View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Beyond “Skin in the Game”
The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage
Securitization That Caused the Mortgage Meltdown

Kurt Eggert
Professor of Law
Chapman University School of Law

Prepared for the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission for its Hearing entitled
“The Impact of the Financial Crisis at the Ground Level – Greater
Sacramento, California.”

Sacramento, California
September 23, 2010

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
The Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission is holding its hearings during a crucial
moment, when the country is slowly recovering from what has been called the “Great
Recession,” a severe economic downturn that was triggered in part because of the boom
and then collapse of the subprime and non-prime mortgage market and the high numbers
of mortgage defaults and foreclosures that the boom and bust left in their wake.1 At the
same time, Congress and federal regulators, along with the financial industry, are
attempting to revive private-label mortgage securitization by establishing new rules of the
road to govern that securitization.2 The new Dodd-Frank bill takes basic steps to remake
mortgage securitization and requires regulators to fill out the full set of rules with new
regulations.
To create those new rules of the road, it is crucial to establish what went wrong
under the previous system so that when private-label mortgage securitization recovers,
we do not find ourselves heading for yet another crash. In my testimony, I will try to
identify what I consider the primary causes of the subprime and non-prime mortgage
boom and bust and what led to the high foreclosure and default rates.3 In addition, given
the location and purpose of these hearings, I will also describe why some California

1

“Subprime” generally refers to loans that carry higher interest rates and fees than the prime loans
guaranteed by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. “Non-prime loans” are those that do not conform to the
standards for agency loans guaranteed by Fannie and Freddie. “Non-prime” is a more inclusive term than
subprime in that it includes not only subprime loans but also “Alt-A” loans, loans that may have near prime
interest rates for borrowers with good credit, but have non-traditional characteristics, such as interest only
or payment-option terms or reduced documentation.
2
Private-label securitization is that done outside the auspices of government-sponsored entities (GSEs)
such as Fannie and Freddie.
3
This testimony is largely a distillation and update of my 2009 article The Great Collapse: How
Securitization Caused the Subprime Meltdown (May 2009). Connecticut Law Review, Vol. 41, No. 4,
2009. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1434691

2

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

communities were especially hard-hit by the subprime boom and bust and the resulting
foreclosures.
Those analyzing the subprime crash and the accompanying defaults and
foreclosures have converged on two main story lines to explain the flaws of
securitization. The first is the idea that the “originate to distribute” model, where lenders
originate loans intending immediately to sell or securitize them, misaligns the incentives
of loan originators because by quickly assigning their loans, they no longer suffer from
the results of loan defaults. Without ongoing “skin in the game,” the theory goes, lenders
have little motivation to engage in careful underwriting to ensure their loans will not
default.4 The second dominant story line is that securitization’s problem was one of
transparency: investors could not determine the risks of the securities created from
subprime and non-prime loans, given the complexity of the resulting securities and the
inadequate disclosures investors were given. Much of the proposed new regulation of
private-label securitization is designed to solve these two problems.
The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010
reflects these twin emphases. Its securitization reforms focus primarily on increased
disclosure to investors and risk retention by originators and securitizers. Federal
regulators who have already been moving forward with their own securitization reforms
also focus on disclosure and risk retention. The Security and Exchange Commission’s
proposed rules regarding securitization, which would revise Regulation AB and other
4

“Skin in the game” is the idea that investors can better trust the decisions of managers or others who stand
personally to lose from bad decisions. Warren Buffett has been widely credited with coining the phrase
“skin in the game.” See, e.g. http://www.worldaffairsjournal.org/new/blogs/rieff/Skin_in_the_Game.
However, Buffett has indirectly denied that he coined the phrase and its usage seems significantly to
predate Buffett himself. See Safire, William. 2006. “Language: Who's got a skin in the game?” The New
York Times, September 17. http://www.nytimes.com/2006/09/17/opinion/17iht-edsafire.2839605.html

3

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

rules related to securitization, would also impose risk retention and much more
disclosure, not only of the loans in the pool but also of the waterfall structure that
determines which tranches receive money and when. The FDIC has also proposed new
conditions for an FDIC-insured issuer to benefit from the FDIC’s securitization “safe
harbor” rule. Use of that safe harbor shields an asset-backed securities issuer from the
FDIC’s power following an issuer’s insolvency to recover assets that have been
securitized. FDIC’s proposed rule includes risk retention and disclosure requirements, as
well as other measures, for such safe harbor.
While the lack of “skin in the game” and of transparency are significant flaws in
how private-label mortgage securitization has been conducted, it is important to
recognize that they are not the only flaws, and that other aspects of securitization played a
major factor in the subprime boom and bust.5 Private-label mortgage securitization has
been structured so that it encourages, at each stage of the origination and securitization of
mortgages, market participants to push risk tolerance to its limits. It encourages brokers
and lenders to make the largest and riskiest loans borrowers will sign and that can be
securitized. Securitization rewards investment houses creating the riskiest loan pool that
the rating agency would bless with high ratings, and then gives financial incentives to
rating agencies to find some way to give high ratings to a large percentage of securities
backed by the resulting risky loans.
Another flaw in private-label securitization is that its use has made it possible and
lucrative for loan originators especially but also investment houses to bargain down the
due diligence efforts of other securitization participants. Lenders have put great pressure
5

In this paper, my critique of securitization is limited to the private-label securitization of residential
mortgage loans as it existed before the subprime collapse. Other forms of securitization, such as credit card
securitization, are structured differently and so have different structural characteristics.

