View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EDITOR'S ADVANCE TEXT
For Release in
Sunday Papers, May 15

TAX AND EXPENDITURE POLICY FOR 1949

*

*

*

A Statement on National Policy
by
THE RESEARCH AND POLICY COMMITTEE
of the
COMMITTEE FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

May, 1949




T

HE TRUSTEES of the Committee for Economic Development
established the Research and Policy Committee "to initiate
studies into the principles of business policy and of public
policy which will foster the full contribution by industry and
commerce to the attainment and maintenance of high and secure
standards of living for people in all walks of life through maximum
employment and high productivity in the domestic economy." (From
CED By-Laws)

CED's Research and Policy Committee of businessmen assigns
questions for study to qualified scholars, drawn largely from leading
universities. Under the By-laws "all research is to be thoroughly objective in character and the approach in each instance is to be from
the standpoint of the general welfare and not from that of any special
political or economic group." (From CED By-Laws)
The monographs prepared by the scholars, after consultation with
the Research and Policy Committee, are published as books by
McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc.
Statements on National Policy, such as the following, are issued by
the businessmen of the Research and Policy Committee. These Statements are based on thorough study and discussion of relevant material
including the research monographs.
Neither the Statement on National Policy which follows nor any
other Statement by the CED Research and Policy Committee claims
either indirectly or by inference to represent the views of the Trustees
or of the businessmen and others throughout the country who are
affiliated with CED. Up to the date of publication, they have not
participated in the background discussion between businessmen and
economists leading toward the development of the Statements.
Statements on National Policy are offered by the Research and
Policy Committee as an aid to clearer understanding of steps to
be taken in reaching and maintaining high levels of productive employment and a steadily rising standard of living. The Committee is
not attempting to pass on any pending specific legislative proposals;
its purpose is to urge careful consideration of the objectives set forth
in the statement and of the best means of accomplishing those
objectives.




RESEARCH AND POLICY COMMITTEE
PHILIP D. REED, Chairman

JAY C. HORMEL

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
GENERAL ELECTRIC COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
GEO. A. HORMEL & COMPANY
AUSTIN, MINNESOTA

WILLIAM BENTON

AMORY HOUGHTON

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
ENCYCLOPAEDIA BRITANNICA, INC. AND
MUZAK CORPORATION
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

ERIC JOHNSTON

JOHN D. BIGGERS
PRESIDENT
LIBBEY-OWENS-FORD GLASS COMPANY
TOLEDO, OHIO

JAMES F. BROWNLEE
FAIRFIELD, CONNECTICUT

WILLIAM L. CLAYTON

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
CORNING GLASS WORKS
CORNING, NEW YORK
PRESIDENT
MOTION PICTURE ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, INC.
WASHINGTON, D.C.

ERNEST KANZLER
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
UNIVERSAL C.I.T. CREDIT CORPORATION
DETROIT, MICHIGAN

MEYER KESTNBAUM

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
ANDERSON, CLAYTON & COMPANY
HOUSTON, TEXAS

PRESIDENT
HART, SCHAFFNER & MARX
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

S. SLOAN COLT

FRED LAZARUS, JR.

PRESIDENT
BANKERS TRUST COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
FEDERATED DEPARTMENT STORES, INC.
CINCINNATI, OHIO

GARDNER COWLES

FOWLER McCORMICK

PRESIDENT AND PUBLISHER
DES MOINES REGISTER & TRIBUNE
DES MOINES, IOWA

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
INTERNATIONAL HARVESTER COMPANY
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

CHESTER C. DAVIS

WILLIAM A. PATTERSON

PRESIDENT
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS
ST. LOUIS, MISSOURI

MARION B. FOLSOM
TREASURER
EASTMAN KODAK COMPANY
ROCHESTER, NEW YORK

HENRY FORD, II
PRESIDENT
FORD MOTOR COMPANY
DEARBORN, MICHIGAN

CLARENCE FRANCIS
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
GENERAL FOODS CORPORATION
NEW" YORK, NEW YORK

GEORGE L. HARRISON
PRESIDENT
NEW YORK LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
UNITED AIR LINES
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

RAYMOND RUBICAM
SCOTTSDALE, ARIZONA

BEARDSLEY RUML
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
R. H. MACY AND CO., INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

HARRY SCHERMAN
PRESIDENT
BOOK-OF-THE-MONTH CLUB
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

H. CHRISTIAN SONNE
PRESIDENT
AMSINCK, SONNE & COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

J. CAMERON THOMSON
PRESIDENT
NORTHWEST BAN CORPORATION
MINNEAPOLIS, MINNESOTA

ROBERT HELLER

W. WALTER WILLIAMS

PRESIDENT
ROBERT HELLER & ASSOCIATES, INC.
CLEVELAND, OHIO

PRESIDENT
CONTINENTAL, INC.
SEATTLE, WASHINGTON




RESEARCH ADVISORY BOARD
SUMNER H. SLICHTER, Chairman

HAROLD D. LASSWELL

LAMONT UNIVERSITY PROFESSOR
HARVARD UNIVERSITY

PROFESSOR OF LAW
YALE UNIVERSITY

ROBERT D. CALKINS, Vice Chairman
VICE PRESIDENT AND DIRECTOR
GENERAL EDUCATION BOARD

DEAN
GRADUATE SCHOOL OF 4
PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
HARVARD UNIVERSITY

DOUGLASS V. BROWN

GARDINER C. MEANS

PROFESSOR OF INDUSTRIAL MANAGEMENT
DEPARTMENT OF BUSINESS AND
ENGINEERING ADMINISTRATION
MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

ECONOMIST
WASHINGTON, D.C.

EDWARD S. MASON

THEODORE W. SCHULTZ
PROFESSOR OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS
THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO

DAVID F. CAVERS

JACOB VINER

PROFESSOR OF LAW
HARVARD UNIVERSITY

PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS
PRINCETON UNIVERSITY

NEIL JACOBY

RALPH A. YOUNG

DEAN
COLLEGE OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA
LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA

ASSOCIATE DIRECTOR
DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTIC^
BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

RESEARCH STAFF
Policy Statement Director
HOWARD B. MYERS

Associate Research Director
HERBERT STEIN

Assistant to Research Director
SYLVIA STONE

Administrative Assistant
ROBERT L. LENHART

Staff Member
ARTHUR VINER

SUBCOMMITTEE ON TAX AND EXPENDITURE POLICY FOR 19Z.9

J. Cameron Thomson, CHAIRMAN
President
Northwest Bancorporation
Minneapolis, Minnesota
John D* Biggers, President
Libbey-Owens-Ford Glass Company
Toledo, Ohio
S. Bayard Colgate
Chairman of the Board
Colgate-Palmolive-Peet Company
New York, New York

TECHNICAL ADVISORS
Roy Blough, Professor of Economics
and Political Science
The University of Chicago
Chicago, Illinois
Norris Darreil
Sullivan and Cromwell
New York, New York
Harry J. Rudick
Lord, Day and Lord
New York, New Yoric

Carlyle Fraser, President
Genuine Farts Company
Atlanta, Georgia
Amoiy Houghton
Chairman of the Board
Corning Glass Works
Corning, New lork
Philip D. Reed
Chairman of the Board
General Electric Company
New York, New York
Harry Scherman, President
Book-of-the-Month Club
New York, New York
W. Walter Williams, President
Continental, Inc.
Seattle, Washington




STAFF CONSULTANTS
Walter W. Heller, Professor
University of Minnesota
Minneapolis, Minnesota
Elizabeth S. May
Professor of Economics
Wheaton College
Norton, Massachusetts

CONTENTS
Page
I.
II.
III.

INTRODUCTION

.

.

.

.

THE 1950 BUDGET
THE CONTROL OF EXPENDITURES

3
12

How to Make Control of Expenditures Effective
Use of the Cash-Consolidated Budget
Clarifying Issues by Improved Classifications,
Issuing a Shorter Budget Statement .
.
.
Defining Public Choices .
Achieving Economy in Government

.

.

Controlling New Items of Expenditure
IV.

1

BUDGET POLICY




The Principles of Budget Policy
Need for Reform of the Tax Structure
Payroll Taxes for Social Security
Budget
The
The
The
The

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

15
17
18
19
20
24.
28
32
33
38
39

Policy for Fiscal 1950
40
Choices Before the Country • .
.
.
•
. 4 0
Need for Reduction of Expenditures
40
Cost of Higher Taxes
.
.
. . . .
41
Cost of Not Providing for Debt R e d u c t i o n " . . .
42

TAX AND EXPENDITURE POLICY FOR 1949
I. INTRODUCTION

For the fiscal year 1950, the President has recommended cash
expenditures of more than $46 billion, an increase of $10 billion
1
over fiscal 1948 and $6 billion over the current fiscal year.
The taxpayer's vision of lower Federal budgets and of lower taxes
to match has faded into an uncertain future*

Instead, he faces the

Presidents recommendations for a $2 billion payroll tax increase
and an additional $4 billion general tax increase. Acceptance of
these recommendations by Congress would raise cash receipts to more
than $50 billion annually at a $230 billion level of national income.
A 45 or 50 billion dollar government bears a heavy responsibility to the American people~a responsibility to spend and tax
wisely.

