The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
Working Paper 76-2 THE NOTIVATION FOR BANK HOLDING COMPANY ACQUISITIONS Walter A. Varvel Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond February 1976 The views expressed here are solely those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. THE MOTIVATION FOR BANK HOLDING COMPANY ACQUISITIONS Walter A. Varvel* I. Introduction The commercial banking system in this country has undergone an unparalleled consolidation movement since the mid-1960's. Bank holding companies (BHCS) have been active since the turn of the century, yet they have become an important force in the banking structure only since 1965 l The phenomenal growth in the number of corporations that hold stock in one or more banks and the increased concentration of banking resources in such entities have prompted much discussion and a wealth of analytical studies of the potential impact of this development on the nation's financial system. Central to many of these studies has been the question of how acquisition by a holding company may affect the performance of an acquired commercial bank. Related to this issue, and often confused with it, is the question of the motivation for such acquisitions. The latter question has yet to be adequately answered. Most efforts to explain the economic basis for bank holding company acquisitions have evolved from a framework designed to measure the resulting impact on the community served by an acquired bank. Attention has been centered on the consistent findings that the profitability of a bank has not been improved, relative to similarly situated independent banks, through acquisition to an extent that would clearly justify *This paper is based on the author's unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, "The Acquisition of Commercial Banks by Bank Holding Companies: A Valuation Approach," Texas A & N University, 1975. acquisition by a wealth-maximizing bank holding company. But conclu- sions based on measurements of bank profitability alone ignore the possibility that owners' claims oneamings streams are altered signi- ficantly by the transaction. This paper examines the hypothesis that the incentives for acquisition lie primarily in potential benefits accruing to owners, i.e., shareholders, who have claims on the earnings streams of the two firms involved. The framework for the analysis centers on a comparison of the valuation of expected future earnings streams for both sets of stockholders under the alternative assumptions, first, that the acquisition is not consummated and second, that it is consummated. Rational behavior implies that owners will exchange claims to earnings only..if they value those received'more than those released. Subsequent sections will investigate the motivation for acquisition from both theoretical and empirical constructs. Some Previous Evidence Among efforts to establish the existence of a "valuation disparity" sufficient to justify a BHC acquisition have been those by Thomas Piper and Steven Weiss. ' In a study of acquisitions during the period 1947 through 1967, Piper argued that the economic incentives for acquisitions of banks "center on the resultant changes, both in the cash flows and earnings of the acquired banks and in the valuation of these cash flows" [14, p. 981. He emphasized the importance of comparing the value of $iper's analysis of bank acquisitions [14] and his subsequent work with Weiss [15] clearly recognized that an alteration in ownership positions resulted from acquisitions. Their consideration of this point was an important shift from concentration on bank performance alone. . 3 alternative ownership interests. For the acquisitions studied, Piper compared the value received by the stockholders of the bank being acquired with the value they relinquished and found that the value of the claims bank stockholders obtained was significantly greater than their previously held claims on the bank. 2 In fact, the ratio at which the holding company stock was exchanged for that of the bank was so favorable to the bank's shareholders that a careful examination of possible earnings differentials between the firms was not necessary. The market values of the stocks have been an adequate (albeit imperfect) gauge of this differential. A much closer look, however, is necessary when trying to explain why BHCs have been willing to pay such premiums. Piper's original study and his later work with Weiss shifted emphasis from the valuation of the stocks traded in the acquisition to the profitability of acquisitions to the stockholders of the parent holding company. Each study concluded that, due to the high premiums paid for bank stock, acquisitions have failed to improve the earnings of the holding companies. The shift from valuation to profitability, however, begs questions concerning the manner in which owners value a given income stream. A valuation framework that includes a constant discount rate, adjusted for expectations of risk, rules out any possibility that the manner in which earnings are valued may change in response to the operating policies and earnings performance of the firm. While such 2Piper's results showed that the market value of BHC stock received exceeded the book value of the bank by 30 percent. In his later study with Weiss, comparing the claims on holding company earnings received by former stockholders of the acquired bank relative to earnings of the bank stock, the median premium was found to be 16 percent. 4 an assumption greatly simplifies the analysis, it ignores a potentially important source of the valuation disparity underlying the incentives for the acquisition of commercial banks.by BHCs; i.e., changes in owners' discount rates due to their evaluation of risk.3 Valuation Via A Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate The most widely used model for valuing risky, multiperiod earnings streams is.the risk-adjusted discount rate. Through this technique, a measure of the magnitude of the earnings flow, usually expected value, is evaluated by a-discount rate that takes into account the rate of time preference and some measure of the degree of riskiness associated with an earnings flow. Individuals must make estimates of future earnings and apply a subjectively determined discount rate to them. Since this approach is not based on any specific assumption as to what constitutes the risk associated with expected earnings, it has serious shortcomings. Unless a specific, dynamic measure of risk is incorporated within the framework, the detection of differences in valuation due to differences in risk is not possible. In order to measure the effect on valuation of an acquisition, knowledge of the pre-acquisition capitalization rate and the response of that rate to the acquisition is required. It is entirely possible that the addition of another income stream with a different discount rate may alter owners' capitalization rates in subsequent periods. 31f owners are concerned with more than just the mean level of earnings, and a measure of risk does affect their discount factor(s), a reduction in the risk associated with a given earnings distribution will reduce the discount factor if owners are risk averse and result in a higher valuation of those earnings. Comparison of earnings means alone will not detect this disparity. 5 A specific present value of earnings cannot, however, be derived without information concerning owners' attitudes toward risk and the trade-off they are willing to make between risk and return. This becomes a serious stumbling block in the search for the motivation for acquisition, but it need not be insurmountable. sets of investors involved in any acquisition: shareholders and those of the BHC. There are two distinct the independent bank Each group obtains a claim on an earnings stream that is somewhat altered from its previous holdings. The acquisition is beneficial if the capitalized value of the transformed earnings stream is greater than that the stockholders perceive would have been available through holding on to their existing claims. A change in this valuation through a shift in capitalization rates, then, could result from either a shift in the investor's measure of risk following the acquisition or the manner in which a given change in risk'affects his capitalization rate. Since the individuals making the valuation comparisons have not changed, it seems reasonable to assume, for simplicity, that the exact form of the capitalization rate function in terms of risk does not change.4 As long as an increase (decrease) in the measure of risk faced by owners is reflected in an increase (decrease) in the discount factor used to evaluate an earnings stream, emphasis may be placed on the expected behavior of risk under alternative situations. If it is assumed that a detected 4For a discussion of the dependence of the form of an individual's capitalization rate function in the presence of uncertainty on the form of his underlying utility function, see Douglas Vickers, Chapters 2 and 4. Vickers suggests that the capitalization rate function is nonlinear in the coefficient of variation of net income and concave upward. 6 difference in the measure of risk results in different capitalization rates, valuation disparities may be sought by comparing alternative earnings performances and 'measures of risk. I These comparisons are made in Section IV of this paper. The Basis For Acquisition The suggested approach for analysis of the economic basis for acquisition is founded upon the premise that the firm that engages in banking determines its operating and organizational structure on the basis of optimization of the economic value of the ownership of the firm, i.e., the owners' wealth position. Owners' wealth is perceived *as the capitalized value of the expected future earnings stream. Since the objective to be maxim$zed is in value terms, specific attention must be given to its components. In general terms, V = IT/P,where V, TT,and p represent, respectively, value, profit, and the owners' capitalization rate (which is adjusted for considerations of time preference and risk). The essential consideration of the analysis for bank owners is the difference in the valuation of their ownership position if they (a) continue their present structure of organization and production as opposed to (b) trading thefr bank stock for partial interest in a . holding company. For BHC owners, it is the difference in the valuation of their ownership claims perceived through (a) the present BHC structure and (b) the expanded organization created through acquisition. The first disparity provides an incentive for the present bank owners to make the transaction, while the second provides the incentive for holding 7 company acquisition activity. The purchase price of the bank stock, usually in terms of a stock-exchange ratio, is then determined by the relative bargaining power of the buyer and sellers and the degree of competition in the buying and selling of bank equity. Regardless of the measure of risk utilized, acceptance of the proposition that owners' conceptions of risk may change over time and may be altered by specific actions of the firm has important implications for the risk-adjusted discount rate and may significantly alter valuation of the earnings accruing to owners. The provision of a dynamic capitalization rate (p), which is a function of the risk associated with a given earnings stream, provides a valuation framework that considers both the earnings experience and the behavior of the d&scounting function used by owners in evaluating their ownership position. (1) In present value terms, H v3 c =t t-l Pt where V is the present value of the future earnings stream to owners, rt is net earnings on owners' equity in period t, pt is the owners' capitalizationrate applied to earnings in period t, and H is the economic horizon of ownership in the firm. In this framework, valuation disparities may be sought for both sets of participants in the transaction--the bank stockholder and the shareholder of the BHC. 5The owners' discount rate in period t (pt) may be further specified: = (l+rl) (l+rZ) . . . (l+rt-1) (l+rt), where rt is dependent on the Pt owners' time preference pattern i (assumed constant) and an appropriate measure of risk, e.g., the coefficient of variation of net income (Vn), which is the standard deviation of the probability distribution of expected net incomes divided by the mean of the probability distribution function. p, then, may also be expressed as functionally dependent on these same variables: p = p(i, Vn). 