4

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

on appraisers to overstate the value of houses to justify loans and on investment houses to
reduce their due diligence in examining loans in order to securitize them. Investment
houses and others securitizers could shop among rating agencies to find the rating agency
that would produce the best rating for securities while demanding the fewest potentially
costly credit enhancements designed to protect investors from excessive loan defaults.
Securitization of non-prime loans also destabilizes the financial markets by being
susceptible to an investor-driven boom and bust cycle. Notably, the recent subprime
collapse was the second one that subprime securitization has experienced. The first
subprime collapse occurred in the late 1990s and was largely driven by economic issues
outside of the subprime market. This boom and bust cycle for mono-line subprime
lenders encourages risk taking by those lenders because they can recognize that if
securitization dries up, they may well be put out of business through no fault of their
own. Therefore, during boom years subprime lenders have the economic incentive to
make as many loans as they can, good or bad, as long as the loans can be securitized.
Subprime lenders have little reason to be concerned about the long term reputational
effect of making bad loans if they may soon be out of business regardless of the quality
(or lack thereof) of the loans they make.
While the “originate to distribute” model explains that securitization undermined
loan underwriting, it is important to recognize exactly how that underwriting was
undermined. Securitization causes originators to focus on “hard” objective underwriting,
underwriting that can be demonstrated and verified through the use of specific data
points, such as the borrowers’ FICO scores, loan-to-value ratios, debt-to-income ratios,
income and assets (Eggert, 2002). In focusing on these objective attributes, lenders

5

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

intending to securitize their loans have less cause to engage in “soft” underwriting, which
examines borrowers’ credit-worthiness more subjectively, looking for evidence of
borrowers’ ability and willingness to repay outside of the data points valued by
securitization (Eggert, 2009). Analysis by economists indicates that much of the decline
in underwriting after 2000 can be explained to the decline in “soft” underwriting.
In addition to creating the conditions for the making of risky and default-prone
subprime and other non-prime loans, securitization amplified the effect of those defaults
beyond the mere losses that the defaults themselves would otherwise have caused. If
financial institutions had held individual loans, their losses would have been significant,
but would have been more transparent to counterparties, investors, regulators and even
the financial institutions themselves. Mortgage losses were amplified by counterparty
risk, when other companies withheld credit because they could not accurately estimate
the amount of subprime risk counterparties held. Had regulators realized the risk that
federally-regulated financial institutions held, they should have demanded measures to
counter or account for that risk. When the subprime collapse happened, no one knew
which institutions were concealing subprime time-bombs on their books, and this lack of
transparency of risk led to a severe credit crunch.
The tail end of securitization, the fact that loans are managed by servicers on
behalf of the trusts that own loan pools, rather than by an individual owner, also
contributes to the increased foreclosure rate, as servicers are more likely to foreclose and
less likely to engage in meaningful loan modifications, than portfolio loan owners would
be. In this way, securitization also amplifies the effects of loan defaults.

6

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

In the following testimony, I will first address why California has suffered so
greatly from the subprime boom and bust. Then I will address each of these factors in
greater detail. Those creating new rules of the road for private-label securitization should
recognize the many factors that played a role in the subprime boom and bust, and not just
focus on “skin in the game” and transparency.

CALIFORNIA AND THE SUBPRIME MARKET
One troubling question for Californians is why California communities were
among the worst affected nationally by the subprime boom and bust and so have suffered
the most from the foreclosure and property value declines that result. A Forbes article
from earlier this year identified Merced, California as the housing market in which
median home prices dropped the most in the entire nation since the second quarter of
2006, falling an astonishing 62% from their high of about $337,000 (Levy, 2010). In
2008, Mountain House, California, a planned city sixty miles east of San Francisco, was
identified as the most “underwater” community in the country, with almost 90% of its
home securing mortgages for more than the house was worth already by 2008 (Streitfeld,
2008).
The subprime boom and accompanying rise in property values was concentrated
in the so-called “Sand States”: California, Nevada, Arizona, and Florida (Tracy, 2010).
These states were ripe for housing booms for several reasons. They were subjects of
higher than average immigration from other states, with Nevada, Arizona and Florida all
recently in the top four “magnet states” with the highest percentage of current state
residents born in another state (Cohn and Morin, 2008). Arizona and Nevada were the

7

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

fastest growing states from 2004 – 2007, with Florida not far behind, while in California,
communities that would later be hit by subprime foreclosures, such as Riverside and San
Bernardino, were also rapidly adding population (Olesiuk and Kalser, 2009). These
states were magnet states because of their job growth, and they, as well as California
exurbs, were ripe for development because of empty land and low building costs.
In California, the cities hardest hit by subprime loans were right outside of large
population center: those in Riverside and San Bernardino counties for Los Angeles and
communities like Fresno, Merced or Mountain Home near San Francisco (Mayer and
Pence, 2008). These “exurbs” grew rapidly to accommodate would-be homeowners who
could not afford houses in the cities. Once a housing boom started in these communities,
the use of subprime loans pushed that boom into a bubble. Rapidly rising prices justified
and covered up increasingly risky loans, as lenders required less and less money down
based on anticipated valuation increases. Rising housing prices covered up a multitude of
sins, and homeowners who got into trouble could typically sell their houses and pay off
their loans, often reaping a profit. Cities with housing bubbles, such as Phoenix and Las
Vegas, had greater percentages of loans that were subprime than expensive markets like
Boston and San Francisco (8 and 12 percent in Phoenix compared to 3 and 4 percent for
San Francisco and Boston, in 2005, for example) (Mayer, 2010).
California’s anti-predatory lending law did little to fend off abusive practices in
the subprime market, as it contained only weak protection for residential borrowers. In
2001, California in 2001 enacted AB 489,6 a bill purportedly designed to deter predatory
lending. However, this law had numerous weaknesses. First of all, the protections only
covered loans under $250,000, an amount raised in 2006 to Fannie Mae’s limit for a
6

The bill AB 489 is embodied in Division 1.6 of the California Financial Code, Sections 4970 to 4979.8.

8

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

conforming single-family first mortgage. The law did little to restrict brokers from
steering borrowers into higher priced loans, and explicitly exempted from liability
assignees who are holders in due course. In other words, even when California’s law was
violated, investors in the resulting mortgage-backed securities were by and large immune
from suit by the borrower.
To make matters worse, California’s weak state law was held to preempt local law
that might have provided homeowners with more protection from abusive lending. In the
case, Am. Fin. Servs. Ass’n v. City of Oakland,7 the California Supreme Court held that
California’s weak state law preempted local ordinances, including Oakland’s much
stronger local ordinance which would have covered more loans, mandated borrower
counseling for high-cost loans, and provided liability to assignees of predatory loans,
including those that had been securitized. Assignee liability is designed to force the
secondary market to police originators in order to avoid liability for abusive lending
(Eggert, 2002). California borrowers were left relatively unprotected as a result of the
weak state law and its preemption of stronger local ordinances.

