View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MISC. 136.3-IOOM-1-53

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
ROUTE SLIP
DATE

6/4/54

Miss McKinstry

To

Floor

OF8th
FROM

M.

Rushton
REMARKS

Kay - this is

the list

I told

Miss Adams we were sending to you.
Perhaps it

may help in locating

the material she is




requesting.

REPORTS OF MR. WILLIAMS
AT MEETINGS OF DIRECTORS ATTENDED BY MR. CALKINS
1944-1949

1/20/44

Post-war domestic economy.

1/27/44

Special report - post-war currency stabilization.

2/17/44

Problems re domestic economy.

4/6/44

Research Department.
stabilization.

6/1/44

Post-war international currency stabilization.

7/6/44

Proposal for formation of international Bank for Recon
struction and Development.

9/7/44

Postwar domestic problems - recent developments.

1/18/45

Problems that might affect interest rates on US Govern
ment securities during post-war period.

3/15/45

Hearings before Committee on Banking and Currency (H.R.2211)
Participation of US in International Monetary Fund and
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

4/19/45

Problems re proposed International Monetary Fund on Inter
national Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

7/5/45

Re Bretton Woods Agreements.

7/19/45

Full Employment Bill of 1945 (S-380).

9/6/45

Wage levels, price controls and other Government problems.

11/1/45

Wage-price policy of Government.

12/6/45

Theory and history of monetary policy during last two decades.

1/3/46

Management of public debt and interest rates.

3/21/46

Changes in bus.and credit situation.

4/18/46

n

Post-war international currency

n

n

5/16/46

Proposed loan by US to Great Britain; British economic problems.

9/5/46

Trends in stock market.

11/7/46

Adequacy of business inventories in relation to anticipated
consumer demands. Budgetary outlook of Government.

2/6/47

International economic situation; Great Britain and other
European countries.




-2-

5/15/47

$250 mil.loan by International Bank forReconstruction and
Development to France.

5/22/47

International Monetary Fund, International Bank for Recon
struction and Development, International Trade Organiza
tion, etc.

6/19/47

International economic problems.

7/3/47

Discussed statement to Joint Congressional Committee on
Presidents Economic Report.

9/18/47

Economic developments in Europe.

10/16/47

Problems of debt management and monetary controls.

11/20/47

Re Presidents recommendation restraining inflationary
bank credit.

1/8/48

Message on State of the Union - taxation and monetary policy.

2/5/48

French program for devaluation of franc,

3/4/48

European Recovery Program.

5/6/48

System's authority over commercial bank reserve require

ments.

etc.

(5/11/48 letter to directors from William I.

Myers enclosing letter to Mr. McCabe,
Governors, on this subject.)

Chmn.,

Board of

6/3/48

European situation.

10/7/48

Economic situation; outlook.

12/16/48

Report on trip to Europe.

3/17/49

Meeting with representatives of Economic Cooperation
Administration.

9/15/49

Business and credit situation.

12/15/49

Scheduled trip to Paris re Interim Report of the Organiza
tion for European Economic Recovery.




This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: End of the Marshall Plan

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

July 1952

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: An Economist's Confessions

Journal Title: American Economic Review

Volume Number: XLII
Date:

March 1952

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: 1

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: The Marshall Plan Halfway

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

April 1950

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: Europe After 1952: The Long-Term Recovery Problem

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

April 1949

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: The Task of Economic Recovery

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

July 1948

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: An Appraisal of Keynesian Economics

Journal Title: American Economic Review

Volume Number: XXXVII
Date:

May 1948

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: 2

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: Economic Lessons of Two World Wars

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

October 1947

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: International Monetary Plans: After Bretton Woods

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

October 1944

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: Currency Stabilization: American and British Attitudes

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

January 1944

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

POLICIES OF THE UNITED STATES
AS A CREDITOR NATION

BY

JOHN H. WILLIAMS
DEAN, GRADUATE SCHOOL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION,
HARVARD

UNIVERSITY

AN ADDRESS
BEFORE THE

ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
AT ITS
ANNUAL MEETING ON
"THE PROBLEMS OF TOTAL WAR AND ROADS TO VICTORY"
NOVEMBER

10, 1943

THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY




1944

POLICIES OF THE UNITED STATES AS
A CREDITOR NATION
JOHN H. WILLIAMS

Dean, Graduate School of Public Administration, Harvard University

FOR

the second time we are facing the problem of

carrying over into peace the spirit of international
cooperation developed in war. Last time our experi
ence was very disappointing. It is a striking fact that the chief
development in economic theory during the inter-war period
was the closed economy analysis, and in economic policy one
of the main developments was the movement in various coun
tries toward self-sufficiency. Some people explain in psycho
logical terms the wave of nationalism that so often follows
war; war develops our pugnacity, and after we have rested a
while we want to fight again. But the explanation goes much
deeper. War profoundly changes international relationships
and presents most difficult problems of readjustment.
In the last war the position of the United States was changed
from a debtor to a creditor nation. Another great change was
in the position of Germany, where economic exhaustion at
home, the loss of foreign assets, and the reparation payments
were major causes of the great post-war inflation. After this
war the United States will be the only large creditor nation.
Some younger countries, such as Canada and Argentina, which
will also come out of the war in a creditor position, will prob
ably in the longer run again become net capital-importing and
interest-paying countries. The most striking change will be in
the position of England; she will enter the post-war period as
a debtor country after having been for more than a century the
world's leading creditor.
England's post-war problem is highly complicated. She has
lost the greater part of her foreign assets, and there is now an
accumulation of sterling balances owed to foreign countries
quite apart from lend-lease transactions-which is estimated at
four to five billion dollars and is growing at the rate of two
billion dollars a year. England is worried about her future
position in shipping and aviation. Her internal reconstruction




No. 4]

UNITED STATES AS A CREDITOR NATION

21

will require imports, particularly of raw materials and food
products, while she is planning to codperate with us in provid
ing relief for other countries. At the same time, because of her
debtor position, she will have the quite new problem of devel
oping a large excess of exports. England will have an interest
second to none in maximizing foreign trade by helping to re
store a multilateral system of world trade. Even her previous
ability as a net importing country to keep the upper hand in
bilateral trade agreements will largely have been lost. But it
seems likely that England will approach the task of interna
tional currency stabilization with a cautious attitude. Two main
questions are: (I) whether any plan for currency stabilization
will give her sufficient freedom both to find the equilibrium
rate of exchange between her currency and others-always a
major problem after a war-and to permit an orderly adjust
ment of rates thereafter as basic conditions change; and (2)
how to reconcile the requirements of international currency
stability with the maintenance of a high degree of control over
her internal economy.
I cannot deal with the general problem of currency stabiliza
tion or the plans now under discussion between our Treasury
experts and those of the British Treasury,' but my remarks
today are concerned with one aspect of that problem. It is part
of the tradition of the subject that the creditor country has a
special responsibility for international monetary and trade re
lations. One of the reproaches running all through the inter
war period was that we did not play our role, and that in con
sequence the restoration of the gold standard in the nineteen
twenties led to intolerable deflationary pressures upon other
countries and a new collapse. Rather than repeat that experi
ence the debtor countries would prefer to take their chances
with bilateral trade agreements and exchange controls, poor as
they recognize this alternative to be. We owe it to ourselves
and to them to survey the inter-war experience and the peculi
arities of our present position.
Many of the worst features of the last post-war period had
nothing to do with the normal relations between debtor and
creditor countries. We ought this time to be able to avoid the
wild gyrations of currencies that followed the last war. Prac
1 See my paper in Foreign Affairs, July 1943, and a forthcoming paper in

the January issue.




22

THE PROBLEMS OF TOTAL WAR

[VoL. XX

tically all nations will come out of the war with effective sys
tems of exchange control, and these should be relaxed only
slowly and carefully. It seems not improbable that England
will retain more permanently control over the short-time move
ments of capital resident in Britain, even though to do this she
must retain the machinery of a general exchange control, and
free trade movements from it by means of general licenses. 2
The main cause of the recurrent flights of capital between
the two wars was the economic and political insecurity in
Europe. If this can be removed we shall be in a better position
to see how much control over capital movements is essential.
Two of the chief mistakes last time, reparation payments and
inter-Allied debts, we must hope will not be repeated. I real
ize I cannot dispose of the reparations question as summarily
as this. German confiscations of property in occupied countries
will require restitution of national ownership, at least; Russia
may demand, and be able economically to accept, payments in
goods or in services; and there may be other possibilities; but
surely the transfer problems which bedeviled the world in the
nineteen-twenties will be avoided. One of our cleverest moves
in this war was to think up lend-lease, and my only regret is
that we did not at the time provide for its extension for perhaps
three years after the peace, on the theory that the first phase
of peace is but a projection of the war-war does not end when
the shooting stops but when the difficult transition back to more
normal international conditions has been achieved. A consid
erable part of the inter-Allied debt last time was incurred after
the Armistice.3
The experiences of the twenties and thirties do not suggest
that the role of a creditor country under post-war conditions is
a simple one. We were condemned, probably more than for
anything else, for our protectionist policy, and the criticism
was deserved; but our policy was quite in line with that of
2 1 am not entirely sure, indeed, that England and some other countries
will forswear all direct control over imports; when the choice is between
this and changing exchange rates the answer is not clear a priori.
SSince the meeting of the Academy, Leon Fraser, at the New York
Herald'Tribune Forum, November 16, 1943, has suggested a "moratorium
for a period of five years of any post-war lend-lease repayments involving
transfers out of Great Britain, any repayments thereafter to be limited to
the return to the creditor, of the same commodity as was shipped."




No. 4]

UNITED STATES AS A CREDITOR NATION

23

other countries demanding but unwilling really to accept the
reparation payments. As a creditor nation we were expected
to assist in restoring and maintaining international stability
by exporting capital. The capital movements occurred, mainly
to Germany and Latin America, but have generally been re
garded since as disturbing rather than corrective factors.
Especially significant was the controversy which developed
after England's return to gold in 1925. The reproach that we
were sterilizing gold and preventing the internal monetary ex
pansion required by gold standard theory was quite unfounded;
as we saw more clearly later, we were in the early stages of
the expansion which led to the crash of 1929, though that was
obscured by the fact that the rise was in security prices and in
incomes rather than in commodity prices. Our attempt to
push out gold in 1927 by lowering interest rates ended in fail
ure, and is thought by many to have intensified the stock market
boom. The chief mistake was in the overvaluation of the
pound. It should make us more aware this time how important
it is to find the equilibrium rates if currency stabilization is to
be attempted with any prospect of success. Despite all that was
written on the subject and the great interest developed in " pur
chasing power parities ", this seems to be mainly a trial-and
error process involving mutual consent and a flexible approach
providing for orderly change in rates as the basic circumstances
warrant. How to do this consistently with the general objec
tive of exchange stability seems to be the essence of the prob
lem; adequate discussion of it would go far beyond the limits
of this paper.
There are some peculiarities of our creditor position which
we ought to puzzle over ourselves and try to make clear to
others. For this r6le we lack many of the advantages which
England had in the nineteenth century. England was at the
center of world trade and finance, sterling was the medium
and the London discount market the clearing mechanism for
international payment, and the Bank of England by its dis
count rate could greatly influence capital movements and the
flow of gold. England had a unique position such as will
probably never be enjoyed by any single country in the future.
When reference is made, as occurs so often, to how well Eng
land performed her function as the creditor country, with the
implication that now it is our turn to do as well, these differ-




24

THE PROBLEMS OF TOTAL WAR

[VOL. XX

ences must not, if we are to think clearly, be forgotten. The
problem has become more difficult all round; and even then it
was not simple or the performance very good much of the time.
The nineteenth century was one of great economic progress but
one marked by great world-wide depressions and by periodic
breakdowns of the gold standard.
But all comparisons are relative, and the problem was sim
pler then than now. For England, once her industrial revolu
tion had come to full development and found full expression in
her trade and capital relations with the rest of the world, there
could be no doubt of where her interests lay and no room for a
divided national feeling about her commercial or financial
policies. Rarely has there been a time, too, when what suited
the creditor country so well suited many of her debtors.
Though there always was a danger that international free trade
theory too literally applied might interfere with the national
development of countries less advanced, and conflicts on this
point were never absent from our colonial period onward, the
nineteenth century witnessed on the whole a harmony of trade
and capital relationships which may never be seen again. Cap
ital exports and interest payments were matched by manufac
tured exports from the lending country and food and raw
material imports from the borrowing countries with cumulative
advantages for both. 4
One of our peculiarities is that we are still a mixed agricul
tural-industrial economy. When we talk of maximizing im
ports there is certain to be a divided national interest about
what imports are involved. At an earlier stage when we were a
great agricultural exporting nation and a young industrial
nation, the emphasis was on protecting manufactures, and the
conflict was between the industrial North and the agricultural
South and West interested in expanding export markets and
getting cheaper manufactures in exchange. Now it is agricul
ture, too, or perhaps mainly, that wants protection, and the day
of an undivided national interest in commercial policy seems
still far distant. I grant that this point can be overstressed,
and I have often said that trade tends to be greatest among
41 have always felt that the full significance of this growth process was
missed by the classical theory of international trade and the gold standard,
which was essentially a static theory assuming full employment of known
resources, and revolved too much around the "terms of trade".