This obligation is especially serious since effective gov-

ernment performance has become a major weapon in the current war of
economies and ideologies.
Success in maintaining America's world leadership depends in
part on demonstrating that our system of government is superior to
authoritarian systems in meeting the economic and social problems
common to both. In that demonstration, tax and budgetary policy
plays a strategic role. A sound fiscal policy can exert a strong

Except as otherwise noted, this policy statement will present
budgetary data in terms of the Federal fiscal year. This runs
from July 1 of one calendar year through June 30 of the next,
and is designated by the second year. For example, the period
from July 1, 1949 through June 30, 1950 is designated as the
fiscal year 1950.




- 2 -

stabilizing influence on the economy. It can be our most important
force making for efficiency in governments

And unlike direct con-

trols over prices, *ages, and production, fiscal policy does its work
in harmony with — not at the expense of — individual freedom of
choice•
This policy statement deals with tax and budgetary policy for
the fiscal year 1950*

It examines the Presidents budget proposals

and some issues they raisea suggests some means of making control of
government expenditures more effective5 and spells out some of the
implications of spending on the scale proposed•




II.

THE 1950 BUDGET

1

From a wartime peak of $94.3 billion in the fiscal year 1945*
Federal expenditures declined to $36,5 billion in fiscal 1948. This
decline was, of course, the natural consequence of the end of hostilities. Moreover, it was reasonable to hope that the decline would
continue.

The 1948 total included large expenditures of a clearly non-

recurring or dwindling character —

the cashing of veterans1 terminal

leave bonds, the costs of surplus property disposal, veterans*s readjustment allowances and so on.
Jhe decline did not continue•

Instead, as Table I shows,

expenditures are higher in 1949 than in 1948 and the President's
budget calls for still higher expenditures in 1950.

The recom-

mendations itemized in the Budget for 1950 total $45#7 billion. In
addition the President has announced, in his budget message and subsequently, that he will submit a request for military aid to the
North Atlantic countries not included in the budget figures. If we
tentatively add $600 million for this item, the 1950 budget totals
$46*3 billion, or$&.8 billion more than actual expenditures in 1948.
The $9#8 billion rise in two years is the net result of decreases in a few major classes of expenditure and increases in a great

This discussion will refer throughout to the cash-cpnsolidated budget
rather than the administrative budget in terms of which Federal expenditures and taxes are commonly stated. For fiscal 1950, the administrative budget figures corresponding to the cash-consolidated
figures in Table I would be $42*5 billion of expenditures and $41.0
billion of receipts. For a description of the cash-consolidated
budget, see pp. 17-18.




- 4 -

TABLE I
Cash Payments to and Receipts from the Public
Fiscal Years 1948, 1949, 1950
a
As shown in the U. S. Budget for fiscal year 1950
(In Billions)
PAYMENTS TO THE PUBLIC
National Defense
International Affairs and Finance
Military aid to North Atlantic countries
Veterans' Services and Benefits
Interest on the Public Debt
Social Welfare, Health, and Security
Other Activities
Total Payments to the Public

Actual
1948

$12.2
5.8

6.8
3.9

2.1

Fiscal Years
Estimated
1949
$11.9

Proposed

1.U

6.7
3.9

2.6

$14.3
6.9
7.9 1
4.0 „
4.5 c

8.1

jj-7
36.5

hL
40.1

21.9

10.2

19.3
11.7

7.8
2.4

8.1
2.6

12.3
8.3
5.3

1.0

1.0

1.2

46.3

RECEIPTS FROM THE PUBLIC
Direct Taxes on Individuals
Direct Taxes on Corporations
Excise Taxes and Customs
Employment Taxes
Deposits by States, Unemployment
Insurance
Miscellaneous Receipts
Less Refunds
Total Receipts from the Public
Excess of Receipts over Payments

4.4
45.4

'8.8

2.9
-2.7
42.9

19.8 ®
c

2.4
-2*1 .

2.8

a/

1950 figures include both existing and proposed legislation. Except for the
sum of $600 million estimated as the net additional cost for "Military aid to
North Atlantic countries", all figures are as shown in the President's budget.
Revenue estimates are based on a projected personal income of $215 billion, corresponding to a national income of $230 billion.

b/

Includes an estimated $2 billion for dividend payments on National Service
Life Insurance.

c/

President's proposed legislation accounts for the bulk of the increase of
1950 over 1949.
Does not include the $4 billion general tax increase proposed by the President.




d

many others. About $3.8 billion less will be spent in 1950 than in 1948
for terminal leave payments, veterans1 readjustment benefits, the U. S•
contribution to the capital of the International Bank and Monetary Fund,
surplus property disposal, and the postal deficit. Therefore, to explain
the $9.8 billion net increase in the total budget we mast find the
source of about $13*6 billion of increase in other programs.
The chief forces at work to raise Federal expenditures are:
1. A great increase of programs for national defense and
foreign aid.
2. A large increase of "domestic11 programs, mainly for
social welfare and resource development.
3. The proposed payment of $2 billion for accumulated
dividends on veterans1 life insurance. (This is a
contractual obligation and annual payments in the
future will be much smaller.)
4* An increase of about $750 million for farm price support
operations resulting from the lower level of farm prices.
5. Higher costs resulting from higher prices and government wage rates.
The effects of higher pr ices and wage rates are spread throughout the budget and cannot be isolated. Moreover, the figure for each
major category of expenditures is itself the sum of many individual items
in which there may be both increases and decreases. With these reservations, Table II identifies the sources of the $9.8 billion net increase
in expenditures from 1948 to 1950.




TABLE II
Change8 in Federal Cash Expenditures, 1948 - 1950
(In Billions)
Actual

Fiscal Years
Proposed
1950*/

tel

MJJ-

-

aA

Risimr Procrams

2StA

43-7.

+ 13.6

Defense and foreign aid

15.5

21.6

+ 6.1

2.0

+ 2.0

Veterans' life insurance dividend

—

Farm price support

-.2

.6

.8

Social welfare S/

3.2

6.2

+ 3.0

Resource development SJ

2.3

A.A

+ 1.6

All other «/

8.8

8.9

+• .1

Includes unofficial estimate of $600 million for military aid to North
Atlantic countries, not included in Budget figures*
b/ Includes veterans' terminal leave payments, U. S. contribution to capital
of International Bank and Monetary Fund, veterans1 readjustment benefits,
costs of surplus disposal, postal deficit.
c/ Includes following budget categories: Social welfare, health and security,
education and general research, labor*
d/ Includes following budget categories: natural resources not primarily agricultural , transportation and communication (except P.O.), agriculture, except price supports*
e/ Mainly interest, general government, veterans' services not elsewhere
specified, housing.




- 7 -

In 1948 Federal cash receipts were $45#4 billion.
The budget estimates show that if no new taxes are enacted receipts in fiscal 1950 would be slightly lass — $45#0 billion.
This Treasury estimate is based on the assumption .that total
personal income will continue at about the $215 billion annual
rate reached in July-December, 1948, as compared with the $195
billion of calendar 1947*

In other words the higher level of

national income, if continued, would nearly offset the effect
of the 1948 tax rate reduction upon Federal revenues.
Even at the national income level assumed by the Treasury,
the yield of existing tax rates would fall $1<>3 billion short of
the proposed expenditures (including the unofficial $600 million
estimate for North Atlantic military aid). The President has
proposed higher rates and broader coverage of payroll taxes as
part of his program for expansion of social security. This tax
increase, if enacted, would add $2«2 billion to cash receipts
in fiscal 1950, according to the budget estimates.

There would

then be a cash surplus of $900 million, compared with

$8.8 billion

in fiscal 1948.
The Presidents Budget Message for 1950 leaves one with
several inescapable impressions regarding government expenditure
policy. First, the Federal Government is trying to do an unprecedented number of things at once. It is pushing its domestic




programs for social and economic betterment — in social insurance,
education, resource development, agriculture and the like -- well
beyond their previous high water marks. It is undertaking the
greatest peacetime preparedness program our country has ever known.
And it is recognizing its new international position with the most
extensive program of foreign relief, reconstruction, and military
aid the world has ever seen.
Second, "the President visualizes the expenditures projected
for 1950 as one step in a rising expenditure trend* He states:
"It must be recognized that expenditures in the fiscal year 1951
are likely to be larger than those for 1950." He adds that "Expenditures for national defense can be expected to rise substantially
above the level estimated for 1950." And many of the commitments we
are asked to undertake now, especially in the fields of resource development and social welfare, would involve steadily rising outlays
for many years»
Thirds there seems to be no limit to the projects pressing
for an qcpenditure of Federal funds.

The President plainly indicates

that many candidates for Federal expenditure are waiting to take up
any slack which might develop through a reduction in costs of existing
projects. Only because of >fheavy prior commitments" ahd "the presence
of inflationary forces in our economy" has he denied "many requests
for additional funds which would normally be desirable." His 1949
Economic Report to the Congress makes the point even more strongly:




"We must pursue affirmative programs for housing and health,
for education and resource development. Yet the fight against
inflation prevents us from undertaking these long-range programs
with the speed and on a scale that would otherwise be desirable.n
Quite apart from these developmental programs, it is evident that
political pressure for larger direct payments to veterans, to
farmers, and to the aged could add billions to the Federal budget.
These impressions are reinforced by looking at the expansion of specific expenditure programafrom 1948 to 1950 and
their projected costs for later years. Most striking, of course,
is the $3«5 billion jump in defense outlays from $10*8 billion
in 1948, excluding terminal leave payments, to $14 #3 billion for
1950.

