View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Unemployment Insurance when the
Wealth Distribution Matters

WP 23-08

Facundo Piguillem
EIEF and CEPR
Hernán Ruffo
UTDT
Nicholas Trachter
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Unemployment Insurance when the
Wealth Distribution Matters∗
Facundo Piguillem

Hernán Ruffo

Nicholas Trachter

EIEF and CEPR

UTDT

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

April, 2023
Abstract
This paper analyzes the welfare effects of unemployment insurance in a life-cycle
model, focusing on partial vs. general equilibrium effects. We study an OLG economy with learning-by-doing human capital accumulation. Agents can be employed or
unemployed. While unemployed agents costly search for new jobs. We calibrate the
model to the U.S. economy, and find that replacement ratio and potential duration are
close to the current one. But, in contrast with the previous literature, we find that the
optimal policies under general and partial equilibrium are almost the same. Through a
series of exercises we conclude that the life-cycle model provides two key components,
crucial for welfare evaluation: it emphasizes workers’ insurance needs by accurately
reproducing the left tail of the wealth distribution, and generates a realistic response
of precautionary savings to transfers.
JEL classification: E62; H21; E24
Keywords: Unemployment insurance. Human capital. Life cycle. Wealth inequality.
General equilibrium.

∗

We thank Fernando Alvarez, Oscar Avila, Emilio Espino, Mark Huggett, Francesco Lippi, Guido Lorenzoni, Guido Menzio, Claudio Michelacci, Juan Pablo Nicolini, Luigi Pistaferri, Rob Shimer, and seminar
participants at UTDT, UNLP, CAF, and the Launch @ lunch seminars at EIEF, and SED, Rome Junior
Macro, LAMES, RIDGE, LAVG, CEF, and EEA-ESEM conferences for useful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

1

Introduction

Unemployment insurance (UI) provides workers with means to smooth consumption after
job loss, but reduces their incentives to find a new job. This trade-off between insurance
and incentives has been the focus of the optimal UI analysis and a fundamental issue of
economic policy for over a century. Although initially controversial, an extensive literature
abstracting from general equilibrium effects widely agrees that UI is socially valuable. How
generous the system should be is still debatable, but there is consensus that it should exist. In
contrast, the literature focusing on general equilibrium points out that public transfers only
substitutes private insurance (through savings), reduces physical capital and production, and
generates additional price adjustments that render UI undesirable. In this paper we show
that both views are reconciled when the sources of wealth inequality are carefully considered
and incorporated.
There are two key elements shaping the discrepancy between partial and general equilibrium approaches in the literature. One is the degree of insurance needs. General equilibrium
models tend to generate few asset-poor workers and, thus, little value for public transfers.
The other is the elasticity of savings to changes in the benefits embodied in the UI system.
Infinitely-lived agents models tend to amplify the response of assets and, hence, social costs
of UI. Throughout the paper we argue that an overlapping generations model provides a
setup that naturally generates the wealth distribution and the capital elasticity of the data,
and we find that a UI system funded through labor taxation has mild effects reducing private
savings and search effort.
We build a life-cycle model where risk averse workers derive utility from consumption and
leisure. They begin their working life without assets or working experience, then accumulate
assets and human capital while working. While employed they can choose their work intensity.
An exogenous separation shock makes workers fall into unemployment, in which case they
are eligible for UI transfers of limited duration. While unemployed, jobless workers actively
search for a job at a utility cost. At the end of their working life, agents retire and receive
a pension from the government. Workers are employed by competitive firms operating a
constant returns of scale technology relying in both, physical and human capital. Finally,
there is a government that provides UI and pension benefits, funded through a proportional
labor income tax, balancing its budget in every period.
This life-cycle structure generates important economic mechanisms that are relevant for
welfare evaluation (Michelacci and Ruffo, 2015). Young workers are typically not able to
save enough to face an unemployment spell because of their limited employment history.
Moreover, due to the increasing life cycle income profile, young workers do not save much at

1

the beginning of their working life. These effects generate a savings life-cycle profile and an
assets distribution that are consistent with the data. In particular, they generate a proportion
of liquidity constrained unemployed workers that is close to the observed. This point is crucial
for the adequate measurement of UI welfare gains. If workers could completely finance their
consumption while unemployed, UI would lack most of its appeal. In addition, the life-cycle
concerns reduce the response of assets to transfers. This is because, in our model, agents
have incentives to save for reasons beyond unemployment risk. Saving for retirement is the
main reason to accumulate assets, explaining most of the assets accumulation.
In this context, we search for the UI replacement ratio and potential duration that maximizes the workers lifetime utility at birth. We find that the optimal policy in partial equilibrium has the same potential duration and a slightly higher replacement ratio than the
current U.S. system, but still close to it (63% compared to the current 50%). The welfare
effects are sizeable, the estimated losses of eliminating the UI system are equivalent to a fall
in 4% of lifetime consumption. Importantly, the result is almost unchanged when we allow
for general equilibrium effects. The reason is that both labor and capital adjust in a similar
proportion, letting capital-labor ratio to remain fairly constant around the optimum. Thus,
the change in factor prices in general equilibrium has small welfare effects.
Our result is consistent with the partial equilibrium literature, but at odds with the previous results in general equilibrium. There are several reasons for this, mostly associated with
the life-cycle effects. The standard approach is to analyze the problem assuming infinitely
lived agents facing unemployment risk. In these frameworks agents have strong incentives to
save when employed (especially when the wage is high) and have infinite periods to do so.
As a result, they are able to accumulate enough assets to insure against most adverse future
histories. Thus, these models typically lack asset-poor workers, generating a distribution of
assets less dispersed than the empirically observed. There is a mechanism akin to Clementi
and Hopenhayn (2006) allowing agents to “escape” the financial constraints. This also implies that in infinitely lived agents’ models the elasticity of assets with respect to UI benefits
is large. Hence, physical capital strongly responds to UI, generating a sizeable reduction in
aggregate production. As a consequence, this modelling choice reduce the welfare gains and
increase the welfare costs of UI.
One may wonder whether matching wealth inequality by other means would be enough
to overcome this problem. For instance, since Krusell and Smith (1998) it is customary to
generate more dispersion by appealing to stochastic heterogeneous discount factors. This
“trick” only reshuffles the savings elasticities of agents, with an average that must remain
approximately constant to generate the same aggregate capital. With infinite periods to
adapt to alternative UI policies, the welfare effects are not far from the standard setup with

2

homogeneous discount factors, for instance, Mukoyama (2013). It is not enough to generate
the right amount of wealth inequality, but to do it by the right reasons.
To show the relevance of life-cycle effects on the distribution of assets and the response
of aggregate capital to changes in UI, we start by shutting down many age dependent components. We eliminate the human capital accumulation process, extend the working life and
give workers a more generous pension. Importantly, we allow for an initial distribution of
assets that reproduces the distribution of assets of those that exit the model. We show that
in this model, with moderated life-cycle effects and consistent with the previous literature,
the optimal UI plummets to close to zero even in partial equilibrium.
Still, one may wonder that UI could be replacing missing instruments to provide intergenerational transfers to the young. To this end, we also construct alternative economies
(where the income life-cycle profile is flatten or where there is a budget constraint by age),
keeping the savings life-cycle profile, and show that the conclusions are maintained. As long
as liquidity constraints are relevant and savings are sufficiently inelastic, for the young due
to scarcity and for the older due to retirement concerns, it is optimal to provide UI.
Finally, one important element in our baseline economy is that even though the UI affects
aggregate capital and labor, it does so proportionally, so that the capital-labor ratio, and
therefore prices, are barely affected. To show this, we analyze alternative funding strategies,
using capital taxation and delay lump sum taxation upon retirement. In these alternatives the
capital-labor ratio is more sensitive and therefore the general equilibrium effects are larger.
We show that whenever the ratio is reduced due to the increase in UI, the general equilibrium
analysis prescribes less generous UI compared to partial equilibrium analysis. Conversely,
whenever the capital-labor ratio is increased due to more generous UI, the general equilibrium
analysis suggests more generous UI compared to partial equilibrium.
Our contribution is, thus, to build a bridge between two branches of the literature and
to emphasize the role of the distribution of assets and the elasticity of savings with respect
to UI. We show that if the capital-labor ratio does not change with UI, the general equilibrium effect is nil. In such a case, partial equilibrium approach is accurate. In the case in
which the capital-labor ratio changes, the additional price effect should be considered for the
identification of the optimal policy.
The paper is structured as follows. In the Section 1.1 we briefly review the extensive
related literature. In Section 2 we present the economic environment and in Section 3 its
calibration to the U.S. economy. Section 4 presents the main results. In Section 5 we present a
series of exercises to understand the underlying economic mechanisms, leaving the robustness
exercises to Section 6. Finally, Section 7 concludes.

3

1.1

Literature review

The trade-off between insurance and search effort has been extensively studied through optimal dynamic contracts by Shavell and Weiss (1979), Hopenhayn and Nicolini (1997, 2009)
and Shimer and Werning (2008, 2006), among many others. These papers emphasize the
role of changing consumption, benefits and labor taxes through the unemployment spell to
provide incentives to job-search. They also show that the optimal policies provide substantial
insurance and increase welfare.
The UI policy has also been studied using sufficient statistics approach since Baily (1978).
That paper proposes that the optimal UI should be set so that the utility loss due to consumption drop upon unemployment equates the elasticity of the duration of unemployment
spell with respect to a balanced budget increase in UI benefits and taxes. A series of papers,
Shimer and Werning (2007), Chetty (2008) and Landais (2015), extend this approach using
search models of the labor market to identify marginal welfare gains and losses of changing
UI. After measuring costs and benefits with the U.S. data, they typically find that the UI
system is close to the optimal or even that there are welfare gains of making it more generous.
The UI system has been also evaluated through quantitative models of the labor market
with moral hazard, as in Hansen and Imrohoroglu (1992). Some of these papers find that
the US system is close to the optimal and they evaluate the welfare gains of introducing
reforms, such as introducing UI savings accounts (Setty, 2017), conditioning UI to assets
of the unemployed (Koehne and Kuhn, 2015), to age (Michelacci and Ruffo, 2015), or to
business cycle variables (Schwartz, 2013). All of them suggest that UI provides relevant
welfare gains.
There are several papers analyzing general equilibrium effects. They do so by introducing
capital as a production factor. They argue that UI imposes strong welfare costs and provides
little welfare gains, making it mostly useless or even harmful (Alvarez and Veracierto, 1998,
2001; Young, 2004; Mukoyama, 2010, 2013; Popp, 2017). A main argument is that both
assets and labor are reduced by UI, causing aggregate activity to fall (Young, 2004). Thus,
once general equilibrium effects are taken into account, induced social costs of UI are strong.
This literature has mostly used infinitely lived agents models. This modelling choice has
been used in Young (2004), that adds capital to Wang and Williamson (2002), and finds that
the reduction in aggregate activity outweighs the insurance of UI. Also, Mukoyama (2010,
2013) concludes that UI is not welfare enhancing in GE. However, these two papers are still
away from generating wealth dispersion that maps to insurance needs.1 Additionally, Young
1

In Young (2004) wealth dispersion arises only from uninsurable employment risk but wealth dispersion
is far below the observed. Mukoyama (2010) generates dispersion by introducing (random) heterogeneous
discount factors. Hence, wealth dispersion is the agents’ optimal choice, and uncorrelated with income shocks.

4

(2004) clearly shows that assets are very elastic, both to UI and to factor prices. These
settings suffer from the same issues pointed out by Engen and Gruber (2001), generating
excessive crowding out of private savings.2 Birinci and See (2022), in a general equilibrium
setting, focuses on the heterogeneous responses to UI, dealing with many of the issues aforementioned, but their model omits capital as a production factor, it does not include the life
cycle behavior, and does not aim to identify an optimal system.

2

The model

The economy is populated by a continuum of agents, a competitive firm, and the government.
At any point in time agents can differ in their age j ∈ {1, 2, 3, ...}, wealth level a, position
in the job ladder κ ∈ K, and their activity status i ∈ {e, u, R} where e denotes currently
employed, u currently unemployed and R retired agents. For those unemployed, the duration
of the current unemployment spell is denoted by ψ ∈ Ψ.

2.1

Competitive Firm

The firm has access to a constant return to scale technology F (K, H), where K denotes
physical capital and H denotes units of effective labor. The firm pays wage, w, per unit of
effective labor, rents capital at the rate r, and incurs a depreciation cost at the rate d. The
firm’s objective is to maximize its profits:
max K α H 1−α − (r + d)K − wH .
K,H

The first order conditions of the firm’s problem provide


K
H

α

w = (1 − α)
,
 α−1
K
r=α
− d.
H

2.2

Agents

Each period, a measure one of agents enter the labor market, with age j = 1. Agents can
work up to age j = T . At T an agent must retire, and collects pension proceeds P w each
period while alive. Agents die stochastically with age dependent probability δ(j). We assume
2

In Young (2004), when UI is eliminated, assets increase by 63% in the absence of factor price adjustments
and by 3% after they adjust.

5

that δ(j) = δj for j ≤ T and δ(j) = δR for j > T , which state that the death probability
is only age dependent for agents in working age. This assumption helps us to simplify the
value after retirement. Note that we are assuming retirement is exogenous at age T . As
Costa (1998) and Bloom et al. (2007) show, the retirement age in the U.S., as in many other
countries, has been continuously decreasing over the last century. Hence, our assumption is
conservative on capturing the effect of aging on savings.3
Let u(c, n, s) denote the per period utility flow of an agent that consumes c, works a
proportion n ∈ [0, 1] of its working time endowment, and exerts s ∈ [0, 1] search effort to find
a job. We assume that u(c, n, s) takes the following form:

1−σ
((1−n)ω c1−ω )



1−σ



1−σ
(c1−ω )
(1−s)1−γ1
u(c, n, s) =
−
γ
0
1−σ
|1−γ1 |




1−σ

 (c1−ω )
1−σ

with γ1 > 1. The employed agent’s formulation is similar
diroglu et al. (2002).
The movements through the job ladder are stochastic
motion:


κt



 κ
t
κt+1 =

κt + 1 with prob. χ(n)



 κ
with prob. 1 − χ(n)
t

if i = e,
if i = u,
if i = R.
to the specification in Abdulkaand follow the following law of
if
if
if
if

it
it
it
it

= R,
= u,
= e,
= e.