FACTORS IN THE SUBPRIME COLLAPSE:
1.

The “Originate to Distribute” Model

Much has been made of the “Originate to Distribute” model of subprime lending.
In 2002, I argued that subprime securitization weakens underwriting because lenders
would be less concerned about whether loans would default, given that they planned
quickly to sell them, and would only do the sort of automated, objective underwriting the
results of which can be communicated to the secondary market (Eggert, 2002). It seems
7

Am. Fin. Servs. Ass’n v. City of Oakland, 104 P.3d 813, 828–29 (Cal. 2005).

9

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

clear that new regulations mandated by the Dodd-Frank bill and being considered by the
SEC and the FDIC are designed to reduce the ills caused by the “originate to distribute”
model. The law and likely regulations will fairly soon require originators to retain some
“skin in the game” by holding 5 percent or so of the subprime securities backed by their
loans, though the exact details will be determined by various federal regulators.
However, it would be a mistake to place too much confidence in the effect of such
efforts. First of all, many subprime originators had so much “skin in the game” in terms
of requirements that they repurchase early defaults or loans that violated their
representations and warranties that they quickly went out of business once the loans went
bad and they were asked to repurchase them. While their creditors would benefit if the
monoline subprime originators had held more assets when they went bankrupt, the
problem seems to have been one much larger than a mere 5 percent retention requirement
would have solved.
Also, how the retention requirement should be structured is difficult to determine.
If originators are required to retain the first loss position, they might well bank on the
retained assets having so little value because of nearly inevitable losses that they should
not affect the lenders’ behavior, especially that of abusive lenders with high default rates.
The worse the lender, the less effect holding a 5 percent first loss position would have on
that lender’s behavior. On the other hand, if originators were required to hold 5 percent
scattered vertically among all of the tranches of a securitization, then they would face
much lower losses even if there were significant default rates.
Nor is merely increasing the retention percentage without its own share of
difficulty. If originators retain too great a percentage of securities in loans they originate,

10

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

they lose much of the advantages of securitization, as they would have less access to
capital. Furthermore, originators who continue to service the loans they make would find
themselves with a growing conflict of interest with the other investors, as the originators’
interest in how the loan is serviced increases.
Instead of accomplishing risk retention solely through forcing originators to hold
mortgage-backed securities, it may be better to have them retain some risk by forcing
them to hold loans in their portfolio for a period of time, say a year, before securitizing
them. The FDIC had proposed such a one-year seasoning requirement but in its latest
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking replaced the seasoning requirement with that of a “a 5%
reserve fund for RMBS in order to cover potential put backs during the first year of the
securitization.” (FDIC, 2010). Requiring seasoning would have some clear advantages
over simply requiring retention of securities. First of all, seasoning would not lead to a
conflict of interest between originators and investors, as the lenders would hold their own
loans. Secondly, it would force lenders to bear all of the risk of early default, and would
prevent them from securitizing a large number of bad loans and then declaring
bankruptcy when the loans quickly go bad. Also, it would reduce the boom and bust
cycle of subprime loans, as lenders who rapidly ramp up their subprime operations would
have to hold the resulting loans for a year rather than quickly transferring them and
immediately relending the money.
2.

Lack of Transparency

Critics have accurately condemned the lack of transparency that private-label
mortgage-backed securitization, as it was structured, provided. Such securitization has
created two kinds of opacity. First of all, investors were not given good information

11

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

about the risks contained in the securities they were purchasing. Secondly, by concealing
those risks in securities with complex, opaque structures, the risks of which were again
sliced and diced among CDOs, credit default swaps, insurance, repurchase agreements
and other hedge attempts, securitization made opaque the subprime risk held by many
different financial institutions.
For private-label securitizations, investors should have been given current loanlevel detail for every security offering, so that they could see what they were buying,
albeit with measures in place to protect borrower privacy. The value of mortgage-backed
securities depends almost completely on the loans themselves, but investors were rarely
given loan-level information. By failing to give investors loan level data, Wall Street
firms were able to continue to securitize non-prime loans despite the deterioration of
underwriting for those loans and their increased risk of default.8 Worse yet, the
prospectuses and accompanying supplement often made claims about the underwriting
used for loan pools, but did not disclose how many of the loans included in the pools
were made as exceptions to the underwriting standards. Instead, the offering materials
reported mere boilerplate language that exceptions might make up “substantial” or
“significant” portions of the pool (Bajaj and Anderson, 2008). The number and character
of exceptions, which ran as high as 50 to 80 percent of some loan pools, would have an
enormous effect on the quality of the loan pool and should have been disclosed (Bajaj
and Anderson, 2008).
Investors often were not notified of the changing nature of the mortgages that
8

According to Randall S. Kroszner, Governor of the Federal Reserve, “The paucity and inaccessibility of
data about the underlying home loans was, in my opinion, one of the reasons that private-label MBS was
able to expand so rapidly in 2005 and 2006 despite a deterioration in underwriting and prospective credit
performance.” (Kroszner, 2008).

