from bearing
the brunt of tight money policies.
Currently, the homebuilding industry is beginning to
decline as money tightens and mortgage interest rates rise.
At the same time, large amounts of credit are extended for
corporate takeovers of companies, for foreign industries, and
for international money market speculation and other
non-essential purposes. Selective credit regulation would make
many of these housing support programs less necessary because
lower interest rates would enable more people to obtain
housing without subsidy.
* Institution pf mortgage revenue bond programs by
municipalities. These tax-exempt revenue bonds would be used
to finance low-interest mortgages, but the benefits should
be restricted to families who cannot afford to pay private
market rates.
* Establishing a Federal Housing Bank.
Such a bank would
assure that loans will be available at 5 to 6 percent
interest -- and under special circumstances at lower rates -for families below a given income level.
* Increasing the authorization for the debt service and
operating subsidy programs in the Housing and Urban Development
and Farmers Home Administration.
Such programs assist lowand moderate-income families in acquiring homes and meeting
monthly payments.

47-977 0 - 79 - 19

286
* Increasing the authorization for the- Public Housing
program, which provides rental housing for low-income families
and elderly individuals in projects owned by local public
housing authorities.
* Increasing the authorization for Section 8 Rental
This program
Housing Assistance to support additional units.
provides low- and moderate-income families with leased standard
rental housing units in privately-owned structures, employing
a flexible subsidy, so that increasing utility and other
operating costs can be met without raising costs of low-income
tenants.

287
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
Energy Prices and Suonlies
Hal Harbour, Fla.
February 20 , 1979

At a time when inflationary fires are burning full blast, it
would be ill-advised and untimely for the Administration to initiate
measures to remove ceilings from gasoline retail prices and to decontrol crude oil prices. Both of these steps, now under consideration by the Administration, would increase inflation and dampen
economic activity.
I
By the Administration's own estimates, gasoline prices would
rise about 4 cents per gallon if controls are lifted. Others
estimate the increase resulting from decontrol at a higher level.
Each one-cent increase in the price of a gallon of gasoline would
cost American consumers about $1 billion a year.
Certainly, if the Iranian cutoff of oil continues and shortages
develop, decontrolled gasoline retail prices would rise even more
dramatically. Gasoline makes up about 46 percent of domestic oil
products. Motor vehicles consume 90 percent of the gasoline.
Mandatory controls on crude oil prices expire on May 31, 1979.
However, the President has the authority to continue controls until
September 1981.
Decontrol of crude oil prices would have an even more devastating
inflationary impact.
If domestic crude oil prices were to rise to
world levels, the direct cost to American consumers would be about
$14.5 billion per year.
In addition, there would be a ripple effect throughout the
economy, the cost of which is difficult to calculate. In the past,
the Library of Congress has estimated the ripple effect at 1½ to 2
times the primary effect.
In truth, decontrol of domestic crude
oil prices is a submission to the OPEC cartel and establishes its
prices as the U.S. price.
Obviously, the economy would suffer from such an action, and
consumers would bear the burden of the effects of decontrol. Only
the oil companies would benefit.
We therefore urge the President not to decontrol gasoline and
crude oil prices.

288
At the same time, the Administration should immediately proceed
with programs for both developing domestic energy supplies and
Recent developments in Iran demonstrate
conserving existing supplies.
that America is still too dependent for a critical portion of its
energy supplies on insecure foreign sources.
So long as there is the current unequal relationship between
the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries, and the-consuming
nations, we can expect continuing oil price increases and resultant
inflationary effects. For the U.S. this is compounded by the willingness of U.S. oil companies to cooperate in these price increase
schemes. The only solution is for the U.S. to develop an importpurchasing mechanism at the governmental level which can deal as
We, therefore, call upon the government
an equal with OPEC nations.
to establish an Energy Import Board, with sole authority to determine the level of U.S. imports and to allocate oil imports, to
negotiate with suppliers to develop a purchase mechanism and to take
any other steps necessary to end the stranglehold the OPEC nations
and the major oil companies now have on the American economy.
While every effort must be made to increase domestic production
of oil and natural gas, there is an urgent need to develop all alternate sources of energy. The two sources most likely to be of greatest
The acsignificance in the short run are coal and nuclear power.
celerated development of nuclear power and coal must be realized
while protecting the environment and maintaining stringent safety and
health standards.
The United States has about 450 billion tons of coal reserves -The country could
more than 700 times the national annual usage.
double or treble coal consumption and still have reserves that
would last more than 200 or 300 years.
Nuclear power currently constitutes a little more than two
percent of total energy supply. The accelerated development of
nuclear power could considerably enlarge that figure and make a
major contribution to the resolution of the energy problem. To
accomplish this, the licensing of nuclear reactors should be
expedited and safe federal repositories established for nuclear
waste.
At the same time, programs for development of alternative
sources must be directed towards such other sources as solar.
biomass, fusion, geothermal, gasohol, coal liquefaction and
gasification, wind, tidal and any other sources.
Private industry, left to itself, cannot or will not develop
For that
the alternative energy sources needed by this country.
reason, the AFL-CIO believes an Energy Independence Authority
should be established to help achieve energy security for the United
States, including the power to launch projects for the production
and distribution of energy patterned after the TVA concept.

289
But the immediate threat of gasoline shortages means that
the United States can no longer wait before implementing a
conservation program that is fair, realistic and effective.
We believe any attempt to ration gasoline by raising prices.
either directly or indirectly, is inherently unfair and will not
work. Likewise we believe rationing based only on registered
motor vehicles, without any provision for allocation on the basis
of need, adjustment of inequities or the alleviation of individual
hardship, must be prevented.
We urge the Department of Energy to consider more than just the
views of industry sources. A program designed without meeting the
concern of labor and consumer groups would be suspect on its face
and would be certain to fail.

ft##

290
Statement by the AFL-CIO Executive Council
on
-

Hosnital Cost Containment

Bal Harbour, Florida
February 26, 1979

The AFL-CIO urges prompt congressional action on a
hospital cost containment program which effectively reduces
runaway inflation in hospital costs without providing
additional burdens on already low-paid hospital workers.
Hospital wages only account for 10 percent of hospital cost
increases, according to the Council on Wage and Price Stability.
While we believe that the cost control features of the
Health Care for All Americans Act are superior to single
programs, such as hospital cost containment, we recognize that
the fight against inflation requires immediate action on
hospital costs.
The major factors in hospital cost inflation are duplicative
services, unnecessary hospital beds, sloppy administration and
unnecessary procedures.

No voluntary effort will be

successful to control these costs.

And a program which

totally ignores increases in professional fees would be a failure.
Therefore, we urge Congress to promptly consider a
mandatory hospital cost control program, with appropriate
safeguards for hospital workers.

291
Background Report
AFL-CIO Executive Council
On
Hospital Cost Containment
Bal Harbour, Florida
February

, 1979

In the last Congress, two hospital cost containment bills received
serious consideration.

One was an administration bill and the other was

a bill introduced by Senator Talmadge (D-Ga.)

entitled the Medicare-Medicaid

Administrative and Reimbursement Reform Act.
At-the Executive Council meeting on May 10, 1978,

the AFL-CIO supported

hospital cost containment in principal, but with the following reservations:
*

*

Hospital cost containment should not
bargaining in the hospital industry,
be a provision for a pass-through of
for low-paid nonsupervisory hospital

interfere with free collective
and, specifically, there should
any wage increases negotiated
workers in the final legislation.

Except for six states that had, at that time, state hospital rate
control commissions established and operating, any federal cost
containment legislation should be administered by the federal government.
If, however, the final legislation did allow more states to
supercede the federal programs, there would have to be a federal
requirement that such state laws would also be required to provide a
wage pass-through for nonsupervisory employees

Without these employee protections,

the AFL-CIO made it clear to the

Administration and Congress that the AFL-CIO would oppose passage of the
legislation when it came to the floor of either the House or the Senate.

Hospital

workers continue to -rank among the worst paid of all nonsupervisory employees
earning an average of $35 a week less than nonsupervisory employees in other
industries.

292
Moreover, the Cctincil on Wage and Price Stability in a staff
report, "The Rapid Rise of Hospital Costs," showed that hospital wages
were the source of only stie-terith of the increase

in hospital costs.

The main cause or inflation in hospital charges has been nonlabor costs.
In the final days of the last Congress, the Talmadge bill was
reported out by the Senate Finance Committee and was debated on the floor
of the Senate.

Senator Nelson (D-Wis.)

introduced an amendment that

guaranteed workers in the hospital industry the right of free collective
bargaining in any hospital cost containment program, federal or state,
set up pursuant to the legislation.

With strong support from the AFL-CIO

and its affiliated unions in the hospital industry, both the Nelson
amendment and the amended bill passed the Senate but not the House.
No hospital cost containment legislation was, therefore, enacted
in the 95th Congress.

The Administration has announced it

will push

for passage of such a bill in the current Congressional session.
The Nelsomr

amendment gave the hospital industry an opportunity to

implement a voluntary cost containment program.

Only if

the voluntary

effort had failed would the mandatory cost containment provisions of the
Talmadge bill, as amended, have become operable.

The main reason why

the AFL-CIO and its affiliates in the hospital industry supported the
Nelson Amendment was that it

would have instituted mandatory controls on

hospital costs, in the event the voluntary effort 'failed, and would have
left the wages of hospital workers subject to free collective bargaining.

293
To date, it

does not appear the voluntary effort of the hospital

industry to control hospital cost inflation is working.

Therefore,

if

the voluntary effort continues to be inadequate, legislation assuring
mandatory cost containment, with proper safeguards for hospital workers,
is needed.
The AFL-CIO had some reservations with respect to the cost
coritainmsent bill which the Senate passed.

These included:

*

Whether legislation that focused solely on containing hospital
charges could control total health care costs. It is too
easy for hospitals to shift expenses from their own budget
to the other segments of the health industry. For example,
pathologists and radiologists can shift from salary to feefor-service and bill patients for x-ray and laboratory work
previously billed by the hospital. This decreases the onbudget costs of the hospital but increases total costs unless
doctors' fees are also regulated. Effective control over
health care costs can only be achieved when all parts of
the medical care delivery system including hospitals, nursing
homes, home health services and, especially, doctors' fees
can be brought under budgetary ceilings.

*

Whether legislation focused on hospital cost containment
would be compatible with a comprehensive and universal
national health insurance program.

The Health Care for All Americans Act which the AFL-CIO supports
would phase-in temporary cost controls over both hospital costs and
physician fees until an administrative structure for implementing the Act
could be established.
It

is anticipated the Administration will shortly introduce a

new cost containment bill.

Senator Talmadge is also expected to re-

introduce a revised version of his bill.
The AFL-CIO will support hospital cost containment legislation if
it

includes effective employee safeguards and is compatible with the

stronger cost control features of the Health Care for All Americans Act.

294

Controls:
An Unfair
Program
Gets
Worse
The Ade.fIi.roaelnn wag. and pnce program is a
one-sidedwage control program with no nppmpnfte
proceduresfor redressof injury to workers, and with
many worker harmrd by (he wage standards themselvs. It procerds from (he mistaken noiton that
wagesare (hr causeof the current ingation It fails to
dral with many of the major factors itfluncing inglanon, particolarly prtce inflation it the nrcessities of
lifr-food. energy, medical care, hoasiog and interest
rntes.
The Administration's program e-empts many types
of price changes It sets a precise measure for wage
changes.,bat a vague standard for pces. It basically
ignores profits, dtvidends, rents and interest
The prie guidelines do not even cover all itemsand indeed they do nor even pretend to control the
major causesof Ingation. Additionally, the basic prco
dcceleration guideines allow those who raised pfires
the most in the past two years to profit further from
that coduct.
For wages there is a single 7 percent number,
e-ily remembered, widely publiced, applicable
across-the.-board,enforced by every employer in the
THISAnTiCLS id.,. lire .,i.e
b, I& AFrco .c
ii,.e hane.e.ri.,.1
sizeTO.cc."...,t .w.. fleda,
AtL
DciOt.,bl.i
-- Ka.t.,...uib
Y..
-4An~.Hi Di,

FreRUARt

IM

country, from multi-billion dollar corporations to the
individual fihr employing only a single worker
The 7 percent is a masimum applicable to every
employee unit. Not every unit rill rereite as much
an 7 percent, but none may get more The wage
controls are self-enforcing through the mechanism
of employers anninas to cooperate with the guvermeat in holding down their employees' pay. There is
no flevibility as far as wagesare concered.
The price guidelines am a striking contasi. There
is no single number. Coverage is not universal There
is no self-enforcing mechanism of organized resistanceto pce rises. Enforcement mechanismsare
partial at best, and largely dependent on guveremet's
ability and Willingness to dispense or withhold faroes through regulatory and procurmeni contract
mechanisms. This machinery has no basis in law
and, in fac, constitutes a control program by indirection in the fare of congressional action denying the
Enectrive Branch the authority to institute controls
The general public will hare an way of knowing
whether paricolar prim incmasesn-o matter how
large-are in compliance or not. Becauseallowable
rates of pice increase ore computed on the basis of
individual company price histones, never before
compiled and not on the public record, the irdiridual
citicen ll h-e no moonsof making an independent
check on compliance Wide latitude is allowed for
13

295

Principal Causes of Inflato,

976-978

Percent of Increase

22

to

M

All

Fo

hle

Necetntlllt

tira
t.l.. i.

t

-w@ -1t.LW
C wsbyAe 1

Nec

price increases an panicnlae product linen and particuIar prducts. and there are aterative roethad,
of tenting compliance ether than thirogh price deceleraion.
There are actoally -everal pice guidelines in addition to the originally annoanced "price decelration
guideline, and there ee a nuberhe of inipa.t.r enclasions even tram the price decelertin goidelines.
Additionally, companien are allowed con-idrahble Ienibility in the chaice of their accounting methods and
in whether to repont as a ningle company or an nparote units within a tingle company.
F-Ploy, and perhaps mant imporantly, there are
certaio situaiinn in which no rniraot applies. Ensenially e-taded for all peacticol purpose., are the
four basic necensitim of life for the average familyfood, honning. energy and medic1 costs. Thnn the-e
in little or no attempt to hold dowo pecen on the
items no family can do without

Price Deceleration Standards
Th. penlroln for "price emdarda" in compi..,
written in atrcae staislcat fannotas, incomplete in
coverage and so gecible as to accommodate pmcticalty any price increase a company might wish to pot
into elfc. It is an elaborate stroctore of hocus-pocus
* Variety of Pice Change Rate: The general pice
decelration standard calls for each company to hold
its average rte of price increase in the yeae beginning Oct. 1, 1978 to 0.5 percenrage points below it
o
arerge annuat rate of price change from the It
""
qoarrer of 1975 to the lant qoarlee of 1977.
14

This produces a varity of pice change rates, rangbig from 1.5 percent to 975 percent. A minimum pice
increase of 1.5 percent is allowed automatcally. The
mavim.m to be allowed for the curien "program
year" is 9.5 percent, for companies that had increases
of 10 percent or more in the 1976-77 period.
There is no logic to the notion that the companies
with the laIrest pice increases in the base period
should continue to be allowed the largest price increases in the co-ent year A company's highly ingflati..y behavior in the past two colendar yeaes
hardly seems an adequate basin for prefeesed treatment in the corrent program. Ta be consisent with
the wage controls, an overall maniwam should logically bh set for all podactm,
* No Marfimam for Product Line or Product Increases: Within the rompay-wide overal average.
there are no limitn on pece increases for iiher individual product tiers or individual products The nky
is the limit as long as there are ofseltiog hold-down
(or pansibly decreases) that will keep the company's
overall price increase aveenge at east 05 percentage
points below the overall 1966-77 rate of price incease. This will enable a company to hold down
pnrces n prodacts where competition is keen and
engage in price gouging 00 products with litile competition. The more linen a company has and the
greater the number of products within prodct lines,
the moe leeway it has.
Since produit line ita iiay hne shihed Loviiderably since 1976-77, an unknown lement of artificinlity in introduced into overill average prce increase
rompoisens. This -a.ld be elminated only by having the price deceeraita
requirements apply
separately to each product line.
New and diseantinued product lines ore entluded
AFL-CIO AMERICAN PEtDERATIONtST

296
from the compututi.o of average onnuaf price increases Custom lines are ao exclded
While some special treatment may be needed for
such prodoct anes, thir exclusion aggravates the
anifidslity of price compaisoos "New products" introduced during the program year could be set at any
price, without affectingthe company's computed rate
of allowable icrrase. In order to itsure that "new
products" do not become a major loophole, effective
policing and enfomement is essential.
a No Limit on Profits Ercept Wages Deceeration
Pat-Through There is no limit on profits or profit
margins fur companies complying with the pice deceleration standard In panicolar, there is no requiremet for a pats-through of cost savings a company
might realize-say from a fall in raw materials prices
or an increasein productivity-ercept foe one ite:
a decreasein the rote of wagp and salary increases.
It is douibtfa that the paxs-through of savingsfrom
wage drceeralion by itself would have much noliceable impact on pries. While the Council on Wage
PNre Stabiliy (COWPS) has constranly stressedthe
idea that wages, salaris and finge beefits comprise
75 percent of company costs, this is only tr-e in the
special "rotor added" acc.untiog used it the National
.Icome Accounts,
Ifcome Accounts, t the National
the cost of materials used it production is subtracted
out, So there is little else to count ia costs etcep
wages and profits. In ordinary accounting, however,
a companyxst for "materials"-a teem which includes such items as energy in addition to raw or
semi-finished production materats-ore very much
present.
Assardiag Io a Standard and Poor Study, wages,
ralses and fringes as a percent of Walesrange dawn
to 7 pe-eet foe oil companies). Use of 7 percent
in the wage deceleratios pass-through eampte produces a total additional decleration requirement of
lessthan one-tenth of a percentagepint.
A company cue also incrr.ae its profits through
manipulation of price inceedsesfoe particular product
lines and products-increasing prices for high profit
items and hold them dawn on low-profit items

Products Exempted
On. aaatin of the guidelineslists a number of product lines which sellees re told to exclude tram their
computations of a-erage price increases These are
basic enemptions from price deceertino requirementx (the aforementioned new and discontinued
product tinesand custom lines appear in this list, bat
except for custom tines. ar not realy basic e-to.sins). Thes exclusions cover raw materials pces
(both farm and industial), pures for scrap, prices
fo materials sold on commodity e-chuoges, and
interest ates. Euport prices are also excluded as ace
"product lines euchanged e other than open arms
FEaBRUARY1171

length transactions,"presumably intra-company safes
The complete list itcludes prces of agrculturot
and industrial row materials (including crode petroIeum and natarol gas) industrial scrap (metal xcrop,
wastepaper); pices of commodities whose historical
and current price changes are closely tied to pice
movements in an oergaized open exchange; expons,
with imports dropped from this list, but still excluded
according to the COWPS QuesrOis and Answes;
pricer of prodccts delivered duneg the program year
where price is determined by contracts emistingbefore
Oct. 2, 1978; puces of product lines e-changed it
other than open rod arms-length tcuesacouos; prices
of new or discontiued product tines; custom product
tines; iterest rates.
osts aaalaslaaa cover the most inflationary
Th
elements in the etire economy The progrom speaks
of dealing with them in other ways-through generfa
goceroert policies affecting their supply and deround Additionally producers may be held to a
"profit macginlimitation" in licu of a price decelerstito standard. Where possible the bhyecs of such
products are to be held to the price deceleration
standard, hut if they cannot do so, they too will use
the "profit margin limitation."
a Treatment of Seters The effect of the enclosionsvanes according to which ectsions are invalved and how imponant they ore is the company's
sales mis Revnuerscemaining ofterexcluding salesof
raw materials, scrap, commodity exchange items, enpoes and items piced under pee-Oct 2 contracts are
called "adjusted set revenues" If "adjisted net roverues" are lessthar 25 percent of the total, the company is excused from any price or profit standard at
al.nIf the other items on the eaclasionlist (iutracompany sales, new or discontinued products, custom
products, and interest rates) make up more than one
third of "adjusted net revenues" the company is excused Icom the pric deceleration standard and uses
the "profit macginlimitation" instead
a Treatment of Bayers The e-empt items become
a cost to other companies and distributors as they
mace into successivestages of production and distribhtino. These bhyers are supposed to observe the
pere drelefotion standards as far as their awn pcices
are concerned, But if such c-ossare a large factor, it
may dnvelop that a compasy "cannot achieve" deceleration, in which case it too will be permitted to
use the "profit margin limitation."
The ultimate impacts of the escWusionscould be
considerable.

The Profit Margin Umitotion
Undar tha prfit margin 1lmItotain, wtten as an
"e-rptios" to the price decelerationstuadard, a company is in compliance with the guidelines if (I) its
"progrom year" profit margin dces not e.ceed is
"profit margie baso" (i.e., the weighted average of
as

297
the tatn biggest pofit -,Sai.s disng the three fineaj
Yeats ended belore Oct 2, 197f8) and (2) its dollba
profit does not exceed profit in the loar qaartets
eaded Oct. 1. 1978 by more thon 6.5 peent plas
the percent increas in real volume of ties. The
profit argit is defined an opeatig profit at a percent of stales.
The stoadard is to be ned by certan
toilets of
encladed prodocts and by roy cotpany oaable to
"cotply oith the prtce decelertion standard beronn
it te impossible to ralenlate itt acrege piceI, elang,
or beatuuo of onetrolltble pni inre-ases in goods
and -nites it boyn." Uncontrollable cost itest are
not defned in the regalation. but pcesnmably would at
least include high costs of eempt raw matealb ard
other ieen encluded from seilet' pnic de.eleratian
requirement
Under a pofit margin studard, the effreti to
allow a percentage past-on ol 11 cost inres therby enlarging total dollar profits and mageifying the
pce increase to the aeut bayer The regutanon does
attempt to abate this effect by setang a dollar limtit
on prufits. The fonnula r..Id stltl gtnerate onsiderable pnce increase hwever, in the ciae of a company with lalling sales volume and shrinking profit
margins in the peagram year A simple dotlar-lardollar pass-through of "unconirnltabe costr increases"
would se-ss
na mce ffectve chek on prices.

,.: .::.::.. :..'.. :'.:::::.

Other Price Standards

I

In edditins tonthb "puce deceleraion niandaod" rod

the "profit margin limiaton,"npecal 'opuitns" have
been added far wholesal and retail trde, sing grass
profit as a percentge of tales, cd for food manufacturing and lood procensing, sing grunt dollar
profit margins Fr profesional fees, the average rate
of increau in the progrum year is not supposd to
exceed 6.5 perce-t and the inu-e for any single
srvice is limited to 9 5 perceni Undoubtedly father
npectal options rod aternuices luo patiular industrne or types of enterpris are in the making.
Federal, state and loral gceremets are inclded
in the definitiuonM "company" in the COWPS guide
lines foe pay standard purpos. For price purpos,
howvee, only "goverment enterpris" are covered
-port, trausit, or water uthoity, publi hospital, or
muinipal uility. User fee charged by a gucerement
body primanrily supponed by tunes are not covered.
According to COWPS' officil O-ustiuns ond
Answe, companies staning uperations fter December 1977 are eicluded Icos the price program, "since
rone of the required infooation is available." Suck
companies are enpecmnd to obser
the pay stndard,
however and to adhere to the "spint" of the progeam
in staking their prkie detions,
By its very nature, the price progam cannot be
monitored by the public at Iarge.With ec-h company
having its own private rate of allowabl pnce in16

rneue carodatued according to iis awn c-afidertial
records, rnd with enanmmus Ieay to vary its puce
aicntse to its awn advotage, the pbhhc is helplest
rod as the dark,
The pobbe will hare to relY solely an COWPS to
catch np with those who might offeod its tliippey
stuadards, a nb whirh COWPS in bvionsly not
quipped to perifn.

~ii.i.:llii'!''.i"ii.i'_'

!!I'.

I

'!ii'

f:!!t

Price Laxity Shows in Profits
Peofins In tb. faterlh qatten., of 1978 cerntily ahom
na signs of being flented in any way by the pice
isaldehies. No eupressioas of cnceo are v-iced by
Admtnsuattird offinrla or by COWPS aboat the
substantial incrasesas busine s profits. Surging prfit
increases are not in keeping with the "asterity" and
".ac.ifice" whih the Adminitraion is urging upon
the publi at large, bat eidently the are entirely
aeputble nmder the an-intlation pengram.
The Wag Streelt are-J recently repoed, "Most
companies will rpon fonh quarter profits well
ahead of a pear aoher." While the overall fig-ret
ar not yet available, the repors for individual fints
indirait a Iarge surge in fuunh qaorer earnings, prtiolarly antug btnks
For nample, Bank Ameia. Carp, the parent oI
the nation's lagest commerdal bank, repoed its
operating eaings surged by 34 percet fuorthe final
quaner of 1978 and by 30 percent for the year
Chas Manhattan rrported a tuigI in fourh quaner
operating incoen of 62 percnt. Citiorp, parent of
the nation's second arget hank, Ciubank, reponed
an operting etmings' incree nl 28 percent while
Mann.fsart
Hanover Carp the foanh largest hank
holding compny, reponed an inereas of 12.9 perent. Fint Nation.. Boston Camrp parent of the Firt
Ntiuonal Bank of Boston, tio indiated a 21 percent
cimb in operting rarings for the fornh quanne
rith yearly ea-ings' increase of 33 percent
According to a specil survey of the 9f lorgett
banks made by the insestrent banking firm of Saluman Bmthers, the average gain in operating ucjings
came to 29.6 pereut for the year rod 25.8 perceur
for the qarer. Acording to the Jan. 29, 1979,
New York Tisen repon on the Salton study,
"Banken and bank analysts cited the absene of jawboning, nr puhbti nrgipgs from Whiugton, flor banks
to hold dosn their interest rMtes as a satju reason for
the impressive eurings An interest rates sarged
thrughout the economy, inks were able to keep
pacc by rasing their own rates-in paniralar, the
prnme rte, the cats charged their most credi-wonhy
corporate ctustoent
The most surpfitvg thing is
the lchk of political pressure .
But it hasnht happened Thais becaus we don't h-ve people nunnmg
acund in Washington "raining that the broke- are
rapsg the comty."
In odditiun to banks, many other corporatioas haveAFL-I'O AMERiCANFEDERATIONIST

298

The Lack of a Legal Basis
Th. Adsnbtretion'a p'ngeom. is described as
voluntary," but it establishes -aions penaltiesfor
those failing to cmply. Penalties are the essence
of a controls program and the antithesis of
"voluntary program"
In Septehber 1978 the Senate passeda 'sense
of the Senate" resolution opposing the roneept
that
oge-prtceor other sthbilitoiton policies be
enforced by the direct or implied threat of administrative actions or decisions pnrsuant to varous
lovs That revolution pointed act that "the employment of such discretionory poweesto promote
unrelated, unouthonied and arbhirarily chosen
w-ge/pnce objectives coessitines a fondamental
habse
of enectve power, mouldarbitranly bhrden
saomesector, idustines and economic groups mee
than others depending upon the discrotiunary
power to compel compliance available to the Esecutive Brunch in each case, and is incompatible
with our
onstitutional framework of divided
powees, proper statutory delegation of authority,
and tegislativerather than ministerial pm-eminence
in public policy-mking." ft also stated that "the
usI of such discration.ry powers to compel compliance with specific, numencol wage and price
stanlaeds amounts Io a de facto -uge-pnce control
program."
The proposed use of the federal procurement
procevs as the enforcement taut for the Administration's wage and pice stabilization program is
in labor's view unlawful Congress hbs denied the
Executive Branch the power to control wages and
prices.
First, Congresschose nut to cenewthe Eonomic
Stabiliation Act of 1970, the legislative authonty
for the wage and price controls promulgated by
President Nisos
Second, it passing the Council on Wage and
Price Stability Act, Congress provided "Nothing in
this act authorizes the cntinuation, imposition, or
ceimposition of any iandatory economic ontrols

with respect to prices, cents,wages, salaries, rporate dividends, or any similar transfers."
So there cold be no misundertanding, the Senate reponr stated "This bill wnuld grant no
mandatory or standby cntrol authority over the
rconomy."
These legislative determinations cannot he
avoided by the solt euphemism that the Adminis
tration's program is voluntary. However labelled,
a system that povides the penalty of deeroseot
for noncompliance with its standards is "mandatory" and is "wage-price contol"
Bat even if this use of goveroment procuroment
as au enforcement tool were not illegal, the rogulatiuns now in effect are discrminatory The program
does not provide due process and does not take
into account the practical differences between
separate classesof goveroment ontrcts.
In a broadly diversified firm, a single violation
of the wageguideline anyhere-evenji inadvertent-ould theoretically subject the Onceto concellatin of the goveromenl contract, as well as
to damuges
Th. p.'la 9ssfdaffn.. are so vagoe that for aol
practical purposes this is us enforcemen of the
wage guideline alone. Since data on price changes
generally will not be calculated unfil some time
in 1980, three is no effective way of determining
prsce c-mpliance
The "termination for defnult" procedure not
only deters a potential conlractor from bidding
but also allows the gavernment to move against
a contractur
aho
hbs received an award for the
costs of roprocuemet.
The procumrmentprocess is not aa appropriate
means of enfoecing a wage-price program. This
should be done directly through appropriate legis
laive authoity granted to a special body whose
position it would be to enforce an economic contrl program

17
1979
PEaflUARY
FEBUttARY
1979

17

299
shown sohbntunialincreasesin the foueth quartee with
Honeywell's profits op 56 percenl, General Foods'
profits p 79 percent, IBM up 27 percent, Mobil Oil
up 10 percent and Alcoa's e.nuingsup 124 percent.

