View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

TESTIMONY TO
THE FINANCIAL CRISIS INQUIRY COMMISSION

HEARING ON

THE ROLE OF DERIVATIVES IN THE FINANCIAL CRISIS

BY ERIC DINALLO
FORMER SUPERINTENDENT
NEW YORK STATE INSURANCE DEPARTMENT

THURSDAY, JULY 1, 2010
DIRKSEN SENATE OFFICE BUILDING ROOM 538

-1-

I would like to thank Chairman Phil Angelides and the members of the Financial Crisis
Inquiry Commission for inviting me to testify today at this hearing on American
International Group, known as AIG.
My name is Eric Dinallo and I was the Insurance Superintendent for New York State
from January 2007 through July 2009, including the period when the crisis developed at
AIG.
I very much appreciate the Commission holding this hearing so that we can discuss what
happened at AIG and what lessons we can learn to improve financial services regulation
and avoid similar crises in the future.
Before I go into detail, I would like to make a few broad points that I think are essential
for understanding what happened at AIG and what lessons we can learn. Please note that
when I speak of AIG, I am referring to the parent company, which is an international
financial services company not regulated by the state insurance departments. I am only
discussing AIG’s insurance companies when I state that explicitly. Also, when I use the
words “we” or “us” or “our” I am referring to the New York State Insurance Department
during the time period when I served as Superintendent.
First, the crisis for AIG did not come from its state regulated insurance companies. The
primary source of the problem was AIG Financial Products, which had written credit
default swaps, derivatives and futures with a notional amount of about $2.7 trillion,
including about $440 billion of credit default swaps. Collateral calls by global banks,
broker dealers and hedge funds that are counterparties to credit default swaps were the
main source of AIG’s problems.
The main reason why the federal government decided to rescue AIG was not because of
its insurance companies. Rather, it was because of the systemic risk created by Financial
Products. There was systemic risk because of Financial Products’ relationships and
transactions with many major commercial and investment banks, not only in the U.S., but
around the world.
Second, and perhaps most important, it is essential to understand why AIG Financial
Products was able to make such huge bets with its credit default swaps with essentially
nothing backing up its promise to pay if the bet went against it. In general, AIG took
advantage of the general tide of deregulation, but there are three specific parts of
deregulation that working together created a perfect storm of financial disaster: 1.
allowing financial institutions to select their own regulator, 2. allowing financial
conglomerates by doing away with the divisions required by the Glass Steagall Act, and,
3. deregulation specifically of credit default swaps.
By purchasing a small savings and loan in 1999, AIG was able to select as its primary
regulator the Office of Thrift Supervision, the federal agency that is charged with
overseeing savings and loan banks and thrift associations. Clearly, OTS’s expertise was
in savings and loans, not complicated international financial institutions conducting a

-2-

huge derivative business. The net effect was that AIG Financial Products was not
effectively regulated, as OTS has admitted in testimony to Congress.
Glass Steagall wisely separated financial services businesses that provided guarantees,
such as insurance policies or bank deposits, from businesses that took on risk, such as
investment banking. But the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act permitted AIG to operate an
effectively unregulated hedge fund with grossly insufficient reserves to back up its
promises. Had AIG Financial Products been a stand alone company, it is unlikely that its
counterparties would have been willing to do business with it because its commitments
would never have carried a triple-A credit rating.
Finally, the Commodities Futures Modernization Act of 2000 specifically exempted
credit default swaps from regulation.
In sum, the combination meant that AIG could operate an ineffectively unregulated hedge
fund selling billions in unregulated securities making billions in promises with no
reserves to back up those promises. Clearly that was a recipe for disaster.
As Federal Reserve Chairman Bernanke said, “AIG had a financial products division
which was very lightly regulated and was a source of a great deal of systemic trouble.”
Chairman Bernanke accurately called the Financial Products unit “a hedge fund basically
that was attached to a large and stable insurance company, made huge numbers of
irresponsible bets, took huge losses.”
When those decisions to deregulate were made, the arguments were that financial
innovation was essential and if the U.S. did not allow activities here, the market and the
profits would go elsewhere. Sadly, it is not clear that not all financial innovation is
positive, not all reduces risk, and not all promotes economic growth. A major
international competitive advantage is the U.S.’s stable, secure and transparent financial
system. If we allow that to be damaged or destroyed, the cost for all Americans will be
steep.
Third, just as AIG was overly aggressive in seeking profits from credit default swaps in
its Financial Products unit, it was also overly aggressive in its securities lending program,
which was operated centrally by the parent company for its insurance companies. Many
insurance companies and other financial institutions use securities lending, but none had
the severe problems that AIG had.
State regulators identified the problems in the securities lending program well before the
crisis and were working with the company to unwind it in an orderly fashion. It was the
crisis caused by collateral calls on the credit default swaps at Financial Products that
made a continuation of an orderly reduction impossible. While there is no question that
the insurance subsidiaries would have had losses from the program, the losses were
manageable and would not have made the insurance subsidiaries as a group insolvent.

-3-

Fourth, the federal rescue of AIG was possible because there were strong operating
insurance companies that would enable the federal government and taxpayers to be paid
back. The reason why those insurance companies were strong is because state regulation
walled them off from non-related activities in the holding company and at Financial
Products.
In most industries, the parent company can reach down and use the assets of its
subsidiaries. With insurance, that is greatly restricted. State regulation requires that
insurance companies maintain healthy reserves for policyholders’ claims backed by
investments that cannot be used for any other purpose. That is why policyholders were
and continued to be protected.