No. 4]

UNITED STATES AS A CREDITOR NATION

25

countries of highest purchasing power, regardless of their spe
cial characteristics; but it remains a troublesome feature of our
international situation, and may well have intensified effects on
other countries after the war, when we shall have synthetic
rubber and other new products formerly imported to think
about.
Another of our peculiarities is that, though this country is
the world's greatest reservoir of capital and will probably al
ways be a net exporter of capital over any long period, it is
probably also, under favorable conditions, still the greatest
magnet for outside capital, for investment and speculation as
well as for safety. In a boom we might easily shift from being
a net exporter to being a net importer of capital, exerting de
flationary pressure upon debtor countries, from which they
could probably not find relief except by direct control of cap
ital outflow. The late nineteen-twenties have been often cited
as an illustration of this phenomenon, and the attraction of
foreign capital into our stock market has been emphasized as
one cause of the great depression.
I have been dwelling mainly upon the difficulties of our
position rather than their solution, and I am afraid this fairly
represents the present state of my thinking. I do, however,
want to make some more positive suggestions. In the imme
diate post-war period the chief need will be for relief and re
habilitation.6 This should be handled by free contributions,
or under lend-lease. But there will also be a need for recon
struction in a broader sense, involving loans. Our Treasury
published in October a tentative plan for an international bank,
but it is difficult to see how there can be a truly international
bank in a world composed of one large creditor and many
debtor countries; however the bank is formally organized, the
funds will have to come chiefly from this country. Relief and
reconstruction will make heavy demands upon American pro
duction during the period of transition from war- to peacetime
production. This demand for exports will come on top of a
huge deferred demand here at home for producer and du
rable consumer goods, a demand backed by the great accumula
tion of unspent wartime incomes. We shall need to ration our

5 Reports

are now beginning to come out of the plans of the United Nations

Relief and Rehabilitation Administration; they call for expenditures of two
and a half billion dollars. See New York Times, November 16, 17,
1943.




26

THE PROBLEMS OF TOTAL WAR

[VOL. XX

production between home and foreign requirements and to
maintain our direct controls, as well as fiscal and monetary con
trols. With the war ended, the task of persuading the public
that these controls are necessary will probably be much more
difficult than now. It is in this early post-war period that the
danger of inflation will be greatest. If the war ends in Europe
before it does in Asia, the difficulties of transition will be les
sened; some expansion of peacetime production should now be
planned, to take effect as soon as war in Europe ends.
Looking farther ahead, the world will need both our capital
and our markets. How to bring both things about is something
of a puzzle. Maximizing foreign trade all round will, of
course, help all countries. But that may not be enough to right
the great unbalance which will exist, and to meet the much
greater needs of England and some other countries to expand
their exports. This is another aspect of the fact that we are not
yet a mature creditor country in the nineteenth-century British
sense. England was a creditor on income account, with a net
excess of imports. In our balance of payments, interest receiv
able is offset by tourist expenditures and foreign remittances,
which will probably increase after the war; and when we add
to these our capital exports we shall probably continue to have
an excess of merchandise exports for a long period to come.
To bring about a combination of exports of capital from this
country accompanied by goods exports from other countries
would seem to require something equivalent to a sustained one
way movement of gold from this country, accompanied by
rising prices here relative to outside price levels, and even, as
some writers suggest, by a continuing direct control over our
exports. But it seems unlikely that such policies will be
adopted. One service we could do to foreign countries would
be to restrict our lending to the really necessary demand in the
foreign country for foreign goods-producer goods and really
essential consumer goods. Expenditures for domestic labor
and resources should be financed at home. Ofteri what is most
needed is engineering or financial advice rather than a loan.
The greatest contribution we can make to world stability is
by maintaining high production and employment here at home.
This would maximize imports and create the most favorable
conditions for reducing tariffs, though it probably would not,
by itself, lessen exports. The advantages of a high level of




No. 4]

UNITED STATES AS A CREDITOR NATION

27

production are sometimes overstated to imply that international
trade adjustment could be made a one-sided process of expan
sion in the high production country. If the expansion could
go on indefinitely without danger of a boom this might be
true, but in the post-war period, as I have said, this danger
will be real. There is also the difficulty I mentioned earlier
of reversal of the capital movement, and the feeding of expan
sion in the creditor country by deflationary pressure on the
outside world. All in all, however, internal stability at a high
level would be much our best contribution.
But this only shifts the emphasis to another problem no less
difficult than international monetary and economic stabiliza
tion. It raises issues about methods on which public opinion is
far from united; and government planning in the domestic
field for the post-war period is probably less advanced today
than in the international. One of the great unknowns, also, is
what is to be the character of internal planning in other coun
tries. In England, many recent utterances by political leaders
and economists seem to foretell the retention of a much higher
degree of internal control, not only for the period of transition
to peace but more permanently, than England had before the
war. How much of such control is compatible with interna
tional monetary stability and a multilateral trade system will
be one of the chief problems of the post-war period.




This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: Currency Stabilization: The Keynes and White Plans

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

July 1943

Page Numbers:




Issue Number:

~_
__~_ __._
~~~__

THE
IMPLICATIONS OF FISCAL POLICY
FOR MONETARY POLICY
AND THE BANKING SYSTEM

By

JOHN H. WILLIAMS
Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK




OF NEW YORK

This paper, delivered at a joint session of the
American Economic Association and the American
Statistical Association at their annual meetings in
New York on December 28, 1941, is published in
the Proceedings of the American Economic Asso
ciation. It is reproduced with permission of that
Association.




THE IMPLICATIONS OF FISCAL POLICY
FOR MONETARY POLICY AND THE
BANKING SYSTEM
I
One of the most striking facts about the development of fiscal
policy in the past decade is that while it grew out of monetary
policy and was designed to supplement and strengthen it, fiscal
policy has ended up by threatening to supplant monetary policy
altogether.
The emphasis on central bank control was carried to great heights
in the late twenties and early thirties. Failures to achieve adequate
control were ascribed to the shortcomings of the central bankers
rather than to any weaknesses inherent in the method of control.
But as the great depression deepened, despite the fact that the
easy money policy was carried to lengths unprecedented in this or
any other country, the conviction grew that whatever might have
been the defects of central bank policy, the main trouble lay in the
inadequacy of this method, by itself, to control investment and the
level of output and employment.
Fiscal policy was designed to supplement monetary policy in two
ways. First, if an easy money policy would not, by itself, suffi
ciently induce investment, this object could be achieved by creating
new community income through budgetary deficits. In this sense,
fiscal policy could perhaps be regarded from the beginning as a
substitute for central bank policy. The analysis of income-creating
expenditures has been the chief preoccupation of fiscal theory. In
the pump-priming version of the theory the emphasis was laid
on the power of deficit spending to stimulate private investment.
In the later versions it was placed on the need for compensating,
by means of public expenditures, for chronic tendencies toward
over-saving and under-investment.
But throughout the analysis attention was also given to the ways
in which fiscal policy could make central bank policy more effective.




[1]

Monetary analysis had been directed increasingly toward the role
of the rate of interest as the controller of investment. Until Keynes'
Treatise on Money appeared in 1930, the main emphasis had
been on control of the short term rate. That short term credit was
the only proper concern of banking and of monetary control was
an idea deeply rooted in the history of banking theory. It appeared
to follow, for example, from the commercial loan theory of bank
assets, which had its roots in the controversies of the banking and
the currency schools in the first half of the nineteenth century, but
which had persisted with such vitality as to dominate the philosophy
and many of the basic provisions of the Federal Reserve Act. While
the theory was never lived up to entirely in banking practice, short
term assets played the predominant role in banking changes and
it was through them that adjustments were made to changes in the
reserve position of the banks. The result was a high degree of
sensitivity in short term open market rates. Historical charts of
interest rates show that until recent years short term rates fluctu
ated widely above and below the long term rates; and some of the
older economic treatises insisted, though I think with much exag
geration, upon the constancy of the long term rate as indicating a
persistent natural tendency of saving and investment to equalize
at an unchanging rate of interest.
Since the first World War, revolutionary changes have occurred
in American banking. The postwar boom of 1919-20 was a great
blow to the commercial loan theorists, for it was an inventory
boom and found its banking expression primarily in excessive
commercial loan expansion. It was followed by important changes
in financial practice, whereby business became increasingly its own
banker so far as working capital was concerned. Commercial loans
diminished. By 1929 commercial paper eligible for rediscount was
only 12 per cent of total earning assets, and by 1932 only 8 per
cent. In the stock market boom of the late twenties, we saw the
enormous increase in security loans both for the banks' own
account and for the account of others. Out of this experience came
the grant of authority to the Reserve System to control the stock




[2]

market use of credit. This was a fundamental, indeed a revolu
tionary, development in monetary policy, away from the traditional
over-all quantitative control of the supply of money toward the
control of a specific use of money.
But the greatest change which has occurred in banking since the
Reserve System was established has been in the growth of bank
investments. This growth began in the first World War when the
banks, with the aid of the new Reserve System, bought government
securities for their own account and made loans to finance purchases
by the public. That this change in the composition of bank assets
was not merely a temporary wartime change was indicated by the
fact that as the federal debt was reduced during the twenties, the
banks did not reduce their holdings of government securities. Then
followed, beginning in 1931, the continuous series of budget deficits
to the present day. The federal debt, direct and guaranteed, has
risen from $15,922,000,000 on June 30, 1930 to $54,747,000,000
on June 30, 1941, and the holdings of federal government securi
ties by the commercial banks have risen from $4,981,000,000 to
$20,098,000,000. At the present time investments, mainly in gov
ernment securities, comprise about 57 per cent of total earning
assets.
As this great change occurred in bank assets, the theory of assets
underwent important changes. The commercial loan theory came
in for closer scrutiny and some of its fallacies were revealed,
though not I think without leaving in it an important kernel of
truth. Attention was directed toward what was called the "monetary
theory" of bank assets, by which was meant that changes in any
type of assets affect the quantity of deposits and currency, which
in turn was held to produce economic changes. The implication
was that what kinds of changes occur in the composition of bank
assets is immaterial.
As bank investments have increased, long term interest rates
have shown increased sensitivity to changes in bank reserves, and
the emphasis in monetary theory has shifted to the need for con
trolling the long term rates, as more effective for the control of




[3]

investment, income, and employment than control merely of the
short term rates. It was in connection with the long term rate of
interest that fiscal policy was expected to strengthen central bank
policy. The appearance of excess reserves came as a distinct shock
to many monetary theorists in the early thirties. Much of previous
monetary theory had been built on the assumption that the banks
would always be loaned up. But it became unmistakably clear,
as bank reserves expanded, that bankers were interested in the
quality as well as the quantity of their assets, and rather than
assume undue risks would hold their reserves idle. It was at this
point that monetary policy and fiscal policy joined hands. The
financing of deficits, combined with pressure through reserves,
affords an avenue for expansion of bank assets and deposits accom
panied by a decline in interest rates. In addition to the new money
thus created, government borrowing provides an outlet for old
deposits which might otherwise remain idle rather than assume the
risks of investment in depression. Theoretically, the decline of
interest rates would begin in the market for short term securities,
but as the short term rates declined the banks would reach out
for longer maturities. The fall in the rate on government securities
would spread to other investments and loans, attracting both bank
and nonbank investors, until after a transition phase of refunding
of old securities, the new issues market would be affected and a
stream of new investment set in motion.
As we look back over the period since 1932, when the excess
reserves and large scale deficits began, we can see that the only
part of this expectation that failed to materialize was the revival
to an adequate extent of private investment. Though the excess
reserves were not used up, bank assets, mainly in government
securities, greatly expanded, and the expansion of bank deposits
was greater than in any previous period in our history. By 1939
demand deposits and currency were over fifty per cent greater
than at the peak of the boom in 1929. As bank reserves and the
money supply expanded, the rates on long term governments and
on the better grade corporate securities fell to the lowest levels in




*[4]

the history of this or any other country, ( 1) and the rate on short
term governments declined to practically zero.

II
My concern today is with the implications of these developments
for the future of banking and of monetary policy. There is no
denying that we have had the most tremendous experiment in
history with the easy money policy. It should be said that the
scale on which the experiment occurred was not intended. The
conscious, deliberate policy of creating excess reserves by central
bank operations lasted only through 1932 and 1933. The enormous
increase of reserves which occurred thereafter was due mainly to
gold inflow and to a much less extent to the silver purchase
policy. But it should be added that for some time the authorities
were not unsympathetic to the continuing expansion of excess
reserves and the decline of interest rates which accompanied it.
The gold sterilization begun in December, 1936 and the raising of
reserve requirements in 1936-37 were not intended to reverse the
easy money policy, though they did indicate a judgment that there
would be no further advantage, and a growing balance of disad
vantage, if the growth of excess reserves were allowed to proceed
unchecked.
Of special significance were the events which accompanied these
attempts to reduce the excess reserves. For a short period in 1937
there was something resembling a government bond panic. One
can readily appreciate the apprehension which was felt. Selling of
government securities by the banks at a time when the government
debt was still increasing could have highly deflationary effects. It
would mean that nonbank investors would be called upon to buy
not only the new securities being issued but also the old securities
being sold by the banks; and this process would have to take place
(1) The most nearly comparable period is that of the late 1890's and early
1900's when interest rates also fell to very low levels. The conditions,
however, were hardly comparable. The securities which sank lowest
were those bearing the national banknote circulation privilege. Moreover,
the national debt was then very small.




[5]

at a time when the volume of deposits, by reason of bank selling,
was contracting. Actually the net amount of selling by the banks,
and the effects of the selling, were exaggerated in the current dis
cussions. If we look at the full year, June, 1936 to June, 1937,
during which the changes in reserve requirements occurred, what
broadly happened was that New York City banks sold securities
while the interior banks bought. But in the crucial first half of
1937 both classes of banks made net sales. The net contraction of
bank holdings of governments was about a billion dollars, and
interest rates advanced by about a half per cent. The episode
revealed once more, as the bank holiday had done in 1933, that
the peculiar vulnerability of New York, which had been responsible
for our money panics prior to the creation of the Reserve System,
still remains a problem, and one that takes on an added significance
now that bank assets consist to such a large extent of securities
subject to fluctuations in market price. The country banks met
the increased reserve requirements mainly by drawing upon their
balances with their city correspondents. Their excess reserve posi
tion remained but little affected, while the New York banks were
subjected to the double pressure of meeting their own increased
reserve requirements and providing reserves for the country banks.
The fact that the raising of reserve requirements was followed
by the new depression of 1937-38 caused some persons to place
the responsibility for the depression upon the reserve policy, while
others ascribed it mainly to the fact that for a brief interval in
1937 the federal budget came into balance. Though in my judg
ment neither of these developments was a major cause of the new
depression, the conjuncture of circumstances had important effects
upon the further development of ideas with regard to both fiscal
and monetary policies. The gold sterilization policy was dropped,
the reserve requirements were moderately reduced, and the Reserve
System's newly developed function of "maintaining orderly market
conditions" for government securities took on added significance.
As for the banks, some said that the new depression, coupled with
the disappearance of any nearby prospect of resumption of monetary




[6]

control, had "saved the banks." While there was, of course, much
exaggeration in this view, it did point to a growing awareness of
the new elements of instability which the combination of excess
reserves and government deficits had introduced into the banking
system. The selling crisis was short-lived. Gold continued to pour
in, the growth of excess reserves was resumed, the banks resumed
their buying of government securities, and the prices of the securi
ties steadily rose to new all-time highs, with some minor setbacks
such as that on the outbreak of the war in 1939 and on our own
entry into the war less than a month ago.
Much the most important change, for our present subject, that
occurred as a result of the new depression in 1937 was the change
in fiscal theory. The conviction grew that we were faced with
something more than cyclical recovery from a major depression.
The emphasis shifted from pump-priming to the need for deficits
as compensation for long-run structural changes in the economy,
changes which were held to be due to chronic tendencies toward
over-saving and under-investment, and which were said to call
for deficits that might be permanent or at any rate should be contin
ued so long as underemployment prevailed.' )
I had been, and still am, sympathetic to the alliance between
central bank policy and pump-priming. They do not differ from
each other in purpose or in general analysis of the problem. Both
are aimed primarily at cyclical variations on the assumption that
aside from such movements the economy can be self-sustaining.
Properly managed they could be mutually reenforcing. In recovery
from depression the deficits might play the larger role, both by
creating new income directly and by helping to implement an easy
money policy. In a boom, monetary policy could play an important
and perhaps even the predominant role. A contraction of bank
reserves, especially if coupled with some direct controls such as
those over stock market and instalment credit, can exert powerful
effects upon investment, output, and employment, provided excess
(1) For my own views see my paper on "Deficit Spending", American Eco
nomic Review, Proceedings, February, 1941.




[7]

reserves are not too large to prevent central bank contact with the
money market. With budget surpluses in boom offsetting deficits
in depression the problems of bank holdings of government securi
ties would not exist, or at any rate would not reach serious
dimensions.
Whether the pump-priming policy could be successful is another
question. As I said in my paper last year, it was really never tried.
There is no evidence that the Administration, as distinct from some
persons within it and some economists offering advice from the
outside, ever had a conscious interest in fiscal policy as an instru
ment of recovery prior to the new depression in 1938. Government
spending was primarily for relief and was regarded mainly as the
unavoidable accompaniment of unemployment until recovery could
be achieved by other means. I have been inclined to agree with
those who hold that relief expenditures do not reach down far
enough into the economic process to afford much leverage. Public
works expenditures, if they could be adjusted to the business cycle,
would probably be more effective, and military expenditures also
would probably have a greater stimulating effect, even in peace
time. Now that our military expenditures are likely to remain
large, for improvements, replacement, and maintenance even after
the initial expansion has been completed, we may have in such
expenditures, so far as they can be adjusted to business cycle
changes, a significant instrument of control of economic fluctuations.
A further important consideration is that if pump-priming is to be
seriously attempted in the future, it must be done in an atmosphere
that is favorable to "business confidence" and must give attention
to the other economic conditions, including the behavior of costs
and prices and the effects of taxation on investment as well as on
consumption, which bear upon the revival of output and employ
ment under private enterprise.
The difficulties for banking and for monetary control grow not
out of pump-priming but out of the long-run spending policies. The
question which I raise is whether a large and growing public debt
which continues to be financed to a large extent by the banking




[8]

system does not make impossible a general monetary policy and
deprive us of the power to vary the interest rate and the money
supply as instruments of control of economic fluctuations.
That such a control is not feasible in war appears to be amply
indicated by the fact that all the countries at war, not only totali
tarian Germany but democratic England, Canada, and our own
country, are pursuing an easy money policy, notwithstanding the
fact that the money supply is redundant and interest rates are at
or near their record lows. This is a situation without precedent
in the history of wars. Prior to the first World War there would
probably have been general agreement that to control inflation we
should place reliance upon monetary controls first, fiscal controls
second, and direct controls last. Even in the last war Treasury
financing was done at rising rates of interest, though there was
little or no deliberate effort to impose restraints upon monetary
expansion. But in the present war the policy is frankly one of
easy money. With this policy I am entirely in accord. A restric
tive monetary policy is not feasible or desirable so long as the
government is the principal borrower and the banks must be relied
upon to do a large portion of the lending. The restraints imposed
upon inflation, must come mainly through direct controls and
through taxation. That the possibilities of financing war by taxa
tion may be limited, however, would appear to be indicated by the
fact that in England, whose war effort absorbs some 50 per cent
of national income, less than 40 per cent of the war expenditures
are met by taxes.01) Our need for borrowing will undoubtedly
remain large. It is, of course, desirable that this financing should
be done as much as possible outside the banks, but unless and until