8 Bank owners will have an incentive to trade their stock only if a valuation disparity is established between the capitalized value of the stream of bank profits accruing to owners through continued ownership in the bank and that,realizable from gaining an ownership interest in the holding company. Specifically, they have an incentive to trade their stock for that of a holding company only if: cvHC where VB is the ownership valuation of the bank, c1is the share in the total ownership of the holding company obtainable by bank owners, and VHC is the total ownership valuation of the BHC. The bank owners' valuation of their portion of holding company earnings will, in this case, be greater than their valuation of expected bank earnings. Pre- vious findings, in terms of this framework, suggest that CLhas been large enough to assure the necessary disparity in valuation of earnings. Similarly, an incentLve for holding company acquisitions exists on the demand side ,for bank stock only if present company stockholders view a similar valuation 'disparity. In particular, only if the acquisition of a commercial bank improves the capitalized value of owners' earnings over that perceived without acquisition will present owners move to acquire the bank, i.e., only if: (3) (vH&~ = t&t/P t>-B < &(++)B = B(vHC)B 9 where(VHc)-Bis the ownership valuation of the holding company without acquiring the bank, B is the proportion of ownership interest in the company retained by present owners (B = l-a), and (VHc)B is the capitalized value of the earnings stream of the holding company including the proposed acquired bank. Even though their percentage ownership (13)falls with an acquisition, present owners may still benefit if earnings increase significantly -- if risk, and, therefore, the vector of owners' capitalizaor tion rates following acquisition - reduced. is For an acquisition to occur, then, both valuation disparities must exist. The present owners of an independent bank and of a holding company will agree to participate in an exchange of stock if each group perceives a positive shift in its ownership valuation resulting from the transaction. Equations (2) and (3) represent the conditions necessary for consummation of an acquisition agreement. nowhere in Of particular interest is the fact that (3) is there any implication that the bank's.profitability must be increased following acquisition. If the owners are assumed to maximize the value of their ownership position, they will be concerned with the valuation of their share of the holding company rather than that of a single subsidiary. It may be that factors such as the structure of organization, production considerations, and costs that optimize the economic valuation of the consolidated company's earnings stream conflict with the attainment of the maximization of one of its subsidiaries' returns. Such an hypothesis is consistent with empirical results here- tofore obtained that suggest that bank profitability is not significantly enhanced through holding company affiliation. 10 In fact, if it is recognized that the acquisition of a bank may have a positive impact on the level and/or stability of earnings of . other subsidiaries within a BHC organization, consideration of changes in bank profitability is an inadequate tool with which to examine the economic basis for acquisition. It is essential that the analysis con- sider both the earnings experience and associated expectations of risk of each ownership position. An examination of both levels of alternative earnings and the manner in which those earnings are valued is necessary before conclusions may be reached. II. Components of the Valuation Framework Within our generalized valuation framework (V = r/p), it is essential to carefully specify each of its components, i.e., (a) the firm's profit function, and (b) the capitalization rate function as perceived by the firm's stockholders. Profit Function Each period's profits are determined by the difference between revenue generated form the firms product markets and the costs asso- ciated with their production. Revenue To allow for varying degrees of demand elasticity, then, the demand conditions in the ith product market are represented by Pi = P (qi); i = 1, 2, product markets. . . ., n; n is the number of distinguishable These show the relation between the alternative 11 supplies of output and the price the firm can charge. The firm can influence the price of at least some of its products by varying its production. With negatively sloped demand curves, the firm can only sell more of a good by lowering its price. Hence, dPi/dqi < 0; except in those markets that may be represented by pure competition. Revenue is defined as (qi)41 , and marginal revenue is the change in revenue as output changes: MRi = (dPi/dqi)qi. Marginal revenue is, for all but the perfectly elastic demand curves, less than price. The purely competitive product markets are special cases of the more general representation. The revenue function of independent banks and holding companies can be expected to differ. Banks are effectively limited to several specific loan, investment, and service categories and frequently further restricted to geographic markets. A holding company has a much wider, diverse scope of product and geographic markets in which it may operate. Cost Conditions The firm (bank or holding company) purchases the services of fixed assets (building, equipment, etc.) and incurs the direct costs of labor services (salaries). In addition, it must pay interest costs on the various forms of money capital (funds) obtained. These include debt capital (Kd), equity capital (K,), demand deposits (DD)--paid in the form of services rendered, time and savings deposits (TD), and other borrowing sources (B) such as the Federal Reserve discount window, federal funds, etc. The interest cost on equity is in the form of net earnings accruing to owners. 12 In addition, the firm must bear other costs that under an administrative cost heading. may be summarized Within this category, we include expenditures on the replacement of management (search costs, direct training or orientation costs, and the loss of realizable returns or foregone earnings incurred during the training period). Also, the delegation of authority from owners to a smaller management group that arises under the corporate structure requires stockholders to incur costs to insure that management is acting in the owners' best interests. These "monitoring costs" result from "team production" where the marginal products of cooperating inputs are not separably observable. Alchian and Demsetz argued that this phenomenon allows input "shirking" that can be detected only by observing the behavior of individual inputs-which is not costless. The search costs (Cg) for management replacements are a function of the number of replacements that must be found (R) and the expenditure on information on candidate capabilities (I,) necessary before the choice may be made. There will be some direct training cost (CT) involved with a new employee as well as indirect costs associated with on-the-job training that may be represented by the foregone earnings (Ef) that could have been realized during the training,period had the original employee not left. Each of these is dependent on the number of replacements necessary (R) and the level of firm production (Q). During this period of training it should be expected that the marginal productivity of labor will be diminished somewhat. Monitoring costs (CM) are a function of the number of employee replacements (R) it is necessary for owners to supervise, the information on management capabilities available to the 13 owners (I,), the degree the incentives of management (TM) have been made to correspond with that of the owners--i.e., the degree to which management returns are linked to the returns to the firm (salary, bonuses, fringe benefits, stock options, etc.), and the aggregate level of firm production (Q). The administrative cost function (0) may be represented, then, as follows: (4) 0 = 8 [Cs(R, I,>, CT@, Q) , Ef (R, 9) , C& I,, IM, Q) 1 where ae/ac,, ae/ac,, ae/aEf, ae/ac, > 0; acS/aR, ac,/az, > 0; acT/aR, acT/aQ > 0; aEf/aR, aE,/aQ > 0; acM/aIc9 acM/aIM < 0; and as/a& acM/aQ > 0. To complete the representation of the firm's cost function, it is necessary to include expenditures on the provision of various supportive business services (C,) and costs of providing additional labor support programs or fringe benefits (C,) incurred by the firm. Many independent banks must rely on other banks or firms to provide such items as computer facilities, data processing and analysis, investment counseling, and other management services. These are frequently provided through a correspondent relationship with a large bank. In addition to explicit payments for some services, the bank maintains correspondent balances on deposit with other banks. These funds are not available to generate loans and investments for the original bank but can be used by the correspondent as any of its other deposits. A full account of expenditures on these business services, then, must include the opportunity cost (in the form of reduced revenue) associated with their provision. Such expenditures are assumed dependent on the bank's level of 'production,Q. 14 A holding company, on the other hand, usually provides these services internally. The parent company, either itself or through one of its subsidiaries, will meet the different needs of the organization and its affiliates. these services. Typically, the bank will be charged directly for What is unique about the holding company, however, is that what is a cost for the user of these services is a