View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

LYNDON BAINES JOHNSON LIBRARY ORAL HISTORY COLLECTION

LBJ Library
2313 Red River Street
Austin, Texas 78705
http://www.lbjlib.utexas.edu/johnson/archives.hom/biopage.asp

ARTHUR OKUN ORAL HISTORY, INTERVIEW I
PREFERRED CITATION
For Internet Copy:
Transcript, Arthur Okun Oral History Interview I, 3/20/69 by David G. McComb,
Internet Copy, LBJ Library.
For Electronic Copy on Compact Disc from the LBJ Library:
Transcript, Arthur Okun Oral History Interview I, 3/20/69 by David G. McComb,
Electronic Copy, LBJ Library.

GENERAL SERVICES ADMINISTRATION
NATIONAL ARCHIVES AND RECORDS SERVICE
LYNDON BAINES JOHNSON LIBRARY

Legal Agreement Pertaining to the Oral History Interviews of Arthur M . Okun

In accordance with the provisions of Chapter 21 of Title 44, United States .
Code and subject to the terms and conditions hereinafter set forth, I,
Arthur M. Okun of Washington, D .C . do hereby give, donate, and convey
to the United States of America all my rights, title, and interest in the
tape recordings and transcripts of personal interviews conducted on March 20
and April 15, 1969 in Washington, D.C . and prepared for deposit in the
Lyndon Baines Johnson Library .
This assignment is subject to the following terms and conditions
(1) The transcripts shall be available for use by researchers as soon
as they have been deposited in the Lyndon Baines Johnson Library .
(2) The tape recordings shall be available to those researchers who
have access to the transcripts .
(3)
I hereby assign to the United States Government all copyright
I may have in the interview transcripts and tapes .
(4)
Copies of the transcripts and the tape recordings may be provided
by the Library to researchers upon request .
(5) Copies of the transcripts_ and tape recordings may be deposited in
or loaned to institutions other than the Lyndon Baines Johnson Library .

Donor
Date

zL 7C61~ .-~
&
.~

2-~ / ? 7o'

ivistof-the Uni
Date

. t-z

7=~

INTERVIEW I
DATE :

March 20, 1969

INTERVIEWEE :

ARTHUR M . OKUN

INTERVIEWER :

DAVID McCOMB

Tape 1_ of' 1
M:

This is an interview with Dr . Afthur M. Okun, who is the former Chatsman
of the Council of Economic Advisers .
Institution in Washington, D .C .

I am in his office now in Brookings

The date is March 20, 1969 ; the time is

2 :50 in the afternoon ; and my name is David McComb .
First of all, I'd like to know something about your background, where
were you born, when, where did you get your education .
0:

I was born in Jersey City, New Jersey, on November 28, 1928 .

I was brought

up most of my life in Passaic, New Jersey ; went to public schools there and
met my wife there .

Then I did my undergraduate and graduate work both at

Columbia in New York City .

In 1952 I went to Yale as an instructor, and

that was my job until coming to Washington--as an instructor, assistant
professor .
M:

You first went to Yale in 1952?

0:

Right .

It was really my first job out of graduate school .

My first venture

into government service was in 1961 when James Tobin of Yale became a
member of the Council of Economic Advisers .
Heller, who -was then Chairman.

He introduced me to Walter

Jim and I had been close friends and

colleagues at Yale, and we made an arrangement whereby I was a consultant
for the Council between January and June o£ 1961 .
check on Inauguration Day .

I earned my first pay

I spent typically Thursday and Friday down in

Washington. during that period, and then meanwhile was teaching school back
at Yale .

As a matter of fact, I picked up one of Tobin's courses that he

.

2
had to drop, so it was a pretty active period for me .
Then at that point, I became a member of the Council staff, and I
was on leave from Yale in the

'61-'62 academic year .

I spent fourteen

months working for Walter and Jim Tobin and Kermit Gordon with the other
members of the Council at that time ; and I was on the staff doing work
primarily in forecasting and fiscal policy, which were my academic specialties .
In September of '62 I returned to Yale and continued to have a
consulting involvement, but a much smaller involvement, in the Council for
'f

the next two years .

I thought I had returned to the academic life .

traded up houses in New Haven in 1963 and then in June '64, to my surprise,
Walter called me and asked whether I would consider becoming a member of
the Council when he left .
president would let him go .

He was then planning to leave as soon as the
I think he said it was already definite that

Gardner Ackley was to be his successor, and hence there would be a vacancy
on the Council, which he was asking about my interest in filling .

That

brought me down-M:

Did you have an interview with White House staff people or with the
President?

0:

At the time of my appointment, no .

In fact, I met the President for the

first time--I know I saw him when he was Vice President in '61- :62, but I
met him really personally for the first time in August of '64 .

Actually,

Walter sort-of transmitted the invitation for the appointment .

I met the

President--at that time I was on the task force to study stabilization
programs--fiscal monetary policy .
M:

Was this a 1964 task force?

0:

That's right .

M:

That was the one when he was putting together his program .

0:

Right .