other sources of funds can be proved adequate it would be the
height of folly to prevent bank-buying of government securities.
(1) In the first nine months of its current fiscal year (April 1-December 31)

the British Treasury spent almost $14,000,000,000, had revenues of less
than $5,000,000,000 and a deficit of $9,000,000,000.
January 2, 1942.




S[9]

New York Times.

III
Under war-time conditions we shall probably have to bow to
this necessity. But what are the implications of an indefinitely
prolonged continuance of large-scale public borrowing thereafter?
This question breaks down into a number of aspects, such as the
future of interest rates, of the volume of deposits, the condition of
the banking system, and the future course of excess reserves and
monetary policy.
One of the main lessons to be drawn from our experiences of
the past decade is that it is possible to overdo an easy money policy.
It is a curious fact that though fiscal policy grew out of the recog
nition that pushing down the interest rate does not adequately
achieve a revival of investment, output, and employment, the
emphasis upon low interest rates was carried over not only into
the pump-priming policy, where it rightly belonged, but also into
the long-run "compensatory" fiscal theories, which in one version
rest upon the assumption of chronic over-saving, and in another
upon the assumption that in a mature economy private investment
cannot be adequate, however stimulated. Doubtless the explana
tion is that even under these assumptions it is desirable to do
everything possible to stimulate private investment. (1) Great
emphasis was placed by Keynes in his General Theory on the
need for reducing the interest rate. His thesis is that since, by
reason of risk and other factors affecting "liquidity preference,"
we cannot.push the interest rate below a certain minimum, we
must use deficit spending (or taxation) to fill the gap between
saving and investment.
The question raised by our experience, however, is whether too
much emphasis has not been placed upon the interest rate as a
cost of investment and too little upon it as an inducement to invest.
Interest is but one of the costs of investment and is unlikely in
most cases to be the controlling one, even though it is more import
1) Another consideration may be the cost of carrying the public debt, but

this is surely a very minor point with those who hold these theories,
since they repeatedly take pains to demonstrate that the economic cost
of public debt is slight.




[10]

ant in long than in short time investment. But there is also the
viewpoint of the lender. When the interest rate falls very low
there may be inadequate inducement to invest out of income, or
even to keep capital invested. This is, one must admit, not alto
gether a simple question. We must recognize, for example, that
some kinds of institutions have increased their investments, even
at falling interest rates, when they have been under pressure to
invest and could find safe investments. As already described, it
was the pressure of excess reserves, combined with the need for
earnings as interest rates declined, which induced the banks to
invest in government securities. One could cite too the increase
of investments of the insurance companies, also under heavy pres
sure to invest premiums and maintain earnings. But such facts do
not prove that the aggregate of investment would not be greater
if interest rates were higher. And when the theoretical problem
posed is that of idle saving, is this not the proper question? One
of the most striking aspects of our experience during the thirties
was that the unprecedentedly large increase in the volume of
deposits and currency which resulted from the combination of
excess reserves and deficit financing was offset by an equally great
decline in the velocity of money. There is no precedent for this
experience, on such a scale, in all preceding monetary history. The
explanation of it is probably complex. One important cause may
well have been the "lack of confidence," quite apart from the
interest rate, on which the business and financial world so much
insisted during the period of New Deal experimentation. But it
may well have been due also to the fact that the interest return
from investment was not high enough to overcome "liquidity
preference."
That an easy money policy can be overdone is indicated also by
the fact that when interest rates fall to very low levels deflationary
stresses and strains appear in the economy which are directly
attributable to this decline. A wide range of institutions and indi
viduals dependent upon fixed income-yielding investments suffer
losses of income whose effects upon their ability and willingness to




[ 11]

invest further, their sense of security, and even their ability to
maintain consumption, work directly counter to the purpose of
the easy money policy. If the low interest rates did actually
achieve an adequate recovery of investment, output, and employ
ment, these adverse effects could perhaps be dismissed as part of
the necessary cost of a successful monetary policy. But when rates
reach such a low level that they accomplish little or nothing further
to stimulate investment, from the side of demand for capital, while
impairing the ability of some important income groups and insti
tutions to invest or even to consume, the easy money policy has
overreached itself.
There have been suggestions in recent years, and some of them
have come from fiscal theorists who in the past have been most
insistent upon low interest rates, that it may be necessary to sub
sidize some classes of interest receivers, by devising special gov
ernment security issues at higher cotipons than the prevailing open
market rates. There could be many candidates for such subsidies
long before interest rates reached Joan Robinson's suggested zero. 0 )
Recently, one or two of the leading insurance companies have
announced an advance in premium rates to offset the decline of
yield upon investments.( 2 ) Savings banks have had to cut their
interest payments to a very low level. Universities and other
endowed institutions have had to cut their budgets. We are told
that in England it is frankly recognized that the government must
sustain the banks by borrowing at rates high enough to cover bank
expenses, and that the same subject has aroused some interest
in Canada.
One of the chief difficulties of an easy money policy, when it
is implemented or accompanied by large government borrowing,
is that it becomes increasingly difficult to reverse the policy. This,
as I have sought to show, has been the main implication of our
(1) Essays in the Theory of Employment, p. 255:

". . when capitalism is
rightly understood, the rate of interest will be set at zero, and the major
evils of capitalism will disappear."
(2) See New York Times editorial. "Easy Money and Insurance," November
22, 1941, suggesting special Treasury issues for insurance companies.




[12]

own experience of the past decade. And it is the main reason
for the suggestions that we may have to make a list of exceptions
to the application of the policy. The larger the public debt and
the greater the continuing need of the government to borrow and
spend, the greater are the hazards for the Treasury and for the
banking system that are involved in any reversal of the policy. For
the Treasury it would mean financing at rising rates of interest,
which means not only a rising cost of borrowing, which by itself
might not be decisive though increasingly important as the debt
expands, but also an increasing worry that the market may develop
an inclination to hold off and wait for better terms and so have
increasingly to be coaxed or threatened. To the banks it would
mean increased earnings on new issues but losses in market values
upon old ones. The result is that even when there may be general
agreement that interest rates have gone too low and that it might
have been better to stabilize them at some earlier time when they
were higher, there is always a strong presumption in favor of sta
bilizing at the current level, if not indeed of allowing them to go
still lower. To put rates up would mean to throw the main burden
of adjustment upon the banking system and the Treasury. That
such a policy would be unwise in war time seems generally to be
recognized, but the problem would be no different in time of peace
if the same facts as to size and distribution of the public debt and
the continuing need for public borrowing prevailed.
One further important aspect of an extreme, easy money policy,
implemented by excess reserves and public borrowing, is that the
effects are different upon different rates of interest. In the debates
about monetary policy in the late twenties and early thirties, one
of the points most emphasized by those who doubted the adequacy
of interest rate control ( 1) as a means of controlling investment,
output, and employment was that there was not one rate of interest
but many, and that the differences in their behavior greatly compli
cated the task of central bank control. One complication was a
(1) See my paper, "The Monetary Doctrines of J. M. Keynes," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, August, 1931.




[13]

perverse cyclical variation, such that when the rates most subject
to monetary control were falling in depression and rising in a
boom in response to central bank policy, other rates were rising
and falling in response to expectations of income affecting risk.
Owing to such factors as defects of market organization, inertia,
local or regional customs, and the importance of personal relations
between lender and borrower, many interest rates were largely
insensitive to quantitative monetary controls, which affected mainly
the open market rates of the large financial centers. Looking back
at our experiences of the past decade, we can see how uneven the
effects of the easy money policy have been. Great gaps have
been opened up in the interest rate structure. At one extreme,
short term open market rates, prior to the recent decline in excess
reserves, had been reduced to virtually zero. Such low rates as
have prevailed for Treasury bills and other high grade short term
paper serve no useful purpose and reflect nothing other than the
abnormality of excessive bank reserves. Were such rates more
nearly in line with longer term rates, as used to be the case, banks
would be under less pressure to reach out for longer maturities
to maintain earnings, and one of the main dangers of banking
instability would be removed. At the other extreme, some other
interest rates, such as mortgage rates and the general level of cus
tomer loan rates outside the larger centers, have been largely
insensitive to excess reserves and have tended to remain rigid
at relatively high levels. For these reasons, the interest rate
discussion has entered a new phase in recent years, ivith a growing
recognition that rates may be both too low and too high at the
same time, the low rates accomplishing nothing further to stimulate
investment while causing injury to many institutions and indi
viduals, while the high rates may still retard investment in some
directions. There has been growing recognition also that this
kind of problem calls for new methods of attack to supplement
the traditional central bank methods. I have not touched upon
the government lending agencies, which are the subject of Professor
Jacoby's paper on this program. But one major question is the
part which such agencies can play in carrying into important areas
of credit the effects of monetary policy. A closely related question,
and one of great importance, I believe, for the future of monetary




[14]

policy, is whether such agencies, exercising as they do important
monetary powers, ought not to be tied more definitely than at
present into the organization of monetary control.

IV
There remain the implications of fiscal policy for the future of
the banking system. We must distinguish between what has already
happened and the long-run effects of large scale, long continued
government borrowing from the banks. As regards our experi
ence thus far, it is easily possible to exaggerate the adverse effects.
The banking system has shown a high degree of adaptability to
the revolutionary changes in bank assets. Each period of unsettle
ment since 1937 in the government security markets has been met
with greater calmness. The banks have made progress in so
arranging their.portfolios as to be able to hold longer term securi
ties through periods of temporary market stress. They have also
developed some sources of new earnings and of service in meeting
the credit needs of the community. Looking back to the bank
holiday of 1933, we can see that the banking system has made
decided progress. Outside the large cities bank earnings have
been well maintained, and even in such centers, where the fall in
open market rates would naturally be most strongly felt, the decline
has not affected the soundness of the banks. But there may be
more serious earnings problems during the war period. In the
thirties the decline of interest rates was in part offset by reduction
of expenses. But with the rise of taxes, wages, and other costs
incident to war there is some danger that the banks may be more
seriously pinched.
Some other effects of long-run government borrowing from the
banks may be more serious than the effect on earnings, as that
has thus far developed. Bank buying of government securities
increases bank deposits. The growth of deposits has two import
ant aspects. One is the monetary aspect. I have always been
dubious about the effect of an increase in the supply of money,
taken by itself, upon money spending and thus upon output and
employment. It is a permissive rather than an activating factor.
There was a time, in the late twenties and early thirties, when




[ 151

such a suggestion was vigorously combatted, but now the pendulum
may have swung too far in favor of this view. Granted that
money supply has only a passive influence unless other factors
are present to stimulate its use, it is not prudent to add continu
ously to a money supply which already is greater, both absolutely
and in relation to volume of output and employment, than at any
previous time in our history. But this is the logical implication of
long continued government spending, combined with excess reserves,
unless the financing can be done outside the banking system.
At least equally serious are the implications of a long continued
large scale growth of bank deposits for the capital position of the
banks. Already there has been a marked reduction in the capital
deposits ratio, particularly in the centers where bank buying of
government securities has been heaviest. It is true there have
been some important offsetting changes. The margin of safety
which capital is supposed to afford depends not merely upon the
quantitative excess of total assets over deposit liabilities but also
upon the soundness and the liquidity of the assets. From this
point of view excess reserves are themselves an important factor
in bank safety, since they constitute a buffer which protects the
banks from being forced to liquidate assets to meet withdrawals
of deposits. It is in this way that the presence of excess reserves
has enabled the banks to reach out for government securities of
longer maturity as the rates on short term assets have declined.
It is true also that the very fact that banks now hold government
securities in large amounts means that the quality of their assets
has improved. In these respects it can correctly be argued, as
some bankers have done, that a smaller capital-deposits ratio is
needed than used to be the case. But some of the implications of
this line of argument I find disturbing. It implies, for example,
that excess reserves will continue to be needed indefinitely, or as
long as bank assets continue to consist of government securities
other than short term securities. It implies also that as deposits
and government security holdings expand and the margin of
capital over deposits becomes thinner, it will be less and less
possible for banks to increase their other assets, except for those
which likewise involve a minimum of risk. Finally, it implies
that the function of the Reserve System would be more and more




[ 16]

that of preserving stability in the government bond market and
less and less that of exercising monetary control. Moreover, if
the banking system is to become more and more a mechanism for
providing funds to finance government expenditure, and a mechan
ism the preservation of whose stability becomes increasingly a
matter of concern to government, could not the ultimate reaction
of the public be that such a mechanism should be a public rather
than a private institution? It would not need a disturbance on
the scale of the bank holiday of 1933 to develop this conviction.
Of course, if bank capital could be increased correspondingly with
bank deposits, the problem of the capital-deposits ratio would be
solved. But falling interest rates and earnings do not encourage
investment in bank capital, and maintaining dividends in the face
of reduced earnings is not a remedy. If capital were provided by
government agencies, the implications of eventual government
ownership would be strengthened, and suggestions of government
subsidies to sustain earnings would point in the same direction.

V
The obvious solution of many of the problems I have discussed
would be to finance government spending outside the banking
system. That we have had to rely so heavily upon the banks is
indeed the great paradox of deficit spending. Why should this
need to be the case, if as the theory maintains, the condition of
under-employment which the spending is to correct is due to over
saving or under-investment? Why should not the saving itself
finance the deficits ? In Kahn's early article on the multiplier this
part of the logic of the process was expressly recognized. He
pointed out that there should be no problem of money supply. The
deficit spending needed to maintain full employment would be
precisely equal to the leakages out of income. ( )
It could be argued that the saving might remain idle and thus
need to be offset by new money from the banking system. But
this is business cycle analysis. It is appropriate to the pump
priming theory, which is cyclical and assumes no increase of either
money supply or public debt for the cycle as a whole. But in the
(1) R. H. Kahn, "The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment,"
Economic Journal, June, 1931, pp. 174, 189.




[ 17]

long-run "compensatory" fiscal theory business cycle influences
play no part. There is no ground for assuming variations in
either the quantity or the rate of use of money, except for the
long-run tendency with which the theory is concerned, which is
the tendency for a part of income to be saved and not invested.
As I have said and as Kahn clearly expected, it is the function of
public spending, by the theory's own logic, to absorb this saving
and restore it to the income stream.
In what may be regarded as an effort to adapt the theory to
business cycle changes and the problem of war-time expansion, it
has been suggested that government expenditures should be financed
by a combination of borrowing from banks, borrowing from non
bank sources, and taxation, in this order, the emphasis shifting
forward as output and employment increase and the danger of
inflation becomes greater. As a fiscal program for war-time expan
