View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

BOARD DF GOVERNORS
DF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Jffice Correspondence
To

Chaiman Eccles

From

Kenneth EL Williams

D a t e , May
Subject:

Union and Nonunion Wages

Oddly enough, comprehensive data on relative wages of union
and nonunion workers have never been collected, and, in so far as I
have been able to find out in checking with the Assistant Commissioner
of Labor Statistics and others, no one has attempted an over-all estimate
of this type#
The reason is that many factors in addition to unionization
influence wage differentials, fbr example, substantial wage differentials
are associated with such things as degree of skill, age, sex, color*
and efficiency of the worker, and type and size of industry, regional
location, size of community and profitability of the employer• Differentials arising from these and other factors as well as those associated
with unionization cut across each other and make measurement of the
amount of differential attributable to any one influence extremely
difficult.
Obviously, what is needed to measure the effect of unionization
alone is to rule out the other major factors influencing wage differentials,
As a minimum, this would require data showing union and nonunion wages
separately in each industry, and desirably, showing the same data broken
down by region and size of community. Although numerous scattered onetime studies have been made distinguishing union and nonunion wages in
selected occupations in certain industry segments, these surveys are
too limited in scope and coverage to be of much help in constructing
over-all estimates for industry or for the economy as a whole*
The only wage data which are at all comprehensive (and they
are incomplete and deficient) are reported in terms of a single average
hourly earnings figure, which is not differentiated as between union
and nonunion, for each industry* There are, in addition, some rough
estimates of union membership as a percentage of the total employment
in selected industries. These two sets of data are about all there
is to work with in constructing an over-all estimate of the differential
between union and nonunion wages.




Chairman Eccles

-2-

A very rough idea of the difference between union and nonunion wages can be obtained by averaging wages by industries taking
into account in the averaging process the volume of union and nonunion
employment in each industry . To do this, we set up two columns of
figures, one headed union, the other nonunion. Since we have only
the one average hourly earnings figure for each industry, we entered
this figure in both the union and the nonunion columns for each
industry. We then averaged separately the earnings in the union
column and in the nonunion column, weighting the earnings figures in
the union column by estimated employment of union members and in the
nonunion column by estimated employment of nonunion members.
This procedure, although dictated by the statistics available, is not satisfactory# It results in some understatement of
the wage differential between union and nonunion workers since no
specific account is taken of such differences within an industry.
Offsetting this source of understatement, however, is the fact that
the full amount of the difference in average earnings among industries
is attributed to the union-nonunion differential. Some of the difference, assigned in this procedure to unionization, however, is not
properly attributable to unionization. It results merely from the
tendency of unionization to be concentrated in heavy industries
located in large cities in the North and West—areas in which wages
are customarily higher than in light industries and service activities
located in smaller cities and in the South. This type of difference
is found even when there is little or no unionization, as for example,
was the case generally before the middle 193Ofs.
The regularly reported series on average hourly earnings
included in January 19i# less than 2k million workers# We prepared
one set of estimates using this series alone. In addition, we
prepared a set of estimates in which we used this series as far as it
went and for the remainder of the wage and salary work force supplemented it by what estimates of hourly earnings we could derive from
more comprehensive employment and income data. Our second set of
estimates covered over 45 million wage and salary workers in January
I9J47* &&<* except for farm operators, self-employed persons in
nonagrioultural activities and unpaid family workers, it represented
total employment in the economy# Specifically included are hired