Niuoo Pay Board roles to allow markers 5th particoulafr low wage increas dueng the prerinus 3
year to catch up somewhat asd negotiate increas
1.5 percent abeve the general overall standard. Na
'catchbup" t-eptioo is included in the present program.

Wage Controls
The 7 p.senen wage neetrsl figure lackn any canceptoal basis. It is simply an arbitrary number.
Wage inrreases are based on wany factors-tncreas in the cat of firing including increased tat
hardens, seceringan appropriate share of prdntintty
gais, maintenance of comparability ith other nurken, the employe' profitability, and other factor.
In one way ur soother,al precious U.S. rasdutoty
wage control progroms took these lments into
consideration. The present progtam does not.
The 7 percent figure does not even matntainnral
income in light of a cot ent flation rate of 9 percent
and the additional tues levied on higher ea-ings.
Precious programs allowed special consideration for
itprocing fringe benefits. This program does not.
In the light of thtn 9 percent inflation rate. the
wagecontrol figure ts well below the eqairalent figure
of the Nitno Pay Board in the make of controls that
Administruittn impeo-d in August 1971. At the time
of that contrle program. prices were increastig at a
4 percent rate, the wagestandard was set It 5.5 percent and the goal of that program was to reduce
inflation to 2.5 percent in the coming year. The 5.5
percent wage standard snmed that worker were
to receite an increa equiralnen to the projected fall
east of fiving (2.5 percent) pI. 3 percent for the
general increasein productivity. The c.orent administration plan does not allow workers to participate
in productivity gains
Whil. the.ea..re. Ie
program does provide a
few minor eceptions. it ignores rany of the enceptitns contatned in the Pay Board program of 1971.
The Pay Board was required by Congress to allow
for additional increasesfor specialfringe beerfits such
an pensions and health plans Such fonge benefits
were prorided by the Pay Board, an ntrm 0.7 percent
over and obesethe general 5.5 percent magestandard.
This nem program does not recognize the special
nature of pension and health benefits.Such benefits
do not espuod current demand for goods and ser-ice-,
hut rather set aside money for these future conDtngencies.
Under the COWPS roles, increased csts associated with mainataintg the first 7 percent of health
benefits mill be charged against the wage standards,
as though the pants could control the costs. No
earlier control program made each a charge. It is
not fair to charge these against the mage standard
while allowing employeesto pue through other costs
acer which they hare no control under the price
standard.
A "catch-up" euception was also provided by the
is

Low-Wage Exemption
A lor-wa.ge ewtemptin has hben included in alt
precious contotl programs. In 1971, when the House
amended the Nixon controls program, it clearly set
fonh the intent to asure that low-wge. workers not
beer the bhnt of the program. In the peronof the
Hose Banking nd Cerreqcy Committee the committee stated: "This section forbids the President,
ander the authority granted by this title, from regultion or olbencise restricting the wages of the werkog pooa or persons whose earnings are otherwAse
substandard.I is the intet'ioen of the ommittee that
this eemption from control apply to all pesons
whose earings are at or below levelsNtablished by
the B.au. of Labor Statisis in determining as
icome necessaryto afford adequate food, clothing
end shelter and similar necesities Absolute enempoIon from wage controls coder this act is also pr
vided in this section for persmonwhose ua-ings are
at qr below the federal minimum wage."
In a Jan. 18, 1972 letter, Rep Wright Patman,
then chairman of the House committee, wrote: "It
is the clear eotion of Congress that the authority
of this act should not be used to penaltef wage
earee by retarding progress toward achievement of
an adequate standard of firing. Certainly that sandard of adeqeacy cannot begin much before the
$7,000 income level iN reached. Granted, this weuld
leave the income of a large number of the nation's
worker unregulated under the act, hut by the some
token, no ono is arguing that the wages received by
these people and the wage increasesgranted to them
constiute a major element in the influtioet conditins that prerailed before implementaion of Phase
I...

Thos n-me .ne.arn for the working poor should
enist .nder this program. As set up by COWPS, it
does not. The Dfeponeme of Laber's lower Ievel
Urban Family Budget referred to in the 1971 amendments would today establish a low-wage enemption
at $5 an hour if the lust published budget for the
fall of 1977 mere used.That amounted to S10,481.
If those figures were updated to the end of 1978 to
reflect changesin the consumer price inden (CPI),
the tower level budget would be $11,726, or S5.64
an hoor
The low-wage eureption in the 1971 contrels
legislaon was related to the lower-level Urban
Fomily Budge. The Ninon Pay Board refused to
abide by the legisletive requirements and set the
low-wage esemption at 51.90 an hoor. After coors
AFL-CIO AMERICAN FEDERAflONIST

300
' proeedings., this figure was raind first to $2.75 an
hour and fihally to S3.50 an hoar. Today that figure
based oo the same bhdget would markoat to $5.64
and not the S4 set in the content program.

Current COWPS
Procedures
The proedarel NI.. st forth by COWPS are one
mote esampleof the noe-sidednature of the so-called
'volunitay" wage and peon program. While these
rulrs requrst firms to provide ptire changesor profit
margins for 1976 and 1977, they do not provide
COWPS with asy rnlightenment aboot current price
changes.
The requestedprice and profit margin informatiun
i, for the bhse period only. with no provisions for
"follow up" reports during the ptogram year Thu.
no remedy has beec established for the basic deficiency in the ability of COWPS Io determine whether
or not the companies are in fact complying with the
pricr pan of the program Followo-p reports are not
requested on either a quarterly or hall-year basis to
ditern-ror compliance with thn profit mangin tests
onaquarterly basis or the half-year ptice decelerations rrquirement.
COWPS alrcady hasdata on collecively bargained
wages-acarlhbl as public information-and on a
current basis. As soonas a union contract is signed
i is public informatino ted frequently repored in
the newspapersfor all to evaluate. Specific changes
in non-nion wages and changes in enecutive pay
and perquisites arc not regulanlyreported or matters
of public knowledge
Prica.
enls
or.
-as
ltebhasirallynot erpmetd and
not ecaluated under COWPS procedural regulations.
The procedural roles allow COWPS to interfere into
even the smallest collective bargaining rlationships
as it stands ready to judge whether any conract,
regardless of sie, is in compliance.
Not so on prices Only the largest firms are asked
to supply any data on prices
Companies with 5,000 or more employers ore to
file with COWPS information o "the method of
compotation" for the wage standard. Bat these data
are not requimd to he furnished to onions dirctly
related to such companies Since this may ie many
instances affect onion collective bangaining relationships, such information should he proided by the
companies to all unions that have a relationship with
soch companies. Affected anions should have the
abiliy to challenge the proposed method of "computaticn" for wage purposes
COWPS illegally assumes for itself the anthoaty
to reqoire prenotification and approval for wage and
price eceptinos The issue of prenolificalion of wage
and price decisions was considered by Congress when
d was possing the legislation esahblishing and conFEBRUARY 1979

tinning COWPS. But that egislation does not include
any prtoistons that grant COWPS the anthority to
require any prenotficatao otn wagesor pnces.
COWPS roles net ap COWPS as racmaker, proerotor, judge, and jury-with no procedure to guarantee a fair heating, or a fair determinain. The roles
give to one anrepresenative odministitaice body
roetml over theeconomk destiny of the onanty, and
aver the wages earned by millions of workers
throughout the country. Shbstantive decisions may
depend entidrely
administration "discrtion." For
-uample, COWPS allown an eueption to the wage
standard for a "gross inequity" but then .regantly
defies a "gross inequity" as "any situation that in
the council's tjdgment, is manifestly unfair." It allows
for no efective appeal from the council's osilateral
dnterminaions.
Only ee9fefsoal.enninin
of the necessary itcalvemeor of employees in COWPS procedures is
accorded. The clear right of employees and their
repreentaives to parocipole in ail proceedings
affecing thew and to receive all cammonicorions
unrereing pay standards un not fully and enpressly
enunciated is the rules.
Coopled with the 'rccnisideratioo" procedres,
the entirn processingof a disputed issue could he on
entremely time-consuming matter. Ponies making
reqoestsand commentsare held to strict time periods
for filing docomenis, but the counril reserves such
time for itsef as it may need to teach its delneminotions. The processcold drag on for months.
The COWPS esles do not accomplish fairness and
doe process, because there is no re-orse from an
adrers or arbitrary council determination other than
the council itself. No entice is given that an injoed
party could appropriately seek relief thrugh the
coons. The council pramalgains the standards, interprets them, prosncutes ther, enforces them, and is
thr judge of its own ntrepretations, all without
statutory authority.
The system dos not provide loe comprhensive
rneiw by on adequate staff nor does it insure don
process. The pere standards need not bh complied
with by all firms, bht just those that are government
supplies The staff of COWPS is not large .eough
to carry oat even the minimal montonog program
and cannot give firms and workers don process or
a fair hearing.
F.d.rIl *mployeos are singularly disertminated
against by the c--eor economic controls program.
Wage and salary omparabiliry laws provide that
federal salares are to bh comparable to these paid
in the p-vati sector. Arbitraily in 1978, a 55 prcrt limit was placed on frderal salary increases,
and that same 5.5 percent increase is projected for
1979 The wage contml figure for federal worhers,
as 1.5 percent heew the figure for all other workers,
is clearly discriminatory and calls for a degree of
sacrifice quite beyond that demanded of others.

301
Representative BOLLING. Congressman Reuss, would you please
assume the Chair, I have to leave.
Representative REUSS [presiding]. Yes; thank you, Mr. Vice
Chairman. Welcome, Mr. Oswald and Mr. Young.
I share Vice Chairman Bolling's evaluation that you have made
a real contribution to our hearings this year.
In your prepared statement, Mr. Oswald, you are in the midst of
listing hopes that the AFL-CIO had, and how they have been
pretty much dashed. But when you get to point 7, a note of cheer
enters, because there, you say-you quote from the need for community development-that the administration's proposed National
Development Bank would facilitate such community development,
and should be approved by Congress.
Actually, between the time that your prepared statement was
sent to the mimeographing room and this minute, the future tense
has changed to a future perfect tense. It should have read, "The
administration's proposed National Development Bank would have
facilitated such community development, and should have been
approved by Congress," and so forth. It is too bad that it has now
been withdrawn by the administration, and, hence, the Congress
effort to approve it would run into presumed administration opposition, and the whole thing must, therefore, be forgotten about.
Wouldn't that be a more accurate statement?
Mr. .OswALD. Yes. I was disturbed with that. One of the points
the President made very strongly was that the National Development Bank was the backbone of what he proposed as an urban
policy, approximately a year ago. There has not been the rehabilitation of some of the centers of depressed cities, as well as some
smaller communities in rural areas. It was the hope that the
National Development Bank would provide funds for that type of
development, both through loans and loan guarantees, as well as,
in some cases, some direct grants.
We have a separate statement of the executive council precisely
on that point, because they also thought that it had such specific
proposals for helping to bring jobs into areas.
Representative REUSS. Have you had an opportunity-I have
not-to look at the fine print in that administration reorganization
to see what they did with the money-I think it was something like
$3 billion in grants, loans, and guarantees-hitherto allocated to
them, the proposed-but now defunct-National Development
Bank?
Mr. OSWALD. At one point, I recall $1.5 billion was allocated and
I am not sure what the current plans are with the withdrawal now.
Representative REUSS. Do you know, Mr. Young?
Mr. YOUNG. I don't know.
Representative REUSS. I would like to ask the, committee staff to
determine that at this point, and let's have it in the record. I think
*it's very important.
[The following information was subsequently supplied for the
record:]

47-977 0 - 79 - 20

302
President Carter's fiscal 1980 budget included a request for $3.5 billion in new
budget authority for the proposed National Development Bank. The allocation of
the requested $3.5 billion by activities is provided in detail in the following table:

NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT BANK
NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT BANK
(Proposed for later transmittal, proposed legislation)
, Program and Financing (in thousands of dollars)
identifiao

e 95-3201-2-1-452

Program by activities:
1. Administration of the bank ....................
.
2. Interest subsidies (loan guarantees) .....
3. Interest subsidies (long-term debt) .......
4. Grants (EDA/Commerce) ......................
.
5. Grants (HUD) ........................................
6. Liquidity facility (loan purchases) .........
7. Disbursements for guarantee claims ......
8. Payments to the Federal Financing
Bank of interest on borrowings to purchase qualified debt................................
10.00

1978 xtual

1979est.

1980
est.

................
.................
.................
................
....
.................
.................

4,236
.................
.................
.................
.................
.................
.................

12,423
1,247,000
263,000
275,000
275,000
1,000,000
32,000

..............

.................

22,500

4,236

3,126,923

Total program costs, funded-obligations ..........................

Financing:
14.00 Offsetting collections from:Non-Federal
sources:.
Sale of qualified debt to Federal Financ....-............. ..... ....
ing Bank ............................................
Redemption of defaulted loans ................
.
....................-.............
24.40 Unobligated balance available, end of year:
Appropriation. ......................................... ................. .................
24.47 Unobligated balance available, end of year:
Authority to borrow .................................
....
.................
Budget authority .............................

Budget authority:
. 40.00 Appropriation............................................
47.00 Authority to borrow (appropriation act)

..............

Outlays ....................................

404,600
500,000

4,236

3,530,423

.................
4,236
................. ...............

3,030,423

Relation of obligations to outlays:
71.00 Obligations incurred, net ............................ .................
..........
72.40 Obligated balance, start of year
74.40 Obligated balance, end of year .................... .................
90.00

-500,000
-1,100

500,000

4,236
.................
-211

2,625,823
211
-2,431,232

4,025

194,802

Source: The Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1980: Appendix., p. 1009.

303
Although the National Development Bank proposal has been withdrawn, a substantial proportion of the requested budget authority and program activities have
been submitted by the President in; S. 914, the National Public Works and Economic
Development Act of 1979. The programs would be administered by the Economic
Development Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce. The budget authority
requested in the NPWEDA for fiscal 1980 includes:
1. Title I-$90,780,000, for Economic Development and Adjustment Planning Assistance and Technical Assistance.
2. Title II-$595,200,000, for Grants for Public Works and Other Economic Development and Adjustment.
3. Title III-$569,350,000, to be appropriated for Development Financing programs, including direct loans and interest subsidies, plus $1,800,000,000, to be authorized for loan guarantees.
4. Title IV-$4,000,000, for Research, Evaluation and Demonstration.
5. Title V-authorizes the appropriation of such sums as may be necessary for the
Administration of the act.

Representative REUSS. I know several hundred additional millions were allocated to UDAG, and if so, that is good, but-Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS [continuing]. I would like to see what happened to the total figures, if those total.figures were maintained
and if they are put in useful places, then we needn't cry forever at
the bier of the National Development Bank. But if the doing-in of
the bank is accompanied by a further belt tightening, you would
share my nonpleasure at that; would 'you not?
Mr. OSWALD. Yes, yes, very much. The only additional money
which we recall at all in the budget in that area was $150 million
for a new targeted aid to communities which is a very small
amount of money in total.
Representative REUSS. Now, on these various youth employment
programs and structurally unemployed programs-Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS [continuing]. Which, I agree with you, are
vitally important, and which have been cut in the current budget,
the administration tends to answer criticism of those cuts by
saying, "Oh, no, we just cut off summer programs for middle-class
kids and we don't really need it," and so on, and so on, can you
comment on that?
Mr. OSWALD. On the youth program, the specifics are that the
middle-class kids are not eligible, should not be eligible. If they
were given, any of the job slots, it was a misuse of the program.
Clearly, the high levels of unemployment, particularly among
black teenagers, in our country indicate the need for a continuation of that program. Those unemployment levels are still running well over 30 percent. In terms of the national manpower
programs, which really were outreach programs and beginning
skill programs, the amount of money that was cut was very small,
$50 million, but they were some of the most effective programs run
by the Urban League, by the AFL-CIO itself, in terms of its
Human Resources Development Institute, and a number of unions
in terms of outreach, senior citizens, rural Americans. We were
told that the administration didn't know, itself, what it was doing
when it was cutting those programs. They thought it was some
discretionary funds of the Secretary, and they just cut out $50
million.

As to the $1 billion cut on the CETA, that was not because
people didn't think that those jobs didn't count, but just because it

304
became a victim to the attempt to automatically bring the budget
deficit below $29 billion.
Representative REUSS. I completely agree with the AFL-CIO and
your testimony that funds to combat structural unemployment'
should have been increased, not decreased, in a time when, although you may not agree with-and don't agree with-the administration's specific fiscal and monetary policies, I would think and
hope that the AFL-CIO would agree on a macroeconomic basis that
we need moderate fiscal and monetary policies.
Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS. We don't want to turn on all the steam
and really create the demand inflation which some people say we
are really suffering from.
Mr. OSWALD. We are in agreement with that, and our differences
in terms of the total amount of the budget involve fairly small
amounts of money. The cuts amount to about $12 to $15 billion,
and the impact on inflation is very small, one-tenth of 1 percent.
That is really not the inflationary problem.
We are concerned that with these cuts in the structural unemployment programs, cuts in social security, which people thought.
was an insurance to which they had benefits entitlement-that is
what they paid for. We are not against budget cuts if the programs
are no longer necessary or no longer .of value, and we are not for
deficits when we have full employment.
It's just that even at the current level of economic functioning,
we still have substantial levels of unemployment, higher than
other times, still fairly high levels of plant underutilization and
most of the inflation pressures are coming from specific areas of
the economy-the food sector, the energy sector, and housing,
which is affected very heavily by the use of the monetary route to
tighten the whole economy.
Representative REUSS. Having said that-as you have, I thinkyou would have much preferred to see a modestly greater budgetary allocation to the overall program of fighting structural unemployment, that doesn't mean that the AFL-CIO is cast in concrete
on any one particular structural unemployment combating program, does it? I say that because, in my view-and I would like to
ask yours-the CETA program, while it contains much that is
good, also contains a lot of foolishness, and that, had there been
appropriate restrictions and cuts in CETA, more than made up by
additions to other programs for fighting structural unemployment,
we might be better off. Would you agree?
Mr. YOUNG. Congressman-Representative REUSS. Would you agree CETA is as good as it
says?
Mr. YOUNG. I don't think you can solve the structural unemployment problem with any one specific Federal program, or, for that
matter, any State and local program.
It's a package of programs that try and get at the problems.
As you know, CETA itself is a package. I think people in Congress, a lot of people around the country and, certainly, the media,
talk about the public service employment features. There are many
other features of CETA dealing with training, dealing with upgrading, dealing with outreach, title III, the one Mr. Oswald referred to,

305
consisting of the national programs to reach into the community
where community-based organizations as well as various groups
seek to bring structurally unemployed people into the private
sector to provide jobs and provide skilled training.
I think the "soft" public works program that the administration
originally proposed last year, and is no longer proposing, was a way
of providing training and help.
The programs under title I and title II of CETA clearly get into
this area. The countercyclical program has an impact because
when those funds are out there, it obviously provides for other
funds that can be utilized or should be utilized for structural-type
programs.
Even the title VI countercyclical program of CETA, which is not
aimed at the structurally unemployed, we feel, has a direct bearing, because as long as you have high unemployment among the
semiskilled and skilled workers, then the private sector is not
going to employ the structurally unemployed. They know that the
skilled and semiskilled are more productive, more effective, and
have more work experience. In fact, the semiskilled and skilled
work force is long-term unemployed by definition, becomes structural, and that is conterproductive. I guess in summation, we look
upon the structural unemployment problem as requiring a package
of efforts, the only real way to get at it. We are not tied to one
specific program. We have been trying to support many of them.
Representative REUSS. The administration's scenario for unemployment is to increase it from 5.8 percent to 6.2 percent in 1979.
Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS. Let me ask you-one or both of you-this
question. Suppose that you were asked to accept as a given fact
that the budget deficit must be reduced to the $29 billion which is
the President's projected deficit. Do you not think, as I do, that
even with that budgetary stringency, it would have been perfectly
possible to heighten the attack on structural unemployment, spend
somewhat more on it, in considerably better coordinated programs,
and find the-not huge, as you point out-additional sums elsewhere in the budget, whether by plugging tax loopholes or doing
away with this or that obsolete or counterproductive spending program, and, thus, by thickening the tax on structural unemployment, come out with an overall unemployment rate which doesn't
go down? I'm being conservative, I'm saying, "Keep it at 5.8 percent."

Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS. Couldn't that have been done, and isn't
that the real tragedy of the administration's approach?
Mr. OSWALD. That is the real tragedy, because we spend large
amounts of money through tax loopholes that nobody really looks
at. Many of those loopholes go to the very wealthy in our society,
where they escape paying the taxes that could be used to offset
costs of worthy programs. One example of such programs is a
union program which has trained many workers to become ironworkers through some of these manpower programs.
The spending is about $2 million a year for that training. Well,
the people who have gone from unemployment, from unskilled jobs,
to working at jobs that pay over $10 an hour, as ironworkers, and

306
paying taxes on that, more than pays off a couple of years of the
spending for these structural programs. It is our concern that when
you cut back, you really leave people for a long time in this pocket
of nonproductive work, of not using their abilities that could be
heightened through training programs, to bring them into the
mainstream of the economy and move them forward.
That is what this budget, in essence, does.
Representative REUSS. And who knows better than you representatives of the AFL-CIO, there isn't a meeting of minds between
you and the administration on the general question of what is
called an incomes policy, wage price suasion, and so on.
The general view of -the AFL-CIO is that it is unfair to ask
working people to abide by a belt-tightening wage ceiling when so
much of the rest of the economy is either uncontrolled, or sees its
economic efforts crowned by profits and rewards unparalleled in
the history of the Republic.
That's been one of the reasons why we don't have in this country
what they have in Austria, where, as you know, at the beginning of
the year, the Chancellor gets together with the representatives of
business, and the representatives of labor, and they work out harmonious goals and the pot is sweetened for workers by some control over the structure of pricing and profits, and by a whole series
of benefits, and by a practical guarantee of full employment.
If the AFL-CIO operated in Austria, do you think Herr Meany
would be willing to sit down with his opposite number at the head
of state and do some meaningful negotiating?
Mr. OSWALD. Congressman Reuss, undoubtedly we would be more
than willing to sit down and do the negotiating on that type of
issue.

Our whole concern is that the current program is so inequitable.
As you well know, as chairman of the House Banking Committee,
for example, the banks have come up with the largest increase in
profits during the fourth quarter of last year ever, and it was the
first quarter under this new program.
On the price side, the Council on Wage and Price Stability says
we can't develop any guidelines even for the price mechanism of
what banks charge in terms of their interest rates over and above
the discount rate or anything else.
Mr. Meany, on many occasions, has indicated a willingness to
cooperate in a national effort to try and curtail inflation in terms
of the labor movement. It's very difficult, however, to do it if there
is no one to negotiate with, and that is basically part of the
problem.
Mr. YOUNG. What we find-Representative REUSS. Are you talking about your opposite numbers in business or the administration?
Mr. OSWALD. Both.
Mr. YOUNG. What we find so hard to live with, Congressman, is
that the employer finds it very patriotic to enforce the wage guideline and when we go to the administration and say, "How do we do
something about enforcing the other side of the guidelines in terms
of legislative proposals," we are told, "These are terribly complex,
very difficult to deal with, and we just can't come up with an
answer."

307
We have suggested, for example, that there could be an excess
profit margin tax tied to the real wage insurance program as one
way of raising revenue.
We, in our testimony before the Ways and Means Committee,
Mr. Oswald and I, both talked about some of the inequities in that
proposal, and said we would be more than willing to work with the
committee and, also, suggested this type of tax.
Then, as I'm sure you know, the Joint.Committee on Taxation
gave us an estimate that the-real-wage insurance proposal, instead
of costing the administration's estimate of $2.5 billion, would probably go to $5 or $6 billion.
Again, we have said, "OK, one of the ways of recovering some of
that revenue is to go the other route, and we will work with you,
let's develop some fair proposals that, in effect, do put some degree
of controls on something besides wages." And, again, we were being
told, "We just don't know how to do it. We don't have the answers.
It's complex. It's tough. The idea may have some merit."
The real way that we can see, the easy way we can do something
about inflation, Congressman, is to put these guidelines in and
then get some compliances from employers who say they'll live
with them.Our people just think that's terribly inequitable, and so do we, of
course.
Mr. OSWALD. I would like to add one other thing in terms of just
the level. This is the first time that the wage guidelines, for example, in all of our experience with control programs, was just established in this fashion, so that the guideline is actually below the
rate of inflation.
During World War II, workers under the most severe economic
conditions were able to get increases in line with the rate of
inflation under what was called the "little steel" formula. Even
under the late Nixon program, there was the 5.5 percent guideline
established when the rate of inflation was 4 percent, and it was
predicted it would get down to 2.5 percent, and there would be a
3.5 percent productivity gain. Now, 7 percent guidelines exist when
you have a rate of inflation of 9.3 percent, which means a real
severe cut in workers' ability to just maintain their standard of
living.
Representative REUSS. Well, what might have been is also a sad
business to contemplate, but we still have a little time.
Maybe we would do better.
Turning to another subject, I like your approach to inflation very
much, as I distill it from your statements and the attachments. It
comes down to this, that while you recognize the need-as you said
before-for moderate and sensible fiscal and rnonetary policies,
that to try to tighten fiscal monetary policy until the pipsqueak is
not going to combat the commanding heights of inflation which are
concentrated, at least for the average family, on food, housing,
energy, and health care-Mr. YOUNG. That's right.
Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS [continuing]. Which have been the big
upward items, and that-you don't quite put it in these terms-it

308
makes no sense to have a heroic fiscal policy and a supertight
monetary policy which is seeing a decline of Ml in the last months.
Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS. And an attempt, by Government action, to
bid up the price of russet potatoes because they come from somebody's district, and bid up the price of sugar because that comes
from somebody else's district, and bid up the price of winter tomatoes because they come from somebody else's district, and raise the
price of gasoline because that comes from still another person's
district.
Mr. OSWALD. Yes.
Representative REUSS. But we are, at one and the same time,
making more inflation and flirting with recession when we do that.
Is that a fair statement of your position?
Mr. OSWALD. That is a fair statement, Congressman. I wouldn't
put it in terms of saying, though, that it is in relation, particularly,
to any Member's district.
Representative REUSS. Of course not, you're more tactful. [Laughter.]
Mr. OSWALD. But I think, also, that part of the issue that we
would like to look at is that part of inflation gets related to some of
the trade pressures and other things. We get very concerned when
there are big increases in domestic prices that may be related
somewhat to the efforts of American buyers as they try and purchase items going out as exports. For example, in hides and leather
goods, the wholesale prices went up 54 percent in 1 year, last year.
Part of that was caused by the decline in cattle slaughtered, but
we also upped our exports substantially. Wheat prices went up
substantially, about 25 percent. We also increased our exports of
wheat about 29 percent. Yes, we need to encourage exports, but we
shouldn't do it at the expense of a domestic inflationary impact. I
think we need to look much more on some of this relationship
between specific products and things.
Representative REUSS. Since leather goods are made in my district, I didn't mention that. Thank you very much. [Laughter.]
We are very grateful to you. I could visit with you all day, and I
would like to, but we have another witness, and you have to get
back to work. Thank you very much, Mr. Oswald and Mr. Young.
We appreciate it.
Mr. OSWALD. Thank you.
Representative REUSS. We will now hear from the United Auto
Workers. Mr. Howard Young, special consultant to the president,
pinch hitting for Mr. Douglas Fraser, president, who, I am sorry to
hear, has a common malady, the bad cold.
STATEMENT OF HOWARD YOUNG, SPECIAL CONSULTANT TO
THE PRESIDENT, UAW, ACCOMPANIED BY JERRY TUCKER,
LEGISLATIVE OFFICE

Mr. YOUNG. Thank you, Congressman Reuss.
Representative REUSS. Mr. Young, we have a comprehensive prepared statement from your president which, under the rule and
without objection, will be received in full in the record.
You may proceed in any way you like.

309
Mr. YOUNG. I have with me Jerry Tucker of the UAW legislative
office here in Washington. As you noticed, President Frazer has a
very bad head cold, and just this morning called and asked if he
could be excused and he apologizes to the committee.
What I would like to do if it is satisfactory with you is read some
excerpts of the prepared statement we submitted and then try to
answer any questions you may have.
The committee's work in reviewing the 1979 Economic Report of
the President is especially important because it is the first report
to be presented under the guidelines of the Humphrey-Hawkins
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act. That law is a commitment for the Congress and the President to move the Nation steadily toward full employment.
. It is true that the law contains an inflation goal for 1983 of 3
percent along with the original goal of 4 percent unemployment.
But the language of the bill specifically rejects "tradeoff" economic
policies-efforts to hold down inflation by raising the rate of unemployment.
In establishing the inflation goal the law says unequivocally:
Policies and programs for reducing the rate of inflation shall be designed so as not
to impede achievement of the goals and timetables
for the reduction of
unemployment.