As wartime stocks are used up and various military pro-

grams grow to their authorized limits, the $14*3 billion figure
could rise substantially. Unofficial estimates place the outof-pocket cost of military aid to the North Atlantic countries
in future years at a level well above the first-year cost of
$600 million included in Table I* As veterans1 readjustment
costs shrink, they may be more than offset by the costs of pension plans such as are recurrently proposed in Congress*

Cash

payments of interest on the debt will rise sharply as war savings
bonds mature#




- 10

In other areas, only oner major item — international
affairs and finance — is now scheduled for substantial reduction in the next few years* Expanding economic and social
programs at home could offset that reduction* Table III shows
that the cost of social welfare and resource development programs will increase by 75 percent from 1948 to 1950 if the
Presidents proposals become law. Social insurance and public
assistance account for $2 billion of the $4*5 billion increase
in this group of activities, and would of course grow steadily,
though not so sharply, for decades to come*

The increase of

nearly half a billion dollars for highways, waterways and airways
is indicative of the growing amounts of Federal money we are devoting to public works. Agricultural programs, even apart from
price subsidies, are expanding by a third of a billion dollars
from 1948 to 1950 and may go on expanding.
Continuation of the 1948-1950 rising trend of Federal
expenditures need not be accepted as Inevitable. Tet, if unchecked by successful efforts at economy —
provements in our relations with Russia —

or by unforeseen imthe new trend will carry

us over the $50 billion mark in the next few years.




- 11 -

TABLE III

Increases in Expenditures for Social Welfare and Resource Development, 1948 - 1950
(In Millions)
Actual
-12A2.

Fiscal Tears
Proposed
i m

Increase
tLWL

Social Welfare

2&12

j m .

mi

Old age and survivors insurance program;
total and permanent disability program;
temporary disability program

559

2245

1686

Public assistance

733

1129

396

Unemployment compensation

856

1170

314

Federal aid to education

—

290

290

Railroad and federal employees
retirement

466

594

128

Public health

146

284

138

Other

453

516

63

Resource P^velpppeqt

28gl

UOO

Highways, waterways, airways

963

1435

472

Land and water (flood control,
power, irrigation, reclamation
etc.)

493

951

458

Agriculture, except price supports

759

1093

334

Atomic energy

475

725

250

Other

131

196

65




-12-

III. THE CONTROL OF EXPENDITURES
The budgetary facts end prospects just reviewedl/bring
us face to face with this basic issue of expenditure policy: Can we
afford to expand government activities so rapidly and on so many
fronts at once? Or are we reaching the margin where the economic
and social costs of certain activities outweigh their benefits?
Closely allied to this issue are three further questions:
First, how can the Executive, the Congress and the public
control expenditure decisions more effectively? How can
Congressional procedure and public understanding be improved?
Second, how can government do a more efficient and
economical job in carrying out the functions assigned
to it?
Third, in what areas should we seek savings through
cutbacks or deferments of projected expenditures?
Federal expenditures that represent one-fifth of total
national income raise in compelling form the issue of balancing

2/We have used the President's budget to represent current expenditure
proposals. The representation is not precise or complete. For example, there is reason to believe that the social security expansion
program submitted by the Administration will not cost as much in
fiscal 1950 as the $1.5 billion included for that purpose in the budget.
On the other hand, proposals for national defense and veterans1 expenditures in excess of the President's recommendation have already made
some progress through the Congress. Nonetheless, the Budget is still
the best available indication of the size of the overall problem.




-13-

public against private spending. 1/ If government continues to expand
so fast and in so many directions at once, we will suffer damaging
consequences to private economic effort and individual freedom of
action. The Committee feels there is much evidence that we are in or
near this danger zone.
Yet, the pressure for larger and larger government spending
continues unabated. Plausible - often persuasive - new claims on
public funds are constantly being made. At the same time, resources
are limited. How are we to strike a balance between private and public
use of available resources?
In the Committeefs opinion, the best insurance that we will
achieve such a balance is a budget policy which puts taxes to work as
a check on government spending, by requiring that taxes be increased if
expenditures are increased. This requirement is a basic element in the
"stabilizing budget policy" recommended by the Committee in 1947 in its
policy statement, Taxes and the Budget. Each new expenditure would be
put squarely to this test: is it worth the additional taxes needed to
finance it? Does the gain from added expenditure exceed the loss from
higher taxes?
In answering this question, we must count as costs not only
the direct reduction of private income through higher taxes but the
adverse incentive effects as well. Are taxes already so high that new

1/ Adding state and local expenditures to Federal expenditures, the Council
of Economic Advisers in its latest Annual Economic Review Concludes: "....it
is expected that total government cash payments will rise to perhaps 61
billion dollars for the calendar year 1949, more than 9 billion dollars
higher than in 1948." In other words, total public spending is running in
excess of ofte-fourth of national income.




-Htax burdens will unduly hamper our economy in providing jobs and
promoting economic progress? Will the higher marginal tax rates undermine the incentives to work, save, and invest which are the main-springs
of increased production and innovation?
Apart from these predominantly economic considerations, the
choice between public and private use of resources must be made with
this very basic question in view: are government expenditures and the
activities they finance beginning to impinge on the area of freedom we
hold essential to our democratic and individualistic way of life? Is
government beginning to do things and make choices for the citizens for
which he should be responsible himself?
It is, of course, clear that we will have to accept very large
Federal budgets until true peace is achieved. The move for economy and
savings in government must proceed in harmony with, rather than at the
expense of, our essential programs of military security and economic
welfare. To the extent that the funds devoted to national defense,
foreign aid, and basic economic and social services are efficiently
spent and carry out the agreed goals of our national policy, they take
priority over the private expenditures they replace.
In the Committee's opinion, this general principle in no sense
rules out reductions in projected government expenditures. On the contrary, it underscores the urgent need to control expenditures more
effectively and to search for savings more vigorously, both through
greater economy and through postponement or curtailment of low-priority
programs.




How To Make Control Of Expenditures Effective
Effective control of Government expenditures requires the
combined action of the Executive, the Congress and the public. The
Executive 1s largely responsible for the initiation and preliminary
screening of expenditure proposals and for the administration of
programs authorized by the Congress, As we point out in another section of this Policy Statement, there is a great need and opportunity
for more efficient and economical administration of government functions. Moreover, despite improvements in recent years, executive
budget procedures still stand in need of reform.
Congress is responsible for weighing the numerous demands for
government expenditure against each other and against the general interest in lower taxes. It must also maintain constant scrutiny and
exert constant pressure for efficiency and economy. No individual or
private agency can do Congress1 job for it. But Congress cannot seme
its function without the advice and support of an informed public.
Congress is not now adequately organized to do its part of
the job. Its machinery is not conducive to a balancing of all of the
items on both sides of the budget against each other. Its present
organization leads Congress inevitably to make particular decisions
without relation to the whole picture of which they are parts. At the
same time Congress is not staffed to exercise a continuing constructive
influence on the day-by-day operation of the government. Its moves
for economy tend to be sporadic and spotty.




-16-

Th© Legislative Reorganization Act of 194-6 attempted to establish the machinery for an over-all approach toward the budget and a
realistic weighing of taxes against expenditures. The essential element
in the Act was the requirement that a legislative budget be voted by
February 15 of each year, upon the recommendation of a joint committee
representing the taxing and appropriations committees of both houses.
However, the date set was too early; no special staff was provided to
do the necessary spade-work; and a conviction that the procedure could
accomplish anything seemed to be lacking. Some critics of the Act have
suggested that the procedure be abandoned.
In the opinion of the Committee, the solution to the problem
liea rather in perfecting and implementing the procedure implicit in the
194-6 Act. The action of the present (81st) Congress in setting a later
date (May 1) for agreement on the legislative budget, fixing a maxiimm
limit on expenditures, accomplished a necessary first step. A second
is to provide an adequate staff for appropriations work on the pattern
of the staff of the Joint Committee on Internal Revenue Taxation, The
third step would be to consolidate all appropriations bills into a
single omnibus bill.
The improvement of machinery alone will not assure wise
Congressional action on expenditures. Congress is naturally and properly
responsive to the desires of the citizens in budget matters.
How can we make citizens more effective in resisting unsound
spending proposals and in promoting the best possible allocation of
funds among the many legitimate functions of government?
To do this requires that budgetary processes lay the necessary
facts on the table in a form that states clearly the costs against which
benefits are to be weighed and also raakes it possible to appraise the



-17-

economic impact of government budgets. Changes in budgetary practice
designed to meet this need are examined in this section.
The improvements in budgetary procedure and presentation which
must be made to facilitate more informed public participation in the
control of Government expenditures can be grouped as follows: (1) use of
the cash-consolidated budget; (2) clarifying policy issues by improved
classifications; (3) issuing a shorter budget statement; (A) defining
public choices..
Use of the Cash-Consolidated Budget
The Committee repeats its earlier recommendation that the cashconsolidated budget be adopted as the basic method of presenting budgetary
facts to the public. This does not mean that the administrative budget,
which now serves as the basis for public presentation, should be abandoned.
It was devised—and still serves—as a necessary instrument of internal
control and management. It gives a complete picture of what each agency
is doing, without distinguishing between an agencyfs transactions with the
public and its relation with other parts of the government, or between
expenditures made in cash and expenditures made by incurring government
liabilities.
The cash-consolidated budget, however, is superior in gaining an
overall view of government operations and in judging the effects of Federal
taxes and expenditures on the economy. Unlike the administrative budget, it
shows the total income and outgo of government, inclusive of trust account
operations."^ Moreover, it is based on actual cash inpayments and outpayments,

l/ For example, it includes in the proposed expenditures for fiscal 1950
the $2.0 billion National Service Life Insurance dividend which is not
shown in the administrative budget. It also adds in the $2.2 billion of
outpayments from the Old Age ana Survivors1 Insurance trust fund and the
&4.1 billion of receipts of this trust fund from payroll taxes.



