View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1

1015 15th Street, N.W. Sixth Floor Washington, D.C. 20005
202.974.2400 Main 202.974.2410 Fax
www.hudson.org

November 22, 2010
Mr. Gary J. Cohen
General Counsel
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission
1717 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Suite 800
Washington, DC 20006-4614
Dear Mr. Cohen:
Your letter of November 17 was forwarded to me by Sarah Knaus. Thank you for
informing me of the possibility that you may use portions of my interview with Mr.
Stanton and Mr. Borzekowski on March 11, 2010.
If you do quote material from the interview, I would appreciate the opportunity to review
the quotations. In advance of the interview, I provided Mr. Stanton with my testimony
before the U.S. Civil Rights Commission on March 20, 2009. Mr. Stanton and Mr.
Borzekowski asked various questions about the testimony, which I answered insofar as I
could recall the facts; most concerned the GSE affordable housing goals established by
HUD as of January 1, 2005 and the regulatory process by which the goals were
developed and promulgated.
My concern is being quoted incompletely and out of context, particularly on matters that
that came up during the discussion with Mr. Stanton and Mr. Borzekowski that I had not
discussed in my Civil Rights Commission testimony. In more recent work, I have
addressed some of these questions explicitly and in more detail.
In July I responded to the U.S. Treasury Department’s call for “Public Input on the
Reform of the Housing Finance System;” my submission updated my testimony to the
Civil Rights Commission, as well as discussing some of the questions raised by Mr.
Stanton and Mr. Borzekowski. I e-mailed the submission to Mr. Stanton a few days later.
For your convenience, I’m attaching that statement.
Coincidentally, I also presented a paper on GSE regulation last Wednesday at a
conference on “The Past, Present, and Future of the GSEs” at the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis. This paper includes further discussion of the affordable housing goals and
other issues that may be relevant to the Commission’s work. I’m attaching a copy of this
paper also in the event that you find it useful.

2
I think both of these papers contribute to an accurate historical record concerning the
affordable housing goals and the GSEs during the years leading up to the crisis.

Thank you again for your letter. I look forward to hearing from you if I can be helpful as
the Commission completes its work.

Sincerely,

John C. Weicher
Director, Center for Housing
and Financial Markets
Hudson Institute

3

The Affordable Housing Goals, Homeownership and Risk:
Some Lessons from Past Efforts to Regulate the GSEs

John C. Weicher
Director, Center for Housing and Financial Markets
Hudson Institute

Conference on
“The Past, Present, and Future of the Government-Sponsored Enterprises”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
November 17, 2010

4
Introduction

This paper draws on my experience as a GSE regulator to address issues
concerning the affordable housing goals and some related matters that are relevant to the
current policy discussions.
I have had a substantial role in GSE regulation on two occasions. As Assistant
Secretary for Policy Development and Research at the U.S. Department of Housing and
Urban Development during 1989-1993, I created and managed a staff to support
Secretary Jack Kemp in his responsibilities as the sole regulator of Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac between the passage of the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery and
Enforcement Act in 1989 and the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and
Soundness Act in 1992. Later, as Assistant Secretary for Housing at HUD during 20012005, I received the delegation of regulatory authority from Secretaries Mel Martinez and
Alphonso Jackson, to serve as “mission regulator,” including the affordable housing
goals, new program approval, and related matters. FHEFSSA had assigned a continuing
role in GSE regulation to the HUD Secretary. He or she retained responsibility for issues
other than safety and soundness. In 1993, Secretary Henry Cisneros delegated that
responsibility to the Assistant Secretary for Housing, and that delegation remained in
place until GSE regulation was consolidated within the new Federal Housing Finance
Agency, under the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008. As Assistant Secretary
for Housing during 2001-2005, I therefore was responsible for managing the GSE
regulatory process within HUD.
I was involved with GSE regulation when the affordable housing goals were
enacted, and when they were promulgated for the 2005-2008 period. In addition, I was
involved for all but five months of the period when the goals promulgated in 2000 were
in effect. The goals went into effect in January 2001 and remained in place through
December 2004; I became Assistant Secretary for Housing in June 2001 and held that
position through April 2005.

5
The Affordable Housing Goals
Among its regulatory responsibilities, HUD was required to formulate the
affordable housing goals for the GSEs, and to monitor their performance. These goals
were established and specified by FHEFSSA (Part 2, Subpart B). They were intended to
codify one of the public purposes of the GSEs, namely, “to provide ongoing assistance to
the secondary market for residential mortgages (including activities relating to mortgages
on housing for low- and moderate-income families involving a reasonable economic
return that may be less than the return earned on other activities).” (This statement of
purpose appears in Section 301(3) of both the Fannie Mae Charter Act and the Freddie
Mac Corporation Act.)
Within HUD, the process of formulating the affordable housing goals involved
four offices: the Office of General Counsel, the Office of Housing, the Office of Policy
Development and Research, and the Office of Fair Housing and Equal Opportunity. The
goals were established through formal rulemaking, following the procedures required
under the Administrative Procedures Act: a proposed rule, a comment period, a review of
comments by the Department, and a final rule. As with all rules, both the proposed rule
and the final rule were reviewed by the Office of Management and Budget, which also
circulated the rule to other interested federal agencies and coordinated their responses.
The rule was always painstakingly developed, with extensive supporting analyses
as required by both the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act
of 1992 (FHEFSSA) and the Administrative Procedures Act. The rule and analyses
issued in 2004 were more than half the length of War and Peace. The proposed rule and
analyses occupied 266 pages of the Federal Register; the final rule and analyses occupied
308 pages. Like other rules, the GSE affordable housing goals rule could be challenged
in court, and needed to be able to withstand a challenge.
In my experience, any proposed major rule has been modified in response to the
comments HUD receives. The affordable housing goals were no exception. The GSEs’
commented that the goal were set too high, because they overstated the investor share
(loans for rental properties) of the single-family mortgage market. HUD accepted this
criticism and in the final rule reduced each target by one percentage point in 2008, and
proportionately (either zero or one percentage point) for 2005-2007. 1
There are three statutory goals:
(1) The Low- and Moderate-Income Housing Goal: loans to borrowers with
incomes at or below the median income for the market area in which they live;
1

The final rule appears in the Federal Register for November 2, 2004. The discussion of the adjustment
for single-family rental loans appears on pp. 63595-63596. The goals were never set in fractions of a
percentage point; the 2005-2007 goals were rounded to the nearest percentage point when the goals for
2008 were reduced by one percent. The Special Affordable Goal and the Underserved Areas Goal were
each reduced by one percentage point for each year from 2005 to 2008; the Low- and Moderate-Income
Goal was reduced by one percentage point for 2008, and left unchanged for 2005 through 2007.

6
(2) The Special Affordable Goal: loans to very low-income borrowers (those
with incomes at or below 60 percent of the area median income), or to lowincome borrowers living in low-income areas (borrowers with incomes at or
below 80 percent of the area median income, living in census tracts in which
the median income of households is at or below 80 percent of the area median
income);
(3) The Underserved Areas Goal: loans to borrowers living in low-income census
tracts (tracts in which the median income of residents is at or below 90 percent
of the area median income) or high-minority tracts (tracts in which minorities
comprise at least 30 percent of residents, and the median income of residents
in the tract does not exceed 120 percent of the area median income).
The goals are commonly expressed in terms of the income of homebuyers or
homeowners, but they also cover rental housing. The Low- and Moderate-Income
Housing Goal, for example, includes loans to multifamily housing owners for rental units
that are affordable to households with incomes at or below the area median. Multifamily
rental housing located within underserved areas counted toward that goal, as well as
owner-occupied housing.
These are complicated definitions, because the concepts of “low-income,” etc.,
are defined in terms of the median income in a metropolitan area or nonmetropolitan
county, not in terms of national income categories, and because there are so many income
categories. For perspective, it might be helpful to keep in mind that the national “poverty
line” for a family of four (the usual reported figure) has generally been about 40 to 45
percent of the national median household income since 1993. All of the income levels
employed as criteria in FHEFSSA are well above the poverty line.
The first goal is based on the income of the borrower or the renter; the second is
based partly on income and partly on location; the third is based on location. A mortgage
can count toward more than one goal; in fact, any loan that meets the Special Affordable
Goal also automatically counts toward the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal. A
mortgage to a very low-income borrower living in an underserved area counts toward all
three.
The goals are defined in FHEFSSA (Sections 1332, 1333, and 1334,
respectively). HUD is empowered to establish numerical targets for each goal: the
percentage of each GSE’s mortgage purchases that should count toward a goal.
FHEFSSA set “transition targets” to apply for at least the first two years and then HUD
issued three sets of targets, by regulation, which became effective as of 1996, 2001, and
2005, respectively. The targets are shown in Table 1. They are expressed as shares of
the GSEs’ mortgage purchases, including both loans purchased for portfolio and loans
which serve as collateral for mortgage-backed securities issued by the GSEs.

7
________________________________________________________________________
Table 1
GSE Affordable Housing Goals, 1993-2008
(share of mortgage purchases by GSEs)

Years
Low- and
Moderate-Income
1993-1995
1996
1997-2000
2001-2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

30%
40%
42%
50%
52%
53%
55%
56%

Goals
Special Affordable

Underserved Areas*

NA
12%
14%
20%
22%
23%
25%
27%

30%
21%
24%
31%
37%
38%
38%
39%

NA – Not Applicable: goals were set in dollar amounts for each GSE rather than
percentages
* The Underserved Areas goal was determined on the basis of 1990 Census tract
geography from 1993-2004, and on the basis of 2000 Census tract geography from 20052008.
________________________________________________________________________
The numerical targets are determined on the basis of activity in that part of the
mortgage market which the GSEs serve – the “conventional conforming market.”
The conventional conforming market excludes:
(1)
(2)
(3)

Federally insured or guaranteed loans: FHA, VA, Rural Housing Service
“B&C” loans: approximately the bottom half of the subprime market
Loans above the conforming loan limit, which until HERA was enacted in
2008 was set as the 90th percentile of the distribution of loans in the
conventional market. For 2008, prior to HERA, the conforming loan limit
was $417,000.
The conventional conforming market includes:

(1)
(2)
(3)

Prime loans: loans rated “A”
“A-minus” and “Alt-A” loans: approximately the top half of the subprime
market
Mortgages on manufactured homes

8

The Goals in Relation to the Conventional Conforming Market
By statute, the targets are to be set with reference to the performance and effort of
the enterprises toward achieving the targets in previous years; the share of the
conventional conforming market that is comprised of loans in a goal category; and the
ability of the GSEs to lead the industry in making loans in a goal category.
The policy issue raised by these factors is whether the GSEs “lead the market” or
“lag the market.” This is shorthand for whether the loans in a given goal category are
included in GSE purchases to the same extent that they are originated within the
conventional conforming market. To give a numerical example, if loans to borrowers
with incomes below the local median represent 50 percent of all loans in the conventional
conforming market in a particular year, then the GSEs are “leading the market” if such
loans represent 51 percent or more of their purchases, and they are “lagging the market”
if such loans represent 49 percent or less of their purchases. (This simple illustration
ignores both the statistical significance and the practical importance of small differences.)
Under the targets established in FHEFSSA to become effective in 1993, and the targets
established by rulemaking as of 1996 and 2001, the GSEs were not asked to “lead the
market” in any goal category; the targets were consistently set so that they could be
fulfilled even though the GSEs “lagged the market.” Under the targets set as of 2005, the
GSEs were asked to “meet the market.” To avoid creating problems for the GSEs, the
targets were phased in year-by-year over the next four years. This is different from the
procedures used in 2001, when the goals were increased quite substantially from the old
level to the new level in a single year, as shown in Table 1.
The relationship between the targets and the market is shown in Table 2, which
compares each goal to the share of such loans in the market served by the GSEs, year by
year.
Table 2 is particularly relevant to a controversy about the goals established for
2005 and later years. The GSEs argued that the goals were too high; the actual market
shares of loans in each category were lower than the goals. Table 2 shows that, in fact,
all of the goals were set below the market in 2005 and 2006. It was possible for the GSEs
to meet the goals and still “lag the market.”

