View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

DECEMBER

TAX FOUNDATION'S

Maintaining

the Value of Our

1961,

Vol. XXII,

No.

12

Money

b y H o n . W m . McC. Martin, Jr.
Chairman, Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System

I

N A WORLD strained by tensions, we are fortunate to live in a country that has consistently
responded to peril with greatness. A savage bombing attack on U. S. soil almost exactly 20
years ago did no more to halt the progress of
——the American people than attacks by bow and
recovery, and now we are embarked upon an expansion that already has carried almost all indicators of
arrow two centuries earlier.

We are a strong and a resourceful nation, with a
role to play in maintaining freedom and civilization
in a beleaguered world, and we are able now, as in the
past, to meet whatever needs may come upon us.
That is so in large measure because we have an economic system of great strength and even greater potential, founded on the principle
of freedom of enterprise and
individual initiative.
It is not my purpose to
engage in predicting economic
levels: already there are estimates aplenty, in a wide range
of sizes. My concern, instead,
is with how to get the most
and the best out of the American economy. But I would
like to note that, in appraisals
of the basic strength and potential of our economic system, there seems to me to
have been a decided tendency
for many years to underestimate rather than to overestimate.
Over the past year we
have had both recession and

overall economic activity to heights well above any
we have ever attained before.
It is, nevertheless, imperative that further progress
be made: too many people are still unemployed, too
much of our business structure is still operating below
most efficient levels, and our growing population must
have more job and business
opportunities.

This Issue In Brief
M o n e y , says M r . M a r t i n in this Review,
" s h o u l d n e v e r be a political i s s u e . " in his
o p i n i o n , t h e necessity t o m a i n t a i n t h e integrity of t h e n a t i o n ' s c u r r e n c y is a c c e p t e d
by t h e r a n k a n d file of b o t h political
p a r t i e s . " N e i t h e r p a r t y can benefit by dep r e c i a t i n g t h e d o l l a r , " h e says.
It is i m p o r t a n t , h e notes, to r e m e m b e r
t h a t w h e n d e a l i n g with t h e subject of
m o n e y " w e a r e also d e a l i n g with t h e faith
a n d c r e d i t of t h e U n i t e d S t a t e s . "
A d e c l i n e in t h e v a l u e of t h e dollar, h e
says, would suggest t o o t h e r n a t i o n s a
decline i n t h e faith a n d credit of t h e U. S.,
" a n d in t h e i r m i n d s signal a decline n o t
only i n A m e r i c a n e c o n o m i c s t r e n g t h , b u t
also i n m o r a l f o r c e . "

I think it no exaggeration to
say that—apart from matters
bearing directly on the question of peace or war—the most
important single development
of recent times has been the
entry of the world into a new
era of vigorous economic and
financial competition.
This is not a new fact, of
course: it has been in the
making for years as, with a
generous assist from us, the
countries of Europe cleared
away the ruins of war, got
their finances in order, developed an industrial base
unprecedented in size and
efficiency, expanded their for-

Copyright 1961 by Tax Foundation, Inc., 50 Rockefeller Plaza, New York 20, N. Y. Material may be re-used with proper credit.




53

TAX

REVIEW,

DECEMBER

1961

eign trade, moved from debtors to creditors, and
opened the way for a freer international flow of
funds by restoring the convertibility of their currencies.
In a parallel development, the United States balance of payments with the rest of the world dropped
from a surplus to a deficit position, reflecting the fact
that the United States was spending, lending, and investing more abroad than foreign countries were
spending, lending,1 and investing here. The deficits
began showing up, 12 years ago, and, save for one
exceptional year, have continued since. This constitutes a problem we dare not overlook and cannot
ignore.
Need Quality of

Self-discipline

Slowly we are all coming increasingly to understand
that in industry, commerce, and finance alike, Americans are in competition not only with each other but
also with the world; in competition not only for goods
and services but also for capital funds; in competition
not only in design, quality, promotion and credit terms
but also in prices; in competition not only as sellers
and lenders but also as buyers and borrowers.
All this brings strains, but it also brings opportunities. An increased international flow of goods, services
and capital is mutually advantageous to all participants, and expanding that flow can benefit us as well
as the rest of the world: with Europe more prosperous,
and with Latin America, Asia, and the old and the
new countries of Africa striving for better standards
of living, opportunities for us to market our goods
also are broadening.
To meet the competition of the world, which we
are feeling with mounting intensity even in our domestic markets, we need the traditional American virtues
of initiative, imagination, inventiveness, enterprise and
managerial skill in order to come up with the right
goods and services, at the right places, in the right
times, and at the right prices.

