View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

73D CONGRESS

2d Session

) HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES (
J
\

REPGKT

No. 1853

STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS
JUNE 1, 1934.—Committed to the Committee of the Whole House on the state
of the Union and ordered to be printed

Mr. STEAGALL, from the Committee on Banking and Currency,
submitted the following

REPORT
[To accompany H.R. 9045]
The Committee on Banking and Currency, to whom was referred
the bill (H.R. 9045) to amend section 5219 of the Revised Statutes,
as amended, having considered the same, report favorably thereon
with an amendment and recommend that the bill do pass as amended.
The amendment is as follows:
Commencing with line 6, page 1, strike out all down to and including line 12 and insert in lieu thereof the following:
SEC. 5219. The legislature of each State may determine and direct the manner
and place of taxing national banking associations located within its limits upon
their real and personal property and also upon their shares: Provided, That in
lieu of such tax upon the shares, the legislature may impose either a tax upon
the net income of such associations or an excise tax measured by net income
received by them from all sources: Provided further, That such taxation shall not
be at greater rates than are imposed, respectively, upon the real and personal
property or shares or income of, or by way of excise
(or franchise) tax upon,
State banks: And provided further, That a State jwhich imposes a tax on the net
income of individuals or corporations, or an excise or a franchise tax on corporations measured by their net income, may abo include in such income of individuals or corporations the dividends from national banking associations located
in the State, but only if dividends from the State banks of such State are similarly
included; and may also tax dividends from such associations located without the
State, but in such case at no higher rate than is imposed on the dividends from
foreign corporations. As herein used the words "State banks" shall mean and
include all persons and corporations engaged primarily in the business of commercial banking; and the word "shares" in its application to individuals engaged primarily in the business of commercial banking shall mean- the capital
and surplus of such business, and the word "dividends" shall in such case mean,
the distributed profits therefrom.
SCOPE AND PURPOSE OF THE BILL

The purpose of this bill is to end the intolerable conditions created
in many of the States by the decision in 1921 in the so-called " Richmond bank tax case" (Merchants National Bank of Richmond,



J

STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BASKETS

256 U.S. 635) relating to the taxation of national baoik shares by the
States; and at the same time* to simplify and bring into Iiaratcmy
with the principle of the bill the alternative methods of bamk taxation
which were introduced by amendments to section 521 SI of the Revised
Statutes passed in 1923 and 1926. Under this bill national banks
and their shareholders are protected against any greater taxation
than that imposed in the case of State banks or individuals or corporations engaged in the business of commercial banking. In the
form in which it is drawn, the bill is an adequate substitute for the
present unsatisfactory law and sets up the only standard which
experience has shown to be at once fair, feasible, and practicable.
CONDITIONS WHEN SECTION 5219 WAS ENACTEB

Section 5219, as it stood at the time of the Richmond bank decision,
had remained unchanged since 1868. In addition to a tax on the real
estate of the banks, it authorized the taxation of the shares,, subject
to, the restriction " that the taxation shall not be at a greater rate
than is assessed upon other moneyed capital in the hands of individual
citizens of such State." Tiiis condition was inserted before the1
adoption of the fourteenth amendment, with its "equal protection"
clause, and during the period immediately following the Civil War.
At that time virtually all the States employed the general property
tax system under which all property was taxed at rates which were
uniform throughout the respective taxing districts. Personal property, tangible and intangible, was subjected to the same tax rate which
was applied to real property. So long as this system prevailed, the
banks had no ground, apparent on the face of the statute, for
complaining of discrimination.
SUCCESSIVE INTERPRETATIONS OF SECTION 5219

