View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Tobias Adrian, Karin Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni

The Federal Reserve’s
Commercial Paper
Funding Facility
1. Introduction

T

he commercial paper market experienced considerable
strain in the weeks following Lehman Brothers’
bankruptcy on September 15, 2008. The Reserve Primary
Fund—a prime money market mutual fund with $785 million
in exposure to Lehman Brothers—“broke the buck” on
September 16, triggering an unprecedented flight to quality
from high-yielding to Treasury-only money market funds.
These broad investor flows within the money market sector
severely disrupted the ability of commercial paper issuers to
roll over their short-term liabilities.
As redemption demands accelerated, particularly in highyielding money market mutual funds, investors became
increasingly reluctant to purchase commercial paper, especially
for longer dated maturities. As a result, an increasingly high
percentage of outstanding paper had to be refinanced each day,
interest rates on longer term commercial paper increased
significantly, and the volume of outstanding paper declined
sharply. These market disruptions had the potential to
constrain the economic activities of commercial paper issuers.
Indeed, a large share of outstanding commercial paper is issued
or sponsored by financial intermediaries, and the difficulties
they faced placing commercial paper further reduced their
ability to meet the credit needs of businesses and households.
In light of these strains, the Federal Reserve announced the
creation of the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF) on

Tobias Adrian is a vice president, Karin Kimbrough an assistant vice president,
and Dina Marchioni a markets officer at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Correspondence: tobias.adrian@ny.frb.org

October 7, 2008, with the aim of supporting the orderly
functioning of the commercial paper market. Registration for
the CPFF began October 20, 2008, and the facility became
operational on October 27. The CPFF operated as a lenderof-last-resort facility for the commercial paper market. It
effectively extended access to the Federal Reserve’s discount
window to issuers of commercial paper, even if these issuers
were not chartered as commercial banks. Unlike the discount
window, the CPFF was a temporary liquidity facility that was
authorized under section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act in
the event of “unusual and exigent circumstances.” It expired
February 1, 2010.1
The goal of the CPFF was to address temporary liquidity
distortions in the commercial paper market by providing a
backstop to U.S. issuers of commercial paper. This liquidity
backstop provided assurance to both issuers and investors that
firms would be able to roll over their maturing commercial
paper. The facility enabled issuers to engage in term lending
funded by commercial paper issuance, which in turn enhanced
the ability of financial intermediaries to extend crucial credit
to U.S. businesses and households.
The CPFF did not address the solvency of issuing firms.
Rather, the focus was on shielding the allocation of real
economic investment from liquidity distortions created by the
run on high-yielding money market instruments that had been
1

Initially, the CPFF was set to expire on April 30, 2009, but it was extended
to October 30 and subsequently to February 1, 2010.

The authors thank Sarah Bell, Marco Del Negro, Michael Fleming, Kenneth
Garbade, Warren Hrung, Peter Kyle, James McAndrews, Patricia Mosser,
Robert Patalano, and Joshua Rosenberg for substantial comments and
contributions. Some sections of this paper are based on notes prepared by
James McAndrews and Joshua Rosenberg in October 2008. Hoai-Luu Nguyen
and Jordan Winder provided outstanding research assistance. The views
expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position
of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

25

triggered by the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. The facility
was explicitly designed to protect the Federal Reserve from
potential credit losses. Issuance to the CPFF was either secured
by collateral or subject to an additional surcharge, which was
calibrated to protect the Federal Reserve from any potential
credit losses.
This paper offers an overview of the Commercial Paper
Funding Facility. We explain the economic role of the
commercial paper market as a source of funding for various
financial intermediaries. We briefly review the events
surrounding the turmoil that led to the creation of the CPFF.
Our study also presents operational details of the CPFF and
documents its usage and effectiveness. In addition, we discuss
the economics of the facility in the context of the financial
system and in relation to the Federal Reserve’s role as lender
of last resort. Also considered are issues associated with the risk
of moral hazard that have been raised following the launch of
the CPFF.

2. Background on the Commercial
Paper Market
The commercial paper market is used by commercial banks,
nonbank financial institutions, and nonfinancial corporations
to obtain short-term external funding. There are two main
types of commercial paper: unsecured and asset-backed.
Unsecured commercial paper consists of promissory notes
issued by financial or nonfinancial institutions with a fixed
maturity of 1 to 270 days, unless the paper is issued with the
option of an extendable maturity. Unsecured commercial
paper is not backed by collateral, which makes the credit rating
of the originating institution a key variable in determining
the cost of issuance.
Asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) is collateralized
by other financial assets and therefore is a secured form of
borrowing. Historically, senior tranches of asset-backed
securities (ABS) have served as collateral for ABCP. As such,
ABCP is a financial instrument that has frequently provided
maturity transformation: While the underlying loans or
mortgages in the ABS are of long maturity (typically five to
thirty years), ABCP maturities range between 1 and 270 days.
Institutions that issue ABCP first sell their assets to a
bankruptcy-remote special-purpose vehicle (SPV).2 The SPV
then issues the ABCP, which is backed by the assets in the
2

An SPV is a legal entity created to serve a particular function—in this case,
purchasing or financing specific assets. “Bankruptcy remoteness” refers to
assets of an SPV being shielded from the bankruptcy of the sponsoring
institution.

26

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

Chart 1

Outstanding Commercial Paper
and the Money Stock Measure (M1)
Billions of dollars

2,500
All issuers

2,000

1,500
M1

1,000

Asset-backed

500
0
1980

Financial
companies

85

90

95

00

05

10

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

vehicle and also by backup credit lines of the sponsoring
institution. If the sponsoring institution enters bankruptcy,
the assets of the SPV do not become part of the sponsor’s
pool of assets.
All commercial paper is traded in the over-the-counter
market, where money market desks of securities broker-dealers
and banks provide underwriting and market-making services.
In the United States, commercial paper is cleared and settled
by the Depository Trust Company (DTC).3
Commercial paper provides institutions with direct access
to the money market. In traditional bank-intermediated
financial systems, borrowing institutions obtain loans from
commercial banks, which in turn are funded primarily by
deposits. Since the early 1980s, however, the U.S. financial
system has undergone a major transformation, as an everincreasing fraction of credit intermediation migrated from
banks to financial markets.
One way to gauge the degree to which this process of
disintermediation affected the commercial paper market is to
compare outstanding commercial paper with the money stock.
Commercial paper represented only 30 percent of the money
stock measure (M1) in 1980. It overtook M1 in mid-1998 and,
at its peak, was 60 percent larger than M1 in August 2007
(Chart 1).4 The sharp contractions of commercial paper in
2007 and 2008 led the ratio of commercial paper to M1 to fall
3

DTC is a subsidiary of the Depository Trust and Clearing Corporation.
See http://www.dtcc.com/.
4
M1 consists of: 1) currency outside the U.S. Treasury, Federal Reserve Banks,
and the vaults of depository institutions; 2) travelers checks of nonbank issuers;
3) demand deposits; and 4) other checkable deposits.