And I actually, really because of the academic year and my kids in

3
school and all of that, came down to Washington in September of '64, and
I was on the staff of the Council for the next two or three months .

But

this, was all in contemplation of the elevation to membership on the
Council .

Then on November 16,

'64, Gardner became Chairman, and I became

a member of the Council .
M:

That's a picture of you and the President and your wife and three boys .

0:

On November 16,

M:

This 1964 task force that you were on, who else was on that task force?

0:

It was chaired by Joe Pechman, as I recall .

'64, when I had just been sworn in as a member of CEA .

one that was chaired by Paul Samuelson .

No . I'm sorry .

That was the

And Locke Anderson,who was on

the CEA staff at the time, worked as executive secretary .
M:

Were the ideas from your task force fairly well received?

0:

Yes .

I think at the time there was still a concern of the task force

about the need for additional stimulus--you know, continuing to invigorate
the economy .

Within a year that situation changed pretty drastically, and

ever since we've been worrying more about how to feed the economy sedatives
than stimulants .

So, to that extent, events made economic thinking of

1964 rather obsolete .
force continued on .
on fiscal policy .

But I think some of the basic ideas of the task
The task force emphasized the need for prompt action

We've had lots of examples of that in recent years, have

urged strongly the proposal for giving the President some discretionary
authority on tax rates, and that's an issue wherein the battle is still to
be fought .
M:

It appeals to everybody except Congress .

Let me ask you a little bit about the mechanics of the Council of Economic
Advisers, how it operates .

When Gardner Ackley was the Chairman would you

divide up the workload among yourselves or what?
0:

The way it operated, both when Gardner :-was Chairman and when I was Chairman--

and pretty much the same way when Walter was Chairman--the world got
divided essentially in half .

And each of the two members other than the

Chairman took half of the subjects and topic areas and assumed a
responsibility for them .

The rationale was that the Chairman had to worry

about everything, and in, some ways didn't take direct responsibility for
anything in a substantive area .

Obviously, tbat'left the Chairman free to

freelance on whatever happened to be the biggest flap of the moment and
also left him for what was'.ihis major distinguishing job, which is that of
being the real liaison of the Council with the White House and indeed with
the President himself .

Obviously, the Chairman did work and does work

with the members of the staff, . but the staff people will :see the two members
of the Council a good deal more .than they will see the Chairman .
M:

Did you specialize with one member--?

0:

Yes .

M:

--getting into one area and the other in another?

0:

Yes .

I could go into this in some detail .

Council, Otto Eckstein was the other member .

When I became a member of the
I was responsible for

forecasting and sort of overall fiscal policy and the whole money financial
area and the international area .

Otto took responsibility for wages and

prices and most of what we call microeconomics, all the particular program
areas ranging from Social Security to stockpiles and coordination with the
Budget Bureau on program decisions .

He also had a responsibility for

sort-of the tax structure, tax reform area as opposed to the overall fiscal
policy .

Then when Jim Duesenberry .came in in February of '66, we did a

little shifting .

Jim's specialty was in the money area, and I gave up the

monetary--financial side of things, handed that to him, and took on the tax
structure in some of the microeconomic areas, although he continued to do

5
wages and prices, and most of the micro-areas that had been Otto's .
M:

Where would the initiative for a study arise?

Would a problem come over,

say, from the President or from the White House staff, or would you foresee
problems and work on them, or just where did the initiative of your work
come from?
0:

Oh, it would come from any direction--internally generated or generated
from the White House .
into blocs .
groups .

It's hard to define .

Let's see if we can break it

One bloc of work was associated with some continuing interagency

Probably the most important of these, at least in my experience

personally, was the Troika--the three agency group, Treasury, Council,
Budget Bureau, that were responsible for keeping the President informed
and advised on overall economic conditions and the budgetary outlook, both
expenditures and receipts .

The Troika not only was a three agency body,

but a three level body as well .

The staff level, called the middle Troika,

which was a member of the Council and Assistant Director of the Budget and
Assistant Secretary of the Treasury ; and then the heads of the agencies
would form the top Troika .

I guess I have hold of the notable distinction

of being the only man who ever served on three levels of the Troika .

In

'61-'62 I was on the staff level, and '64 into '68 I was middle level, and
then became a top Troika man in '68-'69 .
The Troika was really a Kennedy Administration innovation .

I think

it was a very important innovation because it put things on a regular review
basis, which had never been done before .

There was a coordinated effort to

deal with some of these same issues and same problems under the Eisenhower
Administration, but it was sort of an ad hoc affair that when the budget
had to be formulated, they met ; when there was a flap, when somebody would
raise questions about "should we be cutting taxes" or so, they'd hold a

6
meeting, and they'd do a memo, and such .

Here we had a procedure that

assured that the President got at least a quarterly review regularly of
what was new in the economy, whether there was any need to change the
estimates of economic activity, employment, prices, gross national product,
what had been carried in the budget or in the last Troika memo, whether
budget expenditures were outrunning the estimates, whether receipts were
coming in stronger or weaker than had been anticipated .