(1)

Note that an agent can move up in the job ladder with positive probability only when she
is employed, and that this probability, χ(n), depends on her labor intensity choice. Moreover,
the law of motion in equation (1) makes clear that agents cannot fall in the ladder. Every
movement has a permanent effect.
Each step in the job ladder is associated to a particular level of human capital h(κ),
mapping steps κ into units of effective labor. As a result, employed agents receive a net labor
compensation, nh(κ)w(1 − τ ). This is proportional to the effective units of labor supplied
3

As Bloom et al. (2014) argue, as life expectancy increases there are two effects affecting the retirement
decision. On the one hand, workers can extend their working life to compensate the longer retirement, but
on the other hand, the increase in labor productivity that usually accompanies a longer life increases the
demand for leisure (income-wealth effect), which induces an earlier retirement. The net effect of living longer
on the retirement age is then ambiguous. Recent work, such as Shourideh and Troshkin (2017), however,
point to the dominance of the income-wealth effect, except for individuals in top income decile. Alternative
explanations of why agents do not retire older range from an increased female labor force participation, as
proposed by Borella et al. (2017). For a cross-section of countries, Bonfatti et al. (2019) discuss the binding
statutory nature of retirement in many countries.

6

to the firm, nh(κ), and net of the tax liabilities τ , that are used to fund the UI and pension
systems.
Let 1 − πj denote the (exogenous) job separation probability by age. After separation
workers become unemployed and receive insurance in the form of a replacement ratio B(ψ),
where the dependence on ψ shows that the compensation scheme can depend on the duration
of the current unemployment spell. Unemployed agents collect B(ψ)n̄h(κ)w(1−τ ) as income,
which depends on the average labor intensity in the economy, n̄.4
We now describe the problem of retired, employed, and unemployed agents. Let V R (a)
denote the value for a retired agent with current wealth a, let Vje (a, κ) denote the value for
an employed worker of age j with current wealth a and accumulated labor capital κ, and
let Vju (a, κ, ψ) denote the value for an unemployed worker of age j with current wealth a,
accumulated labor capital κ and current unemployment duration ψ.
2.2.1

The problem of a retired agent

When retired, an agent can finance her consumption with her own past savings and transfers
from the pension system. The pension benefits are represented by replacement ratio P . Thus,
a retired agent’s value function V R (a) solves the following Bellman equation:
1−σ

V R (a) = max
′
c,a

(c1−ω )
1−σ

+ β(1 − δR )V R (a′ )

s.t.
c + a′ = (1 + r)a + P w,
a′ ≥ 0 , c ≥ 0.
A natural implication of the problem of a retired agent is that consumption and assets
accumulation are a function of the current agent’s asset level. That is, c = cR (a) and
a′ = aR (a).
4
Linking the benefits to the average rather than the individual’s specific hours of the last job allows us to
simplify the computation, so that we no not need to keep track of one additional state variable. Given that
the number of hours worked are fairly constant, we still refer to B as the replacement ratio.

7

2.2.2

The problem of an unemployed agent

An unemployed agent’s value function Vju (a, κ, ψ) solves:
1−σ

Vju (a, κ, ψ)

(c1−ω )
(1 − s)1−γ1
= max
− γ0
c,a′ ,s
1−σ
|1 − γ1 |

 e
′
u
(a′ , κ, ψ + 1)
+ β(1 − δj ) sVj+1 (a , κ) + (1 − s)Vj+1

s.t.
c + a′ = (1 + r)a + B(ψ)n̄h(κ)w(1 − τ ),
a′ ≥ 0 , c ≥ 0, s ∈ [0, 1].
when j < T . In the last period the problem is slightly different because the agent knows that
at j = T she must retire. Thus, at j = T the objective function must be replaced with the
following,
1−σ

VTu (a, κ, ψ) = max
′
c,a ,s

(c1−ω )
1−σ

− γ0

(1 − s)1−γ1
+ β(1 − δj )V R (a′ ).
|1 − γ1 |

Notice that the optimal choice of search effort is 0 at j = T , because retirement is mandatory
after that period. The solution to the unemployed agent’s problem is a set of policy functions:
c = cuj (a, κ, ψ), a′ = auj (a, κ, ψ), and s = sj (a, κ, ψ).
2.2.3

The problem of an employed agent

For all j < T the employed agent’s value function Vje (a, κ) solves:
Vje (a, κ)

1−σ


((1 − n)ω c1−ω )
e
u
= max
+ β(1 − δj ) χ(n) πj Vj+1
(a′ , κ + 1) + (1 − πj )Vj+1
(a′ , κ + 1, 1)
′
c,a ,n
1−σ

e
u
(a′ , κ) + (1 − πj )Vj+1
+(1 − χ(n)) πj Vj+1
(a′ , κ, 1)

s.t.
c + a′ = (1 + r)a + nh(κ)w(1 − τ ),
a′ ≥ 0 , c ≥ 0 , n ∈ [0, 1].
As with the unemployed worker, the employed worker knows at j = T that next period she
must retire. As a result, even though the constraint set remains the same, at age T the
employed worker’s objective function is given by
1−σ

VTe (a, κ) = max
′
c,a ,n

((1 − n)ω c1−ω )
1−σ
8

+ β(1 − δj )V R (a′ ).

The solution to the employed agent’s problem is a set of policy functions: c = cej (a, κ), a′ =
aej (a, κ), and n = nj (a, κ).

2.3

The government

The government collects taxes and makes the necessary transfers to sustain the UI and
pension systems. It does so by maintaining a balanced budget. This implies that in each
period the following government budget constraint is satisfied:
Z

τ nj (a, κ)h(κ)wXje (a, κ)d(κ

Z

τ h(κ)B(ψ)n̄wXju (a, κ, ψ)d(κ × a × j × ψ)
Z
Z
u
= h(κ)B(ψ)n̄wXj (a, κ, ψ)d(κ × a × j × ψ) + P w X R (a)da.
× a × j) +

where X R (a) denotes the measure of retired agents with wealth a; Xje (a, κ) denotes the
measure of employed agents of age j, with wealth a in the job ladder step κ; Xju (a, κ, ψ)
denotes the measure of unemployed agents of age j, with wealth a, who where in the job
ladder step κ, but have been unemployed for ψ periods.5

2.4

Stationary equilibrium

In what follows we focus on stationary equilibria to compare alternative policies.
Definition. Given a policy rule {τ, B(ψ), P }, a stationary equilibrium is prices {w, r} and
measures X R (a), Xje (a, κ), Xju (a, κ, ψ) ∀j, a, κ, ψ, such that:
1. Agents maximize utility,
2. Markets clear,
Z
H =
Z
K =

h(κ)nj (a, κ)Xje (a, κ)d(j × a × κ),

(2)



a X r (a) + Xje (a, κ) + Xju (a, κ, ψ) d(j × a × κ × ψ).

(3)

3. The feasibility constraint is satisfied,
Z
F (K, H) − dK =

5

Z

R

c (a)X (a)da +
Z

+

R

cej (a, κ)Xje (a, κ)d(j × a × κ)

cuj (a, κ, ψ)Xju (a, κ, ψ)d(j × a × κ × ψ).

See the definition and computation of these measures in Appendix C.

9

At this stage it is worth making some observations. First, H in equation (2) is akin to
the aggregate human capital in the economy. However, it only includes the employed human
R
capital, as there is always idle human capital, with aggregate value h(κ)Xju (a, κ, ψ)d(j ×a×
κ×ψ). Second, notice that the measure of retirees’ assets and consumption do not depend on
the agent’s age. This is due to the assumption that after retirement the survival probability
is constant. Finally, because of Walras’ Law, the feasibility constraint is unnecessary: as long
as the asset’s market clearing condition embedded in equation (3) is satisfied, the feasibility
constraint should also be satisfied.

3

Calibration

We set the model-period equal to a calendar quarter (12 weeks) to have sufficient flexibility on
the unemployment duration spell. We assume that the starting age of an individual (j = 1) is
analogous to 23 years old in calendar time and we set the compulsory retirement age to be 65
years old, setting T = 172. In our baseline calibration we assume that all workers begin their
life with no assets and a proportion 1 − π1 are initially unemployed. In Table 1 we present
the calibrated parameters and functions. We discuss the calibration exercise according to the
quantification method: some are imputed from exogenous sources to the model, while others
require calibration through indirect inference.

3.1

Imputation of parameters

UI system parameters. To calibrate the economy we need to specify the UI system. Following
the literature we set the UI system to provide a replacement ratio of 0.5 for up to 6 months
(two model periods):
(
0.5 if ψ ≤ 2,
B(ψ) =
(4)
0
if ψ > 2.
This replacement ratio is around the values typically used in the literature (for example,
Wang and Williamson (2002)).
Capital share of output α, depreciation rate d, death probability δj and job-keeping probability πj . As it is standard in the literature we set the capital share of output α to be 0.3
and the depreciation rate to d = 0.01.6 We quantify the death probability δj using the 2007
United States survival probability actuarial data collected by the Social Security Adminis6

Along with the assets lost by the assumption that agents do not leave legacies, we add up to 5% of assets
lost within the year.

10

Table 1: Calibration of parameters and functions

Parameter/function

Value

How to calibrate

Moment
Model

Data

standard

-

-

Imputed parameters
Capital share of output α
Depreciation rate d
Death probability δ(j)
Job keeping probability πj

0.3
0.01

standard

0.05 annual†

-

see Figure 19

Social Security data

-

-

see left panel of Figure 3

estimates from CPS data

-

-

Calibrated parameters
Discount factor β

(0.96)1/4

capital to output ratio (2.7)

2.7

-

Labor disutility ω

0.65

40-42 hours worked per week

0.34

0.34

Risk aversion σ

3.86

risk aversion of retirees= 2

-

-

Search cost: level p. γ0

0.27

avg. unemployment rate (2004-12)

0.068

0.068

Search cost: elast. p. γ1

1.8

elast. of job-finding to benefits

-0.32

-0.32

see Figure 1

returns to experience

-

-

Human capital h(κ) and χ(n)

Policy parameters in the calibrated economy
UI system B

0.5

replacement ratio of UI to 50%

-

-

UI system ψ

2

unemployment duration of 26 weeks

-

-

Pension system P

0.045

pension expenditures over GDP

0.068

0.068

Tax rate τ

0.124

Balance budget

-

-

Notes: The model period is set to 12 weeks. Total periods in the labor market T = 172. All workers are born with no assets
and no experience. Initially unemployed workers: 1 − π1 = 0.1233. † In the depreciation rate we compute also the lost capital
due to agents’ death in the model.

tration (see Figure 19).7 Notice that in our model we impose the same death probability δR
for retired agents (with age above 65). We compute δR so that the expected lifetime at age
65 matches the empirical life expectancy which is 17 years; this implies that δR ≈ 0.016. We
set the separation rate by age, 1 − πj , from CPS data, and we depict these rates in the left
panel of Figure 3.8

3.2

Calibration of remaining parameters by indirect inference

We quantify the remaining parameters by calibrating the model to the United States economy.
Discount factor β. As it is standard we target the capital to GDP ratio to calibrate β.
Higher values of it induce higher savings, which in turn increases the capital output ratio.
Labor disutility ω and risk aversion parameter σ. A higher value for ω decreases labor
7

The data is available at www.ssa.gov/oact/STATS/table4c6.html
This data was constructed by Robert Shimer. For additional details, please see Shimer (2012) and his
website http://sites.google.com/site/robertshimer/research/flows. The same disclaimer applies for the job
finding rate which we use later on to compute unemployment rates by age.
8

11

Figure 1: Human capital: data and calibrated model
1.3
1.2

wage

1.1
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
Model

Data

0.6
0

10

20

30

Years of experience
Notes: The red (dashed) line is the non-parametric estimate of the returns to experience as explained in Appendix B.1.
The blue (solid) line is the profile of wages in the calibrated model.

intensity n. Thus, we use the average number of hours worked by the employed as a moment
to identify ω. From McGrattan and Rogerson (2004) we know that individuals between 23
and 65 years old work between 40 and 42 hours per week (depending on sex and marital
status) so our target for the proportion of time spent at work is 0.34. For σ we match the
risk aversion of retirees to the standard value of 2.9
Human capital h(κ), the job ladder K, and χ(n). To maintain tractability we assume
that the job ladder is composed of 10 steps so that K = {1, 2, 3, ..., 10}, and that:

χ(n) =


χ̂

if n ≥ 16 ,

0

if n < 16 .

(5)

so that an employed worker needs to work the equivalent to at least 4 hours per day to have
a positive probability of climbing the ladder. Once above this threshold, the probability of
moving up in the ladder is constant and independent of both n and κ. Each step in the
ladder is associated with effective human capital h(κ). We calibrate h(κ) and χ̂ jointly by
matching the empirical wage - experience profile that arises from a standard regression using
NLSY 1979 (see Appendix B.1). We use the first 8 steps of the ladder to match the empirical
human capital function (with experience levels that range from 1 to 35 years) and we use the
9

Notice that under our utility function specification the relative risk aversion (RRA) is 1 − (1 − σ)(1 − ω),
from where, given RRA and ω, can be used to back out σ.