below 72 percent in the second half of 2009, a fraction not seen
since the mid-1990s.
The mix of unsecured commercial paper and ABCP in the
market has varied considerably over the last few years, as ABCP
represented more than 45 percent of the market between 2001
and 2007. The rise of ABCP is intertwined with the growth
of securitization. Since 1998, financial intermediaries have
increasingly relied on ABCP as a source of funding for assets
warehoused for securitization.5 In the decade prior to the crisis,
ABCP increased from $250 billion in 1997 to more than
$1 trillion by 2007 (that is, from roughly 20 percent to as much
as 50 percent of outstanding commercial paper), fueled by the
considerable distribution of residential mortgage exposure
through structured finance products.
Outstanding commercial paper peaked at a total market
value of $2.2 trillion in August 2007. At that time, ABCP
accounted for more than 52 percent of the total market,
while financial commercial paper accounted for an additional
38 percent and nonfinancial commercial paper approximately
10 percent. Between August 15, 2007, and September 15, 2008,
the market experienced a notable decline associated with
mounting credit problems of ABCP collateral. The initial
decline of outstanding ABCP is often used to date the
beginning of the first wave of the 2007-09 financial crisis.6
As the deterioration of the U.S. housing market accelerated
in the summer of 2007, the riskiness of the ABS used as
collateral in ABCP transactions increased. As a result, ABCP
issuers struggled to issue commercial paper.
Between September 2007 and January 2008, total assets of
commercial banks grew unusually fast as many ABS that were
previously funded in the ABCP market were moved from the
balance sheets of ABCP issuers to those of commercial banks.
As a result of a drying up of funding in the ABCP market,
commercial banks started to fund the ABS in unsecured money
markets, such as the Libor (London interbank offered rate),
Eurodollar, and commercial paper markets, all of which would
also become compromised at the peak of the crisis as credit risk
reached extreme levels.

2.1 Major Commercial Paper Issuers
The Flow of Funds Accounts of the Federal Reserve provide an
overview of issuers in the commercial paper market since the
early 1980s (Chart 2). In the past decade, ABS issuers were the
largest issuers of commercial paper, usually in the form of

Chart 2

Commercial Paper Issuers
Billions of dollars

2,500
2,000
Total

1,500
Commercial
banks
Asset-backedsecurities issuers

1,000

500
0
1983 85

Financial
companies

90

Nonfinancial

95

00

Foreign

05

09

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

ABCP. Commercial paper funding of ABS stopped growing
after Enron’s bankruptcy in 2001, as changes in accounting
and regulatory practices concerning off-balance-sheet entities
required that additional capital be held against the entities
on the balance sheet.7 At the end of 2003, capital regulation
regarding off-balance-sheet conduits changed, and the growth
of ABS-issued commercial paper resumed. Indeed, the growth
in ABS issuance goes hand in hand with the growth of
outstanding ABCP.
The second-largest issuers of commercial paper in recent
years have been foreign issuers of U.S.-dollar-denominated
paper, which include foreign banks and other financial
institutions. Other issuers of commercial paper include finance
companies, nonfinancial corporations, and commercial banks.
For commercial banks, commercial paper issuance is relatively
expensive; a combination of deposits—checking deposits, term
deposits, or certificates of deposit—and borrowing in the
federal funds market is usually a less expensive funding
alternative than commercial paper (Chart 3), although a bank
holding company might issue commercial paper more readily
given the limited availability of deposits and financing that
can be transferred from its commercial banks.8 However,
commercial paper does provide a marginal source of funding
to the commercial banking sector and, at times—and at least
for certain issuers—commercial paper rates are actually lower
than other money market rates, such as Eurodollar rates.
7

5

For an overview of asset-backed commercial paper, see Covitz, Liang, and
Suarez (2009). Overviews of the securitization markets are provided by Adrian,
Ashcraft, and Pozsar (2009) and Acharya and Schnabl (2010).
6
For a comprehensive timeline of the financial crisis, see http://
timeline.stlouisfed.org/.

For an overview of recent accounting changes concerning off-balance-sheet
vehicles, see http://www.fasb.org/cs/ContentServer?c=FASBContent
_C&pagename=FASB%2FFASBContent_C%2FNewsPage&cid=1176155633483.
8
The relationship between commercial banks and affiliated subsidiaries is
constrained by section 23A of the Federal Reserve Act; see http://
www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed/section23a.htm.

FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

27

Chart 3

Chart 4

Federal Funds, One-Month Libor,
and Commercial Paper Rates

Commercial Paper Holdings by Investor Class
Billions of dollars

2,500

Percent

6
2,000

Libor

5

Total

4

1,500

3

1,000
Money market
mutual funds

Financial
commercial
paper

2
1

500

Federal funds

06

07

08

Other financial

0
1983 85

0
2005

Government
Foreign

09

Nonfinancial

90

95

00

05

09

10
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Note: Libor is the London interbank offered rate.

As credit conditions deteriorated in the second half of 2007,
many commercial banks took back onto their balance sheets
obligations that were formerly held in off-balance-sheet
vehicles and funded in the ABCP market. As a result, funding
for these loans, mortgages, and securities migrated from the
ABCP market to the unsecured interbank market, leading to
a widening of the spread between Libor and the federal
funds rate.

2.2 Lenders in the Commercial Paper Market
Commercial paper is held by many classes of investors (Chart 4).
The largest share of ownership is by money market mutual funds,
followed by the foreign sector, and then by mutual funds that are
not money market mutual funds. Other financial institutions that
hold commercial paper include nonfinancial corporations,
commercial banks, insurance companies, and pension funds.
The creation of the Commercial Paper Funding Facility is
closely tied to the operation of money market mutual funds.
Money market funds in the United States are regulated by the
Securities and Exchange Commission’s (SEC) Investment
Company Act of 1940. Rule 2a-7 of the Act restricts
investments by quality, maturity, and diversity. Under this
rule, money market funds are limited to investing mainly in
highly rated debt with maturities of less than thirteen months.
A fund’s portfolio must maintain a weighted-average maturity
of ninety days or less, and money market funds cannot invest
more than 5 percent in any one issuer, except for government

28

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

securities and repurchase agreements (repos). Eligible money
market securities include commercial paper, repos, short-term
bonds, and other money market funds.
Money market funds seek a stable $1 net asset value (NAV).
If a fund’s NAV drops below $1, the fund is said to have
“broken the buck.” Money market funds, to preserve a stable
NAV, must have securities that are liquid and have low credit
risk. Between 1971—when the first money market fund was
created in the United States—and September 2008, only one
2a-7 fund had broken the buck: the Community Bankers U.S.
Government Money Market Fund of Denver, in 1994. In light
of disruptions to the sector in 2008, the SEC is currently
reevaluating 2a-7 guidelines and considering the mandating
of floating NAVs and the shortening of weighted-average
maturities.9

2.3 The Commercial Paper Crisis
of September 2008
Considerable strains in the commercial paper market emerged
following the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. on
September 15, 2008. Exposure to Lehman forced the Reserve
Primary Fund to break the buck on September 16. As a result,
money market investors reallocated their funds from prime
money market funds to those that held only government
securities (Chart 5).

9

For more details on the money market mutual fund universe and the
regulation of 2a-7 funds, see http://www.sec.gov/answers/mfmmkt.htm.

Chart 5

U.S. Money Market Fund Assets by Fund Type
Billions of dollars

2,500
Prime

2,000

1,500
Government

1,000

500
0
2007

2008

2009

2010

Source: iMoney.
Note: The band denotes September 16-October 21.