Now, let me provide some background. Before the crisis, AIG was a huge, global
financial services holding company that did business in 130 countries. At that time, AIG
had 71 U.S.-based insurance companies. In addition to those US based insurance entities,
AIG had 176 other financial services companies, including non-U.S. insurers.
State insurance departments have the power and authority to act as the primary regulator
for the insurance companies domiciled in their state. So the New York Department is
primary regulator for only those AIG insurance companies domiciled in New York. At
the time of the crisis, the New York Insurance Department was the primary regulator for
10 of AIG’s 71 U.S. insurance companies: American Home Assurance Company,
American International Insurance Company, AIU Insurance Company, AIG National
Insurance Company, Commerce and Industry Insurance Company, Transatlantic
Reinsurance Company, American International Life Assurance Company of New York,
First SunAmerica Life Insurance Company, United States Life Insurance Company in the
City of New York, and Putnam Reinsurance Company. AIG’s New York life insurance
companies are relatively small. The New York property insurance companies are much
larger. Other states act as primary regulator for the other U.S. insurance companies.
State insurance regulators are not perfect. But one thing they do very well is focus on
solvency, on the financial strength of insurance companies. State regulators require
insurers to hold conservative reserves to ensure that they can pay policyholders. That is
why insurance companies have performed relatively well in this storm. One clear lesson
of the current crisis is the importance of having plenty of capital and not having too much
leverage.
As noted, by purchasing a savings and loan in 1999, AIG was able to select as its primary
regulator the federal Office of Thrift Supervision, the federal agency that is charged with
overseeing savings and loan banks and thrift associations. The Office of Thrift
Supervision is AIG's consolidated supervisor for purposes of Gramm-Leach-Bliley. In
testimony to the U.S. Senate, OTS has stated that it was responsible for regulating the
AIG holding company and its Financial Products unit.

-4-

When companies are permitted to pick their regulator, the opportunity for regulatory
arbitrage is created. The whole purpose of financial services regulation is to appropriately
control risk. But regulatory arbitrage increases risk because it creates the opportunity for
a financial institution to select its regulator based on who might be more lenient, who
might have less strict rules, who might demand less capital.
This is not a theoretical contention. I refer the Commission to a January 22, 2009 article
in the Washington Post titled “By Switching Their Charters, Banks Skirt Supervision.”
The article reports that since 2000 at least 30 banks switched from federal to state
supervision to escape regulatory action. The actual number is likely higher because the
newspaper was only able to count public regulatory actions. The reporters could not
discover banks that acted to pre-empt action when they saw it coming. In total, 240 banks
converted from federal to state charters, while 90 converted from state to federal charters.
The newspaper was unable to discover if any of those formerly state banks were avoiding
state action.
One of the most important aspects of regulating financial services institutions is setting of
appropriate capital and reserve requirements. You asked what the reserve requirements
were for AIG Financial Products and for the monoline or financial guaranty insurance
companies that we regulate. I cannot tell you what the reserve requirements, if any, were
for Financial Products, as New York did not regulate that entity.
New York Insurance Law imposes explicit capital requirements on monolines;
specifically, monolines are required to maintain a minimum surplus to policyholders of
$65 million. But the $65 million is an absolute minimum. The financial guaranty law
also requires that monolines establish and maintain contingency reserves equal to the
greater of (i) fifty percent of the premiums written for each calendar year for each
category of business or (ii) a percentage of principal guaranteed. The mandatory
percentage depends upon the relative safety of the insured obligation and ranges from
0.55 percent for municipal obligations to 2.5 percent for non-investment grade
obligations. The law also requires the establishment of loss reserves in the event of
adverse development (i.e., reported claims) which must be calculated in the manner
applicable to authorized property/casualty insurers.
You also asked if AIG’s capital and capital requirements were sufficient from 2005 to
2008. The New York Department is not in a position to comment on any capital
requirements for AIG holding company or Financial Products. I can assure you that the
capital of the AIG group's licensed U.S. insurers was certainly sufficient to ensure the
orderly operation of the AIG insurance companies. What’s more, it is clear that AIG
holding company’s top triple-A credit rating was based on the strength of its insurance
companies. But since the assets of the insurance companies cannot be used for the
obligations of the holding company, AIG Financial Product’s counterparties were
mistaken if they thought AIG’s strength protected them. The use of insurance company
funds to support the operations of Financial Products would have been improper and
disallowed under the Insurance Law. Had AIG FP been given a credit rating based on its

-5-

own resources it is unlikely that it would have been perceived as strong enough to keep
the promises it was making.
This is one of the important lessons of the financial crisis: the problem of illusory credit
ratings. Let me be clear what I mean by illusory. Unlike the credit ratings for securities
based on subprime mortgages, there was a solid basis for the top triple-A credit rating for
AIG’s parent company. But as noted, that was based on the strength of its core insurance
companies and the assets of those companies could only be used to support the insurance
operations.
AIG was probably not the only company to take its strong credit rating from its core
business and use that presumed financial strength to go into another line of business
where that strong credit rating was meaningless because the assets of its core business
were protected by regulation. Thus, AIG used its perceived strength to have its Financial
Products unit sell credit default swaps, though it was an illusion that the holding
company’s strength could be applied to the promises Financial Products was making. I
would call that AIG monetizing its top credit rating—using it to make huge profits—for
awhile, anyhow.

