View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO
WORKING PAPER SERIES

Moderate Inflation and the Deflation-Depression Link
Jess Benhabib
New York University
Mark M. Spiegel
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

October 2006

Working Paper 2006-32
http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2006/wp06-32bk.pdf

The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be
interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. This paper was produced under the
auspices for the Center for Pacific Basin Studies within the Economic Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Moderate Inflation and the Deflation-Depression Link
Jess Benhabib
New York University
And
Mark M. Spiegel*
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
October 11, 2006

ABSTRACT
In a recent paper, Atkeson and Kehoe (2004) demonstrated the lack of a robust
empirical relationship between inflation and growth for a cross-section of countries with
19th and 20th century data, concluding that the historical evidence only provides weak
support for the contention that deflation episodes are harmful to economic growth. In this
paper, we revisit this relationship by allowing for inflation and growth to have a nonlinear specification dependent on inflation levels. In particular, we allow for the
possibility that high inflation is negatively correlated with growth, while a positive
relationship exists over the range of negative-to-moderate inflation. Our results confirm a
positive relationship between inflation and growth at moderate inflation levels, and
support the contention that the relationship between inflation and growth is non-linear
over the entire sample range.

Keywords: Inflation, growth, empirics
JEL Classification: E5, E52, E58, E6, E65, E42, E3, E31
*Corresponding author. We thank Andy Atkeson, David Backus and Warren Weber for
providing us with the data. The views expressed in this paper are our own and do not
necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors or the Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

1. Introduction
This paper is a note on Atkeson and Kehoe (2004), “Deflation and Depression: Is
There an Empirical Link?” Policymakers since the Great Depression have indeed been
much concerned that deflation can lead to lower growth rates, if not recessions, and the
recent Japanese experience has exacerbated such concerns [see Krugman,(1997)].
Theoretical models offer differing perspectives. Milton Friedman’s argument that for
economic efficiency the nominal interest rate should be zero and that the price level
should fall steadily at the real rate of interest is well known, and has been formally
reconfirmed by Chari, Christiano, and Kehoe (1996) and by Cole and Kocherlakota
(1998) [See also Benhabib and Bull (1983)]. Others, working with calibrated models
embedding sticky prices and market distortions, find the Friedman rule non-optimal
[Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2004)]. More to the point, Auerbach and Obstfeld (2005)
find that the welfare and output costs associated with liquidity traps and deflations can be
very significant.
Our purpose is not to resolve the differences or to propose another theoretical
model, but to further pursue the empirical approach of Atkeson and Kehoe by introducing
an additional perspective. Folklore has it that too much inflation (hyperinflation) is bad
for the economybecause it increases “shoe-leather” costs, and that deflation is also bad
because prices are sticky, or because of other less-well understood reasons that have
something to do with expectations. If so, we should not expect a linear relation between
growth and inflation, but an inverted U-shaped one. In this note we want to extend
Atkeson and Kehoe by considering such a non-linear relationship. 1

1

See also Bruno and Easterly (1998) and Ghosh and Phillips (1998).

1

Following the methodology of Atkeson and Kehoe, we are only attempting to
characterize the empirical relationship between inflation and economic growth, and do
not claim that there are any causal conclusions one can draw from our results. Our
analysis speaks to Atkeson and Kehoe’s conclusion based on a linear specification that
that data show no obvious relationship, which raises the bar those who claim that
deflation and depression are closely linked.
Using a long cross-country panel data set of five-year growth episodes, we first
confirm Atkeson and Kehoe’s findings of a relatively weak correlation between inflation
and growth under a simple linear specification. However, we then demonstrate that when
one allows for a non-linear relationship so as to capture an inverted-U shape, both the
economic and statistical strength of the relationship increase dramatically in samples
limited to moderate-to-negative inflation.
We then divide the sample according to inflation levels, examining the
relationship in a simple linear specification for samples with average five-year inflation
levels below and above 5%, 10%, and 15%. Our results again show that for sub-samples
limited to negative and moderate inflation levels, the relationship between inflation and
growth is quite strong, with the coefficient estimate for the sub-sample of inflation levels
below 5% being almost four times that of the full sample Atkeson and Kehoe
specification. F-tests confirm the instability of the inflation coefficient across these
thresholds under a linear specification.
Finally, we examine the robustness of our results to conditioning for the volatility
of inflation. It has been argued [e.g. Barro (1976), Judson and Orphanides (1999)] that it
is inflation volatility, rather than inflation itself, that is the primary cause of poor

2

economic performance during high inflation episodes. Nevertheless, our basic results are
robust to conditioning for inflation volatility, in that we continue to observe that growth
is positively related to inflation at moderate inflation levels and that the relationship
between inflation and output exhibits instability when one crosses from moderate to high
inflation levels.