This reallocation unleashed a tidal wave of redemption
demands that overwhelmed the funds’ immediate liquid
reserves. In the week following the Lehman bankruptcy, prime
money market mutual funds received more than $117 billion
in redemption requests from investors concerned about losses
on presumably safe investments, possible contagion from
Lehman’s bankruptcy, and financial institutions with large
exposures to subprime assets. As a result, 2a-7 money market
mutual funds were reluctant, and in some cases unable, to
purchase commercial paper (or other money market assets
with credit exposure). Any purchases made were concentrated
in very short maturities; shortening the duration of their asset
holdings made it easier for money market funds to manage
uncertainty over further redemptions.
As demand by money market funds shrank, commercial
paper issuers were unable to issue term paper and instead
issued overnight paper. Thus, with each passing maturity date
of commercial paper outstanding, an issuer’s rollover risk
increased sharply. Banks bore the increasing risk of having their
credit lines drawn by issuers unable to place commercial paper
in the market precisely when the banks themselves were having
difficulty securing funding from the market and were
attempting to reduce risk.10
More broadly, the deepening dysfunction in the commercial
paper market risked greater disruptions across the real
economy. The sudden disruption in commercial paper
issuance led to higher issuing costs, forced asset sales by entities

unable to raise cash, resulted in greater insolvency risk among
issuers, and increased pressure on credit lines from commercial
banks. Together, these factors resulted in reduced credit
availability to individuals and businesses generally.
The commercial paper market was vulnerable to the credit,
rollover, and liquidity risks that, although small in a period
of stable rates and high liquidity, emerged in the wake of
the Lehman crisis. Investors averse to credit risk shunned
commercial paper issuers that had previously been considered
of high quality but were now thought to be candidates for
default. Domestic financial paper issuance plummeted 24 percent in late 2008. Likewise, rollover risk—the likelihood that
investors will have to be compensated when the issuer rolls
over the maturing paper—is magnified when issuers face lack
of demand. A combination of liquidity risk and jump-todefault risk was manifested through sharp increases in the rates
on A2/P2-rated nonfinancial paper, whose spreads in excess
of the overnight index swap (OIS) rate rose from 296 basis
points on the Friday prior to Lehman’s bankruptcy to 504 basis
points one week later. Over the period from September 15 to
December 31, the spread averaged 539 basis points. These
inherent risks in commercial paper were heightened as money
market mutual funds, the principal investors in commercial
paper, retreated from this market.
In the month following the Lehman bankruptcy,
commercial paper outstanding shrank by $300 billion. About
70 percent of this sharp decline was led by the financial
commercial paper sector, while 20 percent was attributed to
a shrinking of the ABCP market. Notably, the nonfinancial
sector was responsible for only a 6 percent retrenchment in the
size of total commercial paper outstanding. In the period
between the Lehman bankruptcy and the start of the CPFF,
total outstanding commercial paper fell sharply, to $1.5 trillion
from $1.8 trillion. By the end of September 2008, more than
75 percent of commercial paper financing was being rolled over
each day, leaving the market unusually exposed to additional
liquidity shocks.
As rollover risk escalated, institutions relying on
commercial paper were increasingly vulnerable to bankruptcy
if money market fund investors pulled away from the
commercial paper market. Concerned by this growing risk,
the Federal Reserve considered ways to stabilize short-term
funding markets by providing additional sources of funding to
stave off liquidity-driven defaults and help reduce rollover risk.

2.4 The Federal Reserve’s Response
10

Commercial banks provide a liquidity backstop for issuers of commercial
paper. Rating agencies require that issuers have in place lines of credit in a
stipulated percentage of the maximum dollar amount of commercial paper
that may be outstanding under the program. See Bond Market Association
and Depository Trust and Clearing Corporation (2003).

The CPFF was part of a series of extraordinary policy
interventions in late 2008 by the Federal Reserve and other U.S.
government agencies. Other important interventions included:
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

29

1.

the expansion of eligible collateral for the Primary Dealer
Credit Facility (PDCF) and the Term Securities Lending
Facility (TSLF) on September 14;

2.

the expansion of foreign exchange swap lines with foreign
central banks on September 18;

3.

the creation, on September 19, of the Asset-Backed
Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity
Facility (AMLF), which extended “nonrecourse loans”
(secured loans on which lenders can seize pledged
collateral to minimize loss upon default) at the primary
credit rate to U.S. depository institutions and bank
holding companies to finance their purchases of highquality ABCP from money market mutual funds;

4.

the announcement of a temporary guarantee program
for money market mutual funds on September 19;

5.

the October 14 announcement by the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) of the creation of the
Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program (TLGP) to
guarantee the senior debt of all FDIC-insured institutions
and their holding companies as well as deposits in
non-interest-bearing deposit transactions;

6.

the announcement of the Money Market Investor
Funding Facility (MMIFF) on October 21;

7.

the creation of the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan
Facility (TALF) on November 25, under which the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York was authorized to lend up
to $200 billion on a nonrecourse basis to holders of
AAA-rated ABS and recently originated consumer
and small-business loans; and

8.

the November 25 announcement by the Federal Reserve
that it would purchase the direct obligations of housingrelated government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) and
mortgage-backed securities backed by the GSEs.11

3. CPFF Design and Operation
The Commercial Paper Funding Facility was designed to
stabilize short-term financing markets by providing an
additional source of funding to institutions to help them
reduce reinvestment risk and stave off liquidity-driven
defaults. To accomplish this, a special-purpose vehicle—the
CPFF LLC—was created to purchase ninety-day commercial
11

See Adrian, Burke, and McAndrews (2009) for more on the PDCF; Fleming,
Hrung, and Keane (2009) for details on the TSLF; Davis, McAndrews, and
Franklin (2009) for a review of the MMIFF; Ashcraft, Malz, and Pozsar (2010)
for more on the TALF; and Adrian and Shin (2010) for an overview of the
liquidity facilities in a broader context. The impact of the CPFF and other
credit and liquidity programs on the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and its
income statement is described at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/bst_fedfinancials.htm.

30

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

paper from highly rated U.S. issuers and effectively pledge it to
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in exchange for cash.
In the twenty days between the announcement of the CPFF
and its first purchases from registered users, Federal Reserve
staff fine-tuned the facility’s terms and conditions and its
operational design, which included building a new legal,
trading, investment, custodial, and administrative
infrastructure as well as establishing essential financial and
operational risk controls. For the CPFF to be effective as a
liquidity backstop, it had to be simple to use, compliant with
existing market conventions, open to a large cross section of the
commercial paper market while minimizing credit risk to the
Reserve Bank, priced to relieve funding market pressures, and
implemented quickly to forestall another liquidity event. The
facility’s terms and conditions ultimately addressed these
objectives.12

3.1 Operational Design
A market backstop required accessibility by any issuer in the
market. However, purchases of commercial paper could not be
open to any firm needing access to short-term funding, as this
would have deviated from the intent of offering a backstop to
issuers whose short-term funding was disrupted by liquidity
events rather than the firm’s own credit event. To minimize
credit risk, the Federal Reserve limited purchases to top-tier
paper, rated A1/P1/F1 or higher, consistent with 2a-7 fund
conventions in place at the time.13 In late 2008, top-tier
commercial paper accounted for nearly 90 percent of the
market, indicating that the criterion would allow the facility to
backstop the vast majority of the market while also shielding
the Federal Reserve from lower quality credits in the market.
To effectively reduce rollover risk, the CPFF had to offer
term financing beyond what the Federal Reserve had extended
up to that point.14 Since term commercial paper is most liquid
at one- and three-month tenors and funding concerns for the
year-end were mounting, three-month commercial paper
became the logical tenor to offer issuers. Furthermore, the
facility gave assurance that the purchases of commercial paper
would be held to maturity rather than liquidated shortly
thereafter.