By successive decisions of the courts the meaning of the words
"other moneyed capital" was narrowed by the exclusion of various
forms of property, savings banks, building and loan associations,
insurance companies, shares of foreign corporations, etc. It was
further limited by other decisions holding that the capital must be
that of individuals and not of corporations; that it must be used in
the business of employing money; that it must be capital competing
with the business of national banks; that it must be in substantial
amount; and that the discrimination must be intentional and unfriendly. The net result of all this litigation was a general understanding on the part of the banks as well as on the part of the States
that a tax on the shares of national banks could not be defeated if
their substantial competitors, the State banking institutions, were
not given more favorable treatment. This may not have been the
strict legal purport of all these decisions, but it was certainly the
practical effect, because of the exclusion of so many classes as comparatives and because of the difficulty of gratifying the various conditions imposed by the court rulings. That the national banks were not
alarmed by this situation may reasonably be inferred from the fact
that no effort was made by them to have it changed by Federal legislation. It is therefore evident that they could have suffered no real
harm under the long-continued practice which classified them with
State banking institutions.




STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

3

SUCCESS UNDER CLASSIFIED TAX SYSTEMS

Because it was so generally accepted that investments in private
securities could thus safely be put in a different class for taxation
purposes, encouragement was given to the movement for the separate classification of such intangibles. This took the form in State
after State of a low fixed millage rate which was fully justified by
sound fiscal, policy. It need but be pointed out that in the city of
Baltimore the reduction of the tax rate on bonds and foreign stocks,
from the general property rate.of about 2 percent to a special rate of
about one-half percent, increased the taxable basis of such property
in the first year (1897) from $6,000,000 to $60,000,000. In Minnesota the application of a 3-mill rate to moneys and credits increased
the basis of such property for the first year from 13 millions to 115
millions; and, as illustrating the wholesome effects of the law, the
number of persons returning such property rose at the same time
from 6,200 to 41,000. The effect of a reduced rate in Kentucky was
to increase the assessment on bank deposits from 11 millions to 179
millions in 1 year, to which 30 millions were added in the following
year, with progressive increases from year to year.
The crowning instance of enlightened self-interest was in Virginia,
where the very banks in whose favor the Supreme Court had been
persuaded, in the Richmond case, to hold that they were harmed and
discriminated against by a 95-cent rate on the alleged competitive
"other moneyed capital" represented by a $6,250,000 assessment on
mortgages, bonds, and notes, shortly thereafter openly and actively
favored and promoted the passage of the act which reduced the rate
on such property to 55 cents. If anything could more conclusively
confirm the unsubstantial nature of the complaint upon which the
Richmond decision was founded, it is the fact that in spite of the
further material differential thus created as between the rate on bank
shares and the rate on this " other moneyed capital", these very banks
continued to submit to a rate twice as high ($1.10) and were even
willing to enter into binding written agreements to foreclose all right
to claim discrimination.
Wherever this improved system was installed, the results were
gratifying and wholesome. Invariably the taxes paid by the owners
of intangible investments were mateiially greater than had been
collected when the rate on such intangibles was higher. It is obvious
that the great increase in revenue receipts from this source was of
no less advantage to the banks than to other taxpayers. The new
system, in improving the cause of tax honesty, also had the beneficial
tendency of inducing a fairer valuation of other property, because,
by minimizing tax evasion in the matter of intangible property, it
weakened the familiar excuse for underassessment (which always
produces unequal assessment) of all ether property, including real
estate.
BASIS OF RICHMOND BANK DECISION

As the Supreme Court had held (Aberdeen Bank v. Chehalis County,
166 U.S. 440) that since failure to reach intangible personal property
for taxation because of the inherent difficulties of enforcing the law,
did not constitute an intentional discrimination against national
banks, within the meaning of section 5219, the banks had everything



4

STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

to gain by the low-rate classified system of taxing such intangibles.
It seems therefore the irony of fate that the trouble and confusion
caused by the Richmond bank decision should have been due to the
lower rate applied to mortgages and other private investments, which
the court treated as competitive moneyed capital on the mere opinion
of an officer of the bank that loans and investments by individuals
and corporations tend to lower the rate of return "that a bank can
get on a similar investment." There was no evidence in the case to
show the particulars of these investments nor whether any of them
were employed in financial business. This sums up the " testimony "
which the Supreme Court accepted, without more, as proving unlawful discrimination in that case. Apparently it did not occur to the
Court that, on the theory advanced by the bank officer, all money in
the State, available for loans or for such investment as banks are
permitted to make, is in competition with the business of the banks.
REASON FOR LIGHTER TAX ON INTANGIBLES