12

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

were being securitized. For example, while investors might have been told of the number
of no or low documentation loans, they often were not informed that such loans were
being marketed to a different kind of borrower, wage earners who should have easily
been able to document their income (Adelson and Jacob, 2007) Wage earners who can
easily document their income but affirmatively choose not to are significantly more risky
borrowers than non-wage earners that lenders choose for reduced loan documentation
because of the borrowers’ low credit risk (Dungey, 2007). However, this change in the
type of borrower using low documentation loan was not adequately disclosed.
Investment houses also should have disclosed the results of their due diligence
efforts in determining whether the loans fit the purported qualifications of the pool. In
this due diligence process, some portion of the pools would be examined, often by a third
party, to see if the mortgages met the criteria for the pool. What percentage failed in this
examination was important information for investors, as it would tell them about the
actual, as opposed to claimed, underwriting by the lender. Instead of disclosing the due
diligence reports to rating agencies and investors, however, it appears that some Wall
Street firms may have been using those reports primarily to increase their own profits.
According to recent reports, some Wall Street firms used due diligence reports showing a
large number of problem loans in order to negotiate a lower price with the originator,
then securitized the problem loans anyway without disclosing the problems to investors
(Mortgenson 2010). Such behavior, if proven, stands due diligence on its head, and turns
if from a mechanism to protect investors from problem loans to a mechanism for
investment houses to benefit from problem loans at the expense of investors who
unknowingly end up with the bad loans.

13

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

3.

Pushing Risk to Its Limits

One hazard of securitization is that it encourages each market participant to push
risk tolerances to their limits in an effort to maximize profits. For example, during the
subprime boom, mortgage brokers could increase their income by closing as many loans
as possible, convincing borrowers to take the largest loans they would qualify for, and
inducing borrowers accept interest rates higher than what their credit records justified, all
of which increased the risk of defaults. Brokers’ commission was often based on loan
amount and the number of loans, and so if they could upsell the amount of loan and close
as many loans as possible, they could maximize their earnings. This motivated brokers to
learn the limits of lenders’ underwriting standards, often automated, and to push those
limits as far as possible. Worse yet, yield spread premiums, additional payment to
brokers when borrowers accepted interest rates higher than their credit could have
justified, further rewarded brokers who could lure borrowers into taking loans with
higher interest rates, leading to even riskier loans (Gordon, 2009).
As a result of these broker incentives, loans originated through a mortgage broker
have experienced significantly higher delinquency rates (more than 50% higher,
according to one study) than loans originated directly by a bank (Jiang, Nelson, and
Vytlacil, 2009). Jiang, et. al. conclude that brokers not only “apply looser lending
standards” but are also “less diligent in verifying borrower information” than banks
originating their own loans, with the likely result being increased information
falsification for loans originated by brokers.

14

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

While brokers were testing the underwriting limits of originators, originators were
also testing the secondary market to see what loans it would accept, and used the
information they gleaned to weaken their underwriting if they could sell more loans by
doing so. While offering materials for subprime-backed securities touted subprime
lenders’ underwriting standards to investors, it appears that for at least some non-prime
lenders, the primary if not sole underwriting question was whether the loan could be
securitized. In securities litigation by the Securities and Exchange Commission against
Angelo Mozilo, of Countrywide Financial Corp., at one time the nation’s biggest
residential mortgage lender, the SEC has argued that “the evidence is clear that by as
early as July, 2005, Countrywide’s primary ‘underwriting standard’ was not the
borrower’s ability to repay the loan, but rather whether it could sell the loan into the
secondary market, where Defendants apparently hoped the performance of the loan
would then become the purchaser’s problem.”

(SEC Brief, 2010). If so, Countrywide

was succumbing to the siren call of securitization.
When loans were being securitized, again risk tolerance was pushed to the limits.
Because highly rated securities are, all else being equal, more valuable than those lower
rated, and because credit enhancements, like over-collateralization of loans or default
insurance designed to protect investors from the risk of default, can be expensive,
securitizers profit when rating agencies give the maximum high rating for the resulting
securities while demanding the cheapest credit enhancements. Wall Street firms and
other securitizers were rewarded for assembling the worst loans with least expensive
credit enhancements that would receive the desired credit ratings. They pushed rating
agencies to weaken their rating quality.

15

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

Rather than mortgage-backed securities at each rating level with risk tolerances
across the whole band of risk tolerances for that level, the securitizers were encouraged to
create securities always just barely justifying the given rating level (Eggert, 2009,
Brunnermeier, 2009). In other words, when mortgage or CDO securitization produced
investment grade securities, it produced the riskiest investment grade securities that the
rating agencies would permit. This pushing of risk to its edge of tolerance has made the
entire system more fragile. Much like an eco-system with little bio-diversity is more
vulnerable to environmental change, so too a mortgage finance system based on pools of
mortgages all pushed to the limit of risk tolerance is more vulnerable to a financial shock.
4.

Bargaining Down Due Diligence

Securitization atomized the mortgage process, breaking it apart and assigning its
various functions to different business entities (Jacobides, 2001). Instead of a lender
originating, holding and collecting payments for its own loans, a mortgage broker dealt
directly with the borrower, a lender originated the loan, an investment house bundled it
for securitization, a rating agency blessed the resulting securities with its ratings, and a
servicer collected the mortgage payments with perhaps another servicer stepping in to
foreclose. This atomization not only gave market participants incentives that conflicted
with those of investors, with originators, investment houses and even rating agencies
rewarded for quantity of loans over quality, but also gave those interested in quantity
over quality the ability to bargain down the due diligence and quality control of other
market participants.
Home appraisers widely complained of lender pressure to inflate the value they
assigned to houses for lenders. Lenders that hold their own loans desire accurate

16

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

appraisals to protect themselves with an equity cushion should the borrower default. For
lenders that securitize, however, home appraisals represented not a protective mechanism
to reduce loan losses but rather a pesky hurdle to overcome in order to make and sell the
loan. Artificially inflating the appraised values makes loans more valuable by decreasing
their loan-to-value ratios and can also justify higher loan amounts. Banks too often let
their loan officers or underwriters manage the hiring of appraisers, which allowed their
loan officers to pressure appraisers to come up with an appraisal high enough to justify
the desired loan (Taylor, 2004) Appraisers that refused to meet appraisal targets could
expect to lose business as a result (N.Y. Comm’n of Investigation, 2008). Other
appraisers apparently did “play ball” with lenders and brokers, and a review of a small
sample of loans from 2006 that suffered early default showed that more than half had
appraisal problems, such as inaccurate appraisals, conflicting information, or items
“outside of typically accepted parameters” (Fitch Ratings, 2007).
During the boom years, subprime loan securities were in such high demand and
subprime loans hence so valued that subprime originators could demand that investment
houses engage in less due diligence and could resist having to buy back all of the shoddy
loans that the diminished due diligence uncovered. While Wall Street firms might have
ordered twenty-five to forty percent of loans to be reviewed before they were securitized
shortly after 2000, by 2006, this percentage had fallen to, typically, 10 percent (Reckard,
2008). Large subprime originators had so much leverage that they could bargain down
this due diligence, insisting that Wall Street firms engage in far less due diligence for
loans that would be securitized than financial firms would conduct for loans they
intended to hold in portfolio (Muolo and Padilla, 2008).