12

For a comprehensive overview of terms and conditions, frequently asked
questions, announcements, and operational details relating to the CPFF,
see http://www.ny.frb.org/markets/cpff.html.
13
A split rating was acceptable if two ratings were top-tier.
14
The Fed had already started the twenty-eight-day Term Auction Facility
(TAF) in December 2007. On July 30, 2008, an extension to an eighty-four-day
maturity was announced, with an effective date of August 11, 2008. For an
overview of the TAF, see Armantier, Krieger, and McAndrews (2008).

Issuance to the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF)
Issuance Request
Issuer

Trade Details
Primary
Dealer

FRBNY
Transaction Agent

Approval

Eligibility
Approval
Vendor
Oversight

Loan
Request

$

Trade
Details

Issuer’s
Issuing and
Paying Agent

Trade
Reconciliation

FRBNY
CPFF

$

$

Commercial
Paper

FRBNY
Discount Window

Depository
Trust
Company

Custodian Bank
CPFF
Special-Purpose
Vehicle

$
Commercial
Paper

Program
Management
Financial
Reporting

Note: Solid lines represent steps in the transaction; dashed lines represent some of the controls.

In establishing the CPFF, the Federal Reserve faced the
added complication of engaging in transactions that fell
outside of the central bank’s traditional operating framework.
Prior to the creation of the CPFF, temporary emergency
lending facilities created under section 13(3) of the Federal
Reserve Act were forms of secured borrowing with traditional
counterparties—that is, depository institutions or primary
dealers. To address the risks that had emerged in the
commercial paper market, the Federal Reserve had to expand
its lending to include U.S. corporations as well as financial
institutions that would usually not have direct access to its
market operations (finance companies, for example).
The Federal Reserve’s financial transactions were limited
to open market operations with primary dealers and loans
to depository institutions through the discount window.15
The CPFF operation married aspects of both types of Fed
operations with the market conventions of the commercial
paper market. To execute CPFF transactions, the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York used its primary dealers as agents
to the transactions between the Fed and commercial paper
issuers. Primary dealers actively underwrite, place, and make
markets in the commercial paper market, and they had the
ability to funnel CPFF issuance from their clientele to the
facility each day.
By designating primary dealers as agents to the CPFF
transactions, the facility effectively expanded its reach to
hundreds of firms looking for backstop financing. Trade
execution was conducted electronically, with controls and
accuracy checks, and processed “straight through” with limited

manual intervention, allowing multitudes of trades to be
executed quickly and accurately and settled on the same day.
The same-day settlement feature assured firms that the CPFF
could meet an unexpected liquidity need.
Building the facility’s infrastructure in a compressed
timeframe proved a substantial challenge, so the Federal
Reserve enlisted the services of experienced market
participants, including Pacific Investment Management
Company (PIMCO) and State Street Bank and Trust
Company. The SPV created by the Federal Reserve—
CPFF LLC—was held in custody at State Street, a depository
institution. Creating the SPV facilitated discount window
lending to the commercial paper market. Each day, CPFF
purchases were matched by a loan from the New York Fed’s
discount window to the custodian bank, which then
transferred the loan amount to the SVP to fund the purchases.
At maturity, the transaction unwound this way: The issuer
paid the CPFF LLC the loan principal plus interest, which was
determined by the interest rate set on the date of issuance, and
the SPV paid the Federal Reserve Bank of New York the
principal and interest on its loan, set at the federal funds target
on the original loan date.16 Because the custodian bank, the
issuing and paying agent (hired by the issuer to administer the
issuance of and payments on the commercial paper), and all
primary dealers cleared commercial paper through the
Depository Trust Company, the CPFF had in place a
mechanism that allowed it to purchase commercial paper
efficiently through the market’s standard clearing institution
(see exhibit).

15

16

These included loans of cash and securities as well as purchases and sales
of U.S. Treasury and government agency debt.

If the target federal funds rate was a range, then the loan was set at the
maximum rate within that range.

FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

31

Commercial Paper Funding Facility Pricing Structure
Rates and Fees
Lending rate
Credit surcharge
All-in cost

Unsecured Commercial Paper

Asset-Backed Commercial Paper

Three-month OIS + 100 basis points
100 basis points
Three-month OIS + 200 basis points

Three-month OIS + 300 basis points
None
Three-month OIS + 300 basis points

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Note: OIS is the overnight index swap rate.

To sell commercial paper to the CPFF LLC, an issuer was
required to register in advance of the initial issuance.17 The
registration process allowed the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York to verify eligibility criteria (including the
maximum amount the issuer could sell to the facility), review
the issuer’s credit quality, and, among other logistics, process
the registration fee. While the vast majority of registrants
issued to the CPFF shortly after registering, some registered
to retain the option of future issuance should the need arise.
The CPFF’s registration period began on October 20, 2008,
one week prior to the first purchase date, to allow time for
processing the large number of issuers that wanted the option
of issuing to the facility at its inception.

3.2 The CPFF as Liquidity Backstop
Eligibility requirements associated with tenor, credit quality,
pricing, and maximum issuance were structured to help limit
the use of the facility to backstop financing.18 Of all these
requirements, the facility’s pricing structure was the most
influential. It was absolutely essential that the rates on CPFF
issuance were precisely calibrated to ease financial market
stress by offering financing at a rate below the market’s extreme
levels. At the same time, the Federal Reserve had to ensure that
the rates were not too attractive; otherwise, issuers would rely
heavily on the CPFF, potentially impairing long-run liquidity
and market functioning in the commercial paper market. On
October 14, 2008, the Federal Reserve released the pricing
structure for the facility (see table).
17

An “issuer” is the legal entity that issues the commercial paper. If a parent
company and a subsidiary issued commercial paper separately, they were
considered separate issuers for the purposes of the CPFF. Only U.S. issuers of
commercial paper, including U.S. issuers with a foreign parent, were eligible to
sell commercial paper to the SPV.
18
The SPV was allowed to purchase only three-month, U.S.-dollardenominated unsecured and asset-backed commercial paper (rated at least
A1/P1/F1) from U.S. issuers or U.S.-based issuers of a foreign parent company.
Although split ratings (such that one rating is Tier 2) were accepted, A2/P2
paper—which represents about 5 percent of issuance in the commercial paper
market—was ineligible.