-18-

excluding transactions in government liabilities.

Thus, it shows the

amounts being added to and subtracted from private incomes and holdings of
public debt. The cash-consolidated budget makes total cash receipts and
total cash expenditures the hub around which the decision-making process
revolves.
The Committee also recommends that the Budget Message state
each year what projection of national income is used in estimating receipts
and expenditures. Failure to include this figure has caused much needless
confusion in the past concerning the soundness of revenue and expenditure
estimates. The recent announcement by the Secretary of the Treasury that
the 1950 estimates are based on a $215 billion personal income (corresponding to a national income of about $230 billion) is a step in the right
direction.
Clarifying Issues by Improved Classifications
Effestive budget praggntfetipn in a democracy should help the
public to understand the choices that have to be made. Sensible choices
can be made only in terms of government functions, not in terms of
particular organization units. Further, public debate should center on
broad programs such as agricultural subsidies, national defense, international reconstruction and relief and the like. It follows, therefore,

Jj For 1950, for example, the administrative budget shows an expenditure
of $5.5 billion for interest. The actual cash outlay for interest included
in the cash-consolidated budget totals only $4.0 billion, because this
budget excludes the accrual of interest on savings bonds and the payment
of interest on government bonds Owned by government trust funds and
corporations.




-19-

that budget presentation should (a) focus attention on functions by
bringing together related activities and (b) summarize these activities
in categories which aid citizens in making policy decisions.
The new functional classification adopted in 1947 is a commendable first step toward a •'performance budget." It groups expenditures
into such categories as national defense, international affairs and
finance, and veterans1 services and benefits. To complete the process
of giving Congress and the public a clear understanding of what spending
is proposed for each activity of government, the broad functions now
used should be split up into activities and the activities into projects.
This is what the Commission on the Organization of the Executive Branch
of the Government (The Hoover Commission) calls a "performance budget."i/
The appropriations structure would likewise need to be altered with the
objectives of such a performance budget in mind.
Issuing A Shorter Budget Statement
Present budget documents are much too long and complex to be
effective in getting budgetary facts and issues across-to the public.
The budget for 1950 is a six-pound document running to 1625 pages.
Even the more widely available extract, Budget-Message of the President
and Summary Budget Statements, is over 300 pages long. A condensed
statement of perhaps 50 pages is badly needed. It should contain key

1J The Commission^ Recommendation No. I on budgeting is as follows: "We
recommend that the whole budgetary concept of the Federal government
Should be refashioned by the adoption of a budget based upon functions,
activities, and projects: this we designate as a 1 performance budget1."




•20-

excerpts from the President's budget message, together with selected
tables and charts. Skillful preparation and wide distribution of such
a pamphlet would make a real contribution to public understanding of
fiscal affairs.
Defining Public Choices
Putting the above-recommended changes into effect would help
greatly in judging the economic effects of government's activities and
would provide a clearer picture of the costs of government in a particular year. But that year must also be put in its proper perspective if
the citizen is to make intelligent decisions on government spending and
taxing.
The public and Congress are told in January what the government
proposes to spend in the year starting just six months later. But they
are not told how much of this amount is more or less "untouchable11
because of past commitments. Nor can they tell what their choices will
cost them not merely in the year just ahead but over the life span of
the proposed programs.
The public must be given every opportunity to participate in
the broad policy determinations of the Federal program. They naturally
wish to address their attention to the area where choices are still
open. More effective exercise of democratic control of government and
its expenditures would be possible if the budget would focus attention
more sharply upon the new decisions which have to be made.
The Committee recommends an addition to the customary budget
presentation to give us a longer perspective on the choices before us:




For new programs, especially long-run undertakings, the budget
should spell out not merely the costs in the coming year, but insofar
as possible the expected total and pattern of future costs. For longrun undertakings already in progress, the budget should facilitate
continuous review and appraisal by showing their exact status in terms
of past, present, and future expenditures.
The first part of this recommendation centers directly on the
expanding frontiers of government. It is the decisions on new programs,
on proposed legislation, on today1 s commitments for future spending that
determine in large part whether, and in what direction, government is to
expand.
New proposals should be the occasion for reappraisal of existing
programs. Their costs should be assessed in relation to their relative
benefits. Only if new proposals are fully explained can such a comparison
be accomplished and the total program be adjusted to meet the public1 s
preferences.
let, as matters now stand, choices which may be decisive for
the whole program have to be made largely in terms of the cost for the
first year. The statement of immediate costs should be supplemented by
as complete a schedule of future costs as present information allows.
If no satisfactory schedule can be given for a proposal, this alone may
indicate that it is not yet ripe for submission and public decision.
Such a requirement would facilitate control of government expenditures
where they originate and while they are still controllable.
Exclusive attention to new proposals will not, however,
accomplish the requisite public control over the program as a whole.
Long-run undertakings must be subjected to continuous review to make
sure that their development is consistent with the public's wishes.



-22-

Here again, the budget presentation should rake clear the range of choices.
Under present procedure, cooatitments grow out of authorizations which are
not made by appropriations committees and which may involve little or no
appropriation of money at the outset. The public works field provides
the prime example of the dimly understood commitment which tends to grow,
snowball fashion, as the years go by. The original estimate of the cost
to complete the project may be based on limited data. Later revisions
and expansions of the program may be cursorily approved merely as amendments to a decision already made. As the preliruinary explorations are
succeeded by engineering surveys and construction plans, the public
should be informed of revised cost estimates and the Congress should
exercise continuous surveillance of the broad outlines of the undertaking
to ensure that new decisions are consciously made.^/

1/ Quite apart from the merit of the project as such, the Missouri Basin
development is a good example of a long-range undertaking which has
tended to grow piecemeal without adequate Congressional or public control
of the project 8S a whole. When first approved by Congress in 1944* the
estimated cost of completing the entire project was $1,300 million. An
initial authorization of $400 million was made at that time to get work
started. Today, five years later, it is estimated that total federal
costs for the project and related activities may run to $'6,000 million
over a six year period. Part of the increase in estimated costs is due
to price rises since the first estimates were made. Most of it, however,
appears to be a result of more detailed estimating and additions to the
original plan. By June 30, 1949 > construction will have begun$according
to present plans, on work now estimated to cost $1,4-00 million to complete, Some $300 million has been appropriated for this work. These
parts of the total project, at least, appear to have largely passed
beyond the financial control of the public and Congress into the engineering control of the Bureau of Reclamation and the Corps of Engineers.




-23-

Even when the total siae of a project is beyond effective
control because of Congressional authorizations, the rate of expenditure may still be subject to control. The impact of the Missouri
Basin development on the economy, for example, will obviously be quite
different if it is rushed to completion in five years than if it is
spread over fifty years. Here,, the key to control seems to be the
new units or segments of projects started. This stage requires
approval by Congress through actual contract authorizations and
appropriations. An annual summary in the budget document showing the
status, proposed total outlay, and projected timing of the expenditure
of all authorized long-run construction undertakings would contribute
measurably to farsighted control of Federal expenditures.
The Federal civil public works program and proposals shown
in the current budget document are summarized below. Information
on the timing of these expenditures beyond 1950 ig not available.
Estimated
Expenditures in
fiscal 1950
Projects begun before 1950
$2.7 billion
Projects proposed to start in 1950
.3
Projects authorized to start
after 1950
Agency proposals not yet authorized
Total
3.0

Estimated
Expenditures after
fiscal 1950
$6.1 billion
1.9
12.8
1A.0
34.3

Public works is only one of several fields in which activities
are in fact authorized for many years in advance, thus making it difficult
to exercise suitable public policy control by conventional annual, budgeting. The 1950 Budget offers examples from other fields. Universal
military training is estimated to cost |600 million for fiscal 1950, but
the Budget Message mentions a figure of $2 billion for the next year.




-2U-

Evidence is lacking that this figure is founded on careful analysis.
The social insurance proposals offer the paradox of presenting
long-run cost information, but very little one can lay one*s hands
on for the years immediately following 1950. Insofar as possible,
cost data should be set forth for the entire period involved in current
decisions.
Achieving Economy In Government
With each billion dollars added to the federal budget, economy
becomes an issue of more direct concern to all taxpayers - which means
the whole population. Inefficiency that might not have been heavily
damaging in a 5 billion dollar government becomes intolerable at nine
times that figure. It wastes resources that might otherwise have been
put to good use privately or devoted to expansion of needed government
services. Inefficiency begins to be felt in higher taxes than seem
justified. Or alternatively, it results in the vetoing of important
new programs for which there might have been room taxwise in the absence
of waste.
That waste nas become a serious problem in government is substantiated by the findings of the Hoover Commission. The CommissiQn's
reports show that more efficient organization and procedures can, in
the course of time, save hundreds of millions - perhaps even billions of dollars.
The existence of waste in government is hardly surprising.
Government is the nation1 s biggest and most complex business. Its
officials are spending not their own but other people1 s money. And it
is not compelled to live within its income.




