View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 15, 1936.

THE PROPOSED TAX ON UNDISTRIBUTED EARNINGS

Now that there is apparently a disposition to retain a flat fifteen
percent corporate income tax, which gives assurance against any loss of
revenue, it is important to return to the original objectives of the tax
on undistributed earnings. While the primary purpose is, of course, to
raise additional revenue, the special objectives of this particular tax
can only be attained if the practice of the few thousand big corporations
of retaining enormous amounts of undistributed earnings is effectively
checked•
From 1923 to 1929 non-financial corporations reporting net earnings
retained $24,657,000,000*

Since over 90 percent of corporate income is

earned by less than 10 percent of the corporations, the overwhelming
bulk of this figure of retained earnings is represented by a few thousand
big corporations*

Various consequences flow from this fact.

In the first place, it points to a glaring inequality in our tax
laws by means of which billions of dollars of the income of the wealthiest
in the community escape personal income taxes. Only a small amount of
these retained earnings was paid out in dividends during the depression,
non-financial corporations reporting deficits paying out only #3,769,000,000
in the years 1930-33, while non-financial corporations reporting net
income actually retained $1,034,000,000 of their earnings in these years.
From 1926 to 1929, three Mellon corporations paid out only $27,000,000
out of $178,000,000 reported available for common. In the depression
years they paid out only $15,000,000 in common dividends that were unearned.
For various reasons the amount retained was undoubtedly much greater than
these figures show. This loophole in the law should be closed before



-2-

higher income tax rates are imposed on those who cannot evade payment.
Secondly, it is doubtful whether any other factor has contributed
more to the growth of uneconomic bigness, to the lessening of competition,
to the continued absorption of small concerns, to excessive plant
investment, and to the skyrocketing of stock prices, than the ease with
which big corporations have obtained new money by withholding earnings.
Our tax laws have actually encouraged these developments by offering
inducements to retain earnings•
Thirdly, withheld earnings by the few thousand big corporations
not only impede recovery now but make the problem of securing a tolerable
measure of business stability

in the future more difficult of solution.

Of the increase in adjusted demand deposits in member banks from June 30,
1933, to June 30, 1935, of $5,389,000,000, some #3,901,000,000, or 72
percent occurred in cities with a population over 150,000. They represented
presumably mainly large corporate accounts. A special study of large
deposits indicates that from October 25, 1933 to November 1, 1935 some
5,558 accounts increased $882,000,000. The indications now are that
business deposits are in excess of 1929, although both production and
prices are lower. Industry has been disbursing less to the factors of
production than it has been receiving in the sale of products to those
factors. This piling up of idle deposits represents a source of danger
in the future if there should be a concerted move to utilise thenou

It appears, therefore, that the objectives of the proposed tax will
be lost unless the rates proposed are high enough to force the distribution




-5-

of the earnings of the large corporations. The tentative schedule of rates
proposed in the Senate Finance Committee will not achieve this*

Personal

incomes in excess of $74,000 are subject to surtax rates ranging from 47
to 75 percent. The highest rate in the proposed schedule is 45 percent.
Since it is a fair assumption that individuals dominating large corporations have incomes in excess of $74,000, it follows that they will continue
to find it personally advantageous to leave earnings undistributed.
The lowness of the proposed rates is doubtless attributable to the
desire not to make it too difficult for small corporations to grow. Since,
however, it is proposed to retain a corporate income tax, this objective
can best be obtained by exempting earnings up to $15,000 of corporations
other than personal holding companies from the undistributed earnings tax.
The tax would then apply only to some 15,000 to 20,000 corporations and
high rates could be applied. Spokesmen for big corporations have maintained
that the proposed tax would penalize the small corporations; that big
corporations by and large are not only in excellent financial condition but
that in addition they have ready access to the capital markets. Why not
take them at their word?

Exemption of earnings up to $15,000 would deprive

the opposition of its most effective argument} would entail practically
no loss of revenue} and would greatly facilitate the administration of
the tax.
Another partial exemption that appears equitable is the application
of a special rate of 8 percent on earnings withheld because of statutory or charter prohibitions, and earnings devoted to the amortization
of debt outstanding on March 3, 1956. This rate is not too high to be a
burden on corporations to whom the exemption is a practical necessity, and




-4-

yet is sufficiently high to encourage the use of other means of debt
retirement if they are available.
An effective and just method of raising the rates applicable to
undistributed earnings after the exemptions just noted would be to make
the rates higher and then apply them to the percentage of earnings available
for common stockholders, and undistributed to them*

Another way would

be to make the rate applicable to, say, 50 percent undistributed earnings
apply to the whole 50 percent, rather than just to the difference between
40 and 50 percent of undistributed earnings. A precedent for this method
is offered by British practice in levying estate taxes.
It is only by making the rates in effect prohibitive that sufficient
revenue will be raised to permit desirable exemptions; that tax evasion
will be stopped; that smaller stockholders will cease to be penalized;
and that the other monetary, economic and social objectives of the tax
will be achieved• It is not necessary for large corporations to retain
earnings. The opposition has nowhere met the contention that large corporations can obtain all the funds necessary for legitimate expansion from new
stock issues. Even Mr* May, who made the most closely reasoned statement
against the tax, could only say with respect to this point that it seemed
academic and unrealistic, which is remarkably weak considering the cogency
of the rest of his argument. Corporations do not need a surplus in time
of depression. What they do need are comfortable ratios between their
net quick assets and current liabilities and between their net worth and
their indebtedness. They can obtain such ratios as well by stock issues as
by withholding earnings.