17

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

Similarly, Wall Street firms could shop among rating agencies to obtain the most
favorable ratings given the quality of loans, relying on the rating agencies’ conflict of
interest created by the fact that they were paid by the securities issuers they were
supposed to judge rather than the investors they were supposed to protect (Raiter, 2008).
One internal rating agency memo noted, “The real problem is not that the market . . .
underweights ratings quality but rather that, in some sectors, it actually penalizes quality
by awarding rating mandates based on the lowest credit enhancement needed for the
highest rating.”9 Rating agencies appear to have responded to Wall Street pressure by
downgrading the quality of their ratings, especially when doing so would allow them to
secure sole rating authority over a security offering. Benmelech and Dluglosz (2009)
find that where only one agency rated a set of securities, those ratings were more likely to
be downgraded. Becker and Milbourne (2008) find that, at least for corporate ratings,
competition between rating agencies is accompanied by a decrease in rating quality.
Ashcraft, Pinkham-Goldsmith, and Vickery (2010) also find correlation between rating
quality and number of rating agencies who rated a deal, but more importantly conclude
that there was a significant erosion in the quality of credit ratings at the peak of the
subprime boom and that securities backed by high risk loans or low documentation loans
have been consistently overrated.
5.

Subprime’s Boom and Bust Cycle

One of the dangers of securitizing subprime loans is that it links those loans
directly to the capital markets, which for subprime lending is a relatively unstable
funding supply, one that has crashed twice already in the young life of subprime
9

This memo is from a confidential presentation to Moody’s Board of Directors, and was made public for a
hearing Credit Rating Agencies and the Financial Crisis: Hearing Before the H. Comm. On Oversight and
Gov’t Reform, 110th Cong. (2008). http://oversight.house.gov/documents/20081022111050.pdf

18

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

securitization. The securitization of subprime loans started first in the late 1980s, but did
not gain much volume until the mid-1990s (Gittelsohn, 2007). The first subprime crash
occurred in 1998, when the combination of the Russian debt crisis and the collapse of the
private hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) caused investors to jettison
subprime securities in their rush to the safety of U.S. Treasury securities. Subprime
lenders suffered a double blow as they received a lower price for loans they had in the
pipeline at the same time that their cost of funds increased (Sabry and Schopflocher,
2007). The stock values of subprime lenders plummeted, some to zero, and fallen
subprime lenders that had depended on securitization included some of the biggest names
in subprime (Muolo and Padilla, 2008. White, 2006). While subprime lenders had
suffered some greater than expected default rates and had played accounting games, the
first subprime collapse seems to have been for reasons largely external to the subprime
market (Danis and Pennington-Cross, 2005).
Realizing that they are tied to such an unstable money supply would naturally
lead subprime lenders to become greater risk-takers. If a subprime lender had
scrupulously maintained its underwriting standards throughout the subprime boom, it still
would in all likelihood have found itself unable to stay in business, cut off from its
funding source when subprime crashed, as subprime securitization has essentially
disappeared. The lender would have obtained no benefit for forgoing making even
default-prone loans that could be securitized, as there would be no long-term reputational
benefit for good underwriting once the lender is out of business. As federal regulators
and the financial market attempt to restart private-label mortgage underwriting, they must
not only convince investors that the loans will be well-underwritten, they must also

19

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

convince subprime lenders that there are benefits for good underwriting and that lenders
should not just engage in a race to the bottom before the market collapses again.
6.

Securitization and “Hard” vs. “Soft” Mortgage Underwriting

Between 2002 and 2006, underwriting standards became significantly degraded.
For example, the median loan to value ratio of new subprime loans increased from 90
percent to 100 percent from 2003 to 2005 (Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund, 2009). There
has been significant academic discussion about how much this underwriting decline led
to the increased foreclosure and default rate, and how much was due to declining housing
prices, but it appears likely that both played a role. Gerardi, Shapiro and Willen (2009)
argue that declining housing prices led to the rapid increase in foreclosures, though
concede that underwriting standards did decline, creating a set of borrowers “particularly
vulnerable to the decline in prices.” Others note the great role increasingly shoddy
underwriting played in the increase in defaults and foreclosures (for example
Dell’Ariccia, Igan and Laeven, 2008, and Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund, 2009), though
they too note the relevance also of declining housing prices.
Even to the extent that declining housing prices led to the rise in defaults,
securitization still seems to have played a role in the housing price bubble, the popping of
which led to those housing price declines. Some have blamed the bubble on the federal
government’s monetary policies. The national government of the United States and
Canada however had similar expansionist monetary policy in the last decade, yet housing
prices in Canada did not exhibit the boom and bust seen in the United States, and
Canada’s mortgage delinquency rate has been much lower than that of the United States
(MacGee, 2009). MacGee (2009) concludes that the larger subprime market and more

20

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

lax underwriting standards in the United States were critical factors in the housing bubble
and bust, rather than overall monetary policies.
In discussing declining underwriting standards, it is important to recognize the
multiple dimensions of underwriting. Some underwriting is based on hard, objective data
which can be determined with little direct knowledge of the borrower and fairly easily
communicated to the secondary market. Automated underwriting systems, and their use
of data points such as loan to value ratios, borrower income and assets, and FICO scores
use “hard” mortgage underwriting both on the lender level and by the secondary market
to evaluate loans for securitization (Anderson, et. al., 2008). “Soft” mortgage
underwriting is based on more personal, subjective information, such as direct knowledge
of the borrower, the borrower’s explanation for credit mishaps or for anticipated earnings,
or the neighborhood wherein the house is located (Rajan, Seru and Vig, 2010).
Each form of underwriting has its strengths and weaknesses, with hard mortgage
underwriting faster and cheaper, and less subject to favoritism or red-lining, while soft
mortgage underwriting is better at reacting to new and different mortgage conditions with
common sense, rather than relying on a statistical analysis mired in the past (Browning,
2007, Rajan, et. al. 2010). Ideally, lenders would employ both hard and soft mortgage
underwriting, so that the strengths of each would make up for the weakness of the other.
One of the great challenges to restarting subprime securitization will be to reestablish
automated underwriting, given that past subprime default data will have been under a
completely different regulatory regime and those designing automated underwriting
systems will initially have little useful current data on which to base their programs.