9
________________________________________________________________________
Table 2
GSE Affordable Housing Goals Compared to Market Shares
(Percentages of the Conventional Conforming Market Served by the GSEs)

Year

1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

Low- and Moderate-Income Special Affordable
Goal Market
Goal Market
30%
30
30
40
42
42
42
42
50
50
50
50
52
53
55
56

NR
NR
57%
57
57.5
54
58
59
55
50.0
53
58
57
55
52
54

NA
NA
N.A.
12
14
14
14
14
20
20
20
20
22
23
25
27

NA
NA
29%
29
29
26
29
30
26.5
23.5
24.5
28
28
27.5
24.7
26.5

Underserved Areas*
Goal Market
30%
30
30
21
24
24
24
24
31
31
31
31
37
38
38
39

NR
NR
34%
33
34
31
34
35
33
34
34
42
44
44
40
42

NOTE: Market shares are reported to the nearest percent except where the share is
halfway between two percents (e.g., 57.5%), or where the market share is within one
percent of the goal.
NA – Not Applicable: goals were set in dollar amounts for each GSE rather than
percentages
NR – market shares not reported
* The Underserved Areas goal was determined on the basis of 1990 Census tract
geography from 1993-2004, and on the basis of 2000 Census tract geography from 20052008.
SOURCES: 1993-1994, FHEFSSA, Sections 1332, 1333, 1334; 1995-2001, “2005
Proposed Rule,” Federal Register, May 3, 2004, p. 24468.; 2002-2008, Federal Housing
Finance Agency, “The Housing Goals of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the Context of
the Mortgage Market: 1996-2009,” Mortgage Market Note 10-2, February 1, 2010,
Appendix B.
________________________________________________________________________

10

11

GSE Performance Vis-à-vis the Goals and the Market
In fact, that is what the GSEs did, annually from 1995 to 2005. Their
performance is shown in Table 3, which repeats the goals and the actual market share
from Table 2, and adds the actual purchases of each GSE toward each goal.
GSE performance was consistently above the goal, but below the share of the
GSE market that qualified for the goal.
(1) For the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal, both GSEs’ purchases exceeded the
goal but fell short of meeting the market from 1995 through 2005;
(2) For the Special Affordable Goal, Fannie Mae’s purchases exceeded the goal but
fell short of meeting the market from 1995 through 2005, and Freddie Mac’s
purchases exceeded the goal but fell short of meeting the market from 1995
through 2006;
(3) For the Underserved Areas goal, both GSEs’ purchases exceeded the goal but fell
short of meeting the market from 1995 through 2006, with the exception of 2002,
when Freddie Mac fell just short of the goal.
Freddie Mac’s failure to meet the Underserved Areas goal in 2002 occurred
because it double-counted loans which it had purchased in 2001 toward the goals in both
2001 and 2002. These loans covered 22,424 housing units. Correcting for the doublecounting, Freddie Mac fell short of the 31 percent Underserved Areas goal by 90 loans,
or 0.002 percent. There was a similar double-counting of 22,371 units toward the Lowand Moderate-Income Goal, but correcting this error did not affect Freddie Mac’s
performance; it continued to meet that goal in 2002. (This matter is described in the final
rule for 2005-2008, which appears in the Federal Register for November 2, 2004, on p.
63587 and in Table 5.)
In 2006, both GSEs’ purchases met the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal and also
met the market. This was also true with respect to Fannie Mae’s performance on the
Special Affordable Goal in that year.

Table 3
GSE Performance on Affordable Housing Goals
Year

1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

Low- and Moderate-Income
Goal
Market GSE Purchases Goal
FNMA FHLMC
30
30
30
40
42
42
42
42
50
50
50
50
52
53
55
56

57
57
57.5
54
58
59
55
50
53
58
57
55
52
53.6

46
46
44
46
49.5
51.5
52
52
53
55
57
55.5
53.7

41
43
43
46
50
53
50.5
51
52
54
56
56
51.5

N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
12
14
14
14
14
20
20
20
20
22
23
25
27

Special Affordable
Market
GSE Purchases
FNMA FHLMC
N.A.
N.A.
29
29
29
26
29
30
26.5
23.5
24.5
28
28
27.5
24.7
26.5

15
17
14.3
18
19
22
21
21
24
26
28
27
26.4

14
15
16
17
21
23
20.4
21
23
24
26
26
23

Goal
30
30
30
21
24
24
24
24
31
31
31
31
37
38
38
39

Underserved Areas
Market GSE Purchases
FNMA FHLMC
34
33
34
31
34
35
33
34
34
42
44
44
40
42

28
29
27
27
31
33
33
32
33.5
41
43.6
39.4
42

25
26
26
27.5
29
32
31.0*
33
32
42
43
43
38

* Freddie Mac fell just short of underserved area goal in 2002, by 90 loans
NOTE: Market shares and GSE purchases reported to nearest percent except where the number is halfway between two percents (e.g.,
57.5%) or within one percent of the goal, or where the purchase number is within one percent of the market share.
NA – Not Applicable: goals were set in dollar amounts for each GSE rather than percentages
SOURCE: Federal Housing Finance Agency, “The Housing Goals of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the Context of the Mortgage
Market: 1996-2009,” Mortgage Market Note 10-2, February 1, 2010, Appendix B.

What this means is that lenders other than the GSEs – lenders without the various
special privileges that gave the GSEs “agency status” and the ability to borrow at
preferential rates in the capital markets – consistently did a better job of serving
households in each of these goal categories than did the GSEs. Since loans to low- and
moderate-income borrowers, for example, were a smaller share of GSE purchases than
they constituted in the conventional conforming market, other lenders must have been
buying a larger share of loans to low- and moderate-income borrowers than the GSEs.
Those loans were a larger share of their portfolios than they constituted in the portfolios
of the GSEs.
In short, the concern expressed by the GSEs that they could not meet the goals for
2005 and later because they were “too high” was not borne out by the actual market
shares available to meet each goal, or by their purchases, during 2005 and 2006. .
The situation was different in 2007, and the GSEs responded to it differently, as
will be discussed later.

The Goals and the Subprime Mortgage Market
It has sometimes been asserted that the affordable housing goals established in
2005 are substantially responsible for the GSEs’ collapse in 2008. For example, former
Fannie Mae senior officials expressed this view in testimony this spring before the
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission,2 as did the former CEO of Freddie Mac earlier
(Duhigg, 2008).3 It also appears to be the “sense of Congress,” as expressed in the DoddFrank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Subtitle H, Section 1491),
though the statute does not quite say so.4
In fact, the GSEs had been buying A-minus and Alt-A loans since the later 1990s,
according to analyses during the process leading up to the 2000 rule (Bunce and
Scheessele, 1998; Bunce, 2000). They increased their subprime activity in 2003, before
the new goals were proposed for comment in May 2004, and for that matter before
Freddie Mac’s accounting problems came to light (Inside Mortgage Finance Publications,
2009, p. 26). There is direct evidence on the extent to which the GSEs were buying
subprime mortgages, both before and after the 2005 rule went into effect. This evidence
indicates that the affordable housing goals had little if any impact on GSE activity in

2
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, 2010. The witnesses were Robert J. Levin, former vice president
and chief business officer, and Daniel H. Mudd, former president and chief executive officer.
3
But see also Gavin, 2008, and Syron, 2008, where Syron states that the cause of Freddie Mac’s problems
is the collapse in the housing market, rather than the affordable housing goals.
4
The text of the Dodd-Frank Act can be found at http://thomas.loc.gov/cgibin/query/F?c111:6:./temp/~c1113tyqqF:e2676629:

14
these markets. Instead, it appears that the GSEs were responding to the same factors in
the mortgage market as other lenders.
Table 4 reports the dollar values of subprime and Alt-A mortgage purchases by
the GSEs during 2001-2007. As mentioned earlier, but they began buying subprime
mortgage-backed securities (MBS) heavily in 2002. Their subprime MBS purchases
doubled between 2002 and 2003, and doubled again in 2004 – from $38 billion to $81
billion to $176 billion. All this of course happened before the housing goals were
changed in 2005. After the new goals went into effect, their subprime MBS purchases
actually declined slightly, to $169 billion, and then dropped sharply to $110 billion for
2006. Their share of the subprime MBS market rose from 19 percent in 2002 to 33
percent in 2004; then it declined to 27 percent in 2005 and further to 18 percent in 2006,
after the new goals were in place.
Essentially, what happened is that the market for subprime MBS took off in the
early years of the decade, and the GSEs became active in that market for a couple of
years. Then they began pulling back, at the same time that the affordable housing goals
were increased.

Table 4
Subprime and Alt-A Purchases by the GSEs, 2001-2006
(Dollar amounts in billions)
Year

2001
2002
2003
2004

Subprime Loans and MBS
Dollar amount
Share of Market
N.A.
$ 38
$ 81
$176

Alt-A loans
Dollar Amount

N.A.
19%
26%
33%

$
$
$
$

15
66
77
64

27%
18%
31%

$ 77
$157
$178

2005: new affordable housing goals go into effect
2005
2006
2007

$169
$110
$ 60

SOURCE: OFHEO annual reports, “Mortgage Markets and the Enterprises.”

The loan data come from a series of annual reports by the Office of Federal
Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO), the GSE safety and soundness regulator,
entitled “Mortgage Markets and the Enterprises.” From these reports, it also appears that
OFHEO did not think that these purchases posed a risk. In each report, the discussion of

15
subprime purchases was followed immediately by a section on overall single-family
mortgage credit risk in which OFHEO concluded that the risk was not great. Indeed, in
the report for 2007, issued July 21, 2008, a week after the Bush Administration offered a
plan to rescue the GSEs and nine days before HERA was enacted, the discussion was
entitled, “Enterprises Continue to Manage Single-Family Credit Risk.” In the 2006
report, issued June 25, 2007, four months after subprime mortgage problems were widely
reported, the discussion of subprime purchases was followed by a section entitled,
“Enterprise Single-Family Credit Risk Remains Low.” Similar discussions appeared in
earlier reports, going back to 2001.
Table 4 also reports on Alt-A mortgages – loans where the borrower does not
supply full documentation in support of the application. Often the borrower does not
provide income data. Traditionally these were loans to higher-income borrowers with
irregular incomes, such as the self-employed. In recent years, they were extended to
borrowers with much lower incomes.
The table shows that Alt-A purchases by the GSEs increased very sharply from
2001 to 2002, then fluctuated through 2005 (the first year of the new goals), and then
doubled between 2005 and 2006. This might suggest that Alt-A purchases were
influenced by the goals, at least in 2006. But Alt-A loans typically lack information on
the borrower’s income, and two of the three goals are based on income. Alt-A loans
could qualify directly for the underserved area goal, but not for the other two.
Indeed, in both the 2001 and 2005 rules, HUD set forth criteria for counting Alt-A
loans toward the goals.5 As of 2001, the GSEs could exclude mortgages to homeowners
without income data, and mortgages for rental properties without tenant income data and
rent data, from both the numerator and denominator of the Low- and Moderate-Income
Goal and the Special Affordable Goal calculations, but only up to a maximum of one
percent of all home mortgage purchases and five percent of all rental mortgage purchases.
The 2005 rule added a second option. The GSEs could choose to include Alt-A loans in a
given census tract toward the goals, in the same proportion as their mortgage purchases
on owner-occupied homes located in that tract, for which income data was reported,
counted toward a housing goal. If half the home loans with income data in a given tract
counted toward a goal, then half the Alt-A loans in that tract could count toward the goal
as well. The 2005 rule also allowed the same methodology for mortgages on rental
properties, which lacked either income or rent data. The GSEs could choose either of
these methodologies in a given year. In addition, the 2005 rule allowed the GSEs to use
other methodologies, subject to HUD approval.
Under those criteria, the more Alt-A loans that the GSEs have bought, the harder
it has been for them to meet the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal and the Special
Affordable Goal.

5

24 CFR Secs. 81.15(d) and 81.15(e). As noted earlier, the rule appears in the Federal Register for
November 2, 2004. The discussion of Alt-A loans appears on pp. 63626-63627. The rule language appears
on pp. 63641-63642.