revenue for another subsidiary. The payment for these services is not lost, there- fore, but merely transferred within the company. As is frequently the.case, established holding companies operate at a scale where such services are already produced within the company structure (by one of its large banks or nonbank affiliates). The large initial costs of establishing these services (computer facilities, research staff, building, etc.) have already been sunk. The decision criterion becomes the marginal cost of providing such services to one more customer. If this is less than the price of purchase from an outsider, the holding company's earnings are enhanced. Most previous studies of holding company acquisitions and investigations of bank profitability ignore the fact that these payments are simply a transfer from one subsidiary to another and, therefore, do not affect the ownership valuation of the holding company itself. These transfers allow potential cost savings from internal provision of business services. The level of expenditures on fringe benefits for employees (insurance programs, retirement plans, conveniences, etc.) is considered to be a variable under the control of the owners and subject to their 15 manipulation and perception of what its appropriate level should be. It will be argued that owners authorize expenditures in these areas in an effort to increase the retention of present employees (and thereby reduce necessary search and training costs and foregone earnings associated with replacing personnel) and to increase management loyalty to owners (reducing owners' monitoring costs). Specifically, it will be posited that, optimally, owners will incur these costs until the value of these expenditures is just offset by the value of the expenditures saved in the above areas. Labor is very much concerned with the explicit payment for its services. If labor is also assumed to maximize the present value of its future earnings (wage and benefits stream), the chance for advancement to higher paying jobs must affect labor's behavior, The holding company, through its usual policy of promoting from within, offers a wide range of higher paying positions with increased responsibility that add lustre to the organization. The small independent bank cannot do the same. There are relatively few top positions attainable through the process of management succession. As a consequence, banks frequently have trouble securing and retaining qualified people. They have no comparable incentive to provide extensive fringe benefits as do larger holding companies. Such expenditures may not significantly enhance the retention of personnel. The cost function of the firm for each period, then, may be represented by: (5) c = ylF + y2N + rd (Kd/K,, G) Kd + rDDDD i- rTDTD + rgB + e[Cs(R, ICI + CT@, + ‘+(Q) + CF Q) + Ef(R, Q) + CM@, I,, IM, Q)I b 16 where: Yl' Y2¶ rDD' rTD, and rB are the direct costs associated with fixed assets (F), labor services (N), demand deposits (DD), time and savings deposits (TD), and other borrowings (B), respectively. They are assumed exogenously determined either in competitive markets or by regulatory authority. rKdis the COSt Of debt capital (Kd), a function of the debt/equity ratio (Rd/R,) and of a measure of the.degree of product and geographic diversification (G) attained by the firm. Combining the firm's revenue and cost functions, then, gives the profits generated during each period: (6) n = izlP (Qi) Qi - C where n is the number of distinguishable product markets in which the firm operates. The Capitalization Rate Function The firm's capitalization rate is a function of both the time preference pattern of owners and the level of risk that owners associate with any given stream of earnings. In examining this capitalization rate function, it will be assumed that owners' time preference patterns are identical and constant. Any change in capitalization rates, there- fore, must result from shifts in owners' evaluation of risk conditions following a holding company acquisition. As a measure of the level of risk perceived by the firm, this study utilizes the coefficient of variation (V,) of net income expectations. This measure is computed by dividing the standard deviation of the 17 distribution of net incomes by its expected value. It is a ratio, there- fore, describing the relative variability of a set of numbers. . the risk due to variability of earnings flows. V, measures From the definition of the coefficient of variation, V, = an/E(N); or, since net income (NJ equals net operating income (0) minus the total interest paid on debt capital (rKdKd)' andassuming on = ~0: (7) v, = a0 E (0)-qKd where E(0) is the expected value of net operating income and a0 is the standard deviation of net operating income. The coefficient of variation is dependent on the elements on the right hand side of (7). The debt capital supply cost will be assumed to be a function of both the debt/equity ratio @d/K,) and a proxy for the level of product and geographic diversification (G) of the firm: (8) %d = rKd (Q/K,, G) where arKd/a(Kd/Ke) > 0 and aq,/ac c 0, that is, as the debt/equity ratio rises so does the interest cost of debt capital and as the measure of diversification of the firm's product market increases, the cost of debt capital falls. This last result assumes that potential lenders view the risk associated with the placement of debt capital to be reduced if the firm expands the scope or location of its operations. A holding company structure, with production in a wider range of product markets than allowed commercial banks and, except possibly where statewide branching is allowed, a greater geographic dispersion of activities,may expose the total organization to less risk. Earnings variations at individual banks and nonbank 18 subsidiaries tend to cancel out unless a strong positive correlation exists between profit performances. Profit variability between a com- pany's bank affiliates may offset each other due to the extension of loans across a wide geographic area or to a wide range of borrowers. The variance of the profits associated with combining activities a and b may be representedby:ai+b = ai + 62 + 2ro,cb; where r is the correlation coefficient (-1 5 r 5 1). This equation states that the variance of the firm's profits is equal to the sum of the variance of the profits of the separate activities plus the covariance between them. As Hall suggested, the-combination of disparate.activities leads to less total variance and thereby to less total risk. This 'reduced risk through risk-spreading' can be expected to occur unless a strong positive correlation between the profits exists. or negative correlations will reduce variance. 6 Independence Hall does, however, caution that the closer the 'linkages among activities--the less important are the advantages of risk spreading. The functional representation of the coefficient of variation is given by: (9) vn = Vn (00 E(O) 9qd(Kd/Kes G)) where avn/aao > 0, av,/aE(o) <-0, avn/a(Kd/Ke> > 0, aV,/aG c 0. 6Adleman argued that additional profit centers resulted in larger samples and greater stability of profits. A perfect negative correlation between two activities (1:= -1) would completely eliminate variability (assuming CJ$= CJ~and n1 = "2) while zero correlation would result in a reduction in the standard error of the mean from a;; to ax* 1 19 The capitalization rate is, therefore, also seen to be a function of the standard deviation of net operating income, the expected value of net operating income, the level of the debt/equity ratio (or leveraging) of the firm, and the degree of diversification of the firm's activities. (10) = P P(i, Vn>; i = ii P = P(Ts 00, E(O), Kd/Ke, G) where ap/aco > 0, ap/aE(o) c 0, ap/aKd/K, > 0, ap/aG < 0. For convenience, assume that bank owners' patterns of time preferences are identical with each other and with those of holding company stockholders. Therefore, any change in the coefficient of variation of net income will have a positive impact on the owners' capitalization rate and will affect the owners' valuation of the firm's earnings stream. An increase in the degree that the firm is diversified may have an important impact on the capitalization rate. Specifically, at a constant debt/equity ratio, increased G may reduce the coefficient of variation (through effect onrKd or uO),which should reduce p. its Increased diversi- fication may, on the other hand, allow the firm to make greater use of debt without adversely affecting its capitalization rate and offsetting potential gains from financial leveraging. The determinants of the coefficient of variation of net income as postulated provide insight into this question: V, = V,(uO, E(O), Kd/Ke, G). Totally differentiating yields: % (11) dV, = e" aVn + aE(O)'(') avn ava + a(Kd,Ke)d(Kd'Ke) + 2' - 20 For the moment, assuming that the expected value and standard deviation of net operating income are held constant, we may see the relationship between the debt/equity ratio and measure of diversification that must hold for any given value of the coefficient of variation of net income. For dx, dE(O), dag: aV,/aG > 0; since aVn/a(Kd/Ke) This positive relationship is reflected d(K$d av,/aG c 0 and aVn/a(Kd/Ke) > 0. 3 - in Figure 1. The acquisition of a commercial bank by a holding company will increase the firm's degree of diversification from G0 to Gl. The acquisition it- self (through.an exchange of stock) adds equity capital and immediately reduces the firm's debt/equity ratio to (Kd/Ke)l. only at a reduced value for V, (Vi). This is maintainable If the firm decides to expand its use of debt capital to the original debt/equity ratio, it still must be accompanied by a lower Vn (Vi) than the original position. Unless the impact of increased diversification is offset by either an increased standard deviation associated with net operating income (u0~$) or a decreased expected value of operating income (E(O)CE(O>~), the coefficient of variation (V,) and, therefore, the firm's capitalization rate (p) should decline through the acquisition activity. It is evident that increased diversification may allow the firm to utilize a much higher debt/equity ratio, to(Kd/K,)',atthe original values of Vn, uo, and E(0) and, therefore, p. This opportunity is not available to bank owners. Since commercial banks are restricted by-regulation in the degree of diversification into 0 . additional product and geographic markets they may attain, they may (e ( m--m-- .-----Be--- / .