12

Figure 2: Unemployment rate by age

unemployment rate

0.15

0.1

0.05

Model

Data

40

50

0
30

60

Age
Notes: The red (dashed) line is the unemployment rate by age from the data, as implied by the CPS job finding and job
keeping rates. The blue (solid) line is the unemployment rate from the calibrated model.

last 2 steps to extrapolate the ladder up 42 years of experience (so that the experience levels
span the entire working life of agents in the model). Furthermore, the calibration exercise
implies that χ̂ = 0.088. In Figure 1 we plot the estimate of average human capital level and
the calibrated ladder.
Search cost parameters γ0 and γ1 . We target the average unemployment rate to 6.8%,
the average from 2004 to 2012 in the US. At the same time, we target the elasticity of jobfinding rate with respect to UI. We consider the elasticity of -0.32 (Landais, 2015). The
elasticity of job-finding rate with respect to UI is a crucial component for the analysis of
the UI system according to the sufficient statistic literature (Chetty, 2008). In the model,
we measure the elasticity as the partial effects of benefits. To be precise, we change benefit
level (B) only, while we keep taxes and other general equilibrium variables constant. We do
this to isolate the effect of benefits in job-finding rate, and more closely connect with the
empirical literature that compares the unemployment duration of workers with different UI
levels, but with otherwise similar environments (for example Landais (2015); for additional
details about the procedure for calibrating this function see in Appendix B.2). We obtain
γ0 = 0.27 and γ1 = 1.8. Figure 2 presents the unemployment rate by age constructed using
the job keeping probability and job finding probability implied by the CPS (red dashed line)
and the rate implied by the calibration exercise (blue solid line).

13

4

Results

In this section we present the main results of the paper. We first show how the model
performs in non-targeted moments and then we present the welfare evaluations of alternative
unemployment insurance policies.

4.1

Some features of the parameterized economy

A key moment of our analysis is the unemployment rate by age (see Figure 2). The unemployment rate is almost 13% for the young workers (those that in our model begin their
working lives) and then decreases to about 5% for workers close to retirement. The model
does a remarkable good job at matching not only the level but also the slope. This together
with the fact that we also target the elasticity of the job finding rate gives confidence that
the model is well suited for our goal.
The unemployment rate by age profile is generated by (exogenous) separation and (endogenous) finding rates that vary by age. Panel (a) of Figure 3 presents the separation rate
by age. Initial separation is close to 12% for those at the beginning of their working life,
and rapidly decreases to below 4%. Thus, unemployment risk mostly affects young workers.
The blue solid line in Panel (b) presents the job-finding rate by age. At the beginning of
their working life, unemployed workers exert high effort in finding a job. There are two main
reasons for this high effort. First, young workers begin their working life without assets,
so that they need to escape unemployment before UI is exhausted. Second, they invest in
job-search to increase their human capital. This component is relevant during the first half
of the life. After that, human capital does not increase much for the median worker. The
job-finding rate then decreases, when workers are able to better self-smooth consumption
during unemployment. At the end of working life this rate drops because workers are about
to retire, decreasing the value of finding a job.
To understand the reaction of the job-finding rate to changes on unemployment benefits,
in Panel (b) of Figure 3 we also plot counterfactual rates with an alternative replacement
ratio and duration. The red dashed line depicts the job-finding rate when the replacement
ratio is set 10 percentage points higher. This higher transfer reduces the incentives to search
for workers of all ages. The effect of the change in the policy is more appreciable for older
workers. In fact, the elasticity of the job-finding rate with respect to benefits in our model is
smaller for younger workers than for older ones. This feature has been documented elsewhere
(Michelacci and Ruffo, 2015), and arise naturally in a life-cycle setting. The dark dotted line
shows the job-finding rate by age when UI potential duration is extended one model period
(12 weeks). Again, the job-finding rate falls sharply and, again, the fall is larger for older
14

Figure 3: Job-finding and separation rates
0.14

0.9
0.8

0.12

Job-finding rate

separation rate

0.7
0.1

0.08

0.06

0.6
0.5
0.4

0.04

baseline
+0.1 of replacement ratio
+1 quarter of potential duration

0.3

0.02

0.2
30

40

50

60

30

Age

40

50

60

Age

(a) Separation

(b) Job-finding

Notes: Panel (a) reports separation rates as exogenously calibrated in the model (Shimer, 2012). The blue solid line in
panel (b) reports the average job-finding rate by age in the calibrated model; the red dashed line is the average job-finding
rate by age if benefits were to increase by 10 percentage points; the black dotted line is the same profile in the calibrated
model, but if potential duration were to be extended one additional quarter.

workers. Even though the response to the change in duration seems to be larger, one must
bear in mind that the increase in the replacement ratio is 20% (10%/50%), while the increase
in the duration is much larger, of 50% (1/2). For this reason, the elasticities do not greatly
differ.
Figure 4 plots labor income—in panel (a)—and consumption—in panel (b)—of employed
and unemployed workers by age. The blue solid line depicts the average labor income of
employed workers, which it is increasing by age up to a peak at age 45 and then starts to
decrease. The pattern is affected by the human capital profile (as shown in Figure 1) and
total hours worked. In the calibrated economy hours worked increase with human capital
and decrease with assets. For that reason, the model generates a reduction in total labor
income for employed workers after age 50. The dashed red line of Panel (a) also plots the
average unemployed worker’s income. This amount depends on human capital and on the
average duration of unemployment spells. We find that this income is mildly increasing, at a
slower rate than the labor income for the employed. This is partly because the UI exhaustion
is increasing by age. The rapid increase in average unemployment duration at the end of the
working life explains the drop in the average UI transfers for those periods. Panel (b) in the
figure depicts the evolution of average consumption of the employed and the unemployed.
Consumption levels are increasing in age, which is consistent with the accumulation of human

15

0.4

0.4

0.35

0.35

0.3

0.3

Consumption

Labor income

Figure 4: Income and consumption through the life-cycle

0.25
0.2
0.15
0.1

0.25
0.2
0.15
0.1

0.05

0.05
Employed

Unemployed

Employed

0

Unemployed

0
30

40

50

60

30

Age

40

50

60

Age

(a) Labor income

(b) Consumption

Notes: Panel (a) reports the average labor income of employed workers and average UI compensation of unemployed
workers, by age, in the calibrated model. Panel (b) reports the average consumption level of employed and unemployed
workers by age.

capital and assets. There is a strong consumption drop upon separation. A proportion of
the income drop is compensated by dissaving, particularly after age 30.
The agent’s key instrument to insure unemployment risk is assets holdings. Understanding its availability and sensibility to the model’s fundamentals is of a first order issue to
determine the need for additional insurance. Figure 5 presents wealth accumulation through
life. Comparing the calibrated economy with net worth data from the Survey of Consumer
Finances, 2007, we find that the average wealth by age closely follows the data, even when
wealth-age profile is not a targeted moment. The figure shows that workers tend to save little
at the beginning of their working lives, and accumulate wealth at a higher pace after the first
ten years of their working life. At the beginning of the working life, savings are determined
by at least two forces. First, workers expect an increase in their labor income because of
human capital accumulation, so they would prefer to borrow. Second, workers face a high
probability of losing their jobs, and for that reason they want to build precautionary savings. These two forces partially compensate each other, generating a mild increase in assets.
Wealth is accumulated until the end of the working life. During these last years, workers
continue to save to finance their retirement, given that pensions would not fully replace their
income. Thus, life-cycle effects introduce several determinants for savings. Savings are not

16

Figure 5: Wealth by age

assets over annual labor income

7
6
5
4
3
2
1
Model

Data

50

60

0
30

40

Age
Notes: The blue solid line reproduces the level of assets by age reported as a ratio over the annual labor income in the
model. The red dashed line reports the per capita net worth by the age of the head of household over the overall annual
labor income from the Survey of Consume Finance, 2007.

only driven by unemployment risk in our model.
The model reproduces most of the observed wealth inequality. The Gini coefficient for
the assets distribution is around 0.68 and for earnings is 0.37 (see Figure 20). The first figure
is smaller than its empirical counterpart (0.75-0.8) while the second is closer to the observed,
0.4-0.45. See for instance Castaneda et al. (2003). The main area where we fail is in the
upper tail of the distributions, top 1%. However, it is well known that the upper tail of
both, income and wealth distributions are mainly shaped by entrepreneurs, and thus highly
dependent on heterogeneous returns to investments (Cagetti and De Nardi, 2006). Since our
focus is on the labor income earners this discrepancy is mostly irrelevant.10
Given our purposes, the left tail of the asset distribution is more important than the Gini
coefficient. Table 2 reports the distribution of assets relative to income for the employed
and unemployed workers, comparing the calibrated economy with the data.11 The model
performs fairly well when compared to total assets. In the literature (Gruber, 2001; Chetty,
2008) it is generally argued that the relevant savings to hedge unemployment risk are liquid
assets. However, we believe this is a lower bound for the achievable insurance. Other, less
10

There could be additional general equilibrium effects. But since entrepreneurs would be unaffected by
UI, the response of aggregate capital to alternative policies would be even smaller, reinforcing our results.
11
We consider the wealth of the unemployed at the beginning of their unemployment spell. We do so to
abstract from unemployment duration components. We compare to results by Gruber (2001) that restricts
the sample to those that are displaced during the SIPP panel (after the first interview and before the second),
what results in an undersampling of long spells.

17

Table 2: Assets distribution: asset holdings relative to annual labor earnings

Unemployed
Model
10th pctile
25th pctile
50th pctile

(1)
0.02
0.22
1.31

Employed

Data
financial total
(2)
(3)
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.20
0.10
1.85

Model
(4)
0.10
0.72
2.39

Data
financial total
(5)
(6)
0.01
0.06
0.05
0.63
0.20
2.36

Notes: The table reports the distribution of assets relative to pre-unemployment net labor earnings for the unemployed
(columns (1) to (3)) and relative to current net labor earnings for the employed. (columns (4) to (6)). In the model,
the wealth of the unemployed is measured at displacement. Data is from SIPP 1984-1992 panels as reported by Gruber
(2001). Financial assets include interest earning assets in institutions, equity, mutual funds, bonds and checking accounts.
Total assets adds retirement savings accounts, homes, vehicles, and personal businesses, and subtracts unsecured debt.

liquid, assets can serve the same purpose. They can either signal good credit worthiness or
being directly used as collateral. Moreover, if the unemployment spell is sufficiently long the
agent can always reduced its holdings of less liquid assets. If these options were not available,
our model would be somewhat overstating the workers’ consumption smoothing possibilities.
In any case, our model generates a substantial measure of liquidity constrained unemployed workers. In particular, about 67% of workers can self-finance (completely replace
wage income) during a typical unemployment spell with their assets. This figure is half way
between the observed figures, which are 75% if total assets are considered and about 50% if
only liquid assets are taken into account (see Gruber (2001)).

4.2

Welfare analysis and decomposition

We now turn to evaluate the welfare effects of changes in the UI system. We follow the
literature and evaluate welfare at birth,
W1 = (1 − u1 )V1e (a = 0, κ = 1) + u1 V1u (a = 0, κ = 1, ψ = 1) ,
where V1e and V1u are the value functions of employed and unemployed workers at age 1, and
u1 (≈ 0.12) is the proportion of unemployed workers at the beginning of their working life.
We report welfare changes in terms of consumption-equivalent variation. In other words,
we compute the percentage change in consumption at all future dates and states required
to make the agent in the benchmark economy indifferent to the reformed economy in steady

18

state. This measure can be computed as:

1 + CEV1 =

W1P
W1B

1
 (1−ω)(1−σ)

(6)

where W1B is welfare in the benchmark economy and W1P is welfare under an alternative
policy. We choose the policy that maximizes welfare as the benchmark for comparison, and
thus CEV should be read as welfare losses due to not implementing the optimal policy.
We also perform a decomposition of welfare losses. For that purpose, we first consider
(i) an increase in benefits, (ii) the corresponding increase in taxes that balance the budget
in partial equilibrium (PE), and (iii) the effect of changing prices. In this last step, we
change taxes accordingly to balance the budget in general equilibrium (GE). The increase
in benefits would be welfare improving, the change in taxes is welfare decreasing, while the
induced change in prices is the GE effect with an ambiguous welfare effect. In each of these
steps, we consider all the behavioral responses associated to all the shocks.
Let W GE (B0 ) be the welfare evaluation of the B0 (ψ) UI policy in GE.12 As a result of the
GE GE
) are generated.
solution to this economy, a set of endogenous variables (τ0GE , n̄GE
0 , w0 , r
PE
Let P0 = {w0 , r0 } be the price vector and W (B0 ; P0 ) be the solution and welfare evaluation
of the same policy in partial equilibrium, using factor prices P0 . From this solution, fiscal
variables F0P E = {τ0P E , n̄P0 E } are endogenously determined to balance the budget. Finally, let
f P E (B0 ; P0 , F0 ) be the solution of the problem under the same UI policy in PE, but without
W
imposing a balanced budget. In this case, taxes and average hours worked are inputs to the
problem.
Our decomposition rests on the following identity,
f P E (B0 ; P GE , F GE ) .
W GE (B0 ) = W P E (B0 ; P0GE ) = W
0
0
In words, if we evaluate the unbalanced partial equilibrium economy in the endogenous
variables that arise in general equilibrium (such as tax rate, average hours worked and factor
prices), we obtain the same results and, thus, the same welfare evaluation as in GE. The
12

Note that in the notation W GE (B0 ) we have skipped the dependency of B on ψ. We do this to avoid
cluttered notation. Nevertheless, the reader should keep in mind that a different B could be either a change
in replacement ratio, in potential duration or in both.