The primary source of the AIG’s problem was AIG Financial Products, which had written
credit default swaps, derivatives and futures with a notional amount of about $2.7 trillion,
including about $440 billion of credit default swaps. For context, that is equal to the gross
national product of France. Losses on certain credit default swaps and collateral calls by
global banks, broker dealers and hedge funds that are counterparties to these credit
default swaps are the main source of AIG’s problems.
In September 2008, the credit rating agencies told AIG that it was about to be
downgraded. A downgrade would result in AIG Financial Products and AIG facing tens
of billions of dollars of demands for cash collateral on the credit default swaps written by
Financial Products and guaranteed by the holding company.
It is worth noting what AIG was doing with those credit default swaps. The focus has
been on swaps guaranteeing bonds backed by subprime residential mortgages. There
were plenty of those. But AIG was also selling credit default swaps to help banks avoid
their own regulatory requirements for reserves in two ways. First, thanks to AIG credit
default swaps, the banks could pretend the bonds they held backed by subprime
mortgages were risk free and not hold adequate reserves against them. Second, the banks
also used swaps directly to avoid regulations regarding their own reserve requirements.
I would like to quote from a March 6, 2009 story in the Financial Times by Henny Sender
titled “AIG saga shows dangers of credit default swaps”:
In retrospect, a glance at AIG’s second quarter 2008 financial statement makes for
an interesting read. Buried in that report is a cautionary tale showing just how
dangerous credit derivatives can be when combined with insufficient risk

-6-

management and regulatory oversight – or both sides of these transactions.
Unfortunately, few people read the report when it would have been relevant.
The report fully discloses the $446bn in credit insurance AIG sold. The swaps
were written out of AIG Financial Products, a non-bank hidden at the heart of the
insurance giant. But because AIG wasn’t regulated as a bank, it wasn’t saddled
with any requirements to hold capital against these massive potential liabilities.
A large part of those credit default swaps, about $307bn worth, was bought by
European banks in endearingly named “regulatory capital forbearance” trades. By
buying such insurance, these banks didn’t have to hold capital against their longterm holdings of securities. Another large chunk went to Wall Street firms to
hedge their holdings of complicated securities backed by subprime mortgages.
By the end of the year, just this part of this massive book of credit default swaps
would cause almost $30bn in losses and trigger what is likely to prove one of the
most costly bail-outs ever. Meanwhile, the $307bn “forbearance” book produced
a mere $156m in revenue for the first half of last year. These exposures probably
represent one of the most skewed risk-reward equations of all time.
AIG did such a booming business selling credit protection because it offered to
post generous collateral if the value of the insured securities dropped or if its own
credit rating fell. (Other providers, such as the monoline insurers, balked at such
terms.) That collateral was meant to give AIG’s clients assurance that they were
safely hedged. In fact, that sense of safety was always an illusion. Clients hadn’t
reduced their risk; they had increased it.
To quote Chairman Bernanke again, Financial Products “took all these large bets where
they were effectively, quote, ‘insuring’ the credit positions of many, many banks and
other financial institutions.”
In sum, an essentially unregulated institution, AIG Financial Products, sold unregulated
securities, credit default swaps, which were used to help regulated banks evade regulation
and hold less capital in reserve than necessary.
That leads us to a discussion of credit default swaps. Let me first establish why the
insurance regulator for New York is a relevant authority on credit default swaps. I will
expand on these issues at greater length, but to provide a context, I will start with a brief
summary.
As credit default swaps were developed, there was a question about whether or not they
were insurance. Since initially they were used by owners of bonds to seek protection or
insurance in the case of a default by the issuer of the bonds, this was a reasonable
question. In 2000, under a prior administration, the New York Insurance Department was
asked to determine if certain swaps were insurance and said no. That is a decision we
have since revisited and reversed as incomplete. I will provide more detail on these
important decisions shortly.

-7-

After I took office in January 2007, the impact of credit default swaps was one of the
major issues we had to confront. First, we tackled the problems of the financial guaranty
companies, also known as bond insurers or monolines. Credit default swaps were a major
factor in their problems. Afterwards, we were involved in the rescue of AIG. Again,
credit default swaps were the biggest source of that company’s problems. Through these
experiences, we have needed to carefully study the history and issues surrounding credit
default swaps. And we have learned the hard way their impact on markets and
companies.
Let’s discuss what a credit default swap is and the different kinds of credit default swaps.
A credit default swap is a contract under which the seller, for a fee, agrees to make a
payment to the protection buyer in the event that the referenced security, usually some
kind of bond, experiences any number of various “credit events”, such as bankruptcy,
default, or reorganization. If something goes wrong with the referenced entity, the
protection buyer can put the bond to the protection seller and be made whole, or a net
payment can be made by the seller to the buyer.
Originally, credit default swaps were used to transfer and thus reduce risk for the owners
of bonds. If you owned a bond in company X and were concerned that the company
might default, you bought the swap to protect yourself. The swaps could also be used by
banks who loaned money to a company. This type of swap is still used for hedging
purposes.
Over time, however, swaps came to be used not to reduce risk, but to assume it.
Institutions that did not own the obligation bought and sold credit default swaps to place
what Wall Street calls “a directional bet” on a company’s creditworthiness.
In May 2008, I began to refer to swaps bought by speculators as “naked” credit default
swaps both to draw the analogy to naked shorting in stocks, which ironically are
regulated, and to make clear that the swap purchasers do not own the underlying
obligation. The protection becomes more valuable as the company becomes less
creditworthy. I have argued that these naked credit default swaps should not be called
swaps because there is no transfer or swap of risk. Instead, risk is created by the
transaction. For example, you have no risk on the outcome of the third race until you
place a bet on horse number five to win.
I believe that the first type of swap, let’s call it the covered swap, is insurance. The
essence of an insurance contract is that the buyer has to have a material interest in the
asset or obligation that is the subject of the contract. That means the buyer owns property
or a security and can suffer a loss from damage to or the loss of value of that property.
With insurance, the buyer only has a claim after actually suffering a loss. With the
covered swaps, if the issuer of a bond defaults, then the owner of the bond has suffered a
loss and the swap provides some recovery for that loss. The second type of swap—naked
swaps—contains none of these features.