21

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

Securitization led to the decline, if not often the virtual elimination, of soft
mortgage underwriting for loans designed to be securitized. Originators had no incentive
to gather “soft” information that could not be communicated to the Wall Street firms,
rating agencies and investors that would determine which loans would be securitized.
Demyanyk and Van Hemert (2008) conclude that “during the dramatic growth of the
subprime (securitized) mortgage market, the quality of the market deteriorated
dramatically” and that the loan quality declined, even when adjusted for changes in
“borrower characteristics (such as the credit score, a level of indebtedness, an ability to
provide documentation), loan characteristics (such as a product type, an amortization
term, a loan amount, an mortgage interest rate), and macroeconomic conditions (such as
house price appreciation, level of neighborhood income and change in unemployment).”
Anderson, Capozza, and Van Order (2008) found a two-stage decline in underwriting
standards, with hard mortgage underwriting standards declining during the 1990s,
possibly as investors gained confidence in the securitization of subprime loans, and a
second decline after 2004 that was not as readily apparent to the secondary market.
Rajan, Seru and Vig (2010) also find a decline in soft mortgage underwriting, noting that
as securitization increases, the rates of subprime loans for borrowers with similar hard
credit criteria converge, indicating that lenders focus more exclusively on hard
information.
7.

How Securitization Amplifies Default Risk

Securitization perniciously amplified the damage caused by non-prime defaults
beyond the mere losses the defaults would have caused if they had been held by financial
institutions as whole loans. Some financial institutions have regulatory requirements that

22

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

treat investment grade securities very differently from non-investment grade securities.
Financial institutions, either through regulation or by agreement, may have requirements
concerning investment grade securities “hard coded” into them. If they hold too many
securities that are downgraded below investment grade, they may have to raise significant
additional capital, may have their counterparty status threatened or their liquidity
questioned, and may even be considered “troubled” (Berg, 2009). If the investment grade
mortgage-backed securities have all been “rated at the edge” by rating agencies eager to
maximize their rating business, the securities may be too prone to being downgraded,
thus unduly threatening the institution that holds them.
Securitization reduced financial transparency for investors and regulators
attempting to determine the subprime risk held by various financial institutions. Instead
of holding whole loans so that their risk was fairly obvious, financial institutions held
subprime risk that had been sliced apart and reassembled in such complex and
multitudinous transactions that even the financial institutions themselves had difficulty in
determining what their own exposure was. For example, Citigroup recently settled
claims that it had wildly underestimated its subprime exposure, claiming in mid-October,
2007, that it had “only” $13 billion in subprime exposure, only to admit in early
November, 2007 that its “direct exposure” for subprime was about $55 billion, which
included “’super-senior’ tranches of collateralized debt obligations and financial
guarantees known as liquidity puts that allowed customers to sell debt securities back to
Citigroup if credit markets froze,” according to the SEC (Westbrook and Keoun, 2010).
Had Citigroup’s federal regulators realized the extent of its subprime exposure,
they might well have demanded that it take steps to reduce that exposure or to allocate

23

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

additional capital reserves because of the risk. Investors might have pulled out or
threatened to pull out of Citigroup’s stock, giving it further encouragement to reduce its
subprime risk. Because that exposure was relatively hidden, though, regulators and
investors did not have adequate opportunity to rein in Citigroup’s risky behavior.
This lack of transparency contributed greatly to the global liquidity crisis that
followed the subprime meltdown and accompanying increase in mortgage defaults.
Securitization has led to an “opaque web of interconnected obligations,” significantly
increasing counterparty risk, in that financial institutions have difficulty determining the
stability of their counterparties (Brunnermeier, 2009).
Securitization also amplifies the risk of foreclosure by making it harder for
borrowers to obtain appropriate loan modifications. Securitized loans are exhibiting
higher foreclosure rates than unsecuritized loans, not only because of the effect
securitization had on underwriting, but also due to the fact that third-party servicers act
on behalf of investors to collect mortgage payments, monitor defaults and also foreclose.
Securitization makes it more difficult for borrowers to resolve problem loans, due to such
factors as “tranche warfare” whereby a servicer is concerned that a loan modification
may benefit one tranche of a mortgage deal above others, leaving the servicer open to
claims of favoritism and breach of the fiduciary duty to treat all classes fairly (Eggert,
2002). Servicers’ self-interest may also encourage excessive foreclosures, as servicers
may benefit more from the foreclosure than they would from a loan modification (Eggert,
2007). In this way, securitization also amplifies the effects of loan defaults by causing
more loan defaults to turn into loan foreclosures.