The act reflects the conclusion "that sole dependence upon fiscal
and monetary policies or both to combat inflation can exacerbate
both inflation and employment." It calls on the President also to
initiate "specific targeted policies" or "structural policies" to
reduce inflation.
Likewise, the Humphrey-Hawkins law retains its original thrust
of stressing the need for Government action.to meet national priorities. The act addresses the question of the share of gross national
product accounted for by Federal outlays-but it does not explicitly
seek a reduction in that share-only "the lowest level consistent
with national needs and priorities." The bill also seeks to achieve a
balanced Federal budget-but only if this is "consistent with the
achievement of the medium-term goals" for unemployment and
inflation.
THE TARGETS OF THE ECONOMIC REPORT

Unfortunately, we are forced to conclude that the 1979 Economic
Report of the President walks away from the commitments made
so recently in the Huimphrey-Hawkins Act.
We are still being offered rhetorical statements that are encouraging. In his state of the Union address this year the President told
the Congress and the Nation that "it is a myth that we must
choose endlessly between inflation and recession." Rather, he said
that we could "build the foundation for a strong economy with
lower inflation, without contriving either a recession with its high
unemployment or unworkable mandatory government controls."
In his economic message he promised, "We will not try to wring
inflation out of our economic system by pursuing policies designed
to bring about a recession. * * * Stop-and-go policies. do not work."
Yet, whenwe look at the more detailed report of the Council of
Economic Advisers-we find a clear message that the goal of stead-

310
ily reducing unemployment is to be sacrificed to an effort to reduce
inflation by slowing down the growth of the economy.
The annual targets projected for the next 5 years reflect this
tradeoff philosophy. The Economic Report does not recommend
steady progress toward the goal of reducing unemployment to 4
percent within 5 years. Instead it recommends policies designed to
increase unemployment from its current level of 5.8 percent to an
average 6.2 percent for 1979 and 1980.
It then shows that very rapid reductions in the rate of unemployment "would be required" to reach the goal of 4 percent by 1983.
The policies described would seem to be precisely the "stop-and-go"
policies that the President assures us "do not work."
There is the very real danger that the "fiscal and monetary
restraint" will overshoot its mark and plunge the economy into a
major recession. The administration's goal is "to moderate growth
without producing a recession."
But since 1948 we have had five periods of economic slowdown
that lead the Nation into major recessions with sustained periods
of high unemployment-beginning in 1954, 1958, 1960, 1970, and
1974. We should have learned by now that it is hard to flirt with
recessionary forces without ending up by getting pregnant.
In short, the policies of this administration are skating on very
thin ice. If the ice breaks-if we lapse into a recession-it is the
working people of America who will plunge into the chilly waters.
Indeed, it will be those workers with the least seniority-blacks,
teenagers, women, and low-wage workers-who will suffer most
from the increase in unemployment.
The administration is apparently willing to have them bear that
risk. The Economic Report forecasts that its anti-inflation program
of "fiscal and monetary discipline" will slow down economic growth
and increase unemployment to 6.2 percent.
But it goes on to argue that "the inflationary problem can be
dealt with most successfully by persisting with the discipline of
anti-inflation policies for an extended period even if economic
growth for a time should fall below the path that is now forecast."
I think that the verdict on this kind of approach was written 2½/2
years ago:
Now any system of economics is bafikrupt if it sees either value or virtue in
unemployment. We simply cannot check inflation by keeping people out of work.

Those words were spoken by Jimmy Carter before the 1976
Democratic Convention. I think they are as valid today as when
they were spoken.
The second reason why the administration policies will not work
is that they will make it far harder to achieve the goals of the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
If we are to achieve the goal of 4 percent unemployment by 1983,
we have 5 years in which to reduce unemployment by roughtly 2
percent. If we begin now and apply ourselves steadily to the task, it
will mean an average reduction of about four-tenths of 1 percent
each year.
But if we spend the next 2 years going in the wrong directionincreasing unemployment to 6.2 percent in 1979 and 1980-that

311
will leave us with only 3 years in which to reduce employment by
2.2 percent.
The whole logic of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act is that the Government should gear up now for a vigorous but gradual assault
over the next 5 years on the problem of structural unemployment.
Instead, the administration proposes to slip backwards for the next
2 years-making the ultimate task all the more difficult.
The Joint Economic Committee has important new responsibilities under the Humphrey-Hawkins law. Section 302 requires the
committee to report to the House and Senate Budget Committees
its own recommendations for short-term and medium-term economic goals.
The deadline for that report is March 15-less than 2 weeks from
today. If you agree with us that the employment goals in the
Preisdent's Economic Report are inadequate-that they move away
from rather than toward the goals of Humphrey-Hawkins-then
we strongly urge you to propose an alternative set of goals.
Minimum goals for the next 2 years should be that they each
carry us one-fifth of the way to the 5-year goal. We urge this
committee, then, to propose as targets that the unemployment rate
be lowered-from the 6-percent average for 1978-to no more than
5.6 percent for 1979 and no more than 5.2 percent for 1980. The
1980 target would thus be a full percentage point lower than the
6.2 percent proposed in the Economic Report-and represent 1
million fewer Americans out of work.
The common estimate is that that also would represent $20
billion additional available for Federal purposes. Targets for subsequent years should also show steady progress-no more than 4.8
percent in 1981, 4.4 percent in 1982 and 4 percent in 1983.
For the next 2 years, clearly we must have a different mixture of
policies if the economy is to continue to progress toward full employment.
Detailed comments on the 1980 budget proposed by the President
are attached to the prepared statement. I shall not read those.
For now, I will only point out that the 1980 budget is too restrictive. In particular, we must not cut back on jobs programs in a
time when unemployment threatens to increase. On the contrary,
if we are serious about the goals of Humphrey-Hawkins we need an
immediate expansion of jobs programs that are targeted on those
workers with the highest rates of unemployment-including minorities, teenagers, and female heads of households-and on those
areas with the highest rages-including our older industrial cities.
In addition, the present policy of monetary contraction must be
reserved to help maintain demand for housing and business investment.
The conservative economist Milton Friedman has recently
warned that maintaining the present restrictive monetary policy
would eventually plunge the American economy into a recession.
But going beyond the short-term dangers of recession, a faster rate
of monetary expansion is needed to avoid choking off investments
to renew our stock of housing and to stimulate productivity growth.
The Economic Report is frankly pessimistic that the Nation can
reach the employment goals of Humphrey-Hawkins and maintain
reasonable price stability at the same time. That pessimism will be

312
self-fulfilling if we maintain a business-as-usual approach to the
employment goals of the bill and if we continue to stress aggregative solutions to problems that are structural in origin.
What I suggest today is that we adopt a positive, "can-do" attitude toward the employment goals-and we begin to think together
of the new policy tools that must be created in the coming months
if those goals are to be realized.
The Federal Government must create an active process of planning for full employment, including a command center located in
the Executive Office of the President. Such a center would be a
source of ideas for new programs to reduce unemployment in particular parts of the economy.
In order to reduce unemployment nationwide we have got to
address the problem of "runaway shops"-manufacturing operations that are shifted from one part of the country to another,
leaving behind workers without jobs and communities without tax
bases. One part of that problem is the growing array of special
subsidies and special tax cuts that States and local governments
offer to new business.
We in the UAW have a.simple name for this practice among the
States: We call it "economic cannibalism."
Even when companies do not relocate, they use that interstate
competition as a threat to extract new concessions from their home
communities. They even pit one community against another within
the same State, and efforts by State government to control that are
undercut by the competition from other States.
We propose that Congress prevent the States or localities from
imposing one level of taxes-or providing one level of services-for
existing businesses, but providing much more favorable treatment
for new or expanded businesses. States use other objectionable
forms of competition-such as inadequate workers' compensation
and unemployment insurance programs, and undercutting workers'
collective bargaining ability. Better national standards are needed
in those areas also.
There are, of course, other causes of economic dislocation. The
potential unemployment should be avoided when possible, otherwise its impacts must be alleviated.
All across the country there are communities that stand under
the shadow of sudden and substantial job loss. Those communities
would welcome the creation of a standby program that might
rescue their economic future if they should be suddenly struck by
the closing of a major plant, office, or mine. Such a program should
include standby public works and standby Federal procurement
programs designed to meet national needs as well as to provide'
jobs. It might include temporary Federal subsidies under some
circumstances. It should also include the availability of investment
funds to help create a new and more permanent economic base for
a stricken community.
We need a number of other steps to minimize economic dislocation and its impact on workers and their families. Plants should be
required to give advance notice of a planned closing, with time
allowed for negotiations with representatives of the workers and
the community.

313
If a plant does eventually close, workers should be provided with
substantial aid in seeking and in being trained for new employment and resettling in a new community. Employers should be
required to guarantee transfer rights within a corporation and to
cover the worker's reasonable expenses of relocating in a new
community.

We should go beyond the notion that the only acceptable public
job programs are ones sponsored by State and local governments.
Many of our national needs will only be addressed through projects
defined and conducted by the Federal Government. The Tennessee
Valley Authority served to provide jobs while meeting broad regional needs during the 1930's.
Many of today's national needs-in such fields as transportation
and energy-may best be addressed through public investments. A
program of public investments-at the times and places where jobs
are most needed-can be a useful tool in our movement toward full
employment.
To adequately address the problem of localized unemployment
we must adopt new ways of directing private investment to areas
of chronic joblessness.The existing investment tax credit is too often used to help
finance the movement of jobs out of a community with high unemployment and into areas with low employment, or in other ways to
undercut the effort to achieve full employment. It should be repealed.
If Congress feels that some tax incentive for investment is
needed, then a targeted investment tax credit would be better than
the present approach. Investment in areas of chronically high unemployment should be one of the eligibility conditions for that
credit. Such investments could include structures as well as equipment installed in those areas.
From your earlier conversation, Congressman Reuss, apparently
there has been some change in the National Development Bank
proposal, but we still believe that a National Development Banik
would be a useful way to direct investment to economically depressed areas.
These, and other Government actions, to more specifically direct
the pattern of private investment would be preferable to the present efforts that rely on interest rates, generalized tax incentives,
and hopes for satisfactory response from business.
We can still learn from experimentation. We would urge that the
Congress move quickly to establish pilot programs in 8 or 10 communities around the country in which a variety of tools would be
used to achieve full employment for the existing residents. These
"full employment communities" should include a mixture of urban,
suburban, and rural areas.
The employment programs established should be primarily federally funded but include a mixture of State, local, and Federal
operation to insure that they cover a wide range of projects and
tasks.
We should be aiming to create a permanent system of aid to
areas of high unemployment to include both budgetary assistance
and public service employment. At a time of general prosperity

314
such a system would primarily deal with areas of structural unemployment and meet priority needs neglected by the private sector.
But with a general economic downturn, the same system would
be automatically triggered to provide jobs and budgetary relief to
those areas hardest hit by recession. Only by operating both jobs
and budgetary relief simultaneously can we avoid the sort of conflicts that arose during the darkest days of 1975 and 1976.
We need to retain vital public employees as well as to absorb
new employees laid off by the private sector. Only the Federal
Government can provide the resources to meet those needs in areas
of high unemployment.
In conclusion, when last year and the year before our members
and our allies marched and rallied for the passage of HumphreyHawkins, we took the goal of full employment very seriously. We
thought the Congress took it seriously, and we thought the President took it seriously. Today, we must look to you in Congress to
redeem our confidence.
The goal of reducing unemployment to 4 percent can be metand it should be met. It cannot be met through conventional policies and conventional attitudes, but only through new exertions of
intellect and of will.
This is our challenge today. By thinking and acting optimistically and creatively, we can yet achieve full employment and bring a
new definition of security and prosperity into every home in
America.
Thank you very much, Congressman Reuss.
Representative REuss. Thank you very much, Mr. Young.
At this point, Mr. Fraser's prepared statement will appear in the
record.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Fraser follows:]

315
PREPARED

STATEMENT ON THE
1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT
PRESENTED TO THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
BY
DOUGLAS A. FRASER, PRESIDENT
INTERNATIONAL UNION, UNITED AUTOMOBILE, AEROSPACE
AND AGRICULTURAL IMPLEMENT WORKERS OF AMERICA, UAW
March 2, 1979

I am Douglas Fraser, President of the International Union, UAW.

It is

a pleasure and a privilege to have the opportunity of speaking before this Committee
on behalf of 1.7 million members of the UAW.
Your work in reviewing the 1979 Economic Report of the President is
especially important, because it is the first report to be presented under the guidelines
of the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment

and Balanced Growth Act.

Our union

worked tirelessly over many years to secure passage of that bill. We judge the current
Economic Report - as we hope you will judge it -- by how well or how badly it
reflects the mandate that Congress laid down when it passed Humphrey-Hawkins last
fall.
The Meaning of -kxnphrey-HkwAkins
There were times during the congressional debate

on the Humphrey-

Hawkins bill when we feared that it would be too loaded down with amendments to
retain its original thrust.

Now that the bill has become law, however, we can see its

major purpose intact - a commitment by the Congress and the President to move the
nation steadily toward full employment.
The Humphrey-Hawkins low retains its original title -- the Full Employment
and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 - and it "declares and establishes as a national
goal the fulfillment of the right to full opportunities for useful paid employment at
fair rates of compensation of all

individuals able, willing, and seeking to work."

316
It is true that the law contains an inflation goal for 1983 of 3 percent
along with the original goal of 4 percent unemployment. But the language of the bill
specifically rejects 'tradeoff"

economic policies -- efforts to hold down inflation by

raising the rote of unemployment.

In establishing the inflation goal the low says

unequivocally: "policies and programs for reducing the rate of inflation shall be designed
so as not to impede achievement of the goals and timetables ... for the reduction of
unemployment."
monetary

The act reflects the conclusion "that sole dependence upon fiscal and

policies or both to combat inflation can exacerbate both inflation and

employment." It calls on the President also to initiate "specific targeted policies" or
"structural policies" to reduce inflation.
Likewise, the Humphrey-Hawkins low retains its original thrust of stressing
the need for government action to meet national priorities.

The act addresses the

question of the share of gross notional product accounted for by federal outlays -- but
it does not explicitly seek a reduction in that share -- only "the lowest level consistent
with national needs and priorities."

The bill also seeks to achieve a balanced federal

budget -- but only if this is "consistent with the achievement of the medium-term
goals" for unemployment and inflation.
The Tarqets of the Economic Report
Unfortunately, we are forced to conclude that the 1979 Economic Report
of the President walks away from the commitments made so recently in the HumphreyHawkins act.
We are still being offered rhetorical statements that are encouraging. In
his State of the Union address this year the President told the Congress and the notion
that "it is a myth that we must choose endlessly between inflation and recession."

317
Rather, he soid that we could "build the foundation for a strong economy with lower
inflation, without contriving either a recession with its high unemployment or unworkable
mandatory government controls."

In his economic message he promised, "We will not

try to wring inflation out of our economic system by pursuing policies designed to
bring about a recession ... Stop-and-go policies do not work."/
Yet, when we look at the fine print - when we read the more detailed
report of the Council of Economic Advisers -- we find a clear message that the goal
of steadily reducing unemployment is to be sacrificed to an effort to reduce inflation
by slowing down the growth of the economy.

We are warned that "a further reduction

of the unemployment rate during 1979 would run some risk of generating excess demand
and creating inflationary pressures in labor markets.'/

Beyond this, we are told that

"to avoid creation of excess demand, economic growth needs to slow to a pace at, or
somewhat below, the long-term potential rote of expansion"s - in other words, too
slowly to absorb a growing labor force.
The annual targets projected for the next five years reflect this tradeoff
philosophy.

The Economic Report does not recommend steady progress toward the

goal of reducing unemployment to 4 percent within five years.

Instead it recommends

policies designed to increase unemployment from its current level of 5.8 percent to
an average of 6.2 percent for 1979 and 1980.

It then shows that very rapid reductions

in the rote of unemployment - to 5.4 percent in 1981 and 4.6 percent in 1982 "would be required" to reach the goal of 4.0 percent by 1983.
would seem to be precisely the "stop-and-go"

The policies described

policies that the President assures us

"do not work."
Let me be more specific about why I agree with the President that the
policies he proposes will not work.

I/ Economic Report of the President, p.7 7
7/ Economic Report of the President, p.6
A/ Economic Report of the President, p.79

47-977 0 - 79 - 21

318
The Donger of Recession
There is the very real danger that the "fiscal and monetary restraint"
that he advocates will overshoot its mark and plunge the economy into a major
recession.
recession.'-/

The Administration's

goal is "to moderate growth without producing a

But since 1948 we have had five periods of economic slowdown that led

the nation into major recessions with sustained periods of high unemployment
beginning in 1954, 1958, 1960, 1970 and 1974.

--

We should have learned by now that

it is hard to flirt with recessionary forces without ending up by getting pregnant.
The Administration's program of economic restraint comes at a time of
growing consensus among private economic forecasters that we are already on the
brink of a recession.

At the end of last year the six most prominent forecasting

groups were coming in with an average prediction for 1979 of slower real economic
growth and a substantially higher rate of unemployment -- 6.6 percent as against the
6.2 percent in the Economic Report. 5-

The Congressional Budget Office places

unemployment of 6.2 percent at the bottom of its range of predictions for the end of
1979 - and can see the Administration's policies increasing unemployment to as high
as 7.2 percentk/

4/ Economic Report of the President, p.79
5/ The individual estimates were:
Fomeeat

DntoReoc0
ChaseE.torries
-RISE, Lkti-ity of Mid,1hig
Conf-reree Bnord
Wharton,U. of Po.
BusimonoConeil

Iliingo in
Red G

2.0%
1.1
2.0
.9S
2.6
2.0

Unemploymenot
___

6.6
6.8
6.7
6.5
6.2
6.7

6/ CBO, "An onolysis of the President's Budgetary Proposals for Fiscal Year 1980,"
January, 1979, Tables 2 and 4.

319
In short, the policies of this Administration are skating on very thin ice.
If the ice breaks - if we lapse into a recession - it is the working people of America
who will plunge into the chilly waters.

Indeed, it will be those workers with the least

seniority - blocks, teenagers, women, and low-wage workers -- who will suffer most
from the increase in unemployment.
The Administration is apparently willing to hove them bear that risk.
The Economic Report forecasts that its anti-inflation program of "fiscal and monetary
discipline" will slow down economic growth and increase unemployment to 6.2 percent.
But it goes on to argue that "the inflationary problem can be dealt with most successfully
by persisting with the discipline of anti-inflation policies for an extended period even
if economic growth for a time should fall below the path that is now forecast."

-

I think that the ultimate verdict on this kind of approach was written
two-and-a-holf years ago:
"Now any system of economics is bankrupt if
it sees either value or virtue in unemployment.
We simply cannot check inflation by keeping
people out of work."
Those words were spoken by Jimmy Carter before the 1976 Democratic
Convention.

I think they are as valid today as when they were spoken.

I think that

they - more than any new words I might utter today - condemn the policies now
being advocated by the Administration.
Movinig Away from the Unemployment Goals
The second reason why the Administration policies will not work is that
they will make it for harder to achieve the goals of the Humphrey-Hawkins act.
The enactment of these goals was not some hasty and reckless action of
Congress foisted oa an unwary Administration.

Indeed, they ore far more modest than

what Mr. Carter advocated during the presidential campaign, when he said that a
"reasonable" goal would be "3 percent adult unemployment at the end of four years.'"/

7/ Economic Report of the President, p.78 Emphasis added.
B/ Financial World, September 15, 1976.

N,

320
This would imply a goal of overall unemployment of 4 percent by the year 1980.

The

go9l of reaching 4 percent more slowly -- and the entire framework of the revised
bill introduced in late 1977 -- was negotiated out over many months between the White
House and representatives of Senator Hubert Humphrey and Congressman Gus Hawkins.
From that time on the bill enjoyed the vocal support of the President.
If we are to achieve the goal of 4 percent unemployment by 1983, we
have five years in which to reduce unemployment by roughly 2 percent.

If we begin

now and apply ourselves steadily to the task, it. will mean an average reduction of
about four-tenths of a percent each year.

But if we spend the next two years going

in the wrong direction - increasing unemployment to 6.2 percent in 1979 and 1980
- that will leave us with only three years in which to reduce unemployment by 2.2
percent -- requiring an average reduction of more than seven-tenths of a percent each
year.
Here is what the Economic Report says about the problems of approaching
full employment:
"Structural unemployment represents an unacceptable waste
of economic resources and a severe social problem. But the
problem cannot be dealt with by an expansive aggregate
demand policy without generating further inflationary
pressures .... the task must be addressed with measures ...
aimed directly at those who cannot find jobs even in a
relatively fully employed economy."9/
Unfortunately, the President's budget message proposes cutbacks - not
increases -- in the levels of many of these structural programs.
At the some time that the Administration is planning an increase in
overall unemployment it is proposing (in real terms) a 14 percent cut in outlays for
employment and training and a cut as high as 12 percent in outlays for youth employment
programs.

It is also proposing to eliminate more than 400,000 jobs now provided under

the countercyclical public service employment program -- a cut of some 58 percent IO/

9/ Economic Report of the President, p.77
TLiEstimates by the Office of Management and Budget and the U.S. Conference of
Mayors.

321
The whole logic of the Humphrey-Howkins act is that the government
should gear up now for a vigorous but gradual assault over the next five years on the
problem of structural unemployment.

Instead, the Administration proposes to slip

backwards for the next two years - making the ultimate tosk all the more difficult.
Alternative Targets
The Joint Economic Committee has important new responsibilities under
the Humphrey-Hawkins low.

Section 302 requires the committee to report to the

House and Senate budget committees its own recommendations for short-term and
medium-term economic goals.
two weeks from today.

The deadline for that report is March 15 -- less than

If you agree with us that the employment goals in the

President's report are inadequate -- that they move away from rather than toward the
goals of Humphrey-Hawkins -- then we strongly urge you to propose an alternative set
of goals.
In suggesting alternative goals our most important criterion must be that
we aim to reduce the unemployment rate steadily between now and 1983.

Minimum

goals for the next two years should be that they each carry us one-fifth of the way
to the five-year goal of reducing overall unemployment by two percentage points.
urge this Committee, then, to propose as targets that the unemployment

We

rate be

lowered - from the 6.0 percent average for 1978 -- to no more than 5.6 percent for
1979 and no more than 5.2 percent in 1980.

The 1980 target would thus be a full

percentage point lower than the 6.2 percent proposed in the Economic Report -- and
represent one million fewer Americans out of work.

322
Targets for the subsequent years should also show steady progress -- no
more than 4.8 percent in 1981, 4.4 percent in 1982 and 4.0 percent in 1983.

In fact,

it will be easier to achieve the goals of Humphrey-Hawkins if we begin at a faster
pace than I have described -- to allow room for a slower pace in the later years. But
whatever the precise path, the 1983 employment goal is central to the purposes of
the low -- and it can be met.

We must have steady progress toward meeting that

goal over the next five years.
Policy in the Short Run
For the next two years, clearly we must hove a different mixture of
policies if the economy is to continue to progress toward full employment.
Detailed comments an the 1980 budget proposed by the President are
attached to my statement.

I shall not read that, but request that it be entered in

the record of this Committee's hearings.
For now, I will only point out that the 1980 budget is too restrictive.
In particular, we must not cut back on jobs programs in a time when unemployment
threatens to increase. On the contrary, if we are serious about the goals of HumphreyHawkins we need an immediate expansion of job programs that are targeted on those
workers with the highest rates of unemployment -- including minorities, teenagers, and
female heads of households - and on those areas with the highest rates - including
our older industrial cities.

323
In addition, the present policy of monetary contraction must be reversed
to help maintain demand for housing and business investment.

From April 1975, to

September 1978, the money stock (M
2) grew at an annual rote of 10 percent.

But

since September money stock has been growing at an annual rote of less than 3V2
percent.

This is for below what is necessary over the next few years to accommodate

the inflation already built into the economy and to permit real growth of production
and employment.

It is true that -- as in many previous times of high interest rates

- money has been turning over faster than it was early lost year.

But this growth

in the velocity of money is probably not sustainable.
The conservative economist Milton Friedman has recently warned that
maintaining

the present

restrictive monetary policy would eventually plunge the

American economy into a recession! I/

I do not propose to be the first president of

the UAW to be less concerned about the dangers of recession than Milton Friedman.
But going beyond the short-term dangers of recession, a faster rate of monetary
expansion is needed to avoid choking off investments to renew our stock of housing
and to stimulate productivity growth. The Economic Report repeatedly attributes much
of our current inflation to an alleged slow growth of productivity, which it partially
blames on a slowdown of business investment in recent years.

A significant increase

in the present growth rate of the money supply will be required for the banks to be
able to finance continued growth of productive investment.
Chairman Miller of the Federal

Reserve has lowered his target for

monetary growth (again, M2 ) from a previous range of 6V2to 9 percent to a new range
of 5 to 8 percent.

While we are concerned this may be too low a target, a shift to

a more expansionary monetary policy is needed even to get into that lowered range.
We urge that the Federal Reserve Board begin that shift immediately.
I/ Newsweek, February 19, 1979

324
New Tools to Reach Full Employmet
The Economic Report is frankly pessimistic that the notion can reach the
employment goals of Humphrey-Hawkins and maintain reasonable price stability at the
same time.

That pessimism will be self-fulfilling if we maintain a business-as-usual

approach to the employment goals of the bill and if we continue to stress oggregative
solutions to problems that ore structural in origin.
What I suggest today is that we adopt a positive, "can-do" attitude toward
the employment goals - and that we begin to think together of the new policy tools
that must be created in

the coming months if those goals ore to be realized.

1. A Planning Process for Full Employment
The Federal government must create an active process of planning for
full employment, including a command center located in the Executive Office of the
President. Such a center would monitor national and regional job developments, alert
government agencies - including the Federal Reserve System - as to the impact of
their actions on jobs, and be a source of ideas for new programs to reduce unemployment
in particular parts of the economy.
It could also be charged

with other important

tasks: expanding the

statistical basis for employment planning, developing comprehensive projections of labor
supply and demand, providing systematic input into state educational planning, and
fostering more
unemployment.

detailed

surveys

of the causes

and consequences

of individual

325
An important port of the process will be to consider major economic
sectors - such as housing, business investment, motor vehicles, and other consumer
durobles - which are subject to large employment fluctuations.

It is likely that

development of policies targeted toward those sectors, would help achieve balanced
growth of the total economy.
2. Ban on Interstate Competition for New Business
In order to reduce unemployment nationwide we have got to address the
problem of "runaway shops" - manufacturing operations that are shifted from one part
of the country to another, leaving behind workers without jobs and communities without
tax bases.

One part of that problem is the growing array of special subsidies and

special tax cuts that states and local governments offer to new business.
We in the UAW have a simple name for this practice among the states:
we call it "economic cannibalism".

If this country is serious about moving toward full

employment, it cannot let a patchwork of state and local incentive programs lure jobs
away from the workers who have held them for many years.
Even when companies do not relocate, they use that interstate competition
as a threat to extract new concessions from their home communities.

They even pit

one community against another within the same state, and efforts by state government
to control that ore undercut by the competition from other states.
We propose that Congress prevent the states or localities from imposing
one level of taxes - or providing one level of services - for existing businesses, but
providing much more favorable treatment for new or expanded businesses.

States use

other objectionable forms of competition - such as inadequate workers' compensation
and unemployment insurance programs, and undercutting workers' collective bargaining
ability. Better national standards are needed in those areas also.

326
Many states perceive that they have a strong vested interest in incentive
programs for business expansion.

Unfortunately, in the current climate of "dog eat

dog", they do have such a stake.

We ask them to look beyond the present climate

to a time in which there is no need for one state to compete with artificial incentives
because no other state is offering such incentives.

When that time comes every worker

in America will enjoy greater job security - and we will be that much closer to our
goal of full employment.
3. Economic Dislocation
There are of course, other causes of economic dislocation. The potential
unemployment should be avoided when possible, otherwise its impacts must be alleviated.
All across the country there are communities that stand under the shadow
of sudden and substantial job loss of the sort recently experienced in Youngstown,
Ohio.

All segments of those communities would welcome the creation of a standby

program that might rescue their economic future if they should be suddenly struck by
the closing of a major plant, office or mine.

Such a program should include standby

public works and standby federal procurement programs designed to meet national needs
as well as to provide jobs.
circumstances.

It might include temporary federal subsidies under some

It should also include the availability of investment funds to help

create a new and more permanent economic base for a stricken community.
We need a number of other steps to minimize economic dislocation and
its impact on workers and their families.

Plants should be required to give advance

notice of a planned closing, with time allowed for negotiation with representatives of
the workers and the community.

If a plant does eventually close, workers should be

provided with substantial aid in seeking and in being trained for new employment and
in resettling in a new community.

Employers should be required to guarantee transfer

rights within a corporation and to cover the worker's reasonable expenses of relocating
in a new community.

327
4. Public Investrent
As we consider how to create a full employment economy, we should go
beyond the notion that the only acceptable public job programs are ones sponsored by
state and local governments. Many of our national needs will only be addressed through
projects defined and conducted by the federal government.

The Tennessee Valley

Authority served to provide jobs while meeting broad regional needs during the 1930s.
Many of today's national needs -- in such fields as transportation and energy - may
best be addressed through public investments.

There are new energy sources to be

explored, and there are old railroad beds to be developed - and there is no reason
why these activities should be monopolized by the private sector. A program of public
investments - at the times and places where jobs are most needed -- can be a useful
tool in our movement toward full employment.
5. Tarweted Investment Incentives
To adequately address the problem of localized unemployment we must
adopt new ways of directing private investment to areas of chronic joblessness.
The existing investment tax credit is too often used to help finance the
movement of jobs out of a community with high unemployment and into areas with
low unemployment, or in other ways to undercut the effort to achieve full employment.
It should be repealed.
If Congress feels that some tax incentive for investment is needed, then
a targeted investment tax credit would be better than the present approach. Investment
in areas of chronically high unemployment should be one of the eligibility conditions
for that credit; such investments could include structures as well as equipment installed
in those areas.