One reason why intangibles like bonds and mortgages are entitled
to light taxation, or even to total exemption, is because the property
upon which they are secured is already taxed. It was recognized
by the court in Mercantile Bank v. New York (121 U.S. 138, 150) that
a tax on the intangible in such case imposes a double burden. The
exemption, or taxation at nominal rates, of the shares of foreign corporations is justifiable on similar grounds. It follows, therefore,
that though such intangibles were properly to be regarded as competitive to bank shares or to banking capital, there would still be no
reason for requiring that they must be taxed at the rates fairly applicable to bank shares, in order to sustain such tax on the bank shares.
ECONOMIC DIFFERENCES BETWEEN STOCKS AND BONDS

It needs to be emphasized that, from the standpoint of taxation,
there is no similarity between a share of bank stock and a bank
deposit or a credit represented by a note or a bond. The share of
stock represents the ownership of an aliquot part of a going business,
operated under a valuable franchise. It participates in the profit
from the use of all the moneyed capital of the bank. It carries the
right to share in the profit derived not only from the investment of
the so-called "capital assets of the corporation" (the equivalent of
the share investment) but also the profit derived from the use and
investment of funds contributed by others, mostly in the form of
deposits. The shareholder also participates in profits derived from
other lucrative bank activities, involving the use of relatively little
capital, such as rental of safe-deposit boxes and acting as trustee or
in other fiduciary capacities. The additional contributed capital
(deposits) amounts normally to four or five times the amount of the
bank's own "capital and surplus", and in many instances is maintained at a ratio as high as 15 or 20 to 1. It is because the shareholder thus participates in the profits derived from the use of other
people's money besides his own that the dividends often rise to high
figures—and this after payment of all expenses, including taxes.
Proper consideration of the characteristics of the bank share, as
compared with the mortgage or bond or note or other credit, clearly
justifies a difference in their treatment by the tax laws.



STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

5

The failure of section 5219, as interpreted in the Richmond case
and subsequent decisions, to recognize this economic difference is
responsible for the chaotic condition respecting bank taxation throughout the country. A statement in one of the reports of the committee
on taxation of the American Bankers Association illustrates the
extremes to which fallacious comparison may lead. In discussing the
tax status of national banks in Kansas, the report says:
Indeed it is doubtful if they (the banks) could be required to pay more than the
equivalent of the 2% mill nonrecurrent recording tax that is applicable to domestic
real-estate mortgages, if the matter were pressed in the courts.

In Delaware there is an even more astounding situation. Bank
shares there are taxed at the low rate of 2 mills per $100 of book
value; and as bonds, notes, mortgages, and other credits are not taxed
at all, the banks would go scotfree if they were not ashamed or afraid
to take advantage of the remarkable position created for them by the
court decisions.
NONCOMPETING MONEYED CAPITAL

It is impossible to reconcile the theory of harmful competition from
ordinary investments with the opinions expressed in some of the
decided cases. Thus, in the leading case of Mercantile Bank v. New
York (121 U.S. 138), the Court rejected the idea that even the huge
amount of a half-billion dollars invested by the savings banks of
New York could be regarded as moneyed capital competing with the
business of national banks; and yet the investments of savings banks
differ in no essential respect from those of commercial banks except
perhaps in the matter of unsecured loans. Said the Court:
No one Can suppose for a moment that savings banks come into any possible
competition with national banks of the United States * * *. Their multiplication cannot in any sense injuriously affect any legitimate enterprise in the
community.

And in the recent case of First National Bank v. Louisiana Tax
Commission (289 U.S. 60) the Court said:
There is a fundamental difference between banks which make loans mainly
from the money of depositors and the other financial institutions which make
loans mainly from the money supplied otherwise than by deposits.