2. Data
Our data set is very similar to that in Atkeson and Kehoe [AK (2004)].2 Data on
the general price level and output data up to 1980 are obtained from Rolnick and Weber
(1997) and Backus and Kehoe (1992) for Argentina (from 1885), Australia (from 1862),
Brazil (1861), Canada (1870), Chile (1908), Denmark (1871), France (1820), Germany
(1830), Italy (1867), Japan (1885), Netherlands (1900), Norway (1865), Portugal (1833),
Spain (1849), Sweden (1861), United Kingdom (1870), and the United States (1820).
This data runs from early periods to 1992 through 1995 depending on the country.
Remaining years are filled in using data from the IMF’s International Financial
Statistics.
As in AK, we group the data into five-year episodes that start and end in years 9
or 4, so that the entire depression is contained in a single five year sub-sample. We also
follow AK by restricting our attention to moderate inflation or deflation, by restricting
our sample to five year periods that average less than 20% inflation or deflation.
However, as a control, we also examine a sample that includes all five year periods that

2

We have five extra years of data for Italy, 1862-1867, and one extra year for Argentina, Australia and
Denmark, 1884, 1861, and 1870 respectively.

3

average less than 40% inflation or deflation, the sample selection chosen by Bruno and
Easterly (1998).
Summary statistics are shown in Table 1 for samples excluding five year periods
with average inflation or deflation exceeding 40 and 20 percent respectively. Over the
full sample, our data exhibits a positive correlation between average growth and average
inflation equal to 0.14 for both the less than 40% and less than 20% samples. However,
the pre-and post World War II sub-samples demonstrate that the results are likely to be
sensitive to the sample truncation rule chosen. For the pre-World War II sample, the less
than 40% truncation reveals a relatively small correlation between inflation and growth
equal to 0.03 while the less than 20% sample exhibits a larger 0.17 correlation
coefficient. In contrast, the post-World War II sample shows a 0.15 correlation between
inflation and growth for the 40% sample, while the less than 20% sample demonstrates a
smaller correlation equal to 0.08.
As discussed above, we examine the robustness of our results to conditioning for
the volatility of inflation, σ π2 , which we measure as

σ π2t ≡

(

1 n
∑ π it − π t
n i =1

)

2

(1)

where n = 5 is the length of individual years in each observation period and π t is the
mean level of inflation in period t . Table 1 demonstrates that there is a strong correlation
between the level of inflation and the volatility of inflation, as would be expected. We
also tend to find a negative correlation between economic growth and inflation volatility,
with the exception of the post-World War II sub-sample.

4

3. Non-linear Specification
We first estimate the relationship between inflation and growth under the
following simple specification

Δyit = α + β1π it + β 2 (π it ) + ε it
2

(2)

where Δyit represents average annual growth for country i during five-year period t, π it
represents average annual inflation for country i during five-year period t, and ε it
represents an i.i.d. normal disturbance term. We impose the restriction that the coefficient
on the nonlinear term is zero for our linear benchmark and then run the specification
again with the coefficient unrestricted. We estimate using ordinary least squares with
White’s correction for heteroskedasticity.
Our results are shown in Table 2 for the less than 20% and less than 40% samples
respectively. We run the specification for the full sample and for three historic subsamples. Our first sub-sample excludes the depression five year period, 1929-1934, and
the WWII period, 1939-1949.3 Our other two samples include dates before and after this
WWII period.
Looking first at the linear specifications for the sample with inflation rates below
20%, it can be seen that inflation enters with a positive point estimate for all of these
specifications for both samples, and significantly at a five percent confidence level for the
full sample and the sample excluding the Great Depression and WWII, and at a tenpercent confidence level for the Before WWII sub-sample. However, inflation is

3

This specification of the Second World War period follows Atkeson and Kehoe (2004).