32

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

The facility controlled for changes in short-term interest
rates by setting the price of commercial paper issuance to the
CPFF at a fixed spread above the daily three-month OIS rate.
As is common practice in the market, commercial paper issued
to the CPFF was sold at a discount from face value, as
determined by the lending rate, using the standard interest
calculations and the actual over-360-day-count convention.
The all-in costs of the OIS plus 200 and 300 basis points per
year on unsecured and asset-backed commercial paper,
respectively, were determined after performing historical
analysis of several factors, including investment-grade
financing rates in recent interest rate cycles, average spreads
between unsecured and asset-backed paper, and estimation of
potential losses on a diversified portfolio of commercial paper.
The higher funding costs for ABCP in the market (and in the
CPFF pricing structure), relative to unsecured issuance backed
by the full faith and credit of the issuing entity, were an
indicator of the riskiness and illiquidity of the underlying
collateral in ABCP conduits. In addition to conducting
empirical analysis, Federal Reserve staff surveyed a large
number of market participants to distinguish between the
credit and liquidity components of commercial paper rates
at the height of the crisis.
Purchases of commercial paper had to be secured to the
satisfaction of the Federal Reserve. Because financial and
nonfinancial commercial paper is unsecured, the Fed needed to
find alternative means to secure the loans. Although financial
institutions could pledge financial assets as collateral against a
loan (similar to a discount window transaction), nonfinancial
commercial paper issuers would not necessarily have the same
privilege. Assessing the value of nonfinancial assets would
further complicate lending.
Lenders are generally compensated for taking risk by
charging higher interest rates or, in the case of a line of credit,
assessing fees on usage. An assessment of a credit surcharge
more closely approximated market practice and thus became
the default practice for securing a loan. Participation in
the FDIC’s TLGP qualified as a satisfactory guarantee for
unsecured commercial paper, as the U.S. government ensured
repayment on the commercial paper at maturity, thus

removing credit risk.19 TLGP issuers were not required to pay
the unsecured credit surcharge. As the TLGP was not fully
operational on the CPFF’s inception date, TLGP issuers were
initially charged an unsecured credit surcharge for paper
sold to the facility; however, these fees were subsequently
reimbursed once it was established that the entity was covered
by the TLGP.
The registration fee for the CPFF was an additional feature
that further underlined the nature of the facility as a liquidity
backstop. The pricing of the registration fee was not dissimilar
to a commitment fee that a bank would charge a borrower for
an available line of credit. This fee effectively served as an
insurance premium, whereby the issuer bought the option of
issuing to the facility at any time over the life of the program.
The 10 basis point fee was charged on the maximum amount
an issuer could sell to the CPFF, or the greatest amount of
U.S.-dollar-denominated commercial paper the issuer had
outstanding on any day between January 1 and August 31,
2008. The maximum amount of issuance to the CPFF was
reduced by any commercial paper outstanding with investors
at the time of issuance, including paper issued to the CPFF.
These criteria supported the backstop nature of the facility
by limiting issuance to the amount of paper that the institution
maintained prior to the market disruptions in September 2008,
rather than providing additional funding to grow or leverage
issuers’ balance sheets. These terms also disqualified firms that
were not previously active participants in the commercial
paper market from accessing funding through the CPFF.20
The CPFF’s pricing structure and other program
requirements helped ensure that the facility played a
constructive role in restoring stability to the market. At the
same time, they also served to: 1) prevent artificial inflation of
issuance beyond what may be absorbed by investor demand
under normal conditions, 2) ensure that the facility was used as
a backstop in times of stress while also providing a disincentive
to issue to the facility under more liquid market conditions,
and 3) mitigate the credit risk associated with adverse selection
to minimize the Federal Reserve’s exposure to loss relative to
its accumulated capital from program fees.
19

For each unsecured commercial paper transaction to the CPFF, the issuer
was charged 100 basis points per year, calculated from the face value of the
commercial paper at the time of settlement. When distributing the proceeds
of the new commercial paper issuance, the SPV reduced the funds due the
issuer by an amount equal to the unsecured credit surcharge.
20
An ABCP issuer was also deemed inactive if it did not issue ABCP to
institutions other than the sponsoring institution for any consecutive period of
three months or longer between January 1 and August 31, 2008. A few months
after the facility’s inception, the Federal Reserve clarified these terms for ABCP
issuers, announcing that the CPFF would not purchase ABCP from issuers that
were inactive prior to the creation of the facility.

3.3 The Fed’s Counterparty Credit
Risk Management
From the Federal Reserve’s perspective, CPFF lending rates
were analogous to setting haircuts on a nonrecourse loan. In
setting penalty rates for eligible commercial paper, the Federal
Reserve faced a trade-off: Higher penalty rates protect the
central bank from credit risk; however, they limit the amount
of liquidity available to the financial system.
For a given CPFF interest rate, a rate lower than those
available in the market could provide market participants with
arbitrage opportunities. In essence, the Federal Reserve lent
against specific collateral types—in this case, highly rated
commercial paper—at a penalty rate and held a margin of
excess collateral, including cash collateral that should protect
it against any loss under normal market conditions.
The anticipated credit risk of the facility’s aggregate
exposure was an important factor guiding the selection of
registration and credit enhancement fees as well as rates for
unsecured and asset-backed paper. An initial analysis of the
facility’s credit risk was conducted to determine ranges of
expected and unexpected losses under normal and stressed
market conditions. Hypothetical stress losses of 1.03 percent to
1.38 percent were found to reflect historical loss probabilities
based on downgrade probabilities of short- and long-term
ratings. Any estimated potential credit losses by the CPFF SPV
were offset by the facility’s invested income from fees and
interest received on maturing paper.
In this regard, the cumulative invested income represented
the capital available to absorb potential credit losses. The large
flow of interest income from the first wave of maturities
increased the facility’s total capital to more than $2 billion,
yielding a leverage ratio of nearly 3.4 percent (the leverage ratio
is the book value of equity—accumulated through the fee
income—divided by the book value of total commercial paper
held in the facility). This capital cushion provided a sufficient
buffer to absorb the portfolio’s stress losses at a 99 percent
confidence level, as calculated by a team of New York Fed
economists and PIMCO credit analysts. Nevertheless, the
facility’s credit exposures were more concentrated than a
highly granular loan portfolio at a commercial bank, so its
ex post loss results could vary significantly from historical loss
trends. On February 1, 2010, the date the CPFF expired, the
facility had accumulated income in excess of the commercial
paper held in the SPV; as a result, no losses were incurred.

FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

33

3.4 Moral Hazard
The mere existence of a liquidity backstop raises concerns
about moral hazard. In the case of the CPFF, expectations that
the Fed would act as a lender of last resort and purchase
commercial paper could have led issuers to engage in riskier
behavior than they otherwise would have. Through its
eligibility restrictions, the CPFF was structured to address
this possibility of moral hazard.
For example, several months into the program, the
eligibility rules were altered to deter the unintended
consequence of reviving ABCP conduits that had exited the
market. On January 23, 2009, the Federal Reserve announced
that the CPFF would not purchase ABCP from issuers that
were inactive prior to the facility’s creation. In this way,
policymakers sought to limit moral hazard through issuance
that no longer had a natural investor base. In addition, the
CPFF accepted only paper rated A1/P1. Presumably, issuers
that engaged in riskier behavior would risk their top-tier credit
rating and, consequently, jeopardize their eligibility for the
facility.
Despite these eligibility restrictions, as long as a liquidity
backstop exists for an asset market, there will always be some
risk that issuers expect liquidity gaps to be filled for higher
rated financial and asset-backed commercial paper. One way
around this implicit moral hazard would be to publish
information on participation with a lag. The attendant cost
of such publication, however, is the associated stigma. This
creates a risk that the facility will not be used when it is needed
most, even in cases where the liquidity risk is broad-based
rather than firm-specific.