16

GSE Purchases of Subprime Mortgage-Backed Securities.
In addition to the series of reports on “Mortgage Markets and the Enterprises,”
OFHEO and FHFA have issued “Annual Reports to Congress,” which include historical
tables for GSE activity: mortgage purchases, securitizations, delinquencies, enterprise
profits, etc. In 2008, these reports began to include detailed information on GSE
purchases of subprime and Alt-A mortgage-backed securities, though not on purchases of
subprime or Alt-A mortgages for portfolio. Data for Fannie Mae are reported back to
2002, but data for Freddie Mac are only available since 2006.
Fannie Mae’s reported purchases are shown in Table 5, disaggregated into
subprime, Alt-A, and “other,” and within each category separated into fixed-rate and
adjustable-rate. The pattern is similar to Table 4. Total subprime and Alt-A MBS
purchases rose from $7 billion in 2002 to $33 billion in 2003 and to $89 billion in 2004.
Then the new goals went into effect at the beginning of 2005. Purchases dropped by
more than 50 percent that year, to $41 billion. There was a modest increase to $47 billion
in 2006, still not much more than half the 2004 total. This pattern is driven by subprime
ARM MBS purchases, which amount to over 70 percent of the total in each year except
2005, but each of the other categories shows a marked decline between 2004 and 2005.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 5
Private Label MBS Purchases by Fannie Mae, 2002-2007
(dollars in billions)

Year

2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007

Subprime
Alt-A
Subprime &
Other SF
FRM ARM FRM ARM Alt-A Total FRM ARM
0.2
0
0.2
0
0
0.3

5.0
25.8
66.8
24.5
35.6
15.6

1.8
7.7
7.1
3.6
1.5
**

0
0.4
14.9
12.5
10.5
5.2

6.9
33.9
89.0
40.6
47.6
21.3

**
0.1
0.2
0.1
0
0

0.4
0
1.5
0.6
0.5
0.2

Total*

7.4
34.0
90.8
41.4
57.8
37.4

* Total exceeds sum of subprime, alt-A and other SF because of omitted categories
(manufactured housing, multifamily)
** Less than $50 million

SOURCE: FHFA, “Report to Congress: 2008,” Table 1b. Fannie Mae Purchases of
Mortgage-Related Securities - Part 2, Private-Label Detail – revised from first edition.
__________________________________________________________________________

17
Underwriting Changes and the Affordable Housing Goals
Further evidence from a different perspective on GSE behavior comes from an
analysis by HUD staff economists, published in the August 2008 issue of HUD’s
periodical, “U.S. Housing Market Conditions.” This study reports the distribution of
mortgage-to-income ratios for the GSEs and other lenders during 2001-2006. Higher
ratios indicate greater risk of default – mortgage payment burdens that will be a
particularly large share of the borrower’s income. The data are shown in Table 6, for
loans in the 90th percentile of the mortgage-to-income ratio – close to the riskiest loans
being made. To illustrate more directly the effect of the changes, the table also shows
comparable mortgage principal amounts for a family with an income of $60,000, close to
the median family income for mortgage borrowers during 2004-2006.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 6
Risk-Taking by the GSEs and Other Lenders, 2001-2006
( for the 90th percentile of the distribution of home purchase loans)
Panel A – ratio of mortgage principal to income
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

335% 356% 383% 390%
322% 348% 376% 403%
328% 352% 384% 393%

New goals:
2005 2006
397% 380%
389% 392%
388% 365%

Panel B – mortgage loan amount for family with $60,000 annual income
(dollar amounts in thousands, rounded to nearest thousand)
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

$201 $214 $230 $234
$193 $209 $226 $242
$197 $211 $230 $236

New goals:
2005 2006
$238 $228
$233 $235
$233 $219

SOURCE: “Using HMDA and Income Leverage to Examine Current Mortgage Market
Turmoil,” U.S. Housing Market Conditions, Second Quarter 2008, published by the U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and
Research.
________________________________________________________________________
The GSEs began making significantly riskier loans to homebuyers beginning in
2002, offering larger loans to families with a given income level; they took still more risk

18
in 2003. Beginning in 2004, their appetite for increased risk subsided, but their
mortgage-to-income ratios remained high, and very nearly constant, through 2006.
The GSEs were not alone, as Table 6 shows. Beginning in 2002, other lenders
were also taking more risk by relaxing underwriting standards. These lenders – both
portfolio lenders such as commercial and community banks, and issuers of private
mortgage pools – began taking more risk in 2002 and continued to do so until 2005.
They were not subject to the affordable housing goals, but they behaved in the same way
as the GSEs.
For homeowners who refinanced their mortgages, the GSEs relaxed their
standards to a much greater extent, beginning in 2002 and continuing through 2006.
These data are shown in Table 7.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 7
Risk-Taking by the GSEs and Other Lenders, 2001-2006
( for the 90th percentile of the distribution of home refinance loans)
Panel A – ratio of mortgage principal to income
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

331% 338% 347% 385%
314% 331% 346% 402%
346% 366% 388% 434%

New goals:
2005 2006
423% 429%
408% 394%
455% 438%

Panel B – mortgage loan amount for family with $60,000 annual income
(dollar amounts in thousands, rounded to nearest thousand)
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

$199 $203 $208 $231
$188 $199 $208 $241
$208 $220 $233 $260

New goals:
2005 2006
$254 $257
$245 $236
$273 $263

SOURCE: Same as Table 6.
________________________________________________________________________

This is particularly relevant because refinances are less likely to count toward the
affordable housing goals; in general, homebuyers have lower incomes than homeowners
who are refinancing, and homebuyers are more likely to live in “underserved” areas. If

19
the GSEs were being driven by the new affordable housing goals, they would have
relaxed their standards more for home purchase loans and less for refinances. Instead,
they did the opposite. Again, other lenders, not subject to the goals, followed the same
pattern as the GSEs.
The increase in leveraging between 2001 and 2004 is far too large to be accounted
for by the decline in mortgage rates over those years. The decline in rates was about 110
basis points, which is enough to permit about a 30-basis point increase in the mortgageto-income ratio without increasing the risk of default. For both home purchase loans and
refinances, the increase in the ratio for the GSEs was about 55 basis points during those
years. In addition, GSE mortgage-to-income ratios for refinances increased from 2004 to
2005 even though interest rates were stable; and they remained at about the 2005 level
even though mortgage rates increased by over 50 basis points in 2006.
The GSEs relaxed their underwriting standards and began investing heavily in
subprime mortgage-backed securities well before the goals were increased in 2005. After
the goal increase, the GSEs maintained about the same underwriting standards, at least
for home purchase loans, the most likely to count toward any of the housing goals.
Despite the increase in the goals, the GSEs did not take further underwriting risk in order
to meet them.

What Happened in 2007?
By the beginning of 2007, problems in the housing and mortgage markets were
becoming evident. New home construction began to contract in mid-2006, and house
prices as measured by the Case-Shiller Index started to drop at about the same time.
Prices as measured by the OFHEO repeat-sales index – an index based on the homes on
which the GSEs had actually bought the mortgages – were still rising, but more slowly
than earlier; the OFHEO index began to decline in the second quarter of 2007. At the
same time, there were growing problems in the subprime market. In early February,
HSBC and New Century reported unexpectedly large losses on subprime mortgages; they
were the subjects of front-page stories in the Wall Street Journal on consecutive days
(Mollenkamp, 2007; . From that point, subprime mortgage problems were regularly in
the news. The subprime market began to shrivel.
By the end of 2006, lenders were tightening their standards for subprime loans.
The financial regulators issued guidance to financial institutions on nontraditional
mortgage product risks in October 2006, and followed it with proposed guidance on
subprime lending in March 2007, and final guidance in June (Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System 2006; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2007).
The earlier guidance urged institutions to recognize that non-traditional mortgages are
“untested in a stressed environment,” and that they require strong risk management and
capital standards and loss reserves commensurate with the risk. The later guidance
expressed concern about the “heightened risks” to lenders as well as borrowers from
subprime ARMs with teaser rates such as 2/28 and 3/27 loans, loans with very high or no

20
payment or rate caps, low-doc and no-doc loans, and substantial prepayment penalties,
and stated that institutions should develop strong control systems in order to manage the
risks.
This guidance also applied to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, but with a lag.
OFHEO notified Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in December 2006 that they were required
to comply with the guidance on non-traditional mortgage product risks, but the GSEs did
not agree to comply until July 2007, and even then indicated that they would continue to
buy non-traditional mortgages until September 2007 (Lockhart 2007). Similarly,
OFHEO told the GSEs in March 2007 that they must follow the later statement on
subprime mortgage lending, but the GSEs did not agree to comply until September.
The actions of OFHEO and the other financial regulators would have been a
perfect opportunity for the GSEs to ask HUD for relief from the 2007 affordable housing
goals. The subprime market was in the process of shrinking by almost 70 percent from
the 2006 level, and the safety and soundness regulator was telling the GSEs that they
should get out of that market. The section of FHEFSSA establishing the housing goals
states that the Secretary of HUD must consider “the need to maintain the sound financial
condition of the enterprises.” (This appears as Section 1332 (b)(6), Section 1333
(a)(2)(E), and Section 1334 (b)(6).) HUD could hardly have insisted that the GSEs
continue to buy A- subprime loans – the top half of the subprime market – as the total
subprime market shrank, even if house prices were not dropping.
But the GSEs apparently did not make such a request to HUD, nor did they ask
OFHEO to do so. The OFHEO director at that time told the FCIC that he had no
knowledge of any such request by either GSE directly to HUD (Financial Crisis Inquiry
Commission, 2010).6
Instead, the GSEs continued to buy subprime mortgages. In 2007, their share of
the subprime market increased to 31 percent, close to the 2004 level.
The GSEs made the decision to continue buying subprime mortgages, despite the
efforts of their regulator to compel them to get out of that market. They did not seek
relief from the affordable housing goals. They apparently thought there were profits in
the subprime market, and they stayed in it.

The Affordable Housing Goals and Homeownership
6

The director was James Lockhart, speaking in response to a question. In December 2007, HUD notified
both GSEs that it found a substantial probability that the GSEs would fail to achieve two home purchase
subgoals for 2007, and each GSE responded that it considered those subgoals infeasible. In April 2008,
HUD formally determined that the subgoals were infeasible (Montgomery 2008a; Montgomery 208b). In
March 2008, Richard Syron, then CEO of Freddie Mac, told an interviewer that “officials at the
Department of Housing and Urban Development seem receptive to his suggestions that they change the
affordable housing goals” for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (Shenn, 2008). All of these events occurred
after both GSEs had continued to buy suibprime loans, against the guidance of their financial safety and
soundness regulator, for most of a year.

21

The GSEs were established to serve several public purposes, and the affordable
housing goals were intended to delineate some of those purposes and quantify the extent
to which the GSEs were in fact serving them. This section addresses the effectiveness of
the affordable housing goals and GSE activity more generally in achieving one major
policy objective, promoting homeownership, which is particularly relevant to the issue of
whether the goals contributed to the collapse of the GSEs.
The affordable housing goals were not established in terms of the race or ethnicity
of the borrower; nor with respect to whether the borrower is buying a first home,
refinancing a mortgage, or buying a home for the second or third time – or, more broadly,
whether the mortgage is being made to a homeowner, homebuyer, or investor.
Nonetheless, there has long been policy interest in the extent to which borrowers are firsttime homebuyers, and the extent to which they are members of minority groups; indeed,
GSE radio commercials during 2004 frequently featured minority employees describing
their satisfaction from promoting homeownership for minority families. In the policy
discussions and analysis prior to the promulgation of the 2005 affordable housing goals,
HUD analyzed the extent to which the GSEs were serving first-time homebuyers.
A summary of the analysis appears as Table 8. There are two quite different
sources of information, showing the same result.
Panel A is based on the GSEs’ own data on the loans they purchase, which was
provided to HUD in its capacity as the GSE mission regulator; these GSE data are
compared to overall market data from the American Housing Survey (conducted
biennially by the Census Bureau for HUD) and the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act
filings of lenders. During the years 1999-2003, about 38 percent of all home purchase
loans were to first time homebuyers, while only 26 percent of the home purchase loans
that the GSEs bought were to first-time buyers.
Panel B is based on a completely separate data source, the 2001 Residential
Finance Survey (RFS), conducted by the Census Bureau as a supplement to the decennial
Census of Housing. The RFS asked both borrowers and lenders about each loan in its
sample. Borrowers were asked, for example, whether they were first-time homebuyers;
lenders were asked if they sold the loan to a GSE. Panel B shows very similar results
from very different data; according to the RFS, 37 percent of all home purchase loans in
the conventional conforming market were to first-time homebuyers, compared to only 29
percent of the GSEs’ home purchase loans.
The results for minority first-time homebuyers, also shown in Table 8, are similar.
Some 11 or 12 percent of homebuyers in the conventional conforming market were
minority families buying their first home, compared to only 7 or 8 percent of GSE home
purchase loans. Other lenders were doing a better job than do the GSEs in serving firsttime homebuyers, even though these other lenders did not have agency status.