19

decomposition of the welfare gain due to a change from B0 (ψ) to B1 (ψ) can be written as:
benefits effect

z
}|
{
GE
GE
PE
GE
GE
PE
GE
GE
f
f
W (B1 ) − W (B0 ) = W (B1 ; P0 , F0 ) − W (B0 ; P0 , F0 )

(7)

tax effect

z
}|
{
GE
PE
GE
PE
PE
GE
f
f
+ W (B1 ; P0 , F1 ) − W (B1 ; P0 , F0 )
price effect

z
}|
{
PE
GE
GE
PE
GE
PE
f
f
+ W (B1 ; P1 , F1 ) − W (B1 ; P0 , F1 ) .
The total effect of the policy change in general equilibrium can be decomposed as the sum
of three different partial equilibrium effects: the benefits, tax, and price effects. The benefits
effect accounts for the impact of changing the UI system but keeping everything else constant,
including taxes. The tax effect corrects the calculations by the tax change needed to finance
the change in the UI system. The price effect further adjusts the calculations for the price
changes experienced as a result of the change in the UI system. Notice that the sum of the
benefits and tax effects also account for the total effect in partial equilibrium.13 This implies
that the price effect is equivalent to the GE contribution, and encompasses what general
equilibrium adds to the analysis.

4.3

Welfare effects of UI

We now turn to the main results of our welfare evaluations. We evaluate welfare in steady
state for different UI policies. To make sure that we are not identifying a critical point
that is not a global maximum, we compute welfare for a grid of many combinations of
replacement ratios and potential duration. We present the general results and identify the
welfare maximizing policy. We then compare several alternatives to this optimal benchmark,
so that each result should be interpreted as the welfare loss due to being far from the welfare
maximizing UI system. Moreover, in what follows we concentrate mostly on duration values
of at least two model periods. The reason is that in our model the first period is a transfer to
all separated workers, independently of the extension of the unemployment spell. From the
point of view of the worker’s behavior, that type of transfer corresponds more to a severance
pay than to unemployment insurance.
In Figure 6 we present the CEV measure after evaluating the grid in GE. At the origin (no
benefits) there are welfare losses of about 4%. Welfare increases steeply with the replacement
ratio until about 50%, which is the calibrated economy value. After this point, welfare
13

The taxation policy F1P E is consistent with B1 (ψ), in the sense that it balances the budget in partial
equilibrium.

20

Figure 6: Consumption equivalent welfare effects of UI in GE

Notes: The figure plots the consumption equivalent measure (CEV) of welfare comparing each point in the grid of
replacement and potential duration to the welfare maximizing UI (63% replacement ratio and 2 model periods). The plot
is the result of a spline interpolation of the evaluations of a grid of replacement ratios and potential duration.

tends to stabilize and then falls. The fall is moderated when the potential duration is short
(especially at 2 quarters, which is the calibrated duration) and steep when the potential
duration is long (6 quarters or longer UI policies). In our model, long periods of high
replacement ratios (150% for one year and a half, for example) generates a welfare loss of
about 16%. But the same potential duration for a replacement ratio of 50% implies 2%
welfare loss. The maximum welfare is reached at a replacement ratio of 63% and a potential
duration of 2 model periods (six months), that is relatively close to the calibrated economy.
The blue solid line of Figure 7 plots two cuts of the previous function. Panel (a) plots CEV
of changing the replacement ratio with a potential duration constant at 2 model periods. The
welfare maximizing point is at replacement ratio of 63%. The welfare gain from the calibrated
economy is only about 0.2% of permanent consumption, but again, the welfare gain compared
to no-UI is substantial. Panel (b) shows the welfare effects of extending potential duration
while keeping replacement ratio fixed to 50%. It shows that a duration of two model periods
provides the highest level of welfare.
In Table 3 we present the effect of further increasing the generosity of UI from the welfare
maximizing system on several variables. Column (2) shows the effect of increasing the replacement ratio 10 percentage points. Taxes increase from 13% to 14% and both capital and
labor (employed human capital) decrease about 1%. The fall in labor is the result of a reduc21

0.01

0

0

-0.01

-0.01

-0.02

CEV

CEV

Figure 7: Welfare effects of UI in general and partial equilibrium

-0.02

-0.03

-0.03

-0.04

-0.04

-0.05
GE

PE

GE

-0.05

PE

-0.06
0

0.5

1

2

4

6

8

Quarters of potential duration

Replacement Ratio

(a) The effect of the replacement ratio

(b) The effect of potential duration

Notes: The figure plots the CEV of welfare comparing UI systems to the welfare maximizing UI policy (63% replacement
ratio and 2 model periods). Panel (a) sets potential duration to two model periods and shows different replacement
ratios (a grid of replacement ratios is evaluated and the remaining levels are interpolated using a spline). Panel (b) sets
replacement ratio to 50% and shows different potential durations. Blue lines plot cuts of the function presented in Figure 6
and are general equilibrioum (GE) evaluations. Dotted red lines are evaluations in partial equilibrium (PE).

tion in search effort (from 65% to 62% on average), the consequent increase in unemployment
and lower average human capital of the employed, as well a change in total hours worked.
Also, there is a small reduction in wages and a very small increase in interest rate. Column
(4) also shows the same variables when UI potential duration increases to 3 model periods.
Qualitatively, the effects are similar but they are quantitative stronger. Furthermore, the
aggregate capital seems more affected in this case than human capital, leading to a stronger
change in factor prices. Nevertheless, changes in prices are still very small (about 0.1%).
It is worth emphasizing that factor prices are relatively unaffected around the welfare
maximizing policy. (See Figure 21 that provides a more general description of the effect of
UI on the equilibrium variables.) This is a first indication that our environment generates
a drastically different outcome from the previous literature that suggests large general equilibrium effects. For this reason, we now look deeper into the partial and general equilibrium
effects.
Partial and general equilibrium effects. Figure 7 plots the CEV measure for a PE
solution in red dashed lines. In both, panel (a) and panel (b), the welfare effects in PE are
very similar to the ones in GE. In particular, the welfare maximizing policy is practically

22

Table 3: General and partial equilibrium effects of changes in the UI system
Variable
Replacement
Pot.duration
Tax rate τ
Capital K
Human cap. H
Search s
Unemployment
Ratio K/H
Wage w
Int. rate r

Initial
(1)
0.63
2
0.133
171.59
5.87
0.65
0.07
29.22
1.927
0.018

Change in level Change in duration
GE
PE
GE
PE
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
0.73
0.63
2
3
Change in % from the benchmark
6.1
6.1 11.9
11.9
-1.0
-1.5 -2.9
-4.3
-0.8
-0.8 -2.4
-2.3
-5.0
-5.0 -18.6
-18.7
5.3
5.3 28.1
28.1
-0.2
-0.8 -0.5
-2.1
-0.1
0.0 -0.1
0.0
0.1
0.0
0.0
0.0

Notes: The table reproduces the effects of changing UI system in 10 percentage points of replacement ratio, columns (2)
and (3), and one model period of potential duration, columns (4) and (5), from the welfare maximizing UI system. GE:
general equilibrium. PE: partial equilibrium.

indistinguishable between the two. To emphasize this point, we appeal to Table 3 that
presents information related to other variables involved in the previous exercise. Column
(3) reports the main variables of the solution in PE when increasing 10 percentage points
the replacement ratio from the welfare maximizing policy. In this case, capital decreases by
approximately 2%, while human capital is reduced in 1%, leading to a reduction in the capitallabor ratio of less than 1%. This change in the PE capital-labor ratio is what generates a
very small adjustment of factor prices when we allow for general equilibrium effects. In turn,
the fact that wages tend to fall and interest rate tends to rise is what makes the capital-labor
ratio even less responsive in GE. Overall, both solutions are strikingly similar. An analogous
result can be obtained from the increase in potential duration in one additional quarter,
shown in columns (4) and (5).14
Decomposition. Table 4 complements the previous results by performing the welfare loss
decomposition described in equation (7). The next to last column corresponds to an increase
in replacement ratio of 10 percentage points, while the last one corresponds to the increase
in potential duration of one model period.
The increase in the replacement ratio decreases CEV by 0.09% in general equilibrium
and by 0.06% in partial equilibrium. The decomposition provides that welfare changes are
mostly explained by differences in the direct effect of the transfers–the benefits effect– and
14

See Figure 21 for further description of the response of endogenous variables. The PE and GE solutions
are indistinguishable for many of the endogenous variables.

23

Table 4: Welfare gains decomposition
Variable
Replacement ratio
Potential duration

Benchmark/
Tag
0.63
2

Change in UI
Level Pot. duration
0.73
0.63
2
3

Total welfare gains w.r.t. benchmark, CEV in %
General Equilibrium (GE)
-0.09

-1.25

Partial Equilibrium (PE)
Total Welfare Difference, GE-PE (price effect)
Benefits effect
Tax effect

-1.13
-0.12
0.61
-1.73

-0.06
-0.03
0.87
-0.93

Notes: The table reproduces the welfare decomposition of changing UI system in 10 percentage points and one model
period from the welfare maximizing UI system. Welfare gains are decomposed according to equation (7) and transformed
to CEV.

its implications in the government’s tax policy. Interestingly, the general equilibrium effects
that follow from the price change are small, and aids little to explain the differences between
general equilibrium and partial equilibrium effects. The increase in potential duration provides similar results, but multiplied by more than an order of magnitude. The welfare effects
are stronger, leading to an overall welfare loss of 1.25% in GE and 1.13% in PE, with a price
effect of -0.12%. The stronger effects that we find when increasing the potential duration of
the UI system are due to a significantly larger elasticity of the unemployment rate to changes
in duration than to changes in the replacement ratio. As shown in Table 3 an increase of
16% (10/63) in the replacement ratio rises unemployment by 5.3%, so that the elasticity is
around 1/3. Instead, the 50% (1/2) increase in potential duration rises unemployment by
28.3%, which implies an elasticity of almost 0.6. Since the gains due to insurance are similar,
0.9% vs. 0.6%, the larger required increase in taxes to finance the unemployed generates a
substantially larger welfare loss.
Given these results, a natural question arises: what features of the environment generate
the stark difference with the previous literature in general equilibrium? One may be worried
that the UI system is also satisfying other needs. For instance, it could be helping agents to
overcome their impossibility to intertemporally smooth consumption. In Section 6 we show
that this is not the case. Instead, in Section 5 we argue that the mild GE effects are due to
the low substitutability of private savings and public insurance.

24

5

Savings and the optimal UI system

In the previous section we showed that the price effect of changing the UI system is small,
implying that the welfare maximizing UI system in general equilibrium is similar to that
one in partial equilibrium. This is driven by the low sensitivity of the capital-labor ratio.
In this section we single out the model ingredients affecting the way agents react to savings
incentives, and how these feed in to the aggregate wealth distribution, playing a crucial
role in determining the sensitivity of the capital-labor ratio. First, we emphasize the role
of life-cycle effects by eliminating age-dependent features. We use this simplified model to
discuss the relevance of the initial wealth distribution and of the elasticity of aggregate capital
with respect to the unemployment insurance benefits. Second, we show how the model can
generate a substantially different sensitivity of the capital-labor ratio to changes in the UI
system as a result of how these changes affect the agents’ incentives to save and work. In
order to do so, we consider different taxation schemes, as savings rates strongly depend on the
way the UI system is funded. We also show that the sign of the general equilibrium effect–
the price effect–can be positive or negative. That is, whether the general equilibrium model
suggests a more generous UI system than the partial equilibrium model crucially depends on
the sign of the response of capital-labor ratio.

5.1

The relevance of life-cycle

We start by showing that a fundamental feature of our environment is the way workers save
over their life span. To showcase this, we eliminate multiple features of the model that create
heterogeneity across age groups, so that the savings behavior by agents and the equilibrium
wealth distribution resemble those resulting from a model with infinitely lived agents. By
contrasting the results in both models, we argue that the life-cycle profile of savings reduces
the sensitivity of the capital-labor ratio.
Specifically, in this alternative setting we impose finite, but substantially longer lives,
minimizing the resulting age-dependent profiles.15 In particular, we double the number of
periods in the labor market by setting T = 344. We set the death probability to a constant
15

Alternatively, we could solve a standard Aiyagari (1994) economy with infinite lives, and agents subject
to only unemployment risk. We have done so. However, our numerical explorations show areas of stability
issues for some parameters values. The problem arises when the equilibrium interest rate is close to the
discount rate. This happens when there is low (endogenous) risk or high insurance. This problem reduces
the confidence on the results, especially on areas which are of interest. In contrast, maintaining the finite
lives assumption, no matter how large the finite number, preserves the stability for all parameter values.
Some alternative ways to overcome this concern would be: making the unemployment insurance system less
generous, increasing the discount rate, or adding some extra idiosyncratic labor income risk. This last one
seems particularly promising, but would further depart the model from our benchmark, complicating the
analysis and comparison.

25

δj = 0.0047 to get the same expected lifetime than in the calibrated economy16 , and the
survival probability at retirement to δR = 0.008 to double the expected lifetime at retirement.
By setting these numbers, we extend the number of periods in the labor market and, at the
same time, we reduce the importance of retirement: only 20% of each cohort becomes retired.
This is important as we want to mimic a more stationary environment where incentives to
save are kept approximately constant. Retirement is at odds with that purpose, in particular
because retirees rapidly consume their assets. We also eliminate human capital accumulation,
so that the job ladder has only one step, κ = 1, and we set human capital to the average
in our baseline. We eliminate the dependency of the separation rates on age, by setting the
separation rate to a constant 1 − π = 0.044.17
Further, to approximate infinite lives, we allow workers to receive an inheritance at the
beginning of their working lives. To this end, we assume that the wealth distribution at birth
is equal to the wealth distribution of agents that die. Thus, the initial wealth distribution is
endogenous, and will be affected by changes to the UI system. We additionally recalibrate
the discount factor, the pensions level, the utility of leisure, and the search cost parameters.
For that purpose we use indirect inference, where the targets are the capital output ratio
of 2.7, the proportion of time spent at work of 0.34, the pension expenditures over GDP of
6.8%, the unemployment rate of 6.8%, and the elasticity of job-finding rate to UI level of -.32,
the same targets as the baseline economy (see Table 1). We get P = 0.0983, β = (0.9524)1/4 ,
ω = 0.605, γ0 = 0.299, and γ1 = 1.7483.
Figure 8 shows the welfare effects of changing the UI system in the simplified model. The
policy that maximizes welfare in general equilibrium prescribes a replacement ratio of 5%
with two model periods of potential duration. Here, the UI system does not provide much
insurance. The potential welfare gains of moving from the current to the welfare maximizing
policy are approximately 1% CEV. When we analyze the partial equilibrium solution we find
that the welfare maximizing policy is similar to the one in general equilibrium.
Table 5 summarizes the changes in some relevant statistics when the replacement ratio
increases by 10 percentage points above its welfare maximizing level. In general equilibrium
aggregate capital K falls 0.5%, human capital H falls 0.5% and the capital-labor ratio K/L
falls 0.1%. In partial equilibrium K falls 4.2%, H increases 0.2%, and K/L falls 4.4%. As the
table shows, these differences also translate into differences in factor prices in GE: interest
rate increases 0.1% while wages fall 0.03%. Notice how these results differ from those in the
baseline calibration in Table 3, and included in Table 5 as Baseline to ease the discussion.
16

The expected lifetime in our baseline economy is 53 years, which is composed by very high survival rate
during the first 43 years and about 17 additional years of expected lifetime at retirement.
17
This number is consistent to the average monthly layoff and dischargers in JOLTS from 2004 to 2012
(the same period for which we compute the calibrated unemployment rate of 6.8%).