The bank had complained that it was more heavily taxed than
"loan companies; finance and securities companies; pawnbrokers;
homestead and building associations; Federal joint-stock land banks;
life-insurance companies; real-estate mortgage and investment, or
bond and investment brokers."
Furthermore, the Court refused to infer that the national bank
was discriminated against, under section 5219, merely because the
following classes of property were exempted by statute from taxation:
Cash on hand and on deposit; mortgages and mortgage notes on
Louisiana property; loans by building and loan associations secured
by the stock of such associations; debts due for merchandise or
services. Nor would the Court infer hurtful discrimination from the
fact that corporate bonds are assessable at only 10 percent of market
value, while the regular property rate is laid on the full book value
of bank shares, less credit for real estate.
To the suggestion that there was hurtful competition with capital
employed by loan companies, so-called "Morris Plan" companies,



6

STATE TAXATION" OF NATIONAL BANKS

and automobile finance companies, the Court replied that loans by
such corporations differ from bank loans and that such companies
are not competitors of the banks, quoting the language of the lower
court as follows:
The national banks would never handle such business. They prefer to—and
do in fact—lend to such companies.

The opinion of the Supreme Court in the Louisiana case is significant not only because it was rendered after the disturbing rulings in
the Richmond bank case (256 U.S.) and the latter ones in the Wisconsin and Minnesota cases (both in 273 U.S.) but because it refuses
to deal with theoretical grievances and shows a keen comprehension
of the actualities of the situation. It certainly lends support to the
principle of the bill (H.R. 9045) which recognizes that national
banks are protected from genuine, hurtful, and substantial discrimination, when they are put on an equality with others engaged in the
business of commercial banking.
UNSOUND STANDARD OF COMPARISON IN SECTION 5 2 1 9

The underlying fallacy, therefore, of the moneyed capital standard
fixed in section 5219 is that it includes a comparison of two things which
are not properly comparable. So far as there is a comparison of the
tax burden on the shares of the bank with the tax burden on the shares
of substantially competitive moneyed corporations incorporated by the
State where the bank is situated, it compares similar things and lays
down a rational and easily enforceable rule. l And if it compared the
share tax burden, measured by its incidence on the total intangible
resources of the bank, with the tax burden on the intangible resources
of competing corporations, or with the intangible resources of individuals or unincorporated concerns engaged in similar business, the
comparison would also be of like with like. But the defect in section
5219, and the reason why so much difficulty has been encountered in
attempting to apply it, is in the requirement that the tax burden on
the shares of the bank must also be compared with the tax burden on
the gross intangible resources of individuals. In other words, the
tax rate applied to the net worth of the bank is not permitted to be
greater than the tax rate when applied against the gross worth of the
individual, even in States which permit the individual to deduct the
debts growing out of the business.
As has already been shown, banks operate not merely with their
surplus and share capital, but with their entire resources. It is
therefore palpably unfair to limit the rate applicable to their shares
(which are the practical equivalent of capital and surplus) to the rate
applicable to the gross intangible resources, or " other moneyed
capital", in the hands of individuals. Unfortunately, this glaring
defect is now apparently beyond cure by the device of judicial construction, because as recently as the decision in the Minnesota case
(Minnesota v. First National Bank, 273 U.S. 561), decided in 1927,
the Court ruled that under the present section 5219 the tax burden
is to be measured by the value of the bank's shares and not by the
value of its assets; and that, in a comparison of relative tax burdens,
1
It has been held that sec. 5219 has to do with the ''actual incidence and practical burden of the tax upon
the taxpayer, "Amoskeag Savings Bank v. Purdy (231 U.S. 373, 386). And while this sound principle was
applied in that case to sustain the share tax, it seems to have escaped attention since then.




STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

7

it is not permissible similarly to reflect debts and liabilities against
the gross assets of individuals.
AS TO CERTAINTY OF SHARE TAX

It has also been put forward by the banks, as a reason for preferential treatment, that the assessment of bank shares is certain and the
tax thereon collectible, while a considerable amount in bonds and
other taxable credits belonging to private investors eludes the assessor. This argument is without force. By the same token it
would entitle the owners of many other classes of property, especially
of real estate, to a similar concession. Public revenue must, however,
come from somewhere, and it is inevitable that it comes in major part
from sources that are certain. Moreover, it is the certain taxes which
are more readily and more commonly shifted upon others. Bank
taxes are loaded into the expenses w^hich, in normal operations, form
part of the charges collected by the bank for the use of money or for
other services. It is because the taxes paid by the banks of New
York and Massachusetts and other States on ad valorem share assessments which none of them at the time believed to be violative of
section 5219 that the refund of millions of dollars of taxes, in consequence of the unlooked-for decision in the Richmond bank case, were
without real equitable basis, since the banks had already been reimbursed.
EFFECTS OF SHARE TAX CHAOS

As a result of these later decisions which have put private investments in bonds and mortgages into a class with bank shares, the
classified tax systems prevailing in nearly one-half the States were put
in peril of disruption. The ensuing dilemma gave the banks an advantage which they are loth to surrender without a struggle—and the
struggle has now been going on for over a dozen years. The hopeless
plight of income-tax States caused them to submit early to one or the
other of the alternative tax methods offered by the 1923 and 1926
amendments to section 5219, namely, income or excise taxation. Data
presented before the committee show that in Alabama and California
the tax revenue from banks in the first year under the new system
amounted to only one-eighth of the money collected in the previous
year under the share tax; and in New York, Massachusetts, and
Wisconsin, to one-fourth.
Other States have been compelled to reduce the rate of tax by
amending the law—in some cases to the nominal millage rate which
is applied to bonds and other credits; while a number of others have
been forced to the humiliating expedient of a " gentlemen's agreement", whereby the tax rate is set at a figure which the banks deem
to be "fair." In the meantime, the States and local communities
are marking time awaiting remedial action by the Congress. There
are a few States which have escaped embarrassment thus far, some
of them because their law applies the full property rate to moneys
and credits as well as to bank shares, thus bringing the law within
the letter of section 5219. Oddly enough, if banks ever suffer by
reason of low-taxed or untaxed investments, privately held, they
must suffer most in States which undertake the impossible task of
collecting on moneys and credits a tax equal to that on bank shares.



8

STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

Reference has already been made to the large sums which some of
the States were obliged to refund after the Richmond bank decision.
The numerous suits and controversies which arose and the heavy
drafts on their treasuries have not served to allay the feeling that
something must be done, as speedily as possible, to bring order out
of chaos.
During the long period of litigation, agitation, fiscal embarrassment, uncertainty, and general confusion, progress in the improvement
of tax conditions generally, has been halted. States that have the
classified tax are on the anxious bench, while States that have obsolete
systems fear to make a change. There is agreement in the States that
no one of the alternatives offered by section 5219 insures a proper
return except in the few States where the banks continue to pay as
before.
INCOME AND EXCISE TAX ALTERNATIVES

While the right to tax income or to impose an excise tax, given by
the amendments to section 5219 of 1923 and 1926, have only been
availed of by States which were rendered powerless by the Richmond
decision to continue the share tax, it has been thought proper to
retain this alternative privilege for the benefit of States which may
desire to, or may not be in a position to change the systems now
installed. The weakness of the income-tax plan is that when there is
no income there is no tax; and in any event, it may vary materially
from year to year, making it difficult to frame the budgets. Under
the share tax the situation is better. All banks had over many years
accepted it as a fixture and had adapted themselves to it. They paid
the tax on an ad valorem basis, just as they paid the tax on real
estate, and allowed for it in fixing their charges.
The excise tax has this advantage over the income tax, that it permits the inclusion of income whifih would be exempt if directly taxed,
such as interest on Government securities; also on State and municipal
bonds, in the issuing States. It is not perceived that any State would,
in view of this, choose the income tax in preference to the excise tax,
unless there existed some constitutional reason for the choice.
The bill as drawn preserves equality as between National and State
banking institutions. It also retains the existing right in income-tax
States, to include the dividends with the taxable income of the shareholders, whether they reside in or without the State of the bank's
location.
A JUST, SIMPLE AND WORKABLE PLAN