-8-

One problem is that with swaps, defining covered and naked can be much more
complicated. For example, company A that does business with company B may seek to
protect itself from not being paid by company B by buying a credit default swap on
company B’s debt. Clearly here the buyer has a material interest, but not directly in the
bond. Or the buyer of a credit default swap may own the underlying bond when it buys
the swap, but then sell the bond but keep the swap.
At the time of the crisis at AIG, because the credit default swap market was not regulated,
there was no valid data on the number of swaps outstanding and how many were naked.
At that time, estimates of the market were as high as $62 trillion. By comparison, at that
time there was only about $6 trillion in corporate debt outstanding, $7.5 trillion in
mortgage-backed debt and $2.5 trillion in asset-backed debt. That’s a total of about $16
trillion in debt private sector debt.
Now, I think it would be useful to go into some of the old, but highly relevant history.
Betting or speculating on movements in securities or commodities prices without actually
owning the referenced security or commodity is nothing new. As early as 1829, “stock
jobbing”, an early version of short selling, was outlawed in New York. The Stock
Jobbing Act was ultimately repealed in 1858 because it was overly broad and captured
legitimate forms of speculation. However, the issue of whether to allow bets on security
and commodity prices outside of organized exchanges continued to be an issue.
“Bucket shops” arose in the late nineteenth century. Customers “bought” securities or
commodities on these unauthorized exchanges, but in reality the bucket shop was simply
booking the customer’s order without executing on an exchange. In fact, they were
simply throwing the trade ticket in a bucket, which is where the name comes from, and
tearing it up when an opposite trade came in. The bucket shop would agree to take the
other side of the customer’s “bet” on the performance of the security or commodity.
Bucket shops sometimes survived for a time by balancing their books, but were wiped
out by extreme bull or bear markets. When their books failed, the bucketeers simply
closed up shop and left town, leaving the “investors” holding worthless tickets. The Bank
Panic of 1907 is famous for J.P. Morgan, the leading banker of the time, calling other
bankers to a meeting and keeping them there until they agreed to form a consortium of
bankers to create an emergency backstop for the banking system. At the time there was
no Federal Reserve. But a more lasting result was passage of New York’s anti-bucket
shop law in 1909. The law, General Business Law Section 351, made it a felony to
operate or be connected with a bucket shop or “fake exchange.” Because of the
specificity and severity of the much-anticipated legislation virtually all bucket shops shut
down before the law came into effect, and little enforcement was necessary. Other states
passed similar laws.
Section 351 prohibits the making or offering of a purchase or sale of security,
commodity, debt, property, options, bonds, etc. without intending a bona fide purchase or
sale of the security, commodity, debt, property, options, bonds, etc. If you think that

-9-

sounds exactly like a naked credit default swap, you are correct. What this tells us is that
back in 1909, 100 years ago, people understood the risks and potential instability that
comes from betting on securities prices and outlawed it.
With the growth of various kinds of derivatives in the late 20th Century, there was legal
uncertainty as to whether certain derivatives, including credit default swaps, violated
state bucket shop and gambling laws.
The Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000 (“CFMA”), signed by President
Clinton on December 21, 2000, created a “safe harbor” by (1) preempting state and local
gaming and bucket shop laws except for general antifraud provisions, and (2) exempting
certain derivative transaction on commodities and swap agreements, including credit
default swaps, from CFTC regulation.
CFMA also amended the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities and Exchange Act of
1934 to make it clear that the definition of “security” does not include certain swap
agreements, including credit default swaps, and that the SEC is prohibited from
regulating those swap agreements, except for its anti-fraud enforcement authority.
So by ruling that credit default swaps were not subject to state laws or SEC regulation,
the way was cleared for the growth of the market. But there was one other issue. If the
swaps were considered insurance, then they would be regulated by state insurance
departments. The capital and underwriting limits in insurance regulation would threaten
the rapid growth in the market for these derivatives.
So at the same time, in 2000, the New York Insurance Department was asked a very
carefully crafted question. “Does a credit default swap transaction, wherein the seller will
make payment to the buyer upon the happening of a negative credit event and such
payment is not dependent upon the buyer having suffered a loss, constitute a contract of
insurance under the insurance law?”
Clearly, the question was framed to ask only about naked credit default swaps. Under the
facts as presented, the swap was not insurance, because the buyer had no material interest
and the filing of claim does not require a loss. But the entities involved were careful not
to ask about covered credit default swaps. Nonetheless, the market took the Department’s
opinion on a subset of credit default swaps as a ruling on all swaps.
In sum, in 2000 as a society we chose not to regulate credit default swaps. And the
leadership of the New York Insurance Department at that time chose to be part of that
choice.
It bears repeating. The fear in 2000 was that if the U.S. or New York regulated credit
default swaps and required holding sufficient capital, the market would go where
unregulated sellers could make more money. We forgot that the biggest competitive
advantage of the U.S. financial system has always been that we offer safety, security and