This forced all

of us right from the staff level on up through the principal, indeed right
up to the President, to focus at least that often on the fiscal policy
question .

And it also became a forum whereby you'd get a lot of contact

and a lot of intervening discussion among the various Troika people on how
they saw the fiscal policy side of things .

I think this turned it from a

fire alarm system into a continuing watch, and I think it was really an
institutional reform that fitted what I think was the key element in the
whole of the New Economics which was a shift of fiscal policy from meeting
problems to trying to plan and program and sustain prosperity for the
country .

We didn't just wait for a sign of recession and boom, and then

say, "What shall we do about it?"

We tried to think all of the time, and

on a regular basis, "How is the budget meeting the needs of the economy
and to what extent are alterations in order?"

I'm not saying we always

answered these questions correctly, but we were asking the right questions,
and I think that made a lot of difference .
M:

Who originated this Troika idea?

0:

I'm not sure I know exactly how it evolved .

I think one unsung hero in

the process is a staff man of the Budget Bureau, Sam Cohn, who had
suffered through the Eisenhower years--in his own words--and really was
looking forward to an opportunity to do something with the fiscal policy

7
front--and a very able guy, one of the top civil servants in the economic
side of government .

Dave Lusher of the CEA staff, another veteran, I think

also presented the diagnosis that led to much of this . This was initially
really worked out and negotiated between Walter Heller and Dave Bell and
Doug Dillon .

The thing=evolved to a degree where I would say there were

really no basic organizational or institutional changes in it from the time
of its initial conception in the spring of '61 .
M: :

It never did become a statutory group then .

0:

Oh, no .

M:

It was more informal than that .

0 :

Yes, much more informal than that--no Executive Order, no separate line in
the budget .

Basically the people who were covering these areas in the

agencies in any case were coordinating and developing this, but it became
a recognized institution within the operations of the Executive Branch .
The President knew what he was getting when he was getting a Troika memo,
and he knew roughly when it was coming .

Obviously the Troika label came

from the fact that it was a.three-agency body .
M:

Would you send him memos at your discretion, or was this regularized in
any way?

0:

Basically there was a schedule which the people departed from, but it did
serve as a point of departure, as a benchmark .

Each quarter you get

around the middle of the third month of the quarter, the first guess that
the Department of Commerce can make on the quarterly GNP .

In other words,

they would have made that last week for the first quarter of
this year .

They've got two months of figures in pretty well ; they can begin

to see what's shaping up for the quarter ; and this is something which is
for internal use only .

Usually it was at that time that the staff would

8
get together, and they'd look at these figures and they'd say, "Okay, here's
where we thought this would come out a month ago," and they'd have essentially
a comparison of a very preliminary and tentative, you might say, guess at
the actual results of the quarter compared with their prediction of a
quarter earlier .

Along with that, the Budget Bureau would bring in what

information it had about changing course of federal expenditures based on
uncontrollable programs moving faster or slower than they had expected,
based on changes in congressional action from what had been implied or
recommended in the President's budget or what had been guessed internally
previously .
going .

The Treasury would bring in its judgments on how revenues were

So you really did have, at least initially, a kind of division of

labor, Midget having primary responsibility for the expenditure projections
and estimates, the Treasury for revenue projects and estimates, and the
Council for economic activity assessment .
But obviously any staff works together, and people looked over one
another's shoulders, and at times when people would raise questions about
whether the Council's estimates of economic activity were the ones that
ought to be used .

Indeed, over time Treasury pretty well developed its

own staff capability in there, and it came to be a negotiation, much the
same way the Council would second-guess the Treasury's revenue estimates .
Everybody would, particularly once Defense spending started jumping around,
start second-guessing the Budget Bureau's expenditure estimates .

But then

you'd get a week or so of this effort at the staff level which usually
resulted in a single consensus reestimate after some negotiation .
things develop informally .

These

People recognize that they don't report to

their superiors if they're a half-billion dollars off in estimating gross
national product .

They find some way of compromising the difference .

9
If there were major differences of opinion on the part of staffs
representing the different agencies, or itdividual staff members--I don't
think they went into these necessarily feeling that they were representatives
in an agency position .

They were there as experts, and there was a good

deal of academic freedom in feeling that these people were there to call
the shots as they saw them, and to report on how they saw them.

That would

mean that the middle level might feel that if they didn't agree with the
staff, they didn't accept their estimates ; they'd want to modify then in
some way, or go at the principals' level .

Usually at the middle level

when they reviewed the technical estimates, you'd get somebody drafting. a
memo designed for the principal or for the President, trying to summarize
these in a way of bringing out the highlights and indicating where the
major surprises or implications for policy were .
To the extent that during the year, March or June or September, you'd
have any very substantial shift from the preceding quarter, there might be
attempts to show what would happen if you altered the policy .

If you went

in for a tax bill, if you cut expenditures or raised expenditures--sometimes
when we knew we were in major doubt about the outcome of a piece of
legislation which would have big implications for the budget and the economy,
we'd have alternative models saying, "Okay, if Congress does it this way,
here's what we expect ; if Congress does it that way, here's what we expect ."
The President would get this memo ultimately, and often it was
associated with a meeting with the President which got attended, typically,
by just the principals, occasionally the middle-level Troika invited along .
Sometimes if no one thought there was a need to take the President's scarce
time with meetings, you'd just give him the memo .