sion, starting from a state of under-employment, this is the right
pattern. But as I said earlier, it does not seem probable that we
shall be able, at any stage of our war financing, to avoid a sub
stantial amount of borrowing, or to avoid doing a considerable
part of it from the banks.
-It has been suggested that the financing of deficit spending in
the thirties gave evidence of conforming to this pattern. From
1933 to 1936 bank holdings of government securities substantially
increased, but from 1936 to 1939 they were about stationary. This
fact, however, affords no proof that bank investment diminishes as
output and employment expand, unless the expansion is accom
panied by monetary control. The period 1936-39 is the one 1
described earlier. That bank holdings for the period as a whole
did not increase was due to the selling of securities by the banks
in 1936-37, when excess reserves were reduced by the raising of
reserve requirements. When the pressure was removed by further
gold inflow, abandonment of gold sterilization, and a moderate
reduction of reserve requirements, bank buying of government
securities was resumed. The question I raised was whether in
the light of that experience it will be feasible to exert monetary
pressure on the banks so long as their holdings of governments
remain large and the need of large scale borrowing continues.
Since 1939 the banks have greatly increased their holdings, both




[18]

absolutely and in relation to the increase of the public debt. In
1930-39 they took 36 per cent of the increase in the federal debt.
In the two years June 30, 1939 to June 30, 1941, they took 47
per cent. 0 ) This increase has occurred, moreover, at a time when
the need for borrowing outside the banks has received much
emphasis and an organized effort has been launched to attract the
nation's savings. Such an effort takes time to plan and to gain
its full momentum. Probably now that we are actually at war the
nonbank part of our borrowing will substantially increase. But
nothing in our experience thus far indicates that it is possible to
finance large scale, long continued public borrowing without con
siderable dependence on the banking system.
I do not regard the monetary and banking difficulties which I
have discussed in this paper as necessarily decisive arguments
against large scale deficit spending, indefinitely prolonged. My
principal doubts about such a policy rest on other grounds, some
of which I discussed at our annual meeting a year ago. I am not
sure that with careful handling some of the banking difficulties
might not be removed or considerably lessened. One way might
(1) Net Changes in Holdings of Federal Government Obligations
Direct and Guaranteed
(Millions of dollars)

June 30
dates

Total
outstanding
interest
bearing
securities

Commercial banks
Federal
agencies
and trust Central
funds, and Reserve
All
Federal
N.Y. C.
Reserve
member
commerMutual
Insurance
Banks
banks
cial banks savings banks companies*

1916-1919
1919-1930
1930-1940
1940-1941

+24,262
- 9,312
+31,952
+ 6,873

+ 382
+1,122
+7,970
+1,131

+ 645
+ 464
+4,339
+1,782

+ 4,390
162
+11,571
+ 3,546

+ 660
150
+2,590
+ 320

+

1933-1934
1934-1935
1935-1936
1936-1937
1937-1938
1938-1939
1939-1940
1940-1941

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+

+1,196
+ 548
+ 328
+1,361
+1,243
+1,096
+1,074
+1,131

+ 659
+ 558
+ 954
-1,133
+ 110
+ 744
+1,002
+1,782

+
+
+
+
+
+

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+

+ 500
+1,100
+1,300
+1,100
+ 200
+ 600
+ 300
+ 500

5,003
4,607
5,939
2,758
963
3,908
2,538
6,873

2,826
2,416
2,552
712
516
1.654
855
3,546

250
570
510
340
300
350
70
320

500

Other

+18,800
-10,100
+ 3,700
+ 1,400
+

200
0
+ 1,200
+
700
300
+
200
+
300
+ 1,400

* Prior to 1932 holdings of insurance companies were included in other holdings.




[19]

be through lessening the dependence upon excess reserves. This
is in part a matter of altering bankers' psychology by recreating
the willingness and the habit of resorting to the central bank to
meet temporary changes of reserve position. In the past year,
mainly through cessation of gold inflow and the expansion of
deposits and currency, the excess reserves have been greatly
reduced. It is not improbable that within the next year bank
reserves will need to be increased. If, however, advantage could
be taken of the present circumstances to create in our banking
system the conditions which now exist in England and Canada,
where there is assurance of an easy money policy supported by
ample bank reserves but without large excess reserves, that would
be a long step toward removing some of the abnormalities that
have developed in the past ten years. Reduction of excess reserves
would mean, as we have seen in recent months, that short term
interest rates would rise, removing or lessening one of the import
ant gaps in the interest rate structure. With short term rates
higher, banks would be under less pressure to invest in long term
government securities, and we might approach more nearly a
logical division of the government security market, with the banks
holding the short term securities and nonbank investors the long
term public debt. Such a distribution of the debt would lessen the
dangers now involved in temporary fluctuations in government
security prices, and might permit again some use, under peace-time
conditions, of a general monetary control.
I do not think, however, that this change will be easy to bring
about. And it would still remain true that the larger the public
debt becomes the harder it will be to avoid the kinds of difficulties
I have described. The real solution, and the only logical one,
would be to finance deficit spending outside the banking system.
For the advocates of large scale, long continued public spending
this seems likely to become a major challenge. My own belief is
that the monetary and banking difficulties raised by public spending
constitute an added reason for seeking correctives for secular
defects in our economy in other directions, including taxation
though I am convinced that as yet our knowledge of the economic
effects of taxation is not very great-and for using deficit spending
primarily for business cycle changes.




[20]

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: The Postwar Monetary Plans

Journal Title: American Economic Review

Volume Number: XXXIV
Date:

March 1944

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: 1

INTERNATIONAL TRADE WITH PLANNED
ECONOMIES: THE ITO CHARTER

BY

JOHN H. WILLIAMS
Nathaniel Ropes Professor of Political Economy,
Harvard University

AN ADDRESS
BEFORE THE

ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
AT THE
SEMI-ANNUAL MEETING ON
"FREE ENTERPRISE -NATIONAL

AND INTERNATIONAL"

APRIL 17, 1947

THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY
1947




INTERNATIONAL TRADE WITH PLANNED
ECONOMIES: THE ITO CHARTER
JOHN H. WILLIAMS

Nathaniel Ropes Professor of Political Economy, Harvard University

W

I

HEN I last spoke on this-program, in April 1945, our

subject was the Bretton Woods agreements. As we
meet today, the representatives of our country, Eng
land, and sixteen other countries are meeting in Geneva for the
dual purpose of agreeing upon a final draft of an ITO Charter
for presentation to a world conference on trade and employ
ment at some later date, and of making tariff concessions among
themselves. The Monetary Fund, the World Bank, the Inter
national Trade Organization and its Charter, and the current
tariff negotiations are all parts of a general plan, dating back at
least to 1943, for restoring multilateral trade in the post-war
world and reducing, so far as possible, the restrictive trade and
monetary practices which in the inter-war period increasingly
threatened to destroy the multilateral system.
I think I should say at the outset that in my discussion two
years ago, as well as in earlier papers, I favored the International
Bank but had some reservations about the Monetary Fund.
Apart from technical questions about the mechanics of the Fund
and the principles of international monetary adjustment, my
doubts had to do mainly with the question whether in our pre
occupation with a long-run monetary plan we might not fail to
deal adequately with the concrete problems of the transition
period; and, in particular, whether in this over-all approach we
might not fail to recognize that the interconvertibility of the
dollar and the pound is the inner core of the monetary problem
and that its achievement would have to depend upon the meas
ures taken, outside the Fund and the Bank, to correct the British
balance of payments difficulties.




No. 3]

INTERNATIONAL TRADE

37

Perhaps the largest question about the success of our efforts
to restore a multilateral trade and currency system is whether
we have not made a major, and possibly an irreparable, mistake
in not dealing sooner with the British problem. By the time we
got to the Anglo-American loan negotiations in the last half of
1945, much of the spirit of wartime cooperation had been lost,
and the solution arrived at was, in my opinion, inadequate for
the problem. We should have made a gift rather than a loan
perhaps at an earlier date we could have agreed upon a post-war
extension of Lend-Lease. But if it had to be a loan it should
have been interest-free. Britain's problem today is how to in
crease her exports by seventy-five per cent beyond their pre-war
volume while restricting imports to their pre-war level. It
seems increasingly clear that the loan will be used up before the
end of the five-year breathing period that it was intended to
finance; and if by 1952 the British balance of payments deficit
is not corrected, and with enough margin to begin payments on
the loan, it seems idle to expect that our efforts to restore a
multilateral system of trade and currency can be successful.'
One other comment on the Monetary Fund seems relevant to
our current discussions of the International Trade Organization
and its Charter. One point I strongly emphasized was that the
Monetary Fund should not be used in the transition period, be
fore the more normal trade conditions which its logic assumes
had been realized. Thus far, no use has been made of the Fund,
but in accordance with its provisions the member countries have
declared their official parities; and with the general condition of
inflation existing in the world, there has been an understandable
tendency to overvalue relative to the dollar. Whether any such
development was contemplated by the authors of the Fund
agreement, whether, in dealing with such a large-scale problem
of fundamental readjustments of rates as we may face after the
inflationary conditions have passed, the Fund will be able to
avoid another vicious circle of currency depreciations such as
occurred in the inter-war period, and whether it might not have
1 The most serious aspect of the British problem is not whether in the
transition period she will be able to correct her balance of payments deficit
with the aid of the loan, difficult though that problem is, but whether in
the long run she will be able to maintain the new equilibrium required by
her changed international position, including repayment of the loan. This
is primarily a question of productivity and real income. See below, pp. 43-44.




38

FREE EhTERPPRISE

[VOL. XXII

been better to postpone the whole matter of official parities until
more normal trade conditions have been achieved are among the
larger questions for the future.
But one question which seems to be emerging with increasing
definiteness, and which the premature declarations of parities
may have helped to emphasize, is whether countries may not in
future rely mainly upon direct trade controls and use them as
a means of avoiding changes in exchange rates. There was
already a tendency in this direction before the war, and war and
post-war experience may have pushed it further. It may well
be that the general pattern of adjustment technique will be one
of trade restrictions first, exchange controls second, and
exchange-rate variation third. Exchange control over capital
movements is already provided for in the Fund agreement, but
the intention is to do away with exchange control over current
transactions, and the Anglo-American loan agreement provides
for the freeing of British current transactions from exchange
control by July 15 of this year. But in the discussions of the
Bretton Woods agreements in England and elsewhere much was
made of the fact that the monetary agreement did not cover
trade restrictions and that there was still the possibility of ac
complishing through direct import controls whatever the mem
ber countries might seem to be giving up in the way of monetary
controls. It is not surprising therefore that the ITO discussions
have provided the real field for debate as to the reservations on
which countries will insist before committing themselves to any
plan for the restoration of multilateral trade.
II
Throughout the post-war trade and monetary discussions
there has been a common pattern of differences of national atti
tudes, the United States attempting to lead the way toward
multilateral trade and reasonably stable and convertible cur
rencies and the other nations endeavoring to safeguard them
selves against the possible hazards involved. The ITO Charter
has gone through several drafts since it was first drawn up by
our State Department. 2 It was considerably revised at the first
meeting of the Preparatory Committee last fall in London and
2 Proposals for Expansion of World Trade and Employment, November
1945. These proposals developed out of the discussions leading to the British
loan agreement, and were accepted in principle by the British government.




No. 3]

INTERNATIONAL TRADE

39

doubtless will be further modified at Geneva. This has been a
continuous process of relaxing the logic of the multilateral sys
tem in order to gain wider adherence. The number and variety
of " escape clauses " have increased. One of the most funda
mental is the right to protect foreign exchange reserves by direct
import trade restrictions. To this are related the reservation,
much insisted upon, of protecting the home economy against
external deflations-I see no reason why protection from exter
nal inflations should not equally be emphasized-and the reser
vation of a large degree of freedom to deal with economic
fluctuations at home and to protect a country's internal economic
planning.
One interesting difference between the Fund agreement and
the ITO Charter is in the nature and degree of the authority
assigned to the two institutions. Whereas, in the Fund agree
ment, the Fund must be consulted and must give its consent
before there can be any resort, after the transition period, to
exchange control over current transactions (for example, in the
scarce currency provision) or before a member country can
change its exchange rate beyond an initial ten per cent, in the
ITO Charter the individual member country may suspend a
number of major Charter obligations if, on its own appraisal, it
considers certain criteria of economic strain specified in the
Charter to have been fulfilled; in invoking such escape clauses
the member need not even consult in advance with the ITO,
which can, it seems, only review the case and approve requests
for retaliatory action by other nations if deemed justifiable.
The Charter has been criticized as being merely a collection
of escape clauses. Besides those I have mentioned, there are
clauses which permit considerable latitude with regard to inter
national commodity agreements, bulk buying by the state, do
mestic subsidies, protection of young industries, particularly in
undeveloped countries, protection of a country's right to decide
what imports are desirable and what are not, and so on. On
such grounds, the Charter has been described as representing
merely an official sanctioning of the restrictive practices of the
thirties, and perhaps some new ones, whereas its main purpose
before being subjected to international negotiation had been
substantially to reduce such practices.
Such criticism, it seems to me, does not penetrate very deeply
into the nature of the problem. Without denying that we may




V. D' 1 E71". ? 7" T

40

VAtC

CY I I

.V 'D0 1? T 017r'

CIUJC

7^.Vr

TT

A.&LL
J
L VO.

too rdadily concede too much, we have to recognize that under
the conditions now existing in the world it is a choice between
this kind of approach and none at all. In criticizing escape
clauses, we must not overlook the fact that we have our own.
The President has found it desirable to assure Congress that any
trade concessions to-which we might now agree in Geneva will
be withdrawn if they injure any American industry.
III
Much of this is by now familiar ground. We are brought
back always, whether we are discussing the trade aspects or the
monetary aspects, to the fundamental nature of the problem of
international adjustments in the modern world, and to a recog
nition of how much more complex a world it has become since
the English classical economists handed on to us the theory and
the system of free multilateral trade and its monetary comple
ment, the gold standard. That system assumed not only exter
nal freedom of trade at stable exchange rates but also, internally,
a laissez-faire private-enterprise system. Through the free
interplay of economic changes, working through the cost-price
structures of the trading countries tied together through fixed
exchange rates, the countries held each other automatically in
balance in a balanced world. It was a beautiful conception,
though oversimplified even for its own day.
I cannot in this short paper review adequately the changes in
ideas or conditions, but four broad sets of facts must be empha
sized.
1. The multilateral trade system developed out of the con
ditions of an expanding world in which different kinds of coun
tries played complementary roles, the manufactured products of
the industrial countries being exchanged for the foods and raw
materials of the less developed countries, the process being fos
tered by the flow of capital from the more to the less advanced
countries, and the whole system revolving about England as the
trade and financial center. In such a system, international trade
adjustment was to a large extent a self-regulating process, and,
to the extent that it was not, the mechanism of the London
money market in normal circumstances provided such control
as was needed. Even in the nineteenth century, however, the
multilateral system was a fair-weather system, which broke
down under conditions of war and of major booms and depres-




No. 3]

INTERNATIONAL TRADE

41

sions. But there was no room for doubt about its maximizing
effect upon international trade and hence of the desirability of
restoring it whenever it collapsed. Even before the First World
War, there were indications that the system was undergoing
change and that England was losing her central place. Now, as
a consequence of two wars and the intervening maladjustments,
we have a very different kind of world, and one of the basic
questions is whether a substitute can be found to perform Eng
land's role of market of last resort and her role as creditor and
controller of the international system.
2. The system never had the unqualified support of all the
trading countries that its logic assumed. In the nineteenth cen
tury the main reservation was found in the unequal develop
ment of the trading countries and the case, strongly argued vir