328
A targeted credit would be more efficient; it would produce more desirable
investment for each dollar of credit. Even if only part of the general tax credit were
transformed into o substantially more generous targeted credit, there could be less tax
expenditures, but greater incentive to draw private investment back to older industrial
cities and depressed rural areas.
The Administration's proposal for a National Development Bank is a useful
way to direct investment to economically depressed areas.

The budget anticipates

spending authority at about $2.6 billion per year, between 1981 and 1984, for that
Bank.
These, and other government actions, to more specifically direct the
pattern of private investment would be preferable to the present efforts that rely on
interest rates, generalized tax incentives, and hopes for satisfactory response from
business.
6. Full Employment Comrnmunities
As

we

move

toward

a

nationwide

effort

unemployment, we can still learn from experimentation.

to

achieve

4

percent

We would urge that the

Congress move quickly to establish pilot programs in eight or ten communities around
the country in which a variety of tools would be used to achieve full employment for
the existing residents. These "full employment communities" should include a mixture
of urban, suburban and rural areas.

The employment programs established should be

primarily federally funded but include a mixture of state, local and federal operation
to insure that they cover a wide range of projects and tasks.

Such experimentation

could, for example, evaluate partial wage subsidies as a means of easing the transition
of workers from public service employment to the private sector.

329
7. Permanent Program of Countercyclical Aid
With the lapsing of authority and funding for the program of countercyclical
budgetary aid to localities, there will be significant gaps in our aid to distressed
communities.
Instead, we should be aiming to create a permanent system of aid to
areas of high unemployment to include both budgetary assistance and public service
employment.

At a time of general prosperity such a system would primarily deal with

areas of structural unemployment and meet priority needs neglected by the private
sector. But with a general economic downturn, the same system would be automatically
triggered to provide jobs and budgetary relief to those areas hardest hit by recession.
Only by operating both jobs and budgetary relief simultaneously can we avoid the sort
of conflicts that arose during the darkest days of 1975 and 1976.

Mayors wanted to

use federal jobs money to retain police who would otherwise be laid off, but federal
agencies insisted that the funds be used to create new jobs.
formally that both needs mutt be met during a recession.

It is time to recognize
We need to retain vital

public employees as well as to absorb new employees laid off by the private sector.
Only the federal government can provide the resources to meet those needs in areas
of high unemployment.
We do not think that the President's proposals - which will slash the
level of budgetary assistance and target it on a very limited number of cities-2/ -will be adequate to meet the immediate and standby needs of local governments.

I2/ The countercyclical program provided $1.3 billion to local and state governments
in FY 1978. By contrast, the Administration proposal would be for $0.25 billion
in FY 1979 and $0.15 billion in FY 1980.

330
Conclwion: For many years the UAW has been active in the struggle to
achieve full employment in America.

We felt we had achieved a major victory with

the passage of Humphrey-Hawkins, but today we are less sure.

We had hoped that by

today we would all be marching together toward the goal of 4 percent unemployment
within five years.

Instead, we are confronted with an Economic Report that begins

by calling for a hasty retreat over the next two years and concludes by offering
excuses for ultimate defeat.

As we read the words of the Report, we begin to feel

like the ancient navigators who set sail in search of the horizon and found it to be
an ever-receding goal -- always visible, but somehow always out of reach.
When last year and the year before our members and our allies marched
and rallied for the passage of Humphrey-Hawkins, we took the goal of full employment
very seriously. We thought the Congress took it seriously, and we thought the President
took it seriously. Today, we must look to you in the Congress to redeem our confidence.
The goal of reducing unemployment to 4 percent can be met -- and it
should be met.

It cannot be met through conventional policies and conventional

attitudes, but only through new exertions of intellect and of will.
This is our challenge today.

By thinking and acting optomisticolly and

creatively, we can yet achieve full employment and bring a new definition of security
and prosperity into every home in America.

opeiu494

331
UAW Comments on FY 1980 Budget Proposal
Febuory 28, 1979

Last year, the UAW told Congress that the FY 1979 budget went in the
right direction, but it did not go for enough.

After examining the budget released

lost month, we have reached the apposite conclusion: the policies in the 1980 budget
would take us too far in the wrong direction.
We have been also led to remember the events of some years back.

In

early 1975, the UAW estimated that a "bore minimum" program to fight recession and
combat unemployment would take a deficit $15 billion higher than what the Ford
Administration hod requested.

At the end of that year, a deficit of that level hod

actually developed, not as a result of the more stimulative policies we urged, but as
a result of lower revenues, higher public assistance payments, and other sequels to the
depressed economy.
Congress must not allow that to happen again with this year's budget.
The Administration's budget, if enacted, will end up showing a deficit almost as large
as what it would take to bring it up to a current policy level right from the beginning.
But it will do so at a cost of lost jobs, human misery, and lost income.

In economics,

as in health care, the right policy is prevention rather than cure.
The UAW cannot support this year's budget.

Its statement of priorities

runs contrary to our concept of good, effective, and fair government on several counts:
•

equity, as it plans a departure from the reformist social policies first devised and
implemented in the 1960s;

*

sound economics, as its much-vaunted austerity would not defeat inflation but
would raise unemployment;

*

meeting our national needs, as it advocates a substantial addition to a military
budget which is already needlessly high.

332'
We urge Congress

to set aside those proposals that would reduce our

notion's commitment to human resources and social programs below current policy
level, and to finance the first installment of several long-overdue initiatives out of
the excesses in the defense budget.
1. The 1980 Budget is Bad Economics
The Administration

has pronounced inflation to be America's foremost

enemy - a threat to society's welfare, a cancer taking the heaviest toll from the
poor and from those with low or fixed incomes.
Our union recognizes that inflation is a problem.

We worry about it as

we watch many workers, among them some of our own members, suffering disproportionately from the rapid rise in prices; as our retirees bitterly complain to us that
their hard-won pensions are eroding steadily.

Their problem must be met, but not

with a cure that is much more painful than the disease, a cure that actually inflicts
a "double whammy" on the people we are most trying to protect.
We should study past experience, with respect to inflation and the actions
used to combat it, in order to better plan the future.
From a historical perspective, the recent average rate of inflation - both
at wholesale and at retail - has been less than during previous inflationary periods
starting in 1810. During the course of this century, there have been three inflationary
bouts; the current one is the mildest.

333
U. S. Inflation Rates During Periods of Inflation, 1810-1978*
Period

Average Annual Percentage Rate of Price
Consumer Prices
Wholesole Prices

1810-1814
1861-1865
1915-1920
1940-1948
1965-1978
*

7.6%
14.2
14.6
7.0
5.8

8.6%
20.0
17.3
9.7
6.1

The interim periods show falling prices or prices growing at annual rates of under
2 percent.

SOURCE:

Gardner Ackley, "Recent U.S. Inflation in Perspective". Paper presented
at The 26th Annual Economic Outlook Conference, University of Michigan,
November 16-17, 1978. Extracted from Table 1.
If we take a shorter-run approach, i.e., the post-World War 11 period,

comparative data (see chart below) show that the U.S. price record since 1955 is
superior to that of each of the other major industrialized countries except Germany.
(In recent years, this exception is mainly due to the less expansive policies that
Germany has promoted since 1974.)

47-977 0 - 79 - 22

334
Every poll indicates that the American people are fed up with inflation.
We suspect that

what most

working people are

disappointment with their real incomes. And rightly so:

expressing

to the pollsters is

in the last five years, average

real weekly earnings (of nonfarm production or nonsupervisory workers) have dropped
almost five percent.

But this disappointment is scarcely a mandate to throttle the

economy -which will inevitably require further sacrifices of real income.
The Administration has attempted to fend off criticism of its restrictive
fiscal and monetary stance by pointing to its guidelines policy. Indeed, the wage and
price standards were designed to cool the rate of inflation without relying exclusively
on slowing the economy.

When they were first established, we expressed our support

and hope for their success in spite of many reservations about their fairness, equity,
and administrative shortfalls.
Four months have gone by, and time is running out on the guidelines.
Two items give a clue: On the one hand, producer prices showed an across-the-board
annualized increase of 11.6 percent from October to January, which accelerated to
15.6 percent from December to January.

On the other hand, the Wall Street Journal

(2/15/79) reported that one survey of 634 big companies found that 73 percent have
cut budgets for salary increases to 7.1 percent instead of the 8.5 percent previously
planned. Thus, we are on a collision course. Even chief inflation adviser Kahn recently
wondered "how long can we expect labor to come in with 7 percent when prices are
rising at a faster rate." And his deputy John N. Gentry expressed "qualms of conscience"
to try to hold unions to the 7 percent wage standard in the last half of 1979 if food
prices soar in the first half.
The problem goes beyond a question of fairness.

If wages and prices

follow a divergent path long enough, we may be facing an economic downswing as a
consequence of the biased application of the guidelines.

335
The proposed budget includes funds for the Real Wage Insurance (RWI)
program, which the President has accurately described as an essential aspect of the
price-wage guidelines. We have expressed our agreement and support of this program,
along with a detail of our reservations about its design and implementation, to the
House Wayne and Means Committee earlier in the session.
It should be emphasized that one of our criticisms of RWI rests on the
lock of proposed funding beyond FY 1980. That is inconsistent with the Administration's
repeated characterizations of the guidelines as a long term program; just recently
CWPS stated that work is underway on guidelines for 1980.

We believe that RWI must

be provided for as long as guidelines restrain wages.
The Federal Deficit
We strongly object to the Administration's repeated reference to the
government deficit as the cause - or fuel - of inflation.

It is not good economics

and it helps perpetuate a myth among the public.
To begin with, there is nothing intrinsically inflationary in the impact of
a government deficit over and above its effects on aggregate demand.

A recent

Brookings study-, using a simple statistical model on 1954-1977 data, tests and rejects
the hypothesis that there is a direct causal connection between budget deficits and
inflation.

The view that the present inflation is caused by deficits or that cutting

the deficit would help eliminate inflation without causing recession should thus be put
to rest.
recession),

Historically, as shown in the chart below (where the shaded bars represent
most deficits

have come

from

the operation of

built-in stabilizers

(unemployment compensation, public assistance, etc.) during periods of underemployment,
or during periods of war.

*

George L. Perry, "Slowing the Wage-Price Spiral: The Macroeconomic View" in
Papers on Economic Activity, 1978, 2.

336
AuoglA I

lAp,IIFPb
I

PT

(ONIN.I

IN. IIMaI

PT

PT

P~

Annual ale. billion dollars (c-rrefli
PddedalGuerle,,

ph.Sordek

IIAD

fV

19S

506 57

50

59

60

61

62

63

6a

05

66

67

a0

69

70

71

72

73

76

75

76

77

79 1

071

SOURCE
Boslns ConCOtio01Go.
U S. Depaltmenlof Commerce
December
1978

Rather than an attempt to divert additional resources from private to
public use, the current deficit is still, to a large extent, the result of the 1974-75
recession

and of the

programs

undertaken

consequences and stimulate the recovery.

by the government

to alleviate

its

Current overall rates of utilization of labor

and productive capacity do not suggest "overheating

which a somewhat larger deficit

would exacerbate.
Second, no justification is given for picking a deficit limit of $30 billion.
In fact, the Administfation's own OMB Associate Director was quoted as estimating
that, were the deficit $15 billion higher, only 0.2 percentage points might be added
to the inflation rate.*

The focus on a $30 billion deficit appears to be a misguided

public relations exercise on the port of the Administration. It must not distract the
attention of Congress from the much more meaningful task of setting adequate figures
for overall federal spending and for the different budget functions.

In a 2.5 trillion

dollar economy, unforeseeable domestic and international events (bad weather, OPEC
pricing, the Iranian conflict) con have an impact on government finances which could
easily translate into several billion dollars worth of government deficit.

*

2

Wall Street Journal, 12/14/78, p.

337
Third, as previously noted Germany is the only large industrial nation
which has sustained a lower inflation rate than ours; but its government deficit as a
percent of gross national product is larger than the U.S.
In fact, the U.S. deficit has been steadily dropping.

As a proportion of

GNP it is nowwonly 1.1 percent; if we remove the effects of fluctuations in the
economy, and look at the high employment concepts, it has come very close to zero:
Surplus or Deficit (-) as a Percent of GNP
Calendar Year
or Quarter
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978: 1
II
III
IV

Actual
-0.5%
-0.8
-4.6
-3.2
-2.5
-2.6
-1.1
-1.1
n.a.

High-employment
-0.6%
0.2
-1.8
-1.3
-1.3
-1.4
-0.4
-0.4
-0.2

n.a. - not available
SOURCE: Economic Report of the President, January 1979, table 10, p. 46.
The President is publicly putting too much stock on the size of the deficit,
and too little on the relationship of the deficit to the notion's productive capacity.
There is a danger that this will boomerang; undue emphasis on the budget deficit is
only buttressing the proponents of a balanced budget amendment, the latest and most
far-reaching effort of the conservative groups to turn back the clock 50 years on
issues of welfare, government intervention and regulation, society's responsibility to
its needy members, and countercyclical economic policies.

338
The Administration's approach to the deficit is also seriously questionable
on the grounds that, as a target, it is only approached from the side of the federal
spending programs.

No effort is afoot to reduce the vast amount of dollars given

away as tax expenditures.
Yet, tax expenditures are found in all the budget categories into which
direct spending programs are divided; indeed, there are many items of tax expenditures
which should be cut before some of the proposed cuts in spending programs are made.
Instead, they are the first to be funded - automaticolly.

A recent study* examined

several of the proposed reductions in the budget along with the pertinent tax expenditure
categories, and found some glaring inequities.

For example:

the special milk and lunch program for school children comes under OMB's knife

•

for a proposed $358 million cut - but the over $2 billion subsidy for the well off
in lavish meals and martini

lunches on expense accounts remains untouched;

the $255 survivor's benefit in the Social Security Act would be eliminated at a

•

"savings" of $206 million - but the exemption of tax on the gains in property
transferred at death will continue at a cost of almost $10 billion (most of it
accruing to the top one percent of families);
*

low- and middle-income housing programs are being slashed by 17 percent -- but
tax preferences for real estate construction to the tune of $1.3 billion hove been
spared.

Budget Receipts
The way to eliminate this defective and inequitable allocation of austerity
measures - and of revenue dollars generally - is by carrying out a thorough reform
of the tax code which would eliminate all of the unwarranted privileges that are now
part of the law.

None of this is proposed in the FY 1980 budget.

T Statement by Senator Edward M. Kennedy released January 14, 1979.

339
The U.AW has long stood for justice in taxation. Congress made a mockery
of the concept in its last session by enacting a bill that was grossly tilted to benefit
the rich and business. We do not urge Congress to work for tax reform in this session;
the political realities dictate otherwise.

But in dividing up the pie of government

spending, it should be remembered which groups got the biggest piece already.
The Ecoromnic Outlook
The Administration's budgetary policies will have little effect on inflation.
However, along with the crusade of tight credit and slower growth of the money supply
on which the Federal Reserve has embarked, these policies will have a recessionary
impact on the economy.
That much is clear from a comparison between the pre-November economic
forecast of CBO and its post-FY

1980 budget projections for the current

year:

CBO Projections, 1978-1979
July 1978
Jaonuary 1979
GNP (1972 dollars, percent change,
4th quarter to 4th quarter)

2.7 to 4.2

-0.1 to 1.9

Inflation (percent change in the GNP
implicit price deflator, 4th quarter
to 4th quarter)

6.2 to 7.2

7.0 to 9.0

Unemployment rate (end of period,
percent)

5.2 to 6.0

6.2 to 7.2

SOURCE:

"An Analysis of the President's Budgetary Proposals for Fiscal Year 1980,"
Congressional Budget Office, January 1979, Tables 2 and 4; "Inflation and
Growth: The Economic Policy Dilemma," Congressional Budget Office, July
1978, p. xii.

340
The table distinctly shows the slowdown imported to the economy by these relatively
recent policy measures; note the difference in real growth and in the unemployment
rates.

Most private economists and econometric models agree with CBO:

they now

forecast very small or negative growth for late 1979 and/or 1980, and correspondingly
higher rates of unemployment.
Predictably, the Administration denies the possibility of recession in its
own forecast for 1979 and 1980, which is the most optimistic in town - although it
still expects a rise in the unemployment rate to 6.2 percent by the end of the year,
up from 5.8 percent in late 1978.
Even a recession will not be successful in bringing down inflation.

The

same Brookings study mentioned earlier shows that, in a realistic sense, there is no
unemployment-inflation trade-off. For every extra percentage point of unemployment,
it estimates that the inflation rate would be only 0.3 percentage points lower after
one year.

The cost would be astronomical: aver I million jobs, and some $60 billion

in real production - or about $280 per capita - each year.

What about the impact

of that extra 0.3 percentage point of inflation? It would correspond to about $6 billion
in higher prices, which would be transferred mostly from one group of Americans to
another - admittedly in sometimes cruel and arbitrary ways.

Even if all of it would

go abroad (e.g., in larger payments for oil to OPEC countries), the per capita loss
would come at most to only one-tenth of what we would forego under the alternative
of higher unemployment.
A recession,

moreover, would

quickly boost

the deficit; the

extra

percentage point in the unemployment rate would take approximately $20 billion from
the federal coffers (about $5 billion in unemployment compensation, Medicaid, food
stamps, etc., plus $15 billion in lost revenues).
the finances of state governments as well.

There would be a negative impact on

341
As economic statistics are starting to suggest, the talk of recession may
soon leave the realm of speculation for the realm of hard facts.

Paul Samuelson's

words appropriately describe the process:
"Mr. Carter's decision to fight inflation and defend the dollar
has tipped the betting odds toward an outright recession. So,
when and if the next recession comes, you will read lettered
on its bottom: 'Made in Washington."'*
11. The FY 1980 Budget is Bod Social Policy
The composition of budget outlays shows President Carter going bock on
many of the promises made on the campaign trail.
Item:
"We should make major investments in people and not in
buildings and weapons. The poor, the aged, the weak, the
afflicted must be treated with respect and compassion and
with love." (Acceptance Speech for Democratic Presidential
Nomination, July 15,-1976, Congressional Quarterly, July 17,
1976.)
Simple justice dictates that people receive from the government what
government promised.

The proposals to cut some of the benefits now provided under

the Social Security Act are not just - neither are they a sign of respect or compassion.
Other cuts requested in the budget would decrease the allotment of human resources
programs below their current policy level.
Item:
"Our present welfare system robs the taxpayers who support
it, discourages the people who administer it, and sometimes
degrades the people who really do need help.
It is an
extraordinarily complex and difficult problem, even more so
than I had expected.
F1innci

Times World Business Weekly, 1/8/79.

To

342
'Two weeks ago I outlined the principles that must underlie
the reform of the system, and we will have legislative
proposals ready by the end of this summer." (Address to
the 25th UAW Constitutional Convention, May 17, 1977.)
Lost year, President Carter envisaged an allocation of $1.4 billion in FY
1980 for his "Better Jobs and Income" program, with the expectation that in FY 1981
the requests would increase to $14.4 billion and to $38.8 billion the year after that.
This year, he intends to submit a reform package for which he is allowing nothing in
FY 1980, $1.5 billion in FY 1981, and $5.5 billion in FY 1982.

At the some time,

the President is proposing several legislative changes in the AFDC program which
would cut these outlays substantially.
Itern:
Q: "During the campaign, you spoke of cutting the defense budget $5-7 billion.
Will you be able to meet that commitment?
A: "If I don't, I will be very disappointed that (sic) the performance of the
Secretary of Defense and the deputy secretary of defense. Yes, we'll start
immediately with efficiencies and economies in the Defense Department,
relating to organizational structure, long-range planning, predictable kinds of
purchases for rapid delivery once the placements of orders have been mode.
We'll bring up to date, I hope, the repair and maintenance of our defense
capabilities, and we'll be working very hard to cut down the unnecessary
personnel assignments. The cumulative total, I think, of those and other
changes will result in on adequate amount of savings to meet my commitment
News Conference, December 21, 1976, Congressional Quarterly, December 25,
1976.
The record speaks otherwise: from FY 1978 to FY 1980, the requested
increase in defense comes to $20.2 billion, or virtually a 20 percent increase.
No dramatic changes have been proposed
outlays.

in the allocation of budget

However, there is a perceptible trend towards a bigger share for defense

since FY 1976.
This is clearly shown in the following chart, where the bars represent the
real increase in overall budget outlays and in national defense for the fiscal periods
1976-1980, 1978-1980, and 1979-1980.

3423

By contrast, the 'controllable" portion of the outlays requested for human
resources programs - which benefit not only the poor but the middle-income groups
as well - would decline, in constant dollars by almost 15 percent from the FY 1979
estimate.

This is equivalent to $5.3 billion in FY 1980 budget dollars, and would put

the controllable spending in human resources at the lowest proportion of total outlays
in the last three years.

The total allocation for human resources would go up 2.3

percent in real terms from FY 1979 to FY 1980, but that is due to the "relatively
uncontrollable" payments to individuals.
Human Resources - Controllable and Relatively Uncontrollable Outlays
Fiscal Years 1978 - 1980
Actual
TOYW

Estimate
1919

___

( bilflns
Human Resources Total
Minus: Payments to individuals
(relatively uncontrollable)

$253.3

$259.0

$283.2

203.8

223.1

250.5

Total controllable outlays

$ 31.5

$ 35.9

$ 32.7

Total budget outlays

$450.8

$493.4

$531.6

7.0%

7.3%

6.2%

Controllable as percent
of total outlays
SOURCE:

-

The Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1980, table on
p. 03, Taole 1i4 p. 3WJ, table I/ (p. 568).

344
The conclusion from this brief analysis is that President Carter is reducing
the portion of the budget where he can dictote his own poliey.

At the some time,

he is proposing cutbacks in the programs which are the legacy from previous government
action (in the form of relatively uncontrollable outlays).
Both types of actions are reflected in the difference of $12.5 billion
between current service budget outlays and the Administration's request.
amount, over half of the decline is scheduled in human

Of this

resources (notably CETA,

education, and Social Security) and the balance in the rest of the non-defense budget
(notably natural resource and environment programs, commerce and housing credit, and
anti-recession fiscal assistance).
During the "lean" years of the Nixon-Ford Administration the UAW looked
forward to a time when uplifting the poor and the less privileged would once again
become an opportunity for the President to exercise leadership, rather than to be
dragged along.

So we have been rightly shocked and dismayed to see the President

become the spokesman of the groups which want to turn America away from the
progressive programs forged by previous Democratic administrations on the pretense
that America can no longer afford them.
Although the Administration should (and probably does) know better, this
attitude rests on misperceptions of what actually happened during the last decade.
For example, the view that the set of programs to aid the poor has increased enormously
- along with the views that federal expenditures have risen sharply and that the
budget is out of control - is contradicted by the facts.
The Administration has tried hard to dispel the notion that the poor are
being hurt by the cuts in the FY 1980 budget.

Yet our calculations, based on OMB's

own listing, show that in real terms the programs for low income people remained at
a standstill between FY 1978 and FY 1979, and are proposed to be cut by almost I
percent in FY 1980.

345
1.

The Budget By Function
National Defense
The Department of Defense is one agency in Washington which was spored

the sharp budget-cutting knife mercilessly wielded at HEW, DOL, and HUD.

The

Administration proposes a 1.4 percent real increase in budget authority and a 3.1
percent real increase in budget outlays, by far the most generous increase of federal
funds for FY 1980. These figures are in fact larger when the supplemental appropriations
for FY 1979 are subtracted (see table below).
The overall real increases in the defense budget mask the much steeper
gains in procurement and research and development:
Proposed Chorne for FY 1979 to FY 1980

Overall Defense Budget
Procurement
Research and Development

Budget Authority
Nominal
Real

Budget Outlays
Nominal
Real

10.2%
17.1
10.5

10.6%
14.9
13.8

3.3%
9.9
3.6

3.8%
7.8
6.8

NOTE:

Budget authority and budget outlays for FY 1979 are current service estimates.
These are below Administration estimates by $2.4 billion (supplemental
appropriation) in authority and $0.8 billion (supplemental appropriation) in
outlays.
SOURCE: Special Analysis, Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year
_0, tables A-13 and A-14.
That is portly because, while the overall defense budget has a target of 3 percent
real growth, substantial subcategories are scheduled for a real decrease: for example,
Deportment of Defense personnel pay is restricted to the nominal 5.5 percent increase
dictated by the guidelines for federal employees.

346
By focusing on defense activities as a major priority, the Administration
is once again disregarding the views of many security experts who, in study after
study, have concluded that recent and proposed levels of military spending have far
Convinced by those studies, lost year

exceeded the real security needs of our notion.

the UAW urged Congress to transfer at least $5 billion out of the proposed defense
authority and into areas of basic human needs.

We remain convinced that at least

.that much could be squeezed out of the defense budget, without reducing our security.
At the some time, there are many unfulfilled needs in our society - welfare reform,
urban aid, and child core to name a few -- where government spending could and
should make a difference.
In implementing any transfers of funds, sufficient attention should be paid
to the problem which will be faced by employees adversely affected, and by the
communities in which affected facilities are located.
attention should be forthcoming in any event.
eliminate the problems

Indeed, it is our view that such

Even increased military outlays do not

of dislocated workers:

programs are continuously being

terminated, cancelled or cut back at the some time that the overall level of military
spending is on the upswing.
Elsewhere the UAW has developed extensive rationale for the need for
conversion programs and outlined the form they should take.

If conversion is found

not to be feasible, adjustment assistance must be provided to displaced workers and
affected communities as a backstop measure.

This assistance must encompass cash

payments, fringe benefit continuation, and retraining and relocation allowances in the
case of affected workers, and special payments in lieu of tax revenues lost in the
case of communities.

347
Our primary objection is to excessive military output, but even those
expenditures for procurement and research and development (R&D) which may be
necessary result in shortages of human and material resources needed to move forward
in civilian areas.

Thus too few scientists, skilled workers, and others with critical

talents are available to attack unsolved problems in areas such as energy, health,
transportation, etc.

In addition, there is evidence that some of the slowdown in

productivity increase is due to the drain imposed by military priorities.
Therefore, the budget should provide adequate funds to draw additional
resources into non-military R&D, and also to train and upgrade the skills of additional
workers, in order to avoid these shortages.
For example, the impact of stepped up spending on defense R&D and
military procurement will put demands on sectors of the labor market which have
already started to tighten up:
Unemployment Rate
January
Pre-recession
1979
Lowr, 1973
All Workers
Professional and Technical
Managers and Administrators

4.6%
1.9
1.3

5.8%
2.5
2.0

Percentage
Point
Difference
+1.2
+0.6
+0.7

At the some time, employment and training funds are being cut in real terms.
there should be more effort in that area.

Instead

There are surplus workers available who

could be put to work on important projects; with training, many of them could handle
the more skilled jobs that otherwise will remain unfilled.
Unemployment Rate
January
Pre-recession
Low, 1973
1979
Operatives, except transport
Transport equipment operatives
Nonfarm laborers

5.8%
3.1
8.2

7.6%
4.9
9.4

Percentage
Point
Difference
+1.8
+1.8
+1.2

348
- 18 Finally, it is particularly incongruous that this Administration, whose
overriding concern is inflation, chooses to propose such substantial increases in military
spending, the most inherently inflationary type of federal autlay.
We urge Congress to prune the President's excessive request for military
spending.
Social Security
From its inception over 44 years ago, the Social Security system has been
based upon a trust between the American people and their government.

In return for

contributions to the system, workers and their families are promised future protection
against the risks of income loss due to retirement, disability or death.
The Carter Administration's proposed budget for FY 1980 includes several
Although small in the

cost-benefit reduction recommendations for Social Security.

context of the $116.6 billion outlays budgeted for FY 1980, the $600 million cutbacks
would

surely

impact significantly upon the finances of

the affected households.

Furthermore, that is just the initial impact; the results would be much greater in the
future.
Our immediate concern is about "savings" that the President wants to
squeeze out of the disability insurance benefits program.

First, benefits would be

limited to 80 percent of averaged indexed monthly earnings.

Second, benefits for

younger workers would be reduced by counting against them the low earnings most
workers have when they enter the work force.

349
Neither of these changes are justified.

Both have arisen out of the

Administration's concern over the increased number of beneficiaries of disability
benefits, the substantial increased cost of the program, and the projections of further
continued increases. There ore several reasons to believe these projections ore unduly
pessimistic. The incidence rates of newly eligible disabled workers hove declined since
1975, in sharp contrast to the trend established between 1970 and 1975 on which the
high cost estimates are based.

Furthermore, the 1977 amendments cut future benefits

5 percent across the board and the new benefit formula already weighs each year's
earnings more equitably.
The disability insurance benefit program is too important to America's
workers to consider changes as a reaction to an assumed crisis.
The Administration's proposed budget also recommends eight other benefit
reductions; among those are:
*

The phase out of post-secondary student benefits that would affect approximately
800,000 students over the age of 18 who are now eligible to continue to receive
benefits under Social Security until age 22 if they are full time students.

The

Administration's suggestion that it is more appropriate for the surviving children
of deceased workers to apply for education grants and loans provided by HEW is
not relevant to the concept of Social Security as an insurance program.
*

The removal of the automatic lump sum death benefit from the Social Security
program.