--------- / / ------ -- m------- / / FIGURE 1. FINANCIAL LEVERAGE, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE COEFFICIENT OF VARIATION OF NET INCOME 21 realize a similar decline in Vn only through a direct reduction in along GoGo, reduced uo, or an increase in E(0). Q/K, Another useful relationship to be examined within this context is that between G and uo. duo/dG = - aV,/aG aV, aa0 , o For dTn, dE(O), and d(Kd/Ke): -- 1 / As mentioned previously, the acquisition of a commercial bank by'a holding company increases the firm's measure of diversification (Go to G1 in Figure 2). in u0' It is unlikely, however, that this results in an increase As a matter of fact, it may reduce uo. coefficient of variation is reduced (to Vi). an independent bank restricted to Go. Even at ui,. though, the This is not attainable by Given these results and previous assumptions, the firm's capitalization rate should be reduced through diversification. A firm limited to Go that tries to use more debt capital is faced with an increased coefficient of variation of net income unless it can reduce a0 or increase E(0). The use of additional leverage does not necessarily in- crease the coefficient of variation of net income. Given a0 and Go, an increase in operating income induced by a larger debt/equity ratio may result in the initial value for V,. If increased leverage does have a positive impact on "net earnings on equity" as proposed by Lintner7 and Robichek and gFor a discussion of the competing theories on the effect of leverage on equity values, see John Lintner. The "entity value" theory (as represented by Modigliani and Miller) holds that the net operating income of the corporation as a whole (sum of debt and equity values) is capitalized and is reduced by the market value of outstanding debt to determine the market value of the corporate equity. Since the "entity value" is held independent of the proportion of debt in total capital, the sum of the market values of equity and debt is a constant. An addition to debt will reduce net earnings due to additional interest and increase the discount rate due to added risk on equity--together reducing equity values in an amount equal to the value of the debt issued. The "net earnings" theory, in contrast, values corporate equity as determined . l Vi,E(o)‘, (K,/K,) / ------ / ------ ----. v,l,~(4 ( K,/K,)~ / / / / GO FIGURE 2. :I G DIVERSIFICATION, VARIABILITY OF EARNINGS, AND THE COEFFICIENT OF VARIATION OF NET INCOME 22 Myers, the attainment of greater earnings at no higher coefficient of variation reveals that leverage may improve ownership valuation substantially, , The representation of the coefficient of variation in functional form, then, aids in the understanding of the factors that determine its value. It is not realistic to assume that additional use of debt automatically increases the firm's concept of uncertainty associated with its earnings stream. This effect may be offset or even dominated by increased operating income and/or diversification. Recognizing this functional dependency, it is feasible that firms adhering to different operating policies may experience different values for the coefficient of variation of net income. It is also true that the alteration of a firm's organizational structure, which changes its ability to use financial leverage and diversification, may alter the behavior of owners' risk-adjusted discount rates. The acquisition of a bank by a BHC presents such a possibility. Each participating owner alters the structure of the claims on earnings he holds. The independent banker gains partial claim on BHC earnings in exchange for bank stock, while the holding company shareholder attains interest in the bank in return for partial interest in the expanded BHC's future earnings. by the capitalization of net earnings (after depreciation, taxes, and interest). Equity values, therefore, represent the direct capitalization of "net earnings on equity." The debt-equity ratio may have an impact on market values in this approach. Solomon and Kuh are representative of this approach. Lintner endorsed the net earnings approach in hisconelusion: "The sum of the market values of the corporate equity and debt will not be invariant to changes in the finance mix (as asserted in the entity value theory)--in particular stock values will not be equal to equity value less corporate debt--except under fully idealized conditions of certainty. Moreover, with uncertainty admitted, the earnings yield is )‘ a continuously rising (and non-linear) function of corporate leverage-at least beyond some initial range--and not a declining function of leverage beyond some point as inferred from the entity value theory" (p. 268). The analysis in the present study incorporates the net earnings approach. 23 The acquisition drastically expands the measure of diversification and extent of leveraging associated with the claims of the original bank owners while.more moderate changes are experienced by the BHC shareholders. It is entirely possible that the behavior of the coefficients of variation of net income (and thus owners' capitalization rates) may be affected by the transaction. Production Function Before these concepts are combined to describe the valuation framework owners use in determining acquisition activity, the production function must be described briefly. Basically, the banking or financially-related firm is dependent for its production on three classes of factor inputs-fixed assets (F), labor resources (N), and money capital (M). assets represent bank premises, equipment, etc. utilized in the productive process. Fixed N is the labor input Money capital is the amount.of funds actually available to the firm to place into the production of its various loan and investment categories. Additions to M evolve from ex- pansions of equity capital, debt capital, deposits (demand or time and savings), or other borrowing sources (B) such as Federal funds or the Federal Reserve discount window. The firm's level of production in any period t, therefore, may be represented in general form by: Qt = f(Ft, Nt, M, 24 III. THE MODEL Now that each of its components has been discussed, the valuation framework on which owners base their decisions may be more completely specified. Substituting the production function into the revenue func- tion and discounting the firms' future earnings stream in accord with owners' time preferences and the degree of risk perceived (represented by p) yields: (12) v= c- ' Pit(qit)f(Ft, Nt, Mt) - YltFt - 'f(d, ((z)ts - YZtN, Gt) Kdt - 'DDtDDt - rlDtTDt- rgtBt .. - e{c+ Ict) - cB,(Qt) - cq + CT,(Rt, Q,) + $f,(Rt, Ict, IQ, Qt)\ 1 The expression within the brackets is the profit function across the firm's horizon, Foregone earnings (Ef) are included within training costs (CT> for simplification. To create the valuation disparities posited essential for acquisitions to occur, (12) must be specified further to represent the firm under alternative organizational structures. (12a - 12b) and (12~ - 12d) represent, respectively, the valuation frameworks that a set of owners may use to determine whether the decision to trade stock with a holding company (in the case of independent banks) or to acquire an additional bank (for a present holding company) is in their economic interest. 25 .Both disparities must favor acquisition before the transaction will take place. For the bank owners' decision, the relevant functions are: Wd : Pit(qit>f(F t' N,, Mt) - Y1,Ft - yztNt i='l - %dt (($ - 8 (Cst(Q, - C@t) 't) Qt - 'DDtDDt - r+% Ict) + cq(Rt, - CF, Qt) + CMt(% - 'BtBt $9 IMt* Q,)t 1 B and Pit(sit>f(F t' NO (lib) - rKdt((z)ts Mt) 7 YltFt - yz,N, Gt) Kdt - rDDtDDt - 'TDt - mt - rBtBt - 0 {Cst(Rt, Ict) + CTt(Rts Qt) + CMt(Rt' Ict' *Mt' Qt)i 1 - CBt(Qt) - CFt HC where a is the percentage of holding company ownership offered to bank owners in exchange for their stock, and pBt and PHC t are the effective capitalization rates of original bank owners applicable to period t under assumptions of (a) continued ownership in the bank or (b) obtaining interest in a holding company, respectively. Holding company stockholders view the transaction by comparing ownership valuations of continued operation without acquiring the bank (i2c) and that thought obtainable with the addition of the bank (12d). 26 c pit(qit)f(Ft 9 N, 9 Mt) - YltFt - YztNt - 'Kdt ((2) ' 't) Kdt - rDDtDDt - rmtTDt - rBtBt t - 8 {Cs (Rt, t - Cg,(Qt) Ict) + c+, Qt) + $$rt, + IMt' Qdt 1 - CFt HC (12d) H c 'HE = t=l (811 P& n c Pit(qit)f(Ft, Nt, Mt) - YltFt - YztNt [i=l - rKdt ((?k) ts Cy) Kdt - rDDtDD, - rqTDt - 8 {C+ Ict) + $tRt, - CBt(Qt) - cF t Qt) + %it(Rt, - rBtBt Ict’ IMts Q$t 1 H%' where B is the proportion of ownership in the holding company retained by original stockholders (B = 1 - a), and pHCt and pHgtare the perceived effective capitalization rates applied to each period's earnings for holding company owners (a) under continued operation without purchasing the bank and (b) incorporating the bank within the company structure, respectively. For any acquisition to occur, economic incentives must be established for both participants. 12a - 12b) Specifically, VHC must be greater than VB (in and VHE must be larger than VHC (in 12c - 12d). Insight into the comparative magnitudes of these measures may be gained by viewing the relative responses of these functions following shifts in owners' relevant decision variables. There are several variables 27 that. will affect the paths of ownership valuation of the firm. The crucial factor within the present context, however, is the impact shifts in each have on the capitalized value of future earnings streams under the alternative banking organizations. Of particular interest in this respect are expansion of debt and equity capital, increased deposits, the emergence of the need to make replacements in the managerial staff, and the opportunity to diversify the firm's activities into new product and/or geographic markets. In addition, advantages for holding companies will result from familiarity with employees' abilities and extensive provision of fringe benefits to their staffs. Each of the above will be examined in more detail. The analysis will first concentrate on determining whether bank owners have an economic incentive to enter the transaction before the holding company's position is inspected. The valuation schema, as posited above, places dual emphasis on profit and risk expectations (embodied in p) in the effort to explain the incentives present for bank holding company acquisitions to occur. Since the significance of a greater earnings flow for one organization concerning this motivation is obvious, the present analysis will inquire into the possibility that owners foresee different capacities for dealing with risk under the alternative ownership structures. If this phenomenon is present, a valuation disparity is established even if expected earnings flows of the two are judged equivalent (which will be assumed for the present). Differences in the responses of the valuation ofearnings streams (by bank or BHC stockholders viewing alternative structures) provide an 28 important incentive for owners to enter into acquisition negotiations. Time preference patterns are assumed identical and constant, and for convenience, the time subscript will be suppressed in the following presentation. The Bank Stockholder For a bank to facilitateanexpansion Expansion of Equity of pro- duction (loans, investments, other services) it must eventually expand its capital base to meet regulatory demands. In their ownership decisions, bank owners view the comparative impacts on ownership valuation between the different organizational structures as the use of equity capital increases. The maximizing behavior of the independent bank is represented by: aoB aK, = - - 1 (TB) + PB %d aK, Kd aK, )I