26

Figure 8: Welfare effects of UI in general and partial equilibrium, diminished life-cycle
effects

0

0.01

-0.02

0

CEV

0.02

CEV

0.02

-0.04

-0.01

-0.06

-0.02
GE

PEo

PEc

GE

-0.08

PEo

PEc

-0.03
0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1

Replacement Ratio

2

3

4

Quarters of potential duration

(a) The effect of the replacement ratio

(b) The effect of potential duration

Notes: The figure plots the CEV measure comparing UI systems to the welfare maximizing UI policy in general equilibrium (5% replacement ratio and 2 model periods) for the extension without human capital or other life-cycle effects.
Panel (a) fixes potential duration to two periods and studies the effect of changing the replacement ratio on welfare. Panel
(b) fixes the replacement ratio to 5% and studies the effect of changing the potential duration of UI benefits on welfare.
In both panels, the blue line represents the CEV differences in general equilibrium, the dashed red line represents the
CEV differences in partial equilibrium where prices are consistent with a UI system with 0.5 replacement ratio and two
periods of potential duration, and the dotted red line presents the CEV in partial equilibrium where prices are consistent
with the welfare maximizing UI system.

In the baseline economy, changing the UI system away from the welfare maximizing policy
generates very similar effects in allocations in both general and partial equilibrium. As the
table shows, the same is not true in the economy with no age profiles.
There are two reasons for the larger response of aggregate capital. First, in this extension
there are less incentives to save for retirement. Thus, the contribution of the employment
risk motive to total savings is significantly larger, and therefore, aggregate savings are more
responsive to UI. Second, the initial distribution is intergenerationally linked. Thus, any
initial change in assets is then amplified. To be explicit, the fall in savings would reduce
assets of the currently living. When they die, the drop in assets translates into the initial
assets distribution of newborns. Given that this process continues ad infinitum; the fall in
savings is amplified compared to the baseline life-cycle model.
Table 6 extends the decomposition of welfare changes, introducing the update in the
initial distribution of assets. Again, we increase 10 percentage points the replacement ratio
from the welfare maximizing policy, which is 5%, and compute welfare effects. For the ease
of comparison, the column labeled Baseline reproduces the results of the baseline described
27

Table 5: General and partial equilibrium effects of an increase in replacement ratio of 10
pp from the optimal level, diminished life-cycle effects
Variable
Replacement ratio
Potential duration
Change in %
Capital K
Human capital H
Search effort s
Unemployment
Ratio K/H
Wage w
Int. rate r

Baseline
No life-cycle
GE
PE
GE
PE
0.63 to 0.73 0.05 to 0.15
2
2
-1.0
-0.8
-5.0
5.3
-0.2
-0.1
0.1

-1.5
-0.8
-5.0
5.3
-0.8
0.0
0.0

-0.5
-0.5
-1.7
1.6
-0.1
-0.03
0.1

-4.2
0.2
-1.5
1.5
-4.4
0.0
0.0

Notes: The table reproduces the effects on endogenous variables of changing UI system by 10 percentage points from
the welfare maximizing UI system. GE: general equilibrium. PE: partial equilibrium.

in Table 4. Welfare effects in GE have small negative effects, of 0.03% CEV, while welfare
losses in PE are larger, of -0.6%. Thus, moderating life-cycle effects from the model does
not reduce welfare gains due to GE effects; the most important negative welfare effects are
in PE. To understand them, we follow the decomposition. The uncompensated UI transfer
(UI effect) increases welfare in 0.5%, while the corresponding increase in taxes leads to a
welfare loss smaller in absolute value. From these two effects only, it seems that rising UI
would provide small welfare gains. Nevertheless, when we let the initial distribution of assets
to update, there is a very strong welfare loss of 0.6%: savings and assets are reduced due to
the increase in UI, and this feeds into the initial distribution of assets, inducing a negative
welfare effect. Notice, then, that all the negative welfare effects in PE are driven by this last
effect. The comparison with the baseline, where this effect is not present, is clear.
The GE adds to the previous PE two additional steps: first, we change the factor prices
taking initial distribution of assets fixed as in PE; second, we let the initial distribution of
assets to update. When factor prices change (r increase and w drops) the welfare effect is
negative but small (-0.05% CEV). But this price factor change induces an increase in savings
and initial assets that more than compensates for the price factor change, inducing a welfare
gain of about 0.6% CEV, as reported in the last line of Table 6.
All in all, this alternative environment shows that life-cycle effects are crucial for our
result. While there are many differences with the baseline economy, we want to emphasize
two main effects that are quantitatively important: the distribution of assets among the
unemployed and the elasticity of aggregate capital.
In this extension the initial distribution of assets provides the unemployed a means to
28

Table 6: Welfare gains decomposition of an increase in replacement ratio of 10 pp from the
optimal level, diminished life-cycle effects

Variable
Baseline No life-cycle
Total welfare gains (CEV × 1000) w.r.t. benchmark
General Equilibrium
-0.90
-0.33
Partial Equilibrium
-0.63
-5.79
Difference GE-PE
-0.26
5.46
UI effect
8.74
5.06
Tax effect
-9.29
-4.61
Initial distr. of assets
0.00
-6.21
Price effect
-0.23
- 0.45
Initial distr. of assets in GE
0.00
6.36
Notes: the table reproduces the decomposition of welfare effects of changing the UI system in 10 percentage points from
the welfare maximizing UI system.

smooth consumption. Additionally, given that the income profile is flat, the incentives to
save while young are stronger, and these initial assets are saved. As a result, the assets for the
young are higher, and the overall distribution of assets is less concentrated in lower values.
Panel (a) of Figure 9 shows the histogram of the assets of the unemployed workers at separation, comparing this extension with the baseline economy. In the life-cycle economy more
than 25% of unemployed workers has little or no assets at the beginning of the unemployment
spell. The corresponding proportion for this alternative environment is approximately 2%.
Additionally, in this extension the mode corresponds to more than two years of average labor
income, well above the required savings to finance a typical unemployment spell.
The second difference arising from the elimination of the life-cycle effects is that the
elasticity of capital-labor ratio is higher. Panel (b) of Figure 9 shows capital-labor ratio and
relative prices, r/w. Both axes are in logs. The green line represents the baseline economy
with the calibrated level of benefits, under different relative prices.18 The black line represents
the analogous curve when the life cycle features are muted. The fact that the elasticity of the
relative supply of factors is much lower in our baseline economy compared to the extension
can be readily seen from the slope of these lines.
Figure 10 shows the same axis as in the previous figure. Again, solid lines represent the
capital-labor ratio of the economy with the UI system as in the calibrated economy (50%
replacement ratio for two model periods). In this figure, two additional lines are plotted
18

The curve reports the adjustment of capital-labor ratio to relative factor prices. We consider different
relative factor prices and compute the workers’ problem in PE to get the labor and assets supplied. Taxes
are kept constant at the calibrated level and the government budget is not necessarily satisfied.

29

Figure 9: Assets distribution among the unemployed and elasticity of relative factor supply
-4.6

0.35
Baseline

Extension

0.3

-4.65

0.25

log(r/w)

-4.7

%

0.2
0.15

-4.75

-4.8
0.1
-4.85

0.05

Basline

0
0

5

10

-4.9
3.1

15

initial assets / annual labor income

Extension

3.2

3.3

3.4

log(K/H)

(a) Unemployed wealth distribution

(b) K/H relative supply

Notes: Panel (a) represents the distribution of assets relative to average annual labor income of the unemployed at
the beginning of their spell, comparing our baseline economy and the extension without human capital accumulation or
other life-cycle effects. Panel (b) reports the relative factor supply (in logs) as a function of relative factor prices at the
calibrated system (50% of replacement ratio for two model periods or six months), comparing our baseline (green line)
with the extension without human capital (black dashed line)

for each case. The negative slope (dotted) lines represent the relative demand of factors,
that arise from the first order condition of the firms. In absence of depreciation, this would
represent an elasticity of -1. The point in which the green dotted curve and the green solid
curve intersect represent the relative prices and the relative factors in GE for our baseline
economy, panel (a), and the extension, panel (b). Dashed lines represent the relative supply
of factors in the no-UI case (a replacement ratio of zero). The elimination of UI shifts the
supply curve to the right, implying that the capital-labor ratio increases if relative prices are
kept constant. This can be observed with the help of the dotted black line. The comparison
between both panels shows that the elasticity of capital-labor ratio with respect to UI is
larger when there are no life-cycle effects.
The GE in the no-UI case is found where the dashed line intersect the negative sloped
dotted line. To reach this point, relative prices adjust (interest rate down and wages up),
reducing the capital-labor ratio in equilibrium. The comparison between the two panels again
highlights the large elasticity of supply of relative factors with respect to relative prices in
the extension: only a small change in prices is required to restore the capital-labor ratio in
equilibrium in the extension.
All in all, Figure 10 emphasizes two important points: dropping life-cycle effects induces

30

Figure 10: Relative factor supply and demand

-4.65

-4.7

log(r/w)

-4.65

log(r/w)

-4.6

-4.7
supply (0.5,2)
supply no-UI
demand

-4.75
-4.8
3.3

3.4
3.5
(a) Baseline
log(K/H)

-4.75
supply (0.5,2)
supply no-UI
demand

-4.8

3.4

3.6

3.5
(b) Extension
log(K/H)

3.6

Notes: The figure reports the relative factor supply for different relative factor prices at the calibrated system (50%
of replacement ratio for two model periods or six months) in the solid line, and of no-UI in dashed line, comparing our
baseline (left panel) with the extension with diminished life-cycle effects (right panel). The negative slope dotted lines
represent the relative factor demand in each case.

a higher elasticity of capital-labor ratio with respect to both prices and UI changes.
Along with the previous results, we can emphasize two characteristics of this extension:
there are more assets to the unemployed and there is a stronger response of aggregate capital
to UI. These are also features of the infinitely lived agents models, typically used in the
literature to assess the welfare effects of UI in GE. In a way, this exercise shows the reason
why infinitely lived agents models reject the relevance of UI is not the presence of general
equilibrium effects, but that they generate assets distributions and elasticities that reduce
welfare gains and increase welfare costs of UI, even in partial equilibrium.
One may wonder, what environment is more empirically accurate? First, we argue in
Section 4, the baseline version clearly outperforms in terms of assets distribution the extension
without human capital (see Table 2). This extension clearly generates little insurance needs
among workers. Second, while the information on the elasticity of assets with respect to
benefits is scarce, Engen and Gruber (2001), using 1984-1990 data from SIPP, report that
increasing the replacement ratio 10% would lower broad asset holdings of employed workers
by only 0.4%, implying an elasticity of -0.04.19 We find this same elasticity in our baseline
model when we consider aggregate capital; the corresponding elasticity in the extension without
human capital is much higher. In a proper infinitely lived agent this elasticity would be even
higher.20
19

The paper reports several effects of UI on assets, but this is the more closely related to our exercise.
This can be observed in Young (2004) where the elasticity seems very high: without price changes
eliminating UI would increase aggregate assets by 63%. Also, in Koehne and Kuhn (2015) the elasticity is
20

31

5.2

Heterogeneous discount factors

Our results so far show that the distribution and the elasticity of assets are crucial to understand the welfare effects of UI. In particular, when life-cycle effects are mitigated, the model
fails to reproduce the relevance of liquidity constraints of the data and increases elasticity of
assets to levels empirically implausible, rendering UI worthless.
The literature has used heterogenous discount factors to generate larger dispersion in asset
accumulation. As an example, Mukoyama (2010) extends one of the versions of the infinitelylived agents models by introducing stochastic discount factors.21 With this heterogeneity,
that model generates more wealth dispersion and is able to reproduce a Gini of 0.8 (instead
of 0.32 of the model with homogeneous discounting). In spite of this change in wealth
dispersion, the results are qualitatively unchanged compared to the homogeneous case.
We now turn to evaluate up to what extent the introduction of heterogeneous discount
factors in our extension could lead to a wealth distribution more in line with the data and fix
the issues that arise when we abstract from the life-cycle effects. Additionally, we compute
the welfare maximizing policy and compare it with previous results.
For that purpose, we extend the environment described in subsection 5.1 by introducing
two types of workers, with low or high discount factor, βl and βh , respectively. These types
are randomly assigned at the beginning of the life. The other characteristics do not differ:
both types begin their working life with the same chances of being unemployed and the same
initial distribution of wealth. We calibrate these discount factors to maintain the aggregate
capital-labor ratio and to generate an initial distribution of assets among the unemployed
similar to the one in our baseline calibration. We consider this target more adequate for our
purposes and more comparable to our baseline economy than the Gini of the overall wealth
dispersion. On the whole, we set βl = (0.945)1/4 and βh = (0.967)1/4 .
The left panel of Figure 11 plots the initial distribution of assets with this calibration. The
black dashed line shows that, when we consider heterogeneous discount factors, more than
25% of the unemployed workers are liquidity constrained (close to the borrowing limit) at the
beginning of their unemployment spell. This high proportion of unemployed workers with
little wealth to self-smooth consumption can increase the social value of UI. For comparison,
we also plot the same distribution in our baseline economy.
The left panel of Figure 12 shows the CEV of different replacement ratios in this extension,
setting potential duration to two model periods. Both the partial equilibrium and the general
-1. While the exercises are not completely comparable, these responses illustrate the high elasticity in the
infinitely lived agent model.
21
Discount factors are governed by a three-state, first-order Markov process. The calibration in that paper
is set so that 10% of the population are affected by the high level discount factor and 10% by the low level.
The expected duration within these extreme values is 50 years in that model.