24

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

Economists currently do not all agree that securitization increases foreclosures by
limiting effective loan modifications or other workouts. However, those who argue that
loans serviced by third parties have higher foreclosure rates than those held in portfolio
appear to be gaining the upper hand. Adelino, Gerardi, and Willen (2009) discounted the
idea that securitization made effective loan modification more difficult, and asserted
instead that servicers are failing to engage in widespread loan modifications merely
because such modifications would not make economic sense. Instead, according to their
analysis, investors may often benefit if servicers either passively wait to see if borrowers
find some other way to cure the loan or if servicers foreclose, and so avoid the high risk
of re-default after modification. However, a recent paper by Piskorski, Seru and Vig
(2010) has concluded that securitization causes a “foreclosure bias,” noting, “Controlling
for contract terms and regional conditions, we find that seriously delinquent loans that are
held by the bank (henceforth called ‘portfolio’ loans) have lower foreclosure rates than
comparable securitized loans (between 3% (13%) to 7% (32%) in absolute (relative)
terms).” Piskorski, et. al. also note that governmental agency reports on loan
modifications also validate the idea that securitized loans exhibit a “foreclosure bias,”
and state, “OCC and OTS Mortgage Metrics Reports (2009b) point out that the re-default
rate for renegotiated loans serviced by third parties was significantly higher than the redefault rate for loans held in the servicers’ own portfolios (for example, 70% higher after
six months).
It is unlikely that those holding loans in their own portfolios are regularly failing
to foreclose when foreclosing would be in their own best interests. Hence, because loans
held by third party servicers have a foreclosure bias as compared to loans held in

25

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

portfolio, it appears likely that servicers are foreclosing on some loans even when it is in
the interest of the investors not to do so. Foreclosures can cause great damage, not only
to the homeowner, but also to neighboring property values and the community (Eggert,
2009). By causing more troubled loans to be foreclosed rather than resolved,
securitization amplifies the damage of problem loans.
CONCLUSION
Governmental regulators and the financial industry are now in the process of
attempting to re-write the rules of the road regarding private-label mortgage-backed
securitization. The Dodd-Frank bill contains a broad outline of some improvements, but
leaves many of the specific changes to regulations created by a variety of federal
regulators. As those regulators and the financial industry work to put private-label
securitization back together, it is important to recognize that the flaws of the previous
system go far beyond the lack of both “skin in the game” by originators and transparency
for investors. Some in the financial industry are advocating for minimizing the changes
to the system, as if adding a dash of disclosure and risk retention were all that was needed
for a safe and vibrant system of private-label securitization. However, the structural
problems of private-label mortgage securitization go far beyond mere “skin in the game”
and transparency. Those who would seek to prevent another crash need to make bold,
rather than merely cosmetic, changes. By addressing all of the problems of mortgage
securitization, we can maximize our chances to avoid another mortgage crisis caused in
large part by securitization.

26

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

References:
Adelino, Manuel, Kristopher S. Gerardi, and Paul Willen. 2009. “Why Don’t Lenders
Renegotiate More Home Mortgages? Redefaults, Self-Cures, and Securitization.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Working Paper No. 09-4. SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1433777
Adelson, Mark and David Jacob. 2007. “ABS/MBS Litigation Outlook.” Asset
Securitization Rep., November 19.
Anderson, Charles D., Dennis R. Capozza, and Robert Van Order. 2008.
“Deconstructing the Subprime Debacle Using New Indices of Underwriting Quality and
Economic Conditions: A First Look.” (unpublished working paper). SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1160073
Ashcraft, Adam, Paul Goldsmith-Pinkham, and James Vickery. 2010. “MBS Ratings
and the Mortgage Credit Boom.” FRB of New York Staff Report No. 449; European
Banking Center Discussion Paper No. 2010-24S; CentER Discussion Paper Series No.
2010-89S. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1615613
Bajaj, Vikas and Jenny Anderson. 2008. “Inquiry Focuses on Withholding of Data on
Loans.” New York Times, January 12.
Becker, Bo and Todd T. Milbourn. 2008. “Reputation and Competition: Evidence from
the Credit Rating Agency,” HBS Finance working paper 09-051. SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1278150
Benmelech, Efraim and Jennifer Dlugosz. 2009. “The Alchemy of CDO Credit
Ratings.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(5), 617-634.
Berg, Richard S. CEO of Performance Trust Capital Partners, LLC. 2009. Testimony at
Hearings Before the H. Comm. on Financial Services, 111th Cong.,
http://www.house.gov/apps/list/hearing/financialsvcs_dem/berg032509.pdf
Browning, Lynnley. 2007. “The Subprime Loan Machine; Automated Underwriting
Software Helped Fuel A Mortgage Boom.” New York Times, March 23.
Brunnermeier, Markus. 2009. “Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007–
2008,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(1), Winter, 77–100.
Cohn, D’Vera and Rich Morin, Pew Research Center. 2008. “Who Moves? Who Stays
Put? Where’s Home?” December 17. http://pewsocialtrends.org/pubs/721/movers-andstayers

27

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

Danis, Michelle A. and Anthony Pennington-Cross. 2005. “The Delinquency of
Subprime Mortgages.” 8–9 (Fed. Res. Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series, Working
Paper No. 2005-022A, 2005). SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=761804
Dell’Ariccia, Giovanni, Deniz Igan, and Luc Laeven. 2008. “Credit Booms and Lending
Standards: Evidence from the Subprime Mortgage Market.” Unpublished manuscript
from the International Monetary Fund. SSRN: http:/ssrn.com/abstract=1141005
Demyanyk, Yuliya and Otto Van Hemert, 2008. “Understanding the Subprime Mortgage
Crisis” (unpublished working paper). SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1020396.
Dungey, Doris. 2007. Posting of “Tanta” (Doris Dungey) to
CALCULATEDRISK.COM, http://www.calculatedriskblog.com/2007/03/ficos-and-auswe-will-add-your.html (Mar. 19, 2007, 13:13 EST)
Eggert, Kurt. 2002. “Held Up in Due Course: Predatory Lending, Securitization, and The
Holder in Due Course Doctrine.” Creighton Law Review, Vol. 35, 503. SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=904661
Eggert, Kurt. 2007. “Comment on Michael a. Stegman et al.: What Prevents Loan
Modifications?.” Housing Policy Debate, 18(2). SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1081479
Eggert, Kurt. 2009. “The Great Collapse: How Securitization Caused the Subprime
Meltdown.” Connecticut Law Review, 41 (4). SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1434691
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). 2010. Press Release: “FDIC Board
Approves NPR Regarding Safe Harbor Protection for Securitizations.” May 11.
http://www.fdic.gov/news/news/press/2010/pr10112.html
Fitch Ratings. 2007. “Subprime Collateral Trends and Early Payment Defaults”
FitchRatings.com. Apr. 27, 2007.
Gerardi, K., A. H. Shapiro, P.S. Willen. 2009. “Decomposing the Foreclosure Crisis:
House Price Depreciation versus Bad Underwriting.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Working Paper 2009-25.
Gittelsohn, John. 2007. “How Subprime Started in Orange County, Calif.” Orange
County Reg. (Cal.), Dec. 30.
Gordon, Julia, Center for Responsible Lending. 2009. Testimony for Hearings Before
the H. Subcomm. on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit of the H. Comm. on
Financial Services, 111th Cong. 3, March 11.
http://www.house.gov/apps/list/hearing/financialsvcs_dem/gordon_testimony_3-1109_final.pdf