22
By contrast, the GSEs did much better in serving homeowners who were buying a
home for the second or third time – both white and minority homeowners. And they did
a better job in serving borrowers who were refinancing. (These data are not shown in the
Table.)
To my knowledge, these are the most recent data. HUD’s only later report,
covering 2004-2005 and published in 2007, does not include data on first-time
homebuyers (Bunce 2007). FHFA has not addressed this issue.
The subprime mortgage crisis is largely seen as a problem of loans to first-time
buyers who did not know what commitments they were making. At least through 2003,
the GSEs were not particularly active in serving first-time homebuyers.

Table 8
The GSEs and First-Time Homebuyers, 1999-2003
(market shares)

Panel A: GSE, AHS, and HMDA data, 1999-2003
Market

GSEs

All First-time Homebuyers

38%

26%

Minority First-time
Homebuyers

11%

7%

Panel B: RFS data, 2001
Market

GSEs

All First-time Homebuyers

37%

29%

Minority First-time
Homebuyers

12%

8%

SOURCE: Harold L. Bunce and John L. Gardner, “First-Time Homebuyers in the
Conventional Conforming Market – The Role of the GSEs: an Update,” unpublished
paper; U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy
Development and Research, October 2004.
At the same time, however, the overall national homeownership rate was rising to
unprecedented levels. In 1994, the national homeownership rate stood at 64.0 percent; it
had been within 0.2 percent of that rate for a decade, since 1985. The highest rate on

23
record was 65.6 percent in 1980, after 15 years of erratically accelerating inflation. In
1995, the homeownership rate increased sharply to 64.8 percent; it reached a new record
of 65.7 percent in 1997, and it continued to rise through 2004, to 69.0 percent. The data
in Table 8 indicate that the GSEs’ purchases of loans to first-time homebuyers did not
play a major role in that increase, at least for half of the period. During 1999-2003, the
national homeownership rate increased by two percentage points, from 66.3 percent in
1998 to 68.3 percent in 2003; over those years, the GSEs were lagging the market in
mortgages for first-time homebuyers.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 9
National Homeownership Rate, 1994-2007
Year

Homeownership Rate

1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007

64.0%
64.8
65.4
65.7
66.3
66.8
67.3
67.8
68.0
68.3
69.0
68.9
68.8
68.2

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Series H-111, “Housing Vacancy Survey,”
reported by Haver Economics.

24
There was a homeownership boom during the decade 1994-2004, and the GSEs
were by far the largest buys of home mortgages in that decade, but they were not
particularly buying mortgages to first-time homebuyers.

Risk: Capital Standards and Stress Tests
If the affordable housing goals are not relevant to the collapse of the GSEs in
2008, what did cause it? This question can perhaps be answered by looking at another
regulatory issue, this one dating from the period between FIRREA and FHEFSSA when
HUD was the sole regulator of both GSEs (1989-1992).
The Secretary of HUD became the regulator of Fannie Mae when it was chartered
as a privately managed corporation in 1968. In 1984, the Secondary Mortgage Market
Enhancement Act required the Secretary to submit annual reports on Fannie Mae’s
activities (Section 309(h) of the FNMA Charter Act). FIRREA transferred regulatory
authority for Freddie Mac to the Secretary of HUD in 1989, and also required annual
reports on its activities (Section 731(c)(4)). Preparation of these reports was the
responsibility of the Office of Policy Development and Research, and within that office,
the responsibility of the Financial Institutions Regulatory Staff (FIRS), which Secretary
Kemp directed me to establish.
To establish and manage this staff, the Department brought in a well-known
business economist, Ben E. Laden, who had been chief economist for T. Rowe Price and
president of the National Association of Business Economists in 1982. Laden put
together a very small staff of competent professional economists with educational and
professional credentials in housing markets, housing finance, and financial markets
generally. This staff never numbered more than four, including Laden himself. Some
additional support was provided by other HUD economists, all of whom had other policy
issues or HUD programs as their first professional responsibility.
It is worth pointing out, and emphasizing, that HUD never received funding or
staff allocations from Congress for its GSE regulatory responsibilities. From 1968
through 2008, HUD was expected to use money and personnel that were part of its
regular appropriation (which includes an overall staff ceiling). This was true even when
HUD was given responsibility for both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in FIRREA – which
for good measure also put the Secretary of HUD on the Federal Housing Finance Board
ex officio as the deciding partisan vote, also with no HUD funding or staff support.
FHEFSSA left HUD with specific responsibilities for the affordable housing goals, new
program approval, fair housing, and “general regulatory authority,” again with no funds
or dedicated staff for those purposes. It has often been remarked that OFHEO was the
only financial regulator without authority to charge the regulated entities for the cost of
regulation, being forced to rely on annual appropriations from Congress. This was an
important reason for its weakness relative to other regulators. It has rarely been noticed
that HUD did not even have an appropriation.

25
A further complication is that the overall HUD personnel ceiling was steadily
reduced from the late 1970s through the early 2000s, even though HUD’s program
activities were expanding beginning in the early 1980s.
The Capitalization Study: Judging GSE Safety and Soundness
This small staff was responsible for producing the annual reports to Congress for
the years 1989, 1990, and 1991. In addition, FIRS conducted a “Capitalization Study of
the Federal National Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Corporation,” published in November 1991 (U.S. Department of Housing and Urban
Development 1991). This study reported the results of a “stress test” to calculate the
amount of capital which each GSE had at the time, and the amount it would need to
survive a serious economic downturn. In the aftermath of FIRREA and the complicated
process of resolving failed savings and loan associations, Congress was very concerned
about the capital adequacy of all mortgage lenders.
The stress test was based on a scenario developed by Moody’s – a “Depression
Scenario” which Moody’s used to rate private mortgage insurers. This was a 10-year
scenario. To summarize, it basically consisted of one year of flat housing prices, then
four consecutive years of falling house prices at an annual rate of 10 percent, and finally
five years of stable to very slightly rising prices. There was no further price decline after
the fifth year, but no recovery in prices, either.
The Capitalization Study concluded that Fannie Mae could survive between
seven and eight years of this scenario, and Freddie Mac could survive between six and
seven years.
Both GSEs took great exception to these conclusions. They stated that they could
survive for the full ten years.
This was much more than a technical argument. It mattered both economically
and politically. Under the Moody’s stress test, a company was rated AAA if it survived
the test for the full ten years. If it only survived for seven years, it was rated AA. The
GSEs had recently had an argument with Standard & Poor’s, which had rated both of
them AA in the absence of their implicit government guarantee. The outcome was that
S&P pulled back from its rating. But the GSEs did not want this issue raised again.
The HUD analysis was based on the assumptions that the GSEs would continue to
buy mortgages for two years after the economic downturn started. After two years they
would stop buying mortgages, but they would lose money on the mortgages they owned,
including the mortgages they bought after the start of the downturn, and eventually they
would go bankrupt, in about seven years. The HUD analysis also assumed that the GSEs
would maintain their fee structure throughout the ten-year period.

26
The GSEs argued that they would stop buying mortgages immediately – as soon
as the downturn started. In addition, they would raise their guarantee fees and their
service charges. And they would therefore survive for the full ten years.
HUD responded that the beginning of an economic downturn is generally not
recognized until some time has passed: “like many other businesses and observers of the
economy, FNMA and FHLMC could have difficulty diagnosing the beginning of a
downturn and even more difficulty distinguishing the beginning of a recession from the
beginning of a Depression. Therefore, it is foreseeable that FNMA’s or FHLMC’s
management would not take corrective action with respect to pricing or underwriting
until the economy was many months, or even years, into the Depression.” HUD also
questioned how raising fees and ceasing to purchase mortgages could be consistent with
the GSEs’ legislative requirement to have a continued presence in the secondary
mortgage market. (The first stated purpose of each GSE is to “provide stability in the
secondary market for residential mortgages,” according to the Fannie Mae Charter Act
and the Freddie Mac Corporation Act.)7
The Outcomes
HUD lost the argument, politically. In 1992, Congress passed FHEFFSA, and
established a stress test for the GSEs, but that stress test was much less severe than the
Depression scenario. Instead, it was based on the Oil Patch downturn of the early 1980s.
Congress also established a 2.5% minimum capital requirement for on-balance sheet
assets and 0.45 percent of the outstanding principal balance of mortgage-backed
securities. These minimum capital levels were intended as a temporary requirement until
the new independent regulator created in FHEFSSA could put the stress test in place, and
determinate how much additional capital each GSE should hold. The stress test was
complicated; the new financial safety and soundness regulator (OFHEO) spent more than
five years putting it in place and evaluating the GSEs. Then it turned out that the enacted
stress test was so weak that the required capital level to be “adequately capitalized” was
less than the 2.5% minimum capital, for each GSE. This result was not what Congress
expected in 1992.
Almost twenty years later, the outcome of that controversy is now clear. We now
know that HUD won the analytical argument. In fact, it turns out that HUD was
optimistic. Neither GSE could survive three years of a severe economic downturn; they
could barely survive two years. House prices flattened out in the second quarter of 2006,
according to the Case-Shiller national index, or in the second quarter of 2007 according
to the OFHEO home purchase index (now the FHFA index). According to both indices,
prices declined by 4-6% annually – far less than 10% - through the summer of 2008. By
that time, the GSEs were in great trouble and by the fall of 2008 they were in
conservatorship.
7

The argument between HUD and the GSEs is summarized in the Capitalization Study,
“Overview,” Section III, especially pp. 8-9. The full analysis of the stress test, including alternative
scenarios, appears in Chapter II.

27

The GSEs certainly did not stop buying mortgages when the downturn started –
and they did not have enough capital to last three years. They did raise their guarantee
fees in late 2008, however.