32

Figure 11: Assets distribution among the unemployed and elasticity of relative factor supply
with heterogeneous discount factors
-4.6
0.35
-4.65
0.3
-4.7

log(r/w)

0.25

%

0.2
0.15

-4.75

-4.8

0.1
0.05

-4.85

0
0

5

10

15

20

25

Basline

-4.9
3.1

initial assets / annual labor income
Baseline

Extension

Extension

3.2

3.3

3.4

log(K/H)

(a) Unemployed wealth distribution

(b) K/H relative supply

Notes: Panel (a) represents the distribution of assets relative to average annual labor income among the unemployed at
the beginning of their spell, comparing our baseline economy and the extension without human capital accumulation and
heterogeneous discount factors. Panel (b) reports the relative factor supply (in logs) as a function of relative factor prices
at the calibrated system (50% of replacement ratio for two model periods or six months), comparing our baseline (green
line) with the extension without human capital and heterogeneous discount factors (black line)

equilibrium evaluations indicate that the welfare maximizing replacement ratio is low. The
plot is very close to the one presented in Figure 8 and the optimal level is not substantially
different. Also, the CEV welfare gains from the calibrated economy to the optimal level of
benefits are similar.
The right panel of Figure 12 shows the CEV of changing potential duration setting the
replacement ratio fixed to a level close to the welfare maximizing policy. Again, this plot is
similar to the one with homogeneous discounting.
Table 7 shows the effects of increasing the replacement ratio 10 pp. from the welfare
maximizing level of 5%. For the ease of comparison, we reproduce the results of the homogeneous discounting case. The increase in UI reduces both capital and labor by 2.4% and
0.1%, respectively. The change in capital labor ratio in PE leads to a small change in factor
prices in GE.
Table 8 provides the decomposition of welfare gains when the replacement ratio increases
10 pp from the welfare maximizing replacement ratio, comparing the economy with homogeneous discounting to the stochastic discount factor case. We find similar results for both
cases. The main difference between the two cases is that with stochastic discounting the

33

Figure 12: Welfare effects of UI in general and partial equilibrium, diminished life-cycle
effects and heterogeneous discount factors
0.01
0.01
0
0

-0.02

CEV

CEV

-0.01
-0.01

-0.03
-0.02
-0.04
-0.03
-0.05
GE

PEo

PEc

GE

-0.06

PEo

PEc

-0.04
0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1

Replacement Ratio

2

3

4

Quarters of potential duration

(a) The effect of the replacement ratio

(b) The effect of potential duration

Notes: The figure plots the CEV comparing UI systems to the welfare maximizing UI policy in general equilibrium (5%
replacement ratio and 2 model periods) for the extension with diminished life-cycle effects and heterogeneous discount
factors. Panel (a) fixes potential duration to two periods and studies the effect of changing the replacement ratio on
welfare. Panel (b) fixes the replacement ratio to 5% and studies the effect of changing the potential duration of UI
benefits on welfare. In both panels, the blue line represents the CEV differences in general equilibrium, the dashed red
line represents the CEV differences in partial equilibrium where prices are consistent with a UI system with 0.5 replacement
ratio and two periods of potential duration, and the dotted red line presents the CEV in partial equilibrium where prices
are consistent with the welfare maximizing UI system.

Table 7: General and partial equilibrium effects of an increase in replacement ratio of 10
pp from the optimal level, extensions with diminished life-cycle effects and heterogeneous
discount factors
Variable
Replacement ratio
Potential duration
Change in %
Capital K
Human cap H
Unemployment
Ratio K/H
Wage w
Int. rate r

Homog. discount Het. discount
GE
PE
GE
PE
0.05 to 0.15
0.05 to 0.15
2
2
-0.5
-0.5
1.6
-0.1
-0.03
0.10

-4.2
0.2
1.5
-4.4
0
0

-0.5
-0.5
1.7
-0.1
-0.02
0.08

-2.4
-0.1
1.5
-2.1
0
0

Notes: The table reproduces the effects on endogenous variables of changing UI system by 10 percentage points from
the welfare maximizing UI system. GE: general equilibrium. PE: partial equilibrium.

effects of the initial distribution of assets are smaller in absolute value.
34

Table 8: Welfare gains decomposition of an increase in replacement ratio of 10 pp from the
optimal level, extensions with diminished life-cycle effects and heterogeneous discount factors

Variable
Homog. discount Het. discount
Total welfare gains (CEV × 1000) w.r.t. benchmark
General Equilibrium
-0.33
-0.99
Partial Equilibrium
-5.79
-3.3
Difference GE-PE
5.46
2.3
UI effect
5.06
5.58
Tax effect
-4.61
-4.91
Distribution of assets PE
-6.21
-3.94
Price effect
-0.45
-0.33
Distribution of assets GE
6.36
2.9
Notes: the table reproduces the decomposition of welfare effects of changing the UI system in 10 percentage points from
the welfare maximizing UI system.

The results discussed above show the paradoxical finding that, even when the distribution
of assets among the unemployed change dramatically, the UI does not seem to gain social
value. There are several mechanisms that can explain these facts. First, it is important to
bear in mind that lowering the discount factor reduces the incentives to accumulate assets,
and changes many other decisions at the same time. For example, for given state variables,
a lower discounting induce higher consumption and, through the standard income effect,
lower hours worked. Also, the incentives to search are reduced for given state variables.
Furthermore, the job-finding elasticity with respect to UI increases substantially. These
changes are apparent in the agent’s policy functions. They contribute, directly or indirectly,
to reduce the welfare gains of UI. These observations suggest that heterogeneous discount
factors are effective to increase the importance of liquidity constraints at the calibrated
economy but also change important aspects of the economy.
A second important point is that the elasticity of assets, both to UI and to prices, is still
very high. The right panel of Figure 11 shows that the capital-labor ratio elasticity is much
higher than the one of the baseline. The elasticity in this extension is slightly lower than the
one with homogeneous discounting, but the change in capital is still very strong.
This issue turns out to be very important. A high elasticity of capital implies that any
reduction in benefits induces a strong response on savings, and shifts the distribution of
assets to the right. Of course, the changes in assets have in these extensions a direct effect
on welfare: workers begin their life with more assets whenever there is balanced-budget
reduction in UI. This affects the welfare value of UI (see the welfare effects of the initial

35

distribution of assets in PE in Table 8.)
In other words, given that the assets’ elasticity is still very high, liquidity constrained
unemployed still exist in the economy at the calibrated level of UI. However, with lower
levels of UI, savings increase so much that liquidity constrained workers are reduced. In this
sense, public insurance gets compensated with private savings. This result emphasizes the
importance of the assets’ elasticity. If this elasticity is (too) high it is not enough to get the
initial distribution of assets right.
A third point to emphasize is that the heterogeneity in discount factors also implies an
heterogeneity in the valuation of future transfers. A low discount factor reduces the welfare
effects of future conditional transfers such as UI; thus, from the point of view of an impatient
employed worker, UI has little value. To illustrate this point we analyze the savings decisions
of workers.
Figure 13 plots the median asset level of employed workers at j = 160 as a function
of initial assets. The green solid line represents agents with high discount factors in the
calibrated economy. Those workers increase assets as of that age compared to initial asset
level. The black solid line represents the low discount workers. These assets are in all cases
very low. When impatient workers begin their working life with substantial amount of assets
(equivalent to 10 years of annual average income, for example) they deplete their wealth
progressively so that at j = 160 they only have about one quarter of average income. If born
without assets, workers with high discount factor save up to three years of average income
while workers with low discount factor save up to a quarter of income; this means that they
continue to be asset poor the whole working life.
In Figure 13 dashed lines represent the no UI case (when UI replacement ratio is set close
to zero). Impatient workers born without assets save more when they do not have UI, but
just above half a year of average income. The assets holdings at j = 160 are lower for the
patient workers. This is because with no UI r is lower (the capital-labor ratio is larger than
in the calibrated economy).
All in all, Figure 13 suggests that workers with low discount factors decide to be asset
poor. Their priority is current consumption (of both goods and time); the future outcomes,
such as the possibility of becoming unemployed, are less relevant for their current welfare.
Thus, UI transfers will be also less relevant for the welfare of the employed impatient worker.
In a nutshell, the introduction of heterogeneous discount factors allows a more accurate
calibration of wealth dispersion, but at the cost of introducing many other changes directly
related to the valuation of UI transfers or indirectly to its social costs. Additionally, this
setup does not address the issue of the elasticity of assets. If this elasticity is (too) high it is
not enough to get the initial distribution of assets right.

36

Figure 13: Median assets at j = 160 as a function of assets at j = 1 by worker type

assets over income j=160

15
10

2.5

0.5
0.25

h

0

5

l

h

10

no UI

15

l

no UI

20

25

assets over income j=1
Notes: The figure plots the median assets normalized by aggregate annual income at j = 160 as a function of normalized
initial assets, comparing workers with high and low discount factors. Solid lines represent the calibrated economy; dashed
lines represent the economy without UI.

5.3

The role of savings responses

In our baseline economy, an increase in the capital-labor ratio generates welfare gains through
the price effect. The most obvious reason is that an increase in wages will benefit agents. At
the beginning of their lives, workers have no assets and can only earn labor income. Hence,
an increase in wages would clearly improve their welfare. Because the production function
exhibits complementarity between capital and labor, an increase in the capital-labor ratio
increases wages.
Since the only effect of GE is through prices (with the behavioral responses associated
to them), the positive link between wages and the capital-labor ratio is a convenient feature
that helps us clarify the GE effect. Moreover, because workers are born with no assets, the
sign of the price effect is transparent in our model. We use this feature to show that GE
effect could be positive or negative, according to the response of capital-labor ratio to UI.
The response of savings strongly depends on taxes. We now change how taxes are collected
to allow for different results. To this end, we consider two different extensions. In the first
extension, government expenditures are financed 80% by proportional taxes to labor income
and 20% by an additional tax on capital income, τk . This extension would generate a stronger
response of savings to UI. In our second extension, government expenditures are financed 50%
by proportional taxes to labor income and 50% by a lump-sum tax at the end of working
life, T , up to a maximum (equivalent to half of the assets at the end of working life). In this

37

case, a more generous UI would affect savings less than in the baseline model.
We focus on the difference between PE and GE in the welfare analysis. To be clear, we
do not intend to show the convenience of introducing these changes in taxes, but rather to
use them to induce different responses of aggregate capital-labor ratio to UI in PE.
Results Figure 14 shows the capital-labor ratio under different replacement ratios setting
the potential duration to two model periods. For convenience, we reproduce the baseline
economy, panel (a), and we plot the alternative sources of taxation in panel (b) and (c). The
dotted red lines are the solutions in PE. There is a clear contrast between the three cases.
The capital-labor ratio is almost constant in the baseline economy, decreasing in the economy
with capital tax and mostly increasing in the economy with lump sum taxation.
The intuition for the reduction in the ratio due to capital taxation, Panel (b), is that a
more generous UI requires a rise in both labor and capital income taxes, reducing not only
the means to accumulate assets, but also the incentives. In contrast, in the economy with
lump-sum taxes, Panel (c), the capital-labor ratio is increasing. When UI increases labor
taxes rise less compared to the baseline economy, but now the workers must pay a large
lump-sum tax upon retirement. This implies that the worker must save to cover this future
expected tax. These three different responses of capital-labor ratio in PE generate different
GE effects.
In Figure 15 we plot the CEV for different UI replacement ratios under three scenarios:
the baseline in Panel (a) (same as Panel (b) of Figure 7), the economy with capital taxes,
Panel (b), and the economy with a lump-sum taxation, Panel (c). The potential duration is
maintained in two model periods, which is the optimal potential duration in all cases. The
figure plots CEV evaluated in PE in the dotted red line and in GE in the solid blue line.
In the baseline, PE and GE evaluations are almost indistinguishable, delivering almost
the same optimal replacement ratio. In the economy with capital income taxes, Panel (b),
the GE effect evaluated at the optimal policy is negative. This implies that any increase in
the replacement ratio would yield a higher welfare gain in PE than in GE. This can be seen
in the difference between the slopes in the figure: the PE slope is higher than the GE slope.
Consequently, in the welfare maximizing GE evaluation, when the slope in the figure is flat,
the PE evaluation still yields welfare gains. The optimal replacement ratio is thus higher in
PE (71%) than in GE (63%). The reason for this result is that an increase in UI generosity

38

Figure 14: Capital-labor ratio under different tax arrangements
34
30

30

28

28

26

26

33

K/H

K/L

K/L

32

24

24

22

22

20

20

31

30

29
GE

0.4

PE

0.6

0.8

PE

GE

0.4

Replacement Ratio

0.6

28
0.6

1

0.8

Replacement Ratio

(a) Baseline

PE

GE

0.8

1

1.2

Replacement Ratio

(b) Capital tax

(c) Lump-sum tax

Notes: Equilibrium capital-labor ratio from changing replacement ratio, fixing potential duration to two periods. Panel
(a) is baseline economy, panel (b) is the extension with capital tax, and panel (c) the extension with a lump-sum tax.