The numerous hearings conducted before the committees of Congress since the crisis created by the Richmond bank decision of 1921
have but confirmed the conviction that no fairer or sounder or more
practicable rule for the protection of national banks can be devised
than to guarantee to them equal treatment with comparable State
banking institutions. Among the many curative plans proposed in
the various bills introduced since 1921, there is none which is freer
from valid objections than the one now reported. The plan is just.
It is simple. It is workable.. It embodies all the protection that is
necessary or can reasonably be asked for.
Experience has shown that commercial banks and bankers are the
only true, substantial competitors of national banks. Private in


STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

9

vestors certainly are not. Neither are many of the great banking
houses like those in New York who underwrite and buy and sell
securities—unless they do a commercial banking business. This may
be tested by inquiring whether the banks would put them out of
business if they could. They are actually great feeders and businessgetters for the banks and as such are welcomed by them. So, far
from being undesired, the banks have protected and nourished them
and have refrained from using their great power to have restrictions
imposed on them in the conduct of their business—restrictions to
which the banks willing^ submit for themselves.
SPECIAL PROTECTION NOT ESSENTIAL

Banks, National as w^ell as State, are owned by human beings—
hundreds of thousands of them—who are citizens of the States. They
are recognized as essential to the well-being of the body politic. They
cater in some manner to the needs of all the people. Numberless
persons have a very direct interest in the thousands of banking institutions—as stockholders or officers or employees or borrowers or
depositors or as relatives or friends of these. The events of the last
year have proved this, if proof were needed. Communities point
with pride to their banks and the imposing structures many of them
have erected.
If, in view of all this, it could still be conceived that hostile and
injurious action would be taken against banking institutions if again
treated as a class, then it need only be pointed out that there are other
important forms of invested wealth which have had no such special
favor from the Federal Government and have not been impelled to
demand it. The railroads, the telegraph, and the telephone companies
are in times of war even more essential Federal instrumentalities
than the banks—so essential that they deserve all possible encouragement in times of peace as well. They are content with the equal
protection assured them by the fourteenth amendment. In most of
the States, though they have been put into individual classes for the
purposes of taxation, they have felt themselves able to look after
their own interests in that regard without appealing for the special
interposition of Congress. Their property may be classified by the
States for taxation; their receipts may be made to pay tribute;
their stockholders may be taxed on their shares—all free of conditions
laid down by Congress.
The 13,645 National and State corporations engaged in the business
of commercial banking have aggregate resources of 40 billions, an
amount of wealth equaled by few other classes. That they have the
power and influence to prevent hostile or unjust State legislation, if it
were attempted, will be readily believed by all those who have observed the power and influence they have been able to exert in other
directions. The general trend of bank-tax legislation over many
years has been to reduce, and not to increase, their burden. Where
taxes have risen, their increased wealth or profits may have justified
it, or else the taxes of other property owners have likewise been increased in order to meet the growing expenses of government.
Finally, it ought not to be necessary to remind those, if any there
be, who harbor a sincere fear of the consequences if section 5219 should
be restored to its long-accepted meaning, that the act of Congress ii