- 10 -

transparency. If we destroy that perception, the long-term cost to our society is
incalculable.
Why did that matter? As we have seen, the financial system has been placed in peril
because there was no comprehensive management of counterparty risk. Deals were made
privately between two parties. These bilateral arrangements mean that there are no
standards for the solvency of counterparties. The buyer does not know how much risk the
seller is taking on. And there are no requirements for the seller to hold reserves or capital
against the risks it is taking on by selling swaps.
None of this was a problem as long as the value of everything was going up and defaults
were rare. But the problem with this sort of unregulated protection scheme is that when
everyone needs to be paid at once, the market is not strong enough to provide the
protection everyone suddenly needs.
Unlike insurance, credit default swaps are marked to market. That means, the value of the
swap reflects the current market value, which can swing sharply and suddenly. Value
changes require the sellers to post collateral. Sudden and sharp changes in the credit
rating of the issuer of the bonds or of the bonds themselves can produce large swings in
the value of the swaps and thus the need to post large and increasing amounts of
collateral. That capital strain can produce sudden liquidity problems for sellers. The seller
may own enough assets to provide collateral, but the assets may not be liquid and thus
not immediately accessible. When many sellers are forced to sell assets, the price of those
assets falls and sellers are faced with taking large losses just to meet collateral
requirements. As the prices of the assets are driven down by forced sales, mark-to-market
losses increase and the collateral posting cycle continues. Meanwhile, the underlying
assets may continue to perform; paying interest and principal in full.
The above is a substantial part of the problem at AIG. A ratings downgrade on September
15 produced immediate collateral calls. The company did not have sufficient liquid assets
at Financial Products or at the holding company to satisfy these calls.
You asked about New York’s ability to regulate credit default swaps. While the CFMA
preempted state gambling laws, it did not preempt state insurance law. Apparently it was
felt that New York’s letter made that unnecessary.
But given the temper of the deregulatory times, it is fair to assume that if New York had
tried to unilaterally regulate credit default swaps in 2000, it would have been overruled
one way or another. In fact, at the time, the New York Department was part of the
decision to deregulate credit default swaps.
However, when we understood the impact of credit default swaps, New York chose to
act. In May 2008, I publicly warned of the scale of the problem and explained that some
credit default swaps were clearly insurance. Thereafter, I published opinion articles
making this case. On September 22, 2008, we announced that New York State would,
beginning in January 2009 regulate the insurance, or covered, part of the credit default

- 11 -

swap market which had been unregulated—the part which the Insurance Department has
jurisdiction to regulate.
That announcement played an important role in spurring national discussion about a
comprehensive regulatory structure for the CDS market. The result has been exactly what
was envisioned—a broad debate and discussion about the best way to bring controls and
oversight to this huge and important market and concrete progress toward a centralized
risk management, trading and clearing system. After our announcement, then-SEC
Chairman Cox asked for the power to regulate the credit default swap market. The New
York Federal Reserve began a series of meetings with the dealer community to discuss
how to proceed.
The proposals included establishing an exchange, a central counterparty or a
clearinghouse for credit default swaps. On November 14, 2008, the New York Federal
Reserve, the Securities and Exchange Commission and the Commodities Futures Trading
Commission entered into a MOU to facilitate information sharing and data across a
number of areas, including CDS.
At the request of federal regulators and recognizing the federal agency efforts and
anticipated legislative action by Congress, the Department publicly announced that it
would delay its intention to begin regulating part of the CDS market effective January 1,
2009.
Though I am no longer at the New York Insurance Department, staff there has provided
me with the following information so that I can bring you up to date on New York’s
actions on this subject.
Governor David Paterson has put forward Program Bill #50. The bill does not expressly
provide a regulatory regime for credit default swaps. Rather, the bill removes all mention
of CDS from Article 69 of the Insurance Law (the "financial guaranty statute"). These
references were added by the 2004 revision of the financial guaranty law, which
sanctioned by statute practices that had previously been permitted by the Department
administratively. The removal of the statutory references to CDS is intended to eliminate
any implication that some or all CDS are somehow exempt from regulation as insurance.
Rather, the Department will view a CDS as insurance if by its terms it meets the
definition of "insurance contract" as set forth in N.Y. Insurance Law § 1101(a)(1).
The Department is aware that this position represents a radical departure from the current
treatment of CDS, and that this could disrupt the operation of the credit markets. Mindful
of this, Program Bill #50 also contains a provision that would allow the Superintendent to
exempt CDS from the requirements of the Insurance Law under certain circumstances.
This discretion would be exercised if an effective regulatory regime (presumably federal)
were instituted to govern the CDS market.
The Department supports a holistic solution to regulating this market in its entirety. That
can only be created by the federal government. Any effective solution should include

- 12 -

mechanisms to bring much needed transparency to this market as well as centralized data,
capital requirements to ensure that there is sufficient capital and liquidity, and a security
or guarantee fund to manage counterparty default.
There are appropriate uses for credit default swaps. Some amount of speculation can
provide useful information and market liquidity. The best route to a healthy market in
credit default swaps is not to divide it up among regulators. It would not be effective or
efficient for New York to regulate some transactions under the insurance law, while other
transactions are either not regulated or regulated under some other law and by some other
agency. The best outcome is a holistic solution for the entire credit default swap market.
Again, that has to come from the federal government.
The unregulated marketplace in credit derivatives was a central cause of a near systemic
collapse of our financial system. Credit default swaps played a major role in the financial
problems at AIG, Bear Stearns, Lehman and the bond insurance companies. A major
cause of our current financial crisis is not the effectiveness of current regulation, but what
we chose not to regulate. This lack of regulation has been devastating for thousands of
New Yorkers and every taxpayer in the United States. We must see that this does not
happen again.
Credit default swaps must be regulated and sellers must be required to hold sufficient
capital. That will make them more expensive, but it will mean the guarantee has real
value.
Does requiring adequate capital mean the end of financial innovation? Of course not, it
just means that most institutions will operate with less leverage. Risk and reward are
integral to capitalism. But innovators should risk their own capital, not the entire
financial fabric. Setting that balance is where effective regulation comes in.