Hon. William McC. Martin,
Jr., was named President of
the New York Stock Exchange
when 31 years old. He was the
youngest — and first paid —
president in the Exchange's
history. He was appointed a
member and designated as
Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System in 1 9 5 1 ; redesignated Chairman in 1 9 5 5
and 1 9 5 9 . He served as Assistant Secretary of the
Treasury from 1 9 4 9 to 1 9 5 1 . This Review is taken
from Mr. Martin's address at the 2 4 t h annual Tax
Foundation dinner.




But we also need a quality for which we have not
thus far distinguished ourselves—and that is the quality
of self-discipline. By that I mean self-discipline in our
private and in our governmental processes alike.
We simply cannot afford to be priced out of the
market by the wage-price spiral: in our private enterprise, employers must realize that they are competing
with other employers around the world for sales and
profits, and employees must remember they are competing with other workers around the world for jobs
as well as wages.
Neither can we afford to be priced out of the market
by currency inflation: in our governmental operations
we must earnestly avoid budgetary and monetary
practices that can undermine the value of the dollar,
and so undermine our competitive position as both
sellers and buyers of goods and services throughout
the world.
In short, there is mutual need of an urgent nature
for labor, management and government each to measure up to its separate responsibilities, and at the same
time to refrain from behavior that makes it harder
for the others to measure up to theirs.
Having given this broad picture of things as they
seem to me, I want to take this opportunity to record
my views on where the Federal Reserve fits into that
picture, even though I don't think I can add anything
new to what I have said many times over since I
entered upon my present duties, more than ten years
ago.
Care Taken

in Framing

Reserve

Act

In our free society, the responsibility of government, as I understand it, is not to order the lives of
people for them but to provide them a climate of
opportunity that will encourage them to apply their
energy, enterprise, and ingenuity to bettering the lot
of themselves, their families, and their communities,
and thus to promote the welfare of the country as a
whole.
That general responsibility is one in which the
Federal Reserve System shares. The direct responsibility of the System, at all times, is to provide monetary and credit conditions that will encourage business
and employment, safeguard the value of our dollar,
and promote sustainable growth in the economy. By
so doing, it can make an important contribution to
improving the living standards of the people as a
whole—though it can never do more than that because
its powers are limited to credit matters, and business
and employment do not live on credit alone.
Clearly, the framers of the Federal Reserve Act

TAX REVIEW, DECEMBER 1961
were aware that monetary policy would inevitably
require an element of judgment. For they took what
seem to me some very wise precautions to see that
the required judgments would be, in so far as human
capacities permit, impartial, informed, and in the
interest of the country as a whole.
Great care was taken, when Congress entrusted
the power of money management to the Federal
Reserve System during President Wilson's administration nearly half a century ago, to safeguard that power
from becoming a device that could be controlled either
by private interests, on the one hand, or political interests on the other. The framework of the System
was designed to reflect in the best American tradition
a blending of the public interest and private enterprise, and also to accord recognition to the wide areas
of the United States and the local and regional problems that arise out of peculiarly American conditions.
Considerations

in Monetary

Policy

Decisions

That is an important as well as a unique advantage
of the System, as becomes evident when we consider
what is required in formulating a program to provide
credit and money conditions properly attuned to the
economic needs of the day, and of the morrow as well.
The first requirement is a painstaking search for all
the relevant facts that may bear upon the economic
and financial outlook. The next is interpretation and
appraisal of those facts. There are of course other requirements less tangible but not less essential. One is
consciousness of certain principles that underlie and
sustain the American system, to which I have made
brief reference. Another is humility—or perhaps I
should say an awareness that no man can unerringly
foresee the future, and therefore he will do well not
to act as if he could.
All these matters are part of the background of
monetary policy decisions. Perhaps I should mention
as well some basic considerations that enter into making the decisions themselves. The first consideration
is to estimate the financial needs of the general economy—the private sector, as represented by industry,
commerce, agriculture, and consumers, and the public
sector, as represented by the Federal, state, and local
governments. The needs of these sectors are intertwined, but they can be separated for purposes of
discussion.
The United States Treasury, as the financial representative of the Federal government, has the task of
raising the money needed to pay for the expenditures
that are authorized by Congress and made law with
the signature of the President, as it also has the task
of managing the public debt accumulated in that
process. The Federal Reserve's operations in the