5

insignificant for the After WWII sample. Since this sample largely matches that in AK, it
is unsurprising that we obtain a similar point estimate of 0.083 for the full sample. When
we include inflation episodes up to an average of 40%, the correlation under a linear
specification is uniformly weaker, and only statistically significant for the full sample.
Overall, our linear results confirm the AK finding of a modest, if any, correlation
between inflation and growth.
We next allow the nonlinear term to be non-zero. As expected, the nonlinear term
enters negatively in all specifications, although not always at statistically significant
levels. It is significant at a 5% confidence level for our full sample. However, the more
interesting result is that allowing for the non-linear term markedly increases the
economic and statistical significance of the coefficient on the level of inflation. In the
case of the full sample below 20% inflation, the coefficient on the inflation level more
than doubles, to 0.193, and is now significant at a 1% confidence level. We see similar
increases when we include the larger under 40% inflation sample, or for the sub-sample
excluding the Great Depression and WWII or the Before WWII sub-sample. The
exception is the post-WWII sub-sample, which doesn’texhibit a significant relationship
between inflation and growth in either the linear or non-linear specifications.
With the exception of that sub-sample, our results strongly indicate that allowing
for a non-linear inflation term significantly increases the measured linear relationship
between inflation and growth. The data driving this result can be seen in Figure 1, which
plots the below 20 samples and the fitted nonlinear specifications. Again, except for the
post-WWII sub-sample, we find a pronounced nonlinear relationship between inflation
and growth. Concentrating on the full sample, it can be seen that this nonlinearity is

6

driven by the fact that episodes of very poor economic performance tend to be associated
with high or low inflation levels, while episodes of exceptionally strong economic
performance tend to be clustered around modest inflation levels.4

4. Sample split into high and moderate inflation levels
The results above provide some indication that the relation between inflation and
economic performance is nonlinear, although the sample may be too noisy to closely fit a
nonlinear specification. In this section, we instead split our samples in two, above and
below some threshold that may be associated with the level at which inflation begins to
become problematic. Because the value at which this may occur is uncertain, we examine
a variety of potential inflation thresholds, including 5%, 10%, and 15% sample splits. We
then conduct an F-test to determine whether or not the data suggest that the coefficient
estimate on the level of inflation is stable above and below this threshold.
For each sub-sample, we first estimate the simple linear specification

Δyit = α + β1π it + ε it

(3)

above and below the 5% threshold for the below 20% sample.5
Our results are shown in Table 3. For the full sample, it can be seen that there is a
robust positive correlation between inflation and annual growth below all three of our

4

There are outliers. One notable one in our sample is that of the Netherlands from 1944-1949, which
experienced a remarkable 21.28% average economic growth along with very high 1336% average inflation
levels. Of course, the rapid economic growth can be associated with recovery from the war, which is why
we also examine the results excluding the exceptional war and great depression episodes.
5
We use the 20% cutoff because it corresponds to AK. Using the larger 40% cutoff would obviously only
affect the above-threshold sample, while the results below the specified threshold would be identical.

7

posited thresholds. As expected, we obtain the strongest results for the lowest threshold,
i.e. for inflation below 5%. For that sub-sample, we obtain a coefficient estimate on
inflation equal to 0.32, close to four times the value of the estimate we obtained for the
full sample. This point estimate indicates that a 1% increase in the inflation rate would
correspond to a 0.32% increase in the annual growth rate over a five year period. The
estimate is statistically significant at a 1% confidence level. Above the 5% threshold, we
obtain a very insignificant negative point estimate for relationship between inflation and
growth. Our F-test result confirms that the coefficient on inflation is unstable across the
5% threshold.
Moving to higher threshold levels, our qualitative results remain the same. We
obtain positive and statistically significant point estimate for the relationship between
inflation and growth below the 10% and 15% thresholds at 1% and 5% confidence levels
respectively, while the coefficients above these thresholds are negative and insignificant.
Interestingly, the point estimate on the coefficient diminishes as the size of the threshold
increases. Our point estimate for the sample below 10% inflation falls to 0.15, roughly
half the size of the below-5% threshold, and falls again to 0.10 for the below-15%
threshold. This suggests that the positive relationship between inflation and growth
diminishes above modest inflation levels. Our F-test for a structural break above and
below the 15% threshold is insignificant.
The results for the sub-sample excluding the Great Depression and WWII
episodes are similar. We obtain a positive and statistically significant coefficient on
inflation below all of our posited thresholds, and our point estimates again decrease with
the size of the threshold. Above all three thresholds, we obtain negative, but insignificant