-25-

The person who is spending someone elsefs dollars - whether
on a business expense account or on a government job - will usually be
less strict in his standards than if he were spending his own. Vhen
the consequences of spending unwisely or too much are borne by someone
other them the spender, cost-consciousness usually lessens. As government spends a larger and larger proportion of our income, this problem
becomes increasingly serious.
At the same time, bigness and complexity make it difficult to
control and gain accountability in government spending. In a small
business or a small unit of local government, identity or close contact
between the spender and the one who bears the consequences provides the
needed incentive. But as that contact is lost either in the large
corporation or the remote Federal government, the incentive becomes
weaker and wasteful spending tends to grow.
In private units tendencies toward waste are checked by the
painful if not disastrous consequences of living beyond one's income.
But government, by its very nature, lives by different standards.
Unlike private units, which must tailor spending to receipts, government units first decide upon their expenditures and then raise the funds
needed to finance them. Only if we adopt a budgetary policy which makes
higher taxes a consequence of higher expenditures can we enlist the aid
of the revenue test in tightening the expenditure standards of government.
If this general test could be supplemented by a personalized incentive
scheme - one which would relate promotions and higher salaries directly
to superior performance at least cost - we could make real inroads on
the problem of cost consciousness.




-26-

For the most part, inefficiency in government takes intangible
forms - bad organization, deficient procedures, and the lack of incentives
to do things the least expensive way. To the extent that waste consists
of multiplication of agencies doing uncoordinated and overlapping things,
it will yield only slowly to reform. But the more tangible forms of duplication in physical facilities are a promising field for economy, even
in the fairly short run. Duplicate inventories of materials throughout
government, for example, can be liquidated by centralizing both purchasing
and supplies. As the Armed Services become more truly unified, duplication
of air fields, training bases, and service establishments can be avoided
or eliminated.
The Presidentfc recent attempt to cut back the veterans1 hospital
program illustrates, however, the resistance lhat frequently springs up
when an attempt is made to economize. Veterans1 groups imediately protested the cutback. Local groups, in the geographic areas affected,
quickly joined the hue and cry. As a result it appears probable that
most of the cut will be restored.
Resistance of a different kind is encountered in trying to consolidate overlapping agencies, modernize obsolete procedures, and tighten
up on the use of supplies. In part, the economizing process is slowed
down by the resistance of government employees who may lose their jobs
or their power. But the usual vagueness of the issues snd the general
inertia of such a huge organization as the Federal government are more
important obstacles.
The Hoover Commission has made an outstanding contribution in
defining the issues, stimulating public awareness, and offering specific




-27-

suggeetions for reform. The most important of these reforms relate
to such matters as the elimination of duplication, consolidation of
units, improving lines of responsibility end strengthening procedures
for budgeting and expense control.
Perhaps the most impressive case for economy is made by the
Commission's report on National Security. Judging by the report, the
Armed Services provide examples of virtually every type of inefficiency
and waste that exists in government. But the studies of the Commission
have suggested improvements and savings in maiy other areas as well. Only a few
examples need be cited here. In the Veterans' Administration, reorganization and procedural improvement can, it is held, accomplish a 10$6
increase in the average output of each employee, with consequent
savings of as much as $75 million a year. The Task Force report on the
Post Office states that "total annual expenditures in post offices
having receipts of over $1 million per year can be reduced by at least
$90 million if operation^ are placed under better management control,w
though at least $8 million anually will have to be invested to achieve
this economy.
The Research and Policy Committee commends the report of the
Hoover Commission for early consideration and appropriate action.
Giving the President appropriate powers, with safeguards deemed
necessary, to consolidate and reorganize the executive arm of government
would be a hopeful start.
Reliance for achieving economy must also be placed on exposures
of waste, duplication, end inefficiency. Vigilance on the part of individual citizens, civic groups, and news organs in unearthing and




-28-

publicizing examples of wasteful spending has a wholesome effect on
the responsible officials.
The foregoing comments indicate that economy 8nd efficiency
in government can not be achieved either easily or quickly. But they
show just as clearly that economy is not a mere vill-of-the-wisp.
Given the stimulus to achieve economy - and the burdens of a

billion

level of federal spending should certainly provide that stimulus - it
is clear that vigorous efforts in that direction can be very rewarding.
Controlling New Items Of Expenditure
Apart from doing the existing jobs of government at lower
cost, can we effect significant savings by postponing or curtailing
low-priority government programs?
The search for savings will be most fruitful in those areas
where we are currently being asked to undertake new or expanded
commitments. We should focus our attention chiefly on new-item control
rather than tilting at the, windmill of commitments to which we are
legally or morally bound by past actions.
Table IV shows the £8,076 million of expenditures in the
Presidents budget for 1950 which depend on proposed legislation .i^The
largest item in the Table is the £4*655 million for the European Recovery
Program and other foreign aid. Although no legal commitment exists for
these projects, failure to provide funds would be interpreted both at

1/ Excluding expenditures for military aid to the North Atlantic countries.




-29-

home and abroad as breaking a definite moral commitment. Leaving out
this item, we find $3,4-21 million of proposed expenditure which depends
on new legislation, to which we are not yet committed. In this amount
and in the expansion of programs already authorized by statute but for
which appropriations are still required lie the best opportunities for
free choices affecting the expenditure side of the budget. It should
be noted that $1,665 million of the expenditures under new legislation
is for social insurance expansion to be financed by payroll tax increases.
In the field of public works, the Committee thoroughly agress
with the following suggestions made by the President in his budget
message: "Present high costs of construction and large competitive
demands from various sectors of the economy make it necessary to undertake new river basin projects only where urgency, is evident." Further:
"Because of the great increase in the estimated cost of the Missouri
Basin development, the present plan should be reexamined to determine
needed changes."
Parallel with these suggestions, the Committee would raise
two questions. First, is it good public business to spend as much as
$3 billion of public money on construction in 1950 as recommended by
the President? As long as costs are still high and demands for nonFederal construction of some types remain insistent, Federal construction
should be slowed down. Slowing down now would make it easier to speed
up later if economic activity should decline sufficiently to call for
an increase of public works expenditure. Some will protest that a slowdown now would be uneconomical because it would interrupt work already
under way. To this protest it may be answered that the large projects
comprising the bulk of the $3 billion construction item bfeak down into




RO-

TABLE IV

(In Millions)
Cost in Fiscal 1950
International Affairs and Finance
Economic Cooperation Administration
Other Foreign Aid (Greece, Turkey, China, Korea)
Social Insurance
Old Age and Survivors Insurance)
Total and permanent disability )
Temporary disability
)
Unemployment
Medical Care
Other
National defense
Military construction, special programs, military pay
adjustment, etc. (separate amounts not specified)
Universal military training
Public assistance
Slum clearance, low-rent housing,
farm housing and research
Special assistance fdr rental and cooperative housing
Federal aid to education
Grain storage facilities
International wheat agreement
St. Lawrence seaway and power project
Anti-inflation program, rent control, and export control
Surplus property disposal
All other
Total

a

$4655
4300
355
1665
1500
150
15
1756
385
600
65
160
50
290
25
56
8
42
21
54
076

Based on 1950 Budget Message: excludes military aid to North Atlantic countries.




-31-

a series of individual works, especially in flood control and reclamation.
The Committee is convinced that a project-by-project engineering analysis
could squeeze out a sizeable sum for 1950 without impairing performance.
The second question regarding public works is this: are decisions
on the proposed $295 million for new projects in 1950 being made with full
regard to the total costs involved? We have in mind the total of $2.?
billion needed to complete these projects. This proposed expenditure
should be evaluated not simply in terms of the benefits yielded to the
particular area where the projects are located. It should also take into
account for example, the housing or education projects (either public or
private) which may have to be foregone to support the proposed public works.
Particular attention should be given the projects which are at or approaching
the stage of proposed authorizations, such as the St. Lawrence Seaway
and the Columbia River basin development. It is at this stage that control
can be most effective.
There are, of course, other areas in which diligent probing
will reveal opportunities for savings* Such savings can and should be
made without sacrificing essential elements of our programs for military
security and social welfare. But constant vigilance will be needed to
avoid the conversion of Savings on one front into unwarranted expansion
on another front.




-32-

IV. BUDGET POLICT

The proposals In the Presidents January Budget message, excluding the recommended general tax increase, added Up to a cash surplus
of $1*5 billion to be achieved if total personal income remained at about
the $215 billion level of October-December 1948 • The President stated in
January that he would send up at a later date a proposal for expenditure
for military aid to the North Atlantic countries. Inclusion of an
unofficial estimate of $600 million for the purpose would reduce the cash
surplus to $900 million.
The President recommended an increase of tax rates to yield
$4 billion in a full year. He suggested that ftthe principal source . . .
should be additional taxes upon corporate profits", supplemented by higher
taxes on estates and gifts and possibly by an "increase of rates of individual income taxes in the upper and middle brackets*. Because of the normal
lag of tax CQllections, the yield of the additional taxes in fiscal 1950
would be considerably less than $4 billion, perhaps around $2.5 billion.
Thus the Presidents budget recommendations would lead to a
cash surplus of a little over $3 billion at a personal income level Of
$215 billion, the surplus to be achieved by means of a tax increase, mainly
on corporate profits, to offset expenditure increases.
This policy, as explained by the President reflects the belief
that a surplus is necessary to combat inflation, that reduction of the
debt is desirable in conditions of high employment, and that a tax increase
is the best means to achieve the surplus.