We have looked at the history of credit default swaps. It is also worth noting the history
that allowed AIG to set up a unit, Financial Products, which could conduct this business.
By 1933, those who lived through the 1907 credit crisis and the 1929 stock market crash
had recognized two things: there were certain sacred financial services products, such as
bank deposits and insurance policies, that had to be protected at all costs, and those
products should never be exposed to the possible excesses of leveraged investment
banking. The wall between those businesses was institutionalized in the form of the
Glass-Steagall Act of 1933, which kept commercial banks, insurance companies and
investment banks out of each others’ lines of business. Underlying the inherent wisdom
of Franklin Roosevelt and his advisers was the fundamental principle that guaranteed
consumer deposits – whether bank deposits or insurance premiums – must be kept
separate from high-risk investment vehicles such as investment banks and their modern
equivalents, hedge funds and private equity. The goal was to encourage the benefit to the
economy of risk-taking by some financial institutions, without creating the risk of runs on
commercial banks or insurance companies by keeping those activities behind solid walls.

- 13 -

Those walls were removed in 1999 by the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act. The theory was that
large financial institutions able to do commercial and investment banking and insurance
would diversify risk and thus be stronger and less risky.
How has that turned out? Consider AIG, an excellent insurance company, which became
a financial-services conglomerate. AIG’s Financial Products unit was able to sell
hundreds of billions of dollars of credit default swaps and run up $2.7 trillion in notional
exposure because ratings agencies and counterparties wrongly assumed that AIG’s tripleA rating and $1 trillion balance sheet stood behind it. In fact, AIG’s insurance company
reserves were still protected by the moat of state insurance regulation and not available to
bail out Financial Products’ bad bets.
The point is that standing alone – as Glass-Steagall would have required – AIG Financial
Products, looking like a recklessly-run hedge fund, could not have taken on all that risk.
Only being part of a financial conglomerate made that possible. Even though AIG’s
healthy insurance companies and their reserves were protected, those companies took a
substantial hit from the reputational damage. The outcome was the worst of both worlds.
AIG Financial Products did not diversify risk but, instead, concentrated and correlated
risk. So we discovered that an under-capitalized and under-regulated unit of a huge
financial services conglomerate could risk not only that entire enterprise but the many
banks with which it did business, also. It was those risks of a broad market impact that
made the government rescue of AIG necessary.
To prevent cascading damage to the economy, the government not only requires
commercial banks and insurance companies to hold sufficient reserves to deliver on their
guarantees. It also implicitly guarantees it will act to stop runs on commercial banks
through the Federal Deposit Insurance Corp and on insurance companies through state
resolution bureaus and guarantee funds. Through the financial supermarkets, the
government’s implicit and necessary guarantee to act to stop runs was effectively
extended to risk-taking activities with insufficient reserves. Thus the risk-taking activities
could both use high leverage to boost profits and also benefit – without paying the cost –
from the protections of the guaranteed section of the company. If that is not moral hazard,
what is?
Thanks to Gramm-Leach-Bliley financial supermarkets were allowed to grow “too big
and too interconnected” to fail, putting policyholder and bank depositor money at direct
or indirect risk. Instead of reducing risk, the new law created a new, systemic risk that
could bring down an entire institution or the entire marketplace – and leave governments
no choice but to intervene.

You also asked about the AIG securities lending program. It is important to understand
that securities lending did not cause the crisis at AIG. AIG Financial Products did. If
there had been no Financial Products unit and only the securities lending program as it
was, we would not be here today. There would have been no federal rescue of AIG.

- 14 -

Financial Products’ trillions of dollars of transactions created systemic risk. Securities
lending did not.
If not for the crisis caused by Financial Products, AIG would be just like other insurance
companies, dealing with the stresses caused by the current financial crisis, but because of
its size and strength, most likely weathering them well.
Securities lending is an activity that has been going on for decades without serious
problems. Many, if not most, large financial institutions, including commercial banks,
investment banks and pension funds, participate in securities lending.
Securities lending involves financial institution A lending a stock or bond it owns to
financial institution B. In return, B gives A cash collateral worth generally about 102
percent of the value of the security it is borrowing. A then invests the cash. A still owns
the security and will benefit from any growth in its value. And A invests the cash
collateral to gain a small additional amount.
If B decides it wants to return the security it borrowed from A. A is then required to sell
its investment to obtain the cash it owes B. Generally, in a big securities lending program,
A will have either some assets it can easily sell or sufficient cash to handle normal
returns. But if there is a run, if many of the borrowers return the securities and demand
cash, A may not be able to quickly sell enough assets to obtain the cash it needs or may
have to sell assets at a loss before they mature.
As early as July 2006, the New York Department and other state regulators were engaged
in discussions about the securities lending program with AIG. Those discussions at first
related to the issue of risk-based capital and how the companies were reporting their
securities lending program on their financial statements.
It was in the course of those discussions that we learned about the details of AIG’s
securities lending program.
AIG securities lending was consolidated by the holding company in a special unit it set
up and controlled. This special unit was not a licensed insurance company. In theory,
having the parent company operate securities lending centrally was not inappropriate.
The insurance companies could have benefited from reduced operational costs, increased
expertise and reduced risk from sharing any losses. That, of course, assumes a securities
lending program that is run prudently. However, as with some other holding company
activities, this unit pursued its securities lending program aggressively rather than
prudently.
AIG maintained two securities lending pools, one for U.S. companies and one for nonU.S. companies. At its height, the U.S. pool contained an outstanding balance of $76
billion. The majority of the U.S. security lending program was concentrated with 12 life
insurers, three of which were from New York. Those three New York companies
contributed about 8% of the total assets in the U.S. securities lending pool.