tually everywhere except in free-trade England, for protection
of young industries and young countries. But tariffs, though
they modified the terms of trade and may at times have re
stricted its volume, did not interfere seriously with the multi
lateral system so long as England's large free market remained
open.
3. The second great reservation upon the free working of the
multilateral system has been the increasing emphasis upon inter
nal stability at high employment. The maladjustments growing
out of the First World War and the great depression of the early
thirties have greatly increased this emphasis. Indeed, it seems
not too much to say that, taken together with England's
changed position in the world and the growing predominance of
our own country in the grand aggregate of world production,
these changes have completely altered our conception of the
problem, to the point where we find ourselves compelled to
recognize the dependence of order and stability in world trade
upon the maintenance of stability at high employment in the
leading countries, and particularly in this country. Some of
the countries participating in the ITO discussions, notably Aus
tralia, have carried this changed viewpoint so far as to insist that
adherence to a multilateral system must be conditioned on some
kind of guarantee of stable high employment in the United
States, the alternative being complete freedom to the other coun
tries to set up regional or bilateral systems based on common
policies to maintain high production and employment within
the trade area, and to protect themselves against external dis
turbance.




Nt

r-TE?

42

CA CI ,r-l

.

T'E'

.-

PDDIC

,i rlt

rTrV
LV

XXIYTT
.LVJ6

4. To an increasing extent this reservation in favor of internal
stability has been developing into what I think must be recog
nized as a third kind of reservation, namely, the right of a
country to plan its economic and political system, even though
this may mean nationalizing its industries and controlling its
economy for purposes of social security and welfare, as well as
business-cycle stability. Thus we have a very mixed world with
countries ranging all the way from our own still predominantly
private-enterprise system through various degrees of planned
economy embracing elements of state socialism to a completely
controlled economy like that of Communist Russia.

IV
Our problem is how to restore a multilateral trade system
which was the product of the comparatively free economic
world of the nineteenth century in such a world as this and
make it work to the general advantage. It can be done, if at
all, only by a process of evolution, and success will have to de
pend primarily upon what can be done, outside ITO and its
Charter, to promote conditions favorable to such a process. We
shall have to recognize that the task is essentially one of pioneer
ing, of fitting an old technique to a new set of conditions, and
that doctrinaire insistence on old principles and formulas is not
the right approach. On the other hand, it seems no less true
that much of what I have referred to above as reservations upon
the free play of the multilateral system will have to be thought
through anew to see what are the limits which external forces
necessarily impose upon freedom of internal planning.
I have not now much confidence in the suggested formula
that we can have the best of both worlds if only the nations will
combine upon common domestic policies for maintaining high
employment. Though I made such a suggestion regarding this
country and England in my first paper on the Monetary Fund
in 1943 3 I was relying heavily on the intimate wartime coopera
tion we then had; I question now its feasibility even for these
countries; and any general extension of the idea of common do
S"Currency Stabilization: The Keynes and White Plans", Foreign
Affairs, July 1943. Reprinted in my book Postwar Monetary Plans and
Other Essays (2nd ed., New York, 1945), ch. 1. See also R. G. Hawtrey,
Bretton Woods for Better or Worse (London and New York, 1946), pp.
112-14.




INTERNATIONAL TRADE

No. 3]

43

mestic policies to a large number of countries in such a mixed
world seems visionary. Hardly more practicable is the idea of a
" guarantee " for continuing high employment by this country
as the necessary condition for adoption of a multilateral system.
We must indeed recognize the importance, for the problem, of
stability here at home, and the reasonableness of escape clauses
if this condition is not realized; but it will be unfortunate if our
efforts at international trade and monetary coiperation degen
erate into mutual reproaches such as this formula so readily sug
gests.
For the world at large the problem is one of finding the limits
of tolerance which external conditions impose upon the freedom
of internal action. In the inter-war period the international
maladjustments and the great depression, combined with the de
velopment of " closed economy " economics, pushed to extrava
gant lengths, in my opinion, the analysis of currency deprecia
tion, exchange control, and restrictive trade devices as buffers to
protect the home economy and the freedom of internal policy.
Now I think the pendulum is swinging back. The Second
World War has uncovered the absurdity-which was always
there-of supposing that nations ever really had a choice as be
tween living in this world or in closed economies. But the
swing back is only partial. It does not mean that other coun
tries have given up, or should give up, their freedom to plan for
internal stability and security. What is, I think, being forced
upon us is a clearer recognition that such freedom can be exer
cised only within the limits imposed by a country's international
position, by the extent to which its own well-being is dependent
upon its relations with the outside world. Where the pendulum
will come to rest, just what the nature of the ultimate com
promise will be, no one can say. The swing in the British atti
tude has been striking, as between, for example, Lord Keynes's
paper on "National Self-Sufficiency "4 in 1933 and his post
humous paper on " The Balance of Payments of the United
States " " in 1946, or the Chancellor of the Exchequer's recent
statement that British policy is being dominated by the exi
gencies of her balance of payments position;
and almost
4 Yale Review, vol. XXII, Sumner 1933.
5 The

Economic Journal, vol. LVI, June 1946.

e The New York Times, April 17, 1947.




44

-FREEENTERPRISE

[VOL. XXII

nothing now is being heard of currency depreciation as the way
out. To a striking degree, the problem is being posed as the
classical economists might have posed it, in terms of productivity
and real income.
V
I have always insisted that international trade adjustment is a
two-sided process. If for other countries the meaning of this
is that external forces impose upon them limitations of produc
tivity and real income which circumscribe their freedom of in
ternal planning, what are the implications for ourselves?
I referred earlier to England's role in the nineteenth century.
Our position in the world today is in some respects similar to
England's former position, but in some respects it is different.
We are not nearly so dependent on external trade. As our his
tory has so often proved, in our mixed industrial-agricultural
economy there is much more room for internal conflicts about
external policy; and at the same time we are much freer from
external restraints upon internal policy. Though multilateral
trade is the natural and logical complement of our kind of eco
nomic system, we could dispense with its benefits more readily,
in case of need, than almost any other country. It follows that
whatever hazards there may be in restoring multilateral trade,
should it not work well, would affect us less than almost any
other country. At the same time, it is probably true that with
our favorable trade-balance position, our lesser dependence on
foreign trade, and our much greater freedom from controls in
domestic trade, we are less well equipped than some other coun
tries, and perhaps notably England, to play the game of bilateral
bargains and restrictive trade practices if it should come to that.
It is not easy to say what these differences add up to, but it
does seem true that if we are to play England's former role in the
multilateral trade system, we must do it in a more conscious and
deliberate way than ever she did. In the forefront of the prob
lem is the need for maintaining stability at home. This, as I
have said, has been much emphasized by other countries, and
while it can be pushed too far and developed into a general alibi
for bad behavior, it does seem true that the maintenance of high
employment here at home is the greatest single contribution we
can make toward the success of our own efforts to restore multi
lateral trade. But we are far from agreed among ourselves as




No. 3]

INTERNATIONAL TRADE

45

to how this can or should be done, and the most relevant and
hopeful aspect of the matter is that, looking beyond the present
inflation and its correction, we seem to have a good prospect of
sustained high production and employment for some time ahead.
For our external policy there are both trade and financial im
plications, but a less clear prospect as to how matters will turn
out. There is need-and this is where the contrast with Eng
land's earlier position seems to me sharpest-for a rather drastic
reorientation of our outlook on foreign trade. We shall have to
learn not to count upon exports for leverage to sustain high
employment at home if such a policy means putting further
pressure upon the already strained position of other countries.
This is less a question of the volume of exports than of the
export surplus. There will probably be a larger than normal
demand for our goods and services for some time to come, but
long continued one-sided trade can end only in the breakdown
of the system we are striving to restore. For a proper balance
in the world we must increasingly emphasize our imports. We
saw during the inter-war period the evil consequences of a me
chanical propping-up of our economy by one-sided trade involv
ing either a draining from the rest of the world of its monetary
resources or a foreign " investment" which did not give rise to
a flow of goods from the borrowing countries.
But this is one of the thorniest aspects of the whole problem,
and adequate discussion would run much beyond the limits of
this paper. It seems certain that large-scale American financial
aid will be essential over the next decade if we are to achieve the
objectives of the International Trade Organization and its
Charter. Already the total, mainly governmental, has been
large. But the need ahead is probably greater in the aggregate
than that to which we already are committed. How much it
should be, how much of it should be raised from public and
private sources, toward what purposes and what countries it
should be directed, and how it should be administered are among
the largest questions we shall have to face. We need much more
knowledge as to how capital can effectively be spent abroad.
We saw after the last war that foreign investments misdirected
or badly administered are worse than none at all. We greatly
need to develop improved standards and procedures and to dif
ferentiate more carefully between the kinds of expenditures that
should be financed at home by the borrowing countries and
those that should be financed from foreign funds.




46

FREE ENTERPRISE

[VOL. XXII

So far as government aid is concerned, it seems already clear
from our grant to Greece and Turkey that we shall not be able
to stand merely upon the present commitments of the Export
Import Bank plus our participation in the Bank for Reconstruc
tion and Development. In my earlier papers, I emphasized the
need for-stabilization loans, on the model of the League loans
after the last war, loans which have a function lying somewhere
between credits from the Monetary Fund and the Bank's specific
projects for reconstruction and development, loans the purpose
of which should be the general rehabilitation of distressed coun
tries. Some such broad and even liberal definition of the task
of reconstruction seems essential, even though it involves finan
cial risks, if we are to live up to the logic of the International
Trade Organization and restore the capacity of foreign coun
tries to produce and export as rapidly as possible, and at mini
mum expense to standards of living already so depressed in many
countries.
As I have said, our ultimate objective, if we are really to make
the multilateral system work, must be the expansion of our
imports relative to exports. Unfortunately, this is more than a
question of reorienting our commercial policy, difficult though
that is. In the background lies the much debated question of a
chronic shortage of dollars, such as we had in the inter-war
period, and of how much this was due not only to errors of
policy on our part but to a cumulative productivity advantage
by this country, combined with an abnormally strong foreign
demand for our consumer durable goods and capital goods.
Such a case of deep-seated and continuing disequilibrium was not
regarded as possible in the classical theory of international trade,
and foreign investment was always counted upon to bridge any
temporary gap. In the inter-war period, however, capital
movements were often perverse and intensified trade maladjust
ments.
Possibly this time, with capital movements from other coun
tries subject to exchange control and our own to a large extent
governmentally directed, foreign investment may come nearer
to serving its true purpose, which should be to increase the
capacity of the borrowing countries to export. But to alter our
trade balance enough to overcome the dollar shortage problem
may be a long drawn-out process. I find no comfort in Lord
Keynes's suggestion in his last article that the United States is




No. 31

INTERNATIONAL TRADE

47
7

becoming a " high-cost, high-living " country, by which I take
it he meant that our need to import is increasing and our com
petitive ability to export decreasing. When I try to draw up
on paper a list of the changes in imports and exports that might
overcome our export surplus I have difficulty, and find myself
wondering whether any theory of international trade adjust
ment is capable of providing a convincing answer. In any case,
Keynes's reasoning seems not to fit the facts. Historically,
" high living " in this country has been a reflection of high pro
ductivity; and the fact that during and since the war a great
deal of capital has gone into American industry, while national
ization of British industries has been retarded, does not suggest
any lessening of our export advantage in the post-war period.
VI
It seems clear from this brief survey that the development of
a workable system of trade for the post-war world-a system
acceptable to both free and planned economies-will have to be
an evolutionary process. The International Trade Organization
and its Charter can do no more than set the process going, by
providing the machinery and the framework of reference for
continuous international supervision and revision of trade prac
tices and policies. What the result will be we cannot foresee,
but it will certainly be very different from the nineteenth
century system. It will be a compromise between the desire to
benefit from freer international trade and the desire in so many
countries to protect internal planning. The fundamental cri
terion is the necessity of two-sided adjustment. If the experi
ment is to succeed, we cannot expect to impose our kind of eco
nomic system, and the kind of international trade system that
goes with it, upon the rest of the world. But it would be no
less a mistake for other countries to assume that they can have
the advantages of multilateral trade without yielding to any of
its compulsions.
As a working guide toward this kind of compromise, the key
principle of the Charter is that of nondiscrimination. Through
the escape clauses the Charter permits trade restrictions and con
trols in a wide variety of circumstances, but it tries to hold fast
to the essential principle of the multilateral system, which is to
buy in the cheapest market and sell in the dearest. Whether this
7 Economic Journal, vol. LVI, June 1946, p. 185.




V-%

48

"

7-

r 7% -

73 "7-17

FRiEE ENTERRIS

n7

ri

"i' "TT

lVOL. AA

principle can be given force and substance in such a mixed world
is the core of the problem.
The task becomes more difficult the greater is the difference in
the nature of the economies embraced within the system. One
question on which we have no light as yet is whether a com
pletely controlled economy like that of Russia can fit acceptably
into the kind of system we are trying to devise, or would act in
good faith as a member of such a system. Thus far, Russia has
stayed out of the ITO discussions, as she has stayed out of the
Monetary Fund. This may be the better course, from our point
of view as well as hers, until we know more about the possibilities
of trade and monetary coiperation among nations less widely
separated in kind. Russian foreign trade thus far has been as
tonishingly small, and perhaps the chief question at this stage is,
not whether Russia herself should be included in ITO, but how
far she may extend her influence and her system over other
countries.
There are questions about the workability of the principle of
nondiscrimination involving other countries than Russia. One
of the chief is its applicability to state monopolies and state trad
ing. Any kind of trade or monetary restriction, even a tariff,
has some discriminatory effect. But so long as trade is between
individuals (and not dominated by cartels, against which the
Charter takes a strong stand) there is a much better possibility
of its according with competitive commercial principles than
when the trade is between individuals in some countries and state
monopolies in others. Probably only experience can decide how
feasible nondiscrimination is in such a case, but the farther the
movement toward planned economies goes in other countries,
the more this will become the test question for the success of
ITO and its Charter.
In the Charter there are many qualifications and exceptions
to the rule of nondiscrimination, involving such difficult matters
as international distribution of commodities in short supply,
quotas imposed under intergovernmental commodity agree
ments, and the difficulties of establishing global import quotas
without discriminating against countries of origin. We are
brought back to the fact that at best nondiscrimination will
work imperfectly in the present kind of world. At the same
time, attempts to force the principle unduly might well have bad
effects. To the extent that we put pressure on other nations to




No. 3]

INTERNATIONAL TRADE

49

give up their present arrangements before we are prepared to
offer better ones, we are likely to increase the financial cost
to ourselves of reconstruction. Moreover, nondiscrimination
should apply to services we supply to others (such as shipping)
as well as to goods they buy from us; and when we apply it to
goods we ought not to do so in a spirit of seeking advantage for
ourselves. The British have been saying that if they have not
the dollars to buy tobacco (or it might be food) we ought not
to prevent their getting it elsewhere if they have the money or
the goods to trade for it. Nondiscrimination ought not to mean