rKd + aKd =O or (14) QB z (rB) e PB i [( ar Kd Kd + aKd rK aK, cl aKe (14) states that the change in the valuation of the firm's earnings resulting from the impact of an increase in the use of equity on the capitalization rate must equal the additional net marginal revenue LJ product (i.e., MRP less the net change in the level of interest payments on debt capital) for ownership wealth maximization to occur. In the case of banks with total deposits of less than $30 million, a strong tendency to use only equity capital in their capital structure has been observed.8 If the bank does not use debt capital, no change in debt interest payments will occur and the change in valuation induced by a change in the capitalization rate will equalthefull marginal revenue product of more equity. sin& WK, measure of the may normally be considered positive, and since oB and ITBare both positive, 3PB is also =G positive for the independent banker in this case. In other words, the marginal revenue product of additional equity is equal to the required return to investors to compensate them for the use of their funds. On the other hand, if the firm does make use of debt capital.to some extent, the magnitude of the change in ownership valuation (that portion due.to a changed capitalization rate) is dependent on the relative sizes of the components on the right-hand side of (14). The net change in debt interest payments caused by expanded equity has two components: (1) a reduction resulting from a decreased rate of interest on debt capital as lenders view an improved equity position; and (2) an increase resulting from the use of more debt induced by a reduced debt/equity ratio. It is quite conceivable that an increase in equity may elicit a strong enough increase in the use of debt capital to actually increase the total interest payments on debt. In such a case, the change in ownership valuation resulting from a changed capitalization rate will be 8See Piper, p. 121. 30 less than the marginal revenue product of equity, i.e., (aPB/aK,hB < PB MRp ‘e* The increase in the capitalization rate for firms that do use debt capital to this extent will be less, therefore, than the identical firm would experience without the use of debt capital. Identical profit per- formances would result in a greater ownership valuation for the debt users. This is an advantage holding company organizations may provide to owners. The expansion of a firm's equity base may allow a reduction in the interest rate it must pay on its debt. A BHC may, however, expand debt capital significantly in response to the decreased cost and the decline in its debt/equity ratio. As debt increases, the public will re-evaluate the firm's debt instruments and adjust their required rates of return upward. If this process continues to the point where net inter- est payments are increased, the required change in the owners' capitalization rate to assure valuation maximization becomes less than the marginal revenue product realized from the investment of additional equity. From (14) it is evident that between two firms with equivalent profit performances the firm that makes greater use of debt capital can realize a greater valuation of those earnings than, say, a firm that or no use of debt. dom makes little If that same firm has the further advantage of free- of diversification (through acquisition) it may make use of even more debt without disturbing the rate it pays on debt capital. This may allow an even greater disparity in valuation of equivalent earnings flows. 31 Diversification Bank holding company acquisitions, in effect, pro- vide owners with an additional way to expand equity that is not available to independent banks. The acquisition itself brings increased diversifica- tion to the firm's operations as well. This may have a further impact on the availability of debt capital and the valuation of the firm's earnings. This is made clearer by examining the effect on ownership valuation of expanding equity through an acquisition that also increases the firm's diversity in product and/or geographic markets (G). aPHC - CLx.("HC) (15) av,,= a& aqi -+qi-aKe 2 pHC api aqi 391 XC, Kd2 rb)J +’ Pi& 1 =O Rearranging (4.6) and multiplying and dividing through by -%- gives: PHC aoHC aPflC (A& (rHC> (16) aKe + aG = [=h - {[zk +zrKd) oHC 'HC ar% aKd + aG Kd +rrKd The combined effect, 'then, of increased equity and diversification on the capitalization rate is extended to include the net change in debt interest payments allowed by an increase in G. of two components: This change also consists (1) a decrease as a result of reduced rates as lenders view the increased scope 'of the firm's operations, and (2) an increase ..I& due to an expansion in usage of debt. The firm that is afforded the use of additional debt capital to the extent that total interest payments increase as a result of an increase in the firm's degree of diversification will actually realize a smaller increase in the owner's capitalization rate than a bank that is not allowed to diversify to such an extent. For firms with identical profits and originally identical p's, this will result in greater valuation for the diversified debt user. As long as the net effect of diversification on interest payments is positive, owners ' capitalization rates will be smaller than they would be without diversification and debt usage. Valuation advantages under a holding company organization are, therefore, obvious for similar profit levels. This is the situation of interest to us at present. The original bank owner, faced with alternative paths of his capitalization rate in future time periods, will choose the path of lower o values if earnings are expected to be roughly equivalent. The motivation for owners of small banks to choose to trade their interest in the bank for that of a holding company is, therefore, enhanced if they view the prospect of expanding the equity base of the firm by acquisition. The above discussion has assumed that the independent bank and holding company owners have equal access to additional equity capital. It has ignored a very real problem facing smaller commercial banks in recent years--the limited scope for expanding their equity base that has placed an effective ceiling on growth potential. The uncertainty attached to the bank's future capital expansion capabilities, therefore, could cause a further divergence between the capitalization rates of bank owners and holding company owners that- (given profit performance) 33 will lead to a greater valuation of equivalent earnings through a BHC than through an independent bank. Expansion of Deposits Commercial bank deposits is a variable that most bankers can reasonably expect to increase as the economy expands, To examine the impact deposit growth has on ownership valuation, (12a) and (12b) must be differentiated with respect to deposits (time for convenience). deposits . For the independent bank: api + qi a qi (17) aqi 3TiF - ?rD aoB _ ?i?tj(rB) =. C 1 pi Rearranging we have: (18) MRp& - r!& The equivalent term under the holding company structure is: (19) =Fiir!E - = pHC which reveals that the portion of the change in the valuation of the firm attributable to the effect an increase in deposits has on the owners' capitalization rate is equal to the difference between the marginal revenue product of increased deposits and the marginal factor cost of those funds. If it is assumed that growth in deposits will not affect the capitalization rate of the firm, the familiar results evolve that each firm must expand its use of deposits until its marginal revenue product equals marginal factor cost. No information advantageous to the holding company structure is discernible from this situation. Even if 34 deposit growth does have an impact on p, there appears to be no basis for the argument that equivalent deposit increases would affect alternative organizational structures differently. Personnel Replacements and Provision of Employee Benefits Owners realize that occasionally it will become necessary to fill employee vacancies. Whether it is due to death, retirement, or the resignation of a staff member, the firm must make some expenditures on finding a qualified replacement. Retirement is predictable and gives the firm enough notice where it can attempt to make the transition as smoothly as possible. Death and resignation, however, give little warning and can greatly affect the total working efficiency of the firm's staff. All require explicit expenditures of searching for and training a replacement. They also involve the loss of potential earnings due to decreased marginal productivity during the orientation and training period. As has been suggested,' banks are often concerned with the lack of an efficient and well defined program for management succession. The holding company organization provides a program that not only reduces the costs involved with hiring and training a successor, but can often avoid the loss of foregone earnings by promoting'or transferring an experienced, competent person from within the company with little loss in productivity. In addition, owners may experience a reduction in the costs of observing or "monitoring" his performance in comparison with someone hired from outside the company. 9 See Lawrence (19691, pp. 44-45. 35 Neither the holding company nor the independent bank can control deaths or retirements. The holding company, however, provides a means . to retain personnel by reducing the frequency of resignations. The corporate structure, with its several bank and nonbank subsidiaries, provides an attractive network of possibilities for advancement for the young executive--where the independent bank is limited in this respect. Holding companies frequently initiate a centralized training program that provides a pool of management talent to the whole company. ' Employees within each holding company system are usually given priority when positions become available at subsidiary banks. An employee's chance for advancement to a position of added responsibility and increased remuneration, therefore, is not limited to openings that develop within a single bank. The holding company also provides its subsidiaries with fringe benefits (health and accident insurance, retirement plans, etc.) that add to the lustre and provide additional incentive for the employee to remain with the company. The combination of these factors suggests that,holding companies may be more effective at retaining present employees than smaller, less-diversified banks. This undoubtedly has important impli- cations for cost savings and owners' uncertainties connected with personnel replacement. It becomes immediately apparent, however, that expenditures on employee benefits have an impact on other components within the model. Money capital (M) is diverted from production to provide these benefits-thus an opportunity cost in the form of foregone revenue is present. On the cost savings side, however, in addition to reduced search, training, and monitoring costs associated with improved staff retention, training 36 costs and owners' monitoring costs are somewhat diminished by the reduction in the level of