Even though a modest benefit, it still helps families at a time of large

expenses.

Its replacement by a welfare benefit under the Supplemental Security

Income Program is unacceptable.
*

Stopping benefits of parents who have a child in their care age 16 or older.

The

Administration points to the increased proportion of employed widows with children.
However, the present Social Security law already includes a control on the benefits
received by working parents through the earnings limitation provisions.

47-977 0 - 79 - 23

350
These, and the rest of the Administration's proposal, would undermine the
confidence the American people have in the long-term continuation of the program,
and thus the basis for the Social Security system itself.
We agree that the programs that make up the system should be examined
carefully and continuously; that indeed is the task of the Social Security Advisory
Council which the law mandates to meet every four years to review the operation of
the programs and to develop recommendations.

The current report of the Advisory

Council on Social Security is scheduled to be published in October.

Furthermore,

Congress recently established a Commission on Social Security whose work is just now
beginning.
The Administration
misplaced budgetary concerns.

is bypassing these mechanisms in the interest of

The UAW urges Congress to reject these as the basis

for reducing earned protections under Social Security.
Health Care
The proposed health budget indicates a lack of commitment to improve
health care services.

It effectively reduces the research budget of the National

Institutes of Health by 8 percent.

It would eliminate capitotion payments to medical,

nursing and other health professions schools.

It would seriously reduce training funds

and the availability of loon and scholarship funds. It would impair the development of
young researchers - the real hopes for future medical and scientific breakthroughs.
The proposed budget undermines the health core system because it strikes
at research, education and training. We need to provide medical services to those who
need them today.

But it is shortsighted to slow the development of new knowledge;

to stem the process of developing new treatments; to force schools to cut bock training
of our doctors, nurses and scientists of the future.

Together, these programs of

research, education and training provide a basis for our health care system that must
be strengthened - not undermined.

351
Over 34 separate health programs received absolute cuts; and over 24
additional programs are funded well below the current policy level. The dollars involved
are relatively small, especially in relation to the problems which would result..
Employment and Troininq
The budget proposals for this function are clearly inadequate when coupled
with the Administration's forecast of 6.2 percent unemployment for FY 1980.

Here

are some of the highlights:
*

by OMB's estimate, request for outlays in FY 1980 is 8 percent - 14 percent in
real terms - below the current service estimate.

This amounts to $1.3 billion.

By CBO's estimate, which assumes a higher unemployment rate and thus a higher
level of eligibility, the Administration's proposal is $3.1 billion, or 43 percent,
below current policy levels.
*

the countercyclical public service employment program is phased down by about
302,000 jobs from the 1978 level of 725,000 (U.S. Conference of Mayors' estimate).

*

the "targeted" public service employment program remains at the some level of

*

additionally, youth programs are also scheduled for real cuts -- as high as 12

267,000 jobs.

percent - in 1980.

Summer youth programs are scaled down from I million in

1978 and 1979 to 625,000 in 1980 (U.S. Conference of Mayors' estimate).
Some initiatives for which funds are requested, such as private sector
employment programs, may prove useful in the long run. But they cannot be expected
to bridge the gap opened by-the reduction of the countercyclical jobs programs right
away.

352
The President is proposing these actions in an economy where:
*

the Administration's own - overly optimistic - forecast indicates an increase of
500,000 in the number of jobless for FY 1980;

*

those groups of workers who have traditionally been the "lost hired" are sustaining
very high rates of unemployment

even at this late stage of the expansion:
Highest Unemployment
Rate in 74-75 Recession

Black workers
Black adult women
Block teenagers

14.5%
12.6
41.0

Jonuory 1979
11.2%
10.6
32.7

The indications are that these groups have already seen the bottom --even
if at shamefully high levels -- of their jobless rates for this economic cycle.
Public employment programs have been an important part of the economic
recovery; they should not be phased out when the expansion seems on the verge of
exhaustion.

The UAW urges Congress to reject the President's recommendations to

cut funds for unemployment and training back from current policy levels, and to stand
ready to increase those funds if unemployment goes up further.
Aid to Cities
The cuts in CETA would affect not only individuals and families, but
entire communities as well.

Cities that have been struggling to recover from years

of urban decline aggravated by the 1974-75 recession are now fearful that lock. of
federal funds will plunge them right back into fiscal instability, reduction in essential
services, cutbacks in manpower, etc.

353
Countercyclical aid was one important source of federal funds. This post
October, Congress failed to renew the anti-recession financial assistance program.
Since late 1976, the program had pumped more than $3 billion of countercyclical funds
into cities and states with unemployment

rates above 4.5 percent, so long as the

national rote exceeded 6 percent.
The FY 1980 budget makes clear that the post few years of expansiori
of U.S. aid to cities is ending.

Rather than reviving the countercyclical program, the

Administration proposes a transition program to aid a few hard-pressed localities.
Budget authority would be $250 million in FY 1979 and $150 million in FY 1980; in
FY 1978, the anti-recession program paid out $1.3 billion to eligible local and state
governments.
Most state and local governments will not be able to make up the loss
in federal funds, and - because of the regressive nature of most non-federal taxes
--those that do raise taxes will put increasingly inequitable burdens on their lower-and
middle-income residents.
Aside

from

the disappearance

of anti-recession

financial

assistance

programs and the cutbacks in CETA, communities will see their funds for local public
works (aid to local governments for construction programs) practically eliminated as
well.
The budget proposes a National Development Bank with budget authority
projected at about $2.6 billion per year between 1981 and 1984, to support badly needed
investment in economically depressed areas.

We believe that this initiative would

increase jobs in areas with high unemployment

for better than such blunderbuss

investment incentive measures as the general investment tax credit and depreciation
allowances.

354
In our huge economy, not all regions and cities grow and prosper at the
same .rate.

Many of our regions and cities rely heavily on one or a few industries

for their economic well being.
entire

region

generally

When one of those industries declines in a region, the

suffers.

Such

regions

face

rising

unemployment

and

underemployment as family and social ties keep people from departing to look for
wiork in more prosperous regions.

Regions can become more depressed than others

simply because their communities want to remain intact.

A National Development

Bank could assist the creation of jobs in depressed regions and maintain the integrity
of their communities by boosting economic growth.

We strongly recommend enactment

of this budget item.
Again, it will take time to get the activities of the NDB rolling, assuming
it gets congressional approval.

In the meantime, cities should not be allowed to slip

bhck into a downward financial and social spiral; adequate federal funds should be
forthcoming.
Housing and Community Development
Overall HUD budget authority appears to be scheduled for a $2.2 billion
increase.

However, this difference is more than accounted for by carryovers from FY

1978 to FY 1979; in fact, there is a drop in new authority.
Out of the total $33.3 billion for HUD, most of it - $27.4 billion - is
for housing assistance, a function that is planned for a major cut:

the budget proposal

for FY 1980 is $4.3 billion - or 14 percent -- below what HUD estimates to be the
current service level.

As a result, additional Section 8 and public housing units are

being reduced from 360,000 in FY 1979 to 300,000 in FY 1980, a drop of 17 percent.

355
(But a longer perspective, going bock to 1976, would show a drop of 72 percent in the
number of unit reservations.)

The Section 8 Housing Assistance Program has been

HUD's number one program of aid to lower-income families since its passage in 1974.
These families are mostly femole-headed, often elderly, and often block or Hispanic.
We seriously question the timeliness and wisdom of the cutbacks in Section 8: those
groups which constitute its main clientele hove certainly not stopped growing, nor do
they have recourse to any other type of aid to fulfill their need for housing.
Operating subsidies for public housing and modernization funds would be
cut substantially as well.

Thus, the present budget would force managers to either

cut back on services and maintenance to low income households, or increase rental
income -- which in many cases could only be done by serving families at higher income
levels.
None of the cuts in new authority nor the slowdown from the pace at
which new authority was requested in the past appears tailored to the actual housing
or community needs of our urban, low income population. We hope that after Congress
has carried out a detailed scrutiny of the Administration's proposals most, if not all,
of the programs in these functions will be funded at current policy levels.
Congress should approve the proposed inland energy assistance program.
The federal government should hove a general policy to assist states, localities and,
as proposed here, Indian tribes to mitigate the wrenching dislocation that can be
imposed on communities by our fast changing economy. Short of such a comprehensive
approach, programs such as this one that deal with specific causes of dislocation
deserve congressional enactment.

-

356
Energy
The UAW strongly supports research and development in the field of
renewable energy sources. *Thus last year we were pleased to see the substantial role
that this and related items received in the FY 1979 budget.
not

as

encouraging:

commercialization,

the

budget

would

effect

The news this year is

significant. cutbacks on

solar

thus undermining the President's commitment to the increased

utilization of solar energy.
The request for funding of solar applications -- i.e., commercially available
solar technology - is cut bock by about IS percent, or $27.7 million from the previous
fiscol year.
At the some time, the budget

rules out solar space heating

Gs

a

"commercializable" technology, in spite of the dozens of space heating projects already
developed commercially and in service.
The budget also proposes to cancel government plans to buy a large
number of photovoltoic devices which could make the technology competitive for a
wide variety of uses by 1985.
We are encouraged by the recognition given in the budget to the trend
toward slower growth in electricity demand.

That will permit us to proceed with the

caution necessary with respect to nuclear energy.
As a general statement the UAW wants to stress that the energy budget
continues to be weakest on the supply side of the energy equation.

For example, it

is disturbing that public R&D efforts, which we support, often result in a subsidy to
the U.S. energy industry, which adopts publicly-financed technologies and then turns
around and calls for an end to public sector regulation.

357
What the nation needs is greater direct federal involvement in actual fuel
production.

For example, in the fossil fuel area, the proposed budget reflects the

government's continued refusal to expand its role on the supply side. The UAW supports
R&D in coal gasification and liquefaction, oil from shale, and "alternative surface
mining techniques" but that must be supplemented by direct activity in exploration
and production on public lands, and in the importation process.

There is simply no

way to determine true costs, and no way to have a truly national energy policy, except
by the government being one of the active porticipants in sourcing of fuels.
Federal Credit Ceilings
The President has mode the beguiling proposal that Congress set one
annual ceiling on all federal credit activity as a part of the budget process. In addition
to its role of acquiring new debt, the federal government plays in important role in
the extension of credit in our economy.
the government

supports

By guaranteeing loans and lending directly,

the notion's investment in such areas as housing, urban

development and small business.

Federal agencies involved in the extension of credit

need more flexibility than con be permitted by a single annual federal credit ceiling.
We do not object to frequent and timely consolidated reports to Congress
on credit of all types projected to be extended or guaranteed by the government.

Nor

do we doubt that federal credit activity deserves greater congressional attention. When
it determines the stimulus needed for the economy during a fiscal year, Congress
should insure that federal credit actions coincide with planned budgetary fiscal policy.
However we simply believe that a single credit ceiling would unduly restrict federal
credit agencies as they respond to changes in the economy during the fiscal year.

358
Credit extended or backed by the federal government rose from $36.6
billion in 1977 to $59.0 billion in 1978. Most of the change con be traced to increases
in the credit extended to banks and thrift institutions to support their mortgage credit.
New, higher interest certificates helped but were insufficient by themselves to maintain
the flow to these institutions of funds needed for housing.
This fiscal 1978 experience provides a good case in point against a federal
credit ceiling. The amount of credit needed during that period to support mortgages
could not hove been foreseen in September 1977. A ceiling set at that time for fiscal
1978 would hove been too low in all likelihood.

Examples of other agencies with

similar need for flexibility could also be shown.

There are other areas of the budget - such as education and transportation
- which also cause us concern, but could not be odequately analyzed for inclusion in
this paper.
We do not mean to imply that every program should be maintained at
current service levels, or that reduction - or even elimination - of certain programs
would not be justified.
program.

Such determinations must be based on the merits of each

However, it is clear that the Administration's proposal - which starts with

an arbitrary, and unnecessary, limit on the deficit - attacks programs which are more
often inadequately funded to begin with, rather than being a careful reduction of
wasteful activity.

opeiu494

359
Representative REUSS. Congressman Rousselot.
Representative ROUSSELOT. Thank you, Congressman Reuss.
Mr. Young, you mentioned in the earlier part of your statement
what you thought the "add-ons" to the Federal budget should be to
achieve the goal of higher employment, and less unemployment. I
think you said the target should be 6 percent for 1978, 5.6 percent
for 1979, and 5.2 percent for 1980.
Mr. YOUNG. Yes.
Representative ROUSSELOT. Then you put a price tag on that of

$20 billion to be spent by the Federal Government to achieve that?
Mr. YOUNG. No, sir. What I tried to say was that the general
estimate is that if unemployment is 1 percent lower, then, there
will be $20 billion additional available to the Federal Goverment
both because of increased revenues and because of decreased expenditures on things like unemployment insurance.
Representative ROUSSELOT. More people paying taxes is what you
are saying.
Mr. YOUNG. Right. If we could have 5.2 percent unemployment
that would be 1 percent lower than the President anticipates.
Representative ROUSSELOT. Right. Well, you have a laundry list
here of things that you think should be enacted or engaged in by
the Federal Government in order to achieve this lower level of
unemployment, and higher level of employment. Could you give us
a list of where you would spend money at the Federal level to
achieve this?
Mr. YOUNG. Well-Representative ROUSSELOT. You are critical because you believe
we are not doing enough, right?
Mr. YOUNG. Yes.
Representative ROUSSELOT. We ought to spend more money to do
this, you say, and the way you do that is by having the Federal
sector more involved. Where would you spend it besides countercyclical?

Mr. YOUNG. Let me answer that in two parts, if I may.
Representative ROUSSELOT. You see, we can't be quite as nebulous as you have been. We have to really be a little more specific.
Mr. YOUNG. Well, in terms of the immediate future, the 1980
budget.
Representative ROUSSELOT Right.
Mr. YOUNG. We do have some detailed suggestions there, but I
think the important point that should be made is that apparently
no one other than the people who made up the budget believe that
it will produce a deficit of $29 billion. If we follow the policies in
that budget, the estimate of CBO, for example, is that it will
produce a $41 billion deficit.
In other words, we will suffer the ills and then we will spend
money to pay for the cure.
We are saying it would be better to spend that money to prevent
the problems in the first place. So, with respect to the 1980 budget,
we have proposed, really, the very modest goal of saying that it
ought to be at least maintained at current services level. The
estimate for that is roughly $12 billion additional expenditures.
The specific places they would go would generally be to maintain

360
services at the current policy level, though, obviously there could
be some shifts in that area.
That will not do the job-Representative ROUSSELOT. $12 billion more than recommended
by the President, is that what you are saying?
Mr. YOUNG. Yes.
Representative RoUSSELOT. Did you break out where that $12
billion would be spent?
Mr. YOUNG. We did not detail that in the sense that-Representative ROUSSELOT. Or where it would be added on to the
President's program?
Mr. YOUNG. In the President's programs, we would advocate
most of the employment programs,.and the social-security program
be maintained at the current policy levels. Those numbers are laid
out in the CBO report.
* We think that some of those programs should be expanded, but
that that could be done within the $12 billion figure because, as
you will recall from the budget committee testimony, President
Fraser suggested that perhaps $5 billion as a very modest goal
could be moved out of the defense budget and into other programs.
Representative ROUSSELOT. You favor moving it out of defense
yourself.?
Mr. YOUNG. To that extent, yes, sir.
Representative ROUSSELOT. So, if you take $5 billion out of defense, where would you move it-CETA? Where do you want to put
it?
Mr. YOUNG. Into employment programs, for example, into these
experimental full-employment communities that we suggest. When
Mr. Oswald testified, Congressman Reuss said, "Are we wedded to
CETA?" No; we think there should be experimentation with a lot
of different programs and-Representative ROUSSELOT. Are you talking about a pilot program, 8 or 10 communities?
Mr. YOUNG. That is right.
Representative RoUSSELOT. What is the price tag you suggest on
that?
Mr. YOUNG. We have not put a price tag on that.
Representative ROUSSELOT. How would we go about determining
what it was going to cost?
Mr. YOUNG. I think if you were willing to allocate $2 or $3
billion to that, then we would design a program that would fit
within that framework.
[The following letter was subsequently supplied the committee by
Mr. Young with respect to the above response:]
SOLIDARITY HOUSE,
INTERNATIONAL UNION, UNITED AUTOMOBILE, AEROSPACE &
AGRICULTURAL IMPLEMENT WORKERS OF AMERICA-UAW,

Detroit, Mich., March 6,1979.

Re Joint Economic Committee.
Senator LLOYD BENTSEN,

Russell Senate Office Building,
Washington D.C.
DEAR SENATOR BENTSEN: During the Committee hearing on March 2, Congressman Rousselot asked me the amount of funds which might be needed for the "full
employment communities" demonstration projects recommended by the UAW.

361
My response that $2 to $3 billion might be used went well beyond that particular
program. We estimate that a smaller amount, on the order of $1.5 billion should be
adequate for those demonstrations.
I regret any misimpression or confusion which may have been caused by my
initial response.
Sincerely,
HowARD YOUNG,

Special Consultant to the President.

Representative ROUSSELOT. $2 or $3 billion?
Mr. YOUNG. Yes.

Representative RoUSSELOT. How much employment is that going
to produce, new employment?
Mr. YOUNG. That program in itself would not produce a great
deal because it would be an experimentation and demonstration to
develop models that then could be used nationwide.
So, I would not see that as suddenly creating a large number of
jobs in itself, but it would be like any kind of a preparatory
program.
Representative RouSSELOT. So, if we spend $2 to $3 billion on the
full employment community program, it would not produce any
new jobs, it would just be a pilot program to look at it for $2 or $3
billion?
Mr. YOUNG. That particular program.
Representative ROUSSELOT. You see part of our problem here is
that we have looked at a lot of these programs, like CETA, where
we spend approximately $10.5 billion, and we begin to get complaints from some of the local levels that they don't all think it is
really productive work. For instance, in Ventura, Calif., we had
under the CETA program a census taken of pets, I think it was, for
$380,000. That really does not achieve a very long-running productive goal in producing long-term jobs.
We just keep talking about piling more dough into these programs, and when we look at them at the local level, they don't
always produce these long-term productive jobs that you and I are
both interested in.
That is where we are now when you suggest spending $2 to $3
billion for an experimental pilot program, that may, sometime
down the road, produce some jobs. We do not know how long it will
take, or if any permanent productive jobs will be created.
That is what my Governor is now concerned about in California.
He is looking at some of these programs a little more critically.
That is why some of us kind of feel some of that pressure a little
bit now.
All the money we have spent on these programs does not really
produce long-term permanent jobs in many of these areas. Don't
we need to look at that, too?
Mr. YOUNG. Certainly, too-Representative ROUSSELOT. If we are really going to achieve full
employment.
Mr. YOUNG. We would not claim that every program that starts
out is defensible and is needed, but I think in an economy as large
as ours you have got to expect some false starts. I mean, even in
private business one gets false starts, as we are frequently told in
the auto industry that attempts are made to solve problems, they
don't work, so you have to experiment.

362
Representative ROUSSELOT. The difference is in the private sector,
usually they are shut off if they don't produce.
Mr. YOUNG. We would -Representative RoUSSELOT: They just keep going on and on in the
Government. We never really put an end to inefficient programs.
Mr. YOUNG. We don't think that should happen. We think-Representative RoUSSELOT. Have you got a list of some of the
ones that are not doing the job in producing responsible jobs? Do
you have some of those that we might cut back on which would be
helpful to us? You mentioned cutting $5 billion out of defense.
Mr. YOUNG. Yes
Representative RoussELOT. And move that over to what, this
other $12 billion worth of "add-on" programs?
Mr. YOUNG. Yes.
Representative RoUSSELOT. Are you convinced after careful study
that those really produce real jobs and a long-term commitment
also?
Mr. YOUNG. We are convinced that the bulk of those programs
produce real jobs and we are convinced that similar programs of
the same nature can produce jobs and are needed to produce real
jobs; yes.
Representative ROUSSELOT. Thank you, Congressman Reuss.
Representative REUSS. Thank you.
You have given excellent testimony. Tell Mr. Fraser that his line
in his prepared statement, "I do not propose to be the first president of the UAW to be less concerned about the dangers of recession than Milton Friedman," is worthy of a Churchill. [Laughter.]
It is really great.
I like very much the proposal which my colleague, Congressman
Rousselot, just referred to, the full employment communities' suggestion, in fact, what you are talking about here, as I see it, is very
largely something which depends on management, inspiration, charisma, organization, and a gung-ho spirit as much as it does on
dollars; is that so?
Mr. YOUNG. To a substantial extent. We are faced with a very
pessimistic attitude at the moment of "we can't achieve" things,
that we have to settle for shortfalls, and there does not seem to be
objective circumstances that justify that attitude.
In fact, with some more positive approaches we are convinced
that we can do much better; yes.
Representative REUSS. In fact, there is now in place a program of
combating structural unemployment and making for full employment communities which is both open ended and untried; namely,
the tax credit provision which gives an employer a governmental
subsidy for hiring a structurally unemployed person during the
first year or two of employment; is that so?
Mr. YOUNG. Yes, sir. We refer to the wage subsidies as one of the
forms of experimentation that could be used.
Representative REUSS. What I am getting at is since you have not
got that-and a number of other programs, some of them underfunded, but the wage subsidy tax credit is not underfunded, it is
open ended, and if you can get enough new industries making the
things that people of this country need, you could really put a dent
in the unemployment situation.

363
Suppose in these seven or eight communities around the country
that you are talking about, you, the President would appoint, say,
full-employment coordinators in each of the communities, people
like-picking them out of the air-Jim Rouse, the gung-ho developer of Columbia; and Quincy Market in Boston and the development
in Philadelphia; or Felix Rohatyn, the Wall Street smart financier
who has helped keep New York away from the sheriff; or John
Wayne, conservative-but beloved and gung ho; or Beverly Sills; or
Coretta King; or Henry Aaron the baseball player or any one of a
number of others, if you put them in charge, and gave them the
existing tools, might this not turn things around?
Mr. YOUNG. I think what you are probably getting at is that a
number of programs involve better organization and use of money
and resources that are now already available; and that is very
clear. Not all of the proposals that we have listed involve new
expenditures. Some of them involve better ways of doing things
On the other hand, we should not send someone into that battle
with that kind of a charge by not being prepared .to give them the
resources that they will need to make it work.
So, I think it is a combination of the two, that there has to be
better organization, there also have to be resources when needed
and, of course, that investment would help pay for itself because
there is a recovery to both the Federal treasury and the State and
local treasuries if there is less unemployment and less low-income
work going around.
Representative REUSS. We have come to expect of the UAW new
ideas that are well worth examining. It seems to me this is one of
them. Do you have. anything else, Congressman Rousselot?
Representative ROUSSELOT. Yes; thank you, Congressman Reuss.
Mr. Young, we have had several economists tell us that the
present unemployment rate of 5.8 percent or maybe slightly lower,
5.6 percent, really, pretty much represents full employment. What
is your reaction to that? Obviously, in your testimony you disagree,
but I mean, can you give us a little different rationale?
Mr. YOUNG. We have studied the material that has been put out
of that nature, and I would characterize that as a kind of defeatist
approach. In effect, those economists say, well, the demography of
the work force has changed and we have more people in the work
force who historically have had higher unemployment rates so,
therefore, we whould accept the fact that there are higher unemployment rates.
That is just not what, in our view, the game is all about. If, in
fact, as it appears, there has been a change among the attitude of
women toward entering the work force and toward being fully
employed, then to go back and to say, well, women have always
been the marginal group of employees and have had higher unemployment rates, and, therefore, we must now cut back on our
standards and our goal of achievement because of that, is resigning
oneself to defeat rather than saying it is a problem that has to be
overcome and dealt with.
So, I think that those people have not concluded that there is a
reason for high unemployment. They have explained away the high
unemployment without trying to do anything about it.

3614
Representative ROUSSELOT. As you know, there is a group studying this whole issue of what is the real makeup of those that are
critically unemployed, and so forth. I can't disagree with your
comment that because many more women have decided to enter
the work force on a permanent basis that, therefore, we have tried
to justify the higher rates, that maybe the higher level of unemployment would be more acceptable.
Except the issue is sometimes made that when you have two,
three, four people in a family working that, whereas, traditionally
there had been one breadwinner type of thing, that that might
somehow distort the unemployment picture when the second or
third person in a family feels greater flexibility not to work full
time.
Mr. YOUNG. Except that the data-Representative RoUSSELOT. Therefore, that might distort the unemployment figure.
Mr. YOUNG. Yet, on the other hand, when one looks at something like the quit rate, which presumably is what that would
affect, it is not high by historical standards, particularly when you
adjust it for what the historical rate has been among those groups
that are now entering the work force.
So, most people who are unemployed apparently are not unemployed through their own choosing; they are unemployed because
somebody lets them go or somebody does not hire them.
If the kind of rationale that is being offered-these people are
kind of indifferent about working-then you would expect them to
be quitting their job, but that is not what is happening.
Representative ROUSSELOT. What about that group that is nowfor lack of a better term, we call them in the subterranean economy-working for cash, and they don't report much of it; it is a
second or third job, maybe. Do you think that distorts the unemployment figure.
Mr. YOUNG. I have read some of that material and talked to
Ferman out at the University of Michigan, who is doing some of
those studies, but I must admit I don't have a feel of how big that
is or how ,significant it is in the economy.
Representative ROUSSELOT. Therefore, for some of those individuals that are in that "economy" or however we refer to it, don't
report income, they may receive unemployment benefits. Have you
checked that very much? Should we be concerned about that?
Mr. YOUNG. I think that we certainly should be concerned with
administering the programs properly. If people are not entitled to
benefits, certainly, we should check into that.
Again, I don't know how large an issue that really is or how
significantly it would change the overall picture.
Representative ROUSSELOT. Thank you, Congressman Reuss.
Representative REUSS. Thank you. And thank you, gentlemen.
You have made a real contribution, too, and we are greatful to you.
Mr. YOUNG. Thank you.
Representative REUSS. We will stand in recess until March 8
when we shall resume our hearings.
[Whereupon, at 11:26 a.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene
at 10 a.m., Thursday, March 8, 1979.]

THE 1979 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE
PRESIDENT
THURSDAY, MARCH 8, 1979
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,

Washington, D.C.
The committee met, pursuant to recess, at'10 a.m., in room 6226,
Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Parren J. Mitchell (member
of the committee) presiding.
Present: Representatives Mitchell, Brown, and Wylie; and Senators McGovern, Sarbanes, Javits, and Jepsen.
Also present: Louis C. Krauthoff II, assistant director-director,
SSEC; David W. Allen, William R. Buechner, Kent H. Hughes, M.
Catherine Miller, and L. Douglas Lee, professional staff members;
Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; and Katie MacArthur,
press assistant; and Stephen J. Entin, minority professional staff
member.
OPENING STATEMENT OF REPRESENTATIVE MITCHELL, PRESIDING

Representative MITCHELL. This hearing will now come to order.