Policy Implications
The history of the affordable housing goals since FHEFSSA carries several
lessons for public policy.
First, while public policy goals can be advanced in the context of broader housing
policy objectives, the process is complicated and probably not the most effective way to
achieve the policy goals. The affordable housing goals were set “below the market,”
meaning that lenders other than the GSEs were buying more loans that met the goals than
did the GSEs themselves. For at least half of the recent homeownership boom, the GSEs
were concentrating on loans to homebuyers who already owned a home, and loans to
homeowners who were refinancing their mortgages. The extent to which the goals
achieved the public policy purpose of promoting homeownership is therefore somewhat
problematical.
Second, the affordable housing goals exemplify a basic conflict between public
purpose and private profit. The GSEs were privately-owned corporations whose
stockholders expected that they would be profitable; in fact, they were told to expect high
and rising returns by GSE management. At the same time, they were required to devote
resources to achieving public policy objectives. In that tug-of-war between those
objectives, private profit consistently won. This was the case for both the affordable
housing goals and the capital requirements. The GSEs made no effort to address HUD’s
concern about the inherent conflict between its Charter Act responsibility to support the
secondary mortgage market in times of stress, and its strategy for surviving a serious
economic downturn.
Third, the GSEs will not hold any more capital than they are forced to hold. The
HUD stress test indicated that Fannie Mae should have about 35 percent more capital
than it had, and Freddie Mac should have twice as much. The GSEs did not want to hold
anything like that amount; they wanted to rely on their then-implicit government
guarantee to borrow cheaply, instead of subjecting themselves to the discipline of the
financial markets. That incentive will remain for any reconstitution of the GSEs, with
either an implicit or explicit guarantee. Within the GSE framework, it is very difficult to
design “incentives to encourage appropriate alignment of risk bearing in the private
sector” or;” to promote market discipline,” issues raised in the Treasury Department’s
invitation to comment on the future of the GSEs last summer.
Fourth, it is virtually impossible for Congress to formulate an appropriate stress
test. Legislation prescribing the details of such a test is not an effective way of regulating
the GSEs. Econometric modeling is a complicated and highly technical process. The

28
serious and well-meaning effort of 1991-1992 resulted in a test whose results ran directly
counter to Congress’ expectations, and which failed to identify the GSEs’ burgeoning
problems in a timely manner. In a sense, Congress was fighting the last war. In the early
1980s, Fannie Mae was significantly underwater; interest rates rose sharply and Fannie
Mae had a large portfolio of low-interest loans from the 1970s. Eventually the
disinflation that resulted from a more stable monetary policy began to bring down

Conclusion
If the affordable housing goals don’t account for the GSEs’ purchases of high-risk
subprime mortgages and their subsequent financial collapse, what does? The best
explanation is the simplest. The GSEs badly misjudged the risk of subprime and Alt-A
mortgages. They thought there were large profits to be made in the growing subprime
market, and they sought to maintain and expand their share of the home mortgage market.
They were not alone in misjudging the risks of subprime mortgages; so did other lenders.
Indeed, the GSEs were by no means the first lenders to run into problems with their nonprime portfolios; HSBC and New Century were front-page news in February 2007. But
the GSEs, because they were bigger – and were required to hold less capital – took the
biggest risks and had the most spectacular problems.
The GSEs have made other misjudgments than threatened their solvency.
Economists have often analyzed risk for financial institutions along three dimensions:
interest rate risk, credit risk, operations risk. The GSEs have experienced all three.
In the early1980s, Fannie Mae faced enormous interest rate risk problems. It had
purchased large volumes of mortgages carrying low interest rates in the later 1970s; it
then had to fund those mortgages with expensive borrowing in the 1980s. The low-rate
portfolio was colloquially termed the “block of granite.” Fannie Mae tried to chip away
at it whenever it was possible. But until mortgage rates turned down in the mid-1980s,
Fannie Mae was significantly underwater. The market value of its assets was less than
the market value of its liabilities.
In the early 2000s, both GSEs incurred operations risk on a large scale. Freddie
Mac’s accounting problems first came to public attention in 2003; it had been smoothing
out its reported earnings, to persuade investors that it was “steady Freddie” – a good
investment regardless of market conditions. In 2004, it became known that Fannie Mae
had a policy of manipulating earnings so that its top executives would get very large
bonuses.
The credit risk problems leading to the conservatorship of 2008 are the most
recent example. The GSEs bought risky loans that went bad, not understanding the risks
they were taking. When their financial position became precarious, it was much more
convenient for the GSEs to blame the affordable housing goals, than to admit to mistakes
made by their own choice.

29
Many years ago in graduate school I studied economic history under a
distinguished expert in the history of banking and finance, the late Earl J. Hamilton. He
once observed that financial reform in the United States had occurred under three
circumstances: during wars, during depressions, and during the first term of President
Woodrow Wilson. Since then, he would have found it necessary to add: during
inflations, to account for the collapse of the housing finance system as a result of the
unprecedented peacetime inflation of the late 1960s and 1970s. The common feature of
all these circumstances is that they were periods of extreme economic stress. (The
reforms under President Wilson were a reaction to the depression of 1907 and the
recognition that the National Banking System had outlived its ability to serve the
economy effectively.)
The extraordinary collapse of the GSEs does not fit into this pattern. It occurred
during a period of economic growth, with low inflation. This is a unique experience in
our history.
It occurred because the GSEs were able to build up substantial political clout, as
witnessed by the weak regulatory structure established in FHEFSSA. A significant
component of that regulatory structure concerned the capital standard; the GSEs did not
have to hold capital to the same extent as other mortgage lenders. The GSEs were
politically strong enough to stave off financial reform legislation after their accounting
problems were identified, and after they became bywords for incompetence.
Fundamentally, the structure of the mortgage market after FIRREA - two large
institutions sponsored by the federal government with competitive advantages over other
lenders – generated the problems that we confront today.

30
REFERENCES
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Federal Financial Regulatory
Agencies Issue Final Guidance on Nontraditional Mortgage Product Risks,” September
29, 2006, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/20060929a.htm.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Federal Financial Regulatory
Agencies Issue Final Guidance on Subprime Mortgage Lending,” June 29, 2007,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/20070629a.htm.
Bunce, Harold, “The GSEs’ Funding of Affordable Loans: A 1999 Update,” U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and
Research, Housing Finance Working Paper HF-012, December 2000.
Bunce, Harold L., “The GSEs’ Funding of Affordable Loans: A 2004-2005 Update,” U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and
Research, Housing Finance Working Paper HF-018, June 2007.
Bunce, Harold L. and Gardner, John L., “First-Time Homebuyers in the Conventional
Conforming Market – The Role of the GSEs: an Update,” unpublished paper; U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and
Research, October 2004.
Bunce, Harold L. and Scheessele, Randall M., “The GSEs’ Funding of Affordable Loans:
A 1996 Update,” U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy
Development and Research, Housing Finance Working Paper HF-005, July 1998.
Duhigg, Charles, “At Freddie Mac, Chief Discarded Warning Signs,” New York Times,
August 5, 2010.
Federal Housing Finance Agency, “Report to Congress: 2008,” May 18, 2009.
Federal Housing Finance Agency, “The Housing Goals of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
in the Context of the Mortgage Market: 1996-2009,” Mortgage Market Note 10-2,
February 1, 2010.
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, “Hearings and Testimony: Subprime Lending and
Securitization and Government-Sponsored Enterprises, Day 3,” April 9, 2010,
http://www.fcic.gov/hearings/04-09-2010.php.
Gavin, Robert, “Syron’s Side of the Story,” Boston Globe, August 6, 2010.
Inside Mortgage Finance Publications, “The Rise and Fall of the Subprime Market,”
2009.

31
Lockhart, James B., III, “Housing, Subprime, and GSE Reform: Where are we headed?”
speech to the Exchequer Club of Washington, DC, July 18, 2007.
Mollenkamp, Carrick, "In Home-Lending Push, Banks Misjudged Risk: HSBC
Borrowers Fall Behind on Payments; Hiring More Collectors," Wall Street Journal,
February 8, 2007, p. A1.
Montgomery, Brian D., “Letter to Daniel H. Mudd,” April 24, 2008,
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/349/HMG_MAE_-_2007_Feasibility_-_April_2008.pdf.
(2008a)
Montgomery, Brian D., “Letter to Richard F. Syron,” April 24, 2008,
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/353/HMG_MAC_-_2007_Feasibility_-_April_2008.pdf.
(2008b)
Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight, “Mortgage Markets and the Enterprises
in (200y);” annual reports for 2000-2007 (no report for 2002),
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/15312/Report_HMM_and_the_Enterprises_in_2008.pdf;
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/1161/MortgageMarkets2006.pdf;
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/1159/mme2005.pdf;
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/1155/mme2004report.pdf;
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/1149/MME2003.pdf
http://www.novoco.com/low_income_housing/resource_files/research_center/ofheo_GSE
s_2001.pdf;
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/1139/MMin2000.pdf.
Shenn, Jody, “Rules Let Too Many Poor People Buy Houses, Syron Says (Update 2),”
March 13, 2008.
http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aRGiT9IV3UC0.
Syron, Richard F. “Statement before the Committee on Oversight and Government
Reform, U.S. House of Representatives,” December 9, 2008,
http://oversight.house.gov/images/stories/Hearings/110th_Congress/Fannie_Freddie/Testi
mony_Richard_F._Syron.pdf.
U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, “Capitalization study of the
Federal National Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Corporation,” November 1991.
U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development
and Research. “Using HMDA and Income Leverage to Examine Current Mortgage
Market Turmoil,” U.S. Housing Market Conditions, Second Quarter 2008. The authors
are listed as William J. Reeder and John P. Comeau, in a note at the end of the paper.

32

TO:

The U.S. Department of the Treasury
The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development
c/o www.regulations.gov

Re: Public Input on Reform of the Housing Finance System
eDocket Number: Treas-DO-2010-001
eDocket Number: HUD-2010-0029

Dear Sirs or Mesdames:
Thank you for the opportunity to comment on the important policy issue of the
reform of the United States housing finance system. I am submitting comments on the
first two of the seven questions raised in your invitation. These responses are based on
my experience with the regulation of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
I have had a substantial role in GSE regulation on two occasions. As Assistant
Secretary for Policy Development and Research at the U.S. Department of Housing and
Urban Development during 1989-1993, I created and managed a staff to support
Secretary Jack Kemp in his responsibilities as sole regulator of Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac between the passage of FIRREA in 1989 and FHEFSSA in 1992. Later, as Assistant
Secretary for Housing at HUD during 2001-2005, I received the delegation of regulatory
authority from Secretaries Mel Martinez and Alphonso Jackson, to serve as “mission
regulator,” including the affordable housing goals, new program approval, and related
matters. My comments will focus on two issues, one from each of those periods, which
are relevant to the first two questions on which you have solicited public input.
My responses to these questions begins on the next page. Thank you again for
the opportunity to comment. I will be very happy to respond to any further questions or
provide any further comments that may be helpful to you.
Sincerely,

John C. Weicher
Director, Center for Housing and
Financial Markets
Hudson Institute
john@hudson.org
(202) 974-2425

33
Question 2: GSE Safety and Soundness – Stress Testing in 1991
My first comment concerns safety and soundness and capital adequacy and is
relevant to question 2: What role should the federal government play in supporting a
stable, well-functioning housing finance system and what risks, if any, should the federal
government bear in meeting its housing finance objectives?
The Secretary of HUD became the regulator of Fannie Mae when it was chartered
as a privately managed corporation in 1968. In 1984, the Secondary Mortgage Market
Enhancement Act required the Secretary to submit annual reports on Fannie Mae’s
activities (Section 309(h) of the FNMA Charter Act). FIRREA transferred regulatory
authority for Freddie Mac to the Secretary of HUD in 1989, and also required annual
reports on its activities (Section 731(c)(4)). Preparation of these reports was the
responsibility of the Office of Policy Development and Research, and within that office,
the responsibility of the Financial Institutions Regulatory Staff, which Secretary Kemp
directed me to establish. HUD duly prepared and submitted to Congress annual reports
for 1989, 1990, and 1991.