This was -an application

of the general rule that you could count on the President doing his homework .

10
He responded very well to written briefing information .
M:

Within the Troika, did you have any difficulty explaining or in effect
selling economic ideas to the Treasury people?

0:

Not really .

I think there were differences of a significant sort in 1961

and into 1962 .

There's no question that from the outset Dillc~rt and Heller

were giving President Kennedy quite different advice .
M:

Can you explain the difference?

0:

Yes, sure .

I think after that-

The economist's diagnosis of the ills of the economy right at

the start in 1961 was that it had been over-sedated with an excessively
restrictive budget, which had so 'sapped its strength that you weren't
getting the revenues from that budget ; and therefore the budget looked as
though it wasn't restrictive .

Still you had a deficit, but the deficit was

associated with trying to get too big a surplus and therefore holding down
incomes and profits to the point where the revenues weren't coming in .

We

developed a concept called the "full employment surplus" of trying to show
where the budget would be if the economy was on a high employment growth
path and trying to show that basically you had a much too tight budget, and
that from the economist's point of view the right medicine was one of a
more stimulative budget which would bring the economy to full employment,
reduce unemployment, strengthen investment, give us a lot more output for
which there were and remain very urgent uses .

Obviously, this would mean

in the short run that you'd have to do things which would make the budgetary
deficit a lot bigger .
Now, we argued, and I think the facts proved ultimately that there was
a good deal of merit in this, that if you did the right thing in terms of
either more government spending or a tax reduction of major proportions,
that you'd invigorate the economy enough so that incomes would'be much

11
higher and therefore you'd get higher revenues as a result of those higher
incomes, enough to offset this, that at least the large deficit that would
be incurred would be a transitory phenomenon .

There were some rhetorical

statements made about how you could balance the budget by stimulus and so
forth.

I'm not sure one could ever demonstrate that indeed you collected

more than you gave away, but at least you got a very major offset to this .
I think the chief constraint to rational overall economic policy in 1961
was the vehemence of the commitment to balance budgets ; the notion of
budgetary deficits as sin had prevailed and been strengthened during the
1950's .
M:

Did this feeling prevail in the Treasury department at the time?

0:

No, I don't think it was anywhere nearly--it wasn't shared initially by the
Treasury.

But Treasury. took. the view that'while there were-goQd arguments for priming

the pump with an anti-recession recovery program that was designed to meet
the particular weakness of early 1961, that the case hadn't been made for
a more sustained program of economic stimulus .

And I think the Treasury

was very sensitive to the feelings that there might be adverse reactions
by foreign central banks and the international financial community to a
program of economic stimulus, that this might hurt our balance of payments
unduly in their view .
M:

This was Dillon's position?

0:

Yes .

I don't mean to caricature these things, and I am caricaturing them .

This was a difference of degree, but it was a pretty big difference of
degree, and it came up in several very specific ways .

I remember President

Kennedy had been unwilling to really take issue strongly with the balanced
budget idealogy in early '61 .

Indeed he had run on a platform in which he

had sharply criticized Eisenhower for the big deficit of fiscal '59 .

Many

12
of the early efforts to get some stimulus into the economy were coupled
with rhetoric that really was pretty low-grade by a professional standard .
Oh, there was a wonderful passage we used to call the "Seven Escape Hatch
Clause" in an early Kennedy economic message which said, "The program I am
now proposing will balance the budget provided that, a, b, c, d--" all of
these things were purely untenable provisions .

But there was a feeling of

a political need to pay lip service to this orthodox creed .
This came up again in July '61, which perhaps was Walter Heller's first
very major substantive victory on the fiscal policy front . . There was this
Berlin crisis add-on to the Defense. budget at that time, and a great deal
of advice was being given to the President to couple that with a proposal
to raise taxes at a time when the economy was practically flat on its back,
with a 6-percent unemployment rate .

There wasn't the slightest economic

danger of adding that small amount to Defense spending at the time .
rather amusing .

It was

Much of the support and enthusiasm for this tax proposal

came from people who were making national security policy and thought that
it would be great to show that we care so much about Berlin that we're
ready to raise taxes for it .

And I think some of the political types in

the White House saw this as the first opportunity to implement the "sacrifice"
theme that had been so important in Kennedy's campaign .

You know, he told

people they had to ask what they could do for the country .

He hadn't told

them what they could do for the country, but they could pay higher taxes .
It took quite a battle on the part of the Council to stand up and say, "The
people who would be making the sacrifice here are the people who would be
unemployed," and those weren't quite the people whom we wanted to apply the
sacrifice to .

This kind of masochistic display wasn't going to convince

the Russians or anybody else .

It was just going to weaken the economy .

13
As I recall--this is a story I know only second and third-hand--but
until a few hours before Kennedy went on television to make his proposal,
there were two drafts of the speech, one of which had the tax increase in
it and one of which did not .
M:

So he was not really convinced right up to that point?