8

coefficient estimates. F-tests confirm the presence of a structural break at statistically
significant levels for the 5% and 10% thresholds, but not for the 15% threshold.
We also obtain similar results for the Before-WWII sub-sample. The coefficient
estimate on the inflation rate is positive and significant for all three thresholds, and
decreases in the size of the threshold. Above all three thresholds, our point estimates are
modestly negative and insignificant. F-tests confirm the presence of a structural break at a
1% confidence level for the 5% and 10% thresholds, and at a 10% confidence level for
the 15% threshold.
The great exception, again, is the post-WWII sample, which is insignificant above
and below all three posited thresholds. Unsurprisingly, the data also fail to confirm the
presence of a structural break across all three thresholds. Still, even for this sub-sample
we obtain a relatively large point estimate on the inflation coefficient of 0.16 for the
sample including inflation levels below 5%.
Overall, dividing the sample above and below some threshold value gave a much
stronger indication that there was a positive relationship between inflation and growth for
modest inflation levels. A notable exception is the post-World War II period, which
failed to demonstrate a structural break at statistically significant levels for either sample.

5. Inflation volatility
In this section, we examine the robustness of our results to the inclusion of a
measure of inflation volatility, measured as the variance of inflation over the five year

9

period. We examine the same specifications as those above with inflation volatility
measure added.
Our results are shown in Table 4. Table 4.1 repeats the non-linear specification
from Table 2 for the full sample and the sub-sample with the Great Depression and
WWII periods excluded. It can be seen that our point estimates for the inflation
coefficient and the nonlinear term are basically unchanged. The inclusion of a nonlinear
term results in a large increase in the coefficient on inflation in levels, to 0.19 for the full
sample. Inflation volatility enters negatively, but is insignificant except for the linear
specification with the Great Depression and WWII removed, and then only at a 10%
confidence level.
We add our measure of inflation volatility to the linear specifications with
structural breaks in Table 4.2. Our coefficient estimates for the below-threashold subsamples are almost identical to those in Table 3. We again obtain a coefficient estimate of
0.32 for the below-5% sub-sample, and our point estimate diminishes as the structural
break threshold increases. As before, our F-tests identify a statistically-significant
structural break at the 5% and 10% threshold levels, but not at the 15% threshold level.
The results for the below-threshold sub-sample for the sample excluding the Great
Depression and WWII are also similar.
The major innovation from including inflation volatility arises in the abovethreshold sub-samples. Inflation in levels is still very insignificant, but inflation volatility
enters negatively at a 1% confidence level for all of our posited thresholds. This result
suggests that the harmful effects of high inflation episodes is associated with the

10

volatility of inflation rather than the level of inflation, which is in keeping with the
previous literature.

6. Conclusion
This paper reexamines the long-term evidence on inflation and economic
performance by allowing for inflation and economic performance to follow a non-linear
relationship. We find that for low and negative inflation levels, the correlation between
inflation and economic performance is quite strong. Below a 5% threshold, our
coefficient estimates indicate that a 1% increase in average inflation levels is associated
with a 0.32% increase in average annual growth. These results are robust to the inclusion
of a measure of inflation volatility. Interestingly, we also found that in samples of high
inflation episodes it was inflation volatility, rather than inflation itself, that had a
measurable adverse impact on economic growth.
We should reiterate Atkeson and Kehoe’s acknowledgement that there is no
causality claim here, rather as in their case, we are just observing the correlations
between these two variables. However, our results contrast sharply with those of Atkeson
and Kehoe for low and negative inflation levels, over which the raw data does appear to
indicate a strong positive link between inflation and economic performance. At a
minimum, the truncated results seem to provide support for effort by monetary authorities
to avoid deflationary episodes.
The one exception to our general results is the After-WWII sub-sample, over
which we fail to find a statistically significant coefficient between inflation and economic

11

performance, even with the sample of episodes below 5% average inflation. This sample
includes the Japanese experience in the 1990s, which exhibited poor growth with
deflation. This might lead some to conclude that while a positive relationship existed
historically, it has broken down in more modern eras. However, it should be pointed out
that our point estimate for the relationship between inflation and growth is quite
comparable to the two full sample values, suggesting that there was not a discernable
dropoff in the relationship after the war. Instead, it appears that the relationship has
grown more noisy, resulting in larger measured standard errors and precluding statistical
inference at standard confidence levels.