The Capitalization Study: Judging GSE Safety and Soundness
In addition, HUD conducted a “Capitalization Study of the Federal National
Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation,” published in
November 1991. This study reported the results of a “stress test” to calculate the amount
of capital which each GSE had at the time, and the amount it would need to survive a
serious economic downturn. In the aftermath of FIRREA and the complicated process of
resolving failed savings and loan associations, Congress was very concerned about the
capital adequacy of all mortgage lenders.
HUD based the stress test on a scenario developed by Moody’s – a “Depression
Scenario” which Moody’s used to rate private mortgage insurers. This was a 10-year
scenario. To summarize, it basically consisted of one year of flat housing prices, then
four consecutive years of falling house prices at an annual rate of 10 percent, and finally
five years of stable to very slightly rising prices. There was no further price decline after
the fifth year, but no recovery in prices, either.
The Capitalization Study concluded that Fannie Mae could survive between
seven and eight years of this scenario, and Freddie Mac could survive between six and
seven years. Both GSEs took great exception to these conclusions. They stated that they
could survive for the full ten years.
This was much more than a technical argument. It mattered both economically
and politically. Under the Moody’s stress test, a company was rated AAA if it survived
the test for the full ten years. If it only survived for seven years, it was rated AA. The
GSEs had recently had an argument with Standard & Poor’s, which had rated both of

34
them AA in the absence of their implicit government guarantee. The outcome was that
S&P pulled back from its rating. But the GSEs did not want this issue raised again.
The HUD analysis was based on the assumptions that the GSEs would continue to
buy mortgages for two years after the economic downturn started. After two years they
would stop buying mortgages, but they would lose money on the mortgages they owned,
including the mortgages they bought after the start of the downturn, and eventually they
would go bankrupt, in about seven years. The HUD analysis also assumed that the GSEs
would maintain their fee structure throughout the ten-year period.
The GSEs argued that they would stop buying mortgages immediately – as soon
as the downturn started. In addition, they would raise their guarantee fees and their
service charges. And they would therefore survive for the full ten years.
HUD responded that the beginning of an economic downturn is generally not
recognized until some time has passed: “like many other businesses and observers of the
economy, FNMA and FHLMC could have difficulty diagnosing the beginning of a
downturn and even more difficulty distinguishing the beginning of a recession from the
beginning of a Depression. Therefore, it is foreseeable that FNMA’s or FHLMC’s
management would not take corrective action with respect to pricing or underwriting
until the economy was many months, or even years, into the Depression.” HUD also
questioned how raising fees and ceasing to purchase mortgages could be consistent with
the GSEs’ legislative requirement to have a continued presence in the secondary
mortgage market. (The first stated purpose of each GSE is to “provide stability in the
secondary market for residential mortgages,” according to the Fannie Mae Charter Act
and the Freddie Mac Corporation Act.)
The argument between HUD and the GSEs is summarized in the Capitalization
Study, “Overview,” Section III, especially pp. 8-9. The full analysis of the stress test,
including alternative scenarios, appears in Chapter II.
HUD lost the argument, politically. In 1992, Congress passed FHEFFSA, and
established a stress test for the GSEs, but that stress test was much less severe than the
Depression scenario. Instead, it was based on the Oil Patch downturn of the early 1980s.
Congress also established a minimum capital requirement of 2.5% for mortgages held in
portfolio and 0.45% mortgage-backed securities and other off-balance sheet obligations,
intended as a temporary requirement until the new independent regulator created in
FHEFSSA could put the stress test in place, and determinate how much additional capital
each GSE should hold. The stress test was complicated; the new financial safety and
soundness regulator (OFHEO) spent more than five years putting it in place and
evaluating the GSEs. Then it turned out that the enacted stress test was so weak that the
required capital level to be “adequately capitalized” was less than the 2.5% minimum
capital, for each GSE. This result was not what Congress expected in 1992.
Almost twenty years later, the outcome of that controversy is now clear. It turns
out that HUD was optimistic. Neither GSE could survive three years of a severe

35
economic downturn; they could barely survive two years. House prices flattened out in
the second quarter of 2006, according to the Case-Shiller national index, or in the second
quarter of 2007 according to the OFHEO home purchase index (now the FHFA index).
According to both indices, prices declined by 4-6% annually (far less than 10%) through
the summer of 2008. By that time, the GSEs were in great trouble and by the fall of 2008
they were in conservatorship.
The GSEs certainly did not stop buying mortgages when the downturn started –
and they did not have enough capital to last three years. They did raise their guarantee
fees in late 2008, however.

Why the Issue Matters
This episode has implications for current policy discussions.
First, the GSEs will not hold any more capital than they are forced to hold. The
HUD stress test indicated that Fannie Mae should have about 35 percent more capital
than it had, and Freddie Mac should have twice as much. The GSEs did not want to hold
anything like that amount; they wanted to rely on their then-implicit government
guarantee to borrow cheaply, instead of subjecting themselves to the discipline of the
financial markets. That incentive will remain for any reconstitution of the GSEs, with
either an implicit or explicit guarantee. Within the GSE framework, it is very difficult to
design “incentives to encourage appropriate alignment of risk bearing in the private
sector” or;” to promote market discipline,” important concerns raised in Question 2.
Second, it is virtually impossible for Congress to formulate an appropriate stress
test. Legislation prescribing the details of such a test is not an effective way of regulating
the GSEs. Econometric modeling is a complicated and highly technical process. The
serious and well-meaning effort of 1991-1992 resulted in a test whose results ran directly
counter to Congress’ expectations, and which failed to identify the GSEs’ burgeoning
problems in a timely manner. In a sense, Congress was fighting the last war. In the early
1980s, Fannie Mae was significantly underwater; interest rates rose sharply and Fannie
Mae had a large portfolio of low-interest loans from the 1970s. Eventually the
disinflation that resulted from a more stable monetary policy began to bring down
mortgage rates by 1983, but Congress remained focused on interest rate risk, giving little
attention to either credit risk or operations risk, both of which were important factors in
the debacle of 2008.
Third, in a balancing between public purpose and private profit, the GSE gives
more weight to private profit. The GSEs made no effort to address HUD’s concern about
the inherent conflict between its Charter Act responsibility to support the secondary
mortgage market in times of stress, and its strategy for surviving a serious economic
downturn.

36
Question 1: Federal Housing Objectives – Affordable Housing Goals
My second comment concerns the affordable housing goals and is relevant to
question 1: How should federal housing finance objectives be prioritized in the context
of the broader objectives of housing policy?
FHEFSSA assigned a continuing role in GSE regulation to the HUD Secretary.
He or she retained responsibility for issues other than safety and soundness. In 1993,
Secretary Henry Cisneros delegated that responsibility to the Assistant Secretary for
Housing, and that delegation remained in place until GSE regulation was consolidated
within the new Federal Housing Finance Agency, under the Housing and Economic
Recovery Act of 2008. As Assistant Secretary for Housing during 2001-2005, I therefore
was responsible for managing the GSE regulatory process within HUD.

The Affordable Housing Goals
Among its regulatory responsibilities, HUD was required to formulate the
affordable housing goals for the GSEs, and to monitor their performance. These goals
were established and specified by FHEFSSA (Part 2, Subpart B). They were intended to
codify one of the public purposes of the GSEs, namely, “to provide ongoing assistance to
the secondary market for residential mortgages (including activities relating to mortgages
on housing for low- and moderate-income families involving a reasonable economic
return that may be less than the return earned on other activities).” (This statement of
purpose appears in Section 301(3) of both the Fannie Mae Charter Act and the Freddie
Mac Corporation Act)
Within HUD, the process of formulating the affordable housing goals involved
four offices: the Office of General Counsel, the Office of Housing, the Office of Policy
Development and Research, and the Office of Fair Housing and Equal Opportunity. The
goals were established through formal rulemaking, following the procedures required
under the Administrative Procedures Act: a proposed rule, a comment period, a review of
comments by the Department, and a final rule. As with all rules, both the proposed rule
and the final rule were also reviewed by the Office of Management and Budget, which
also circulated the rule to other interested federal agencies and coordinated their
responses
The rule was always painstakingly developed, with extensive supporting analyses
as required by both the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act
of 1992 (FHEFSSA) and the Administrative Procedures Act. The rule and analyses
issued in 2004 were more than half the length of War and Peace. Like other rules, they
could be challenged, and must be able to withstand a challenge.
There are three statutory goals:

37
(4) The Low- and Moderate-Income Housing Goal: loans to borrowers with
incomes at or below the median income for the market area in which they live;
(5) The Special Affordable Goal: loans to very low-income borrowers (those
with incomes at or below 60 percent of the area median income), or to lowincome borrowers living in low-income areas (borrowers with incomes at or
below 80 percent of the area median income, living in census tracts in which
the median income of households is at or below 80 percent of the area median
income);
(6) The Underserved Areas Goal: loans to borrowers living in low-income census
tracts (tracts in which the median income of residents is at or below 90 percent
of the area median income) or high-minority tracts (tracts in which minorities
comprise at least 30 percent of residents, and the median income of residents
in the tract does not exceed 120 percent of the area median income).
The goals are commonly expressed in terms of the income of homebuyers or
homeowners, but they also cover rental housing. The Low- and Moderate-Income
Housing Goal, for example, includes loans to multifamily housing owners for rental units
that are affordable to households with incomes at or below the area median. Multifamily
rental housing located within underserved areas counted toward that goal, as well as
owner-occupied housing.
These are complicated definitions, because the concepts of “low-income,” etc.,
are defined in terms of the median income in the metropolitan area or nonmetropolitan
county, not in terms of national income categories, and because there are so many income
categories. For perspective, it might be helpful to keep in mind that the national “poverty
line” is about 40 percent of the national median household income. All of the income
levels employed as criteria in FHEFSSA are well above the poverty line.
The first of the goals is based on the income of the borrower or the renter; the
second is based partly on income and partly on location; the third is based on location. A
mortgage can count toward more than one goal; in fact, any loan that meets the Special
Affordable Goal also automatically counts toward the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal.
A mortgage to a very low-income borrower living in an underserved area counts toward
all three.
The goals are defined in the statute (Sections 1332, 1333, and 1334, respectively).
HUD is empowered to establish numerical targets for each goal: the percentage of each
GSE’s mortgage purchases that should count toward a goal. FHEFSSA set “transition
targets” to apply for at least the first two years and then HUD issued targets, by
regulation, that became effective in 1996, 2001, and 2005. The targets are shown in
Table 1. They are expressed as shares of the GSEs’ mortgage purchases, including both
loans purchased for portfolio and loans which serve as collateral for mortgage-backed
securities issued by the GSEs.

38
________________________________________________________________________
Table 1
GSE Affordable Housing Goals, 1993-2008
(share of mortgage purchases by GSEs)

Years
Low- and
Moderate-Income
1993-1995
1996
1997-2000
2001-2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

30%
40%
42%
50%
52%
53%
55%
56%

Goals
Special Affordable

Underserved Areas

NA
12%
14%
20%
22%
23%
25%
27%

30%
21%
24%
31%
37%
38%
38%
39%

NA – Not Applicable: goals were set in dollar amounts for each GSE rather than
percentages
The Underserved Areas goal was determined on the basis of 1990 Census tract geography
from 1993-2004, and on the basis of 2000 Census tract geography from 2005-2008.
________________________________________________________________________
The numerical targets are determined partly on the basis of activity in that part of
the mortgage market which the GSEs serve – the “conventional conforming market.”
The conventional conforming market excludes:
(1)
(2)
(3)

Federally insured or guaranteed loans: FHA, VA, Rural Housing Service
“B&C” loans: approximately the bottom half of the subprime market
Loans above the conforming loan limit, which until HERA was enacted in
2008 was set as the 90th percentile of the distribution of loans in the
conventional market. For 2008, prior to HERA, the conforming loan limit
was $417,000.
The conventional conforming market includes:

(1)
(2)
(3)

Prime loans: loans rated “A”
“A-minus” and “Alt-A” loans: approximately the top half of the subprime
market
Mortgages on manufactured homes

Under FHEFSSA, the GSEs were allowed to continue making the kinds of loans
they were making before the statute was enacted and the first numerical targets were

39
established by HUD. Analysis during the process leading up to the 2000 rule found that
the GSEs were making “A-minus” and “Alt-A” loans.

The Goals in Relation to the Conventional Conforming Market
By statute, the targets are to be set with reference to the performance and effort of
the enterprises toward achieving the targets in previous years; the share of the
conventional conforming market that is comprised of loans in a goal category; and the
ability of the GSEs to lead the industry in making loans in a goal category.
The policy issue raised by these factors is whether the GSEs “lead the market” or
“lag the market.” This is shorthand for whether the loans in a given goal category are
included in GSE purchases to the same extent that they are originated within the
conventional conforming market. To give a numerical example, if loans to borrowers
with incomes below the local median represent 50 percent of all loans in the conventional
conforming market in a particular year, then the GSEs are “leading the market” if such
loans represent 51 percent or more of their purchases, and they are “lagging the market”
if such loans represent 49 percent or less of their purchases. Under the targets established
in FHEFSSA to become effective in 1993, and the targets established by rulemaking as of
1996 and 2001, the GSEs were not asked to “lead the market” in any goal category; the
targets were consistently set so that they could be fulfilled even though the GSEs “lagged
the market.” Under the targets set as of 2005, the GSEs were asked to “meet the market.”
To avoid creating problems for the GSEs, the targets were phased in year-by-year over
the next four years. This is different from the procedures used in 2001, when the goals
were increased quite substantially from the old level to the new level in a single year, as
shown in Table 1.
The relationship between the targets and the market is shown in Table 2, which
compares each goal to the share of such loans in the market served by the GSEs, year by
year.
Table 2 is particularly relevant to a controversy about the goals established for
2005 and later years. The GSEs argued that the goals were too high; the actual market
shares of loans in each category were lower than the goals. Table 2 shows that, in fact,
all of the goals were set below the market in 2005 and 2006. It was possible for the GSEs
to meet the goals and still “lag the market .”