money field must be conducted with recognition of
the government's borrowing requirements, for two
reasons: first, although the Federal Reserve has no
part in tax or expenditure decisions, it does have a duty
to prevent financial panics, and a panic surely would
follow if the government, which represents the people
as a whole, could not pay its bills: second, it would
be preposterous for the Federal Reserve to say in
effect that it didn't approve of the expenditures authorized by the Congress and ordered by the President,
and therefore it wouldn't help enable the Treasury to
finance them.
So, seeing to it that the credit base is large enough
for the Treasury to borrow whatever is needed to pay
the government's lawfully incurred bills is an obligation binding upon the Federal Reserve. On the other
hand, there is a reciprocal obligation on the part of
the Treasury to conduct its operations with recognition
of the Federal Reserve's responsibility for orderly
credit and economic conditions, and for stability of
the dollar. The Treasury obviously would not expect
the Federal Reserve to inflate the money supply,
thereby putting the entire economy in jeopardy, merely
so that the Treasury could get money at an artificially
low rate. So, with complementary responsibilities, the
Federal Reserve and the Treasury must work together
in complementary fashion. Neither can ignore the
forces of supply and demand that are reflected in the
market place and attempt to dictate what interest
rates should be. Instead, both must assess market
forces and determine their policies accordingly.
Market Forces Must be Allowed to

Operate

Now, as to the needs of the private sector of the
economy: the credit needs of business—including
agriculture—characteristically expand at certain seasons, and it is always the job of the Federal Reserve
to see that these seasonal needs are met. The Federal
Reserve has always done so, and will keep on doing
so. It is one thing for interest rates to rise under the
pressures of a heavy demand for credit, and another
thing for money to become generally unavailable. The
forces of the market must be allowed to operate, and
to be reflected in interest rates, but it would be fantastic for the economy to be stifled by unavailability
of credit. Because this is a vast country, money may
be less available in one area than another for limited
periods, but it is up to the Federal Reserve to see that
the seasonal requirements of business are met.
A third factor that requires consideration in determining monetary policy is that of growth. The volume of money must grow with the growing population
and the growing scale of economic activity and productive capacity, so the base of bank reserves must
55

TAX REVIEW, DECEMBER

1961

be expanded accordingly. How much growth there
should be is more difficult to say. I do not profess to
know what the figure ought to be, and I doubt that a
precise figure can be set as desirable for year-in-andyear-out purposes.
In the matter of growth measurements, one needs
to be extremely careful. Growth in the money supply
must be related to the country's real needs. At any
time that borrowers crowd banks with loan demands
on a scale much greater than can be judged reasonable
for growth needs, they can expect the result to be some
rise in interest rates. If that rise does occur, it merely
signals continuance of the Federal Reserve policy of
letting the supply and demand for credit be reflected
in market rates of interest. Certainly it does not signal
a policy of choking off the flow of credit and forcing
rates artificially higher, for there is not any such policy
and there is not going to be one of that kind.
Keeping

Credit Conditions

Attuned

to Needs

Still another factor that we have to deal with is
psychology, or to use the economists' jargon—expectations—and no reliable yardstick has yet been devised
to measure this factor. What things really are may
count most in the long run, but what often counts in
the short run is what things seem to be—what people
think they are. I recall instances over the years when
we were proceeding to provide for a rate of growth
in the money supply that, even in retrospect, seems
to me pretty close to perfect. But even if the calculations were right in fact, they were on occasion wrong
in the scales of psychology. And what counted was
not what the facts were, but what people thought they
were or were going to be.
Let us take a look at what the Federal Reserve has
been doing in recent times to keep credit conditions
attuned to the needs of a nation caught in a crossfire between domestic and international problems.
On the domestic front, to help bring about recovery,
expansion, and sustained growth in production and
employment, the Federal Reserve has been operating
to make sure that the banking system can meet every
resonable borrowing need.
On the international front, to help hold down the
outflow of capital and gold prompted by the continuing balance of payments deficit, the Federal
Reserve has been operating to see that the outflow is
not aggravated by the pull of international differentials in interest rates.
The domestically-oriented operations began nearly
two years ago, when the Federal Reserve moved early
in 1960 to try to buttress the economy against weaknesses that were to become increasingly evident after
56