3.5 The CPFF’s Relation to Other
Federal Reserve Liquidity Facilities
To address the strains in dollar funding markets that emerged
immediately after the Primary Reserve Fund “broke the buck,”
the Federal Reserve introduced, in addition to the CPFF,
two other facilities under section 13(3): the Asset-Backed
Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity
Facility and the Money Market Investor Funding Facility. All
three facilities supported short-term funding markets and
thereby increased the availability of credit through various
mechanisms, although the CPFF was used more heavily than
the other facilities.
Two factors help explain the CPFF’s considerable use. First,
the CPFF addressed problems in short-term debt markets at
their root—through direct lending to issuers—at a time when
issuers faced potential liquidity shortfalls as a result of market

34

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

dislocations. Indeed, the main factor distinguishing the CPFF
from the other two facilities is the CPFF’s role as a backstop to
issuers, whereas the other facilities provide emergency lending
to institutional money market investors. Second, the CPFF
backstopped issuance of both unsecured and secured
commercial paper, while the AMLF funded only ABCP and the
MMIFF special-purpose vehicles purchased only certificates of
deposit, bank notes, and commercial paper from specific
financial institutions.21
While the MMIFF was a liquidity facility for money market
mutual funds in the case of abrupt withdrawals by investors,
the CPFF effectively bypassed the money market universe by
allowing issuers to issue directly into it. Thus, the two facilities
addressed slightly different needs.
The AMLF was launched by the Federal Reserve on
September 19, 2008. The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston was
authorized to make loans to U.S. depository institutions and
bank holding companies for the purpose of financing
purchases of ABCP from money market mutual funds. The
program specifically sought to help the money market mutual
funds facing elevated redemption requests to meet their
funding needs. The AMLF operated via a custodian bank,
and lending occurred directly through the discount window.
Money market mutual funds sold ABCP to their custodian
bank, which would subsequently pledge the ABCP to the
discount window against a cash loan. The AMLF was made
operational in a very short timeframe, because it was much less
complex than the CPFF. However, the AMLF accepted only
highly rated ABCP, not unsecured commercial paper. AMLF
usage peaked on October 8, 2008.
The CPFF, PDCF, TSLF, TALF, and AMLF shared the
common features of being liquidity facilities aimed at
stabilizing funding in the money markets and being created to
counteract the financial market turbulence that threatened the
stability of the system as a whole. 22 Effectively, these facilities
extended the Federal Reserve’s lender-of-last-resort role to
include nondepository institutions (the PDCF, TSLF, and
AMLF) and specific securities markets (the CPFF and TALF).
The facilities were based on the Federal Reserve’s ability to
extend credit to “any individual, partnership, or corporation”
under “unusual and exigent circumstances,” as per section
13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act.23
21

The economic rationale for the MMIFF is described in detail by Davis,
McAndrews, and Franklin (2009).
22
See also the November 18, 2008, testimony of Federal Reserve Chairman Ben
Bernanke before the U.S. House of Representatives’ Committee on Financial
Services on the subject of the Troubled Asset Relief Program and the Federal
Reserve’s liquidity facilities: http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/
testimony/bernanke20081118a.htm.
23
For details on the powers of Federal Reserve Banks, see http://
www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed/section13.htm.

4. CPFF Usage and Its Impact on
the Commercial Paper Market
An issuer’s decision to use the CPFF was predicated in part on
the cost of issuance to the facility relative to the cost of issuance
in the market or other alternative funding sources. As we
discussed, the facility’s pricing was designed to be cost-effective
during times of market stress, but prohibitively expensive
during times of normal market function. Accordingly, as
conditions in financing markets normalized in 2009, CPFF
usage progressively declined.

Chart 6

Commercial Paper Funding Facility Issuance
Outstanding
Billions of dollars

400
350
300
Unsecured commercial paper

250
200
150
100

4.1 Usage and Market Impact

50

Asset-backed
commercial paper

0

The facility’s assets grew rapidly at inception, reaching
$144 billion in the first week of operation. Assets more
than doubled, to $293 billion, after one month and totaled
$333 billion by the end of December 2008 (Chart 6). CPFF peak
usage occurred in the third week of January 2009, exactly
three months after the first issuance date, with approximately
$350 billion in commercial paper held in the SPV. Throughout
2009, CPFF use steadily declined, reaching a level of around
$10 billion in December.
At its peak level, the portfolio was primarily composed of
financial commercial paper. The portfolio became more and
more tilted toward ABCP after the first vintage of the CPFF
matured at the end of January 2009. The large share of ABCP
in the facility, which continued to increase during 2009,
illustrated the continuing difficulties obtaining funding in
collateralized money markets.
Issuers to the CPFF included a variety of ABCP conduits—
single-seller, hybrid, multi-seller, and securities arbitrage
conduits—and other financial institutions that conducted
banking, insurance, and credit finance in the United States.
Issuance trends varied widely across registrants, reflecting
the ability of issuers to finance in the market, reduced leverage
in the financial system, a consolidation of issuers in the
marketplace, and access to other government programs,
among other factors.24
24

Single-seller conduits are established to fund the assets originated by one
seller, or one seller and its subsidiaries and related entities, while multi-seller
conduits are structured to fund assets originated by a variety of sellers, typically
all clients of the sponsoring commercial bank. Securities arbitrage issuers
primarily fund highly rated securities, and investors in the conduits are
exposed to the risk of default, or credit risk, of those securities. Hybrid conduits
incorporate the structural features of two or more conduit types. Most hybrid
conduits have multi-seller and securities arbitrage characteristics. Bate,
Bushweller, and Rutan (2003) explain conduits in more detail.

2008

2009

2010

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

As of December 31, 2009, two-thirds of CPFF holdings were
unsecured and the remaining third constituted ABCP. The
unsecured paper was issued predominantly by banks and
nonbank financials (diversified financials), some of which
included TLGP-guaranteed paper. Insurance companies also
issued unsecured paper, although to a lesser degree. By the end
of 2009, many insurance companies faced losses in light of their
exposure to mortgage financing; insurance represented just
one of many sectors adversely affected by the financial crisis
and economic downturn. Rating agencies subsequently
downgraded the commercial paper of several insurance
companies, effectively compromising their eligibility for
the CPFF.
ABCP issuance accounted for a growing proportion of assets
in the CPFF, suggesting that conduits were having greater
difficulty reentering the market and posing some risk of
adverse selection in the facility. ABCP conduits were widely
used as a means to fund “hard-to-finance” assets. Consequently,
it was not surprising to observe a more gradual retrenchment
from the facility by this sector. However, ABCP issuance in
the market and in the CPFF declined naturally as assets
amortized, securitization slowed, and assets were consolidated
to parents’ balance sheets. In addition, ABCP programs shrank
with changes to regulatory capital requirements and
accounting rules.
The CPFF indeed had a stabilizing effect on the commercial
paper market, as shown in Chart 7. At its peak in January 2009,
the CPFF held more than 20 percent of all outstanding
commercial paper. By the time it expired on February 1, 2010,

FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

35

Chart 7

Chart 8

Total Commercial Paper Outstanding

Weekly Commercial Paper Issuance

Billions of dollars

2,000

Billions of dollars

Percent

CPFF launch

1,000

40

800

30

600

20

400

40

10

200

20

81+ days (including CPFF)
21-80 days
5-20 days
1-4 days
Non-CPFF term/total issuance

Total outstanding in CPFF
(Left scale)

1,500

1,000

(Right scale)

100
80

60

M1
Total outstanding
Asset-backed
in market
(Left scale)

500
CPFF as percentage
of market

Financial
companies

(Right scale)

0

0
2008

2009

2010

0

0
2008

2009

2010

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Note: CPFF is the Commercial Paper Funding Facility.