0:

I'm not sure that he'd ever, up to that point, been confronted hard with
the issue .

As I understand it, the afternoon of that speech he focused on

the economic aspect of this Berlin decision, and Sorenson, who was drafting
the thing had drafted it both ways .

Then he went along with the CEA advice .

I don't think Treasury took a particularly strong stand in favor of
the tax increase .

What Dillon did do, which had very important implications

for a subsequent economic policy, was to urge the President strongly to
couple this increase in the fiscal '62 deficit with a promise to balance
the budget for fiscal '63 that would be proposed in January of '63 .
wording was put into that late July '61 message :,

This

And it became an albatross

subsequently because we clearly wanted a deficit for fiscal '63 on economic
grounds .
An amusing incident that I recall hearing about--President Kennedy
made some statements that seemed to be wiggling off the hook of this
balanced budget commitment at a press conference in August or September
'61 .

Dillon called him the next day and told him that we'd upset foreign

bankers and urged him to clarify what he meant and reaffirm his determination .
Walter, who had been delighted by the President's ability to see this more
pragmatically, was told that Kennedy felt he had to do this, that he did
indeed reaffirm that and that there was a balanced proposal in the fiscal
'63 budget, which never materialized at all .
I think the key manifestation of Kennedy's conversion to the Heller

14
creed was the commencement address that Kennedy gave at Yale in June 1962,
which was something--he really wanted to do this .

And it was clear--again

operating on other people's Stories--he wanted a myth-exploding speech,
and he ordered that it be focused on economic policy .

He really went after

the balanced budget myth as the key myth that needed to be destroyed .
During that period there was a good deal of discussion over whether
there could be a quick tax cut legislated in the summer of 1962 at a time
that the economy was slowing down .

There was a real effort by the Council

to convince the President that that would be an appropriate recommendation,
and he concluded that it was politically unfeasible .
"quickie tax cut," and, boy, that killed it!

It got labeled a

Congress never wants a "quickie"

anything .
But when Kennedy announced his decision on that, he did say publicly
that he was going to go for a major tax reduction bill in January 1963,
and indeed he did .

As you know, that didn't get enacted during 1963 ; and

it was really the first item on President Johnson's agenda, and perhaps
his first major legislative victory .

It got passed on February 19, 1964 .

When, after a few months of skepticism and mixed returns, it became clear
that the economy had been very substantially invigorated by this--I suppose
the time I came to Washington in the fall of '64 the economists were riding
about as high a crest of esteem and respect for the success of the tax cut
as has ever been achieved .
M:

It would seem that Walter Heller had a major task, in effect, educating John
F . Kennedy about this .
What does he do?

Q:

Yes .

How did Heller go about educating a President?

Does he send him memos, talk to him on occasion?

I don't really know just how much of what kind of communication there

was between Heller and President Kennedy .

I know there was a flood of

15
paper that went from the Council to the White House .

Even after Kennedy

was personally sold there was a further educational problem of convincing
the public and convincing the Congress .

I know at one point Heller

essentially got the President's permission to run in advance of policy
making and go out and make the case publicly before the President actually
signed on to a stimulative fiscal policy .
education .

Heller did a great job of public

He got a lot of press attention to the whole fiscal policy

arena and to the possibilities of prosperity ; to try to popularize a notion
that an underemployed economy was a great national waste .

One of my first

tasks on the Council was to try and estimate what our potential was .

That

estimate of potential output I guess remains my best known professional
contribution as an economist .

It's widely referred to as "Oken's Law ."

M:

This was when you first became a Kennedy consultant?

0:

Yes .

M:

In the early '60's?

0:

In early '61, I worked on "Okun's Law ."

M:

Is "Okun's Law" still valid?

0:

I'm always amazed .

It has no right to hold as well as it does .

It wiggles

off now and then, but it's a law that's violated only in the second decimal
place .

It's a very shorthand approximation to a bunch of complicated

relationships, and says essentially that you lose roughly three percent of
the potential output for each one percentage point extra unemployment
that you sustain .
M:

And that three-to-one relationship holds pretty well .

Did you also struggle in this early '60's period with the phenomena of
"Phillips' Curve" and the inflation versus the unemployment?

0:

Obviously, the inflation problem was always there, but it was more of a
nightmare than a reality .

It was an additional reason that conservatives

16
had for opposing expansionary economic policy .

It didn't have great popular

impact at the time because there wasn't any very evident inflationary
experience or imminent threat at a time like that .
There were a couple of things .

I think the Council really conceived

of the inflationary threat that would be posed as the economy began to
recover in a way that perhaps fitted the mold of the mid-50's, where we'd
run into most of our problems in the area of concentrated industry and big
labor .

Steel had been the bellwether of the 1955, '56, '57 inflation .

I

think much of that thinking of the fear of a repetition of the mid-'50's
experience influenced the whole formulation of the guideposts by the
Council in late '61--appeared for the first time in the January '62 report .
That wasn't an area that I was directly involved in to a great extent at
that time, although there would be staff meetings and broader groups and
so forth where I would get into it to a degree .