mid-1960 and bring about the short but painful recession that carried through to early 1961. These
operations were extended as the recession deepened,
then maintained through recovery into expansion.
In the course of pursuing these operations, the
Federal Reserve made possible over a period of 18
months since May 1960 a $20 billion growth in the
deposits of the commercial banking system, after
adjustment for seasonal variation—$15 billion of it in
time deposits and over $5 billion in demand deposits.
These increases represent annual rates of expansion
of 8 percent in total deposits and 3 percent in demand
deposits. These substantial increases in the spending
power, actual and potential, of the American public
provide a monetary base for the economy's advance
to heights far beyond anything yet seen. Yet the total
volume of deposits is not high relative to the level of
economic activity currently existing, not to mention
the potential for further growth represented by unused
resources. Continued bank credit and deposit expansion will be needed without incurring risk of excess,
although perhaps not at the same high rate as was
appropriate in the last year and a half of economic
recovery from recession.
The internationally-oriented operations began in
October 1960, and were extended in February 1961,
as the Federal Reserve's open market transactions in
government securities for the purpose of providing
bank reserves were broadened, first to include securities with a maturity up to 15 months, and next to
include all maturity sectors. Until October 1960,
these transactions had been confined, with few exceptions, to securities with a maturity under one year.
System Has Done Its Part
By spreading the direct impact of Federal Reserve
purchases over a wider range, these operations exerted
some influence, supplementary to the much more important steps taken by the Treasury, in holding shortterm rates at around the 2Vi percent level despite the
decidedly easy posture of monetary policy. Some
assistance was thereby rendered in keeping short-term
capital in this country. If these funds, looking for
higher interest rates abroad, had moved outward in
greater quantities, our international account imbalance
would have been made even more serious.
It is not my purpose either to apologize for or to
boast about the Federal Reserve's operations, on
either of these fronts. What I really feel is that the
System has made an earnest effort, and I believe a
constructive one, to do its part in dealing with national
problems of diverse character. But I would not want
to deceive you, or myself, by claiming victories that
have not yet been won.

TAX REVIEW, DECEMBER 1961
Of one thing I am quite sure: we cannot make solid
progress on a shaky foundation. And the possibility
of getting the most and the best out of the American
economy is going to be lost if we delude ourselves
into thinking that we can substitute gimmicks or short
cuts for hard work and honest values.
Much concern is centered these days on whether
the consumer will expand his buying and thus clear
the way for more production and more jobs, in growing number.
>
Must Try or Resign Selves to

pecay

Well, consumers now have more income and considerably more savings than they have ever had. Would
it be too old-fashioned to think that the solution may
lie in trying to offer the consumer more for his
money? All we'd have to do would be to let the consumer share in the benefits of increasing productivity
—an undertaking that could be facilitated if government, management and labor would work together to
hold costs down all around.
In our external, as well as our internal economic
and financial affairs, much the same questions arise.
Does anyone think we'll be better off in our international accounts, or even as well off as now, if American products become more expensive abroad, and the
American dollar becomes cheaper, either as a result of
the wage-price spiral or of currency inflation, or both?
What if, instead, we put our minds and hearts into
convincing the whole world, by performance, that the
value of American products and of American dollars
will always equal or better that of other countries'
products and currencies?
In any event, it seems to me we have no choice but
to make the try or else resign ourselves to eventual
decay. Does anyone truly feel our country's reputation as a safe haven for short- and long-term investment funds can interminably withstand the sort of
deficits in our balance of payments we've had so persistently in recent years? Does anyone seriously believe we can indefinitely avert a damaging drain of
capital and gold resources except by taking actions to
eradicate the fundamental causes?
Is it too much to expect the richest society the world
has ever known to get its income and expenses enough
into line—in one way or the other—so that it isn't perennially passing out IOU's in lieu of paying its bills?
Let me say that I don't think anybody here or
abroad questions the ability of our country to "afford"
whatever amounts it needs for the national defense
and for the social benefits the American public demands as well. But I think there are a great many who