Figure 15: Welfare effects of UI replacement ratio under different tax arrangements
5

10-3

10-3

5

-5

-5

-5

CEV

0

CEV

0

CEV

0

-10

-10

-10

-15

-15

-15

GE

-20
0.4

PE

0.6

GE

-20
0.8

10-3

5

0.4

Replacement Ratio

PEo

0.6

PEc

0.8

GE

-20
1

0.6

Replacement Ratio

(a) Baseline

PEo

0.8

PEc

1

1.2

Replacement Ratio

(b) Capital tax

(c) Lump-sum tax

Notes: The figure plots CEV of changing replacement ratios fixing potential duration to two model periods. Panel (a)
reproduces Figure 7. Panels (b) and (c) show extensions with capital and lump-sum tax, respectively. The dashed line
labeled P Ec is CEV in PE with prices fixed to the calibrated economy (replacement ratio =50% and potential duration=2).
The P Eo line is CEV in PE with prices fixed to the optimal policy, 63% replacement ratio in Panel (b) and 88% in Panel
(c).

Figure 16: Welfare effects of UI potential duration under different tax arrangements
0.01

0.01

implies0 a fall in the capital-labor ratio, inducing a negative GE effect.
0

0

-0.01

-0.01

-0.03

CEV

-0.02

CEV

CEV

-0.01

-0.02

-0.03

-0.04

-0.03

-0.04
GE

-0.04

PE

GE

-0.05

PEo

PEc

GE

-0.05
1

2

3

Quarters of potential duration

(a) Baseline

4

-0.02

PEo

PEc

-0.05
1

2

3

Quarters of potential duration

(b) Capital tax

4

1

2

3

4

Quarters of potential duration

(c) Lump-sum tax

Notes: The figure plots the CEV of changing UI potential duration while setting replacement ratios constant and close
39 additional notes to Figure 15.
to the welfare maximizing replacement ratio in each case. See

Table 9: General and partial equilibrium effects of an increase in replacement ratio of 10
pp from the optimal level, extensions with different tax arrangements
Variable
Replacement ratio
Pot.duration
Change in %
Capital K
Human cap. H
Search s
Unemployment
Ratio K/H
Wage w
Int. rate r

Baseline
Capital tax Lump-sum tax
GE
PE GE
PE
GE
PE
(1)
(2) (3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.63 to 0.73 0.63 to 0.73
0.88 to 0.98
2
2
2
-1.0
-0.8
-5.0
5.3
-0.2
-0.1
0.1

-1.5
-0.8
-5.0
5.3
-0.8
0.0
0.0

-1.6
-0.8
-4.8
5.2
-0.8
-0.2
1.0

-7.0 -0.8
-0.2 -1.4
-4.7 -14.7
5.1 10.8
-6.8
0.6
0.0
0.2
0.0 -0.7

0.8
-1.5
-14.7
10.9
2.4
0.0
0.0

Notes: The table reproduces the effects of changing UI system in 10 percentage points from the welfare maximizing
system for the baseline economy (columns (1) and (2)), for the extension with capital tax (columns (3) and (4)) and for
the extension with a lump-sum tax (columns (5) and (6)).

Instead, when the UI is partially funded with lump-sum taxes at the end of the working
life the GE effect is positive. This means that the welfare gains in PE are lower than in GE.
This can be observed from the slopes of the figure. At the optimal GE replacement ratio,
the slope of the PE welfare function is negative. This means that the replacement ratio
that maximizes welfare in PE (89%) is lower than in GE (95%). The reason for this is that
capital-labor ratio increases with a more generous UI.
Figure 15, panels (b) and (c), reproduce two PE welfare evaluations. The first one,
labeled P Ec , uses factor prices of the calibrated economy. The second one, labeled P Eo , uses
factor prices in the welfare maximizing GE replacement ratio. This last, crosses the GE line
in its maximum. An important feature of these two PE welfare evaluations is that they are
approximately parallel. This implies that the initial price at which we evaluate PE economies
does not change the welfare maximizing policy.
For completeness, in Figure 16 we present the analogous to Figure 15 but keeping fix
the replacement ratio and moving potential duration. In the baseline economy, welfare gains
in PE and GE are similar and almost indistinguishable. With taxes to capital income the
welfare gains in PE are clearly higher than the gains in GE. Finally, with lump-sum taxes
upon retirement, welfare gains in GE are higher than those in PE. This could be appreciated
when changing potential duration from 1 to 2; for longer potential durations the difference
is minor.
In Table 9 we provide information about some endogenous variables due to an increase

40

Table 10: Welfare gains decomposition of an increase in replacement ratio of 10 pp from
the optimal level, extensions with different tax arrangements

Variable

Baseline Capital tax Lump-sum tax
(1)
(2)
(3)
Total welfare gains (CEV × 1000) w.r.t. benchmark
General Equilibrium
-0.90
-0.98
-2.45
Partial Equilibrium
-0.63
0.79
-3.54
Difference GE-PE (price effect)
-0.26
-1.78
1.09
UI effect
8.74
8.49
9.07
Tax effect
-9.29
-7.57
-12.38
Notes: The table reproduces the welfare decomposition of increasing UI replacement ratios in 10 percentage points from
the welfare maximizing system, comparing the baseline economy, column (1), the extension with capital income tax,
column (2), and the extension with a lump-sum tax, column (3).

in the replacement ratio, to complement Figure 14. For the ease of comparison, columns (1)
and (2) reproduce the results for the baseline economy. Columns (3) and (4) show the results
for the economy with capital taxes. Comparing these two, the large difference between GE
and PE is evident. The reduction in aggregate capital is 7% in PE, while the decrease in
human capital is 0.2%. There is, thus, a substantial reduction in the capital-labor ratio of
6.8% in PE. This large substitutability between private and public insurance leads to a large
change in prices, increasing the net return to capital in 1% and decreasing wages in 0.2%, in
general equilibrium. Columns (5) and (6) show the results for the economy with a lump-sum
tax. In this case, on the contrary, an increase in UI replacement ratio induces a rise in the
capital-labor ratio of about 2.4% in PE, generated by a decrease in human capital of about
1.5% and an increase in aggregate capital of 0.8%. In GE, thus, price changes have the
opposite sign: wages increase (0.2%) while net returns to capital go down in 0.7%.
The discrepancy in the elasticity of the capital-labor ratio reflects in important differences
between the welfare evaluations of the partial vs. general equilibria. Table 10 presents
the welfare decomposition exercise when replacement ratio increases 10 percentage points.
Column (1) reproduces the decomposition in our baseline economy, while column (2) and
(3) presents the results for the extensions. As described above, the difference between GE
and PE welfare gains are negative (-0.18% of CEV) when there are taxes to capital income,
and are positive (0.1% of CEV) when there is a lump-sum tax at the end of the working life.
These difference are the price effect, that depends on the capital-labor ratio.

41

6

Robustness

We have shown our main conclusions through our life-cycle model. In our baseline economy,
GE and PE evaluations do not differ much around the calibrated UI policy and the welfare
maximizing UI is close to the current policy in both GE and PE. So far we have restricted
the planner to use only a replacement ratio and potential duration. Thus, the planner has
not enough instruments. For example, we do not let the planner to choose age-dependent UI
(Michelacci and Ruffo, 2015), or condition UI to assets (Koehne and Kuhn, 2015).
A concern could be that the planner might be using UI to make transfers to the young
and, in this way, smooth consumption through life, ameliorating the effects of liquidity constraints. Given that young workers have higher unemployment risk, a higher UI would be
an intergenerational transfer. To address this concern, we consider two extensions. In the
first extension we eliminate the possibility of intergenerational transfers by balancing the
UI budget by age: UI transfers for age j are financed by a labor income tax for workers of
the same age. In the second extension we eliminate the life-cycle income profile by setting
age-dependent taxes, while keeping the benchmark UI system, flattening the income profile.
Note that in both cases we use age-dependent taxes, but in the first case tax rates are higher
for the young and in the second tax rates are negative for the young, see Figure 17. We focus
on whether the welfare maximizing UI policy changes compared to the baseline model.
The welfare maximizing policy does not change much: the potential duration is again
two model periods and the replacement ratio is slightly above the calibrated one. Figure 18
shows the CEV of different replacement ratios for two quarters of potential duration. Panel
(a) shows the CEV for the economy in which UI budget is balanced by age; panel (b) shows
the CEV for the economy in which net labor income profile is flat. In both cases, the welfare
maximizing policy is close to 50% (56% in panel (a) and 53% in panel (b)). As in the baseline,
the GE and PE evaluations do not differ much.
Both cases appear to be similar in shape and at their maxima. Nevertheless, the welfare
gains are lower in panel (b). For example, the no-UI welfare loss is close to 4% in panel
(a) and 2.5% in panel (b). The main difference between the two cases is that when the
labor income is constant in age, workers save earlier in life. Thus, they can more effectively
self-smooth consumption during the unemployment spell. At the same time, this behavior
generates a distribution of assets that is less connected with the data, with fewer liquidity
constrained workers. All in all, these exercises show that our results are not driven by a
planner using UI to attain intergenerational transfers: when we eliminate this possibility,
through a budget by age, or we erase differences in average labor income by age, the main
results are maintained.

42

Figure 17: Age-dependent tax rates
0.17

0.3
0.2

0.16

0.1
0.15

tax rate

tax rate

0
0.14
0.13

-0.1
-0.2
-0.3

0.12
-0.4
0.11

-0.5

0.1

-0.6
30

40

50

60

30

40

Age

50

60

Age

(a) Balanced budget by age

(b) Constant profile of net labor income

Notes: The figure plots the age dependent tax rates for the robustness cases in which UI for a given age is financed by
taxes to employed workers of the same age, panel (a), and in which age dependent taxes are set to provide a constant
profile of net labor income, panel (b).

0.005

0.005

0

0

-0.005

-0.005

-0.01

-0.01

-0.015

-0.015

CEV

CEV

Figure 18: Welfare effects of UI under age-dependent taxes

-0.02

-0.02

-0.025

-0.025

-0.03

-0.03

-0.035

-0.035
GE

-0.04
0

0.2

0.4

PEc

0.6

GE

-0.04
0.8

1

0

Replacement Ratio

0.2

0.4

PEc

0.6

0.8

1

Replacement Ratio

(a) Balanced budget by age

(b) Constant age profile of net labor income

Notes: The figure plots the CEV of changing UI replacement ratios setting potential duration to two model periods in
the two robustness exercises (see additional notes to Figure 7.)

43

7

Conclusion

This paper evaluates the welfare effects of unemployment insurance in general equilibrium
using a life-cycle model. With our quantitative model, calibrated to the US economy, we have
shown that unemployment benefits provide important welfare gains. The welfare maximizing
policy is moderately more generous than the current one. We obtained similar results for the
evaluation in general equilibrium and in partial equilibrium, when factor prices do not adjust.
Additionally, we provided a decomposition of welfare gains that shows that the price effect is
relatively small in our baseline model. It follows that the general equilibrium effects do not
necessarily impose strong welfare costs – as the literature seems to suggest. Life-cycle effects
provide two relevant features: the distribution of assets among the unemployed reproduces
the importance of liquidity constraints of the data and the response of aggregate capital to
benefits is weakened. We discussed some extensions of the model to show these features.
The elimination of human capital accumulation and the endogenous provision of initial asset
as coming from legacies – among other changes – reduce the relevance of life-cycle effects
and at the same time eliminate most of the welfare impact of unemployment insurance. Two
crucial features of this extension are that the distribution of savings are such that there are
few asset-poor unemployed workers, reducing insurance needs, and that aggregate capital
responds strongly to unemployment insurance, increasing costs of providing insurance.
The focus of this paper was the economic mechanisms that savings and capital introduce
in general equilibrium. But in the broader literature, there is another important general
equilibrium effect. The search externalities and congestion effects in matching models can
alter the welfare effects of unemployment insurance and other policies related to job-search
decisions. The possible interaction between the two effects is an avenue of future work.