And, as you know, there

was the big confrontation between the steel industry and President Kennedy
in April 1962, which really was the first threat of that kind of an
inflationary pressure coming out of a concentrated sector of the economy .
The whole guideposts area was thus one major concern, one activity of the
Council in trying to head off that type of inflationary threat_-and also
in evincing a clear public image of our concern with the price level
problem, basically saying that the way to deal with the problem in a world
of 6 or 7 percent unemployment was not to keep the economy flat on its
back, but rather to deal with what seemed to be the key area of threat to
price stability .
The other thing which was a very powerful force in the early '60's
was this so-called structural unemployment thesis that really was linked
to the inflation argument .

The argument was that somehow the demands and

17
requirements of the labor force had changed in such a dramatic way that
whereas it might have been possible in the mid-'50's or in the '40's to
have 4 percent unemployment without extreme bottlenecks and pressures,
that you couldn't do it again because you just had a lot of labor that
wasn't employable, wasn't ready to meet the nedds of modern industry and
so forth ; and therefore the economy really was more fully employed than it
looked by judging from the unemployment numbers ; and therefore you'd run
into inflation rather than increases in production and employment a lot
faster if you just tried to stimulate the economy through traditional
fiscal and monetary policy tools .
This had a very small but very vocal professional backing .

I guess

Killingsworth of Michigan State was the chief and most ardent exponent of
structural unemployment and gave it its academic respectability .

But there

were a lot of people in Washington who believed or were predisposed to
believe that this was the case, including even people in the Labor department
who saw this as a grand argument for moving more rapidly on the manpower
front, and less emphasis on overall fiscal techniques of dealing with the
employment problem .
It created some very strange bedfellows--extreme, if you will,
humanistic liberals who saw .things as a particular structural--this is a
general problem economists have of getting people to see the aggregates .
You know, everybody who looks at an unemployment problem sees particular
people who are unemployed, and there are always special reasons why they're
unemployed .

Everybody who looks at prices in an inflationary period can

find specific reasons why each and every price that's going up is going
up ; and yet there's something about the environment that makes a difference
on why you have a 7 percent.unemployment at one point and 3 1/2 at another,

18
and something about the environment that explains why consumer price index

in

rises at 1 percent one year and 4 percent
circumstances .

Those are always there .

another .

It's not the special

It's the overall condition of the

economy .
Let me mention another way in which the tradeoff or Phillips curve
problem was faced .

The Council did want to set an unemployment target,

and it did advance 4 percent early in the game as an interim target for
unemployment .
liberals .

That was too low for the conservatives and too high for the

We were getting pressures on both sides and excoriated by Leon

Keyserling and the labor movement and so forth for having such an
unambitious goal .
M:

What was your basis for choosin& 4 percent?

0:

It was a very subjective kind of judgment about where we'd be.likely to
run into unemployment--the problem of inflation in a serious way .
matter of fact, I saw Jim Tobin last week .
one experience .

As a

We were trying to recollect

There was a consultants' meeting Walter had in which Paul

Samuelson, Joe Pechman, one or two others who were present, and everybody
drew his own Phillips curve .
M:

You were there, too?

0:

Yes--and several of the staff people .

This must have been September of

'61--or thereabouts--in a world with 6 1/2 percent unemployment and trying
to guess where and whether the Phillips curve bent .

I remember at the time

Jim Tobin said, I think, "Dammit, tae ought to keep these things on file
and look back on them some day ."

I doubt that they were ever put in a file .

We were both trying to remember who drew the Phillips curve how .

I think

the general feeling was we would have to make some compromise from the
complete stability on wholesale prices and the 1 percent trend on consumer

19
prices that we were getting at the time in order to get the 4 percent
unemployment .

But you could probably do that with a 2 percent rate of

price increase, and we thought that probably would be tolerable .

I

remember the general judgment that that's about where the public's tolerance
of inflation would give out .

Nobody at that time would have thought that

3 or 4 percent inflation would be an acceptable situation in the American
economy .

That's really a judgment about what kind of public reaction you

get to the tradeoff between consumer prices and unemployment rather than
the question of what the real terms are on which the tradeoff operates .
M:

That of course would be very difficult to judge, what the public reaction
would be .

0:

Yes .

You're setting an unemployment target, and you have to ask yourself,

"Okay, what kind of price behavior would be likely to accompany that, and
will that be an acceptable one ."
M:

Has this question of unemployment and inflation, the whole concept of the
Phillips curve--has this been a central question for economists in the
decade of the '60's?

Has it been something that the Council has discussed

and talked about more or less continually?
0:

Well, certainly more from '64 to '68 and '69 than in the early '60's .
There's no doubt in anyone's mind that we were pretty far from the ideal
tradeoff, compromise point, in the early '60's .

I think there is this

real distinction between perhaps the '61-'64 period and that since then.
In the first period I think it was really quite easy to diagnose what
the economy needed .