12

References
Auerbach, Alan J & Obstfeld, Maurice. (2005). “The Case for Open-Market Purchases in
a Liquidity Trap,” American Economic Review, 95, 110-137.
Atkeson, Andrew and Kehoe, Patrick J. (2004). “Deflation and Depression: Is There an
Empirical Link?,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 94, 99-103.
Backus, David K. and Kehoe, Patrick J. (1992). “Paths of Development for Early- and
Late-Bloomers in a Dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin World,” American Economic Review, 82,
864-888.
Barro, Robert J. (1976). “Rational Expectations and the Role of Monetary Policy,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, 2(1), 1-32.
Benhabib, Jess and Bull, Clive. (1983). “The Optimal Quantity of Money; A Formal
Treatment,” International Economic Review, 24, 101-111.
Bruno, Michael and Easterly, William. (1998). “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, 41(1), 3-26.
Chari, V. V.; Christiano, Lawrence J. and Kehoe, Patrick J. (1996). “Optimality of the
Friedman Rule in Economies with Distorting Taxes.” Journal of Monetary Economics,
37(2), 203-223.
Cole, Harold L. and Kocherlakota, Narayana. (1998). “Zero Nominal Interest Rates: Why
They’re Good and How to Get Them,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review, Spring, 22(2), 2-10.
Ghosh, Atish, and Phillips, Steven. (1998). “Warning: Inflation may be Harmful to your
Growth,” IMF Staff Papers, 45(4), 672-710.
Judson, Ruth and Orphanides, Athanasios. (1999). “Inflation, Volatility and Growth,”
International Finance, 2(1), 117-138.
Krugman, Paul, (1998). “It’s Baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity
Trap,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1998(2), 137–187.
Rolnick, Arthur J. and Weber, Warren E. (1997). “Money, Inflation, and Output under
Fiat and Commodity Standards,” Journal of Political Economy, 105(6), 1-50.
Schmitt-Grohe Stephanie and Uribe, Martin, (2004). “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary
Policy under Sticky Prices,”Journal of Economic Theory, February, 114, 198-230.

13

Table 1: Summary Statistics
Inflation less than 20%
Average
Inflation

Period
Full Sample
Excluding GD and WWII
Before WWII (Pre-1939)
After WWII (Post-1948)
Great Depression

(π )

Average

Inflation

Growth ( y& ) Volatility

(σ )
2

ρ (π , y& )

π

3.30
3.22
0.83
5.70
-3.68

3.04
3.19
2.47
3.64
-0.18

30.67
29.84
44.51
15.42
25.35

Average

Average

Inflation

0.14
0.13
0.17
0.08
0.40

ρ (π , σ π2 ) ρ ( y& , σ π2 )
0.19
0.17
0.28
0.43
-0.38

-0.05
-0.08
-0.05
0.18
-0.32

# obs
391
351
193
171
16

Inflation less than 40%

Period
Full Sample
Excluding GD and WWII
Before WWII (Pre-1939)
After WWII (Post-1948)

Inflation
4.42
4.38
1.40
7.44

(π )

Growth ( y& ) Volatility
3.07
3.18
2.42
3.72

(σ )

44.42
41.13
50.99
38.88

2

ρ (π , y& )

π

0.14
0.08
0.03
0.15

ρ (π , σ π2 ) ρ ( y& , σ π2 )
0.49
0.47
0.47
0.63

0.02
-0.11
-0.12
0.17

Note: Average levels of and correlations between inflation, growth and volatility.
Definition of volatility is in the text. Statistics for Great Depression are the same for 20%
and 40% samples

14

# obs
411
370
198
186

Table 2: Inflation and Growth
Sample:
Dependent Variable:
Average Income Growth

Inflation less than 20%

Inflation less than 40%

Linear
Non-Linear
Linear
Non-Linear
Specification Specification Specification Specification
Full Sample
π

0.083**
(0.036)