10

STATE TAXATION OF NATIONAL BANKS

remain under the control of the Federal law-making body and that
the two Houses of Congress will continue to be open for business.
In conformity with 2a of rule XIII of the House rules, there is
herewith printed in full section 5219 of the Revised Statutes, as
amended, printed in brackets, and the proposed new matter printed
in italics, as follows:
SEC. 5219. [ T h e legislature of each State may determine and direct, subject
to the provisions of this section, the manner and place of taxing all the shares of
national banking associations located within its limits. The several States may
(1) tax said shares, or (2) include dividends derived therefrom in the taxable
income of an owner or holder thereof, or (3) tax such associations on their net
income, or (4) according to or measured by their net income, provided the following conditions are complied with:
1. (a) The imposition by any State of any one of the above four forms of
taxation shall be in lieu of the others, except as hereinafter provided in subdivision
(c) of this clause.
(b) In the case of a tax on said shares the tax imposed shall not be at a greater
rate than is assessed upon other moneyed capital in the hands of individual citizens
of such State coming into competition with the business of national banks:
Provided, That fronds, notes, or other evidences of indebtedness in the hands of
individual citizens not employed or engaged in the banking or investment business
and representing merely personal investments not made in competition with such
business, shall not be deemed moneyed capital within the meaning of this section.
" (c) In case of a tax on or according to or measured by the net income of an
association, the taxing State may, except in case of a tax on net income, include
the entire net income received from all sources, but the rate shall not be higher
than the rate assessed upon other financial corporations nor higher than the highest of the rates assessed by the taxing State upon mercantile, manufacturing, and
businessr corporations doing business within its limits: Provided, however, That a
State w hich imposes a tax on or according to or measured by the net income of,
or a franchise or excise tax on, financial, mercantile, manufacturing, and business
corporations organized under its own laws or laws of other States and also imposes a tax upon the income of individuals, may include in such individual
income dividends from national banking associations located within the State on
condition that it also includes dividends from domestic corporations and may
likewise include dividends from national banking associations located without
the State on condition that it also includes dividends from foreign corporations,
but at no higher rate than is imposed on dividends from such other corporations.
" (d) In case the dividends derived from the said shares are taxed, the tax shall
not be at a greater rate than is assessed upon the net income from other moneyed
capital.
" 2 . The shares of any national banking association owned by nonresidents of
any State, shall be taxed by the taxing district or by the State where the association is located and not elsewhere; and such association shall make return of such
shares and pay the tax thereon as agent of such nonresident shareholders.
" 3 . Nothing herein shall be construed to exempt the real property of associations from taxation in any State or in any subdivision thereof, to the same .extent,
according to its value, as other real property is taxed.
"4. The provisions of section 5219 of the Revised Statutes of the United
States as heretofore in force shall not prevent the legalizing, ratifying, or confirming by the States of any tax heretofore paid, levied, or assessed upon the shares
of national banks, or the collecting thereof, to the extent that such tax would
be valid under said section."]
The legislature of each State may determine and direct the manner and place of taxing national banking associations located within its limits upon their real and personal
property and also upon their shares, provided that in lieu of such tax upon the shares,
the legislature may impose either a tax upon the net income of such association or an
excise tax measured by net income received by them from all sources: Provided
further, That such taxation shall not be at greater rates than are imposed, respectively,
upon the real and personal property or shares or income of, or by way of excise (or
franchise) tax upon, State banks: And provided further, That a State which imposes
a tax on the net income of individuals or corporations, or an excise or franchise tax
on corporations measured by their net income, may also include in such income of
individuals or corporations the dividends from national banking associations located
in the State, but only if dividends from the State banks of such State are similarly



STATE TAXATION" OF NATIONAL BANKS

H

included; and may also tax dividends from such associations located without the
State, but in such case at no higher rate than is imposed on the dividends from foreign
corporations. As herei/i used, the words "State banks" shall mean and include all
persons and corporations engaged primarily in the business of commercial banking;
and the word "shares" in its application to individuals engaged primarily in the
business of commercial banking shall mean the capital and surplus of such business,
and the word "dividends" shall in such case mean the distributed profits therefrom.
In case of a tax on shares, the shares of any national banking association owned by
nonresidents of any State shall be taxed by the district or by the State where the association is located and not elsewhere; and such association shall make return of such
shares and pay the tax thereon as agent of such nonresident shareholders.




o