Our convictions were very strong that what was wrong

primarily with the American economy was the lack of vigor of aggregate
demand, and the measures to invigorate aggregate demand were the basic
answer to the overall problem of prosperity .

That's what we were really

20
focusing on, not structural distribution or other problems .

But this was

the first item on the priority list that the doctor could order for a
patient .

The problem was that of getting the patient to take the medicine

rather than knowing what to prescribe .

It was that that put all the

emphasis on educating the President, the Congress, the public, making the
case publicly--you know, really improving the packaging, the labeling, the
palatability of the medicine rather than improving the prescription at
that time .

Obviously, we did a lot of economic analysis on how big a tax

cut we'd like ideally, what the appropriate unemployment target might be,
what could be done to supplement general fiscal policy through manpower
programs, how well guideposts could help to fend off the evil day that
inflation reared its ugly head, and all that .

But I think still you'd

find that the largest emphasis of the Council's activity was on the
salesmanship of a product rather than on the development of

a superior

product, because that was what the real need was .
And I think it's fortunate historically that Walter's personality
and talents fitted in immensely well for that .

He's a great publicist ; he's

a great salesman .

No one can put across ideas in more simple and lucid

form than he can .

He's a guy who loved the limelight and enjoyed the

opportunity to really drive this home publicly .

I do think the hard

economic problems came up when the patient was willing to take our medicine,
and we got closer to a point where you had to make some tough judgments
on how much stimulus did you want, and what could you do about the tradeoff .
M:

This was the problem essentially of the latter '60's, '64 to, say, the
present .
It came really late in '65 ; it really became critical and acute .

0:

Yes .

M:

Does that tax cut in '64 that finally came through under President Johnson

21
represent a milestone then for these new concepts for the New Economics?
Is this in a sense a triumph of the ideas?
0:

Yes, this was certainly the big breakthrough of unprecedented fiscal action .
No one had ever before enlarged the deficit by cutting taxes deliberately
at a time when the economy wasn't in recession, wasn't threatened by
recession, when federal expenditures were going up .
in the book in terms of orthodox fiscal policy .
bringing the economy up to full employment .

It broke every rule

It was an investment in

It worked .

And within some

period of time it was clear that it was working .
M:

I would assume that Walter Heller also had to educate Lyndon Johnson when
Johnson became President, and that Heller had to, in effect, go through
this again with him .

0:

Yes, although I don't think he had as much trouble breaking down the
balanced budget myth all over again .

I think that notion of fiscal

orthodoxy had been pretty well dispelled .

I'm not sure it ever

played as

much of a part in President Johnson's ideology as it perhaps had in President
Kennedy's .

I remember right after President Johnson became President, Walter's

having to try to explain the logic of the tax cut, why it was so important,
why it deserved top priority on his legislative agenda, and I gather that
President Johnson was a very willing student . He accepted the diagnosis .
He did push it hard .
M:

He got it through .

His record kind of amazed everyone .

In retrospect, did that 1964 tax reform perform as you predicted?

Did it

perform adequately?
0:

Yes .

Great success .

I Wrote it up in September '65, trying to make some

post-mortem estimates, and it all came out looking very healthy .
basically what I'm saying is it wasn't all that hard .

But

There was a lot of

room for error in there, and it wasn't the kind of task in terms of taxing

22
one's professional talents and ability that suddenly the later episodes
evolved, because it was pretty easy to say, "This patient needs a lot of
vitamins and it isn't terribly important whether you administer a couple
of teaspoons or a tablespoon .-.and-a-half ."

I think the economy could have

gone up a little faster in '64 without triggering off inflationary pressures .
You did have this elbow room and what came from the fact that we were so
far from a desirable point that it was easy to know what direction we ought
to be headed in .
M:

Let me go back to your interagency relationships in your work .
have also worked some with the Quadriad .

You must

And apparently, from the

information I gather, the major--if it can be called that--the main
confrontation between the Council and the Federal Reserve: System came in
late '65 .
0:

That's right .

M:

And for the most part the rest of the time the relationship was rather
harmonious, is that correct?

0:

That's correct .

There was much less relationship with the Federal Reserve

prior to that event that there was after that event or than there was with
other agencies .
Troika .

The quadriad was organized very differently from the

With one exception I'll go into in a minute, there wasn't- an

attempt to develop a coordinated position or staff effort that flowed up
the line .

There were meetings- there were efforts for consultation and so

forth, involving Bill Martin, and almost invariably in the early years, as
I understand it, involving Bill Martin alone .

I don't think the Council

ever met as a group with the Federal Reserve Board as a group during that
early period .

There was a fair amount of contact with people on the staff

of the Federal Reserve, although even that wasn't a tremendous effort .

It

23
was sort of with individuals as individual economists and not in any
coordinated way .
Now in '65 Dan Brill got promoted at the Federal Reserve Board to a
more senior staff position .

I don't think it was quite the position he

has today, but that was an important development in coordination .

He

worked very closely and was very friendly with members of the Council,
and I think that improved the coordination .
During the summer of 1965 Martin was getting concerned about excessive
monetary ease, really, I think more in termsoof financial markettconditions
than some threats of unsound financial structures in the financial
institutions--too,much borrowing by consumers and so forth, rather than in
terms of an overall judgment that the economy was going too fast at the
time .