Good morning. We would like to welcome both Secretary Kreps
and Secretary Marshall here this morning. Later on today we will
have the opportunity to hear from Mr. Ronald Brown, who is the
vice president of the National Urban League.
Secretary Kreps, as you are well aware, a fundamental improvement in our trade position is critical to a healthy dollar. We have a
lot of work cut out for us to achieve a healthy dollar-a $34 billion
trade deficit last year cannot be dismissed lightly. I know that
forecasts call for a considerable decline in our deficit by the end of
1979 due to fewer imports and enhanced competitiveness of our
goods from the depreciation of the dollar.
But I believe we have to do more than let market forces carry
the ball. Madam Secretary, you have made export policy trips to
Japan just last fall, to Russia this winter and are planning a trip to
our newest potential market-the People's Republic of China-this
spring. Although we are running minor surpluses with the latter
two countries, we ran a deficit of $11.5 billion in 1978 with Japan,
one of our major trading partners.
These trips are an obvious expression of your interest in developing our export policy. Can you tell us what substantive policy
changes have been made as a result of these trips? How does the
Commerce Department intend to use those $20 million in funds
earmarked to aid small- and medium-sized businesses in their
export efforts?
(365)
47-977 0 - 79 - 24

366
Turning to our domestic economy, we would like you, Secretary
Kreps, to tell us if you see any sectoral imbalances that may be
developing in the near future. We have seen a few scattered signs;
that is, housing starts and industrial production indicating an initial slowing down of the expansion. Yet, there has been some
discussion about the existence of excess demand pressures. What is
your judgment on those issues?
As a final point, excessive and unnecessary Government regulations are an important cause of inflation. One of the most effective
ways we could bring down these costs is through a regulatory
budget that would put a cap on the costs each agency could impose
on the private sector. Secretary Kreps and our chairman, Senator
Bentsen, have discussed this in the past, and I hope we can have a
progress report on the Commerce Department's efforts in this area.
I have some comments I will make very briefly to you, Mr.
Marshall, and then turn to the testimony.
- The President has said, Mr. Secretary, "We will not reduce inflation at the expense of the most vulnerable members of our society-the poor, the elderly, and those who have difficulty finding
jobs even in a higher employment economy." I think it is a joint
task of Congress and your Department to make sure that promise
is kept.
However, I find it difficult to be sanguine when the administration's forecast this year is an increase, not a decline, in the unemployment rate.
The Humphrey-Hawkins bill set the goal of a 4-percent unemployment rate by 1983. Don't you think an unemployment rate rise
this year will deal a serious setback to the achievement of that
goal? How does your Department intend to deal with an increase in
those cyclically unemployed as well as the enormous backlog of the
structurally unemployed? I hope you can give us some reassurance
that the Department of Labor is prepared to meet both of these
problems.
Now, Madam Secretary, as I understand it, you are on a very
tight time schedule, that you must leave by 11:15. We do have
copies of your prepared statement. If you so desire, you may submit
that for the record in its entirety; however, if you care to speak
from it, fine.
Let me confer with my colleague Congressman Brown to see if he
has an opening statement.
OPENING STATEMENT OF REPRESENTATIVE BROWN

Representative BROWN. Thank you. It is always good to have you
as Secretary up here and to see labor and management together.
I have just heard as I drove over to this side of the Hill that we
now have a wholesale price index announcement that indicates
that it jumped 1 percent last month at the 12-percent annual rate
and that this is the wholesale price index which is going to be
translated through to the general consumer price index, I assume,
within a month or so, indicating that we are moving into a doubledigit inflation rate.
In your comments-I know they are prepared-but in your additional comments I would like to have you address that, which I

367
consider to be our endemic problem, a very serious problem and
one which I hope we have some new solutions for that are somewhat different from those which we have tried in the past because
they seem to be the same solutions we tried for the last dozen or 20
years, and they seem not to be working, if the wholesale price
index this morning is any indication of the trend, and I think it is
a continuation of the trend.
So, if both of you have the opportunity to address that problem
for us, not because I am not sensitive to the problems which my
colleague and respected friend Parren Mitchell has raised with
reference to the chainlike structural unemployment and legislation
on that area and other problems that are in the area of social
concerns that grow out of our economic situation, but precisely
because I am concerned about those things, because I see the same
pattern continuing in this current situation where we are going to
a sharper and sharper inflation rate, higher and higher interest
rates, and eventually that peaks out and drops over the edge, and
we all suffer for it except the people who suffer most are those
about whom we should all be concerned, the deprived, like the
unskilled, and so forth, because they are the ones least able to cope
with that kind of evolutionary process.
So I would hope that you would address yourself to how we can
avoid that peaking and ultimate collapse that has been patterned
now that seems to be repeating with increasing severity, with
shorter degree times in between in the rhythmic curve, and one
which I think carries with it what I would consider as again to be
the major problem in our economy, and that is inflation.
We seem to have been using what I guess I would call a trickle
up theory, and that is that we spend money at the Federal level
and then hope that that is good for the rest of the economy.
I would say that the only thing that is sort of unusual in that
policy of trickle up that is accomplished is that we are defying the
law of gravity, at least as far as inflation is concerned.
Representative MITCHELL. I would like to make a suggestion if I
may. Let us take testimony from both of the Secretaries and then
ask questions, if that is agreeable with you.
Secretary MARSHALL. Yes.
Secretary KREPS. Yes.
Representative MITCHELL. Madam Secretary, we are iii your
hands.
STATEMENT OF HON. JUANITA M. KREPS, SECRETARY OF
COMMERCE

Secretary KREPS. Thank you, Mr. Congressman.
In the questions which you raised with respect to international
trade funds which you had asked me to address, you raised several
questions which I hope my testimony will address. I will be glad to
go very quickly through that testimony.
Representative MITCHELL. Before you do, would you like me to
ask for a unanimous consent request so that all of your testimony
will be submitted for the record, since you will be speaking extemporaneously?
Secretary KREPS. Yes.

368
You raised, Mr. Congressman, a question of whether we could
not find ways to define exports in spite of the fact that you did not
want to rely on market forces altogether. From my testimony, you
will see that the administration has attempted to bring about
certain policy changes, particularly under the national export
policy, that will speak to that particular problem.
You raised the question of cyclical imbalances in trade. I would
like to speak to those problems.
I also would like to address the question of geographical imbalances.
Finally, I would like to address the question of the basic explanation that is being given for some of the negative trade balances, in
particular the question of productivity and the question of innovation and our ability to compete nationally.
You have heard, Congressman, a great deal of testimony about
the domestic outlook; I shall leave that topic to Secretary Marshall.
The state of the domestic economy is very closely related to the
international accounts and to our dollar componenets to the extent
that we are able to subdue inflation, which would strengthen our
competitive position-therefore improving our trade balance by promoting exports. Only in this way can we strengthen the dollar
value and hope for our stability in international markets.
Focusing my remarks here on the balance of trade and the
policies that we need to adopt to increase our foreign trade, I
should like to comment on the Department's work on another issue
that is directly related; this is innovation and productivity.
Representative MITCHELL. I am sorry. I didn't hear your last
statement. I think you need to pull your mike a little closer to you.
Secretary KREPS. I am not sure it is working. Is it? Is it working
now?
Representative MITCHELL. I can hear you. I don't know whether
the rest of the audience can.
Have the staff check the mikes and see if they are working
properly, please.
Secretary KREPS. All right.
The international trade balance can be analyzed in any one of a
number of ways. We are all acquainted with the recent history of
the deficit in the aggregate. The deficit that you mentioned, the
$34 billion in 1978, and an unprecedented deficit of $75 billion over
the past 3 years. The 1978 current account deficit-including payments for services, income on foreign investments, and certain
other "invisible" items-of $17 billion.
It should be noted, however, that last year the quarterly figures
suggested that there was a turning point. The trade deficit peaked
in the first quarter at an annual rate of nearly $45 billion, but
declined by the fourth quarter to a rate of $30 billion, even though
during this time oil imports had actually increased.
The factors that are responsible for this narrowing in the deficit
led us to expect a further decline in 1979.
Our projections which were made prior to the recent oil disruption have indicated that in 1979 we will have an improvement of
perhaps $9 billion from the 1978 trade deficit. This will, of course,
be affected by the recent changes in oil availability and oil prices,

369
but it is also affected by the possibility of some reduction in oil
consumption.
The situation is currently uncertain with respect to the deficit
and our Department is working on new projections growing out of
the Iranian oil problem. We will be glad to furnish you those
estimates as soon as they are ready.
Our trade balance can also be analyzed in bilateral terms; you
referred to this in your opening questions. The most commonly
discussed bilateral balance is that with Japan. It has recently
surpassed Canada as the single largest exporter of manufactured
goods to the United States. In 1977-78, our bilateral deficit in
merchandise trade with Japan rose from $8 billion to $12 billion,
our largest deficit with any country.
Japan's surplus is also an important portion of her $17 billion
global current account surplus. This has become incidentally the
largest surplus in the world and larger than the OPEC surplus of
$11 billion.
We see that from our point of view the yen appreciation and the
policy measures that we have taken have begun to have some
effect on our merchandise trade balance with Japan. In the fourth
quarter of 1978 this deficit dropped to about a $9 billion annual
rate, but overall continues to be very high. The administration has
made clear to the Japanese Government that the problem must be
solved in the interests of the world's economic stability.
Each of these ways of looking at the trade balance is important,
but it does seem to me that there are at least two perspectives that
we ought to concentrate on here. The first is the perspective of
manufactured goods.
An examination of our trade in manufactured goods tells us a
great deal about our overall international trading relationship.
Among both our exports and imports, manufacturers who supply
the biggest category of goods have been the backbone of our
strength in foreign trade over the last half century. For the last 4
years, however, from 1974 to 1978, the volume of our manufactured
exports grew hardly at all. Indeed, manufactures deteriorated from
a $12 billion surplus to a $6 billion deficit in that period. Now that
$18 billion slide is nearly as large as the deficit of the overall trade
balance during that period.
Manufactured goods are the category of trade with the greatest
potential for improvement in our view. They comprise the key to
resolving our trade problems. Since the first quarter of 1978, the
volume of manufactured exports has, in fact, grown at an annual
rate of more than 15 percent. We are encouraged by this.
By the fourth quarter of last year our balance in manufactures
was back into surplus at an annual rate of $1.5 billion.
The foreign trade data for January released last week showed a
fairly sharp 1-month setback in the balance for manufactures. This
setback may not be fully reversed in February, but we don't think
it is a pattern that will hold. We will see improvement in part,
despite the January deficit which resulted, from increased demand
for goods generated by the economy's very high growth rate in the
fourth quarter.
Regarding the prospects for a growing surplus in manufacturing,
we think that the process of goods this year is good because our

370
economic growth is slowing while the growth abroad is accelerating, because we are now in the stronger competitive position resulting from dollar depreciation, and because our export promotion
efforts, we think, will begin to bear fruit during the coming year.
Of particular importance to our trade balance is the component
of capital goods. The export .of capital goods represents the strongest category of manufactured goods. Our surplus in this category
was $27 billion last year, which is almost twice as large as our
surplus in agricultural goods. However, this too, has remained
essentially unchanged for the past 3 years.
The plateau is traceable to the increased imports for our expanding economy and the fact that foreign markets have been hampered by poor utilization of existing capacity.
Again there are encouraging signs, although not a sufficient
basis for firm projection yet, in the data on trade in capital goods
during the last half of 1978. U.S. exports of capital goods increased
in value by about 20 percent over the first half of the year. We
expect foreign markets to continue to improve. On the other hand,
imports in this area have flattened and, if these trends continue,
we will see a needed change in this most important trade category.
If I could turn to the other perspective on the trade balance
which needs attention, which is the perspective of the region of the
world involved.
Prospects for improvement in our trade balance are good for
most areas with the most notable exception being that of the OPEC
countries. We registered a $14 billion deficit with OPEC last yearabout $1 billion less than the average for the preceding 3 years.
The stability of oil prices and U.S. oil imports in 1978, plus some
growth' in our exports to the OPEC countries, brought about this
improvement. Higher oil prices and, if supplies are available, the
resumption of import growth will worsen our trade position with
the OPEC countries in 1979 and for an indeterminant period we
will see a decline in our exports to Iran.
The largest improvement in our trade should be a reversal of our
declining surplus with the industrial nations which accounted for
most of the deterioration in our accounts. We think it is likely that
our trade surplus with Western Europe will grow this year, that
our deficits with Canada and Japan will diminish.
Turning then to the question regarding China that you raised,
this stirs the imagination of the public. Our exports to China,
although small, nearly quintupled last year, rising to $824 million.
This year we expect that figure to double again. We think the
dollar level, although remaining small, will continue to rise. We
should not expect our trade with China to affect dramatically our
overall trade balance in the next few years.
Also of importance is the comparative trade performance in our
country compared with Western Europe and Japan in third country markets. For example, our respective trade balances over the
last 3 years indicate that in non-OPEC developing countries, both
Japan and Western Europe have more favorable trade balances
than we have. Stated differently, the export performance of Europe
and Japan in such third country markets suggest that they have
more competitive products, more aggressive marketing, fewer domestic impediments to exporting or some combination of these.

371
The data have special significance for the importance of our
cultivating both new attitudes and new policies with respect to
export.
I should like to comment very briefly on the export policies that
we have been pursuing.
This committee has recently heard discussions on many of the
policies that are relevant to the state of our domestic economy as
well as to our international trade situation. Among these are macroeconomic policies, the conclusion and implementation of the multilateral trade negotiations, and others. All of these are important.
We should, however, emphasize the importance of export measures directly; measures that only recently have been recognized in
this country as economic policies of fundamental importance.
After decades of development with seemingly limitless natural
resources, vast and expanding domestic markets and entrenched
indifference to exporting, we have begun as a nation to focus on
the importance of exports to our national economic health. The
trade deficits and the exchange rate declines created by abrupt
spiralling payments for oil and other imports have forced us to give
our attention to the export half of the trade equation. President
Carter's announcement of a national export policy reflects a recognition of the importance of our trade balance and, indeed, echoes
your own sentiment that trade cannot always be left to the market
forces.
The national export policy is only a beginning, we recognize this.
Greater importance lies in its creation than in its particular elements. Increased authorization of the Export-Import Bank, enhanced export promotion programs at Commerce and State, the
ongoing study of export disincentives and a computerized system of
foreign market opportunities are important measures, but they fall
short of government support that is needed for our own domestic
firms in competing with foreign firms.
The national export policy is an important new category of economic policy, albeit its implementation is in its infancy. We cannot
expect instant results.
I know that Members of Congress have a strong interest in
assisting U.S. exporters and that this subject may be considered
this year in connection with the multilateral trade negotiations
and other legislation. Indeed, a logical step on export policy may be
to integrate implementation of the MTN with a strengthened
export expansion drive.
Finally, if I may turn just quickly to the question of productivity,
which is an important element of our ability to compete. The
decline in productivity growth is central to our domestic problem of
inflation and the threat which it poses to the stability of production and employment. Productivity growth lagging behind that of
industries abroad, places our producers at a disadvantage in international trade and contributes to the whole complex of problems
that arise from a prolonged trade deficit.
The last decade has witnessed a remarkable slowdown in the
rate of productivity growth in this country. Last year productivity
in the private economy increased by one-half of 1 percent compared
to an increase of 11/2 percent in 1977. This compares to a trend rate
of about 3.1 percent annually between 1950 and 1967.

372
The greatest slump in productivity growth is centered on nonmanufacturing sectors-particularly construction, mining, and
retail trade. While overall productivity in manufacturing has declined by much less, serious problems have been encountered in
many industries.
A number of possible factors account for this decline in productivity. I should be glad to discuss these, as I am sure Secretary
Marshall would. The end of migration out of the low productivity
farm sector, the shift toward a younger, less experienced work
force, expenditures for pollution abatement and worker safety, the
benefits of which are not counted in our. national economic accounts, slower growth in the amount of capital per worker; and a
lag in research and development expenditures are the factors involved. The Department of Commerce has recently completed a
comprehensive review of our knowledge about the causes of the
decline in productivity growth, and I have attached to my prepared
statement a copy of this paper.
Closely related to the pace of productivity growth is, of course,
the innovation in industry. This was the focus of a domestic policy
review undertaken in May 1978 pursuant to President Carter's
instruction.
This review deals with the effects industrial innovation of such
Federal policies as procurement, patents and information, direct
support of research and development, environmental, health and
safety regulations, and regulations of industry structure and competition.
The role of small business in the innovation process will be a
special concern of this policy review which will soon be reported to
the President.
We have had senior executives from industry, labor, academic,
and public interest groups participate in this review, as well as
policymakers.
As I have said, we will be making recommendations to the President by the end of March, and I would hope that they would lead
to actions that would be helpful to stimulate productivity growth.
Mr. Congressman, I have sketched through my testimony, and at
the appropriate time I shall be glad to respond to questions.
Representative MITCHELL. Thank you very much, Madam Secretary.
[The prepared statement of Secretary Kreps, together with the
paper entitled "The Productivity Decline: Its Causes and Effects,"
follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HON. JUANITA

M.

KREPS

Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee, I am pleased to appear before you
to testify on the state of the economy. Your invitation presents an opportunity to
continue ihe fruitful relationship that has existed between the Commerce Department and the Joint Economic Committee in the past.
This Committee is familiar with the domestic economic outlook. Employment
continued to rise at a healthy rate in January, and the unemployment rate declined
another notch to 5.8 percent. New orders, particularly for steel, aircraft and machinery rose sharply. However, industrial production, personal income, and retail
sales rose more slowly in January than in the fourth quarter, and housing starts
declined sharply. Much of the slowdown in production and housing starts was due to
extreme weather in some sections of the country. The recent data are generally

373
consistent with our expectation that economic growth will slow from the fourth
quarter's exceptionally strong pace.
Prices rose sharply in January. The advance was broadly based. While we do not
expect this rate of increase to persist or accelerate throughout the year, recent price
data demonstrate once again the stubborn nature of our inflation problem and the
importance of making our anti-inflation program succeed.
In response to the interests expressed in your letter of invitation, I should like to
give you a brief account of the Commerce Department's forecasts for several major
subsectors. of the economy in 1979. Then, because the health of our domestic economy today depends on the healthy development of our international economic relations, I shall turn to an analysis of the U.S. balance of trade and to policies that in
my view would foster further improvement in our foreign trade. In closing, I shall
say a few words about our Department's work on the critical questions of productivity and industrial innovation in the American economy.
INDUSTRIAL OUTLOOK

Within the framework of the overall forecast for the economy, we anticipate
major differences in performance among key industrial sectors. The Commerce
Department's recently released 1979 U.S. Industrial Outlook provides one-year and
five-year projections for some 200 manufacturing and service industries. I should
like to review some of the highlights of these forecasts.
Construction

Construction spending in 1979 is expected to decline slightly in real terms. For
the first time in several years, this important sector will not contribute to the
Nation's overall economic growth.
The most significant factor in our construction forecast is an expected decline in
housing starts of about 300,000 units from over 2 million units started in 1978. This
decline has been much longer in coming than most experts had foreseen. Housing
starts in December were at an annual rate of 2.1 million units, the tenth consecutive month above the 2 million mark. The historical pattern of financial disintermediation, whereby savings institutions lost deposits to money and capital markets
offering higher yields, was arrested in the middle of 1978 by authorizing these
institutions to issue savings certificates with more competitive interest rates. Although this has shielded the housing sector from credit insufficiency in 1978, a
moderate decline in credit available and housing starts is expected to occur in 1979.
The slump in starts in January to an annual rate of 1.7 million could be the
beginning of such a decline, but we think the size of this drop was considerably
exaggerated by the weather.
This.decline in the housing sector will be partly counter-balanced by growth of
other types of construction activity. Industrial and commercial buildings in the
private sector and sewer system construction in the public sector promise strong
performances in 1979, continuing the 1978 trend. Even after adjusting for inflation,
industrial building activity rose by about 25 percent and commercial building by 10
percent during 1978. While growth in these categories will slow in 1979, even the
smaller gains will help to offset the housing decline.
The lower number of housing starts will have direct effects on building materials
sectors where some scarcities have appeared during 1978. For example, we expect
the production of lumber and softwood plywood to decline by about 5 percent.
Household furniture sales also are expected to show little growth.
An important corollary of the leveling off of construction activity should be a
significantly lower inflation rate in this sector in 1979. During 1978 the price
deflator for structures rose by nearly 12 percent compared to a rise in the GNP
deflator of 8.3 percent.
Steel

The outlook for Steel in 1979 is favorable, with domestic industry shipments
projected to increase nearly 4 percent to over 101 million net tons. The projected
1979 shipment volume will be the third highest on record after the boom years of
1973 and 1974, when the industry shipped about 110 million tons.
The expected increase in domestic shipments results from an anticipated decline
in imports to between 16 and 17 million tons (14 percent of the market) from the
record high in 1978 of 21 million tons (18 percent of the market).
The import decline reflects the substantial increase in the price of imported steel
caused by the trigger price mechanism, which became effective in 1978. From an
average of $298 per ton (foreign value, excluding freight and duty) in the first four
months of 1978, the average price had increased to $376 per ton by December 1978.

374
Industrialequipment and components
Shipments of industrial equipment and components rose by over 10 percent in
1978 to $72 billion and this year are expected to increase by another 8 percent.
Exports rose by 13 percent to $13.9 billion in 1978 and are expected to rise 9 percent
in 1979.
This industry is comprised of some 16 major subsectors, which include several
with growth rates among the fastest projected for any sector in 1979. For instance,
shipments of metalworking production machinery, which is vital for the manufacture of thousands of products made from the melting and processing of metal, are
expected to grow by 15 percent in 1979.
Shipments of machine tools are expected to rise by 29 percent. Last year's increase in foreign orders for machine tools was very strong. Exports are expected to
rise by 22 percent in 1979 to about $900 million. Domestic new orders for machine
tools in 1978 reached a value of nearly $4 billion, a gain of 44 percent from 1977.
The industry at the end of last year had a backlog of nearly $3.5 billion.
Motor vehicles
Motor vehicle sales are projected to total 14.9 million units in 1979, a 3.3 percent
decline from the 1978 record level of 15.4 million units. Passenger car sales are
expected to decline to 10.8 million units in 1979 from 11.3 million units in 1978.
Truck sales, which were limited by production capacity in 1978, are expected to
continue at the record 1978 rate of 4.1 million units.
Domestically produced passenger car sales are forecast at 9.0 million units in 1979
versus 9.3 million in 1978 with the market share of domestically produced cars
increasing to 83.3 percent in. 1979 compared with 82.3 percent in 1978 and 81.4
percent in 1977. The increased market share of domestically produced cars reflects
both the reduced value of the dollar relative to the Japanese yen and German mark
and the introduction of more small car lines that compete directly with imports.
Textiles and apparel
The textile and apparel industries experienced slow, steady growth in 1978. Indications are that this will continue in 1979.
Textile mill product shipments in 1978 were $44 billion, a 3.5 percent gain over
1977. Apparel industry shipments for the year were estimated to have been $38
billion, 2.7 percent above 1977. The value of textile and apparel imports in 1978 was
$7.0 billion, substantially more than in 1977. The value of exports rose 10 percent to
$2.6 billion. The industry is concerned about the effects of increasing imports, the
MTN and regulatory actions, particularly with regard to cotton dust and noise
standards.
The Administration recognizes the importance to the industry of an effective
textile and apparel program. To that end we have:
Led in the renewal of the international multifiber arrangement which provides a
framework for an orderly expansion of international textile trade;
Renewed and strengthened our bilateral agreements that cover 75 percent of U.S.
cotton, wool and man-made fiber textile and apparel imports;
Consulted with foreign suppliers and in some cases have taken unilateral actions
to prevent disruption from supplier countries not covered by bilateral agreements;
Begun a textile and apparel export expansion program that:
Identifies growing export markets,
Attacks non-tariff barriers to our exports, and
Provides firms the information they need to export.
Established a program to assist apparel industry productivity.
The computing equipment industry
The computing industry, consisting of manufacturers of computer systems, peripheral equipment and parts, shipped more than $15 billion worth of products in 1978.
Shipments in this fast-growing sector are expected to increase by 15 percent in 1979.
Computers are critical to operations of business and government and are expected
gradually to find use in the home as well. As a result of continuing, rapid technological change, computer equipment is becoming smaller, less expensive and easier to
use. The linkage of computers with telecommunications is anticipated to grow into a
major new market-data communications-by the mid-1980's.
Exports of computer equipment and parts in 1978 reached $4.1 billion with
imports totaling $755 million. The potential for a continued high volume of computer exports in the future is considered strong. The developed countries should continue to offer good market potential, and less developed countries also are looked to as
important markets for these products in the 1980's.

375
Aerospace industry

Industry shipments were about $39 billion in 1978, a gain of 19 percent over 1977.
New orders rose to 39 percent over the 1977 rate. Unfilled orders at year's end
totaled $80 billion, roughly 40 percent more than a year earlier.
As the Nation's leading contributor among manufacturing industries to the balance of trade, the aerospace industry showed a trade surplus of $8.5 billion in 1978.
The industry has produced about 70 percent of the transport aircraft in use today
by the world's airlines. Exports of large transport aircraft were $2.6 billion in 1978,
up from $1 billion in 1977.
Industry shipments are expected to be $47 billion in 1979. The increase results
largely from continued high demand for large transport aircraft. Exports of large
commercial transports could approach a value of $4.9 billion, an increase of 88
percent over 1978. Increased demand for additional seats/cargo space following
deregulation of the U.S. airlines accounts for a portion of the increased requirements for large transports.
INTERNATIONAL TRADE

The state of our domestic economy is closely linked to the health of our international accounts and to the dollar's performance in exchange markets. To the extent
that we succeed in subduing inflation, for example, we strengthen our competitive
position in international trade and help to maintain a stable dollar. On the other
hand, to the. degree that we improve our trade position through promoting exports
or by reducing the barriers facing U.S. goods abroad, we may help strengthen the
dollar, thereby relieving one source of inflationary pressure at home.
Our international trade balance can be analyzed from a number.of perspectives.
We are well acquainted, for example, with the recent history of our deficit in the
aggregate: on a balance-of-payments basis, a merchandise-trade deficit of $34 billion
in 1978; an unprecedented deficit of $75 billion over the past three years; a 1978
current-account deficit-including payments for services, income on foreign investments, and certain other "invisible' items-of $17 billion.
Last year's quarterly figures suggest a turning point, however; the trade deficit
peaked in the first quarter at an annual rate of nearly $45 billion, but declined as
the year progressed to an annual rate of $30 billion in the fourth quarter, even
though oil imports increased during the year. The factors responsible for this trend
lead us to expect a further decline in the trade deficit in 1979, although estimating
the size of the improvement is complicated by the uncertainties now surrounding
the outlook for oil prices and supplies.
Commerce Department projections made prior to the recent oil supply disruptions
indicated an improvement in 1979 of perhaps $9 billion from the 1978 trade deficit.
This outlook will be affected by higher oil prices, but it also is affected by the
possibilities for offsetting reductions in oil consumption. The situation is currently
very uncertain, but our Department is working on new projections which we will be
glad to provide when they are ready.
Our trade balance also can be analyzed in bilateral terms. Most commonly discussed is our bilateral balance with Japan, which recently surpassed Canada as the
single largest exporter of manufactured goods to the United States. From 1977 to
1978, our bilateral deficit in merchandise trade with Japan rose from $8 billion to
$12 billion, our largest deficit with any country. Japan s surplus with the United
States is nearly half of her $25-billion global trade surplus. Japan's surplus with us
is also an important portion of her $17-billion global current-account surplus. This
huge surplus has become the largest source of economic disequilibrium in the
world-exceeding the $11-billion current-account surplus of the OPEC countries.
Yen appreciation and policy actions on both sides have begun to reduce this
imbalance somewhat. U.S. merchandise trade with Japan was in deficit by about $9
billion at an annual rate in the fourth quarter of 1978, compared to $13 billion in
the first half of the year. This deficit, however, continues to be much too large. The
Administration has made clear to the Japanese government that this problem must
be solved in the interest of the world's economic stability.
Each of these analyses of the deficit is important, and each has significant
implications for U.S. policies. In my discussion today, however, I should like to focus
on two other perspectives which I believe offer useful insights into the kinds of
policies that we need to follow.
Manufacturedgoods

Examination of our trade in manufactured goods tells us a great deal about the
anatomy of our international trading relationships. Among both our exports and
imports, manufactures comprise the biggest category of goods and have been the

376
backbone of America's strength in foreign trade over the last 50 years. For the four
years from 1974 to 1978, however, the volume of odr manufactured exports grew
hardly at all. From 1976 to 1978, the balance of trade in manufactures deteriorated
from a $12-billion surplus to a $6-billion deficit (see Table 1). That $18-billion slide is
nearly as large as the decline in the overall trade balance during the period.

END-USE CATEGORIES
TABLE 1.-U.S. TRADE BALANCE BY MAJOR
value]
f.a.s.
ofdollars,
[Inbillions
Commodity

1976

Total............................................................
Foods, feeds, beverages.............................................
.......
Industrial supplies.....................................
...................
Fuels .....
Other .
Capital goods, excluding autos ...........................
Automotive vehicles...................................................
Consumer goods, excluding autos ...........................
Special category (military goods) ...........................
Agricultbral commodities...........................................
Manufactured goods...................................................

+8.1
-28.9
-29.9
+1.0
+27.4
-4.9
-10.5
+2.6
+12.1
+12.5

1977

1978

$-26.5
$-5.9

$-28.5

+5.6
-42.1
-40.2
-1.9
+25.4
-6.6
-13.0
+3.2
+10.7
+3.6

+9.7
-42.8
-38.4
-4.4
+26.8
-9.9
-17.9
+4.5
+14.8
-5.9

Manufactured goods are the category of trade with the greatest potential for
improvement and comprise the key to resolving our trade problems. In fact, the
balance in this key sector now is recovering. Since the first quarter of 1978, the real
volume of U.S. manufactured exports has grown at an annual rate of more than 15
percent. By the fourth quarter of last year, our balance in manufactures was back
into surplus at an annual rate of $1.5 billion. To offset the rising deficit for oil and
continue reducing our overall trade deficit, this surplus must increase much further.
Foreign trade data for January, released last week, showed a fairly sharp onemonth setback in the balance for manufactures. While this setback may not be fully
reversed in February, we think that it is an anomaly in a longer-term pattern of
improvement, resulting in part from demand for goods generated by the fourthquarter's very rapid rate of domestic economic growth.
The prospects for a growing surplus in manufactures this year are good for three
reasons. First, economic growth abroad is expected to continue or to accelerate
moderately, while U.S. economic growth will slow. Second, U.S. firms are now in a
stronger competitive position because depreciation of the dollar over the past two
years has raised the prices of foreign products relative to those of U.S. products,
making our goods more attractive both to foreign buyers and to American customers. Third, we hope that our export l*omotion efforts, working in this conducive
environment, can begin this year to make a long-term contribution to a stronger
trade balance.
Of particular importance to our trade balance in manufactured goods is the
component of capital.goods. Exports of capital goods represent our strongest category of manufactured goods: our trade surplus in capital goods last year was $27
billion-almost twice as .larke as our surplus in agricultural goods. However, this
surplus hasqbeep essentially unchanged for the past three years. During the same
three years, the deficit in our accounts for industrial supplies, including oil, rose by
over $14 billion, and our deficit for consumer goods rose by over $11 billion.
The plateau in our capital-goods surplus is traceable to increased imports for our
expanding economy and to the fact that markets abroad have been hampered by
poor utilization of existing capacity. Economic expansion is continuing in other
industrial countries, and we expect these export markets to strengthen. Moreover,
this category of exports can be stimulated through actions to speed technological
innovation in American industry, to facilitate export financing, and to eliminate
disincentives that impede export growth.
Particularly encouraging signs-although' not a sufficient basis for firm projections-are to be found in the data on trade in capital goods during the last half of
1978. Departing from the trend of the past three years, U.S. exports of capital goods
increased in value by about 20 percent over the first half of the year. Imports, on
the other hand, flattened as the year progressed. If these improved trends continue,

377
they will provide a needed and welcome change in our most important trade
category.
US. trade by region
Another perspective on the trade balance comes from an examination of the trade
outlook by region. Recent regional patterns, particularly when contrasted with
those for our principal trading competitors, Europe and Japan, raise important
issues.
The prospects for improvement in our trade balance are good for most areas, the
notable exception being the OPEC countries. We registered a $14-billion deficit with
OPEC last year-about $1 billion less than the average for the past three years. The
stability of oil prices and of U.S. oil imports in 1978 plus rapid growth of our exports
to OPEC countries yielded this result. Higher oil prices and a resumption of oil
import growth will worsen our trade position with OPEC countries in 1979, however, and for an indeterminate period we shall see a decline in our exports to Iran,
a country to which we exported some $3.7 billion worth of goods last year.
The largest improvement in our trade should be a reversal of our declining
balance with the industrial nations, which accounted for most of the recent deterioration in our accounts (see Table 2). It is likely that our trade surplus with Western
Europe will grow this year, and our deficits with Canada and Japan should
diminish.
The area that has captured the imagination of the public this year is China,
where the establishment of diplomatic relations and China's vigorous efforts to
modernize its economy create new market opportunities for U.S. exporters. Our
exports to China nearly quintupled last year, to $824 million; this year they are
expected to double again. The dollar level of such trade remains relatively small,
and we should not expect trade with China to affect dramatically our overall trade
balance in the next two or three years. However, with a reduction of trade barriers
between the two countries and aggressive selling efforts by U.S. firms, our exports
to China could rise significantly in the 1980's. Although imports from China also
will grow, we can expect to maintain a substantial surplus.
We have paid close attention for good reasons to our bilateral trade balance with
other major regions and countries, particularly the arresting figures on our trade
with Japan. Also of importance, however, are the comparative trade performances
of our country versus Western Europe and Japan in third-country markets.
TABLE 2.-U.S. TRADE BALANCE BY REGION
[In billions
of dollars,
f.a.s.value]
Country

1976

1978

1977

....................