Chairman Eccles

farmworkers, domestic service workers, all government employees,
nonproduction (white collar) workers in manufacturing, and all salaried
employees as well as wage earners# These latter groups are rarely
organized and for some purposes they ought to be excluded. However,
for the purpose of estimating the distribution of total wage income
among workers of all kinds to see who has gained or lost as a result
of war and post-war inflation, these groups ought to be included•
On the basis of our all-inclusive estimates, we found that
average hourly earnings in January I9ltf were fl.10 for all employees$
with union workers receiving $1.21 and nonunion workers fl.07» Thus,
union workers received Ik cents or over 13 per cent more than nonunion
workers on the average. In 1939* average hourly earnings of all employees
were 62 cents, with union workers receiving 70 cents and nonunion
employees receiving 59 cents# The difference in favor of union workers
in 1939 w a s H cenfcs or nearly 19 per cent. The table on the next page
summarizes the results of the wage calculation for all employees
shown separately for union and nonunion for two categories of manufacturing and for nonmanufacturing workers. The higher rate shown
for nonunion than union manufacturing workers is due to the inclusion
of 95 per cent of the white collar workers in the nonunion group.
The over-all results are not significantly different when
the calculation is carried through leaving out government workers,
nonproduction workers in manufacturing, and hired farm workers although
the level of earnings of both union and nonunion workers is reduced
slightly in I939 «id January I9I47 and the differential in favor of
unions is increased a bit in the latter period. Similarly, the results
are practically the same when I9I4O rather than 1939 is used since
average earnings in I9I1O were only slightly higher—less than 2 cents
an hour—than in 1939.
The less inclusive series, which is broken down into fairly
small industry groups, indicated that year-round hotels at 65 cents in
January 19^7 had the lowest average hourly earnings of any industry group
in the series# They were followed by power l&undries at 75 cents, and
cleaning and dyeing establishments at 87 cents—all largely nonunion.
The highest wage reported was for anthracite mining at #1.59# followed by
construction at |1#55> bituminous mining at $l.i49 a&cl automobile manufacturing at |l # 39" a ll highly organized. However, in between the situation
was mixed. Wholesale trade and electric power and light which are mostly
nonunion paid #1.20 and #1.31 respectively, while apparel and tobacco manufacturing which are highly organized paid #l#0lj. and 9^ cents respectively.




-URelative Wages of Union and Nonunion Employees

All
.
Employees-/
January 1947
Estimated employment (millions)
Per cent i n unions
Average Hourly Earnings
All employees
Organized
Unorganized

Manufacturing
Production
TotalJ*
Workers 3 /

Kbnmanu-. /
facturin^ar

45.6
3k

15.4
5k

12.5
66

30.2
23

#1.10
1.21
1.07

$1.25
1.19
1.32

$1.16
1.18
1.11

$1.03
1.21*
.99

10.1

k2

8.2
50

25.0
17

$ .71
.67

$ .63
.66
.61

$ .58
.73
.55

Average for 1939
Estimated employment (millions) 35.1
Per cent i n unions
2k
Average Hourly Earnings
All employees
* .62
Organized
.70
Unorganized
.59

.Ik

Wage Increases 1939 to January 1947
All
/
Bmployee&if
In Cents Per Hour
All employees
Organized
Unorganized
In Percentages
All Employees
Organized
Unorganized

Manufacturing
TotalS^ Production
Workers 3 /

Nonaaanu-i/
facturing-ir

51
48

54

53

52
58

52
50

45
51
144-

77
73

76

84
79

78
70

81

78
78

82

80

\J Includes all persons employed, except farm operators, unpaid family workers,
and self-employed persons in nonagricultural activities#
^ Includes nonproduction (largely white collar) workers, whose average earnings
are high.
Excludes nonproduction workers#
Inoludes Government employees (whose average earnings are about the same as
manufacturing employees), hired farmworkers and domestic servants (whose
earnings are very low), as well as all wage and salaried workers in trade,
finance, service, transportation, public utilities, mining, and construction*