44

References
Abdulkadiroglu, Atila, Burhanettin Kuruscu, and Aysegul Sahin, “Unemployment
Insurance and the Role of Self-Insurance,” Review of Economic Dynamics, July 2002, 5
(3), 681–703.
Aiyagari, S. R., “Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving,” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 1994, 109(3), 659–684.
Alvarez, Fernando and Marcelo Veracierto, “Search, self-insurance and job-security
provisions,” Working Paper Series WP-98-2, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 1998.
and , “Severance payments in an economy with frictions,” Journal of Monetary Economics, June 2001, 47 (3), 477–498.
Baily, Martin Neil, “Some aspects of optimal unemployment insurance,” Journal of Public
Economics, 1978, 10 (3), 379–402.
Birinci, Serdar and Kurt See, “Labor Market Responses to Unemployment Insurance:
The Role of Heterogeneity,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics forthcoming.
David E. Bloom and David Canning and Richard K. Mansfield and Michael
Moore, “Demographic change, social security systems, and savings,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 2007, Vol. 54, 92-114.
David E. Bloom and David Canning and Michael Moore, “Optimal Retirement with
Increasing Longevity,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 2014, 116 (3), 838-858.
Andrea Bonfatti and Selahattin Imrohoroglu and Sagiri Kitao, “Aging, Factor Prices
and Capital Flows,” USC Working Paper. 2019.
Borella, Margherita and Mariacristina De Nardi and Fang Yang, “The Effects of
Marriage-Related Taxes and Social Security Benefits,” Working Paper 23972, National
Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, October 2017.
Cagetti, Marco and Mariacristina De Nardi, “Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and
Wealth,” Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 114(5), pages
835-870, October 2006.
Castaneda, Ana and Javier Diaz-Gimenez, and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull, “Accounting
for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth Inequality,” Journal of Political Economy, August 2003,
111 (4), 818–857.
Chetty, Raj, “Moral Hazard versus Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Political Economy, 2008, 116 (2), 173–234.
Clementi, Gian Luca, and Hugo A. Hopenhayn, “A Theory of Financing Constraints
and Firm Dynamics.,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2006, vol. 121, no. 1, 2006, pp.
229–265.
45

Dora L. Costa, “The Evolution of Retirement: Summary of a Research Project,” American
Economic Review, August 1998, Vol 88 n. 2, 232-236.
Engen, Eric M. and Jonathan Gruber, “Unemployment insurance and precautionary
saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2001, 47 (3), 545–579.
Gruber, Jonathan, “The Wealth of the Unemployed,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 2001, 55 (1), pp. 79–94.
Hansen, Gary D and Ayse Imrohoroglu, “The Role of Unemployment Insurance in an
Economy with Liquidity Constraints and Moral Hazard,” Journal of Political Economy,
February 1992, 100 (1), 118–142.
Hopenhayn, Hugo A and Juan Pablo Nicolini, “Optimal Unemployment Insurance,”
Journal of Political Economy, 1997, 105 (2), 412–38.
Hopenhayn, Hugo A. and Juan Pablo Nicolini, “Optimal Unemployment Insurance
and Employment History,” Review of Economic Studies, 2009, 76 (3), 1049–1070.
Koehne, Sebastian and Moritz Kuhn, “Should unemployment insurance be assettested?,” Review of Economic Dynamics, July 2015, 18 (3), 575–592.
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr, “Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the
Macroeconomy,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 106, no. 5, 1998, pp. 867–896.
Landais, Camille, “Assessing the Welfare Effects of Unemployment Benefits Using the
Regression Kink Design,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, November 2015,
7 (4), 243–278.
, Pascal Michaillat, and Emmanuel Saez, “A Macroeconomic Approach to Optimal
Unemployment Insurance: Theory,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, May
2018, 10 (2), 152–181.
McGrattan, Ellen R. and Richard Rogerson, “Changes in hours worked, 1950-2000,”
Quarterly Review, 2004, 28 (Jul), 14–33.
Michelacci, Claudio and Hernán Ruffo, “Optimal Life Cycle Unemployment Insurance,”
American Economic Review, 2015, 105 (2), 816–59.
Mukoyama, Toshihiko, “Understanding the welfare effects of unemployment insurance
policy in general equilibrium,” 2010, (286).
, “Understanding the welfare effects of unemployment insurance policy in general equilibrium,” Journal of Macroeconomics, 2013, 38 (PB), 347–368.
Popp, Aaron, “Unemployment insurance in a three-state model of the labor market,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2017, 90 (C), 142–157.
Schwartz, Jeremy, “Unemployment Insurance and the Business Cycle: What Adjustments
are Needed?,” Southern Economic Journal, January 2013, 79 (3), 680–702.
46

Setty, Ofer, “Unemployment Insurance and Unemployment Accounts: The Best of Both
Worlds,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 03 2017, 15 (6), 1302–1340.
Shavell, Steven and Laurence Weiss, “The Optimal Payment of Unemployment Insurance Benefits over Time,” Journal of Political Economy, December 1979, 87 (6), 1347–62.
Shimer, Robert, “Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment,” Review of Economic
Dynamics, April 2012, 15 (2), 127–148.
and Ivan Werning, “Liquidity and Insurance for the Unemployed,” American Economic
Review, 2008, 98 (5), 1922–1942.
and , “On the Optimal Timing of Benefits with Heterogeneous Workers and Human
Capital Depreciation,” Working Papers 12230, National Bureau of Economic Research
2006.
and , “Reservation Wages and Unemployment Insurance,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2007, 122 (3), 1145–1185.
Shourideh, Ali and Maxim Troshkin, “Incentives and Efficiency of Pension Systems,”
Working Paper, Carnegie Mellon University, 2017.
Wang, Cheng and Stephen Williamson, “Moral hazard, optimal unemployment insurance, and experience rating,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2002, 49 (7), 1337–1371.
Young, Eric R., “Unemployment insurance and capital accumulation,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, November 2004, 51 (8), 1683–1710.

47

Appendix
A

Appendix of figures
Figure 19: Mortality rates by age

mortality rate

0.02

0.01

0
30

40

50

60

70

80

Age
Notes: Mortality rates of the model. Up to age 65 these rates are computed from Social Security Administration data;
from then on a constant rate is set to reproduce 17 years of life expectancy.

48

1.0

1.0

0.8

0.8

wealth (%)

wealth (%)

Figure 20: Assets and wages distribution

0.6
0.4
0.2

0.0

0.6
0.4
0.2

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

population (%)

population (%)

Gini area
Perfect equality line
Lorenz curve

Gini area
Perfect equality line
Lorenz curve

(a) Assets

(b) Wages

1.0

Notes: The figure reports the Lorenz curve of the assets, panel (a), and wages, panel (b), in the calibrated model.

49

Figure 21: Endogenous variables in GE and PE

(a) w

(b) τ

(c) Unemployment

(d) K

(e) H

(f) Ratio

Notes: The figure plots endogenous variables in GE (blue solid lines) and PE (red dotted lines) for different UI systems,
characterized by replacement ratios and potential durations. Panel (a) reports wages as a ratio to the wage in the
calibrated economy.

50

B
B.1

Calibration
Human capital

We calibrate the human capital function h(κ) and the probability of moving up the labor
capital ladder χ̂ by matching the empirical return to experience function. As it is standard in
the labor literature we postulate a regression that relates wages with experience, educational
attainment, and some controls correlated with ability,
X
X
ln wi,j =
αj Ij + αx′ Xi + βtci +
ακ′ Iκ + εi,j , εi,j ∼ N (0, σ)
(8)
j

κ∈K

where wi,j denotes the wage of individual i at time j, tci denotes individual i time spent in
college, Iκ is a dummy variable for each experience level κ, and Ij is a dummy for each year.
Notice that we are not imposing a functional form for the return to experience. Instead, our
non parametric specification allows each experience level to affect wages in a different way.
We run this regression using data from National Longitudinal Survey of the Youth 1979 and
we present the results of the estimation in Table 11. To use the regression results to back out
h(κ) notice that in the model the hourly wage is wh(κ) so that equation (8) can be rewritten
as
X
X
ln hi,j (κ) =
αj Ij + αx′ Xi + βtci +
αl′ Il − ln w + εi,j , εi,j ∼ N (0, σ) ,
j

l≤κ

so that the human capital function implied by the data is
h(κ) = e

B.2

P

l≤κ

αl I l

(9)

Search cost function

We calibrate the search cost function to the unemployment rate and to the elasticity of
job-finding rate with respect to UI benefits. For that purpose we compute the elasticity
in the model as follows. First, we consider an increase of 10% of benefit level in a partial
equilibrium economy maintaining the tax rate constant. We measure the change in the search
effort (job-finding rate) in partial equilibrium for each state variable and we aggregate this
change using the distribution of unemployed workers of the baseline economy. We think
that this exercise is more in line with elasticities estimations that arise from comparing
changes in benefits for some eligible UI recipients only, such as those analyzed by Landais
(2015). The elasticities presented in that paper are the result of exploiting regression kink
methods for different states of the US. This method compares the unemployment duration
of eligible UI unemployed workers within the state in a given period. Thus, this elasticity
can be interpreted as a purely labor supply decision, with no role for general equilibrium or
macroeconomic effects.22 Second, we focus only on the effect on the first period job-finding
rate. We do this because the response of job-finding rate is key in the periods in which the
worker is eligible, and less relevant afterwards.
22

We use the result in Table A4, third column, which we consider an intermediate level of those reported
within Landais (2015).

51

Table 11: Returns to experience

ln wi,j

coefficient

standard error

0.142
0.202
0.269
0.332
0.350
0.388
0.425
0.440
0.468
0.474
0.498
0.527
0.527
0.558
0.578
0.576
0.600
0.586
0.600
0.615
0.637
0.647
0.677
0.682
0.690
0.721
0.737
0.745
0.781
0.761
0.781
0.786
0.803

0.016
0.016
0.016
0.016
0.016
0.016
0.017
0.017
0.017
0.018
0.018
0.019
0.019
0.02
0.021
0.022
0.022
0.023
0.023
0.024
0.025
0.025
0.026
0.026
0.027
0.027
0.028
0.029
0.030
0.032
0.035
0.037
0.044

0.216
-0.071
0.072
0.112
YES

0.004
0.004
0.001
0.018

Yearly experience
2nd year
3rd year
4th year
5th year
6th year
7th year
8th year
9th year
10th year
11th year
12th year
13th year
14th year
15th year
16th year
17th year
18th year
19th year
20th year
21st year
22nd year
23rd year
24th year
25th year
26th year
27th year
28th year
29th year
30th year
31st year
32nd year
33rd year
34th year
Controls
male
minority
time in college tc
i
constant
Year dummies
R-squared
# of observations

0.166
48491

Notes: The coefficients are the result of estimating equation (8) with data from the NLSY79. We trimmed the data in
the following way: we dropped all the observations for agents which did not have at least 10 observed wages and whose
average wage is in the lowest or highest 5 percent of the average wage distribution. We look at wages of individuals that
graduated from high-school between 1977 and 1992 and for which we have at least 10 observations of wages. We further
trimmed the data to discard individuals which average wages where either in the lowest or highest 5 percentile of the
average wage distribution. Our wage data starts in 1979 on an yearly basis until 1991 and then bi-yearly until 2010.

C

Measures

Let 1 (a′ = a) be an indicator function which takes the value of one if a′ = a.

52

The measures Xje (a, κ), Xju (a, κ, ψ), X R (a) solve the following system of equations,
Z Z

X R (a′ )
1 − δT
=
XTe (a, κ)1 a′ = aej (a, κ) dadκ
1 − δR
1 − δR

Z Z Z

u
′
u
+
XT (a, κ, ψ)1 a = aj (a, κ, ψ) dadκdψ
Z

+ X R (a)1 a′ = aR (a) da
Z
u

Xj+1
(a′ , κ + 1, 1)
= (1 − πj ) Xje (a, κ + 1)1 a′ = aej (a, κ + 1) da
1 − δj
Z
u
′

Xj+1 (a , κ + 1, ψ + 1)
=
[1 − sj (a, κ + 1, ψ)] Xju (a, κ + 1, ψ)1 a′ = auj (a, κ + 1, ψ) da
1 − δj
X1u (0, 1) = 1 − π0
X1u (a, 1) = 0 for a > 0
Z
e

Xj+1
(a′ , κ + 1)
= πj χ (nj (a, κ)) Xje (a, κ)1 a′ = aej (a, κ) da
1 − δj
Z

+πj [1 − χ (nj (a, κ + 1))] Xje (a, κ + 1)1 a′ = aej (a, κ + 1) da
Z Z

+
sj (a, κ + 1, ψ)Xju (a, κ + 1, ψ)1 a′ = auj (a, κ + 1, ψ) dψda
X1e (0, 1) = π0
X1e (a, 1) = 0 for a > 0
For the previous equations, we have assumed that agents are born with no assets and
that a proportion 1 − π0 begin their working life without a job.

D

Numerical Algorithm

Given any policy rule B(ψ), fix a equally spaced grid A = [a1 , a2 , ..., aN a ] of points for
assets. Here we set a1 = 0, aN a = 50 and N a = 1500. Fix a grid for human capital
H = [h1 , h2 , ..., hN h ]. With h1 = 0.25, N h = 10. Each hi for i = 2, ..., N h is generated using
the Mincerian equation. Finally fix a tolerance level ϵ > 0 sufficiently small. These are the
parameters of the algorithm and are kept fixed throughout. Then, choose a capital-labor
ratio R0 and total government expenses Ψ0 . Then.
Step 1 Given R0 compute the implied wage, w, and interest rate, r, using the firm’s first order
conditions. Then, given prices we can solve the problem of the retired agent. This is
done using the standard value function iteration method. The solution to this problem
generates a value function V r (a) and a policy function a′r (a).
Step 2 Given factor prices and Ψ0 compute the tax, τ , that makes the government budget
constraint hold with equality.

53

Step 3 Given τ , r, w and V r (a) we solve the employed and unemployed problem by backward
induction. In this step is important to notice that the optimal search effort depends
only on the continuation utilities. That is, taking first order conditions we obtain


γ0
ŝ(j, h, a , ψ) = 1 −
e
u
′
β(1 − δj )[Vj+1 (a , h) − Vj+1
(a′ , h, ψ + 1)]
′

1/γ1

Since the solution to this equation does not guaranty that s ∈ [0, 1] we choose
s(j, h, a′ , ψ) = min{max{ŝ(j, h, a′ , ψ), 0}, 1}
Note that this is not the optimal search effort yet, since it depends on a′ and not on a. It
only says how much effort the agent would exert contingent on saving a′ . However, we
can replace the above equation in the value function of the unemployed agent reducing
the dimensionality of the maximization problem. Once we performed the maximization
we obtain a′u (j, h, a, ψ) and therefore the optimal search effort is given by,
s∗ (j, h, a, ψ) = s(j, h, a′u (j, h, a, ψ), ψ)
Finally, the employed agent problem generates a′e (j, h, a, ψ)
Step 4 Given a′e (j, h, a), a′u (j, h, a, ψ), a′r (a) and s∗ (j, h, a, ψ) we compute the measures using
the laws of motions of Section 2.4. Once the measures has been computed we calculate
aggregate workers capital, K ′ , aggregate labor, L and total government expenses Ψ1 .
′

ent

and check distances. If |R0 − R1 | < ϵ stop:
Step 5 Given K ′ and L compute R1 = K +K
L
solution found. Otherwise set R0 = ϕR1 + (1 − ϕ)R0 , for some ϕ ∈ (0, 1) and Ψ0 = Ψ1 ,
and go to Step 1.

54