40
________________________________________________________________________
Table 2
GSE Affordable Housing Goals Compared to Market Shares
(Percentages of the Conventional Conforming Market Served by the GSEs)

Year

1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

Low- and Moderate-Income Special Affordable
Goal Market
Goal Market
30%
30
30
40
42
42
42
42
50
50
50
50
52
53
55
56

NR
NR
57%
57
57.5
54
58
59
55
50.0
53
58
57
55
52
54

NA
NA
N.A.
12
14
14
14
14
20
20
20
20
22
23
25
27

NA
NA
29%
29
29
26
29
30
26.5
23.5
24.5
28
28
27.5
24.7
26.5

Underserved Areas
Goal Market
30%
30
30
21
24
24
24
24
31
31
31
31
37
38
38
39

NR
NR
34%
33
34
31
34
35
33
34
34
42
44
44
40
42

NOTE: Market shares reported to nearest percent except where the share is halfway
between two percents (e.g., 57.5%), or where the market share is within one percent of
the goal.
NA – Not Applicable: goals were set in dollar amounts for each GSE rather than
percentages
NR – market shares not reported
The Underserved Areas goal was determined on the basis of 1990 Census tract geography
from 1993-2004, and on the basis of 2000 Census tract geography from 2005-2008.
Sources: 1993-1994, FHEFSSA, Sections 1332, 1333, 1334; 1995-2001, “2005 Proposed
Rule,” Federal Register, May 3, 2004, p. 24468.; 2002-2008, Federal Housing Finance
Agency, “The Housing Goals of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the Context of the
Mortgage Market: 1996-2009,” Mortgage Market Note 10-2, February 1, 2010, Appendix
B.
________________________________________________________________________

41

GSE Performance Vis-à-vis the Goals and the Market
In fact, that is what the GSEs did, annually from 1995 to 2005. Their
performance is shown in Table 3, which repeats the goals and the actual market share
from Table 2, and adds the actual purchases of each GSE toward each goal.
GSE performance was consistently above the goal, but below the share of the
GSE market that qualified for the goal.
(4) For the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal, both GSEs’ purchases exceeded the
goal but fell short of meeting the market from 1995 through 2005;
(5) For the Special Affordable Goal, Fannie Mae’s purchases exceeded the goal but
fell short of meeting the market from 1995 through 2005, and Freddie Mac’s
purchases exceeded the goal but fell short of meeting the market from 1995
through 2006;
(6) For the Underserved Areas goal, both GSEs’ purchases exceeded the goal but fell
short of meeting the market from 1995 through 2006, with the exception of 2002,
when Freddie Mac fell just short of the goal.
Freddie Mac’s failure to meet the Underserved Areas goal in 2002 occurred
because it double-counted loans which it had purchased in 2001 toward the goals in both
2001 and 2002. These loans covered 22,424 housing units. Correcting for the doublecounting, Freddie Mac fell short of the 31 percent Underserved Areas goal by 90 loans,
or 0.002 percent. There was a similar double-counting of 22,371 units toward the Lowand Moderate-Income Goal, but correcting this error did not affect Freddie Mac’s
performance; it continued to meet that goal in 2002. (This matter is described in the final
rule for 2005-2008, which appears in the Federal Register for November 2, 2004, on p.
63587 and in Table 6.)
In 2006, both GSEs’ purchases met the Low- and Moderate-Income Goal and also
met the market. This was also true with respect to Fannie Mae’s performance on the
Special Affordable Goal in that year.

Table 3
GSE Performance on Affordable Housing Goals
Year

1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

Low- and Moderate-Income
Goal
Market GSE Purchases Goal
FNMA FHLMC
30
30
30
40
42
42
42
42
50
50
50
50
52
53
55
56

57
57
57.5
54
58
59
55
50
53
58
57
55
52
53.6

46
46
44
46
49.5
51.5
52
52
53
55
57
55.5
53.7

41
43
43
46
50
53
50.5
51
52
54
56
56
51.5

N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
12
14
14
14
14
20
20
20
20
22
23
25
27

Special Affordable
Market
GSE Purchases
FNMA FHLMC
N.A.
N.A.
29
29
29
26
29
30
26.5
23.5
24.5
28
28
27.5
24.7
26.5

15
17
14.3
18
19
22
21
21
24
26
28
27
26.4

14
15
16
17
21
23
20.4
21
23
24
26
26
23

Goal
30
30
30
21
24
24
24
24
31
31
31
31
37
38
38
39

Underserved Areas
Market GSE Purchases
FNMA FHLMC
34
33
34
31
34
35
33
34
34
42
44
44
40
42

28
29
27
27
31
33
33
32
33.5
41
43.6
39.4
42

25
26
26
27.5
29
32
31.0*
33
32
42
43
43
38

* - Freddie Mac fell just short of underserved area goal in 2002, by 90 loans
NOTE: Market shares and GSE purchases reported to nearest percent except where the number is halfway between two percents (e.g.,
57.5%) or within one percent of the goal, or where the purchase number is within one percent of the market share.
NA – Not Applicable: goals were set in dollar amounts for each GSE rather than percentages
Source: Federal Housing Finance Agency, “The Housing Goals of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the Context of the Mortgage
Market: 1996-2009,” Mortgage Market Note 10-2, February 1, 2010, Appendix B.

43

What this means is that lenders other than the GSEs – lenders without the various special
privileges that gave the GSEs “agency status” and the ability to borrow at preferential rates in the
capital markets – consistently did a better job of serving households in each of these goal
categories than did the GSEs. Since loans to low- and moderate-income borrowers, for example,
were a smaller share of GSE purchases than they constituted in the conventional conforming
market, other lenders must have been buying a larger share of loans to low- and moderateincome borrowers than the GSEs. Those loans were a larger share of their portfolios than they
constituted in the portfolios of the GSEs.
In short, the concern expressed by the GSEs that they could not meet the goals for 2005
and later because they were “too high” was not borne out by the actual market shares available to
meet each goal, or by their purchases, during 2005 and 2006. .
The situation was different in 2007, and the GSEs responded to it differently, as will be
discussed later.

The Goals and the Subprime Mortgage Market
It has sometimes been asserted that the affordable housing goals established in 2005 are
substantially responsible for the GSEs’ collapse in 2008. For example, former Fannie Mae
senior officials expressed this view in recent testimony before the Financial Crisis Inquiry
Commission, and as did the former CEO of Freddie Mac earlier.
There is direct evidence on the extent to which the GSEs were buying subprime
mortgages, both before and after the 2005 rule went into effect. This evidence indicates that the
affordable housing goals had little if any impact on GSE activity in these markets. Instead, it
appears that the GSEs were responding to the same factors in the mortgage market as other
lenders.
Table 4 reports the dollar values of subprime and Alt-A mortgage purchases by the GSEs
during 2001-2007. As mentioned earlier, the GSEs had been buying A-minus and Alt-A loans
since the later 1990s, but they began buying subprime mortgage-backed securities (MBS)
heavily in 2002. Their subprime MBS purchases doubled between 2002 and 2003, and doubled
again in 2004 – from $38 billion to $81 billion to $176 billion. All this of course happened
before the housing goals were changed in 2005. After the new goals went into effect, their
subprime MBS purchases actually declined slightly, to $169 billion, and then dropped sharply to
$110 billion for 2006. Their share of the subprime MBS market rose from 19 percent in 2002 to
33 percent in 2004; then it declined to 27 percent in 2005 and further to 18 percent in 2006, after
the new goals were in place.
Essentially, what happened is that the market for subprime MBS took off in the early
years of the decade, and the GSEs became active in that market for a couple of years. Then they
began pulling back, at the same time that the affordable housing goals were increased.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 4

44
Subprime and Alt-A Purchases by the GSEs, 2001-2006
(Dollar amounts in billions)
Year

2001
2002
2003
2004

Subprime Loans and MBS
Dollar amount
Share of Market
N.A.
$ 38
$ 81
$176

Alt-A loans
Dollar Amount

N.A.
19%
26%
33%

$
$
$
$

15
66
77
64

27%
18%
31%

$ 77
$157
$178

2005: new affordable housing goals go into effect
2005
2006
2007

$169
$110
$ 59

Sources: loan data, OFHEO annual reports, “Mortgage Markets and the Enterprises;” size of
subprime market, Inside Mortgage Finance Publications, “The Rise and Fall of the Subprime
Market,” 2009.
________________________________________________________________________

The loan data come from a series of annual reports by the Office of Federal Housing
Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO), the GSE safety and soundness regulator, entitled “Mortgage
Markets and the Enterprises.” Also, it appears that OFHEO did not think that these purchases
posed a risk. In each report, the discussion of subprime purchases was followed immediately by
a section on overall single-family mortgage credit risk in which OFHEO concluded that the risk
was not great. Indeed, in the report for 2007, issued July 21, 2008, a week after the Bush
Administration offered a plan to rescue the GSEs and nine days before HERA was enacted, the
discussion was entitled, “Enterprises Continue to Manage Single-Family Credit Risk.” In the
2006 report, issued June 25, 2007, four months after subprime mortgage problems were widely
reported, the discussion of subprime purchases was followed by a section entitled, “Enterprise
Single-Family Credit Risk Remains Low.” Similar discussions appeared in earlier reports, going
back to 2001.
Table 4 also reports on Alt-A mortgages – loans where the borrower does not supply full
documentation in support of the application. Often the borrower does not provide income data.
Traditionally these were loans to higher-income borrowers with irregular incomes, such as the
self-employed. In recent years, they were extended to borrowers with much lower incomes.
The table shows that Alt-A purchases by the GSEs increased very sharply from 2001 to
2002, then fluctuated through 2005 (the first year of the new goals), and then doubled between
2005 and 2006. This might suggest that Alt-A purchases were influenced by the goals, at least in
2006. But Alt-A loans typically lack information on the borrower’s income, and two of the three
goals are based on income. Alt-A loans can qualify directly for the underserved area goal, but
not for the other two. Indeed, in its 2005 rule, HUD set forth criteria for counting Alt-A loans
toward the goals. (As noted earlier, the rule appears in the Federal Register for November 2,
2004; the discussion of Alt-A loans appears on pp. 63626-63627). Under those criteria, the more
Alt-A loans that the GSEs have bought, the harder it has been for them to meet the Low- and
Moderate-Income Goal and the Special Affordable Goal.