Chairman Eccles

-5~

It should be noted again that the estimates of relative
union and nonunion wages presented here and the more detailed estimates
upon which they are based are at best rough approximations derived from
industry averages and are hence subject to very serious qualifications
both as to the level of earnings shown and the size of the union-nonunion
differential Some general observations about the variety and character
of wage differentials may be worth noting at this point as an indication
of the problems involved. These observations are based upon examination
of many of the one-time scattered surveys of particular industries and
occupations, upon the extensive but older material I used in establishing
the WPA wage scales with their numerous skill, regional and city-size
differentials, and upon the industry type of data utilized in the above
estimates. In summary, it may be said thatt
1. Wages in the West are higher than in the North generally
and those in the North are substantially higher than in the South* Thus,
a study of the basic lumber industry in August I9kh showed average
straight-time hourly earnings of 72 cents for the United States, of
|1.18 for the West, of 73 cents for the North, and of 52 cents for the
South.
2. Wages tend to be higher, the larger the size of the
community. For example, stationary engineers in power laundries on
the Pacific Coast in July 19l*5 received #1.21 an hour in communities
of 100,000 and over, fl.05 in communities between 25,000 and 100,000
population, and 93 cents in communities under 25,000 population.
Further variation probably would have been shown if the study had
contained additional size breakdowns.
3» Skilled workers usually receive substantially more than
semi-skilled and unskilled workers but the size of the differential is
not constant among regions or over time, even for the same occupations
in the same industries. For example, in Atlanta, the differential
between the unskilled building laborer rate and the bricklayer rate is
fl.25; in Chicago, the differential is only 70 cents* Unskilled workers
in some industries and areas receive higher wages than skilled workers
in other industries and areas. A skilled carpenter in York, Pennsylvania
receives fl.30 a & hour while an unskilled building laborer in Chicago
receives fl.30 and in Newark #1*55»
]±. Women are paid substantially less than men. This is
typically so when women work on types of jobs largely held by women
but it is also likely to be true when women do the same work as men.




Chairman Eccles

-6-

5* Union workers typically receive higher wages than nonunion
workers, but sometimes nonunion plants pay higher wages in order to
forestall organisation or for other reasons* Several studies indicate
higher nonunion than union rates in New England for the same job and
industry even though in the other regions of the country union rates
are above nonunion rates#
6* Wages tend to be higher in firms in which profits are high
than in less profitable firms*
7* Wages tend to be higher in large firms than in small ones*
8* Wages tend to be higher for workers paid on a piece or
incentive basis than for workers paid on a time basis.
9* Wages tend to be higher in industries in which labor cost
is a small proportion of total cost than in industries in which labor
cost is a high proportion of total cost# Saying it another way, there
is a tendency for wages to be higher in highly mechanized industries
than in less mechanized ones* Typically, this means wages tend to be
higher in durable and heavy goods lines than in light or nondurable
goods production*
10* Wages tend to be higher in industries characterized by
monopolistic conditions or price administration than in industries in
which product prices reflect more closely short-run supply and demand
influences.
11* There is some tendency for wages to be higher in industries
characterized by wide cyclical or seasonal fluctuations than in industries
in which employment is more stable*
12* The general structure of wage differentials among industries,
in which textile workers are typically toward the bottom of the wage scale
and printing workers are near the top with other industries in between
ranged in some rough relation to durability of product, seems to be about
the same here as in other countries for which studies have been made,
namely, Canada, Great Britain, and Sweden*
These generalizations are not entirely consistent with each
other and substantial exceptions can be cited to prove the contrary of
nearly every statement* An additional point may be mentioned, namely,
that the average reported industry wage may not be the typical wage in
any sense* Thus a study of plant workers in sheet-metal establishments




Chairman Scoles

-7-

in January 19^5# showed average straight-time hourly earnings of $1.06.
Yet only 2.1 per cent of the workers received earnings in the group
between |1.05 and #109.9» Wage classes containing significant proportions
of total employment ranged from under 50 cents to over $1.80 with the
percentages spread fairly evenly at 5 cent intervals in between.
In general, union leaders long have claimed that the differential
between union and nonunion wages is great and is attributable to unionization*
Economists have tended to minimize the ability of unions to increase wages
much above that which would result from the operation of normal economic
influences, except of course, in those instances in which unions have
established a tight monopoly over some particular skill or skills in an
individual labor market. In my opinion, unions unquestionably have tended
to raise the wages of their members somewhat above those paid to nonunion
workers in the same area and industry and at times of inflation to push
their wages and wages generally up farther than they would otherwise go.
There is also little doubt but that unions have held their wages higher
in periods of depression than they otherwise would be. What effect this
may have had on nonunion wages or upon economic conditions generally is
not entirely clear.