π2
# Observations

391

0.193***
(0.059)
-0.010**
(0.004)
391

0.056**
(0.028)

0.123**
(0.058)
-0.005
(0.004)
351

0.027
(0.025)

0.170**
(0.076)
-0.010
(0.008)
193

0.015
(0.048)

0.051
(0.114)
-0.002
(0.007)
171

0.021
(0.031)

411

0.110**
(0.050)
-0.002
(0.002)
411

Excluding GD and WWII

π

0.068**
(0.031)

π2
# Observations

351

370

0.091**
(0.043)
-0.003**
(0.002)
370

Before WWII

π

0.104*
(0.060)

π2
# Observations
After WWII
π

193

0.026
(0.039)

π2
# Observations

171

198

186

0.177**
(0.073)
-0.011***
(0.003)
198

0.040
(0.068)
-0.001
(0.002)
186

Note: Estimation by OLS with White’s heteroskedasticity correction. *, **, and ***,
indicate statistical significance at 10, 5, and 1 percent levels respectively.

15

Table 3: Samples Split by Inflation
Dependent Variable:
Average Income Growth

Full Sample
π

F-value
# Observations

π ≤ 5%

π > 5%

π ≤ 10%

π > 10%

π ≤ 15%

π > 15%

0.319***
(0.070)

-0.001
(0.002)

0.153***
(0.050)

-0.001
(0.002)

0.103**
(0.049)

-0.001
(0.002)

10.36***
284
141

4.78***

2.19

353

72

377

48

0.133***
(0.041)

-0.000
(0.002)

0.074**
(0.037)

-0.001
(0.002)

Excluding GD and WWII

π

F-value
# Observations
Before WWII
π

F-value
# Observations

0.179**
(0.069)

-0.001
(0.002)

3.64**

5.76***

2.08

260

123

323

60

340

43

0.262***
(0.086)

-0.071
(0.047)

0.246***
(0.073)

-0.035
(0.058)

0.121*
(0.068)

-0.070
(0.068)

6.10***
174
26

7.76***

2.73*

183

17

190

10

0.015
(0.057)

-0.001
(0.002)

0.005
(0.048)

-0.001
(0.002)

After WWII

π

F-value
# Observations

0.184
(0.166)

-0.001
(0.002)

0.64
94

0.84
103

148

0.37
49

161

Note: OLS estimates of relationship between inflation and growth using White’s
heteroskedasticity correction. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5%
and 10% confidence levels respectively.

16

36

Table 4: Inflation Volatility and Growth
4.1. Linear and non-linear specifications
Dependent Variable:
Average Income Growth

π

Full Sample
Linear
Non-Linear
Specification Specification

0.091**
(0.035)

0.187***
(0.061)
-0.009**
(0.004)

0.077**
(0.031)

0.110*
(0.060)
-0.003
(0.005)

-0.003
(0.002)
391

-0.002
(0.002)
391

-0.003*
(0.002)
351

-0.002
(0.002)
351

π2
σ π2
# Observations

Excluding GD and WWII
Linear
Non-Linear
Specification
Specification

4.2. Samples split by inflation
Dependent Variable: Average Income Growth
π ≤ 5%
π > 5%
π ≤ 10%
Full Sample
π

σ π2

F-value
# Observations

F-value
# Observations

π ≤ 15%

0.323***
0.003
0.149***
0.003
0.110**
(0.074)
(0.002)
(0.052)
(0.002)
(0.048)
0.001 -7.42e-06** -0.002 -7.69e-06*** -0.004*
(0.003) (3.08e-06) (0.003)
(2.77e-06)
(0.002)
10.10***
284
141

Excluding GD and WWII
π
0.182**
(0.076)

σ π2

π > 10%

0.003
(0.002)

4.56**

2.19
72

377

48

0.132***
(0.042)

0.003*
(0.002)

0.080**
(0.036)

0.003
(0.002)

3.40**

-8.15e-06*** -0.004**
(2.45e-06)
(0.002)

5.60***
123

0.003
(0.002)
-7.64e-06***
(2.79e-06)

353

0.001 -7.69e-06** -0.000
(0.004) (3.09e-06) (0.003)

260

π > 15%

323

-8.05e-06***
(2.63e-06)
2.08

60

340

43

Estimates on constant coefficients have been suppressed and are available upon request.

17

18