45

Table 4 is based on the annual studies released by OFHEO; the data are shown as
reported by OFHEO for the preceding year (for example, the 2005 report contains data for 2004).
In 2009, FHFA revised its 2008 Annual Report to Congress, to correct tables reporting Fannie
Mae’s purchases of private label securities for the years between 2002 and 2006. The 2008
Annual Report was originally submitted by FHFA on May 18, 2009, and revised on September
29. (The changes appear in Tables 1b and 5b of the revised report. The easiest way to track
them is to compare the revised 2008 report from FHFA to the 2007 report by OFHEO, which
reports the data before the revisions for each of the affected years.) The changes consist of
reclassifying private label securities originally listed as “other,” to “subprime” or “Alt-A” private
label securities. The most substantive change is a reclassification of $32.6 billion of “other”
adjustable rate single family private label purchases to “subprime” adjustable rate single family
private label purchases in 2004. There are also smaller reclassifications in the same direction
for 2003 and 2005, amounting to $9.9 billion and $8.1 billion, respectively. The effect of the
reclassifications is that subprime purchases rose more sharply from 2002 to 2004 than shown in
Table 4, and then declined much more precipitously in 2005 and 2006. Subprime purchases
apparently rose from about $40 billion in 2002 to $91 billion in 2003 and to $217 billion in 2004,
before the goals were increased. Subprime purchases then declined from $217 billion in 2004 to
$177 billion in 2005, the first year of the new goals, and finally to $111 billion in 2006.
There was a negligible impact on reported Alt-A purchases: less than $1 billion in any
year between 2002 and 2006, with no change in 2003.
The revised data indicate that the GSEs moved away from subprime mortgages much
more sharply between 2004 and 2005 than is depicted in Table 4. The data reinforce the earlier
conclusion that the increase in the goals had little if any effect on GSE purchases of subprime
mortgages. The GSEs began retreating from the subprime market, at the same time that the
affordable housing goals were increased.
Underwriting Changes and the Affordable Housing Goals
Further evidence on GSE behavior comes from an analysis by HUD staff economists,
published in the August 2008 issue of HUD’s periodical, “U.S. Housing Market Conditions.”
This study reports the distribution of mortgage-to-income ratios for the GSEs and other lenders
during 2001-2006. Higher ratios indicate greater risk of default – mortgage payment burdens
that will be a particularly large share of the borrower’s income. The data are shown in Table 5,
for loans in the 90th percentile of the mortgage-to-income ratio – close to the most risky loans
being made. To illustrate more directly the effect of the changes, the table also shows
comparable mortgage principal amount for a family with an income of $60,000, close to the
median family income for mortgage borrowers during 2004-2006.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 5
Risk-Taking by the GSEs and Other Lenders, 2001-2006
( for the 90th percentile of the distribution of home purchase loans)
Panel A – ratio of mortgage principal to income
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004

New goals:
2005 2006

46
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

335% 356% 383% 390%
322% 348% 376% 403%
328% 352% 384% 393%

397% 380%
389% 392%
388% 365%

Panel B – mortgage loan amount for family with $60,000 annual income
(dollar amounts in thousands, rounded to nearest thousand)
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

$201 $214 $230 $234
$193 $209 $226 $242
$197 $211 $230 $236

New goals:
2005 2006
$238 $228
$233 $235
$233 $219

SOURCE: “Using HMDA and Income Leverage to Examine Current Mortgage Market
Turmoil,” U.S. Housing Market Conditions, Second Quarter 2008, published by the U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research.
________________________________________________________________________
The GSEs began making significantly more risky loans to homebuyers beginning in
2002, offering larger loans to families with a given income level; they took still more risk in
2003. Beginning in 2004, their appetite for increased risk subsided, but their mortgage-toincome ratios remained high, and very nearly constant, through 2006.
The GSEs were not alone, as Table 5 shows. Beginning in 2002, other lenders were also
taking more risk by relaxing underwriting standards. These lenders – both portfolio lenders such
as commercial and community banks, and issuers of private mortgage pools – began taking more
risk in 2002 and continued to do so until 2005. They were not subject to the affordable housing
goals, but they behaved in the same way as the GSEs.
For homeowners who refinanced their mortgages, the GSEs relaxed their standards to a
much greater extent, beginning in 2002 and continuing through 2006. These data are shown in
Table 6.
________________________________________________________________________
Table 6
Risk-Taking by the GSEs and Other Lenders, 2001-2006
( for the 90th percentile of the distribution of home refinance loans)
Panel A – ratio of mortgage principal to income
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

331% 338% 347% 385%
314% 331% 346% 402%
346% 366% 388% 434%

New goals:
2005 2006
423% 429%
408% 394%
455% 438%

Panel B – mortgage loan amount for family with $60,000 annual income

47
(dollar amounts in thousands, rounded to nearest thousand)
Before the housing goals were increased:
2001 2002 2003 2004
GSEs
Portfolio Lenders
Private Mortgage Pools

$199 $203 $208 $231
$188 $199 $208 $241
$208 $220 $233 $260

New goals:
2005 2006
$254 $257
$245 $236
$273 $263

SOURCE: Same as Table 5.
________________________________________________________________________

This is particularly relevant because refinances are less likely to count toward the
affordable housing goals; in general, homebuyers have lower incomes than homeowners who are
refinancing, and homebuyers are more likely to live in “underserved” areas. If the GSEs were
being driven by the new affordable housing goals, they would have relaxed their standards more
for home purchase loans and less for refinances. Instead, they did the opposite. Again, other
lenders, not subject to the goals, followed the same pattern as the GSEs.
The increase in leveraging between 2001 and 2004 is far too large to be accounted for by
the decline in mortgage rates over those years. The decline in rates was about 110 basis points,
which is enough to permit about a 30-basis point increase in the mortgage-to-income ratio
without increasing the risk of default. For both home purchase loans and refinances, the
increase in the ratio for the GSEs was about 55 basis points during those years. In addition, GSE
mortgage-to-income ratios for refinances increased from 2004 to 2005 even though interest rates
were stable; and they remained at about the 2005 level even though mortgage rates increased by
over 50 basis points in 2006.
The GSEs relaxed their underwriting standards and began investing heavily in subprime
mortgage-backed securities well before the goals were increased in 2005. After the goal
increase, the GSEs maintained about the same underwriting standards, at least for home purchase
loans, the most likely to count toward any of the housing goals. Despite the increase in the
goals, the GSEs did not take further underwriting risk in order to meet them.

What Happened in 2007?
By the beginning of 2007, problems in the housing and mortgage markets were becoming
evident. New home construction began to contract in mid-2006, and house prices as measured
by the Case-Shiller Index started to drop at about the same time. Prices as measured by the
OFHEO repeat-sales index – an index based on the homes on which the GSEs had actually
bought the mortgages – were still rising, but more slowly than they had been prior to 2006; the
OFHEO index began to decline in the second quarter of 2007. At the same time, there were
growing problems in the subprime market. In early February, HSBC and New Century reported
unexpectedly large losses on subprime mortgages; they were the subjects of front-page stories in
the Wall Street Journal on consecutive days. From that point, subprime mortgage problems were
regularly in the news. The subprime market began to shrivel.
Also, by the beginning of 2007, lenders were tightening their standards for subprime
loans. The financial regulators issued guidance to financial institutions on nontraditional

48
mortgage product risks in October 2006, and followed it with proposed guidance on subprime
lending in March 2007, and final guidance in June. The former guidance urged institutions to
recognize that non-traditional mortgages are “untested in a stressed environment,” and that they
require strong risk management and capital standards and loss reserves commensurate with the
risk. The later guidance expressed concern about the “heightened risks” to lenders as well as
borrowers from subprime ARMs with teaser rates such as 2/28 and 3/27 loans, loans with very
high or no payment or rate caps, low-doc and no-doc loans, and substantial prepayment
penalties, and stated that institutions should develop strong control systems in order to manage
the risks.
This guidance also applied to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, but with a lag. OFHEO
notified Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in December 2006 that they were required to comply with
the guidance on non-traditional mortgage product risks, but the GSEs did not agree to comply
until July 2007, and even then indicated that they would continue to buy non-traditional
mortgages until September 2007. Similarly, OFHEO told the GSEs in March 2007 that they
must follow the later statement on subprime mortgage lending, but the GSEs did not agree to
comply until September.
The actions of OFHEO and the other financial regulators would have been a perfect
opportunity for the GSEs to ask HUD for relief from the 2007 affordable housing goals. The
subprime market was in the process of shrinking by almost 70 percent from the 2006 level, and
the safety and soundness regulator was telling the GSEs that they should get out of that market.
The section of FHEFSSA establishing the housing goals states that the Secretary of HUD must
consider “the need to maintain the sound financial condition of the enterprises.” (This appears as
Section 1332 (b)(6), Section 1333 (a)(2)(E), and Section 1334 (b)(6).) HUD could hardly have
insisted that the GSEs continue to buy A- subprime loans – the top half of the subprime market –
as the total subprime market shrank, even if house prices were not dropping.
But the GSEs apparently did not make such a request to HUD, nor did they ask OFHEO
to do so. The OFHEO director at that time told the FCIC that he had no knowledge of any such
request by either GSE directly to HUD.
Instead, the GSEs continued to buy subprime mortgages. In 2007, their share of the
subprime market increased to 31 percent, close to the 2004 level.
The GSEs made the decision to continue buying subprime mortgages, despite the efforts
of their regulator to compel them to get out of that market. They did not seek relief from the
affordable housing goals. They apparently thought there were profits in the subprime market,
and they stayed in it.

The Affordable Housing Goals Relative to the Broader Objectives of Housing Policy
Question 1 asks how policy objectives such as the affordable housing goals should be
prioritized in the context of overall federal housing policy. The history of the affordable housing
goals since FHEFSSA carries two lessons.
First, while public policy goals can be advanced in the context of broader housing policy
objectives, the process is complicated and probably not the most effective way to achieve the
policy goals. The evidence indicates that the affordable housing goals had little if any impact on
the credit risk problems of the GSEs. But at the same time, the goals were set “below the

49
market,” meaning that lenders other than the GSEs were buying more loans that met the goals
than did the GSEs themselves. The extent to which the goals achieved public policy purposes is
therefore somewhat problematical.
Second, the affordable housing goals exemplify a basic conflict between public purpose
and private profit. The GSEs were privately-owned corporations whose stockholders expected
that they would be profitable; in fact, they were told to expect high and rising returns by GSE
management. At the same time, they were required to devote resources to achieving public
policy objectives. In that tug-of-war between those objectives, private profit consistently won.
This was the case for both the affordable housing goals and the capital requirements

Conclusion
If the affordable housing goals do not account for the GSEs’ purchases of high-risk
subprime mortgages, what does? The best explanation is the simplest. The GSEs badly
misjudged the risk of subprime and Alt-A mortgages. They thought there were large profits to
be made in the growing subprime market, and they sought to maintain and expand their share of
the home mortgage market. They were not alone in misjudging the risks of subprime mortgages;
so did other lenders. Indeed, the GSEs were by no means the first lenders to run into problems
with their non-prime portfolios; as mentioned earlier, HSBC and New Century were front-page
news in February 2007. But the GSEs, because they were bigger – and were required to hold
less capital – took the biggest risks and had the most spectacular problems.
The GSEs have made other misjudgments than threatened their solvency. Economists
have often analyzed risk for financial institutions along three dimensions: interest rate risk, credit
risk, operations risk. The GSEs have experienced all three, often spectacularly.
In the early1980s, as mentioned earlier; Fannie Mae faced enormous interest rate risk
problems. It had purchased large volumes of mortgages carrying low interest rates in the later
1970s; it then had to fund those mortgages with expensive borrowing in the 1980s. The low-rate
portfolio was colloquially termed the “block of granite.” Fannie Mae tried to chip away at it
whenever it was possible. But until mortgage rates turned down in the mid-1980s, Fannie Mae
was significantly underwater. The market value of its assets was less than the market value of its
liabilities.
In the early 2000s, both GSEs incurred operations risk on a large scale. Freddie Mac’s
accounting problems first came to public attention in 2003; it had been smoothing out its
reported earnings, to persuade investors that it was “steady Freddie” – a good investment
regardless of market conditions. In 2004, it became known that Fannie Mae had a policy of
manipulating earnings so that its top executives would get very large bonuses.
The credit risk problems leading to the conservatorship of 2008 are the most recent
example. The GSEs bought risky loans that went bad, not understanding the risks they were
taking. When their financial position became precarious, it was much more convenient for the
GSEs to blame the affordable housing goals, than to admit to mistakes made by their own choice.
Many years ago in graduate school I studied economic history under a distinguished
expert in the history of banking and finance, the late Earl J. Hamilton. He once observed that
financial reform in the United States had occurred under three circumstances: during wars,
during depressions, and during the first term of President Woodrow Wilson. Since then, he

50
would have found it necessary to add another circumstance: during inflations, to account for the
collapse of the housing finance system as a result of the unprecedented peacetime inflation of the
late 1960s and 1970s. The common feature of all these circumstances is that they were periods
of extreme economic stress. (The reforms under President Wilson were a reaction to the severe
depression of 1907 and the recognition that the National Banking System had outlived its ability
to serve the economy effectively.)
The extraordinary collapse of the GSEs does not fit into this pattern. It occurred during a
period of economic growth, with low inflation. This is a unique experience in our history.
It occurred because the GSEs were able to build up substantial political clout, as
witnessed by the weak regulatory structure established in FHEFSSA. A significant component
of that regulatory structure concerned the capital standard; the GSEs did not have to hold capital
to the same extent as other mortgage lenders. The GSEs were politically strong enough to stave
off financial reform legislation after their accounting problems were identified, and even after
they became bywords for incompetence.
Fundamentally, the structure of the mortgage market after FIRREA - two large
institutions sponsored by the federal government with competitive advantages over other lenders
– generated the problems that we confront today.
Public policy should not make the same mistakes again.