- 15 -

The program historically maintained sufficient liquidity to meet cash demands and the
remaining funds were invested almost exclusively in the highest-rated securities. Even
the few securities that were not rated at the top level of triple A, were either double A or
single A. Today, with the perfect clarity of hindsight, we all know that those ratings were
not aligned with the market value of many mortgage-backed securities, which made up
60 percent of the invested collateral pool.
In addition, there was a mismatch in maturity between the mortgage-backed securities
and the short-term lending. As state regulators monitored the program, we became
increasingly concerned about the market value and liquidity of the mortgage-backed
securities and about the maturity mismatch. AIG officials did not agree with our concerns
and continued to defend the choice of investments, even as they were winding down the
program.
In 2007, because of those concerns and as the problems in the subprime mortgage market
began to affect the price of the securities, state regulators began working with the
company to start winding down the program. Unfortunately, the securities lending
program could not be ended quickly because, beginning in 2007, some of the residential
mortgage securities could not be sold for their full value. At that time there were still few
if any defaults, the securities were still paying off. But selling them would have involved
taking a loss.
Still, we insisted that the program be wound down and that the holding company provide
a guarantee to the life companies to make up for any losses that were incurred during the
process. In fact, the holding company provided a guarantee of first $500 million, then $1
billion and finally $5 billion.
Neither the NYSID nor any other state regulator issued a written directive to AIG to wind
down the securities lending business. The lack of a directive is not unusual. First,
regulators are usually able to ask for and obtain even substantial changes in insurers’
behavior without having to make a formal, written demand. Insurers recognize that state
regulators have substantial power and usually prefer to cooperate. Second, a written
request that would be disclosable to the public asking a company to sell a large quantity
of securities would alert others to the insurer’s plans thus making sales more difficult and
expensive. Also, in the case of securities lending, raising written (and thus public)
questions about the program could cause counterparties to contractually end the loans
(versus continuing to roll over the loans) and cause forced sales and losses. The state
regulators were successfully working with AIG to expeditiously reduce the size of the
program in an orderly manner to reduce losses without the complications of a written
request.
In 2008, New York and other states began quarterly meetings with AIG to review the
securities lending program. Meanwhile, the program was being wound down in an
orderly manner to reduce losses. From its peak of about $76 billion it had declined by
$18 billion, or about 24 percent, to about $58 billion by September 12, 2008.

- 16 -

At that point, the crisis caused by Financial Products caused the equivalent of a run on
the AIG securities lending program. Borrowers that had usually rolled over their
positions from period to period began returning the borrowed securities and demanding
their cash collateral. From September 12 to September 30, borrowers demanded a return
of about $24 billion in cash.
There are two essential points about AIG and its securities lending program. First,
without the crisis caused by Financial Products, there is no reason to believe there would
have been a run on the securities lending program. We would have continued to work
with AIG to unwind its program and any losses would have been manageable.
Second, even if there had been a run on the securities lending program with no federal
rescue, our detailed analysis indicates that the AIG life insurance companies would have
been solvent. Certainly, there would have been losses, with some companies hurt more
than others. But we believe that there would have been sufficient assets in the companies
and in the parent to maintain the solvency of all the companies. Indeed, before September
12, 2008, the parent company contributed slightly more than $5 billion to the reduction of
the securities lending program.
But that is an academic analysis. Whatever the problems at securities lending, they would
not have caused the crisis that brought down AIG. And without Financial Products and
the systemic risk its transactions created, there would have been no reason for the federal
government to get involved. State regulators would have worked with the company to
deal with the problem and protect policyholders.

I would like to also review briefly what the New York Department has done generally
about securities lending in the insurance industry.
Based on what we were seeing at AIG, but before the crisis in September, the Department
warned all licensed New York companies that we expected them to prudently manage the
risks in securities lending programs. On July 21, 2008, New York issued Circular Letter
16 to all companies doing business in New York which expressed Department concerns
about security lending programs. We cautioned them about the risks, reminded them of
the requirements for additional disclosure and told them we would be carefully
examining their programs.
On September 22, 2008, the Department sent a Section 308 letter to all life insurance
companies licensed in New York requiring them to submit information relating to
security lending programs, financing arrangements, security impairment issues and other
liquidity issues. (Section 308 is the provision of the NYS Insurance Law that gives the
Department the authority to request additional information between periodic
examinations.) The New York Department staff then conducted a thorough investigation
of the securities’ lending programs at life insurance companies that were licensed in New
York. The results were reassuring. Almost all of the companies had modest sized

- 17 -

programs with highly conservative investments, even by today’s standards. Companies
with larger programs had ample liquidity to meet redemptions under stress. What became
clear was that AIG was in a uniquely troubling situation.
Through our chairmanship of the National Association of Insurance Commissioners
Statutory Accounting Practices Working Group, we also successfully worked to have the
NAIC adopt increased disclosure rules for securities lending programs.
You asked if AIG was able to take advantage of a regulatory gap by having its holding
company operate its securities lending program. I believe the answer is no. It is true that
the company was able to take inappropriate risks with the program. But there is no reason
to believe that it could not have directed all its insurance companies to take similar risks
if they were all operating their own programs.
The program was invested in triple-A rated securities, as required. State insurance
regulators, like almost everyone else at the time, thought those ratings meant something.
The key point is that while state regulators did allow AIG to be too aggressive, we came
to understand the problem through our normal regulatory activities and forced the
company to change. Regulation, like all human activities is a process of learning. The
state insurance departments have learned about the need to keep a much closer watch on
securities lending and have set clear standards. And it is worth noting that it was only
AIG that was using securities lending in such a risky manner. And, like everyone else, we
have learned a hard lesson about the value of credit ratings, an issue the NAIC is still
working to resolve.