$-5.9

$-26.5

Developed countries...................................................
Canada .......
....................
Japan................................................................
Western Europe ...........................
Germany, Federal Republic of..................
Other Western Europe ...........................
Other developed countries ...........................
OPEC
...........................
Non-OPEC developing countries ...........................
Asia-3 countries,...........................................
Other developing countries ...........................
Centrally planned economies...........................
China, Peoples Republic of ...........................

+3.6
-2.1
-5.4
+9.6
+0.1
+9.5
+1.5
-12.5
+0.2
-3.0
+3.2
+2.6
-0.1

-3.7
-3.8
-8.0
+7.1
-1.2
+8.3
+1.0
-19.1
-5.2
-4.0
-1.2
+1.4

Total .......

(2)

$-28.5
-13.4
-5.2
-11.6
+3.4
-3.0
+6.4
-0.1
-14.0
-4.4
-5.3
+0.9
+2.7
+0.5

Hong
Kong,
Kora,
andTaiwan.
Less
thanSO.05
billon.

For Example, our respective trade balance and the trends over the past three
years indicate that, in non-OPEC developing countries, both Japan and Western
Europe have more favorable trade balances than the U.S. Stated differently, the
export performance of Europe and Japan in such third-country markets surpasses
our own, suggesting that they have more competitive products, more aggressive
marketing, fewer domestic impediments to exporting, or some combination of the

378
three. These data have special significance for the importance of our cultivating
new attitudes and new policies with respect to exporting.
Export policies

This Committee has heard discussions recently of many important policies that
are relevant to the state of our domestic economy as well as to our trade situation.
Among these are macroeconomic policies, both fiscal and monetary; energy policies;
the conclusion and implementation of the multilateral trade negotiations; and
others. All are important. I should like, however, to concentrate on the importance
of export measures-measures that only recently have been recognized in our
country as economic policies of fundamental importance.
After decades of development with seemingly limitless natural resources, vast and
expanding domestic markets, and entrenched indifference to exporting, we have
begun to focus on the importance of exports to our national economic health. The
trade deficits and exchange-rate declines created by abruptly spiralling payments
for oil and other imports forced us to devote our attention to the export half of the
trade equation. President Carter's announcement of a National Export Policy reflects a recognition of the importance of our trade balance to the overall state of our
economy.
The National Export Policy, which is only a modest beginning, is more important
for its creation than for any of its particular elements. Increased authorizations for
the export-import bank, enhanced export promotion programs at Commerce and
State, the ongoing study of export disincentives, a computerized system of foreign
market opportunities-these and other aspects of the export policy are all vitally
important, even though we must recognize that they fall short of the government
support often afforded to foreign firms. In short, the elements of the National
Export Policy announced by President Carter last fall are important economic
measures; the policy from which they spring, however, is still in its infancy. A
primary goal of the National Export Policy is to foster a change in attitude. Policies
to provide greater assistance to exporters and to minimize export disincentives are
only a small part of the answer. Other policies, including agreements regulating
government assistance offered to competing foreign suppliers, will be necessary.
Japan presents unique problems, even though the Japanese have shown greater
awareness of their responsibility to reduce their trade surplus. In the Department of
Commerce, we are pursuing a strategy to increase U.S. firms' awareness of business
opportunities in the Japanese market. It was as a part of this effort that I led a.
large U.S. export development mission to Japan last October. We also are continuing to campaign intensively through the newly created Trade Facilitation Committee to remove or reduce specific Japanese impediments to imports which our exporters have identified. In their discussions with Secretary Blumenthal last week, the
Japanese indicated that they recognize the significance of this problem.
By these steps we have begun to facilitate the exporting process. We cannot
expect instant results. I know that you in Congress have a strong interest in
assisting U.S. exports, and this subject may be considered this year in connection
with the multilateral trade negotiations (MTN) and other legislation. Indeed, a
logical next step on export policy may be to integrate implementation of the MTN
with a strengthened export expansion drive.
PRODUCTIvrry

Finally I should like to touch briefly on the subject of productivity. The decline in
productivity growth is central to our domestic problem of inflation and the threat
which it poses to the expansion of production and employment. Productivity growth
lagging behind that of industries abroad places our producers at a disadvantage in
international trade and contributes to the whole complex of problems that arise
from a prolonged trade deficit.
The last decade has witnessed a remarkable slowdown in the rate of productivity
growth in the United States. Last year labor productivity in the private economy
increased by only 0.5 percent compared to an increase of 1.5 percent during 1977.
This compares to a trend rate of growth of about 3.1 percent annually between 1950
and 1967, and a 2.3 percent trend rate from 1967 to 1973.
The greatest slump in productivity growth is centered in nonmanufacturing sectors, particularly construction, mining, and retail trade. While overall productivity
in manufacturing has declined by less, serious problems have been encountered in
many industries.
A number of possible factors account for declining productivity: the end of migration out of the low-productivity farm sector; the shift toward a younger, less experienced work force; expenditures for pollution abatement and worker safety, the

379
benefits of which are not counted in our national economic accounts; slower growth
recently in the amount of capital per worker; and a lag in research and development expenditures. The Department of Commerce recently has completed a comprehensive review of our knowledge about the causes of the decline in productivity
growth. I have attached to my statement a copy of this paper. Our work on the
subject is continuing.
Another matter of central importance to the pace of productivity growth is the
rate of innovation in industry-the focus of a domestic policy review, undertaken in
May of 1978 pursuant to President Carter's instruction. Among other things, this
review deals with the effects on industrial innovation of such Federal policies as
procurement, patents and information, direct support of research and development,
environmental, health and safety regulations, and regulation of industry structure
and competition. The role of small business in the innovation process will be a
special concern of this policy review.
Senior executives from industry, labor, academic and public interest communities
have participated in the review, as well as policymakers from more than 30 Federal
agencies. Public participation culminated in a series of public symposia in January.
Recommendations will be delivered to President Carter at the end of March.
This study has obvious implications for trade, particularly since the United
States' greatest comparative advantage has been in the high-technology industries.
Both the rate of industrial innovation and the broader question of general productivity growth affect the whole gamut of the Nation's economic problems and deserve
our highest-priority attention. As we continue our work on these issues, which must
comprise important elements of any national industrial policy, we shall be happy to
keep the Committee informed.
Mr. Chairman, that concludes my prepared remarks. I shall be pleased to respond
to any questions the Committee might have.
Attachment.
THE PRODucTIvITY DECLINE: ITS CAUSES AND EFFECTS'.
The answer to the productivity enigma probably will be found only among the
nuts and bolts of industry (to adapt the "needle-in-a-haystack" metaphor to an
industrial setting). The Department of Commerce is examining these nuts and bolts,
using its expertise on individual industrial sectors plus its economic and technical

specialists.
Significance of the productivity decline
Average labor productivity in the private domestic economy rose by 3.1 percent
per year from 1950 to 1967, but its growth slowed to 2.3 percent from 1967 to 1973
and dropped to 1.2 percent from 1973 to 1977, partly because of the recession. For
sensible comparisons it is vital to measure productivity growth between years of
comparable capacity utilization. Many statements ignore this principle. The years
chosen above appear to be the best for comparison, although capacity utilization in

1977 was considerably below that in 1967 or 1973.
Labor productivity is a simplified concept that fails to take account of the
amounts of capital and other resources combined with labor in the production
process. To the extent that the growth of labor productivity approximates that of
total factor productivity, rising real output per hour worked is the basis for rising
real income per hour. In fact, slower growth in output per work hour since 1967 has
been associated with slower real income growth. If productivity had continued to
rise since 1967 at its previous rate, its level (and by inference real income per hour
worked) would be more than 15 percent higher than it is.
This income gain would have been realized primarily in terms of lower domestic
prices and perhaps a somewhat higher exchange rate. The most marked slowdown

in productivity growth has occurred, however, in sectors which are not much involved in international trade.
Confirmed reasons for the slowdown
The end of shift from farming to higher-productivity sectors accounted for one-

fifth to one-quarter of the productivity decline; this shift was traceable to a one-time
revolution in farm technology that will not be repeated.
'A synopsis submitted to the Productivity Council. Prepared by the Office of the Chief
Economist, Department of Commerce, February 1979.

380
OFGROWTH OFPRODUCTIVITY
TABLE 1.-AVERAGE ANNUAL RATE
1950-67

Construction .3.2
Mining .4.4
Transportation............................................................
..............
Communication
Utilities......................................................................
Wholesale trade.........................................................
Retail trade................................................................
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Services.....................................................................
Durable manufacturing .....................................
Nondurable manufacturing.....................................

(2)
1967-77

(1)-(2)
Change

-1.8
-1.9
2.3
5.5
2.0
1.8
1.5
0.5
0.9
2.2
3.3

2.9
5.2
5.9
2.6
2.3
0.3
1.2
2.2
3.0

- 5.0
-6.3
- 0.6
0.3
- 3.9
-0.8
-0.8
0.2
-0.3
0.0
0.3

ANNUAL AVERAGE
CONTRIBUTION TOTOTAL
TABLE 2.-GROWTH IN PRODUCTIVITY WITHIN SECTORS,
(1)

Construction

1950-67

~~

~ ~~(2)
(1) -(2)

1967-77

Construction..............................................................
Mining ..
Transportation............................................................
Communication ..

0.24
15
.19
10

-0.12
-.04
.13
.17

Utilities......................................................................

.13

.06

Wholesale trade.........................................................
Retail trade...............................................................
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Services.................... ................................................
Durable manufacturing .....................................
Nondurable manufacturing.....................................
Total private nonfarm .2.35

.19
.33
.03
.16
.42
.41

.14
.19
.05
.12
.45
.44
1.59

Change

-0.36
-.19
- .06
.07
- .07
-. 05
- .14
.02
-.04
.03
.03
- .76

October
1978.
Source:
Council
onWage
andPrice
Stability,
"Inflation
Update,"

The shift toward a younger, less experienced work force accounts for another 20
to 25 percent of the decline but should be largely reversed in the next 10 to 15
years, as the number of new workers declines and the large group that entered the
labor force from 1965 to 1980 moves into its most productive years.
Pollution abatement and worker safety expenditures: Denison has ascribed a
growing productivity cost to these factors (cf. Survey of Current Business, January
1978). Their effect on true productivity (including benefits not measured in the
national income accounts) presumably was positive in the early stage of implementing these policies, given the heavy industrialization of the United States and the
lack of attention to pollution and many aspects of worker safety before the mid1960's. The costs now are rising rapidly, however, and it is time to reexamine the
efficacy of these and other regulatory standards set for the 1980's.
The collapse of productivity in three nonmanufacturing sectors accounted for 90
percent of the net decline in nonfarm productivity growth shown in Table 2.
Construction: Despite intense controversy about the accuracy of the statistics, our
research indicates that the productivity decline is more than a figment of the data.
Measurement problems cannot account for any substantial part of the apparent
productivity plunge. A technical paper by the Office of the Chief Economist, Department of Commerce, is available on this issue. The construction labor force has
shown an even greater shift toward inexperienced workers than the economy as a
whole, however, and we are continuing to examine this sector to identify other
sources of this disappointing performance.
Mining: Mine health and safety regulations, reclamation statutes and new union
rules have cut coal mining productivity sharply (40 percent underground since 1969
and 28 percent in surface mines since 1973). Many inexperienced workers also have
entered this sector. Reopening of marginal mines also has contributed to declining
productivity. Coal prices would have risen anyway after cartelization of oil prices,

381
and tighter safety and reclamation regulations were good ways to spend some of the
revenues. Excess profits seem now to have been absorbed, however, and future
policy must proceed with caution to balance needs for energy, exports, environmental protection and worker safety. No such windfall price increases have come to the
aid of other mining sectors. Some of the productivity losses in those sectors have
been caused by production cutbacks due to low demand.
Retail and Wholesale Trade: The lag in productivity growth in retail trade seems
to be concentrated, according to the figures, in foodstores and eating and drinking
establishments (30 percent of the retail sector). Productivity in foodstores dropped
by about 9 percent from 1972 to 1974, followed by a very meager recovery. At the
same time, chain foodstores substantially shortened their hours in the wake of the
energy shortages of autumn 1973, which should have boosted productivity. Moreover, automated cash registers introduced in recent years should make inventory
and resupply procedures more efficient. Productivity in eating and drinking establishments has been virtually stagnant (growing at 0.5 percent per year) for the
period, 1966-1977. This too defies explanation in light of the rapid spread during
this period of supposedly efficient fast-food chains. Flagging productivity in these
retail sectors was partly offset by the major boost in output per labor hour in
gasoline service stations, especially with the widespread introduction of "gas and
go" stations since 1975. Productivity growth in wholesale trade remained strong
through 1973 but appears to have collapsed since then; this requires explanation.
Release of the 1977 Economic Census within the next few months will provide a new
basis for examination of this poorly documented sector.
Other debatable propositionsabout the slowdown
A Slowdown in Capital-Labor Ratios: It often is alleged that slower growth of
capital-labor ratios since 1967-in other words, a deficiency of capital investmentis responsible for slower growth of productivity. This would not be surprising in
view of the sudden acceleration in labor force growth after 1965 due to demographic
factors. If one focuses on business structures and equipment, one finds that the
growth of the net stock of this type of capital accelerated in the period, 1966 to 1973,
but the capital-labor ratio grew somewhat more slowly than in the earlier period2.8 versus 3 percent per year. On closer examination, however, lower investment in
the farm sector accounts entirely for the slowdown in the capital-labor ratio, for the
substitution of capital for labor in farming was largely completed by 1966. In the
nonfarm business sector there was a slight acceleration in the capital-labor ratio
even after excluding pollution abatement expenditures.
After 1973, however, growth of the capital-labor ratio slowed down. Clearly the
recession of 1974-75 had a major negative impact, and the recovery was by no
means complete by 1977 (the latest data year). The unprecedented declines in the
net capital-labor ratio in 1976 and 1977 stem from the much publicized lag in
business investment during this recovery period together with the exceptionally
rapid employment growth. The lag in investment presumably was due to the extent
of unused capacity in many sectors plus a reluctance to invest in the face of
exceptional uncertainty about economic conditions, energy prices and regulatory
changes. Also, the prices of capital goods have risen very sharply since 1973.
A slowdown in research and development: Confusingly diverse statements are
heard on this subject because of the disparate trends in civilian R. & D. versus
military-space R. & D. Total R. & D. declined in real terms from 1968 to 1972,
because of reductions in the high levels of military and space R. & D. of the 1960's.
It regained its 1968 level only in 1977. Real civilian R. & D. has risen every year
except 1975 and, since 1973, has tended to revive somewhat as a share of GNP. In
particular, large increases in company-funded R. & D. in 1973 and 1976 plus boosts
in federal funding for energy and environmental R. & D. in 1977 and 1978 have
raised the total. Projections of civilian R. & D. spending for 1979 indicate little, if
any, increase as a fraction of GNP. (See table and charts that follow.)
The shift from goods to services production: The broadly defined services sector
has an average productivity level as high as the goods-producing sector, because of
the highly capitalized and rapidly expanding utilities, communications and transportation services sectors. The narrowly defined services sector, on the other hand,
has grown rapidly with low productivity but remains only about 15 percent of the
economy and incapable of explaining a large part of the productivity slowdown. An
intermediate version of this proposition might explain more, e.g., one encompassing
narrowly defined services plus retail and wholesale trade. We are examining this
variant.
It is worth pointing out that productivity growth in manufacturing did not decline
significantly before 1973. Its decline since 1973 can be explained largely by lower
capacity utilization. Agricultural productivity continues to grow rapidly. This tends

47-977 0 - 79 - 25

382
to imply that our lagging trade performance is not due to a productivity bust in
sectors engaged in trade (although other nations' manufacturing productivity may
be growing faster). It also suggests that proposals to solve productivity problems
that concentrate on manufacturing may put the emphasis in the wrong place.

Table 3

Trends in

National

Federal Goverent
"All Civilian 1/"
I(mil. i97-2$) ---

Year

R&D Funds, Excluding Federal Funds for NationalDefense
and Space; 1969-1979

(mtil.

2
Private Industry
(percent denge)
1972$)

842

mil. 1972$)

Total
(percent change)

1970

4,121
4, 234

2.7

11,484

-1.1

878

4.3

16,596

0.1

1971

4,751

12.2

11,311

-1.5

931

6.0

16,993

2.4

1972

4,882

2.8

11,698

3.4

960

3.1

17,540

3.2

1973

4,975

1.9

12,718

8.7

985

2.6

18,681

6.5

1974

5,263

5.8

13,204

3.8

1,001

1.6

19,468

4.2

1975

5,456

3.7

12,670

-4.1

1,012

1.1

19,138

-1.7

1976

5,575

2.2

13,356

5.4

1,038

2.6

19,969

4.3

1977 (prelim)

6,324

13.4

13,871

3.9

1,064

2.5

21,259

6.5

1978 (est)

6,903

9.2

14,320

3.2

1,118

5.1

22,341

5.1

1979 (est) /

7,125

3.2

14,647

2.3

1,136

1.6

22,908

2.5

1969

11,613

All Other &/ /
(mil. 1972J)
(percent change)

CO
CO5

Conpound Annual Rate
of Change 1969-79

5.6

2.3

_

13 areas, including Health, Energy, Science, Environment.

?/

Limited amounts of privately funded military and space-related research is
included in these categories.

2/

Universities, Colleges, and other non-profit institutions.

/

16,577

An 8-percent inflation rate is assumid
Source:

National Science Foundation

3.0

3.3

384
Chart 1

2-9.
Federal obligations for R&Dby major function, 1969-76
;, -

f
. rndoirn
i~~~iniaut~

~~

*

*

Coarad 1s72dollarn'

.

,n

,
x

.

reg

S12

$12

11

11

10

10

Silhlar
7/

r, A

Rf/

50.
S
SAll
chilian
RA

-1R

-d:

--

- -- -4

4

I

71

7t

71

'73

Se

75

7ic

1969

71

7t

75

7iS.R

75

76

1969,

71

73

70

76

o
1969

.

A..t.7tJ
SWmwIR

ICI

1-..w-2

eLiwlb

55

385
Thoughts about the future

Maintaining good business conditions is the most important productivity policy.
All others are futile without this. Recession would reverse productivity and business
investment growth and set them back permanently.
Recognize the potential of natural corrective forces. The progress of knowledge
continues, and a backlog of opportunities for productive investments accumulates
during periods of poor business conditions such as those dominating the past ten
years. This backlog can be unlocked by the return of better business conditions and
greater confidence in the future.
Focus regulatory policy to stress the use of approaches based on cost-effectiveness,
flexibility in application and clear, well-specified objectives.
The very quick and substantial productivity payoff from relaxing regulation in
the airline industry suggests that consideration should be given to actions that
unlock existing potential by increasing competition (e.g., in surface transportation,
communications, the professions, etc.) and that reduce government-imposed costs
through cutting paperwork and other regulatory burdens.
Policies dealing with industrial innovation-patent policies, R. & D. spending, tax
provisions or government loans-are the concerns of the Interagency Industrial
Innovation Task Force, which will report on its findings shortly.
Other important types of policies affecting productivity are tax policies, training
and technology policies, and industrial adjustment policies. No attempt is made here
to elaborate on these. Meanwhile, efforts are being made to improve the measurement and analysis of productivity.
AVERAGE
ANNUAL RATES
OFCHANGE INOUTPUT FOR
EMPLOYEE HOURS FOR
SELECTED
INDUSTRIES,
1947-66 AND 1966-76
Industry
(SIC
cde)

Mining:
Iron mining, usable ore (1011) ......................................
Copper mining, recoverable metal (1021) ......................................
Coal mining (111,121) ......................................
Bituminous coal and lignite mining (121) ......................................
Nonmetallic minerals (14) ......................................
Crushed and broken stone (142) .23.9
Manufacturing:
Canning and preserving (203) ..............
.....................
Grain mill products (204) ...................................
Flour and other grain mill products (2041) ...................................
Cereal breakfast foods (2043) ..............
.....................
Rice milling (2044) ....................................
Blended and prepared flour (2045) ...................................
Wet corn milling (2046) ....................................
Prepared feeds for animals and fowls (2047,48) .............................
Bakery products (2051) ...................................
Sugar (2061,62,63) ...................................
Candy and confectionery products (2065) ...................................
Malt beverages (2082) .........
..........................
Bottled and canned soft drinks (2086) ...................................
Tobacco products-total (2111,21,31) ...................................
Cigarettes, chewing and smoking tobacco (2111,31) ......................
Cigars (2121) ...................................
Hosiery (2251,52) ...................................
Sawmills and planing mills, general (2421) ...................................
Paper, paperboard, and pulp mills (2611,21,31,61) ........................
Corrugated and solid fiber boxes (2653) .........................................
Synthetic fibers (2823,24) ....................................
Pharmaceutical preparations (2834) ...................................
Paints and allied products (2851) ...................................
Petroleum refining (2911) ...................................
Tires and inner tubes (3011) ...................................
Footwear (314) ...................................
See footnotes at end of table.

1947-66

1966-76

3.8
3.6
6.6
6.8
14.1

2.7
34.0
4.0
32.0
8.5
s4.7
2.1
3

2.0
4.6
3.5
4.3
22.2
3.7
1.4
6.6
4.8
23.5
3.9
23.2
4.1
35.0

23.7
5.9
4.2
1.9

0.8
-0.2
-3.5
-3.6
2.3
3.6
3.2
42.9
2.0
4l.2

41.3
41.4
45.3

43.4
1.8
1.5
4.7
6.7
3.2
1.7
1.3
2.7
8.7
2.1
3.5
4.5
8.1
4.8
2.5
3.1
2.3
0.4

386
INDUSTRIES,
EMPLOYEE
HOURS
FOR
SELECTED
OFCHANGE INOUTPUT FOR
AVERAGE
ANNUAL RATES
1947-66 AND 1966-76-Continued
Industry
(SICcode)

1966-76

1947-66

2.2
1.7
3.5
3.5
3.3

.............................
Glass containers (3221)
...................................
Hydraulic cement (3241)
.
Structural clay (325) ...................................
;.
...............
.
Clay construction products (3251,53,59)
..............................
Clay refractories (3255)
Concrete products (3271,72)
..
......................
*
.::.,..22.3
Ready-mixed concrete (3273) ............... .
:...........................
Steel (331) .....
............................
Gray iron foundries (3321)
..
Steel foundries (3324,25)
..........................
Primary copper, lead, and zinc (3331,32,33) .
.
.
...
Primary aluminum (3334)
:
.
..
...
Copper rolling and drawing (3351)
Aluminum rolling and drawing (3353,54,55) ...................................
Metal cans (3411) ....................
..
.............
.
.
Major household appliances (3631,32,33,39)
Radio and television receiving sets (3651) ......................................
Motor vehicles and equipment (371) ......................................

1.3
4.7
23.3
23.1
24.0
3.2

1.7
2.4
'...........:.:......
1.8
2.6
5.3
6.7
26.6
2.5
26.8
26.1
s4.8

1.8
2.6
1.9
2.3
1.2
. -0.5
5.8
1.7
4.6
3.2
3.4

Railroads, revenue traffic (401 Class 1).
.....................................
..
Intercity trucking (4213 PT.)
...........
Intercity trucking (general freight) (4213 PT.) .
............................
Air transportation (4511)
Petroleum pipelines (4612,13)
.........................
.'
Telephone communications (4811) .......................
.....................................
Gas and electric utilities (491,92,93) .
Retail food stores (54)
...............................
Franchised new car dealers (5511) ......................................
Gasoline service stations (5541) ...........
....
Eating and drinking places (58)
........................
........................
Hotels and motels (7011) ...........

4.6
'........................
2.8
2.4
7.9
29.6

3.4
42.3
'2.0
4.4
6.0
5.6
3.6
0.8
2.5
4.3
0.5
1.3

.

41.9

21.4

Other:

7.2

7.3
23.1
22.5
22.8
'......
20.9

22.7

*1954-66.
21958-66.

*1963-66.
1966-75.
1957-66.
*1966-74.
1951-66.
Statistics,
U.S.Dpartment
ofLabor.
Source:
Bureau
ofLabor

Representative MITCHELL. Mr. Marshall, before you begin, please
understand that I am not attempting to impose any time constraints, but I know that the Secretary has to leave at 11:15 this
morning and obviously the members of the committee want to
question her. Could you give me an idea as to how long you will be
testifying, roughly? In doing so, I can make a determination as to
whether or not we go into questions now.
Secretary MARSHALL. It won't take me any more than, I think, 20
minutes at most to do and I can accelerate that if you want me to.
Representative MITCHELL. I would appreciate it. I know the members want to hear your testimony. Would you limit your testimony
to 15 minutes.
Secretary MARSHALL. All right.

387
Representative MITCHELL. That will give us an 'pportuAity
to
question both of you.
Senator JAVITS. Congressman Mitchell, may I just apologize.
I cannot stay. I am handling the Taiwan bit'on the floor. They
are both friends, even though I cannot stay for questions.
Representative MITCHELL. We will also be debating the Taiwan
issue on the House side.
Mr. Secretary, please proceed.
STATEMENT OF HON. RAY MARSHALL, SECRETARY OF LABOR
Secretary MARSHALL. Thank you.

Congressman Mitchell, members of the committee, the first part
of my prepared statement which I will simply summarize with
your permission and enter into the record, deals with the progress
that we made in dealing with the problem of unemployment.
I think that you are well aware of that but I think it is important to emphasize that we are making substantial progress, and
have made substantial progress towards achieving the HumphreyHawkins employment goal of 4 percent.
The decline that we have witnessed in the last year is nearly
twice as large as the average annual reduction needed to reach
that objective and it makes me be optimistic that in spite of the
fact that it will be difficult to do it, that we nevertheless can do it;
that is, that unemployment was just under 8 percent and is now
under 6, and we have gone more than halfway toward that 4percent objective.
Inflation remains a problem and, as Secretary Kreps pointed out,
the decline in the value of the dollar is a problem. We think that,
because of the decline of cyclical unemployment, in the immediate
future we should concentrate on structural problems in the economy, both on the unemployment side and on the inflation side.
The reason for that is that the most effective way to deal with
the problem of inflation at this juncture is to reduce structural
unemployment among those who are not in short supply, who have
much higher unemployment rates than the average, and, therefore,
who will not contribute to the inflationary pressures or labor shortage in any way as a result of their entering the work force.
In fact, we think the contrary is the case, that it is much less
inflationary to have people enter the work force than most of the
alternatives available. There is a structural aspect of inflation
which manifests itself in differential rates of inflation in different
parts of the economy.
This is true of the labor market as well as product markets and
we think, therefore, that it is important to concentrate on the
structural aspects with both inflation and unemployment.
I think it would be a mistake if your opening question implied
for us to ignore, however, the possibility of a cyclical downswing.
We don't expect a significant downswing but we think we need to
be prepared for it in the Department of Labor and in the administration. As you recall on the CETA reauthorization bill we main-

tained the capability of increasing the countercyclical jobs program
if we needed to do that and the problems of rising unemployment
are above the amount that we expect.