production. Monitoring costs are further affected through a possible improved alignment of managements' motives with owners' welfare.. As owners' trust in senior management increases, they expend less time and worry over the need for supervision--freeing them to attend to other matters. Examination of these expenditures will not add directly to the establishment of valuation disparities between the organizational frameworks,but it is anaspect of the firm's behavior revealed by the model and may lend support to the concerns for employee retention, managerial succession, and owners' trust in management. Differentiating (12) with respect to CF yields: ag -- aR acs acs aR acF +qi--- (20) + 39 zT acT aQ= aq aM acF a0 ET acT -- aR aR acF + Rearranging and dividing by p gives: (21) ae a% z ax & aR acM aR -- -- l+mM’ a$ acF )I aR acF 37 (21) reveals that the explicit cost of providing the,benefits to employees plus the foregone revenue from decreased production is exactly offset by the sum of the marginal savings from (a) reduced search, training, and monitoring costs due to a reduction in R, (b) reduced training, monitoring, and business services costs associated with a reduction in production, and (c) reduced monitoring costs due to the greater trust in management that owners experience. This implies then that owners may be willing to make additional explicit net expenditures if compensated by certain implicit cost savings (e.g., marginal time savings for owners). Expenditures on employee benefits for banks and holding companies alike appear in the . annualearningsreports do not. of each. Reductions in owners' monitoring costs If a monetary value were assigned to this time savings and deducted from the cost side of the earnings statement, it could have a significant impact on the reported earnings of the firm. For this reason, the earnings statement of the firm that experiences savings in monitoring costs through its activities may be somewhat understated. The BHC Stockholder Holding company owners will decide to acquire a bank only if they can similarly establish that the valuation of their earnings stream will be enhanced as a result. Company shareholders compare the ownership positions attainable under the alternative organizational structures. In the case of a proposed acquisition, the comparison is between the perceived performance of the BHC (inclusive of the bank) following the acquisition of a banking subsidiary and that performance expected without its acquisition. If the former is deemed superior to the latter, 38 the motivation for the company to pursue the acquisition is established. The distinction between organizational structures will not be as precise as the comparison provided independent bank owners. Instead of the alternatives presented in the choice between an independent bank and the holding company organization, the present situation involves whether or not an extension of the company structure will be positively reflected in the ownership valuation of the firm. The search for the valuation disparity necessary for acquisition to occur must again focus on both profit and risk considerations. Equations (12~) and (12d) (representing the alternative structures) will be differentiated with respect to the variables of crucial importance to company stockholders. The case for an extension of the company structure to include a$new acquisition lies chiefly in the owners' views of the comparative effects of expansion of equity capital, availabilityoand use of debt capital, and an increased degree of product and/or geographic diversification on their positions of ownership. In addition, the importance of employee retention and owners' monitoring costs will again be examined. Increase in Equity Capital The holding company may increase its equity position through retained earnings, the sale of stock on the market, the purchase of additional shares by present owners, or issuing new stock and trading for the stock of another firm (acquisition).. The last method delivers a portion of the ownership of the holding company to the bank owners with the original company stockholders retaining a smaller percentage ownership than before (6 =,l - cr)but of a larger unit (holding company plus the newly acquired bank). Searching 39 for a difference in ownership valuations, a comparison of the second and fourth alternatives can be made--i.e., issuing new stock, selling it for cash to outsiders, and maintaining the present company structure versus trading those same new issues for the stock (and thus the assets) of a bank. Each method will leave the original company owners with B(0 < B ( 1) of the ownership. A comparison of the first and fourth or third and fourth alternatives would be just as easy with present owners maintaining total ownership (6 =l) in the first and third cases. Differentiating (12~) and (12d) with respect to K, yields: (22) avHC r = e aPHC 8aK, (rHC) +B pi& 'HC a% pi aK, + qi K -( >I and a&l B-aK, dc) av& (23) a~,= pii; ar,, -( aKd yKd+aK,rM e -- 0 P* HC ar,, aKd ? 'd + -% 'Kd aq -aqi 1 =O aqi aK, > =O 40 Rearranging and dividing through by 1 and B , respectively, yields: pHC 'HC apHC ff e aKpiT) (24) = [mKe- ($hd+&Kd)j HC and (25) As before, (24) and (25) represent the owners' wealth maximization conditions that result from the expansion of equity capital through the sale of stock and an acquisition through the transfer of new company stock for that of the acquired firm, respectively. The latter -method may or may not have an increase in the firm's degree of diversification associated with it. For present purposes, it will be assumed that the acquisition does introduce the company into a new product and/or geographical market represented by a simultaneous increase in G. If the increased diversification (G) combined with the expansion of equity resulting from the acquisition induces a greater usage of debt capital (with resultant increased debt interest payments) than experienced through an expansion of -equity with no diversification, and if (m&)Hi is not any larger than (MRPIQHc, than that of (24). Therefore, the left-hand side of (25) is also smaller than its counterpart in (24). ~PITIC + aPfiC< aR, T aPHC Ticg’ the right-hand side of (25) is less If THC = 'rr&and if oHC = P;kC originally, i.e., the acquisition method results in-smaller in- crease in the owners' capitalization rate than the alternative method of 41 equity expansion. Comparing equivalent profit expectations, company shareholders will choose that organizational structure that provides the smaller p value. This action will maximize the owners' valuation of earnings. Expansion of Debt Capital Present company stockholders consider the possible positive impact an acquisition may have on the future ability of the firm to raise funds through the issuance of debt instruments. This is precisely the case just presented where(a) an expansion of equity may allow the company to also increase its usage of debt, and/or(b) an increase in the measure of diversification in production (G) further extends the company's debt capacity. If the latter does not accompany the acquisition, it is difficult to argue that owners anticipate lower p values than if the acquisition did not take place. The establishment of a valuation disparity in favor of acquisition associated with the expanded use of debt capital is then dependent upon distinguishable profit expectations. Implicit Returns Through BHC Activity If an extension of the holding company structure (through,acquisition) results in an improvement for the company in employee retention through increased opportunities for company personnel-- thereby inducinigreductions in certain administrative costs (search, training, monitoring) associated with replacements--over that. possible without acquisition, a valuation disparity may be created. Further, if the additional opportunities for advancement and prosperity persuade present employees that their future lies in the well-being of the company and its owners rather than pursuing their own self-interests (i.e., causes 42 a shift from a management-interest oriented firm to an owner-interest oriented firmlO> , owners may realize additional monitoring cost savings through the reduced time spent in supervision of management. Even if the explicit'cost savings are not reflected in improved earnings performantes , implicit savings (not accounted for in earnings statements) may form the basis for the necessary disparity in valuation if reported earnings are equivalent. Rather than attempting to quantify these implicit savings and adjusting earnings, they may be accounted for within the model by assuming that they are reflected in the manner in which owners value reported earnings flows. Specifically, the owners' capitalization rate is adjusted to reflect these developments. The reduction in owners' monitoring costs are in the form of less time and worry that owners must spend supervising (a) the filling of personnel vacancies and (b) the behavior of management. As owners gain additional confidence and trust in management and as the frequency of necessary replacements declines, the owners' measure of uncertainty accompanying a given income stream will likely be affected. If this is reflected in a smaller value than would occur with greater monitoring costs, a valuation disparity arising from extending the BHC structure may appear. For this purpose, equation (12) will again be differentiated with respect to expenditures on employee benefits (CE). Unlike in equation (18), however, it will presently be assumed that the "For discussions of the effect of separation of ownership and control see Baumol, Cohen and Reid, and Monsen, Chiu, and Cooley. Each argue that management-controlled firms may place less emphasis on profitassociated variables than owner-controlled firms, sacrificing them for performance goals regarded as more consistent with management interest. In a study.with Downs, Monsen suggests that management-controlled firms may sacrifice profit rate and growth rate for reduced risk acceptance. 