The Principles of Budget Poller
a
Any recommendation on budget policy for/particular year reflects,
explicitly or implicitly, certain principles or attitudes about the nature
of budget policy in general*

Should we seek to balance the budget each

year, or should the size of the surplus vaiy with economic condtions?
Should policy each year be guided lay a current economic forecast or should
we rely on more objective standards? Ve must first arrive at general
answers to such questions before we can agree upon, or even discuss usefully,
year-tagr-year budget policy. Our budget is too big, the short-run pressures
and uncertainties too great, to allow us to improvise budget polipy as we
go along.
In 1947 the Committee developed the basic principles of a workable
budget policy that would contribute to economic stability, government
economy and debt reduction*

The key to the program is this:

"Set tax rates to balance the budget and provide a surplus for
debt retirement at agreed high levels of employment and national income.
Having set these rates, leave them alone unless there is some major change
in national policy or condition of national life*"
The meaning of this recommendation and the reasoning that lies
behind it were explained in detail in our Policy Statement "Taxes and the
Budget". Ve shall spell out the main implications here only in brief and
general terms.
If the recommended policy wer* followed, the size of the actual
surplus would vaiy with the size of the actual national income. The lower
employment and national income are, the smaller will be the yield of the




-34-

existing tax rates and the higher the amount of payments for unemployment
compensation. There would be an automatic rise or fall of the surplus
that would tend to check any rise or fall of national income and so to
help maintain stability*

Thus, suppose we arrange our budget expenditure

programs and tax rates so that there would be a cash surplus of $3 billion
at a national income about the current level of $230 billion. If the
national income falls to, say, $215 billion or $200 billion, tax revenues
will decline and unemployment compensation payments rise. The budget
will take less income away from private individuals and businesses and
pay more to them. This will serve to cushion the decline of national
income. In present conditions, when a large part of Federal revenue comes
from corporate profits taxes and business break-even points are unusually
high, a decline of national income wauld reduce tax collections especially
sharply and could easily result in a substantial deficit.
In theory it would be possible to go beyond this automatic
effect of economic fluctuations upon the budget and the corresponding
effects of the budget in reducing fluctuations. That is, in theory it
would be possible to cut taxes in depression and raise taxes in inflation
and so make a greater contribution to stability. But such a policy can
only be effective if the timing is right. It will contribute to
instability, not to stability, if the tax rate changes come too soon or
too late. The well-known unreliability of economic forecasting, plus
the difficulties of getting quick action on tax rates, lead us to conclude
that such a program would be unlikely in fact to contribute to stability.*
In conditions of extreme depression or inflation it may be desirable to




-35-

go beyond the automatic operation of the stable tax-rate program and reduce
or increase tax rates. But in more moderate fluctuations the maximum
contribution of the budget to stability *will, we believe, be obtained
from the general policy we have recommended.
Adherence to the stabilizing budget principle would promote
economy in government. To maintain taxes at the recommended level—enough
to yield a reasonable surplus at agreed high levels of national income—
would require that an increase in government expenditure programs be
matched by a corresponding increase in tax rates. This requirement
would not, of course, serve as a substitute for the constant sifting and
winnowing which is necessary to assure the maximum return per dollar of
government expenditure. Moreover, the Committee recognizes that it may
be undesirable to raise tax rates to meet a large and clearly temporary
expenditure increase. But if the basic principle is followed the general
aversion to higher taxes would be a valuable check on unnecessary expansion of the level of government expenditure.
The Committee's proposal would establish the reduction of the
Federal debt as a recognized item on our fiscal agenda. Its policy would
neither accept a constantly mounting debt as inevitable nor put us in
the straitjacket of compulsory debt retirement each year. Rather, debt
would be retired at and above satisfactory levels of national income
and employment, i.e., when the economy could afford it. If, on the
average, we achieve our go8.1 of maintaining high employment, the debt
would be gradually reduced.
The Committee does not rely on budget or fiscal policy alone
to achieve economic stability. As the Committee pointed out in
Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Greater Economic Stability, economic




-36-

stability requires coordinated action on many fronts. Fiscal policy
must be coupled with monetary and debt management policy. Monetaryfiscal policy, in turn, needs to be buttressed by appropriate wage-price
and agricultural policies and by greater contributions to economic
stability than have hitherto been forthcoming from policies prevailing
in construction, foreign trade and international finance, banking and
insurance, and in the management of individual businesses.
We wish particularly to emphasize that the effectiveness of
budgetary policy as a force for economic stability depends on how well
the debt is managed. A surplus of cash receipts over expenditures will
be more deflationary if it is used to build up the Treasury1 s cash
balance or to pay off government bonds held by the Federal Reserve Banks
than if it is devoted to repayment of savings bonds. Similarly, a
deficit financed by borrowing from commercial banks will be more expanr
sionary than one financed by borrowing from individuals. Changes in
composition of the debt can have significant economic effects. For example, during an inflation it would be appropriate to intensify the
program for selling savings bonds.
The principle recommended here is that the relation between
expenditures and tax rates be so adjusted as to yield a moderate
surplus at agreed high levels of employment and national income.
Application of the principle requires some definition of the size of
the surplus and the high level national income.
In 1947 the Committee suggested that tax rates should be set
at a level that would yield a $3 billion cash surplus under conditions
of high employment.




-37-

The Committee recognizes that it is impossible to determine
now for the indefinite future how large a cash surplus will on the average
be consistent with the maintenance of stability at high employment.
believe that in the prospective condition of the American economy an
annual cash surplus of $3 billion will not ordinarily be too large for
the achievement of prosperity, especially if we adopt policies with
respect to the tax structure, money and the debt that stimulate private
investment. If this belief should in the future prove clearly erroneous,
if the $3 billion annual withdrawal from private incomes and liquid assets
should prove an excessive drag upon the economy, it will be desirable to
reduce the figure.
The revenue estimates included in the Presidents January
budget message were based on the assumption that total personal income
would continue at about $215 billion a year. This is approximately the
level that orevailed in the second half of 1948, somewhat below the peak
reached at the end of 1948, and probably close to the current (Spring 1949)
level. It is a level of income at which we have had high employment with
an average level of prices near the present level. The personal income
figure of $215 billion corresponds to a national income figure of $230
billion. Conceivably with a sufficient decline in prices high employment
could be maintained at a level of national income lower than $230 billion.
However, any considerable fall of national income carries with it the
risk of unemployment. There is no strong reason for setting tax rates
high enough to yield a cash surplus at a national income figure below
that used in the preparation of the budget estimates. Therefore we
consider it a reasonable interpretation of our general principle at the




-38-

present time that the budget should be set to yield a $3 billion surplus
at about $230 billion national income. It should be clear that this
does not imply a forecast that the national income will actually be $230
billion in 1949-1950. If the national income is lower the surplus would
be, appropriately, lower.
Need for Reform of the Tax Structure
Before turning to the application of our general principle
to the question of the total level of taxes in 1949-1950 we wish to
emphasize that tax policy is not merely a question of totals. It is
also a question of the character of the taxes that yield the total.
Our present tax system has seriously detrimental effects upon the
vitality and efficiency of our productive system. We have described
these effects and made suggestions for remedying them in an earlier
policy statement.-^ We shall not repeat them here. Major changes in
the tax structure have often in the past been the by-products of major
changes in the level of taxes. However, this need not be the case.
Important structural improvements can be achieved without any change
in the over-all level of taxes. In fact, the prospect that we may
have to live for some \Aiile with the present over-all level of taxes
makes it especially urgent that we proceed with structural improvements • The present heavy burden of taxes aggravates the structural
defects of the existing system.

1/ Taxes and the Budget» a statement on National policy by the
Research and Policy Committee of the CED, November, 1947, pp. 35-63.




-39-

Fayroll Taxes for Social Security
The President1s proposals include $2.2 billion of payroll
tax increase to finance broader social security benefits. These
benefits, in turn, are estimated by the Budget to account for $1.6
billion of expenditures.
Without passing on thfe merits of the expansion of social
insurance recommended by the President,^ the Committee would agree
that higher payroll taxes are the appropriate means of financing it
under present circumstances. Such taxes are appropriate here because
(1) direct and recognizable benefits are being given in exchange;
(2) they generate the feeling that benefits are received as a matter
of right rather than charity. The Committee is mindful, however, of
the broad interest of society in the welfare of the aged and the consequent justification of a measure of financial support from the
general revenue. Also, as benefits are increased and coverage is
widened, making social insurance more truly a general government
function, we will approach the point where, as the Committee suggested
in Taxes and the Budget* it becomes "appropriate to reconsider the
entire financial status of the system."

1/ The Comnittee has earlier recommended one large single element in
the program, namely, the broadening of old-age and survivors1 insurance.
Ye have also suggested broader coverage of unemployment compensation
and liberalization of benefits. See Taxes and the Budget, pp. 62-3•




-40-

Budget Policy for Fiscal 1950
The Choices Before the Country
The expenditure proposals now before the Congress confront
the country with the necessity for choosing among three courses of
action.
1. To hold expenditures down - so that a moderate cash
surplus would be yielded by existing tax rates under
conditions of high employment.
2. To allow expenditures to rise and to increase tax ratesso that ft ax revenue would cover the increased expenditures
plus a moderate cash surplus at high employment.
3• To allow expenditures to rise and not to increase tax
rates - so that there would be at most a very small
surplus and possibly a deficit even at high employment.
The Need for Reduction of Expenditures
In the present situation the only acceptable course to follow
is to reduce expenditures.
The Committee recognizes the inescapable character of some of
the largest Government expenditure programs. It appreciates the grave
risks that must be weighed t>y those who have to decide the amounts to
be spent for national defense or foreign aid. These decisions cannot
be governed entirely, or even primarily, by fiscal considerations.
But the .existence of a large, hard core of expenditures in
the budget does not mean that the budget as a whole is untouchable.
On the contrary, the extraordinary demands that the current international
situation make upon the Federal budget compel us to practice economy
everywhere with more than ordinary rigor. The question is not whether
we can find expenditure programs in the budget that are useless. The
important questions are (1) can the most essential programs be trimmed