Our involvement with AIG changed substantially on Friday, September 12, 2008. The
immediate spark for the crisis was the sudden decision by the credit rating agencies to
downgrade AIG without waiting to see the results of its restructuring only two weeks
away. The downgrade would require AIG to post additional collateral against its credit
default swaps and against its guaranteed investment contracts. AIG’s initial estimates
were that it would need about $18 billion in cash to post collateral. While AIG had assets,
including its insurance companies, worth many times this amount, the assets were not
liquid and could not be used to solve the collateral problem. Thus it appeared initially that
the company had a liquidity problem. That is, it was not short of capital, but it was short
of cash because it could not turn most of its assets into cash quickly enough.
The Department received a call from two AIG senior executives informing us of the
company’s serious and immediate liquidity problem, and asking for assistance. We had
conference calls with AIG leaders Saturday morning and then went over to their office
for the remainder of the weekend to provide assistance and be in a position to expedite
the consideration of any regulatory actions that might be needed to get through the crisis.
The Department worked with AIG to develop solutions, vet proposals and find
transactions that would stabilize AIG while protecting policyholders. As a result, we

- 18 -

developed a proposal that the Governor announced on Monday, September 15. This plan
would have allowed AIG to temporarily access about $20 billion of excess surplus assets
in its property/casualty insurance companies while fully protecting policyholders.
There are some key points that are important to understand. The proposal was just that, a
proposal that we agreed to consider. It was never finalized. Agreement was dependent on
conditions that would guarantee the protection of policyholders, including a substantial
investment from capital providers and a restructuring of the US operations that would
essentially make the life insurers subsidiaries of the property/casualty operations. Thus
the $20 billion liquidity provided would be one part of a total solution of the company’s
problems. At the point at which we were discussing this proposal, everyone thought that
AIG only had a temporary cash flow problem. When it became clear after a few days that
the problem was much bigger, our proposal was dropped and replaced by the government
rescue.
The basis of the proposal was that AIG had plenty of assets, but could not turn them into
cash quickly enough to meet the demands for collateral. Also, AIG’s property insurance
companies had excess surplus, that is, surplus above what was legally required to protect
policyholders. We were willing to consider allowing the parent company to temporarily
borrow more liquid assets such as municipal bonds from its property insurance
subsidiaries in exchange for less liquid assets, but only if the less liquid assets were worth
more than the municipal bonds.
We were very carefully vetting the assets being purchased by the property insurance
companies to ensure they were of high quality. We were also being careful to make sure
that the amount of securities remaining in the companies was sufficient to pay all claims,
meet statutory risk-based capital requirements and still have billions of dollars in extra
surplus.
When it became clear that the company needed more money and that the original plan
was not feasible, the Federal Reserve asked two banks to try to form a commercial bank
group to raise the necessary funds. Eventually, it became clear that no commercial private
sector rescue was possible. At that point, the Treasury and Federal Reserve proposed the
$85 billion bridge loan and our proposal was no longer needed.
Staff of the Department participated in meetings at AIG over the weekend of September
12 through 14 and then in the meetings at the Federal Reserve that eventually resulted in
the rescue. We were involved in meetings and informal discussions about different ideas
and provided expertise on insurance issues.
Following the rescue, New York’s involvement with the parent company has been
substantially reduced. Those issues have been handled by the Federal Reserve. However,
the New York Insurance Department co-chairs a 50-state task force created by the
National Association of Insurance Commissioners to monitor the financial condition of
the insurers, oversee and facilitate the sale of any insurance operations and coordinate
state regulatory responses. One of the main purposes of the task force is to protect

- 19 -

policyholders by ensuring that insurance operations are purchased by stable, responsible
entities capable of operating them successfully. And the Department will also ensure that
the regulatory approval process is efficient and does not hold up transactions.

To sum up, what happened at AIG demonstrates the strength and effectiveness of state
insurance regulation, not the opposite.
The only reason that the federal rescue of AIG is possible is because there are strong
operating insurance companies that provide the possibility that the federal government
and taxpayers will be paid back. And the reason why those insurance companies are
strong is because state regulation walled them off from non-related activities in the
holding company and at Financial Products.
In most industries, the parent company can reach down and use the assets of its
subsidiaries. With insurance, that is greatly restricted. State regulation requires that
insurance companies maintain healthy reserves backed by investments that cannot be
used for any other purpose. I’ve said that the insurance companies are the bars of gold in
the mess that AIG has become.
There are activities that the states need to improve, such as licensing and bringing new
products to market. But where they are strong has been in maintaining solvency.
I would note that at a time when financial services firms are in trouble because they do
not have adequate capital and are too highly leveraged, at a time when commercial banks
and investment banks have very serious problems, insurance companies remain relatively
strong. Clearly a lesson from this crisis is that all financial institutions should be required
to hold sufficient capital and reserves to meet their promises.
Now, I would be happy to answer your questions.

- 20 -