28

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

Jacobides, Michael G. 2001. “Mortgage Banking Unbundling: Structure, Automation
and Profit.” Mortgage Banking, Jan. 1.
Jiang, Wei, Ashlyn Aiko Nelson and Edward Vytlacil. 2009. “Liar’s Loan? Effects of
Origination Channel and Information Falsification on Mortgage Delinquency.”
(Unpublished manuscript.) SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1421462
Kroszner, Randall S., Governor, Bd. Of Governors of the Fed. Res. Sys. 2008.
“Improving the Infrastructure for Non-Agency Mortgage-Backed Securities.” Speech at
the Federal Reserve System Conference on Housing and Mortgage Markets, December
4. http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kroszner20081204a.htm.
Levy, Francesca. 2010. “Cities where homes have lost the most value.” Forbes.com,
January 4. http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/34644840
MacGee, James. 2009. “Why Didn’t Canada’s Housing Market Go Bust?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary. September.
Mayer, Christopher. 2010 “Housing, Subprime Mortgages and Securitization: How did
we go wrong and what can we learn so this doesn’t happen again?” Testimony before the
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, February 27.
http://www.fcic.gov/hearings/pdfs/2010-0227-Mayer.pdf
Mayer, Christopher J. and Karen M. Pence. 2008. “Subprime Mortgages: What, Where,
and to Whom?” NBER Paper Series, Vol. w14083. SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1149330
Mayer, Christopher, Karen Pence, and Shane M. Sherlund. 2009. "The Rise in Mortgage
Defaults." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(1): 27–50.
Mortgenson, Gretchen. 2010. “Seeing vs. Doing.” New York Times, July 25.
Muolo, Paul and Mathew Padilla. 2008. Chain of Blame: How Wall Street Caused the
Mortgage and Credit Crisis. P. 39
N.Y. Comm’n of Investigation. 2008. “A Perfect Storm: Easy Money And The
Mortgage Meltdown: The Subprime Mortgage Crisis In New York State 9–10.”
http://www.sic.state.ny.us/Docs/Public%20Reports/pdf/MortgageCrisis.pdf.
Olesiuk, Shayhna M. and Kathy R. Kalser, FDIC. 2009. “2009 Economic Landscape,
Sand States: Anatomy of a Perfect Housing-Market Storm,” April 27.
http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/quarterly/2009_vol3_1/AnatomyPerfectHousing.htm
l
Piskorski, Tomasz, Seru, Amit and Vig, Vikrant. 2010. “Securitization and Distressed
Loan Renegotiation: Evidence from the Subprime Mortgage Crisis” Chicago Booth

29

Kurt Eggert, Beyond “Skin in the Game”: The Structural Flaws in Private-Label Mortgage Securitization

School of Business Research Paper No. 09-02; AFA 2010 Atlanta Meetings Paper.
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1321646
Raiter, Frank L.. 2008. Statement at Credit Rating Agencies and the Financial Crisis:
Hearing Before the H. Comm. On Oversight and Gov’t Reform, 110th Cong.
http://oversight.house.gov/documents/20081022102804.pdf
Rajan, Uday, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig. 2010. “The Failure of Models That Predict
Failure: Distance, Incentives and Defaults.” (Chi. Graduate Sch. Bus., Research Paper
No. 08-19). SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1296982
Reckard, E. Scott. 2008. “Subprime Mortgage Watchdogs Kept on Leash.” Los Angeles
Times, Mar. 17.
Sabry, Faten and Thomas Schopflocher. 2007. “The Subprime Meltdown: Not Again!”
Am. Bankr. Inst. J., Sept. 2007, at 1, 1.
Securities and Exchange Commission’s Opposition To Joint Memorandum of Points and
Authorities in Support of Defendants Motions for Summary Judgment or Summary
Adjudication (“SEC Brief”). 2010. August 16.
http://www.scribd.com/doc/36412677/S-E-C-s-Brief-Opposing-Mozilo-s-Motion-toDismiss
Streitfeld, David. 2008. “A Town Drowns in Debt as Home Values Plunge.” New York
Times, November 10.
http://www.nytimes.com/2008/11/11/business/11home.html?ref=todayspaper
Taylor, Gary P. on behalf of Appraisal Inst. 2004. Testimony: Broken Dreams in the
Poconos: The Response of the Secondary Markets and Implications for Federal
Legislation: Hearings Before the H. Subcomm. on Capital Markets, Insurance and
Government Sponsored Enterprises of the H. Comm. on Financial Services, 108th Cong.
11. http://www.appraisalinstitute.org/newsadvocacy/downloads/ltrs_tstmny/AI-ASAASFMRA_Poconos_Lng_Stmnt.pdf
Tracy, Joseph S. 2010. “What the Fed Did and Why.” Speech before the Westchester
County Bankers Association. June 25.
http://www.newyorkfed.org/newsevents/speeches/2010/tra100625.html.
Westbrook, Jessie and Bradley Keoun. 2010. “Citibank Pays $75 Million to Resolve
Subprime-Disclosure Probe.” Businessweek.com, July 30.
http://www.businessweek.com/news/2010-07-30/citibank-pays-75-million-to-resolvesubprime-disclosure-probe.html
White, Brenda B. 2006. “A Short History of Subprime.” Mortgage Banking, March.

30