388
What we think is required at this stage is to concentrate heavily
on the problem of inflation. The reason for that is that we believe
that if we don't bring inflation under control it will be very difficult for us to achieve Humphrey-Hawkins objectives. That is, we
will have a recession and that recession will lead to rising unemployment and a rising Federal budget deficit.
With respect to the deficit we think that the $29 billion is about
right. I do not think it would be a good idea to try to balance the
budget every year. I think there is no evidence that a balanced
budget guarantees a healthy economy.
The budget should be viewed as the result of the economy as well
as causing the economic activity. We should look at the relationship between the rising unemployment, for example, and the
budget deficit as well as the effect of the deficit on inflation.
There is no necessary relationship between the budget deficit
and inflation.
We don't believe-and my prepared statement goes into some
detail on this-that there is much evidence of tightness of the labor
market now that contributes to inflationary pressure. We rather
believe that the inflationary pressures are caused by things outside
of the labor market. But we do believe that we should use this
opportunity and this occasion of a tight budget and within the
budget constraints, to concentrate most of our resources on the
people who need the most help.
I call your attention to the fact that that is what we are doing in
the CETA system. Until the CETA reauthorization of 1978, in order
to be eligible for the CETA programs, you had to be unemployed or
disadvantaged. Now you must be unemployed and disadvantaged.
We believe that it is also important for us to improve the system
not only by targeting but by concentrating more of our resources to
try to develop linkages between the public employment training
system and the regular economy.
So, in short, Congressman Mitchell, we believe that we can
achieve those Humphrey-Hawkins objectives. We believe the evidence we have put together so far in reducing unemployment
indicates the way that we can do that.
We believe that the mechanisms are outlined in the HumphreyHawkins bill it would make it possible for us to accomplish those
objectives. We do believe that we have to concentrate much more
in the next year or year and a half on containing inflation while
we simultaneously reduce the differentials in unemployment rates.
I express that because, even though the overall unemployment
rate will probably not go down, we can do a lot to cause the
differentials to be reduced by concentrating most of our resources
on the people and places with the highest levels of unemployment.
We believe that that will also help with the inflation fight because many of the sources of inflationary pressures in our economy
originate during recessions. That is, the time that we don't invest
in people through education and training. When we are operating
at partial capacity that we don't get the investment in plant and
equipment and a failure to get investment tends to be one of the
factors responsible for declining productivity. All of those things
show up as inflationary pressures when the economy improves.

-

389

I think that what we need to do on the inflation front is to
improve the operation of the labor market, improve the training of
people in our labor market information system, and improve the
effectiveness of our program so that we use public resources as
efficiently as possible. I think we need to concentrate on the sectors
of the economy that tend to be most responsible for inflationary
pressures-food, energy, health, and housing-and to do everything
that we can to overcome the inflationary pressures that appear in
those sectors of the economy. That is essentially the policy that we
have developed.
Our overall wage-price standards are designed to concentrate
public attention on above-average increases in wages and prices
and then to try to hold down those wage and price increases to
standards that we have established. We will take other measures to
relieve shortages if shortages exist, to overcome market power that
tends to make it possible for people to increase their wages and
prices when there are no shortages, and to introduce as much
stability as we can in the system. I believe that one of the main
ways that we can reduce the inflationary pressures that tend to
show up in the economy is to generate stability because a careful
examination of those pressures indicates that many of them are
due to instability.
Congressman Mitchell, I will end my testimony there.
I have a white paper that, with your permission, I would like to
put into the record also that we prepared on the CETA system and
its role in achieving the Humphrey-Hawkins objectives of both 4percent unemployment and stable prices.
Representative MITCHELL. Without objection, your prepared
statement and white paper will be entered into the record at this
point.
[The prepared statement of Secretary Marshall and the white
paper entitled "The New Comprehensive Employment and Training Program" follow:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HON. RAY MARSHALL

Good morning Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am pleased to be
here to discuss the current economic situation before this Committee.
Last year substantial progress was made towards the Humphrey-Hawkins Act
unemployment goal. Employment increased by 3.9 percent (3.6 million persons)
between the fourth quarter of 1977 and the fourth quarter of 1978. Over the same
period, the unemployment rate dropped from 6.6 percent to 5.8 percent. This decline
is nearly twice as large as the average annual reduction needed to reach the 4.0
percent goal in 1983.
But the news on the price front was discouraging. The Consumer Price Index, for
example, rose 9 percent between December 1977 and December 1978. In addition,
the value of the dollar deteriorated sharply, largely as the result of faster growth
here than abroad. These two adverse developments led to decisions to slow the rate
of economic growth during the 1979-90 period to avoid the possibility of making
. inflation worse by overheating the economy.
During the period of slow growth it is especially important that we proceed with
structural programs designed to reduce unemployment among those most in need
since their prospects will not be improved over the next few years by overall
economic growth. Furthermore, it is an important time to make progress with
structural programs designed to reduce inflation. If these programs are successful,
economic growth can be increased in subsequent years. The next two years should
be viewed as a time when the impacts of structural programs are allowed to catch
up with the impacts of past aggregate demand growth.
In addition, given the state of the art of economic forecasting, it is essential that
we maintain the countercyclical capacity of public service employment as now

390
specified by Title VI of the Comprehensive Employment and Training Act, to
protect workers if our forecasts are incorrect.
Role of aggregate demand

I want to emphasize that the Administration wants to moderate the growth of
aggregate demand, not to stop it, much less to move the economy into recession.
We feel that a deficit of $29 billion is the right deficit for the economy at this
time. A higher deficit would increase by too much the risk of worsening inflation
and a lower deficit would reduce by too much the prospects for economic growth at
an acceptable level. The $29 billion figure is consistent with our need to balance our
dual objectives of lowering inflation and unemployment.
There are those who argue that we should be required to balance our budget at
all times. I do not agree with this view. Balanced Federal budgets do not guarantee
a healthy economy. The largest deficit of the last five years occurred in fiscal year
1976, a year in which the inflation rate was 5.9 percent; the lowest deficit was
registered in a year in which the inflation rate was 11 percent. It is simply not true
that the size of the deficit is proportional to the inflation rate. The appropriate
deficit or surplus depends on the state of the rest of the economy.
The policy we have chosen for 1979 and 1980 is one of moderate growth. We feel
unemployment rates are already at high enough levels to preclude the possibility of
a surge in inflation because of labor shortages. In fact, there is a substantial margin
between existing employment rates and rates that have been associated in the past
with accelerating inflation.
It has become popular to quote the unemployment rate for prime-age males, men
aged 25 through 54, as the rate most closely associated with inflation. This rate
dropped from 3.9 percent during the fourth quarter of 1977 to 3.3 percent during the
fourth quarter of last year, but it remained well above the 2.5 percent rate averaged
in 1973 when inflationary pressures arose. Other demographic, geographic, occupational, and industrial measures of unemployment show similar patterns-substantial improvement over a year ago, but levels well above those that existed in 1973.
This thesis is also supported by observing where the greatest increases in prices
occurred. Although the CPI increased 9 percent last year, the prices of goods,
excluding food and the cost of mortgage interest payments, rose only 7.7 percent.
Acceleration of food price inflation and mortgage interest costs cannot be attributed
to labor market pressures. These factors tend to cause higher wage rates rather
than to be caused by them. Import price increases, the widening of profit margins,
and the reduction of productivity growth were all important sources of the increase
in inflation in 1978. None of these were caused by wage pressures. The larger wage
increases that did take place in 1978 were no higher than historical experience
indicates should be expected when price inflation accelerates as it did during that
year.
Unfortunately this exogenous inflation is projected to continue in 1979, and to be
made worse by energy price problems which did not bother us a year ago.
The economy ended 1978 with considerable forward momentum-high sales, low
inventories, high levels of business fixed investment-and with the prospect of a
substantial personal and business income tax cut this year. This will maintain
growth at a reasonable rate through the first part of the year. Later, however,
growth may slow.
Since the only possible justification for slower growth is to reduce inflation, it is
essential that we make progress during this period with our anti-inflation program.
And, since an undeniable characteristic of slow growth is a lack of progress against
unemployment, it is important we use this period to strengthen our structural
programs so unemployment continues to fall among those most in need. Simultaneous progress against both inflation and unemployment requires successful structural programs addressed to both problems. These programs are linked to our
overall economic policy through the Humphrey-Hawkins framework.
Reducing structuralunemployment

Reducing structural unemployment is an integral part of Humphrey-Hawkins Act
strategy.
Recent research indicates that increased employment of the hard-to-employ exerts
little, if any, current inflationary pressure. In the long run we believe it reduces
inflation, because it adds to the supply of skilled workers.
Employment and training programs conducted through the Labor Department
have been and will continue to be more and more closely targeted toward those
individuals whose chronic unemployment or underemployment is due to lack of
adequate preparation for the labor market as reflected by their low incomes. Our
progress in targeting these programs has been gratifying. Economically disadvan-

391
taged enrollees as a proportion of the total rose from 47 percent in fiscal year 1976
to 61 percent for fiscal year 1978 for programs conducted under Title II, from 44
percent to 80 percent under Title VI and from 76 percent to 80 percent under
Title I.
The first results of the Continuous Longitudinal Manpower Survey are now in
and they indicate that local CETA programs have in fact been effective in improving the labor force experience of enrollees. This survey is our basic source of data on
program participants.
While gratifying, the Department of Labor views these results as only the beginning of progress that can be made. This year CETA programs will be expanded to
meet a broader range of individual needs and will be even more carefully targeted
to reach those in greatest need. Connections with the private sector will be strengthened, through private industry councils, implementation of the targeted employment tax credit, cooperation with non-profit agencies, and improvement of the Job
Service. I am including for the record the Labor Department's White Paper on the
new Comprehensive Employment and Training Program, which describes these
changes in more detail.
Moreover, existing programs should do a better job this year. Partly this will
result from strengthened management at the national and regional office levels,
from a number of increased controls over abuse required by the CETA reauthorization, and from an entirely new program of management assistance for local program managers. In addition, it will result from the experience local program managers have themselves gained in working with economically disadvantaged persons
and learning how best to produce the improvements in skills and experience required both for the needs of the sponsor and for the improved employability of the
enrollee.
In summary, our structural employment programs will continue to support our
overall objectives of reducing unemployment and inflation and of distributing the
burden of unemployment more equitably among our citizens. We expect to make
progress this year in improving the quality of these programs and in determining
the quantitative links between these programs and the overall goals.
Structuralprograms to reduce inflation

The anti-inflation program announced by the President last October is off to a
good start. The American public generally wants to break the wage-price spiral that
began over ten years ago. Compliance is now the rule, noncompliance the exception.
The program is expected to reduce this year's price inflation by three-quarters of a
percentage point from what would otherwise have been the case.
Given anticipated food and energy price inflation during 1979, however, it is
important that every avenue of potential price deceleration be explored. Compliance
can be expected to continue if workers' real. incomes are preserved, but not necessarily if they are eroded by price inflation. I would therefore like to discuss some of
the areas where additional anti-inflationary initiatives have been taken.
Last April, the President called for the development of special programs to deal
with individual sectors of the economy where government actions have the greatest
potential for reducing inflation. He specifically named housing, medical care, food,
transportation, energy, and primary metals as sectors to be investigated.
Some progress has been made. The Administration's hospital cost containment
program is one example. Changes in airline regulations that produced dramatic
improvements in productivity and reductions in fares are another.
On a smaller scale, the Department of Labor has organized tripartite committees,
representing business, labor, and government for the purpose of increasing productivity in specific industries. In Chicago such committees are attempting to reduce
seasonality in construction. In Massachusetts labor-management committees are
acting to improve productivity of workers in municipal governments.
It is noteworthy that many CETA employees are reducing the demand for energy
by weatherproofing low-income housing while learning their trades.
But clearly much more can be done. I would recommend the establishment of
targets and time constraints to investigate special sectors demonstrating high inflation rates. We need to find specific solutions to specific problems, both large and
small. Enlistment of microeconomists and program operators in helping to manage
the battle against inflation may prove to be the decisive factor in the outcome.
Achieving Humphrey-Hawkins Act goals

The short and long terms goals described in the Economic Report of the President
are achievable, though difficult. I have been asked to address the unemployment
goals in particular.

392
Prospects of obtaining the economic growth required to hold the unemployment
rate in the neighborhood of 6 percent during 1979 are good. Despite monetary
stringency, the economy entered this year with foreward momentum and with few
dangerous imbalances; current growth also is receiving the stimulation produced by
personal and business income tax reductions.
The improvement of growth and reduction of unemployment forecast for 1980, on
the other hand, depends heavily on progress made this year in reducing inflation. If
the President's wage and price guidelines are supplemented with significant structural efforts to reduce inflation in particular sectors, this progress can be made, and
macroeconomic growth can proceed towards levels required to reach HumphreyHawkins Act goals.
Near-term uncertainty, however, means that it is necessary to preserve built-in
stabilizing capacity within our economic system. These include the countercyclical
capacity of Title VI of the Comprehensive Employment and Training Act. If the
economy were to begin to slip into recession, some of the impact could be absorbed
by the provision of title VI which provides authority for the President to request an
increase in funding for public service employment when unemployment rises.
Beyond 1980, faster growth will be required-though not unusually fast by historical standards. The constraint beyond 1980 will not be our ability to grow, but our
ability to avoid inflation. The unemployment reductions needed will not be as large
as those we have experienced recently. In less than four years, the unemployment
rate has fallen 3.3 percentage points. What remains is an additional 1.8 percentage
points of decline to be accomplished in 4¾ years. Even from 1980 on, what will be
needed is a reduction of 2.2 points in three years, clearly not larger than our
average progress over the last four years. The trick is to accomplish this growth
without inflation. That is why our structural anti-inflation program is so important.
It will also be important to avoid a recession. As I discussed before this Committee last year, I believe that recessions may even raise inflation rates in the long run.
Improvement must continue in the skills of the American labor force, partly as the
result of training and public service employment programs, but largely the result of
experience working in the private economy. Capital investment required between
now and 1983 must also proceed on schedule if Humphrey-Hawkins goals are to be
met. Nothing will reduce capital accumulation more than a recession.
In addition, international economic policy and immigration policy must be coordinated with manpower goals established under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. Meeting
these goals will be extremely difficult within the context of a world economy that
has not yet recovered from recession. If the U.S. labor force had grown as it has, but
our employment performance had paralleled that of Europe and Japan, the unemployment rate would be over 20 percent in the United States today. Not only has
disparity between U.S. growth and growth abroad led to trade imbalances, and
deterioration of the value of the dollar; it has also led to increased propensities to
immigrate to the U.S. Under these conditions it will be necessary to look more
carefully at the domestic impacts of both legal and illegal immigration.
Given sustained economic growth, I remain optimistic that the Humphrey-Hawkins goals can be met. Careful targeting and other measures such as the project
approach are succeeding in reducing substitution connected with public service
employment programs. Job experience, even in training programs, has been found
to be an effective device for improving the employability of targeted workers.
Studies of the impacts on inflation of reducing unemployment of various groups now
point even more strongly to the probability that the unemployment rate of low-skill
workers has little if any impact on wage inflation. This means our structural
employment programs will support our anti-inflation effort and are an important
ingredient in reducing unemployment in a non-inflationary way.
Thank you very much. I will be happy to answer any questions which you may
have.
WHITE PAPER ON "THE NEW COMPREHENSIVE EMPLOYMENT AND TRAINING
PROGRAM"'
THE ROLE OF OUR EMPLOYMENT AND TRAINING SYSTEM
During the past several years employment and training programs have played an

increasingly important role in strengthening the performance of the American
economy and securing a more equitable distribution of its benefits. Employment and
training programs contribute to the efficiency of our economic system in several
ways. In times of strong economic growth they reduce inflationary pressures by

I Prepared

by the U.S. Department of Labor, Office of the Secretary.

393
improving the performance of labor markets, increasing worker productivity, and
expanding our supply of skilled workers. During economic downturns, by maintaining incomes, employment and skill levels and minimizing dependence on welfare
and unemployment, insurance, they set the stage for stable economic recovery.
Employment and training programs also contribute importantly to the equity of our
economic system by improving the access of all Americans to the opportunity to
support themselves and their families.
Direct employment policies have now become an important and permanent tool of
economic policy, strengthening the effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policies in
promoting stable economic growth and reducing the adverse side effects of both
economic expansion and contraction. Until recent years, however, employment and
training programs were too small in scale to permit measurement of their potential
effectiveness in this larger role.
Ten years ago employment and training programs were an insignificant item in
the U.S. budget. This year over $11.7 billion will be spent by the Federal Government for this purpose. The budget for Fiscal Year 1980 calls for expenditures of
$11.0 billion. The fundamental factor supporting this expansion is a growing national awareness that, even in periods of overall prosperity, sizeable investments must
still be made to assist those 'disadvantaged in the labor market by background,
location, or discrimination. But much of this immediate expansion has been in
response to economic recessions. This was the case when President Carter took
office while the country was enduring the high rate of unemployment which followed the 1973-74 recession. Since 1977, spending for Department of Labor jobs and
training programs has increased by 73 percent. Much of this was due to the
Economic Stimulus Package launched by this Administration. In contrast, there has
been only a 14 percent increase in spending for other discretionary federal programs
in this period. This fact, more than any other, provides a clear indication of the
high priority placed on employment programs by the Carter Administration.
CETA'S RECORD OF PERFORMANCE

Despite this unprecedented growth there can be little question that our employment and training system has performed well. Aggregate statistics tell one part of
the story. When President Carter took office, the unemployment rate was 7.8
percent. By December of 1978, it had fallen to 5.9 percent. A large part of this
improvement can be attributed to the normal resilience of the economy in recovering from a downturn in the business cycle. But substantial credit should go to both
macroeconomic policies of the Administration and the direct employment measures
initiated as part of the Economic Stimulus Package. Along with the 7.2 million jobs
created in the private sector, 1.3 million jobs and training opportunities were
created during this period by the various components of the Comprehensive Employment and Training Act (CETA).
CETA has helped assure that the benefits of economic recovery are extended to
all classes of workers including the most disadvantaged. For example, it is estimated
that a third of the increase in black employment (6 percent) experienced during this
period is directly attributable to the CETA job system. Employment gains for the
most disadvantaged groups were particularly impressive. Employment of black teenagers had actually decreased during the preceding 8 years, but has increased by 27
percent since the start of this Administration. About 22 percent of all black teenagers employed in October 1978 were working in youth programs under the CETA
system. During the Stimulus expansion, more than 86 percent of new CETA enrollees were economically disadvantaged. In the past, it had been less than half.
This dramatic expansion was done:
On schedule;
Without the creation of a large, new Federal bureaucracy;
Without high administrative expenses;
Without a significant degree of substitution of CETA workers for regular municipal employees; and
On a local basis. Bureaucrats sitting in Washington did not mandate what jobs
CETA workers could hold or the type of work they needed to do. On a local level,
thousands of innovative projects were launched such as park renovation in Boston,
home health care in North Carolina, bike trail building in Atlanta, water quality
monitoring in Wisconsin, river cleanup in Rochester, and weatherization of low
income homes in many locales.
These kinds of results in so short a period were due to the concerted efforts of an
enormous number of public and private institutions. The CETA system is made up
of over 26,000 operating units. They include the national and regional offices of the
Department of Labor and 460 State, county and local government units who, as the

394
CETA prime sponsors, subcontract with an estimated 25,000 non-profit and governmental organizations. There are also 54 State employment security agencies and 950
national CETA programs with hundreds of subcontractors. The roughly 1.3 million
CETA job and training slots serve almost 4 million economically disadvantaged
persons each year.
This experience has demonstrated that direct employment and training policies,
as administered through our decentralized CETA system, are an effective tool of
economic policy which can move rapidly and directly against the problem of unemployment. Recent analysis of CETA program experience confirms the findings of an
earlier Congressional Budget Office study that CETA is the most efficient tool of the
Federal Government to reduce unemployment. Additional dollars spent under the
CETA program produces three times as many jobs as dollars spent elsewhere in the
budget and with less inflationary pressure than more general stimulative policies.
THE NEED FOR 'A NEW STRATEGY

The range and diversity of our employment and training system is its greatest
asset. No unitary system could respond as quickly or effectively to the great diversity in community needs, population characteristics and labor market conditions that
exists throughout the country. CETA's connections to other governmental, community service and vocational organizations also enable local programs to build upon
the management and training capabilities of existing public and private organizations, assure that public service employees perform useful community services and
facilitate transition of participants to private sector employment.
While decentralization has many benefits, this complexity of structure, combined
with the recent pressures of unparalleled growth has placed great strain on the
employment and training system. In particular:
Faulty program design diluted resources available to meet the special needs of the
most disadvantaged workers.
Not enough attention was given to building closer links between the private
sector and employment program and training programs. While the percentage of
CETA program graduates placed in the private sector has been steady, there has
been no marked improvement.
There was inadequate attention paid to the development of management capability at each level of the system. Little has been done to identify, encourage and
replicate successful programs.
Effective monitoring and control systems were either not created or have not kept
pace with expanding system requirements. As a result, program abuse was not
successfully controlled or corrected.
These deficiencies must be remedied promptly if the system is to maintain public
confidence. Employment programs have generally benefited from strong public support. Even in the wake of Proposition 13 and other anti-tax initiatives, a detailed
public opinion survey recently conducted for the Department of Labor showed
strong public support for federal activities in direct employment and training.
Seventy-six percent of respondents supported direct job creation particularly for
priority groups such as low income persons and heads of families with children. Two
sentiments underlie this public support-a firm belief that people should be able to
work if they want to and that creating jobs is a cheaper way of assisting the
unemployed than providing welfare or unemployment benefits. Most of the public
also believes that public employment programs produce useful community services
and they support local control over the kinds of jobs created. Nonetheless there is
considerable public concern about abuses and inefficiencies in job program design
and administration.
We must respond to this concern promptly and effectively. Many promising social
programs have atrophied or been abandoned because management failures have
resulted in public disillusionment. Budget restraint increases the urgency of responding to the legitimate concerns of citizens that their tax dollars are used
effectively. This current mood provides us with a challenge to demonstrate that
public programs can be useful, efficient and effective.
During the last year, the Department of Labor has been developing a coordinated
plan for an improved employment and training system. Building upon important
new legislation, a series of regulatory and management initiatives have been undertaken to develop a system which is responsive, comprehensive, accountable and
manageable.
These initiatives, many of which are already being implemented, are described in
the following sections under the four major areas of required improvement:
(1) Improving service to those who most need assistance;
(2) Strengthening connections with the Private Sector;

395
(3) Improving program management; and
(4) Controlling fraud and abuse.
IMPROVING SERVICE TO THOSE WHO MOST NEED ASSISTANCE

The CETA reauthorization legislation enacted last fall approaches this objective
in two ways: (1) Providing a broader range of programs to meet varying needs of
individuals; and (2) focusing government programs on those in greatest need. The
strategy to provide more and better service to the poor has five program components. All of them share similar improvements in program design. These improvements are strict eligibility requirements, more emphasis on training, limits on
wages and program duration and strengthened prohibitions against substitution of
CETA employees for regular state and municipal workers.
Major program components to implement this strategy include the following:
General structural employment and trainingprograms

The new Title II of the CETA reauthorization legislation establishes a permanent
"structural" employment assistance program. It provides for a broad range of employment and training programs aimed at improving the skills of the disadvantaged
in the labor market. The structural title of CETA is a permanent program of fixed
size. For the first year it authorizes $2 billion for training, job search assistance,
outreach, and work orientation and $3 billion for transitional Public Service Employment. In addition to the amounts allocated directly for training, at least 10
percent of all Public Service Employment funds must be used for associated training
costs. This proportion will rise to 22 percent over time.
Eligibility will be restricted to the most disadvantaged. A person must be either
receiving welfare or unemployed for 15 weeks of the last 20 weeks and come from a
family with income less than 70 percent of the BLS low income standard during the
last six months. To promote transition into regular economy employment and to
avoid disruption of local labor markets, Public Service Employment wage levels are
set at levels appropriate to relatively unskilled workers. No supplementation of
wages by States or localities is allowed and all new jobs must be at the entry level.
The formula used to allocate funds among areas under the Public Service Employment section of Title II has been modified to channel funds to areas with concentrations of low income families and generally high levels of unemployment. Except for
specific exceptions approved by the Secretary, no participant may remain in a
public service job for more than 18 months. This limitation is intended to reduce the
possibility of substituting CETA employees for regular state and municipal employees. It will also increase the number of people who can participate in these programs and emphasize the transitional nature of public service jobs.
The employment opportunity program: Welfare reform

A major emphasis of the Administration's new welfare reform proposal is to
improve the opportunities and abilities of parents in low income families to provide
a decent income for their families through their own work effort. The Employment
Opportunity Program (EOP) component of the welfare reform package will be the
major vehicle for achieving thiis objective. Like the new CETA Title II, this will be
an employment and training program for disadvantaged workers. Many of the
features of this program will be similar to CETA Title II programs. However, the
Employment Opportunity Program moves beyond the current Title II in attempting
to meet the full demand for employment and training assistance by primary earners in welfare eligible families with children. Although final program decisions have
not been made, the Employment Opportunity Program could more than double the
number of structural public service employment jobs.
As in Title II, emphasis is placed on skill acquisition, upgrading and transition to
the private sector. However, the program also seeks to insure that the opportunity
exists for such individuals to earn a basic income either through private sector work
or a public service job, which, together with supplementary income assistance, will
assure an above poverty line income.
A series of pilot projects, currently in the planning stage, in 15 geographically
diverse sites throughout the country will provide a sound management basis for the
orderly implementation of welfare reform. The projects will test and evaluate detailed organizational and programmatic models for meeting the varying needs of
those who would be served by welfare reform. Those models which prove most
successful will then be included in an intensive program of technical assistance,
which will lead to the full implementation of the employment and training component of welfare reform.

396
Youth programs

A second major initiative are programs designed to meet the special needs of
disadvantaged youth in making the frequently difficult transition from school into
productive employment. In August of 1977, a major youth employment initiative
was launched under the Youth Employment and Demonstration Projects Act
(YEDPA). The Act created four new programs designed to increase youth employment and employability and to explore a number of innovative approaches for
providing services to young people.
Youth incentive entitlement pilot projects (YIEPP).-The purpose of this program

is to help economically disadvantaged youth complete high school. Sixteen to 19
year olds in selected geographic areas are guaranteed a year-round job if they agree
to attend high school. Through a nationwide competition 17 eligible areas were
selected. Jobs are guaranteed for an average of 20 hours a week during the school
year and up to 40 hours in summer. About 30,000 jobs are to be provided during an
18-month period.
Youth community conservation and improvement projects (YCCIP).-This program

is designed to develop the vocational potential of jobless youth through well-supervised work of tangible community benefit. YCCIP is for unemployed 16 to 19 year
olds with preference given to those out-of-school with the most severe problems in
finding jobs. Roughly 20,000 jobs are to be created in community-planned projects
lasting up to one year with supervision by skilled workers.
Youth employment and training programs (YETP) -This program seeks to en-

hance job prospects and career preparation of low-income youths aged 14 through 21
who have the most severe problems in entering the labor market. Those eligible are
youth from families whose incomes average about $8,900 a year. Youths from
families with lower incomes receive preference. About 170,000 job, training and
service opportunities will be provided once the program is fully operational.
Young Adult Conservation Corps (YACC).-Patterned after the New Deal's Civil-

ian Conservation Corps, the aim of YACC is to give young people experience in
occupational skills through productive work on conservation and other projects on
federal and non-federal lands and waters. Youth aged 16 through 23 who are
unemployed and out of school are eligible. A capacity of about 25,500 openings was
planned. YACC is operated cooperatively between the Departments of Labor, Agriculture, and Interior.
These programs have an estimated total job creation potential of about 200,000
slots. Under the CETA reauthorization, they will be continued as part of Titles IV
and VIII of CETA along with the Job Corps which, by March of 1980 is scheduled to
provide some 44,000 slots in residential work and training programs. Except for the
Young Adult Conservation Corps, the programs authorized under the Youth Employment and Demonstration Projects Act will expire at the end of 1980. During
this next year a full scale evaluation of these programs and demographic trends in
the labor force will be completed. Such a review would enable us to seek a reauthorization of a youth employment program based on the experience of what has and
has not worked.
Countercyclical unemployment programs

Title VI of the CETA reauthorization provides for PSE programs designed to
alleviate countercyclical unemployment related to general downturns in the economic cycle. The needs of workers who are unemployed because of the general
economy are somewhat different from the needs of the hard-core unemployed. As a
result, there are some unique elements in this aspect of the program. Title VI is not
a permanent program. The size of the program depends on how much above 4
percent the unemployment rate is. Under this title, less emphasis is placed on
training and acquiring work experience. Less emphasis is placed upon reaching
those who have the most serious long-term employment problems. However, the
program is aimed at those with the greatest current need. To be eligible, a worker
must be receiving welfare or be unemployed for 10 of the last 12 weeks and come
from a family with income of less than 100 percent of the BLS low income standard
over the last 3 months. Since Title VI is aimed at those who are unemployed
because of the general state of the economy, skill levels will be higher than under
structural Public Service Employment programs. As a result, supplementation of
base salaries by states and localities will thus be allowed. However, supplementation
will be limited to 10 percent of total wages.
Developingjob linkages with other federally funded programs

The Department is trying to increase the use of CETA workers in other Federally
funded programs such as low-income housing rehabilitation, energy conservation,
rural transportation, community law enforcement, environmental clean-up and

397
monitoring, day care, services for t