question whether we can afford indefinitely not to
pay—willingly—the costs we willingly incur.
Budget decisions are always hard to make, especially when exceedingly costly measures are rendered imperative to protect the nation against an
unparalleled threat of total destruction. Our present
budget troubles come not nearly so much from decisions made in this or in any other single year—even
fiscal 1959 with its peacetime-record deficit—as from
the fact that we have shown budget deficits in 25 of
the last 31 years, many of them prosperous years in
which a surplus would have been more logical to
expect.
Since 1946, the dollar has declined in value to 65
cents. That suggests the dimensions of the job to be
done in the future. It also makes the job itself more
difficult, and more urgent. The resultant higher level
of costs makes it harder not only to maintain our
competitive position in the world, but also to retain
world-wide confidence in our ability and will to maintain the dollar's value henceforth. Dollar erosions,
like nuclear blasts, leave behind cumulatively poisonous effects.
Look for Fault in

Ourselves

In my view, it would be grossly unfair and wholly
unfruitful to blame any one administration for our
national debt's growth and our currency's shrinkage.
Deficit financing has marked many administrations,
and the emergency of war has forced it on many of
our presidents, with inflationary consequences they
could not prevent. From its founding, the United
States has had 34 presidents and I am certain none
of them has ever welcomed a deficit or advocated
inflation as an instrument of policy. If we the people
want a culprit, we had better look for fault in ourselves, as well as in somebody else. And we had better
give a collective assist to presidential commitments to
balanced budgets, whenever they're proffered. The
least thing we can do for our country is to stop asking
it to do more for us.
My observations on the need to maintain the value
of our money have not come from feelings of despair.
I have been prompted, instead, by belief that in a
democracy, where the ultimate responsibility for
policies rests with the people, any observations on
matters of national concern have some chance of
serving the public good.
The integrity of the dollar is not
Otherwise, it could not be a topic
anyone in my post: it is my deep
central bank—which must always

a political matter.
for discussion by
conviction that a
assist incumbents
57

TAX REVIEW, DECEMBER 1961
but never candidates—must not, in any time or place,
be engaged in partisan politics.
It is important to remember that when we deal with
the subject of money, we are also dealing with the
faith and credit of the United States.
As a recent trip has reminded me, to people abroad,
much more than to Americans, the dollar is a symbol
of this country's strength. Thus, a decline in the value
of the dollar, to say nothing of a formal devaluation,
would suggest to them a decline in the faith and credit
of the United States, and in their minds signal a decline
not only in American economic strength but also in
moral force.
Money: More Than Symbolic

Value

But money has more than a symbolic value. In
functioning as a medium of exchange, as a standard
for measuring value, and further as a means of storing value, it serves—so long as it is kept stable in value
itself so that it may perform those functions—to keep
our entire economy functioning efficiently for the
maximum benefit of all.
There is still another aspect of money we should
never forget. And that is that money—if good—is an
•

58



instrument of liberty. As we know from history, it was
not until payment in labor and produce was supplanted by payment in cash that men were able to
break the bonds of serfdom that had bound the mass
of them for life to their native plot of soil and their
native status in society.
Money gave men freedom of movement and of
leisure. It gave them the ability to change the nature
and place of their work and the locality of their possessions at will. It gave them freedom to do as they
pleased with the product of their labors; to eat it or
to drink it, to give it to a church or charity, to spend
it for learning, to save its value against some unforeseen event, to use it to raise living standards for themselves and their families, or to put it aside to fortify
their independence when they wish to assert it.
For these, and for many other reasons, money
should never be a political issue. There are numerous,
legitimate areas of difference between the parties on
matters of both theory and practice on which the
voters are divided by their convictions or interests.
But in my judgment, it is clear that the necessity to
maintain the integrity of our currency is accepted by
the rank and file of Democrats and Republicans alike,
and that neither party can benefit by depreciating
the dollar.