-41-

and carried on more economically and (2) oan the less essential
programs be deferred, curtailed, or eliminated, in view of the great
demands being made upon the budget.
Expert investigation has shown that large amounts can be saved
by reorganization and more efficient operation of the government. In
this connection we have referred in Section III to the findings of the
Hoover. Commission. It is critically imperative that these potential
savings be realized quickly and fully. Ve have also pointed out that
many of the expenditure programs, new and old, submitted to Congress
represent decisions to be made, not necessities to be accepted. Jhere
is, for example, a choice in the rate 8t which we push ahead expanding
public works programs. There are choices in the rate at which we introduce other new programs and carry on old ones.
Vhatever may be said for the "need11 for certain projects that
will increase expenditure, the need must surely be weighed against the
cost. Under present conditions the cost is raising taxes or foregoing
debt reduction* Either cost is too high.
The Cost of Higher Taxes
The burden of taxes in the United States is heavy. Federal
taxes alone take about one-fifth of the national income. Federal,
State and local taxes together take about one-fourth of the national
income. This heavy tax burden is a serious threat to the growth and
efficiency of the American economy. The heavy tax burden reduces the
supply of capital available for investment in expansion and improvement
of productive capacity. It represses the incentives to use funds in
risky, forward looking enterprises, since the Government will take a




-42large share of the rewards if the enterprise is successful but will
only share in any losses to a much smaller extent, if at all. In some
cases the high share that the Government takes of additional earnings
weakens the drive to personal effort. A continuing, large flow of
capital into additional productive capacity, a continuing search for
new and better ways of using funds and personal talent are essential
to the future strength of this country and to the wellbeing of the
whole population, indeed of the whole democratic world. Adding to the
existing tax burden would further weaken these basic supports and
stimulators of our economy.
A tax increase would be particularly risky at the present
time*

There has already been a substantial softening from the boom

economic conditions of a year. ago. Employment and production are
still higi, as this is written• We are not now in a depression. But
no one can tell when the decline may stop or how far it may go* We
should not, if we can avoid it, add the real and psychological impact
of a tax increase to the forces making for the current readjustment*
The Cost of Not Providing for Debt Reduction
The principle that if expenditure levels are increased taxes
should be increased sufficiently to provide for debt reduction during
periods of high employment we regard as essential to the long-run
stability of the American economy. Failure now to hold expenditures
moderately below the revenues that would be yielded by our tax system
under conditions of high employment would be & dangerous departure
from that principle.
This principle is a necessary safeguard against excessive
increase of government expenditure. It should be abandoned only in




-43-

the most extraordinary circumstances.

It is not - and should not be - an

insuperable barrier to any increase of expenditure.

But it does impose

upon the government and the public the discipline of counting the costs
of their expenditure decisions. Thus it tends to confine expenditures
to those of vhich the value is clear after the costs as well ks benefits
have been weighed. There is no practical substitute for the requirement
that taxes be raised when expenditure programs are inpreased|as a means
of bringing the costs as well as the gains into the balance of expenditure decisions. Vithout this balancing we would be exposed to the
danger of continuous expansion of the scope of government and uneconomical
diversion of resources from private to government use.
The principle that the debt should be reduced in periods of
high employment is also a necessary safeguard against a long-run inflationary trend. The Committee has recognized that the importance of
combatting economic instability makes it undesirable to attempt to reduce
the debt during a period of depression. The same consideration points
to the necessity of providing for a

surplus in prosperous times. If

we run deficits in depression and yet enforce no check against deficits
in prosperity we shall get not stability but economic fluctuations
around an inflationary trend.
We have indicated that to increase taxes would be especially
risky now in view of the present business uncertainty. To allow

ex-

penditures to rise so far that existing t***i would not ffleld a surplus
at high employment would add to the existing uncertainty.
suggest an inability to manage our fiscal affairs.




It would

-u-

The Committee's conclusion is: The costs of not curtailing
expenditures are too hiah to pay, in terms of their effects upon the
stability and efficiency of the American economy.

Congress and the

President have -the responsibility for weighing these costs. They cannot
safely accept the position that because expenditure reduction is
difficult the only choice lies between raising taxes and foregoing
debt reduction.

The course of least resistance may be to approve ex-

penditure increases and not to raise taxes.

However, if the effort to

reduce expenditures finally fails, it is the Committee's judgment that
Congress must assume responsibility for raising taxes, as the least
dangerous of the two other alternatives.*

In our judgment, however,

a tax increase is not necessary because, barring major unforeseen
international developments, expenditures for the coming fiscal year can
be reduced.

* Footnote by Beardsley Ruial: It would not be inconsistent with the
position taken \yy the Committee in its policy statement, Taxes and the Budget,
if non-recurring expenditures were financed by the sale of Savings Bonds
to the public. Such sales would be in some measure an alternative to
taxation.




CED BOARD OF TRUSTEES
W. WALTER WILLIAMS, Chairman
PRESIDENT
CONTINENTAL, INC.
SEATTLE, WASHINGTON

HARRY A. BULLIS

CHESTER C. DAVIS

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
GENERAL MILLS, INC.
MINNEAPOLIS, MINNESOTA

PRESIDENT
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS
ST. LOUIS, MISSOURI

WILLIAM BENTON, Vice-Chairman

O. C. CARMICHAEL

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
ENCYCLOPAEDIA BRITANNICA, INC.

PRESIDENT
THE CARNEGIE FOUNDATION FOR THE
ADVANCEMENT OF TEACHING
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
NORTHERN PACIFIC RAILWAY COMPANY
ST. PAUL, MINNESOTA

JOHN W. CARPENTER

R. R. DEUPREE

and

MUZAK CORPORATION
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

MARION B. FOLSOM, Vice-Chairman
TREASURER
EASTMAN KODAK COMPANY
ROCHESTER, NEW YORK

WALTER D. FULLER, Vice-chairman
PRESIDENT
THE CURTIS PUBLISHING COMPANY
PHILADELPHIA, PENNSYLVANIA

ERIC JOHNSTON, Vice-Chairman
PRESIDENT
MOTION PICTURE ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, INC.
WASHINGTON, D. C.

PHILIP D. REED, Vice-Chairman
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
GENERAL ELECTRIC COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

FRANK W. ABRAMS

CHARLES E. DENNEY

PRESIDENT
TEXAS POWER AND LIGHT COMPANY
DALLAS, TEXAS

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
THE PROCTER * GAMBLE COMPANY
CINCINNATI, OHIO

EVERETT NEEDHAM CASE

JOHN S. DICKEY

PRESIDENT
COLGATE UNIVERSITY
HAMILTON, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
DARTMOUTH COLLEGE
HANOVER, NEW HAMPSHIRE

WILLIAM CHENERY

CLARENCE DYKSTRA

VICE PRESIDENT
THE CROWELL-COLLIER PUBLISHING CO.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

FRANK A. CHRISTENSEN
PRESIDENT
THE CONTINENTAL INSURANCE COMPANY

and

FIDELITY & CASUALTY COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
STANDARD OIL COMPANY
( N E W JERSEY)
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

W. L, CLAYTON

GEORGE S. ARMSTRONG

M. W. CLEMENT

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
ANDERSON, CLAYTON & COMPANY
HOUSTON, TEXAS

PROVOST
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA
LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA

MORRIS EDWARDS
PRESIDENT
THE CINCINNATI STREET RAILWAY COMPANY
CINCINNATI, OHIO

M. H. EISENHART
PRESIDENT
BAUSCH & LOMB OPTICAL COMPANY
ROCHESTER, NEW YORK

MILTON S. EISENHOWER
PRESIDENT
KANSAS STATE COLLEGE OF AGRICULTURE

"RESIDENT
GEORGE S. ARMSTRONG * COMPANY, INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
THE PENNSYLVANIA RAILROAD COMPANY
PHILADELPHIA, PENNSYLVANIA

JOHN W. BARRIGER, III

ERLE COCKE

O. J. ELDER

PRESIDENT
THE FULTON NATIONAL BANK
ATLANTA, GEORGIA

PRESIDENT
MACFADDEN PUBLICATIONS, INCORPORATED
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
CHICAGO, INDIANAPOLIS & LOUISVILLE
RAILWAY COMPANY
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

HILAND G. BATCHELLER
PRESIDENT
ALLEGHENY LUDLUM STEEL CORPORATION
PITTSBURGH, PENNSYLVANIA

FRANK N. BELGRANO, JR.
PRESIDENT
FIRST NATIONAL BANK
PORTLAND, OREGON

JOHN D. BIGGERS
PRESIDENT
LIBBEY-OWENS-FO*"* GLASS COMPANY
TOLEDO, OHIO

SARAH G. BLANDING
PRESIDENT
VASSAR COLLEGE
POUGHKEEPSIE, NEW YORK

W. HAROLD BRENTON
PRESIDENT
BRENTON BROTHERS, INCORPORATED
DES MOINES, IOWA

HENRY P. BRISTOL
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
BRISTOL-MYERS COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

JAMES F, BROWNLEE
FAIRFIELD, CONNECTICUT




S. BAYARD COLGATE
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
COLGATE-PALMOLIVE-PEET CO.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

JOHN L. COLLYER
PRESIDENT
THE B. F. GOODRICH COMPANY
AKRON, OHIO

S. SLOAN COLT
PRESIDENT
BANKERS TRUST COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

ARTHUR H. COMPTON
CHANCELLOR
WASHINGTON UNIVERSITY
ST. LOUIS, MISSOURI

EDWARD B. COSGROVE
PRESIDENT
MINNESOTA VALLEY CANNING COMPANY
LE SUEUR, MINNESOTA

GARDNER COWLES
PRESIDENT AND PUBLISHER
DES MOINES REGISTER & TRIRUNE
DES MOINES, IOWA

DONALD DAVID
DEAN
GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION
HARVARD UNIVERSITY
BOSTON, MASSACHUSETTS

AND APPLIED SCIENCE
MANHATTAN, KANSAS

MARK F. ETHRIDGE
PUBLISHER
THE COURIER-JOURNAL

and

THE LOUISVILLE TIMES
LOUISVILLE, KENTUCKY

JAMES A. FARLEY
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
THE COCA-COLA EXPORT SALES COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

R. EARL FISHER
SAN FRANCISCO, CALIFORNIA

RALPH E. FLANDERS
UNITED STATES SENATE
WASHINGTON, D. C.