43 firm's capitalization rate is affected by the consequences. This will occur through an upward adjustment in the expected earnings of the firm following improvements in both staff retention and owners' trust in management. Decreased monitoring of the replacement and productive pro- cesses result in time savings to owners that may be as important as expected dollar earnings. Owners certainly would prefer an earnings stream plus leisure time to equivalent earnings without leisure. This effect may be incorporated within the capitalization rate function by redefining expected operating income E(0) to include an addition for time savings E(t), i.e., E(O)* = E(0) + E(t). tion of net income (V,) would then become: p Vt The coefficient of varia= 00 [E(O)+E(t)I-qd(Kd/Ke,G)Kd then becomes dependent on [E(O) + E(t)] rather than just E(0). Further, as owners gain more faith that management will not seek to cheat them or pursue non-owner goals, they may allocate more of their time to other matters and less to the supervision of management. This is brought about through an improved alignment of management's motives with stockholders' interests that may result from an addition to employee benefits. The reduced monitoring costs, therefore, are reflected in p through an impact on E(t). As E(t) increased (E(0) remaining constant), the coefficient of variation (Vc) declines and, thus, p declines. The comparable expression to (18), adjusted to allow for this impact on p, is given by (26). ' 44 3 ,(26) p I ae zT l+mM- acT -aQ a6 acF )I (26) implies that the ownership valuation maximizing firm will increase expenditures on employee benefits until the change in ownership due to a percentage decline in the owners' capitalization rate just equals the net cost of such benefits. The net cost is the explicit cost of the benefits plus the marginal revenue product of the funds diverted from production minus the explicit savings on search, training, and business services expenditures that result. A shift in the capitalization rate from this source could have very important implications for the valuation of earnings streams. It appears, therefore, that the firm that provides additional bene- fits to its employees (in the form of higher salaries, insurance and retirement plans, stock options, attractive vacation plans, etc.) may receive implicit returns that offset the loss in potential profits caused by the diversion of funds from production to the provision of fringe benefits. These returns are present in the form of a solution to the firm's management succession problem, reduced staff turnover, and monitoring cost reductions. This is frequently the experience of BHCs. They provide extensive benefit programs to their employees and charge each subsidiary directly. Such increases in operating expenses have often been cited as the primary reason why banks have not experienced . 45 an improvement in profitability following acquisition. Although operating revenues "generally increased significantly after acquisition, . . . , revenue increases were typically matched by correspondingly large increases in operating costs" (Piper and Weiss, p. 5). BHC operating expenses may similarly offset an improved revenue experience due to a shift in product mix or efficiencies of the company structure. However, the implicit (not reported) returns thereby gained may cause the ownership valuation to be significantly increased. Though important, improved profitability is not the only source of the valuation disparity sought to explain BHC acquisitions--that source may rest in the capitalization rates used to evaluate a given income stream. IV. EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION The argument presented to this point suggests that a valuation framework, by taking expectations of future earnings and a measure of risk associated with the pattern of future earnings into account, can explain the economic motivation of both independent bank owners and BHC shareholders to negotiate an acquisition. The remainder of this paper investi- gates the gains accruing to holding company shareholders through acquisition. A BHC's acquisition of a commercial bank involves the dilution of its present ownership in an attempt to increase the present value of the ownership retained. This result is assured if the original BHC owners believe that following the acquisition their earnings will be greater, with equivalent or reduced risk, than they would be without acquisition. 46 This result could also occur, however, through a reduction in owners' risk with equivalent or improved future earnings. Any motivation for acquisition arising from the combination of reduced earnings and reduced risk or increased earnings and increased risk following acquisition is entirely dependent on trade-offs between risk and return within individual preference functions. Since such information is not known, substantiation of our hypothesis must rest on those cases where movements in risk and return do not have conflicting effects on valuation. The tendency in recent experience for multi-bank holding companies to acquire numerous commercial banks, and at relatively short intervals, seriously complicates the empirical task of isolating the impact of individual bank acquisitions on BHC earnings performance. The only feasible empirical test has to involve the entire acquisition program of the holding company and concerns itself with whether or not the policy of expansion through acquisition improves the value of earnings accruing to owners. Benefits of acquisition may be explored by a direct comparison of the trends in the earnings experienced over the post-acquisition period under the alternative ownership positions. The appropriate comparison involves the values of earnings accruing to those owners holding stock in a BHC at the time of acquisition--for they are the individuals contemplating the transaction. A major problem with this approach is that data that would reveal the earnings of a holding company had the acquisition not taken place, are not available. 47 Fortunately, however, this technique is applicable to one group of acquisitions within the last decade. Many of the acquisitions in the late .1960's were facilitated by the simple reorganization of an independent bank into another corporate form that was permitted to acquire additional banks. This was especially prevalent in states where mergers and/or branching were prohibited or limited by state law. The corporate trans- formation often involved nothing more than the exchange of new BHC stock for the stock of an existing bank. At the same time, additional BHC shares were issued in exchange for the stock of one or more additional banks. In other words, lead bank owners traded 100 percent ownership in the bank for less than total ownership in an expanded banking organization. Comparison of the earnings trend of that.specific set of owners following reorganization with what they would have realized had they retained their independent ownership in the bank provides a measure of the potential benefits to owners via acquisition through a BHC organization. Such a comparison is 'possible making use of previous empirical results that have shown commercial bank profitability to be relatively unaffected by acquisition. 11 This comparison was chosen because it pro- vides the only appropriate data available that examine the incentives for acquisition. Reports of Income exist for the years following acquisition. for the holding company on a consolidated basis and for the lead bank separately. valuation. These provide the basis for the direct comparisons of owners' There are no comparable data available that reveal the earnings performance of a multi-bank holding company excluding any particular acquired bank. Benefits accruing to original owners of these lead banks llThe reader is referred to Fischer, Lawrence (1967), Piper, Talley, and Ware for a good sample of this literature. 48 through reorganization and acquisition, then, may be used as a subsample to shed light on the economic incentives present in the larger population . of BHC acquisitions. If bank earnings are not affected by acquisition, the appropriate comparison to be made is between the trends of the ownership valuations of (a) the original bank owners' equity interest in the bank and (b) the interest obtained by that same group of owners in the expanded BHC organization through an exchange of stock. This comparison, requiring complete knowledge of stock splits, dividends, and dilution of owners' percentage share of total earnings, began the year immediately preceding the acquisition and continued for at least five years after the time of acquisition.12 The sample was restricted to those reorganizations occurring between 1962 and 1969, with all but three occurring since 1966. The average levels of earnings, average growth rates in earnings, and coefficients of variation of levels and growth rates of earnings (as measures of owners' risk) were computed over the period for both of the ownership alternatives. These sample data permit mean difference tests to be performed on the arguments of the valuation function. Table I shows that the mean difference in average annual earnings over the entire post-acquisition period was substantial. Previous owners of the lead banks realized an average improvement of $330,978 per year through the reorganization. This sum was not statistically significant, 12The sample consisted of 18 BHCs and associated lead banks located in seven Federal Reserve Districts with data available for at least five years after reorganization. The lead banks, all members of the Federal Reserve System, ranged in deposit size from approximately $100 million to $650 million at the time of reorganization. The necessary information was available for the sixth year for seven of these holding companies and banks and was incorporated into the analysis. Earnings accruing to original owners were computed by multiplying total net income of the firm by their percentage ownership in the firm for each year. TABLE 1 COMPARISON OF EARNINGS PERFORMANCES THROUGH BHC AND CONTINUED OWNERSHIP IN LEAD BANK FOLLOWING REORGANIZATION Banking Firm 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 '13 14 15 Avg. Income of Lead Bank That Would Have Accrued to Owners of Lead Bank Avg. Income of BHC Accruing to Owners of Lead Bank $1,078,111 2,305,407 5,071,545 1,679,674 1,632,975 2,022,951 1,506,681 1,455,996 2,369,669 7,676,530 3,722,490 6,955,577 5,382,316 3,155,189 4,815,430 ,$1,305,487 2,702,661 5,147,484 1,862,217 2,185,064 1,918,527 1,778,686 1,455,526 2,635,102 8,849,941 3,809,746 6,650,758 4,999,337 3,528,637 4,726,720 Difference (BHC-Lead Bank) $ 227,376 397,254 75,939 182,543 552,089 - 104,424 272,005 470 265,433 1,173,411 87,256 - 304,819 - 382,979 373,448 - 88,710 Avg. Growth Rate in Net Income of Lead Bank Avg. Growth Rate in Net Income Through BHC Avg. Difference (BHC-Lead Bank) 12.55% 13.63 9.13 13.92 17.15 17.36 8.00 21.65 4.18 .9.22 8.11 10.99 13.58 16.92 7.93 16.02% 12.57 10.10 18.63 27.13 18.84 14.64 22.00 10.82 13.28 10.59 9.40 11.56 22.98 6.90 3.46% - 1.06 0.97 4.71 9.97 1.48 6.64 0.35 6.64 4.07 2.48 - 1.60 - 2.02 6.07 - 1.02 TABLE (continued) 16 17 18 , Avg. Income of Lead Bank That Would Have Accrued to Owners of Lead Bank Avg. Income of BHC Actruing to Owners of Lead Bank Difference (BHC-Lead Bank) $2,300,507 3,387,176 1,775,490 Banking FirlIl Mean 1 $2,103,128 5,972,261 2,620,029 $- 197,379 2,585,085 844,539 $3,238,536 (568,712.187) $3,569,512 (698,058.187) $ 330,978 Avg. Growth Rate in Net Income of Lead Bank 35.11% - 4.82 2.36 12.05% (19.954346) Avg. Growth Rate in Net Income Through BHC Avg. Difference (BHC-Lead Bank) 30.83% 6.35 16.34 15.50% (16.037262) *significant at the .20 level Note: Standard deviations given in parentheses Sources: Moody's Bank and Finance Manual and internal records of seven Federal Reserve Banks. - 4.28% 11.17 13.98 3.45X* "t"=l.345 49 however, due largely to the considerable variance within sizes of firms included in the sample. The growth rates in net income did display a significant difference, though only at the .20 level. Specifically, the growth rate in earnings through the BHC was an average of 3.45 percent greater per year than would have been the case had the owners maintained their interest in the bank alone. Growth rates may be especially revealing since they, at least partially, compensate for size discrepancies within the sample. At the same time there was no significant difference between coefficients of variation of net income over the entire period. The coefficients of variation of growth rates of income, however, exhibited a significant difference at the .05 level over the interval. Specifically, this .measure of risk was substantially reduced through the acquisition program as reflected in Table 2. A comparison of earnings experience over time, shown in Table 3, indicates that holding company owners actually experienced reduced earnings through reorganization and acquisition in the first year relative to the experience of the bank alone. This first-year reduction in earnings appears attributable to the large premiums paid for bank stock. Each year there- after, however, earnings are progressively larger under the BHC structure. This trend is also reflected in the difference in growth rates of earnings. 