Very few people were predicting boom in the economy in the summer

of '65, even after the initial Vietnam appropriation went up .

There were

many more people concerned about this overaged expansion dying :out than
about a takeoff into a boom .

And the famous Martin speech of June `65 was

focused largely on the stretched-out financial system and speculation and
the like rather than on a general overheating of the economy .
nevertheless I think this did pose an issue .

But

Martin talked about tightening .

And there was an agreement in September '65, as I recall, to start
some coordinated staff work . We asked the President to ask a set of
questions--I'm not sure to what extent this was suggested to him by someone
else--"what are the experts' views on where the economy is going ; and
what's the threat of inflation; would tighter money help on the regulatory
supervisory front ; or should we be doing things there?

If our effort is

really to tighten up on abuses of credit markets, do you want to just cut
the total flow, or do you want to pinpoint the abuses?"

I think that was

24
a very key question of strategy, and if you do it by regulating the overall
flow of moderating it, you impose more restraint on overall economic
activity than you want .
In light of these questions, Martin agreed to have some kind of a
joint staff effort .

It was the only time that one was launched .

There was

a special quadriad group that was formed to supervise this research--Paul
Volcker of Treasury ; Charlie Zwick, who was then Assistant Director of the
Budget ; Dan Brill ; and myself .

As our work went on, it became increasingly

clear that the economy was speeding up and that some of these problems
were getting to be more general economic problems .

But we still doubted

strongly on the basis of what we knew and thought we knew and believed
about federal spending and .tba- like,'.that it was a real-threat .,
We did basically write a memo which we completed about the 1st of
November in '65, which went somewhat beyond our mandate .
was living dangerously in taking the position he did .

I thought Brill

It really was a

policy recommendation saying we ought to keep monetary policy about where
it was, should not tighten for the remainder of the year, consider in
light of the budget where we would be for 1966 ; and if GNP outlook exceeded
seven hundred and twenty billion or so, that would be a signal for a
tightening-up policy which might call for higher taxes or for a tightening
of the monetary policy .

Basically the judgment would have to be made at

that time of the degree and the choice of instruments used for restraint .
Basically our judgment at~.the time was the 720 GNP for 1966 looked
'way out of the question.

The typical standard business forecast was

running around--I remember one of the business economists labeled it the
"Jet Model forecast ."--everybody who had a 707-billion GNP for 1966 .

But

we weren't putting ourselves in the position then of committing ourselves

25
to a particular forecast .
I remember when we signed the document, Brill said, "I'll bet we've
made monetary policy for the rest of this year ."

He said, 'Well, Martin's

going to feel obliged to distribute this, and it's a pretty reasonable
position for arguing against taking action now .

A lot of guys on the

Board are predisposed not to take action anyway ; it gives them a good
consensus excuse for doing this ."
Well, it turned out that the Fed did move the next month, and that memo
was never distributed to the other members of the Federal Reserve Board .
In fact, Sherm Maisel testified in pain some months later that he'd just found
out about its existence, and he had never seen it .
it .

Bill chose to sit on

His own argument was that financial markets just wouldn't wait, and

that there was a sufficient danger of a real mess that required the Fed
to act at that time rather than waiting to make a coordinated budget
decision .
We'll never know, but I still feel that there's some chance that if
monetary policy had not committed itself to restraint, that you could have
made a better argument for going up with a tax increase in the January '66
budget, which would have been highly desirable .

It would have been

possible at that time to say, "Look, we're threatened with inflation .
Something is going to have to be done on the restraint side .

We don't

want tight money ."
Well, once the Fed moved, they seemed to be committed to tight money
anyway, and any tax proposal could no

longer rest heavily on that kind of

a sharply defined choice between this or tight money .

You could still

have maybe argument that money would have to get a lot tighter, but it didn't
pose the thing in a saleable way .

26
After that, the sense of failure of communication and of some
personal unpleasantness on both sides from this split on policy led to a
very determined and much more formalized effort at coordination .

We had

lunch at the Federal Reserve starting February 1966 every two weeks on
Thursday-M:

Was this the entire Council?

0:

Yes .

The three of us and almost seven members of the Board always invited--

had good, although not perfect, attendance ; Martin typically there,

And

as a result of this, there was a much more--there was informal things that
flowed out of this .

You'd get into a luncheon conversation ; somebody

would follow it up ; and there'd be phone calls and such .
M:

This was prompted on both sides then?

0:

Yes .

M:

Both the Council and the FRS saw some lessons then--

0:

Yes .

M:

And since that time the coordination has been better .

0:

Much better .

I think the actual invitation came from Ball Martin .

I developed rather good personal relations with Martin, and

came to respect--although I'm not sure I understand the guy , a great deal-and I think really to sense what an honest and conscientious broader guy
he is than his public image .
M:

It's 4 o'clock and you have work to do .

I think this would be a good time

to break, and we can take up with this the next time .
0 :

Sure .