C. SCOTT FLETCHER
PRESIDENT
ENCYCLOPAEDIA BRITANNICA FILMS INC.
WILMETTE, ILLINOIS

PERCIVAL E. FOERDERER
PRESIDENT
ROBERT H. FOERDERER ESTATE, INC.
PHILADELPHIA, PENNSYLVANIA

HENRY FORD, II
PRESIDENT
FORD MOTOR COMPANY
DEARBORN, MICHIGAN

WILLIAM C. FOSTER

THOMAS ROY JONES

C. HAMILTON MOSES

DEPUTY UNITED STATES SPECIAL
REPRESENTATIVE
ECONOMIC COOPERATION
ADMINISTRATION
PARIS, FRANCE

PRESIDENT
ELIZABETH, NEW JERSEY

PRESIDENT
ARKANSAS POWER ft LIGHT COMPANY
LITTLRROCK, ARKANSAS

CLARENCE FRANCIS

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
UNIVERSAL C. I. T. CREDIT CORPORATION
DETROIT, MICHIGAN

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
CENERAL FOODS CORPORATION
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

ALEXANDER FRASER
PRESIDENT
SHELL UNION OIL CORPORATION
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

CARLYLE FRASER
PRESIDENT
GENUINE PARTS COMPANY
ATLANTA, GEORGIA

ALFRED C. FULLER
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
THE FULLER BRUSH COMPANY
HARTFORD, CONNECTICUT

ATF INCORPORATED

ERNEST KANZLER

HENRY P. KENDALL
PRESIDENT
THE KENDALL COMPANY
BOSTON, MASSACHUSETTS

MEYER KESTNBAUM
PRESIDENT
HART, SCHAFFNER & MARX
CHICACO, ILLINOIS

ROY E. LARSEN
PRESIDENT
TIME, INCORPORATED
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

LARRY E. GUBB

FRED LAZARUS, JR.

PHILCO CORPORATION
PHILADELPHIA, PENNSYLVANIA

PRESIDENT
FEDERATED DEPARTMENT STORES, INC.
CINCINNATI, OHIO

JOHN M. HANCOCK
PARTNER
LEHMAN BROTHERS
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

GEORGE L. HARRISON
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
NEW YORK LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

H. J. HEINZ, II
PRESIDENT
H . J . HEINZ COMPANY
PITTSBURGH, PENNSYLVANIA

ROBERT HELLER
PRESIDENT
ROBERT HELLER & ASSOCIATES, INC.
CLEVELAND, OHIO

PAUL G. HOFFMAN
ADMINISTRATOR
ECONOMIC COOPERATION
ADMINISTRATION
WASHINGTON, D. C.

WILLIAM E. LEVIS
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
OWENS-ILLINOIS GLASS COMPANY
TOLEDO, OHIO

PRESIDENT
THE CLEVELAND ELECfRIC ILLUMINATING
COMPANY
CLEVELAND, OHIO

J. SPENCER LOVE
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
BURLINGTON MILLS CORP.
WASHINGTON, D. C.

THOMAS B. McCABE
CHAIRMAN
BOARD OF GOVERNORS
OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON, D. C.

WILLIAM McCLELLAN
ALEXANDRIA, VIRGINIA

PRESIDENT
HOLLAND ENGRAVING COMPANY
KANSAS CITY, MISSOURI

FOWLER McCORMICK

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
ARMCO STEEL CORPORATION
MIDDLETOWN, OHIO

JAY C. HORMEL
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
GEO. A. HORMEL & CO.
AUSTIN, MINNESOTA

AMORY HOUGHTON
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
CORNING GLASS WORKS
CORNING, NEW YORK

HENRY R. JOHNSTON

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
THE COCA-COLA COMPANY
ATLANTA, GEORGIA




WILLIAM J. MURRAY, JR.
PRESIDENT
MC KESSON & BOBBINS INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

WILLIAM A. PATTERSON
PRESIDENT
UNITED AIR LINES
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

MORRIS B. PENDLETON
PRESIDENT
PLOMB TOOL COMPANY
LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA

MALCOLM PIRNIE
MALCOLM PIRNIE ENGINEERS
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

REUBEN B. ROBERTSON
PRESIDENT
THE CHAMPION PAPER & FIBRE COMPANY
CANTON, NORTH CAROLINA

NELSON A. ROCKEFELLER
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

RAYMOND RUBICAM
SCOTTSDALE, ARIZONA

BEARDSLEY RUML
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
R. H. MACY & CO., INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

LOUIS RUTHENBURG
PRESIDENT
SERVEL, INC.
EVANSVILLE, INDIANA

E. C. SAMMONS
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
INTERNATIONAL HARVESTER COMPANY
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

JAMES H. McGRAW, JR.
PRESIDENT
MCGRAW-HILL PUBLISHING COMPANY, INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
UNITED STATES NATIONAL BANK
PORTLAND, OREGON

HARRY SCHERMAN
PRESIDENT
BOOK-OF-THE-MONT3 CLUB
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

GEORGE H. MEAD

HARPER SIBLEY

HONORARY CHAIRMAN
THE MEAD CORPORATION
DAYTON, OHIO

SIBLEY FARMS, INC.
ROCHESTER, NEW YORK

EUGENE MEYER
THE WASHINGTON POST
WASHINGTON, D. C.

NEW YORK, NEW YORK

HARRISON JONES

PRESIDENT AND PUBLISHER
NEWSWEEK
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

ELMER L. LINDSETH

LOU HOLLAND

CHARLES R. HOOK

MALCOLM MUIR

GEORGE L. MORRISON
CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD AND
PRESIDENT
GENERAL BAKING COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

S. ABBOT SMITH
PRESIDENT
THOMAS STRAHAN COMPANY
CHELSEA, MASSACHUSETTS

H. CHRISTIAN SONNE
PRESIDENT
AMSINCK, SONNE & COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

JOSEPH P. SPANG, JR.

J. CAMERON THOMSON

SIDNEY J. WEINBERG

PRESIDENT

PRESIDENT
NORTHWEST BAN CORPORATION
MINNEAPOLIS, MINNESOTA

GOLDMAN, SACHS & COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

GILLETTE SAFETY RAZOR CO.
BOSTON, MASSACHUSETTS

PARTNER

CHARLES E. WILSON

ROBERT GORDON SPROUL

NILES TRAMMELL

PRESIDENT
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA
BERKELEY, CALIFORNIA

PRESIDENT
NATIONAL BROADCASTING COMPANY, INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

ELMER T. STEVENS

MANAGING DIRECTOR
AMERICAN CAS ASSOCIATION
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
RAYMOND CONCRETE PILE COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

CHAS. A. STEVENS & COMPANY
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

JAMES W. YOUNG

JOHN P. STEVENS, JR.

LOUIS C. UPTON

PRESIDENT
J. P. STEVENS & COMPANY, INC.
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

SENIOR CONSULTANT
J. WALTER THOMPSON COMPANY
NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT
NINETEEN HUNDRED CORPORATION
ST. JOSEPH, MICHIGAN

JOHN STUART

J. D. ZELLERBACH
PRESIDENT

ALAN VALENTINE

CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD
THE QUAKER OATS COMPANY
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS

CROWN ZELLERBACH CORPORATION
SAN FRANCISCO, CALIFORNIA

PRESIDENT
UNIVERSITY OF ROCHESTER
ROCHESTER, NEW YORK

CHARLES P. TAFT

HARRY W. ZINSMASTER

CINCINNATI, OHIO

L. A. VAN BOMEL

WAYNE C. TAYLOR

NATIONAL DAIRY PRODUCTS CORPORATION

PRESIDENT

ADVISER ON FINANCIAL AND FISCAL POLICIES
ECONOMIC COOPERATION
ADMINISTRATION
WASHINGTON, D. C.

Secretary

Elizabeth H. Walker




GENERAL ELECTRIC COMPANY
SCHENECTADY, NEW YORK

H. CARL WOLF

MAXWELL M. UPSON

PRESIDENT

PRESIDENT

PRESIDENT
ZINSMASTER BREAD COMPANY
DULUTH, MINNESOTA

GEORGE F. ZOOK

NEW YORK, NEW YORK

PRESIDENT

JOHN H. VAN DEVENTER

AMERICAN COUNCIL ON EDUCATION
WASHINGTON, D. C.

BRONXVILLE, NEW YORK

Policy Statement Director

Information Director

Howard B. Myers
Director, Finance Division

W. Frederic Mosel

Nate White
Field Director

Robert S. Donaldson

Editors Advance text, May 1949 (4991) 5M
Committee for Economic Developmext
444 Madison Avenue, New York 22, N.Y.