13 In general, therefore, it appears that earnings for the BHC not only increased faster on an absolute basis when compared to the bank but also on a percentage basis, indicating that the difference between the two increases over time. 131f BHC earnings are depressed in the immediate post-acquisition . period, the experience of the third and fourth years.following reorganization is not surprising, since most of the BHCs in the sample made additional acquisitions in those years. TABLE 2 COMPARISON OF COEFFICIENTS OF VARIATION OF GROWTH RATES OF NET INCOME THROUGH BHC AND LEAD BANK FOLLOWING REORGANIZATION Coefficient of Variation of Income Growth Rates For Lead Bank Banking Firm Coefficient of Variation of Income Growth Rates Through BHC Difference (BHC;Bank) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 - 1.071895 2.645937 1.242849 1.130456 1.007689 1.248705 2.543271 1.649359 4.325461 3.987330 1.770638 0.605394 1.570596 1.196462 1.877712 0.729631 4.253756 3.889851 0.594423 1.851482 1.181919 0.234433 1.402617 1.160084 1.520361 1.323782 0.560705 0.941209 2.029515 0.795784 1.168754 0.772820 2.031342 0.571625 1.354321 0.564985 -0.477472 -0.794455 -0.060930 -0.896023 0.394928 -0.088621 -1.022910 -0.325577 -3.764756 -3.046121 0.258878 0.190390 -0.401842 -0.423642 0.153629 -0.158007 12.899434 -3.324865 Mean 2.041496 (1.260457) 1.114450 (0.530057) -0.927045* "t"=3.026 * significant at the .05 level Note: Standard deviations given in parentheses. Sources: See Table 1. . TABLE 3 COKPARISON EARNINGSTHROUGH BHC AND O'F LEAD BANK BY INDIVIDUAL YEAR Years Following Reorganization 3 years 4 years 5 years 6 years $3,936,692 $4,138,920 $5,004,592 3,268,524 3,520,821 3,545,288 3 247,005 180,031 260,829 416,144 593,632 1,757,589 21.49% (17.635) 25.07% (23.100) 9.27% (12.966) 16.37% (16.855) 6.11% (9.427) 12.01% (11.622) 26.08% (25.869) 11.47% (16.958) 10.92% (16.048) 14.43% (24.288) 0.93 (14.228) - 0.86 (20.027) - 4.59% 13.50" "t"=1.999 5.18 12.87** "t"=2.358 1 year 2 years $2,659,982 $3,189,644 $3,529,352 Owners' Net Income Through Lead Bank 2,867,316 3,009,613 Difference (BHC-Bank) -.207,334 Growth Rate of Net Income Through BHC Growth Rate of Net Income Through Lead Bank Owners' Net Income Through BHC Difference (BHC-Bank) * - 1.65 1.94 significant at the .lO level **significant at the .05 level Notes: Sixth year data based on seven BCHs and associated lead banks. of 18. Standard deviations given in parentheses. Sources: See Table 1. Other years based on sample size 50 If owners are aware of this trend, they may willingly accept losses in the first year after acquisition in order to receive claims on increasingly improved earnings in later years. If primary interest is placed on later years by omitting the first year's results from the analysis, the inference is altered somewhat (see Table 4). The average annual difference in net income increases to $444,784 while the difference in coefficients of variation of net income remains slightly negative. still not significant, however. These differences are The difference in average income growth rates increases to 5.27 percent, significant now at the .lO level, while the difference in coefficients of variation of income growth rates widened, i.e., became more negative. This difference remained significant at the .05 level. V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS Trends are established within the first few years following acquisition, therefore, that improve the present value of earnings flowing to owners relative to that attainable without reorganization. Owners have experienced improvements in the level of earnings to which they hold claims and, apparently, this improvement grows over time. Figures 3 and 4 chart the relative experiences in mean earnings and income growth rates for the alternative ownership positions, respectively. In addition, to the extent that the owners' conception of risk is accurately measured by the coefficient of variation of income growth rates, risk was reduced through the acquisition program. If, as assumed, this is reflected in lower capitalization rates associated with the expanded banking organization, a basis for disparity in both the numerator and denominator of the TABLE 4 COMPARISON OF EARNINGS PERFORMANCES THROUGH BHC AND LEAD BANK DELETING FIRST YEAR FOLLOWING REORGANIZATION Mean Difference in Average Annual Net Incomes (BHC-Lead Bank) Mean Difference in Coefficients of Variation of Net Incomes $444,784 -.005253 *significant at the .lO level **significant at the .05 level Mean Difference in Average Income Growth Rates Mean Difference in Coefficients of Varfation.of Income Growth Rates 5.27%* -1.708652** Net Income ($ millions) 6 1 O- I 1 I 2 I 3 I 4 I 5 I 6 Years After Acquisition FIGURE 3. LEVELS OF EARNINGS THROUGH BHC AND LEAD BANK Income Growth Rates (X) 28 24 16 12 8 4 \\v \\ F 0 I -4. I 1 I 2 I 3 I 4 I 5 I 6 Years After Acquisition FIGURE 4. INCOME GROWTH RATES THROUGH BHC AND LEAD BANK 51 valuation framework (V = IT/~)is present. The existence of significant disparities in either or both of the variables specified does not guarantee a significant valuation disparity in favor of acquisition. Without specific information of underlying utility functions (e.g., how risk affects the capitalization rate function or the relative importance of earnings and uncertainty in the valuation function), all that can be determined is an ordinal ranking of alternative ownership valuation positions--much as described in Figure 5. If owners are risk averse, they prefer a position with greater income (IT~>~o)and no increase in p. The same result may be obtained with equivalent earnings and a reduced capitalization rate function (increase from 1 to where PO p. and pl represent vectors of expected capitalization rates in future periods and p. > ~1. VI is preferred to VC and owners choose the value of the earnings stream associated with the expanded BHC structure. Since the exact shape of the owners' preference pattern is not known, we can only be sure that positions between and including points A and B are preferred to point C. Points to the left of AC (such as D) and below BC (E) involve movements in ITand p that have conflicting effects on valuation and may not legitimately be compared to point C. These results become even more meaningful when it is realized that earnings streams attained through a BHC structure may be somewhat depressed by subsequent acquisitions during the period of analysis. This tendency would decrease the difference in earnings performance when comparisons are made over a short post-acquisition interval and with firms that acquired other institutions after the time of the original acquisition. Victor of Expected Earnings n Positions Preferred to Point C IIP (l/P), (I/P), Inverse of Vector of Expected Capitalization Rates FIGURE 5. VALUATION INDIFFERENCE CURVES: TRADE-OFF BETWEEN RETURN AND RISK (OWNERS ASSUMED RISK AVERSE) 52 A note of caution should be injected, however, The sample used represents a special class and a very small proportion of the total population of acquisitions taking place. Whether or not measuring benefits to lead bank owners who formed holding companies to acquire other firms is representative of the benefits accruing to stockholders of established BHCs through acquisition may be questioned. It does, however, provide a rational explanation for the formation of many BHCs that is consistent with the theory of wealth maximization. 53 REFERENCES 1. M. Adelman, "The Antimerger Act, 1950-60," American Economic Review, May 1961, 51, 236-44. 2. A. Alchian and H. Demsetz, "Production, Information Costs and Economic Organizations," American Economic Review, December 1972, 62, 777-95. 3. w. Baumol, Portfolio Theory: town, N.J. 1970. The Selection of Asset Combinations, Morris- 4. K. Cohen and S. Reid, 'The Benefits and Costs of Bank Mergers," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, December 1966, 1, 15-57. 5. G. Fischer, -Bank Holding Companies, New York 1961. 6. G. Hall, "Some Impacts of One-Bank Holding Companies" in Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago 1969, 73-94. 7. E. Kuh, "Capital Theory and Capital Budgeting," Metroeconomica, Aug.Dec. 1960. 8. R. J. Lawrence, The Performance of Bank Holding Companies, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington 1967. 9. Part I," Staff , 'Operating Policies of Bank Holding.Companies: Economic Study No. 59, Board of Governors of'the Federal Reserve System, Washington 1969. 19. J. Lintner, "Dividends, Earnings, Leverage, Stock Prices and the Supply of Capital to Corporations," Review of Economics and Statistics, Aug. 1962, 44, 243-69. 11. F. Modigliani and M. Miller, "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment," American Economic Review, June 1958, 48, 261-97. 12. R. Monsen, J. Chiu, and D. Cooley, "The Effect of Separation of Qwnership and Control on the Performance of the Large Firm," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Aug. 1968, 82, 435-57. 13. , and A. Downs, "A Theory of Large Managerial Firms," Journal of Political Economy, June 1965, 73, 221-36. 14. T. Piper, The Economics of Bank Acquisitions by Registered Bank Holding Companies, Research Report No. 48, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, March 1971. 54 15. and S. Weiss, 'The Profitability of Bank Acquisitions by MultiBank Holding Companies," New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Sept.-Oct. 1971. 16. A. Robichek and S. Myers, "Problems in the Theory of Optimal Capital Structure," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, June 1966, 1, l-35. 17. E. Solomon, "Measuring a Company's Cost of Capital," Journal of Business, Oct. 1955, 28. 18. s. Talley, The Effect of Holding Company Acquisitions on Bank Performance, Staff Economic Study No. 69, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington 1971. 19. D. Vickers, The Theory of the Firm: New York 1968. 20. R. Ware, "Performance of Banks Acquired by Multi-Bank Holding Companies in Ohio," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, MarchApril 1973. Production, Capital, and Finance,