that if countries cannot buy from us we will not let them buy
from others.
VII
In a multilateral trade world, many of the current difficulties
would disappear. We would not, for instance, have the distor
tions of soft versus hard currencies; a country's trade could be
cleared with all others as a whole. We are seeing today, as in
the pre-war period, the vicious-circle consequences that ensue
when multilateral trade breaks down. And we are finding it
no easy matter to live in a world part planned and part free.
Thus Belgium, after correcting her internal inflation by drastic
monetary measures, removed controls and has enjoyed perhaps
the best recovery in Europe. But she is finding it hard to sub
mit to British restrictions on imports while her own markets re
main open to British goods. Sweden, which has been moving
increasingly toward a planned economy since the middle thirties
but has prided herself on her multilateral trade policy, has since
the war made a trade agreement with Russia and has.appreciated
her currency to shut out the effects of our price inflation follow
ing the breakdown of OPA. But the combination of export
trade to Russia and other countries financed by Swedish credits
and of cash-financed imports whose volume has been stimulated
by the currency appreciation has been draining her exchange re
serves. Last March she was forced to impose a direct control
of imports, which drew a rather sharp note of inquiry from this
country. There are indications that the trade position of
Canada, which also appreciated her currency to stave off our
high prices, is developing along similar lines.
Developments of this sort in the transition period, along with
the British difficulties, the uncertain future of the German econ-




50

V.

C
r

rann

' X?,C T
LLPVINZ

P

fl t1

ICE

rVnTr

LJ

LV UL-

YYTT
%..

omy, and the many other uncertainties in Europe, do not sug
gest the early reestablishment of a multilateral trade system.
But they do indicate the necessity of starting from where we
are and not trying to impose some system ready made. One
point we should emphasize for ourselves is the need for tolerance
and understanding of the difficulties of others. The main haz
ards and hardships rest upon them. As the London Economist
has been emphasizing, a policy of austerity in Britain or else
where implies for its success an attitude of leniency in other
countries, and particularly here. For the transition period, and
perhaps for some time thereafter, our attitude toward bilateral
agreements and discriminatory practices will have to take ac
count of circumstances, and the question to be asked should be
whether they are likely to encourage a growth of trade or have
the opposite effect, rather than whether they violate the pure
principles we are seeking to promote.
The International Trade Organization can hardly be inaugu
rated before the latter part of 1948, and, as in the case of the
Monetary Fund and exchange restrictions, its provisions regard
ing trade restrictions will not go into effect until the end of
the transition period. For the success of the experiment much
will depend upon what happens between now and 1951. In
creating conditions favorable to the restoration of a multilateral
trade system, the heaviest responsibility will be our own.
Granted that the outcome must be some kind of compromise,
will it be possible in such a heterogeneous world, part controlled
and part free, to move in the direction of the multilateral sys
tem, which is the logical counterpart of our free-enterprise econ
omy, or will the balance swing the other way? Perhaps it is
rash to try to answer the question, but it does seem clear that
the greatest contribution we can make toward preserving our
kind of economic system, here and elsewhere in the world, will
be through the maintenance of a stable and prosperous economy
at home coupled with a liberal and constructive trade and invest
ment policy abroad.




PROCEEDINGS OF THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
Vols. I-II.

All issues available, except No. 3 of each of these volumes.

All issues available, except No. 2 of Vol. VI.
* Inflation and High Prices: Causes and Remedies, 144 pp. (June, 1920)
* American Foreign Trade Relations, 186 pp. (February, 1921)
National Expenditures and Public Economy, 208 pp. (July, 1921)
Industrial Co6peration, 256 pp. (January, 1922)
The Railroads and Business Prosperity, 176 pp. (July, 1922)
The Money Problem, 130 pp. (January, 1923)
Law and Justice, 230 pp. (July, 1923)
American Economic Policies Since the Armistice, 231 pp. (January, 1924)
Wealth and Taxation, 148 pp. (May, 1924)
The Future of Prices at Home and Abroad, 205 pp. (January, 1925)
Popular Ownership of Property, 198 pp. (April, 1925)
Trade Ass'ns and Business Combinations, 236 pp. (January 1926)
International Relations and Problems, 500 pp. (July, 1926)
Problems of Prosperity, 145 pp. (January, 1927)
Stabilizing Business, 152 pp. (July, 1927)
America as a Creditor Nation, 173 pp. (January, 1928)
Fact-Finding in Labor Disputes, 194 pp. (June, 1928)
The Preservation of Peace, 131 pp. (January, 1929)
Railroad Consolidation, 125 pp. (Tune, 1929)
Business, Speculation and Money, 123 pp. (January, 1930)
Public Control of Power, 210 pp. (May, 1930)
The Young Plan in Operation, 118 pp. (January, 1931)
Depression and Revival, 129 pp. (June, 1931)
Can Prices, Production and Employment Be Effectively Regulated? 146 pp
(January, 1932)
No. 1. The Crisis in World Finance and Trade, 140 pp. (May, 1932)
Vol. XV.
No. 2. Steps Toward Recovery, 135 pp. (January, 1933)
No. 3. Tariffs and Trade Barriers, 91 pp. (June, 1933)
No. 4. Current Problems of Unemployment and Recovery Measures in Operation,
108 pp. (January, 1934)
Vol. XVI. No. 1. Money and Credit in the Recovery Program, 124 pp. (April, 1934)
No. 2. The Stabilization of Peace, 147 pp. (January, 1935)
No. 3. Problems of Social Security Legislation in the U. S., 132 pp. (June, 1935)
No. 4. The Constitution and Social Progress, 139 pp. (January, 1936)
Vol. XVII. No. 1. Economic Recovery and Monetary Stabilization, 135 pp. (May, 1936)
No. 2. Transportation Development in the United States, 136 pp. (January, 1937)
No. 3. The Foreign Policy of the United States, 134 pp. (May, 1937)
No.4. Expenditures of the Federal Government, 137 pp. (January, 1938)
Vol. XVIII. No. 1. Essentials for Sustained Recovery, 122 pp. (May, 1938)
No. 2. Monopoly and Competition in Industry and Labor, 143 pp. (January, 1939)
No. 3. The Preservation of Democracy-America's Preparedness, 111 pp. (May, 1939)
No. 4. The Effect of the War on America's Idle Men and Idle Money, 133 pp.
(January, 1940)
Vol. XIX. No. 1. Economic Nationalism, Trade Barriers and the War, 110 pp. (May, 1940)
No. 2. The Defense of the United States, 146 pp. (January, 1941)
No. 3. America Faces the Future, 119 pp. (May, 1941)
No. 4. American Industry in a War of Machines, 111 pp. (January, 1942)
Vol XX.
No. 1. Winning the War, 100 pp. (May, 1942)
No. 2. Transportation in Wartime and the United Nations, 111 pp. (January, 1943)
No. 3. Mobilization of Manpower and Pressing the Fight for Freedom, 96 pp.
(May, 1943)
No. 4. The Problems of Total War and Roads to Victory, 143 pp. (January, 1944)
Vol. XXI. No. 1. Problems of War and the Transition to Peace, 128 pp. (May, 1944)
No. 2. Shaping the Economic Future, 139 pp. (January, 1945)
No. 3. World Organization-Economic, Political and Social, 191 pp. (May, 1945)
No. 4. European Recovery, 112 pp. (January, 1946)
Vol. XXII. No. 1. Labor Policy and Labor Relations, 107 pp. (May, 1946)
No. 2. Developing a Working International Order-Political, Economic and Social,
143 pp. (January, 1947)
No. 3. Free Enterprise-National and International, 108 pp. (May, 1947)
SOut of print. The Proceedings are sent, together with the Political Science Quarterly as
part of the membership privileges, to all members and subscribing members (libraries, institutions,
etc.) of the Academy. The annual membership dues are $5.00.

Vols. HI-VIII.
No. 1.
Vol. IX.
No. 2.
No. 3.
No. 4.
No. 1.
Val.X.
No. 2.
No. 3.
No. 4.
Vol. XI.
No. 1.
No. 2.
No. 3.
No. 4.
No. 1.
Vol. XII.
No. 2.
No. 3.
No. 4.
Vol. XIII. No. 1.
No. 2.
No. 3.
No. 4.
Vol. XIV. No. 1.
No. 2.
No. 3.
No. 4.

The publications of the Academy are sold to non-members as follows: single issues of the
Proceedings, $2.50; single issues of the Quarterly, $1.00.




THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
BOARD OF DIRECTORS
President
Lawis W. DOUGLAS

Vice-President
TnoxAs J. WATSON
Becretary
GRAYSON L. KInR
W. RANDOLPH BURGESS
RosnBT M. HAre
THOMas W. LAMoNT
WALTEn T. LATTON

LzE WOLMA

Treasurer
SAM A. LEWISOHN
SAMUE McCUNn LINDSAT
JOH J. McCLor
RoswnrL MAGILL
WsSLY C. MITCHEL

Director
ETHEL WARNER
SHEPABD MORGAN
THOMAS I. PABxINSOU
WIxAM L. RANSOM
Owm D. YOUNG

Managing Editor of the PoliticalScience Quarterly and Proceedings
JoHN A. KowT

WINSTON CHURCHI
CHABLs E. HUGHE
S

HONORARY MEMBERS
JOHN BASSETT Moon
MONTAG C. Nosasm
CHAwLE RIsr

ALIeRT SHAW
EMnao rL Tomo

The Academy of Political Science, founded in 1880, is composed of men and
women interested in political, economic and social questions. The annual dues
are $5. Members and subscribing members (libraries, institutions etc.) receive
as part of their membership privileges the current issues of the Political
Science Quarterly, the semi-annual Proceedings of the Academy and invita
tions to Academy meetings.
The Political Science Quarterly is published in March, June, September
and December by the Academy of Political Science and is edited by the
Faculty of Political Science of Columbia University. The Proceedings are
published in mid-winter and mid-summer. Single issues of the Quarterly, $1;
single issues of the Proceedings, 2.50. Prices on back numbers and bound
volumes will be quoted on request.
Members and subscribing members are urged to notify the Academy
office of any change of address.

If members and subscribing members wish to discontinue membership in
the Academy, notice to that effect should be sent; otherwise it is assumed that
the membership will be continued.
Communications regarding the Academy should be addressed to the Director
of the Academy of Political Science, Fayerweather Hall, Columbia University.
New York 27, N. Y.




This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: International Trade Theory and Policy - Some Current Issues

Journal Title: American Economic Review

Volume Number: XLI
Date:

May 1951

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: 2

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: The Implications of Fiscal Policy for Monetary Policy and the Banking
System
Journal Title: American Economic Review

Volume Number: XXXII
Date:

March 1942

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: 1

This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: Federal Budget: Economic Consequences of Deficit Financing: Deficit
Spending
Journal Title: American Economic Review

Volume Number: XXX
Date:

February 1941

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: 5

ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL ASPECTS
OF THE DEFENSE PROGRAM

BY

JOHN H. WILLIAMS
DEAN OF THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION,
HARVARD UNIVERSITY

AN ADDRESS
BEFORE THE

ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
AT ITS
SEMI-ANNUAL MEETING ON
" AMERICA FACES THE FUTURE"
APRIL i6,

1941

NEW YORK
PUBLISHED BY THE
ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE




1941

ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF THE
DEFENSE PROGRAM
JOHN H. WILLIAMS

Dean of the Graduate School of Public Administration
Harvard University

THE

problems of defense are like those of war itself.
When I took part in the Academy's program on
"America's Preparedness" in the spring of 1939, I
pointed out that one important difference between war and
preparation for war is that a war, even a long war, is relatively
short whereas preparation for war may be indefinitely con
tinued; its yearly cost would be much less than that of war but
would have to be borne for a longer period. I did not then
foresee that the defense program upon which we embarked last
year would be dictated by circumstances requiring us to make
our maximum possible effort in the shortest possible time. By
their scope and by the urgent necessity for speed our present
defense expenditures and our aid to Britain raise problems
which are practically identical with those of actual war.
These problems are fundamentally economic rather than
financial or monetary. Finance is but a means to an end. The
end is to make available to government the goods and the man
power that it needs for war or defense. The economic changes
involved are twofold. We need to divert resources from peace
to war-time purposes. But we also need to develop our re
sources to maximum capacity.
The necessity for sacrificing peace-time for war activities is
the most familiar aspect of war economics, and the most funda
mental. It is a two-sided process, on the one side a diversion
of productive facilities to war needs and on the other a diver
sion of the nation's money income. The problem is to keep
the two kinds of change reasonably in balance. If we do not
divert the nation's income from ordinary consumption and in
vestment to defense expenditures the government will have to




46

A~MERICA FCACES THE FUTURE

[VOL. XIX

create additional money to pay for defense, and if meanwhile
a part of the nation's productive resources has been transferred
from peace to war production, output as a whole will be rising
less rapidly than money incomes, and expenditures will be
raising prices rather than output. This, very simply, is the
problem of inflation. The sacrifice, of course, is not escaped
by failing to take the steps necessary to curtail peace-time con
sumption and investment. It merely takes a different form;
with prices rising our money incomes buy less. Experience has
taught repeatedly that when this inflationary process has taken
hold of an economy to a marked degree it is much the most
undesirable form which the sacrifice could take, and may end
by stalling the entire economic machine. But war problems
are never simple, and it is not nearly so clear that some rise of
prices is not desirable if it serves to stimulate production where
needed, and if we have at hand the power to control it.
The most difficult aspect of the problem is the time aspect.
As already stated, the question is not merely one of diverting
the community's money income and productive resources from
peace to war; it is also one of developing resources and ex
panding output to the fullest extent. Unless the country is
already running at maximum capacity when the defense pro
gram starts, this objective logically precedes the other; and
we have to be careful in attending to the diversion problem not
to prevent or retard our reaching our potential maximum per
formance. As Price Commissioner Henderson has said, the
first defense against a rise of prices is increased production.
We must be as careful of avoiding undue or premature restric
tive measures as we are alert to the necessity of warding off
inflation. Economists differ not so much about the financial
and monetary principles that apply to this kind of situation as
they do about where we are in the expansion process and how
much further non-defense expansion is permissible. The prob
lem is made still more difficult if, as in the case of income tax
changes, we have to try to foresee where we will be six to nine
months later when the changes called for will go into effect.
The lesson of 1917 was that we should have diverted income
and productive resources much more promptly than we did
from peace- to war-time needs. But to have applied this lesson
by superficial analogy to our situation in the middle of 1940,




No. 3]

FINANCING DEFENSE PROGRAM

47

when the present defense program began, would have been the
greatest mistake that we could have made. In 1917 we were
already in the midst of a war boom. Our economy was much
smaller in relation to the world economy than it is today, and
purchases by belligerents were larger in relation to our capac
ity than they have been thus far in the present war. When
our present program began we still had large surpluses of
many basic products, of man power and equipment. Since that
time production has markedly increased. The Federal Reserve
index has in recent months been about 140 as compared with
an average of 122 in 1940 and Io1

in 1929.

Not only have

we now a volume of production and of national income never
previously reached, but it seems certain that as the defense
expenditures and the aid to Britain expand further, production
and income will substantially increase.
But even today our problem is not primarily one of general
pressure upon resources. We still have large unemployment,
though the estimates differ rather widely both as to its present
amount and as to how fast it will be absorbed by the defense
program. We continue to have large surpluses of many basic
products, and in the field of agricultural policy efforts continue
to be directed toward restricting output and raising prices. In
the noncontinuous process industries there is still much room
for increasing output by increasing the number of shifts, and
there is still much room generally for lengthening hours of
work. On the farm, as the last war showed, there is a poten
tial industrial labor force of two to three millions. In industry
today, apart from some threatened bottlenecks, there is much
more danger of curtailed production and rising prices and costs
from labor conflicts than from any general pressure on re
sources. In recent months there has occurred a fairly substan
tial rise in the prices of basic commodities, not only in imports
where it is most marked, but in some domestic prices. But
there is still no sign of a general spiral price rise that might
be called inflationary. For a price rise of the kind and extent
which has thus far occurred, it seems probable that increased
production coupled with specific price controls is still the best
method of control.
One factor which has an important bearing on this question
of the limits of permissible expansion is the great advance of




48

AMERICA FACES THE FUTURE

[VoL. XIX

technology since the last war. That such an advance has
occurred is recognized by economists of every shade of opinion.
During the thirties it was frequently coupled with tendencies
toward oversaving and underinvestment as an explanation of
underemployment and depression. Whatever may have been
true of the past ten years we cannot plead today a lack of out
lets for our technical skill. It is for this reason that I have
been from the outset of the defense program, and still am,
interested in the question how far we can safely and wisely
permit the defense program to supplement rather than supplant
our peace-time requirements. I recognize that that is a more
difficult objective, but also I think a more intelligent one, than
a premature " all-out" emphasis on sacrifice. The longer the
period over which our effort is to be made, the more vital it is
that we should develop fully, and be prepared to sustain, as
much as possible, our economic strength and staying power.
This, to repeat, is the difficult problem of the time schedule.
It by no means suggests any subordination of the need for
sacrifice, but emphasizes the need for so timing it that it will
be at its maximum when pressure on resources is greatest. It
requires that we guard against diverting income and resources
from peace-time use before we are actually ready to use them