Note: CPFF is the Commercial Paper Funding Facility.

the facility represented only 1 percent of market issuance. The
self-liquidating feature of the CPFF is illustrated by the steady
decline in the amount of outstanding commercial paper
throughout 2009.
During the crisis period after Lehman’s bankruptcy and
prior to the CPFF’s start-up, the fraction of term commercial
paper issuance collapsed as money market funds shortened the
duration of their assets to ensure against further redemption
pressures (see Chart 8). In fact, more than 75 percent of
commercial paper issued in the second half of September and
in early October consisted of maturities of only one to four
days. As a result of the shortened maturities, total weekly
commercial paper issuance rose rapidly during the crisis. Once
the CPFF started operation on October 27, term commercial
paper issuance began rising and quickly reverted to a tight
range of between 30 and 40 percent of total commercial paper.
The expansion of the CPFF was accompanied by a
narrowing of the spread between commercial paper rates
and comparable OIS rates (Chart 9). The degree to which the
narrower spread was attributable to the CPFF’s expansion
requires further research, but the coincidence suggests that
the program had a meaningful effect.
The one-month AA-rated financials spread declined from
188 basis points in October 2008 to 38 basis points in
December 2009 (the latter being the average of daily business
day rates during December). Over the same period, the ABCP
spread declined from 256 basis points to 86 basis points.25
25

The decline in the less liquid market of three-month commercial paper rates
was also substantial. We report the one-month rates because of greater data
availability.

36

Percent

50

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

Meanwhile, the spread for A2/P2 commercial paper—which
was not eligible for the CPFF—rose from 483 basis points to a
December average of 503 basis points. The one-month A2/P2
spreads to OIS continued to rise through the end of 2008, as
creditors demanded increasing compensation from lower rated
issuers for use of their balance sheets over year-end, a period
when firms typically reduce leverage for the purpose of
financial reporting and minimize risk amid a period of reduced
market liquidity. Only after the passage of year-end did the
spread between eligible A1/P1 and ineligible A2/P2 paper
narrow.
The CPFF’s holdings rose rapidly in the first three months
following the facility’s creation, likely because the rates it
charged were considerably below the average market rates. As
average commercial paper rates began to decline throughout
2009, CPFF usage declined as well.
Average spreads on commercial paper issued in the market
(Chart 9) mask the actual cross-sectional dispersion of rates
across issuers within each credit rating bucket. The underlying
dispersion in rates owes partly to the fact that investors,
particularly money market funds, have policies that limit their
concentrations to counterparties in order to manage their credit
exposure and maintain diversification. As money market funds
effectively became more risk averse and attuned to credit
differentiation, some funds responded to the financial crisis by
either charging higher rates to issuers perceived as potentially
more risky or barring certain names altogether from their
portfolios.
Continued issuance to the CPFF amid declining commercial
paper rates highlighted the wide range of rates transacted in the

Chart 9

One-Month Commercial Paper Rates Less
One-Month Overnight Index Swap Rate
Basis points

600
A2/P2

500
400
AA-rated asset-backed
commercial paper

300
200
100
0
-100

AA-rated
nonfinancial

2008

AA-rated financial

2009

2010

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bloomberg.

market. Although the one-month commercial paper interest
rate charged for AA-rated ABCP averaged 32 basis points in the
second half of 2009 and never exceeded 62 basis points, ABCP
issuance into the CPFF at the penalty rate of 300 basis points
(for the three-month maturity) occurred throughout the year,
suggesting that some issuers continued to find CPFF rates
attractive relative to market rates.
Another possible explanation is that demand for issuance
fell short of some issuers’ required funding needs. At the onset
of the crisis, investors were less willing to hold large positions
in commercial paper; thus, issuers may have been left with no
option other than to satisfy remaining liquidity needs by
issuing to the CPFF.

4.2. “Roll”
“Roll” refers to times when issuers retire existing commercial
paper at its maturity, but still require funding and therefore
issue new paper. In other words, it represents the number of
times when commercial paper is reissued, or “rolled over.”
Because the maturity of CPFF commercial paper was ninety
days, rolls occurred once a quarter.
From the beginning of the CPFF to its end, there were
five rolls of ninety-day commercial paper. The first roll was
the most significant, given that CPFF holdings represented
20 percent of the total commercial paper market. Market
analysts had speculated that the still-fragile commercial paper
market might come under additional strain if the maturing
paper were reissued over a highly concentrated period into

the private market. However, the first roll went smoothly, as
issuance into the private market remained small and whatever
financing returned to the commercial paper or other private
markets was relatively dispersed (some issuers prefunded
their CPFF maturities and used the proceeds to pay the
maturing issuance in the CPFF).
Throughout the second and third rolls, an increasing
percentage of smaller dollar amounts came due and was paid
down. By the fourth roll, in October 2009, approximately
80 percent ($28 billion) of the commercial paper in the CPFF
matured, of which roughly $20 billion was paid down. As a
result, commercial paper holdings in the CPFF amounted to
just 1 percent of the total commercial paper market following
the penultimate roll.
The most dramatic effect of the rolls was seen in the
composition of CPFF holdings. With each roll, ABCP became
an even greater share of CPFF holdings as money funds
continued to shun secured paper, particularly if it was
perceived to be of poor credit quality. Most of the remaining
ABCP may have been of lower credit quality and had no natural
buyer. This transformation in CPFF holdings raised
policymakers’ concerns about adverse selection into the
program and about complications that would arise if certain
issuers could not have repaid upon the program’s conclusion.

4.3. Impact on the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet
Compared with the other new liquidity facilities or with
outright purchases, the CPFF had a large effect on the Fed’s
balance-sheet growth. Only foreign exchange swaps and the
TAF made larger contributions. During this period of relatively
rapid expansion in assets, the Fed’s liabilities expanded
primarily through excess reserve balances, although some
of the balance-sheet expansion was sterilized by increased
issuance of Treasury SFP bills.26 While the CPFF contributed
to growth in reserves, the contraction in the facility’s holdings
also outpaced that of other Federal Reserve programs, given its
punitive rate structure. This contraction significantly offset the
reserves creation of later programs, such as the Large-Scale
Asset Purchase Program.27
26

On September 17, 2008, the U.S. Treasury announced the Supplementary
Financing Program (SFP), through which the Treasury issues a series of
Treasury bills, separate from its current borrowing program, and deposits the
proceeds from these issuances into an account at the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York. Funds in this account drain reserves from the banking system and
therefore offset the reserve impact of Federal Reserve lending and liquidity
initiatives. Interest on reserves is discussed in Keister and McAndrews (2009).
27
The impact of the CPFF and other credit and liquidity programs on the
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and income statement can be found at http://
www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_fedfinancials.htm.

FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

37

The CPFF’s penalty fee represented income for the Federal
Reserve. The facility generated roughly $5 billion in net income
from its inception to its close in April 2010. This amount
represented a relatively large share of total profits from the
liquidity facilities, estimated to be $12.9 billion as of December
2009 (Fleming and Klagge 2009). These profits, which were
transferred by the Federal Reserve to the Treasury, ultimately
helped reduce the financial burden on taxpayers.
The economic interpretation for the income generated
by the CPFF is as follows. During fall 2008, the private
market for commercial paper was severely disrupted by the
reallocation of short-term savings from prime money market
funds to Treasury-only funds. As a result, the Federal Reserve
established the CPFF as a lender-of-last-resort facility to
address the temporary liquidity distortions created by the
money market reallocations. However, by law, the Federal
Reserve had to protect itself against potential credit losses.
It therefore loaned to commercial paper issuers at a penalty
rate, which in turn generated income from the facility.
While market rates for commercial paper were unusually
high, commercial paper issuers were willing to pay the penalty
rate, thereby transferring money to the taxpayer. As such, U.S.
households gained in the aggregate. In addition to the fee
income generated by the CPFF, taxpayers also benefited from
the facility’s role in potentially preventing commercial paper
issuers from being forced into bankruptcy, an event that could
have distorted real investment decisions.

5. Conclusion
The Commercial Paper Funding Facility serves as a noteworthy
model for the Federal Reserve’s role as lender of last resort—a
role that, in this case, reached beyond depository institutions.
In contrast to traditional discount window lending, the CPFF
supported liquidity in a particular market as opposed to
supporting the liquidity of a particular set of institutions. Like
the discount window, the CPFF was constructed as a backstop,
not as a permanent source of funding. While the discount
window accepts a very broad range of collateral—including
loans, mortgages, and securities—the CPFF focused on a
particular asset class, but had less stringent requirements for
the types of institutions that can borrow. The CPFF can be
considered a model of liquidity provision in a market-based
financial system, where maturity transformation occurs
outside of the commercial banking sector in a quantitatively
and economically important magnitude.

38

The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility

The legal basis for the CPFF stemmed from section 13(3)
of the Federal Reserve Act, requiring the use of such a facility
in “unusual and exigent circumstances.” As such, the Federal
Reserve does not have the authority to make the CPFF a
permanent liquidity backstop. This in turn has implications
for the ongoing debate on regulatory reform. The financial
market crisis of 2007-09 demonstrated the current financial
architecture’s vulnerabilities to liquidity crises emanating from
nondepository institutions. As such, an important component
of regulatory reform focuses on improving the resiliency of
money markets to financial and economic shocks. Many
ongoing reform efforts aim to reduce the vulnerability of
money markets to liquidity crises. These efforts focus
particularly on reforming money market funds, the
commercial paper market, and the repo markets.
It has long been understood that the public sector plays a
crucial role in the provision of liquidity. In times of aggregate
liquidity shortages, only the monetary authority can act as
lender of last resort, owing to its ability to create money.28
Traditionally, the lender of last resort has been available only to
depository institutions because the vast majority of maturity
and liquidity transformation took place in those institutions.
Since the mid-1980s, however, the rapid growth of a marketbased system of credit formation has allowed for maturity
transformation by a wide range of institutions, including
money market funds, finance companies, and securities
broker-dealers, and through a range of market instruments,
such as asset-backed commercial paper and tri-party repo.
Despite the recent crisis, it seems likely that large amounts
of maturity and liquidity transformation will continue to be
conducted outside of depository institutions—and therefore
without access to the traditional lender of last resort—in what
is known as “the shadow banking system.”29 The public
sector’s role in providing backstop liquidity to the shadow
banking system will continue to be debated. Although the
duration of the CPFF was necessarily limited, the facility
provides a model for a market-based lender-of-last-resort
liquidity backstop, which could serve as a guide for future
policy discussion.

28

See Holmström and Tirole (1998) for a theory of public liquidity provision,
Diamond and Dybvig (1983) for a classic justification of discount window
lending, and Acharya, Gale, and Yorulmazer (2008) for a setting with
rollover risk.
29
Adrian, Ashcraft, and Pozsar (2009) provide a detailed overview of the
shadow banking system.

References

Acharya, V., D. Gale, and T. Yorulmazer. 2008. “Rollover Risk and
Market Freezes.” Unpublished paper, New York University
and Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Acharya, V., and P. Schnabl. 2010. “Securitization without Risk
Transfer.” Unpublished paper, New York University.
Adrian, T., A. Ashcraft, and Z. Pozsar. 2009. “Shadow Banking.”
Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Adrian, T., C. R. Burke, and J. J. McAndrews. 2009. “The Federal
Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility.” Federal Reserve Bank of
New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 4,
August.
Adrian, T., and H. S. Shin. 2010. “The Changing Nature of Financial
Intermediation and the Financial Crisis of 2007-2009.” Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 439, March.
Armantier, O., S. Krieger, and J. McAndrews. 2008. “The Federal
Reserve’s Term Auction Facility.” Federal Reserve Bank of
New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15,
no. 5, July.
Ashcraft, A., A. Malz, and Z. Pozsar. 2010. “The Federal Reserve’s Term
Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility.” Unpublished paper,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Bate, S., S. Bushweller, and E. Rutan. 2003. “The Fundamentals of
Asset-Backed Commercial Paper.” Moody’s Investors Service
Structured Finance Special Report, February 3.

Covitz, D. M., N. Liang, and G. A. Suarez. 2009. “The Evolution of
a Financial Crisis: Panic in the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper
Market.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Finance and Economics Discussion Series, no. 2009-36,
September.
Davis, J., J. McAndrews, and K. Franklin. 2009. “The Money Market
Investor Funding Facility.” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York.
Diamond, D. W., and P. H. Dybvig. 1983. “Bank Runs, Deposit
Insurance, and Liquidity.” Journal of Political Economy 91,
no. 3 (June): 401-19.
Fleming, M. J., W. B. Hrung, and F. M. Keane. 2009. “The Term
Securities Lending Facility: Origin, Design, and Effects.” Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and
Finance 15, no. 2, February.
Fleming, M. J., and N. Klagge. 2009. “Income Effects of Federal Reserve
Liquidity Facilities.” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York.
Holmström, B., and J. Tirole. 1998. “Private and Public Supply
of Liquidity.” Journal of Political Economy 106, no. 1
(February): 1-40.
Keister, T., and J. McAndrews. 2009. “Why Are Banks Holding
So Many Excess Reserves?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Staff Reports, no. 380, July.

Bond Market Association and Depository Trust and Clearing
Corporation. 2003. “Issues and Recommendations Regarding
Commercial Paper Settlement Practices.” White paper, March 3.

The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
or the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York provides no warranty, express or implied, as to the
accuracy, timeliness, completeness, merchantability, or fitness for any particular purpose of any information contained in
documents produced and provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in any form or manner whatsoever.
FRBNY Economic Policy Review / May 2011

39