foi defense. It requires us to bear in mind, for example, that
in the fiscal year 1942, despite all possible efforts for speed,
our military expenditures will probably not exceed one fifth of
our national income, whereas those of England in the same
period will absorb one half to three fifths of her income. But
to determine just where we are on the time schedule there are
no easily recognizable criteria, except the inflationary price rise
which as yet, I believe, is not in evidence. It is on this point,
as I have said, that economists differ at present much more
than on the principles of control which are applicable.
One especially important aspect of the advance of technology
in the past two decades is its bearing on employment. The
constantly reiterated goal of monetary and fiscal theorists dur
ing the past ten years has been to achieve " full employment ".
But we have to recognize that this objective is more difficult
than had been thought. It took England a year and a half
of actual war to get full employment. I am not suggesting
that in this great effort which we are making we may not




No. 31

FINANCING DEFENSE PROGRAM

49

achieve full employment, but it will be a late rather than an
early development and not a useful guide to policy. Most of
the dangers which we fear will have occurred, if we do nothing
about them, before full employment is reached. The older
economists thought of inflation as occurring when we had
reached the limits of economic capacity, including full employ
ment, but under modern conditions there is no clean-cut line
between what we call bottlenecks and a general inflation.
" Economic capacity " is itself a relative term. If inflation
should arise in the present phase of the defense program, it
would be of the "bottleneck" variety, arising out of special
shortages of materials or of particular kinds of labor, equip
ment or plant, or out of particular labor or price policies. The
higher the level of production reached, the greater will be the
possibility that such disturbances arising out of special situa
tions will spread throughout the economy and produce results
essentially similar to those of a general inflation. In propor
tion as these special problems are solved, the inflation danger
will be pushed farther off in time and become more and more
a problem of pressure upon our general economic capacity and
resources. Some economists have endeavored to estimate when
and at what level of output this condition will be reached.
Such estimates are largely in the nature of abstract speculation,
but it does seem probable that by the time we reach a national
income of ninety to a hundred billion dollars (which probably
will be next year), and sooner if the bottlenecks are not well
handled, we shall need to be pursuing a positive policy aimed
at preventing a general inflation.
As we survey the whole defense problem, the economic poli
cies called for fall into two main categories which may be
labeled general and special. The special problems are those
of the Office of Production Management and of the recently
created Office of Price Administration. These are the questions
of most immediate importance. They will be discussed here by
others this afternoon - questions of price control, priorities,
labor policies. I will only say that with respect to some of
these problems there may be some need for a new orientation
on the part of government. We have for ten years been fight
ing depression, and many of our policies have been directed
toward lifting prices or wages. Our agricultural policies, in




50

AMERICA FACES THE FUTURE

[VOL. XIX

particular, may need reexamination from this point of view,
and also our policies toward housing, of which I will speak
later.
But as production expands, special control measures will
need to be supported increasingly by more general measures
designed to control and direct the community income. These
general measures are financial and monetary. The methods of
financing war and defense are taxes, loans and monetary ex
pansion, and the problem in general is how best to employ the
first two methods to avoid the third. The appropriate fiscal
policy is one combining borrowing and taxation in such pro
portions that borrowing will decline and tax revenue increase
as the national income rises.
Both borrowing and taxation are designed to reach savings
and to restrain consumption, but the borrowing, if wisely
planned, can reach savings more promptly and surely than
taxation, and since it is voluntary is less likely to be restrictive.
The Treasury has recently announced its savings bond pro
gram, which it is to be hoped will yield substantial revenue.
Such a program should not, however, be pushed to the point
of forcing the community to borrow from the banks to buy
government securities, as happened in the last war. At the
same time, so long as there is a prospect that government bor
rowing may have to be on a large scale, it would be unwise
to place obstacles in the way of bank buying of government
securities, even though such buying means a further increase
in our already redundant volume of deposits.
In planning our tax program it is important to recognize
how productive our present tax system, including the revenue
measures passed in 1940, will be at higher levels of national
income. Further increases in taxes should be planned not
primarily with a view to raising revenue, and certainly not on
the basis of any preconceived formula about the proper propor
tions between taxing and borrowing, but primarily with a view
to their effect upon the expansionary process and the dangers
of inflation. As already stated, the problem is complicated by
the fact that the restriction of community expenditures can be
overdone as well as underdone, and in the case of income taxa
tion is complicated further by the time lag before the new
rates go into effect. One of the difficulties in planning a com-




No. 3]

FINANCING DEFENSE PROGRAM

51

bined program of taxing and borrowing is that the tax pro
gram if overdone may compete seriously with the savings
bonds. Apart from the time lag, income taxation is preferable
to general commodity taxation even when the purpose is to
restrict consumption. General commodity taxation is not only
highly regressive, bearing most heavily on the smallest in
comes, but it is more likely also to act as a deterrent to produc
tion. We must be careful, however, not to fall between two
stools. The great mass of consumption is out of the small in
comes, and if our purpose really is, at the appropriate stage,
seriously to curtail consumption we must either tax commodi
ties generally or substantially lower the income tax base.
Logically precedent to taxation of general consumption is the
taxation, by means of excise taxes, of special consumption,
such as durable consumer goods which compete directly with
the needs of defense industries.
There remain the monetary aspects of the program and the
role of monetary control. Prior to the last war the order of
emphasis on control measures would probably have been on
monetary measures first, fiscal measures second, and direct
measures last. But as a result of this war and the last, which
have provided unfortunately an unprecedentedly good labora
tory for the study of war control measures, the order appears
to have been reversed. In a defense program, as in war, there
are special reasons for not relying upon a general monetary
control such as might seem appropriate in dealing with peace
time expansion of economic activity. A general monetary con
trol, through bank reserves and the quantity of money, is aimed
at interest rates and is designed to affect the cost and avail
ability of funds for investment, which in turn affects the volume
of national income, output and employment. But in war or in
defense there is the special circumstance that the government
is and must be the principal borrower, and that the success of
the defense effort rests essentially upon the success of the
financing program. The possible dangers which might arise
from an excessive money supply or from low interest rates
must be weighed against the necessity of ensuring the success
of the government's financial program upon which the military
expenditures depend. Faced with this dilemma, nations are
compelled to consider alternative methods of preventing ordi-




52

AMERICA FACES THE FUTURE

[VoL. XIX

nary consumption and investment from weakening the military
effort and bringing on the general inflation which would logi
cally follow if neither monetary nor other restrictive measures
were adopted. It is no accident that other countries, democ
racies like England and Canada as well as Germany, have in
this war subordinated general monetary controls to other types
of control and are pursuing a program of combining low in
terest rates and ample bank reserves with fiscal measures and
more specific controls designed to prevent inflation. This in
general is the type of program upon which this country has
embarked, though it is as yet in an earlier stage of develop
ment. The reason in such circumstances why nations have
learned to prefer other anti-inflationary measures than the
monetary is not merely that such a program facilitates Treas
ury financing, important as that is, but also that it is much the
more effective method of safeguarding against inflation. His
torically, there is no proof that if war-time inflation is not
prevented by more direct control measures combined with wise
fiscal policy, it will or can be prevented by a general monetary
control.
In our own case, too, there is the circumstance that a decade
of deficit spending has introduced new elements of instability
into our monetary and banking system. Rising interest rates
mean a fall in price of old securities, and, with government
securities the chief asset of the banks, such price declines might
have serious effects. Any attempt by the banks to avoid
losses by selling securities would mean that non-bank investors
would have to absorb both the old issues and the new, or else
would require large-scale buying, directly or indirectly, of
Treasury securities by the central bank. Disturbances of this
sort in the government security markets have historically been
one of the most familiar causes of inflation. One large ques
tion which may fairly be raised as a result of the past decade
of deficit spending combined with large excess reserves is
whether we have not introduced a new element of rigidity into
our economic system in the form of low interest rates, and
whether fiscal policy which at the outset was intended to sup
plement monetary policy has not ended by supplanting it.
But there are special forms of control which go more directly
to the heart of the problem of war or defense, and far from




No. 3]

FINANCING DEFENSE PROGRAM

53

interfering with Treasury financing may positively assist it.
One such measure would be the rationing of the private capital
market. Such a policy, as practiced in Germany or England,
is intended to prevent private investment from competing with
military requirements, but as yet no such problem appears to
have developed in this country. Another and more pressing
problem is the competition of durable consumer goods with the
needs of the defense industries. In this area there appear to
be important opportunities for co5peration between the mone
tary authority and other agencies of government. The machin
ery of price controls, priorities and rationing may well prove
ineffective unless accompanied by monetary measures designed
to control expenditures on durable goods. The two areas in
which this problem seems now most pressing are the field of
instalment credit for automobiles and other durable consumer
goods and the field of residential housing.
With respect to automobiles, the decision has already been
made to curtail production in the next model year. How far
this action needs to be supplemented by instalment credit con
trol applied to automobiles and other durable goods is a ques
tion deserving careful study. Even more important, I believe,
is the housing question. If it were not that we have still in
our minds as the yardstick for comparisons the top years of the
twenties, when we were having a housing boom perhaps with
out parallel in our history, everyone would probably recognize
that residential building has attained major dimensions; and
the fact that the defense program itself requires great building
activity is all the more reason why we should examine anew
the policies of stimulating private construction which were
designed to overcome depression and have been continued into
a quite different kind of situation.




PROCEEDINGS OF THE ACADEMY

OF POLITICAL SCIENCE

I No 3. of each of these two volumes is out of print. Other numbers available
II. } All isues available.
IV.
I
V. No. I. Revision of the State Constitution. Part I, 262 pp. (October, 1914)
No. 2. Revision of the State Constitution. Part II,215 pp. (January, 1915)
No. 3. Government of the City of New York, 263 pp. (April, 195)
No.4. Annual Report of the President of the Academy (July, g195)
Vol. VI. No. 1. American Mercantile Marine, 208 pp. (October, 1915)
No. 2. *Prevention of Cruelty to Animals in the States of Illinois, Colorado
and California, 112 pp. (January, 1916)
No. 3. Constitutional Imperialism in Japan, 104 pp. (April, 1916)
No.4. Military Training: Compulsory or Volunteer, 262 pp. (July, 1916)
Vol VII. No. 1. Labor Disputes and Public Service Corporations (January, 1917)
No. 2. The Foreign Relations of the United States, Part I (July, 1917)
No. 3. The Foreign Relations of the United States, Part II (July, I917)
No. 4. Economic Conditions of Winning the War, 172 pp. (February, 1918)
Vol.VIII. No. I. National Conference on War Economy, 134 pp. (July, 1918)
No. 2. War Labor Policies and Reconstruction, 221 pp. (February, 1919)
No. 3. The League of Nations Covenant, 16o pp. (July, 1919)
No. 4. Railroad Legislation, 268 pp. (January, x92o)
Vol. IX. No. I.*Inflation and High Prices: Causes and Remedies, 144 pp. (June, x92o)
No. 2. *American Foreign Trade Relations, 186 pp. (February, 1921)
No. 3. National Expenditures and Public Economy, 208 pp. (July, 1921)
No. 4. Industrial Co6peration, 256 pp. (January, 192x)
Vol. X. No. I. The Railroads and Business Prosperity, 176 pp. (July, 1922)
No 2. The Money Problem, 13o pp. (January, 1923)
No. 3. Law and Justice, 230 pp. (July, 1923)
No. 4. AmericanEconomicPoliciesSince theArmistice, 231 pp. (January, i194)
Vol. XL No. I. Wealth and Taxation, 148 pp. (May, 1924)
No. 2. The Future of Prices at Home and Abroad, 205 pp. (January, 1925)
No. 3. Popular Ownership of Property, 198 pp. (April, 1925)
No. 4. Trade Ass'ns and Business Combinations, 236 pp. (January, 1926)
" ol.XII.No. i. International Relations and Problems, 5oo pp. (July, 1926)
No. 2. Problems of Prosperity, 145 pp. (January, 1927)
No. 3. Stabilizing Business, 152 pp. (July, 1927)
No. 4. America as a Creditor Nation, 173 pp. (January, 1928)
Vol. XIII. No. 1.Fact-Finding in Labor Disputes, 194 pp. (June, 1928)
No, 2. The Preservation of Peace, I31 pp. (January, 1929)
No. 3. Railroad Consolidation, 125 pp. (June, 1929)
No. 4. Business, Speculation and Money, 123 pp. (January, 1930)
Vol. XIV. No. I. Public Control of Power, 210 pp. (May, 1930)
No. 2. The Young Plan in Operation, I8 pp. (January, 1931)
No. 3. Depression and Revival, 129 pp. (June, 1931)
No. 4. Can Prices, Production and Employment Be Eflectively Regulated?
146 pp. (January, 1932)
VoL XV. No. I. The Crisis in World Finance and Trade, 140 pp. (May, 1932)
No. 2. Steps Toward Recovery, 135 pp. (January, 1933)
No. 3. Tariffs and Trade Barriers, 91 pp. (June, 1933)
No. 4. Current Problems of Unemployment and Recovery Measures in Opera.
tion, io8pp. (January, 1934)
Vol XVI. No. x. Money and Credit in the Recovery Program, 124 pp. (April, 1934)
No. . The Stabilization of Peace, 147 PP. (January, 1935)
No. 3. Problems of Social Security Legislation in the United States, 132
(June, 1935)
No. 4. The Constitution and Social Progress, 139 pp. (January, 1936)
VoL XVII.No. I. Economic Recovery and Monetary Stabilization, 135 pp. (May,
i936)
No. 2. Transportation Development in the United States, 136 pp.(January, 1937)
No. 3. The Foreign Policy of the United States, 134 pp. (May, 1937)
No.4. Expenditures of the Federal Government, 137 pp. (January, 1938)
VoLXVIII. No. . Essentials for Sustained Recovery, 122 pp. (May, 1938)
No. 2. Monopoly and Competition in Industry and Labor, 143 pp.(January,I939)
Preparedness, Il pp.
No. 3. The Preservation of Democracy -America's
(May, 1939)
No.4. The Effect of the War on America's Idle Men and Idle Money, 133 pp.
(January, 1940)
Vol. XIX.No. I. Economic Nationalism, Trade Barriers and the War, I ropp. (May, z94o )
No. 2. The Defense of the United States, 146 pp. (January, 1941)
No. 3. America Faces the Future, 119 pp. (May, 1941)

Vol.
Vol.
Vol.
Vol,

*Out of print. The Proceedings are sent, together with the Political Science Quarterly as part of

the membership privileges, to all members and subscribing members (libraries, institutions etc.) of the

Academy. The annual membership dues are $5.oo.

The publications of the Academy are sold to non.members as follows: single issues of the Proceed
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
ing prior to Vol. XI, No. 3, $r.5o; subsequent issues $2.50; single issues of the Quarterly, $1.oo.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
BOARD OF TRUSTEES
President
WizszY C. MrTCBeu
Vice-Presidents
RosWEl C. McCI
Lws W. DouwVAS
Director
Treasurer
Secretary
ETEmL WAtrN
SAM A. LzWISOHN
T. DowUaN
WzIuax L RANSOM
Sm WALTE T. LArzox
W. RANDwuL Bu zSS
SAMUEL MCCUNB LINDSAY THOMAS J.WATsoN
Laow FFAS
LoWouLMA
RoBET M. HAmo
SHEPAD MOoGAN
THonA W. LAmoxT
THOMAs I. PAKxnson
OWEN D. YouNG
Managing Editor of the Political Science Quarterly and the Proceedings
JOHN A. Kfotr
No.

HONORARY MEMBERS
CHAsI.E E HUGH s
JoHN BASSETT MOOE

MONTAGU C. NOUMAr
CHAxmxs RIST

EMnuo sm. ToaO
ALBST SHAW

L S. ROWE
The Academy of Political Science, founded in 188o, is composed of men and
women interested in political, economic and social questions. The annual dues
are $5. Members and subscribing members (libraries, institutions etc.) receive
as part of their membership privileges the current issues of the Political
Science Quarterly, the semi-annual Proceedings of the Academy and invita
tions to Academy meetings.
The Political Science Quarterly is published in March, June, September
and December by the Academy of Political Science and is edited by the Faculty
of Political Science of Columbia University. The Proceedings are published
in mid-winter and mid-summer. Single issues of the Quarterly, $x; single
issues of the Proceedings, $2.5o. Prices on back numbers and bound volumes
will be quoted on request
Members and subscribing members are urged to notify the Academy
office of any change of address.
If members and subscribing members wish to discontinue membership in
the Academy, notice to that effect should be sent; otherwise it is assumed that
the membership will be continued.
Communications regarding the Academy should be addressed to the Director
of the Academy of Political Science Fayerweather Hall, Columbia University.
New York.




This document is protected by copyright and has been removed.

Author(s): John H. Williams

Article Title: The British Crisis: A Problem in Economic Statesmanship

Journal Title: Foreign Affairs, An American Quarterly Review

Volume Number:
Date:

October 1949

Page Numbers:




Issue Number: