View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

|' JL/J.3'3

WOMEN WORKERS
IN

POWER LAUNDRIES

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
WOMEN’S BUREAU



BULLETIN NO. 215

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
L. B. SCHWELLENBACH, Secretary

WOMEN’S BUREAU
FRIEDA S. MILLER, Director

★

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER
LAUNDRIES

Bulletin of the Women’s Bureau
No. 215

UNITED STATES
GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1947

For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U. S. Government Printing Office, Washington 25, D. C.
Price 20 cents







—

CONTENTS
Page

LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL
CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION
The industry----------------------------------------------------------Growth of industry
Types of establishments
Special characteristics__________________________________________
Purpose and scope of survey---------------------------------------------------------- -Selection of industry-------------------------------------------Purpose of survey_____________________________________________
Scope of survey -CHAPTER II. OCCUPATIONS
Nature of occupations-------------------------------------------------------------------------Occupational distribution of women
11
CHAPTER III. EARNINGS
Intracity variations.. 1------_------------------ -------------------------------------- -Average for all occupations'
Selected occupations
15
Earnings and size of establishment_______________________________
Intercity variations,—.-----------------------------------------------------------------------Differences between two regions--------------------------------------Intercity differences within each region----------------------------------------Earnings and size of city
20
Earnings and cost of living------------------ ----------------------------------Method of wage payment-------------------------------------------------------------------Incentive method
22
Extent of use and occupations affected---------------------------------Effect on earnings_______________________________________
Time method________________________________________________
Absence deductions for weekly workers _____________________
Recent changes in method of wage payment--------------------------------Wage progressions
26
Wages and productive labor costs....---------------------------------------- —
Laundry earnings compared with earningsin other industries---------------CHAPTER IV. PRICES
Laundry services---------------------------------------- -----------------------------------Principal types of service
30
Wartime regulations on service and prices-----------------------------------Wartime changes in service------- ---------------------------------------------------Services selected for price-analysis--------------------- —-----------------Methods of pricing----------------------------------------------------------------------------Computation of prices------------------------------------------------------------------------Analysis of price structure------------ ...--------------------------------------------General price uniformity within city-----------------------------List price of shirts._____
Pound price of damp wash_____________________________________
Pound price of family finish
38
Price and size of city--------------------------- -----------------------------------Summary-----------------------------------Prices and earnings--------------------------CHAPTER V. SHIRT PRODUCTIVITY
Factors influencing productivity______
Variations in shirt output___________
Effect on shirt output of hand finishing and size of unit------------------Productivity and method of wage payment-------------------------------------Productivity and earnings--------------------------------------------------------------




ni

v
1
2
2
4
—4
5
6
9
13
13
17
18
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
30
30
31
32
33
34
34
35
35
38
38

47
47
48

IV

CONTENTS

CHAPTER VI. HOURS
Scheduled weekly hours
50
Other working time conditions___________________________
Workday, lunch periods, rest periods
52
Holidays
53
Trend in hours changes
53
CHAPTER VII. PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS
General observations*________________________________________ _____
Conditions in work area
55
Ventilation_______________________ ___________,.. 1______
Illumination
57
Lay-out___
Equipment______________________________
Housekeeping--------------------------------------------------------------------------Employee-welfare facilities
61
Drinking facilities____________
Washing facilities______________________________________________
Toilets___________________________
Seating.
64
Dressing, rest, and lunch room facilities:_______________________

Page
52

55
55
58
59
60
62
62
63
65

TABLES

1. Number of power laundries visited and their employment, by locality,
1945
2. Intracity differences between plants in average hourly earnings of
women production workers, by city
14
3. Intracity differences between plants in average hourly earnings of
women shirtline operatives, by city
16
4. Intracity differences between ■ plants in average hourly earnings of
women flatworkers, by city
17
5. Relative differences in the cost of equivalent goods, rents, and services
in selected cities, March 1945, compared to average hourly earnings
of women production workers in powerlaundries, July 1945________
■ 6. Comparison of average hourly earnings of time and incentive workers
in selected occupations, by city
24
7. Earnings of women productive workers and productive labor costs in
six citiesr.------8. Comparison of average hourly earnings of women production workers
in power laundries with earnings in other industries in the same city.
9. Retail prices of selected laundry services, by city____________________
10. Comparison of average hourly earnings of women shirtline operatives
with list price of shirts, by region
41
11. Comparison of average hourly earnings of women machine pressers
with price per pound of family-finish service, by region____________
12. Shirt production per operator-hour, by locality.. __________________
13. Comparison of shirt production per operator-hour and method of wage
payment, by region__________________________________ ____________
14. Comparison of average shirt production per operator-hour and average
hourly earnings of shirtline operatives, by region_________________
15. Weekly hours of work scheduled Dy plants for women production
workers, by locality_____________________________________

8

21

27
29
36

42
46
48
49
51

ILLUSTRATIONS

Balcony view of most of the finishing departments in a laundry_________
Women opening bundles of soiled laundry. Note fluorescent iighting and
individual air vents which bring fresh air into each booth_____________
Note lockers and showers in this rest room for women laundry workers___
A modest employee cafeteria in a laundry. Free coffee is featured_______




vn
10
65
66

LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL
United States Department of Labor,
Women’s Bureau,

Washington, April 22, 1947.
I have the honor to transmit a report on women workers in
power laundries. The report is based on a survey made in 1945 by
the Women’s Bureau, whose agents visited 258 power laundries in 38
selected cities or towns located in the Midwest or in the Southeast.
In selecting the power-laundry industry for survey, the Women’s
Bureau, fulfilling its statutory function “to promote the welfare of
wage-earning women,” was guided by the anticipated return to the
industry of displaced women war workers. Information was obtained
on all conditions affecting the employment of women production
workers. Presenting what was found in 1945, this report must be
read in the light of general conditions then prevailing.
The survey was planned by Caroline Manning and by Isadore
Spring who also directed the statistical work with the assistance of
Leo Robison. Margaret K. Anderson directed the field work. The
report was written by Sylvia R. Weissbrodt who was assisted by Grace
E. Ostrander in the analysis of the data.
Grateful acknowledgment is given to the American Institute of
Laundering, to the labor organizations in the industry, and to the
individual employers whose cooperation made this survey possible.
Respectfully submitted.
Frieda S. Miller,
Director.
Hon. L. B. SCHWELLENBACH,
Secretary of Labor.
Sir:




FOREWORD

What conditions confront women laundry workers in the postwar
period? To obtain factual information of help to employers in de­
veloping good employment conditions for women was the purpose of
this survey. By pointing to the striking differences in standards from
laundry to laundry within the same city, and by contrasting a rela­
tively high-standard region of the country with one of low standards,
this survey shows that progressive managements in the industry itself
have proved the practicability of adequate wage and employment
standards, pointing the way to those all too numerous establishments
‘ still clinging to depressed standards.
VI




/

P

;

BALCONY VIEW OF MOST OF THE FINISHING
DEPARTMENTS IN A LAUNDRY




VII

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES
CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION
THE INDUSTRY

A laundry owner of Tampa, Fla., in discussing differences in the
rate of turn-over among the jobs in his laundry, expressed under­
standing of the high turn-over among his “flatwork ironers’’—they
were the new workers and those lowest paid, he said. But the high
turn-over among his “sorters” perplexed him—they were the highest
paid women workers in his plant, he added. In this southern laundry,
the low-paid flatwork ironers received $16 for a 54-hour week, while
the “high-paid” sorters received all of $18 for a 54-hour week. More­
over, it was only under the stress of war conditions, in 1943, that
hours had been reduced from 58 a week. These twin evils—low wages
and long hours—are still found in many laundries in many cities. On
the other hand, progressive managements, in city after city, have
demonstrated by their own practices that laundry employment need
not be synonymous with depressed wage and employment standards
GROWTH OF THE INDUSTRY

The power-laundry industry, grown in the past 30 years from a
shirt and collar business to one of the major service industries in the
country, had a sales volume in 1945 of approximately 650 million
dollars. Laundry service, officially declared essential to the health
and welfare of the people during the recent war, has come to be ac­
cepted among large parts of the population as one of the necessities
and comforts of modern living. About 275,000 people depend on its
almost 6,800 establishments for a livelihood.
Like other services performed in the home exclusively not too
many years ago, laundering with the use of power-driven machines is
now a well-entrenched industry. It is estimated that commercial
laundries now get slightly less than 10 percent of the total potential
laundry business. Much of the same sort of work, obviously, is still
done in homes. But urbanization, smaller apartments, an increasing
number of women in the labor force, the shortage of household help,
and the virtual disappearance of the unpaid family household worker,
as well as the trend toward relieving the housewife of the more onerous
household tasks are among the forces contributing toward the demand
for commercial service. Measured by its total receipts, there is no
doubt that the industry is growing. In 1942, a new high in dollar
volume was attained, and each succeeding year, 1943, 1944, and 1945,
has brought record-breaking receipts to the industry.
741469—47------ 2




1

2

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

TYPESIOF.ESTABLISHMENTS

The power-laundry industry is composed of three basic types of
establishments—family laundries, institutional laundries, and com­
mercial wholesale and linen supply establishments. Family laundries,
selling their services primarily to the individual consumer at retail,
constitute by far the dominant group. Less than 7 percent of the
establishments, in 1939, did linen supply work either exclusively or
predominantly.
Although characteristically an industry composed of small units,
it has shown a tendency toward larger establishments and expanded
services. The “average” family laundry receives from its customers
about $100,000 a year. Such an average, however, obscures the
marked contrasts between the small and large units. In 1939, just a
little over half the establishments accounted for over 90 percent of
the industry’s dollar volume and provided employment for almost 90
percent of the industry’s employees. Together, therefore, with many
small plants (almost half of the total), generally employing 1 to 3
persons, are the relatively few large establishments doing a substantial
share of the business. In 1939, only 314 establishments, less than 5
percent of the total, each with annual receipts of a quarter of a million
dollars or more, together were responsible for 30 percent of the
industry’s total receipts. These large laundries, in addition to the
regular family-laundry service, generally offer a variety of other
services, such as dry cleaning, rug cleaning and storage, fur cleaning
and storage, and hat cleaning.
SPECIAL CHARACTERISTICS

Commercial laundry service shares with other service industries
the characteristics of time and place limitations. Customers want
their laundry processed and returned at a particular time. The
industry, unlike manufacturing industries, cannot store inventories
for future sale. At the same time, because the processing is of
short-lived utility in that the garments soon become soiled and again
require laundering, the establishments generally serve localized
markets, insulated from competition from other communities. These
factors determine the distribution of establishments. Laundries are
operating throughout the country, in all large cities, and in hundreds
of smaller cities; in short, in almost every community large enough
to support at least one establishment.
Several other special characteristics of the industry have particular
bearing on an understanding of the industry itself and more specifically
on the wage and employment standards practiced in the individual
plants. It is, significantly, a woman-employing industry, a fact
which has had far-reaching effects on its wage standards. Women,
almost 200,000 in number, constitute almost two-thirds of the work
force.
More than in other service industries, total pay-roll costs consume a
high percentage of receipts. Approximately 52 cents of every revenue
dollar is paid out in pay roll.1 Most of the plant operations require
individual handling. Aside from washing and drying, processes in
which several garments can be handled in a machine at one time, all
1 This figure, based on 1939 census, includes salaries of paid executives of corporations.




INTRODUCTION

3

other plant processes require individual handling of the garments,
despite the use of power-driven machinery. This means that the wage
bill represents the largest single item in the employer’s costs.
It is difficult, if not invalid, to compare the pay-roll ratio in the
laundry industry with that in manufacturing or trade industries.
Pay-roll cost percentages, being expressed in relation to revenue, are
obviously affected by the component elements of revenue. Laundries
do not produce a physical product, and therefore the return on raw
material costs is not, as in manufacturing, reflected in total receipts.2
Unlike the distributive trade industries, laundries do not have to get
a return on merchandise costs.
The two major elements in the laundry employer’s pay-roll costs
are productive labor, which consumed, in 1944, 35 percent of receipts,
and routemen’s wages and commissions, 11 percent of receipts.
Because laundries sell predominantly the processing performed by
their labor force, they should be vitally concerned with modern
techniques for using that labor force most effectively. Efficient
operating methods, increased productivity, and a realistic concern
for the welfare of the employees to enable them to yield maximum
quality output should be the benchmarks of the cost-conscious
employer.
The industry is profitable, having been consistently “in the black”
for over a decade. Total return to management during the three war
years, 1942-44, averaged over 7 percent of sales; over 2K percent
represented net operating profit, and 4% percent was drawn off for
executive salaries. Rates of profit, however, varied substantially,
not only with the volume of business of the individual plants but also
with their locations. The higher the volume of business, the higher
was the net profit rate. Laundries having a weekly sales volume of
less than $1,000 showed an average loss of 4.42 percent of sales for
the three war years, whereas those in the next higher volume classifi­
cation ($l,000-$2,000 weekly) averaged 0.10 percent profit. This
rate of net profit increased consistently in the higher-volume groups,
reaching an average net profit rate of 4.24 percent of sales in laundries
doing $8,000 and over a week in business. The rate of profit also
differed markedly in different areas of the country. Laundries in the
Southern and far Western States3 realized a higher rate of net profit
• than did those in other areas of the country.
The power-laundry industry is not one of widespread union organi­
zation. It is estimated that only 30 to 40 percent of the industry’s
production workers are working under terms set by collective-bargain­
ing agreements. And it is only within the past decade that this organi­
zation was accomplished. As recently as 10 years ago union member­
ship was insignificant. Only 600 paid members belonged to the
Laundry Workers’ International Union (AFL) in 1936, and some
laundry drivers were affiliated with the International Brotherhood of
Teamsters (AFL). Significant organizational strides were made by
the AFL laundry workers union in 1938-40 and by the CIO union,
Amalgamated Clothing Workers of America, which entered the
2 Laundries do have productive supply costs which, in 1944, consumed less than 10 percent of revenue.
3 Southern—North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Kentucky, Tennessee, Alabama, Missis­
sippi, Arkansas, Louisiana, Oklahoma. Texas, New Mexico, District of Columbia, Maryland, Virginia,
and West Virginia. Far Western—Washington, Oregon, California, Nevada, and Arizoua, A few laundries
in British Columbia, Canada, are also included in this group.




4

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

laundry field in 1937 and achieved almost complete organization of the
industry in the New York area by 1941. Total membership in the
AFL laundry workers union, however, apparently reached a plateau
in the war years, having remained unchanged in the past 4 years from
its 50,000 membership figure of 1943. Comparable data are not
available for the CIO union.
.
Much of the union membership appears to be centered in certain
large cities, such as San Francisco, Seattle, and Portland on the west
coast; New York, Jersey City, and Philadelphia on the east coast; and
middle western cities such as Chicago, St. Louis, Kansas City, Detroit,
and Milwaukee. Some union contracts are also in force in scattered
southern cities, among them, Birmingham, Atlanta, and, more recently
New Orleans. The provisions of some of the southern-city contracts,
however, still leave much to be desired. Both the CIO and AFL
unions currently report activity in the South.
The extent of union organization thus far attained in the industry
lags behind that in most manufacturing and many nonmanufacturing
industries.
PURPOSE AND SCOPE OF SURVEY
SELECTION OF INDUSTRY

In selecting the power-laundry industry for survey, the Women’s
Bureau, fulfilling its statutory function “to promote the welfare of
wage-earning women,” was guided by the anticipated return to the
industry of displaced women war workers. Always an employer of
large numbers of women, the industry was faced during the war with
the wholesale exodus of its regular w’orkers attracted to the higher
wages and more desirable plant environment and working conditions
in war-manufacturing industries. Cut-backs following the cessation
of hostilities forced women workers in all parts of the country to rees­
tablish themselves in industries offering postwar job openings to them.
Seeking to reconstitute their work forces disrupted by the labormarket upheaval incident to the war, laundries must also expand to
meet that part of consumer demand not heretofore satisfied because
of war shortages and restrictions. Again assuming their peacetime
importance to women workers as a whole, power laundries loom,
especially significant as a reemployment field for women war workers,
fresh from the rewarding experience of higher wage and employment
standards in war factories.
•
Historically the industry has been among the lowest paying for
women workers. A Women’s Bureau survey conducted in the war
period among women employed in 10 war-production areas showed
that take-home earnings of women working in war plants considerably
exceeded those of women working in laundries. Take-home pay in
war plants averaged over $35 in half the areas surveyed, but in laun­
dries, with the exception only of west coast laundries, take-home pay
averaged $25 or less, and, in one area, as low as $16 a week. These
earnings, low enough, were nevertheless higher than in many other
localities in the country because they were received during the war
period in war-congested areas of tight labor markets. Some women
in the South are still being paid 1$ and 25 cents an hour.




INTRODUCTION

5

Like those in other intrastate trade and service industries, women
working in laundries usually do not enjoy the benefits of the Federal
Fair Labor Standards Act4 which assures to workers in interstate
industries a minimum rate of at least 40 cents an hour and time and
one-half the employee’s regular rate of pay for hours in excess of 40
per week. Kecognizing that many women laundry workers have long
been subjected to unconscionably low wages, every State with an
active, applicable minimum-wage law of its own has established,
either through a specific minimum-wage order or the statute itself, a
legal floor to women’s wages in laundries. No other industry has such
extensive coverage under State minimum-wage programs. Yet low
wages still are widespread in many places. Twenty-two States do not
have a minimum-wage law. Three States, Kansas, Louisiana, and
Oklahoma, have inactive laws. In a fourth State, Maine, the law
cannot be applied to laundries because it is limited, by its terms, to
the fish-packing industry only.
Even in those 235 States, however, which have established a mini­
mum wage for laundries, the rates fixed are so low in most as no
longer to fulfill the legislative purpose of establishing a living wage.
Only 75 States fix a rate for the entire State as high as the 40-cent
minimum of the Federal Act. And it was only through recent revision
(1943-47) of previously established rates that these 7 States achieved
higher minima. In 13 other States, the rate set is 30 cents an hour
or less for all or part of the State. In Arkansas a minimum wage of
$1.25 per day for experienced workers has remained unchanged since
its establishment as far back as 1915. The Arkansas rate, like others
which have never been adjusted to increased living costs since origi­
nally issued, is patently no longer adequate to assure decent living
standards.
_
_
_
The last report made on women’s peacetime earnings in laundries
was in October 1940, when a Women’s Bureau study showed that the
average earnings of about 25,000 women laundry employees in 11
large industrial States were 36 cents an hour —average earnings which
bore the doubtful distinction of being the lowest among 24 selected
woman-employing industries (22 manufacturing and 2 service).
PURPOSE OF SURVEY

What conditions confront women laundry workers in the postwar
period? To obtain factual information on all conditions affecting the
employment of women spells out the objective of the survey. To help
employers develop good labor standards was the underlying purpose
which determined the method used in obtaining the information. By
pointing to the striking differences in standards from laundry to
laundry within the same city, and by contrasting a relatively highstandard region of the country with one of low standards, this survey
will show that progressive managements in the industry itself have
proved the practicability of decent wage standards, pointing the way
to those all too numerous establishments still clinging to appallingly
depressed standards. .
* On the basis of recent U. S. Supreme Court decisions, the Act was applied, effective Jan. 15, 1947, to
laundry and linen supply firms which receive more than 25 percent of their total gross receipts from services
provided to commercial and industrial customers for business purposes.
.
5 Includes District of Columbia, counted as a State. All information on State minimum-wage rates is as
of March 16, 1947.




6

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

SCOPE OF SURVEY

'

In order to fulfill the purpose of the study, two regions of the
country showing contrasts were selected for survey—the Middle West
and thej Southeast. Women’s Bureau agents in the fall of 1945
visited 258 laundries in 38 places (cities and towns) in 11 States —3 in
the Middle West: Illinois, Indiana, and Missouri; 8 in the Southeast:
Alabama, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, North Carolina, South Caro­
lina, Tennessee, and Virginia.
Southeastern States 6
The southeast region was selected for more intense survey because
it has long been the low-wage, low-income section of the country.
Per capita income has for many year’s been consistently lower in the
Southeast than in other regions of the country. Although the gap is
being narrowed (substantial gains were made in the war years), per
capita income payments in the southeastern region in 1945 were only
67 percent of the national average. ■
Annual wages of all workers covered by unemployment compensa­
tion laws averaged only $1,706 in 1944 in the Southeast; the $2,380
average for the rest of the country exceeded the southeastern region
by almost 40 percent. In the low-paid service industries the difference
was much greater—workers in the Southeast averaged only $1,222 a
year, those in the rest of the country, $1,806, or almost 50 percent
more.
Many of the Southeastern States, aside from being low-wage areas,
do not provide their workers with adequate legal safeguards through
State laws regulating labor standards. Over half the States in the
country have minimum-wage laws but only one of the Southeastern
States (Kentucky) has such a law. Two of the five States without a
maximum-hour law for women are in the Southeast—Alabama and
Florida. In three other Southeastern States, the legal maximum is
as high as 60 hours a week (Kentucky, Georgia, and Mississippi).
Florida has no laws regulating the payment of wages, and those in
North Carolina and Alabama are extremely limited in coverage.
Mississippi is the only State in the country without a workmen’s
compensation law of any kind. Among the eight Southeastern States
having such laws, only two, Kentucky and Virginia, have the preferred
compulsory type. The unemployment compensation laws are usually
of more limited coverage in the Southeast than in many other parts
of the country. Only 1 of the 217 States in the country which
regulate industrial home work is in the Southeast—Tennessee.
Middle Western States
The three Middle Western States selected for survey contrast with
the southeastern region. In Illinois, per capita income payments in
1945 exceeded the national average; in Indiana, they were about the
same as the national average; in Missouri, 92 percent of the national
average. Wage-earner income in these States in 1944, measured by
the $2,350 average annual wage of all workers covered by unemploy­
ment compensation laws, topped slightly the national average of* 1
8 This section covers the nine States commonly considered to comprise the southeastern region of the
country—Alabama, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, Tennessee,
Virginia. Mississippi, however, was not included in the survey.
1 Includes District of Columbia, counted as a State.




INTRODUCTION

7

$2,302, but exceeded substantially the $1,706 average of the South­
east. Service-industry workers covered by unemployment compen­
sation laws averaged $1,725 a year in the three Middle Western
States (a close approximation to the national average), compared to
only $1,232 in the Southeast.
City Samples
In selecting the cities to be surveyed in each of the two regions, no
effort was made to obtain a scientific sample representative of the
region as a whole nor of the individual States within each region.
Rather a variety of individual cities differing in size and type were
chosen in each region. Within each city, however, a representative
cross-section or all of the power laundries of the family service type
employing 25 or more employees were visited by Women’s Bureau
agents. Hand laundries, institutional laundries, and power laundries
specializing in linen supply or other commercial trade were omitted.
The selection of establishments was made following consultation with
employers’ associations and union officials. Only a representative
group of laundries was visited in the larger cities, whereas in the
smaller places, wherever possible, all the laundries of the specified
size and type were visited. The group of 258 establishments included
in the survey are therefore representative of 38 selected cities—92
laundries were located in 14 midwestern cities, and 166 laundries, in
24 southeastern cities. These laundries employed a total of over
21,000 workers, almost three-fourths of whom, or about 16,000, were
women.
Most of the laundries surveyed (about four-fifths of them) offered
dry cleaning as well as laundry service. Dry cleaning business usually
accounted for about 10 to 20 percent of the receipts of midwestern
laundries, but about 25 to 40 percent (and sometimes much more) in
southeastern laundries. The survey, however, was confined solely to
the laundry operations. Employers were interviewed, pay-roll
records were transcribed, and inspections made in the plants to obtain
information on such subjects as earnings, productive-labor costs,
prices, productivity, hours, and working conditions.
The survey was directed to the conditions affecting women pro­
duction workers only, who, over 14,000 in number, constituted 84
percent of all laundry production workers and almost two-thirds of the
total laundry employment in the 258 establishments. Wage data
gathered in the survey were based for the most part on the week
ended July 15, 1945. In order to have data comparable from city to
city, the same pay-roll week was used in each city, except where that
week was not normal. The Bureau of Labor Statistics cooperated
with the Women’s Bureau in obtaining the wage data.
Although most of the laundries were incorporated, their type of
business organization differed materially in each region. The mid­
western laundries, on the whole, operated as corporations (about
four-fifths of them did), whereas in the southeastern cities, only about
half were incorporated, and the others were either partnerships or
individual proprietorships. Approximately one-sixth of the laundries
were reported to be units of a chain of two or more establishments.
Sometimes the separate units of the chain were located in the same




8

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

city; some establishments, however, were parts of chains with units
in different cities of the same or other States.
Table 1 presents the cities included in the survey and the number
of laundries, with their employment, visited in each city.
Table 1.—Number of Power Laundries Visited and Their Employment, by Locality, 1945
, All employees *

Locality

Num­
ber of
plants
visit­
ed
Total

Women

Women

Route-

Percent Total
Per­ Total
of total
Num­ cent
Num­ produc­
ber
of
ber
tion
total
workers

All localities___________
Middle West
Illinois: Chicago____ ________
Indiana:
Indianapolis..
Other places
Evansville
Lafayette
South Bend
Terre Haute. ............
Missouri:
Kansas City... ________
St. Louis......................... .
Other places____________
Cape Girardeau
Hannibal
Jefferson City
Joplin _.
Springfield
St. Joseph

258 21,422 15,787
92 7, 729 5,138
30 2,947 1,593

Southeast............... ............................
Alabama: Birmingham_______
Florida:
Jacksonville. .......................
Tampa_____ ____ _______
Georgia:
Atlanta......... ...................
Savannah..... .......................
Other places
Brunswick
Columbus
Macon
Kentucky: Louisville
North Carolina:
Charlotte._
Winston-Salem____
Other places:.................... .
Burlington. _______
Raleigh
Wilmington
South Carolina:
Charleston
Columbia___ ___________
, Other places............... .........
Greenville__________
Spartanburg
Tennessee:
Memphis......... .....................
Other places
Knoxville __________
Nashville........................
Virginia: Hampton Roads area.
Newport News. _____
Norfolk
Portsmouth_____...

166 13, 693 10, 649
15 1,297 1,028

73.7 16,796 14,065
66.5 5,966 4, 648
54.1 2,116 1,430

83.7 2 2,076
77.9
971
67.6
521

All
others—
Total

2, 550
792
310

8
14
5
2
3
4

748
1,028
507
114
169
238

491
693
309
82
123
179

65.6
67.4
60.9
71.9
72.8
75.2

539
820
408
82
139
191

421
617
277
66
112
162

78.1
75.2
67.9
80.5
80.6
84.8

105
102
50
14 •
13
25

104
106
49
18
17
22

10
16
14
1
1
1
4
3
4

820
1,407
779
(13) 2
(3)
(3)
188
189
261

633
1,125
603

77.2
80.0
77.4

667
1,183
641

582
1.050
548

87.3
88.8
85.5

71
112
60

82
112
78

151
154
196

80.3
81.5
75.1

153
159
212

134
144
178

87.6
90.6 •
84.0

15
13
22

20
17
27

77.8 10,830
79.3 1,007

9,417
891

87.0
88.5

1.105
93

1,758
197

13
8

1,322
469

1,049
371

79.3
79.1

1,101
383

958
332

87.0
86.7

88
32

133
54

10
8
10
2
3
5
8

979
507
831
147
303
381
654

755
397
699
135
253
311
482

77.1
78.3
84.1
91.8
83.5
81.6
73.7

750
372
684
123
259
302
528

643
332
619
118
231
270
438

85.8
89.2
90.5
95.9
89.2
89.4
83.0

83
35
32
5
8
19
62

146
100
115
19
36
60
64

9
3
14
1
7
6

710
180
912
(3)
440
433

528
137
712

74.4
76.1
78.1

555
146
732

475
127
652

85.6
87.0
89.1

67
19
81

88
15
99

341
343

77.5
79.2

364
339

322
305

88.5
90.0

. 38
38

38
56

6
12
11
7
4

412
726
687
477
210

334
589
518
361
157

81.1
81.1
75.4
75.7
74.8

334
569
566
391
175

290
499
485
334
151

86.8
87.7
85.7
85.4
86.3

16
37
50
31
19

62
120
71
55
16

9
14
48
6
16
2
10
4

1,616
1.143
556
587
1,248
, 189
780
279

1,206
872
433
439
972
127
631
214

74.6
76.3
77.9
74.8
77.9
67.2
80.9
76.7

1,260
856
424
432
987
137
623
227

1,098
720
362
358
858
106
556
196

87.1
84.1
85.4
82.9
86.9
77.4
. 89.2
86.3

219
91
42
49
100
25
54
21

137
196
90
106
161
27
103
31

1 Excludes employees engaged in dry-cleaning operations.
2 Includes 4 women.
3 Withheld to avoid disclosure.
* Includes 1 plant for which employment data not available,




Production and
related workers

CHAPTER II. OCCUPATIONS
NATURE OF OCCUPATIONS

The occupations found in a laundry can be grouped into three
major divisions. Most important numerically are the production
employees—a group comprising all workers engaged in actual launder­
ing operations. About 78 percent of all laundry workers employed
in the establishments surveyed were production workers. Women
predominate in this group. Constituting not less than two-thirds
of the production workers in any city, women formed 80 to 90 percent
of the productive work forces in most cities. The second occupational
division covers routemen (drivers) who made up 10 percent of the
total employees, and the third division (12 percent of the total)
covers all other employees, including office, power-plant, and
repair-maintenance workers. Normally women are not employed
as routemen but a few were found working in this occupation in 1945
in an Atlanta and in a Savannah laundry.
The 258 laundries surveyed employed 14,065 women production
workers who worked at almost every production job found in the
industry. The relationship of these jobs to one another and the con­
tribution of each to the completed laundry bundle can be seen by
tracing a bundle through the various processes in an average laundry.
. Let us start with the homemaker who, gathering soiled articles, finds
that her bundle contains some flatwork (sheets, pillow cases, towels),
wearing apparel (shirts, socks, handkerchiefs, pajamas), and some
specialty items such as a wool blanket and curtains. The customer
itemizes the articles on the list accompanying her bundle and specifies
the desired type of service from a variety offered. She might request
that, after washing, all the items be returned damp; or that only the
flatwork be ironed and the wearing apparel returned ready for her to
iron at home; or that all articles in the bundle should be ironed by the
laundry. If this homemaker holds a full-time job, the likelihood is
she will have little time or energy to iron her laundry at home and will
perhaps request “family-finished service,” which means that all
articles in the bundle are to be washed and “finished” (ironed) on
machine presses. Any necessary “touch-up” will be done by handironers, and menders will repair torn articles. Upon being returned
to the customer, all articles in a family-finished bundle are ready for
use.
The bundle is picked up at the customer’s home by a routeman who
delivers it by truck to the laundry plant. If the customer had pre­
ferred “cash and carry” service, she herself could have taken the bundle
directly to a “call office” at the plant or to a branch office where it
would be picked up by a driver and brought to the plant.
The marking department starts the bundle through the productive
processes. Here, the bundle is weighed by a weigher or marker, and
the marker opens it and lists and identifies (marks) the individual
articles so that items following different courses through the laundry
may be later reassembled. The distinguishing mark placed on the
articles may bo visible or “invisible” (visible only in ultra-violet light)
inking, or it may be a removable label sewed or stapled to the article.
A classifier separates the bundle, putting flatwork in one group, shirts
741469—47------ 3
9




10

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

in another, specialty items in a third, and all other articles into separate
groups according to fabric and color. Each group is put into an
individual net bag, and each bag is marked with a large pin numbered
with the “mark” assigned the customer.
The laundry is conveyed in carts to the washroom where a loader
puts it into washing machines, often called “washwheels.” In some

■ iH
WOMEN OPENING BUNDLES OF SOILED LAUNDRY. NOTE FLUORESCENT LIGHT­
ING AND INDIVIDUAL AIR VENTS WHICH BRING FRESH AIR INTO EACH BOOTH.

plants the markers and classifiers, working on a mezzanine floor, drop
the laundry down chutes into the washing machines. A washman,
in charge of washing operations, admits the washing solution into the
machines which wash and rinse the laundry. A 'puller removes the
wet laundry from the washers and dumps it into a chain basket or
perforated cage, in turn lowered into an extractor—a centrifugal
drying machine which expels water from the washed articles. After
this operation, the extractor operator, lifting the laundry from the ex­
tractor, places it into carts which are sent to different sections of the
plant. Some articles are then tumbled instead of ironed. Bath
towls, for example, are tumbled to remove creases without leveling
the nap. The tumbler operator loads, operates, and unloads the tum­
bling machine. Other articles are sent to the finishing departments.
Sheets and pillow cases are sent from the washroom to the flatworkers, an ironing crew composed of three groups of workers. Two
shakers pick up the wet pieces of flatwork, shake them to uncrumple
them, and place them on a rack. Two feeders place the pieces on the
flatwork ironer in position for the ribbons to carry them through the
machine. Two folders (also called catchers or receivers) receive the
ironed flatwork and fold it.
Handkerchiefs are finished on a small machine, often operated by
one person, the handkerchief ironer, who shakes out the handkerchiefs,




OCCUPATIONS

11

spreads them on the ironer, removes and folds the ironed pieces.
Shirts are finished on a group of specialized presses—a shirtline.
The number of shirtline operatives in a unit varies, depending on the
type of equipment used and the degree of specialization practiced.
The operators perform successive operations on the same shirt. Each
member of the shirtline crew operates one or more of the presses—
collar-and-cuff press, bosom press, body press, sleever, collar former,
and yoker. One operator folds the shirts, and a hand ironer may
touch them up.
Other garments such as pajamas and houscdresses are finished on
garment presses in the wearing-apparel finishing section where the
presses are operated by press operators who may tend more than one
press. Socks are pulled over a heated sock form by a sock ironer who
removes the socks when they are dry and free of creases and who also
sorts them.
The specialty-finishing department handles such items as blankets
and curtains. The customer’s woolen blanket, possibly hand washed
and already extracted, is sent to the finishing department where a
carding-machine operator feeds the blanket into a carding machine
which brushes and raises the nap of the blanket as it passes between
the rolls, or where a carder brushes the blanket with a hand card.
Curtains are dried on a large frame (curtain drier) onto which the
stretcher-drier operators press the curtains. Fluted edges are shaped
with a pair of corrugated irons by the fluting-machine operator, and
ruffled edges are finished by the hand ironer.
As each group of the customer’s articles is completed in the various
finishing departments, it is sent to the sorters (assemblers) who assemble
all the items belonging to the customer. A checker examines the bun­
dle to ascertain that nothing is missing. The bundle, after being
packaged by a wrapper, is sent to the delivery department where a
routeman picks it up and delivers it to the owner.
As can be seen from the foregoing description, much of the plant’s
floor space is occupied by presses, which, being steam-heated, generate
heat and humidity often causing considerable discomfort, especially
in hot weather. Workers in the marking department are subjected
to the unpleasantness of handling soiled clothing. Employees in the
sorting department must adhere to high standards of accuracy so
that customers’ complaints due to missing items or failure to follow
special requests are reduced to a minimum.
OCCUPATIONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WOMEN

The women production workers perform almost all of the jobs in
marking, finishing, and sorting departments. At the time of the
survey in 1945, about 5 percent of the women also assisted in the
washing department where the jobs are normally held by men. In
laundries of the southeastern cities it was typical to find Negro women
in the finishing departments and white women in the marking and
sorting departments.
The. degree of job specialization found in individual laundries
varied"with the size of the establishment; the larger laundries had
more specialized job break-downs, whereas the smaller ones often
assigned employees to different jobs during the course of a day or




12

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

week in response to fluctuations in the work-load of the various units.
The women production workers on the pay rolls of the 258 laundries
were grouped in nine occupations; these women were markers, wash­
ers’ helpers and tumblers, flatworkers, shirtline operators, other
machine pressers, hand ironers,1 sorters, working supervisors, and
general or miscellaneous production workers. A laundry employing
50 women production workers usually had about 14 flatworkers, 8
shirtline operatives, 7 other machine pressers, 6 markers, 7 sorters,
and 8 other workers (hand ironers, working supervisors, etc.).
Flatworkers generally composed the largest single occupational
group. Considerable differences were found, however, from la undr vT
to laundry in the relative importance of this group. Two-fifths of
the laundries employed 20 to 30 percent of their women production
workers as flatworkers. But in about one-fifth of the establishments,
flatworkers constituted less than 20 percent, and in one-sixth of the
plants they were substantially more important, constituting 40 per­
cent or more.
Differences from plant to plant in the occupational distribution
of their women production workers, though most marked for the
flatworkers, were not confined to this occupation. In almost twothirds of the laundries, shirtline operatives represented 10 to 20
percent of the woman productive force, but in most of the other plants
the shirt crew was relatively more important. Other machine press­
ers, constituting 10 to 20 percent of women workers in almost threefifths of the laundries, were significantly less important in many.
Markers and sorters, combined, generally accounted for a fourth
of the woman productive force. Several laundries, however, primarily
in Chicago and Kansas City, were able to handle the marking and
sorting operations with substantially smaller proportions of their
women.
The differences from plant to plant in the relative importance of
each occupation can be traced, in part, to the types of service offered
in each and the distribution of the laundry’s business among those
services offered.
In the war period some laundries had discontinued family-finish
service, and these plants would obviously have little need for wearingapparel pressers. Other laundries, having discontinued hand “touchup,” would not require hand ironers. Two Chicago laundries, for
example, both employing about the same number of women workers,
showed distinct differences in the occupational distribution of their
work forces. One laundry, employing 52 women production workers
and offering all the basic services, reported that one-fifth of the
women were either machine pressers or hand ironers. The other
laundry, employing 57 women and not offering the family-finish
service, had neither machine pressers nor hand ironers.
There is no doubt, either, that the operating methods used in the
plant affected the relative importance of each occupation. Differ­
ences from plant to plant can be caused by differences in marking
methods, the extent to which labor-saving devices are used, the
degree of specialization, plant efficiency, and flow of work through
the plant.
1 Includes all hand Ironers except those workine on shirtline crews who are classed with shirtline operators.




CHAPTER III. EARNINGS1
INTRACITY VARIATIONS
AVERAGE FOR ALL OCCUPATIONS

Average hourly earnings among competing laundries within the
same city were vastly different, demonstrating a conspicuous lack of
wage standardization. In an overwhelming majority of the cities
surveyed, employees working in the city’s highest-paying laundry
earned 30 to over 50 percent more than those in the lowest-paying
laundry.
_ .
Four or more establishments were visited in 27 of the 38 cities
included in the survey. In these 27 cities, average hourly earnings
in the top-wage plant exceeded those in the lowest-wage plant by an
average of 12 cents. A 12-cent differential in a typically low-wage
industry yields a substantial percent difference—it amounted to an
average difference of as high as 39 percent. In some cities the differ­
ence was much greater. Birmingham was one of them. Here, em­
ployees in the highest-paying plant, averaging 36 cents an hour, came
close to earning twice as much as those less fortunately employed in
the lowest-paying plant where hourly earnings averaged only 19
cents. Norfolk was another. In this city, employees in one plant
averaged 56 cents an hour, those in another only 30 cents.
Midwestern cities, though not having differences as high as 50
percent, such as were found in several southeastern cities, also showed
a marked lack of uniformity in earnings within the same city. Chicago
topped the list with a difference of 22 cents, or 43 percent, between the
lowest- and highest-paying plant. ' Indianapolis, where the difference
was 40 percent, was close behind.
That wage standardization within a city is possible is demon­
strated by the earnings found in three of them—Kansas City, Terre
Haute, and Raleigh, where average hourly earnings in different plants
of each city differed by no more than 3 cents.
The fact that the laundries in a city were operating under a union
contract did not necessarily serve to standardize wages. In 4 of
the 27 cities under consideration, all or most laundries were organized,
and wage scales were set by union agreement. Two of them, Kansas
City and Terre Haute, were among the three cities of striking wage
uniformity. The other two, however, Chicago and Birmingham,
showed marked differences from one establishment to anothes.
Table 2 shows the variation from one laundry to another within the
same city.i
i Information obtained on earnings was based, for the most part, on the week ended July 15, 1945. This
information may no longer represent current conditions. Among other changes which have taken place
since July 1945, it is known, for example, that the St. Louis laundries have since been organized and are
operating under a union contract calling for a 40-cent minimum rate. Similarly, under a renegotiated union
contract in Birmingham, rates are higher than those reported at the time of survey.




13

14
Tabic 2.

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES
Infracify Differences Between Plants in Average Hourly Earnings of Women
Production Workers, by City 1

City

Middle West:
Illinois: Chicago.............
Indiana:
Evansville.................
Indianapolis______
Terre Haute_______
Missouri:
Joplin........................
Kansas City..............
St. Joseph.................
St. Louis_________
Southeast:
Alabama: Birmingham..
Florida:
Jacksonville............
Tampa. ______ ____
Georgia:
Atlanta......................
Macon........... ...........
Savannah...............
Kentucky: Louisville...
North Carolina:
Charlotte...................
Raleigh......................
Wilmington..............
South Carolina:
Charleston................
Columbia..................
Greenville.................
Spartanburg..............
Tennessee:
Knoxville..................
Memphis_________
Nashville...............
Virginia:
Norfolk____ ______
Portsmouth...............

Number Average hourly earnings
of plants1
reporting
All plants*
Range

Difference between
lowest- and highestpaying plants
Actual

Percent3

29

$0.61

$0.51-0.73

$0.22

43

5
8
4

.46
.53
.46

.40- .53
. 45- . 63
.46- .48

.13
.18
.02

32
40
4

4
10
4
16

.37
.47
.39
.43

.35.46.35.38-

.40
. 49
.42
. 50

.05
.03
.07
.12

14
7
20
32

15

.30

. 19- . 36

.17

89

12
8

.38
.39

.33- .46
.30- .46

.13
.16

39
53

10
4
7
8

.34
.26
.32
.50

. 29. 23.27.41-

. 38
. 30
. 38
.55

.09
.07
.11
.14

31
30
41
34

8
6
6

.35
.32
.34

.29- .40
.30- . 33
. 24- . 40

. 11
.03
.16

38
10
67

6
10
7
4

.34
.28
.25
.27

.29. 25. 21. 23-

.40
. 34
. 31
. 32

.11
.09
.10
09

38
36
48
39

6
9
5

.35
.33
.31

. 32- . 39
. 30- . 38
.25- .36

.07
.08
.11

22
27
44

10
4

.41
.42

.30- .56
.29- .53

.26
.24

87
83

1 Lists only those cities in which 4 or more laundries were visited.
•
* City averages take into account the number of plants in each city but not the number of women pro­
duction workers in each plant.
3 This represents the percent by which earnings in the highest-paying plant exceed those in the lowestpaying plant.

Although the power-laundry industry has long been among the
lowest-paying fields of employment for women, wage practices of
many employers themselves prove that it need not be a depressedwage industry. In most cities there was one and often there were a
few establishments where women earned substantially more than in
other establishments of the same city. Moreover, as will develop in
subsequent chapters, these higher wage-standard laundries did not
necessarily charge higher prices than others in the city, and often
their productive labor-cost ratios were lower than in other low-wage
plants. .In Louisville, for example, women’s hourly earnings in four
plants averaged 55 or 54 cents, but in the other four plants earnings
lagged behind at averages of 47 cents or less and as low as 41 cents.




EARNINGS

15

Indianapolis showed a similar picture. Two laundries where women
averaged 63 and 61 cents an hour stood out as wage leaders, but
in all other plants average earnings were 55 cents or less. Even
in the unusually low-wage cities in the Southeast, some laundry
owners found it possible to pay wages high enough to enable their
employees to earn considerably more than employees of other
laundries. In Wilmington, for example, where average earnings for
all plants was at the conspicuously low level of 34 cents and where
women in one establishment averaged only 24 cents, one plant stood
above all others in that hourly earnings there averaged 40 cents.
In the very low-wage city of Columbia, too, where average earnings
in most plants hit lows of 25-28 cents, women in one plant averaged
34 cents—hardly an adequate wage level but nevertheless much
higher than in other laundries of the city.
SELECTED OCCUPATIONS

Flatworkers, constituting numerically the most important occupa­
tion, were also generally the lowest paid in the five basic women’s
production occupations. The highest-paid workers were usually
the markers and sorters. Earnings of shirtline operatives and of other
machine pressers generally fell at some point between those of flatworkers and of markers and sorters. Only a few cities varied from
this pattern. Shirtline operatives, rather than markers and sorters,
took top place in average earnings in four localities—Chicago, Kansas
City, Louisville, and small Missouri cities. Other machine pressers
averaged highest earnings in two cities, Indianapolis and Memphis.
Because earnings differed from one occupation to another, plant
to plant differences in occupational composition may account for
the great variety in average earnings within each city. But such
differences are obviously only a partial explanation. The observa­
tion on lack of wage standardization within a city, made in the
first section, was reinforced by the marked differences found from
plant to plant in earnings in the same occupation. This was out­
standingly true of shirtline operatives who, in many cities, earned
over 70 percent more in the highest-paying plant than those working
in the lowest-paying plant. Intracity differences were so great
that in two cities shirt operatives in one plant averaged almost twice
as much as those in another, and in two other cities the difference
was even greater. In Chicago, for example, where the city average
for shirt operatives was 69 cents, the average in three plants was as
high as 90 cents, compared to a low in three other plants of 55 or 52
cents. Similarly, shirt operatives in one Birmingham plant averaged
45 cents, those in two others only 21 cents. As table 3 shows, the
greatest difference was found in Norfolk, the least in Terre Haute.
Moreover, as will be discussed in a subsequent chapter, differences in
productivity were not necessarily reflected in differences in earnings.




16

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

Table 3.—Intracity Differences Between Plants in Average Hourly Earnings of Women
Shirtline Operatives, by City 1

City

Number Average hourly earnings
of plants
All plants2

Middle West:
Illinois: Chicago._ .
Indiana:
Evansville___ ____
Indianapolis__ ____
Terre Haute....................
Missouri:
Joplin_____ _____
Kansas City_______
St. Joseph___
_
St. Louis_________
Southeast:
Alabama: Birmingham..
Florida:
Jacksonville_________
Tampa___ _
Georgia:
Atlanta____ _____
Macon_______
Savannah______
Kentucky: Louisville_____
North Carolina:
Charlotte... ..
Raleigh______
Wilmington________
South Carolina:
Charleston________
Columbia________
Greenville________
Spartanburg..........
Tennessee:
Knoxville___________
Memphis_____ ____
Nashville___ _____
Virginia:
Norfolk_____ ______
Portsmouth_________

Range

Difference between
lowest- and highestpaying plants
Actual

Percent3

.28

$0.69

$0.52-0.90

$0.38

73

5
8
4

.51
.57
.46

.40- . 57
.51- . 61
. 45- . 46

. 17
.10
.01

43
20
2

4
10
4
16

. .37
.53
.41
.47

.35. 49. 35. 36-

. 40
. 71
. 46
. 66

.05
.22
.11
.30

14
45
31
83

15

.31

. 21- . 45

.24

114

12
8

.35
.44

. 30- . 53
. 30- . 52

.23
.22

77
73

10
4
7
8

.34
.25
.28
.58

. 30. 22. 22. 44-

. 52
. 37
. 38
. 70

.22
. 15
. 16
.26

73
68
73
59

8
6
6

.34
.32
.29

. 27- . 53
. 28- . 40
.22- .38

.26
. 12
. 16

96
43
73

6
10
7
4

.41
.28
.23
.25

.32. 22.19.22-

. 55
. 35
. 30
. 31

.23
. 13
. 11
.09

72
59
58
41

6
9
4

.37
.33
.33

.30- . 46
. 27- . 39
. 28- . 38

. 16
. 12
. 10

53
44
36

10
4

.44
.52

.31- .72
.31- .59

.41
.28

132
90

1 Lists only those cities in which 4 or more laundries were visited.
2 City averages take into account the number of women shirtline operatives in each plant.
2 This represents the percent by which earnings in the highest-paying plant exceed those in the lowestpaying plant.

Earnings of flatworkers, the least skilled workers and probably
those whose occupation is most comparable from one plant to another,
also showed marked variations within each city, though not as wide
as for shirt operatives. In nearly two-thirds of the cities, flatworkers
in one plant earned 40 percent or more above those in another plant.
Because flatworkers were the lowest-paid workers, differences from
plant to plant in several southeastern cities meant the difference
between meager earnings of 17-22 cents and those over 30 cents.
Table 4 shows the differences between one plant and another within
each city.
Comparison of average earnings in each of the other occupations
among laundries in the same city also revealed the same lack of wage
standardization found among the numerically more important groups
of flatworkers and of shirt operatives.




17

EAENINGS

Table 4.—Intracity Differences Between Plants in Average Hourly Earnings of Women
Flafworkers, by City 1

City

Middle West:
Illinois: Chicago__
Indiana:
Evansville___
Indianapolis............................. ........
Terre Haute__
Missouri:
Joplin. ................... ........................
Kansas City__________________
St. Joseph_______________
St. Louis______________ ______
Southeast:
Alabama: Birmingham____
Florida:
Jacksonville
Tampa____________ _________
Georgia:
Atlanta
Macon
Savannah.___ ________________
Kentucky: Louisville
North Carolina:
Charlotte________________ _____
Raleigh___ ________________
Wilmington
South Carolina:
Charleston________________
Columbia____ _______________
Greenville_______________
Spartanburg........
.....................
Tennessee:
Knoxville..
Memphis_____ __________
Nashville____________
Virginia:
Norfolk________ ___________
Portsmouth___________________

Number Average hourly earnings
of plants
reporting
All plants 2
Range

Difference between
lowest-and highestpaying plants
Actual

Percent3

29

$0.56

$0.48- 0.69

$0. 21

44

5
8
4

.47
.49
.45

.40- .50
. 39- . 63
.44- . 45

. 10
.24
.01

25
62
2

4
10
4
16

.36
.46
.39
.39

.33.45. 35. 31-

. 46
. 49
. 40
. 50

. 13
.04
.05
. 19

39
9
14
61

14

.27

. 19- . 31

.12

63

12
8

.31
.35

. 24- . 40
. 28- . 40

. 16
. 12

67
43

10
4
7
8

.29
.21
.25
.44

. 24. 20. 20.37-

. 34
. 25
. 32
. 51

. 10
.05
.12
.14

42
25
60
38

8
6
6

.29
.26
.28

. 25- . 36
. 22- . 30
. 21- . 33

.11
.08
.12

44
36
67

• 6
10
7
4

.24
.24
.21
.22

. 20. 18. 17. 19-

. 32
. 39
. 27
. 34

. 12
.21
. 10
. 15

60
117
59
79

6
9
5

.30
.31
.25

. 28- . 35
. 26- . 39
. 22- . 29

.07
. 13
.07

25
50
32

10
4

.37
.41

. 28- . 45
. 30- . 46

. 17
.16

61
53

1 Lists only those cities in which 4 or more laundries were visited.
2 City averages take into account the number of women flatworkers in each plant.
* This represents the percent by which earnings in the highest-paying plant exceed those in the lowestpaying plant.

EARNINGS AND SIZE OF ESTABLISHMENT

Women’s earnings appeared to be unaffected by the size of the
laundry, measured by the total number of laundry production em­
ployees (men and women). When the plants were divided into two
groups of less than 50 and of 50 and more laundry production em­
ployees, and these groups compared, it was found that in the Middle
West a somewhat higher proportion of the smaller establishments
showed low earnings. But in the Southeast, it was the reverse—a
higher proportion of the larger units tended to be in the low-earnings
group.
Within each of the cities, the larger establishments sometimes paid
more, sometimes less than the smaller units. In a few cities, in each
region, the largest establishment showed the highest earnings, but in
several communities first place in earnings was taken by the smallest
laundry visited. In some places several of the city’s larger laundries
741469—47------4




18

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

reported earnings below the city average, and in several places the
lowest earnings were found in the largest establishment. Wage prac­
tices of employers therefore show it is feasible for both large and
small units to pay adequate wages.
INTERCITY VARIATIONS
DIFFERENCES BETWEEN TWO REGIONS

Laundries where hourly earnings averaged less than 40 cents, the
minimum established by the Federal Fair Labor Standards Act, were
infrequently found in the midwestern region, whereas most laundries
in the Southeast had average earnings under 40 cents. In the Middle
West, well over four-fifths of the establishments reported average
earnings of 40 cents or more. The relatively few plants with average
earnings below 40 cents were in Missouri, concentrated in St. Louis
and the smaller cities. Sharply contrasted was the southeastern
region where the situation was just the reverse. Here, laundries
with averages of 40 cents or more were the exception rather than the
rule. Less than one-fifth of them achieved average hourly earnings
as high as 40 cents, found primarily in Louisville and Hampton Roads,
a few in Jacksonville and Tampa, and one each in Charlotte and
Wilmington. All other establishments reported average earnings of
less than 40 cents.
Average earnings as high as 65 cents and over were found in the
Middle West in some Chicago laundries. But in the Southeast the
highest average was only 56 cents, found in one Virginia laundry.
In not one midwestern laundry did average earnings fall below 35
cents. On the other hand, three-fifths of the southeastern laundries
fell below this level, and almost one-fifth of these showed appallingly
low averages of 19 to 25 cents.
Average earnings in a city or an establishment do not give the
complete picture. A relatively high average may conceal very low
earnings received by individual women workers. Unless depressed
wages are wiped out entirely, a laundry cannot be classed among those
with adequate wage standards. Six of the 14 midwestern cities had
eliminated earnings below 40 cents—Chicago, Kansas City, and all
cities visited in Indiana except Indianapolis where only 5 percent of
the women earned under 40 cents.
Not one of the 24 southeastern cities equalled this standard.
Louisville, where only 9 percent of the women earned less than 40
cents, approached the higher wage-standard cities of the Middle West,
but in all other southeastern cities large proportions of the women
received less than 40 cents an hour. Substandard earnings were so
widespread that it was common to find, in city after city, over 80
percent of the women earning less than 40 cents. In contrast with
all 14 midwestern cities, where not 1 woman earned less than 30
cents an hour, most southeastern cities showed relatively large pro­
portions of women earning less than this substandard wage. In 2
of these cities, Greenville and Spartanburg, about 3 out of 10 women
averaged even less than 20 cents an hour.
The unreasonably low earnings received by women laundry workers
in southeastern cities stands in sharp relief against the information on




19

EARNINGS

net profit rates supplied by laundry owners themselves to their em­
ployer association. As was stated in the introductory chapter,
southern laundries averaged a higher rate of net profit than did laun­
dries in most other regions of .the country.
INTERCITY DIFFERENCES WITHIN EACH REGION

In the Middle West, Chicago stood out as a city in which women’s
earnings were far and away above those in all other cities. Here,
women averaged 61 cents an hour. Not one woman earned less than
45 cents, and some earned as much as $1 an hour. Among the larger
cities, Indianapolis ranked second to Chicago. Women in Indian­
apolis averaged 54 cents an hour, and 13 percent of them received less
than 45 cents. Kansas City and St. Louis followed next in line
among the larger cities, with averages of 47 and 44 cents, respectively.
Among the smaller cities, those in Indiana showed higher earnings than
small Missouri cities. Women in' each of the four smaller Indiana
cities averaged 46 cents or more and, in South Bend, as high as 55
cents. In contrast with Indiana, the six smaller Missouri cities
combined showed low average earnings of only 38 cents. The pro­
portions of women earning less than 40 cents ranged from about onethird in St. Joseph to almost 90 percent in Joplin.
Two localities, Louisville and Hampton Roads, grouped with the
southeastern cities, differed from the usual for this region. Louisville,
where women averaged 50 cents an hour, was the only southeastern city
in which no women earned less than 35 cents an hour. Earnings in the
Hampton Roads area averaged 42 cents an hour—a relatively low
wage standard, but one nevertheless that brought this locality up to
above-average for the region. Women laundry workers averaged
less than 40 cents an hour in each of the other southeastern cities
and in some of them, materially less. In Birmingham, for example,
women averaged only 30 cents, and in some cities of South Carolina
and Georgia averages fell as low as 24 to 29 cents.
In contrast with the Midwest where not one woman received less
than 30 cents, all southeastern localities except Louisville had vary­
ing proportions of women earning under this amount. Earnings in
many places were so low that sizable proportions of the women
received even less than 25 cents an hour.
Below are listed the cities in which one-fifth or more of the women
earned less than 25 cents an hour.
Percent earning
under 25 cents

City

Macon, Ga______
Greenville, S. C...
Spartanburg, S. C.
Columbus, Ga___
Columbia, S. C__
Charleston, S. C__
Savannah, Ga___
Nashville, Tenn_ .
Wilmington, N. C

.
.
.
.
.
.
.

65
60
59
50
37
35
28
21
21

At the other end of the scale are the higher-paid women employees.
But in the Southeast, even these workers rarely received more than
60 cents an hour.




20

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

EARNINGS AND SIZE OF CITY

Within each of the two regions, cities of less than 50,000 popula­
tion showed lower earnings than those of 50,000 and over. Among
the larger cities, however, there appeared to be no consistent relation
between size of city and earnings.
In 7 States, where 3 or more citie's of varying size were visited, it
was possible to compare earnings in large and small cities within the
State. The 2 large cities in Missouri, St. Louis and Kansas City,
showed substantially higher earnings than the 6 smaller communities.
In each of the other 6 States, however, the difference between the
large and small cities was not so clear cut. Indiana, for example,
showed that earnings in Indianapolis, the largest city, were consid­
erably higher than in each of 3 smaller cities, but were nevertheless
exceeded by earnings in South Bend, almost a fourth the size of
Indianapolis. Earnings in the 5 North Carolina cities, which vary
greatly in size, differed by no more than 3 cents. In 2 States, Georgia
and Tennessee, the smallest cities visited paid more than each of the
larger ones. For example, Brunswick, a city of only 11,000 popula­
tion, showed average earnings of 37 cents, above the 34-cent average
of Atlanta which was over 20 times its size. -Similarly, Knoxville,
about a third the size of Memphis, showed slightly higher earnings.
EARNINGS AND COST OF LIVING

Although a woman laundry worker living in Birmingham earned
about half what an Indianapolis worker earned, it did not mean that
her living costs were correspondingly lower. On the contrary, it
costs the average wage earner exactly the same thing to maintain
the same standard of living in each of these cities. Moreover, food
costs, an important item of expense, are higher in Birmingham than
in Indianapolis.
Often, persons seeking to justify low wages hit upon the defense
that living costs are lower in one city than another, hence workers
don’t need as much in wages. In evaluating such claims it is always
safe “to look at the record.” The record on living costs shows that
in 1945 a dollar went just as far in Indianapolis as it did in Birming­
ham or Savannah. The striking fact is that living costs differ only
slightly from one city to another, whereas earnings in one city might
be half what they are in another. The woman laundry worker in
southeastern cities, far from being able to buy more for less, simply
has to do without. What may be surprising to some is that 1945
living costs in each of six southeastern cities for which information
was available were higher than in Kansas City, but earnings of
women laundry workers were far lower. The following table shows
the relative differences in living costs from one city to another, in
terms of the cost to the average wage earner of maintaining the same
standard of living in each of these cities. The cost in Birmingham
is shown as 100, which means simply that, on the average, what
costs $1.00 in Birmingham costs no more nor less than $1.00 in
Indianapolis, costs $1.01 in Memphis, $1.07 in Chicago, and $0.99 in.
Kansas City.




21

EARNINGS

TABLE 5.—Relative Differences in the Cost of Equivalent Goods, Rents, and Services
in Selected Cities, March 1945,1 Compared to Average Hourly Earnings of Women
Production Workers in Power Laundries, July 1945

City

Chicago-------------St. Louis_____________________________
Atlanta________ ______________________
Jacksonville___________________________
Memphis*____________________________
Norfolk______________________________
Birmingham__________________________
Indianapolis_____________________
Savannah____________________ ________
Kansas City_

Average hourly
Living costs
earnings of women
(costs in
'production workers
Birmingham=100)
in laundries

■

107
103
101
101
101
101
100
100
100
99

$0.61
.44
.34
.37
.32
.42
. 30
.54
.31
.47

i The differences show how much more or less is required in one city than another to buy the items in a
typical budget for a city family in order to maintain a given level of living, that of the average wage earner.
The differences are duo primarily to differences in prices and rents and also to the influence of climate on
clothing and household requirements.

Table 5 shows the relative differences in living costs from one city
to another, but it does not show the actual dollar-and-cents costs.
For this important information it is necessary to turn to other sources.
To measure the adequacy of a wage in terms of dollars-and-cents
living costs, it is essential to know how much is earned a week or,
better yet, how much is earned a year. Although this type of infor­
mation was not obtained during the survey, the conclusion is ines­
capable that hourly earnings as low as those found in many places
cannot possibly enable these women to maintain a standard of living
of adequacy and health. Hourly earnings of 30 cents, for example,
yield $12 for a standard 40-hour week and $14.40 for a 48-hour week.
Even if the woman were to work 54 hours a week, 30 cents an hour
provides her with only $16.20 for this onerously long workweek.
Even a 40-cent rate yields only $16 for 40 hours, $19.20 for 48 hours,
and $21.60 for 54 hours.
How far short such earnings fall of the amount needed for a de­
cent, American standard of living can be seen from a comparison of
these earnings with actual living costs. According to surveys or
estimates made in 1945 or 1946 in widely separated States through­
out the country, a self-supporting working woman needs anywhere
from about $28 to about $35 a week, as a minimum, to live at an
adequate standard of living. A weekly wage of $12 a week doesn’t
foot the bill, nor does $21.60.
METHOD OF WAGE PAYMENT

'

The growing use of an incentive method of wage payment was re­
flected in the establishments visited. Some form of incentive pay
had been introduced in almost all the cities visited (32 of 38), but in
only 7 cities was a relatively high proportion of the women affected
by it. About three-fourths of the more than 13,000 women for whom
wage data were secured were paid on a time basis: some by the hour,
others by the week or day. Weekly workers, so-called, especially
prevalent in many southeastern cities, were considered weekly workers
by management, but they did not conform to the usual type of
weekly worker found in manufacturing establishments.




22

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

INCENTIVE METHOD

Wage-payment methods geared to output rather than horns worked
were of many types. Sometimes the workers were paid by the num­
ber of pieces or pounds produced, sometimes a piece rate was ap­
plicable only for units completed above a specified quota or standard,
or a bonus may have been paid for production of a particular stand­
ard and under prescribed circumstances. The payment may have
fluctuated with the production of an individual worker or of a group
(group incentive). Of the varieties of plans encountered, some had
been more or less scientifically installed and executed, and others
seemed to have been instituted without too much pre-planning.
Extent oj Use and Occupations Affected
Detailed information on the type of incentive plan in use was not
secured. It is therefore not possible to describe the operation of
these plans nor to measure their effectiveness either from the em­
ployer’s or employee’s point of view. In order to make such judg­
ments, it would have been necessary to make a comprehensive sur­
vey directed to this particular subject. The information obtained
permits only a simple classification of workers according to method
of wage payment and some broad comparisons between time and in­
centive workers’ earnings and production.2
Although only about one-fourth of all the women included in the
survey were paid on an incentive basis, all but 6 of the 38 cities
visited showed the use of incentive pay in one or more laundries. In
9 cities the proportion of women affected was relatively insignificant—
less than 10 percent of all in the city. But sizable groups of women
in 23 cities were paid on an incentive basis, a practice especially wide­
spread in 7 cities where between 40 and 60 percent of the women were
paid on this basis. Three of these cities were in the Middle West:
Chicago, St. Louis, and Evansville; and four were in the Southeast:
Memphis, Portsmouth, Newport News, and Charleston.
An incentive pay method was in operation in more than half the
laundries reporting pay-roll information (129 of 246) and was applied
most frequently to the shirtline operatives. Almost 90 percent of the
plants using such pay method had placed the shirtline under incentive.
Incentive systems were also used often for the other machine pressers. As a matter of fact, incentive pay methods were found in use
somewhere in every production occupation held by women. Mark­
ing, sorting, flatwork, and hand ironing occupations had some in­
centive workers in over 20 percent of the laundries where incentive
methods were practiced. In about a fourth of laundries using incen­
tive pay, only one occupation was affected, usually the shirtline.
Another fourth had such pay methods in operation for two occupa­
tions, usually the shirtline and other machine pressing. But about
half the plants using incentive pay had devised such systems for
three or more women’s occupations, and a few laundries paid all or
most of the women plant workers by such methods.
2 For comparison of production of time and incentive workers, see pp. 47-48




EARNINGS

23

A higher proportion of the larger plants used incentive pay than
of the smaller units, but a significant proportion of the small laundries
had adopted such pay methods, enough to indicate the practicability
of incentive pay in establishments of all sizes. On the shirtline, even
in plants where there were no more than a total of 4 or 5 shirt opera­
tives, incentive pay was frequently found in operation. ,
Effect on Earnings
.
Women workers paid under an incentive method generally earned
substantially more than time workers.3 Table 6 presents the earn­
ings of time and incentive workers in the same occupation in each
city where there was a sufficient number of both time and incentive
workers and of plants to justify comparison.
It is apparent that incentive workers did not enjoy the same degree
of advantage in each city, and in one city they actually earned less
than time workers. Among the shirtline operatives the earnings
difference in favor of incentive workers ranged from 6 percent in
Atlanta to 53 percent in Norfolk. Among other machine pressers,
another group to whom incentive pay was often applied, it was also
found that the margin favoring the incentive workers differed marked­
ly in different cities. Incentive machine pressers in Savannah and
Norfolk averaged 50 and 59 percent, respectively, more than time
workers, but in several cities the difference was under 10 percent.
Charleston was the only city encountered where incentive workers
averaged less than time workers.
The difference in earnings between time and incentive workers
would probably have been reduced if it had been possible to limit the
comparison to workers of the same degree of skill, experience, and
length of service and to job duties more exactly comparable from one
plant to another. Payroll evidence shows, for example, that new or
inexperienced workers are more apt to be paid on a time rather than
an incentive basis, thereby depressing the general average of time
workers’ earnings.
The establishment of an incentive system, though affording a
distinct earnings advantage to the workers affected, did not neces­
sarily eliminate substandard earnings. In several southeastern cities
the incentive systems had obviously been built on such low rates that
many incentive workers, presumably exerting additional effort to
increase their earnings, could not earn as much as 30 cents an hour.
There is no doubt that the level of earnings possible under an incentive
system has a direct effect on the success of the plan. Workers under
an incentive plan who do not stand a chance of earning a living wage
are not provided the stimulus essential to the plan’s success. That
many southeastern incentive plants did not match the productivity of
midwestern plants may have been partially caused by inadequate
wages.4
3 Average hourly earnings for time workers represent straight-time hourly rates. For incentive workers,
average hourly earnings were derived by dividing one week’s actual straight-time earnings (including all
incentive payments and production bonuses) by the actual number of hours worked during that week.
4 For discussion of productivity and method of wage payment, see pp. 47-48.




24

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

Table 6.—Comparison of Average Hourly Earnings of Time and Incentive Workers in
Selected Occupations, by City 1

Time

City

Incentive

Num­ Aver­ Num­ Aver­
age ber of age
ber of hourly
hourly
wom­ earn­ wom­
earn­
en
en
ings
ings

Percent
Percent
Time
Incentive
by
by
which
which
incen­
incen­
tive
Aver­
Aver­ tive
earn­ Num­ age Num­ age
earn­
ings
ber of hourly ber of hourly ings
exceed wom­
exceed
wom­
earn­
earn­ time
time
en
en
ings
ings earnings
earnings

SHIRTLINE OPERATIVES
Middle West:
Chicago, Til__ ______
Evansville, Ind
Indianapolis, Ind____
St. Louis, Mo
Southeast:
Atlanta, Ga
Birmingham, Ala____
Charleston, S. C_____
Charlotte, N. C_____
Columbia, S. C______
Greenville, S. C_____
Louisville, Ky
Memphis, Tenn
Norfolk, Va
Raleigh, N. C_______
Tampa, Fla

OTHER MACHINE PRESSERS

72
12
18
47

$0.58
.47
.50
.39

235
40
52
117

$0. 72
. 53
.60
.50

24
13
20
28

25
119

.32
.29

63
27

.34
.39

6
35

31

.30

30

.38

27

16
39
41

.49
.31
.36

36
141
32

.62
.33
.55

27
7
53

25

.37

23

.51

38

52

$0. 58

21

$0. 63

9

26
61

.52
.40

19
66

.72
.55

39
38

20

.33

62

.39

18

16
16
44
17
21
68
41
22
35

.35
.31
. 25
.23
.45
.33
.34
.29
.24

58
30
21
25
31
92
38
11
19

.27
.34
.34
.25
.63
.36
.54
.41
.36

-23
10
36
9
40
9
59
41
50

MARKERS
Middle West:
Chicago, 111-------------Indianapolis, Ind____
St. Louis, Mo
Southeast:
Louisville, Ky
Memphis, Tenn
Norfolk, Va

SORTERS

60
39
63

$0. 62
.53
.48

28
20
47

$0. 77
.64
.52

24
21
8

18
94
32

.47
.31
.41

24
74
16

.56
.34
.63

19
10
54

81

$0. 57

36

$0.68

19

97

.42

38

.45

7

55

.40

23

.62

55

FLATWORKERS
Middle West:
Chicago, 111__ ______
Indianapolis, Ind____
St. Louis, Mo
Southeast:

HAND IRONERS
•

348
91
179

$0. 53
.45
.36

193
49
102

$0. 62
.57
.44

17
27
22

88
110

.29
.35

129
51

.33
.42

14
20

16
13
45

$0.61
.47
.39

27
11
10

$0. 75
.62
.51

23
32
31

' Lists only cities in which 3 or more laundries show at least 10 time and 10 incentive women workers in the
selected occupation.

TIME METHOD

Although incentive pay methods appeared to be of increasing
importance in some occupations, time methods- continued to affect
most of the women workers, three-fourths of whom were paid on this
basis. Almost half of all plants surveyed used time methods only, and
virtually all of the others paid some of their women workers according
to time worked rather than output.
Time workers in manufacturing industries are usually paid by the
hour, and the employees themselves have no difficulty in under­
standing how their gross weekly earnings are calculated—the known




EARNINGS

25

hourly rate is multiplied by the hour’s actually worked. The rela­
tively few salaried workers in manufacturing, paid by the week,
month, or year, have a specified rate of pay, generally received in full
regardless of an occasional absence by the worker.
Not equally clear-cut is the classification of many laundry workers
in several southeastern cities. Almost all the time workers in the
midwestern cities were paid on the basis of an hourly rate, but in
several southeastern cities many of the women were designated by
their employers as weekly workers, particularly in some cities of the
Carolinas, Georgia, Florida, Tennessee, and Virginia.
Absence Deductions Jor Weekly Workers
On attempting to determine just how these so-called weekly workers
in the Southeast are paid, one finds that many are somewhat of an
anomaly, and that employers’ methods of calculating weekly pay are
of the type prohibited in industries covered by the Fair Labor
Standards Act. .Despite the fact that their employers consider them
weekly workers, many, aside from not being paid for overtime work,
are subjected to deductions for absences. Moreover, in several
cities, it appeared to be common practice to make a penalty deduction
for absence over and above what the employee would have earned had
she worked a full week.5 Comprehensive information on these
peculiar methods of making deductions was not obtained in every
laundry visited. However, sufficient, evidence was supplied by em­
ployers to throw light on the inequities of these practices. Aside
from the obvious injustice of these “penalty deductions” in principle,
they often affected low-paid workers, further whittling down an
already inadequate wage.
Illustrations of some of the practices found in use follow:
Saturday absence (reported in several cities and more frequently
than the other practices)—Despite the fact that the workweek
called for fewer hours on Saturday than on other days (usually
half-day on Saturday), the same amount was deducted for a
Saturday absence as for one on any other day; that is, one-sixth
of the week’s pay. For example, in one South Carolina laundry,
typical of several practicing this method, some flatworkers were
paid $9.50 for a 5)(-day, 45%-hour week. Saturday called for
4-hours’ work for which the employees actually earned 84 cents
($9.50 per week -=-45}i hours =$0.21 per hour; 4 hours x $0.21
per hour =84 cents). However, if this flatworkcr were absent on
Saturday, one-sixth of her $9.50 week’s pay was deducted, or
$1.58—a deduction almost twice the amount she would actually
have earned (84 cents) had she worked on Saturday.
Full Saturday pay contingent upon other attendance—Although the
employer may actually require his employees to work only half a
day or not at all on Saturday, pay for Saturday was calculated as
if it were a full day, and full payment was contingent upon the
s To calculate hourly earnings of these workers, for the purpose of presenting the wage data in this report,
the employee’s weekly rate of pay for a full-week’s work was divided by the number oi hours in the plant’s
standard workweek. The hourly rates of pay thus derived do not reflect, therefore, the penalty deductions
actually in use.
741469—47-------5




26

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

employee's attendance on other specified days of the week. In a
North Carolina laundry, for example, where employees usually
were not required to work on Saturday at all, an employee absent
on Friday lost one-third of her week’s pay (presumably for Friday
and Saturday) though she had failed to put in only one-fifth of
the time required of other workers. In another laundry a penalty
deduction was made even if the absence occurred on a day other
than Friday.
Flat-rate deduction jor absence—Another South Carolina laundry,
for example, deducted 40 cents an hour for all absences—an
amount which exceeded the workers’ 36-cent average hourly
earnings.
Weekly rate converted to penalty-hourly rate when absence occurred —
A Tennessee laundry with a 50-hour workweek paid its weekly
workers a flat weekly rate for 50 hours or more a week. Not only
were these employees not paid at all for overtime hours beyond
50 but, when absent, were paid on the basis of a lower hourly rate
and only for hours actually worked. In a week in which no over­
time was required, flatworkers, for example, were paid $12.50
for 50 hours, yielding 25 cents an hour. If the worker were
absent for any part of the week, she was paid at the rate of only
19 cents an hour for hours actually worked.
RECENT CHANGES IN METHOD OF WAGE PAYMENT

Employers were asked whether they had instituted a change in
method of wage payment since January 1942. Relatively few re­
ported a change affecting all or some employees—only 59—about
one-fourth of those whose laundries were visited. Among midwestern
laundries reporting a change, it was as likely to have been a shift
from a time to an incentive method as vice versa. In the southeastern
region, on the other hand, shifts from a time to an incentive basis
were much more prevalent than those from incentive to time.
When the change was from time to incentive, laundrymen generally
said it had been made to increase production. When the reverse
change was made, employers reported they had to discontinue incen­
tive pay because during the war years theyhad been using inexperienced
help who could not produce enough to earn a decent wage under an
incentive system. One employer also referred to the impracticability
of his incentive system under conditions of high turn-over and ab­
senteeism, and another said he had dropped incentive pay because he
did not have enough shirt business to keep the shirt operatives busy.
WAGE PROGRESSIONS

Single job rates characterized the practices in most of the laundries
visited. Relatively few made provisions for automatic rate increases
with length of service. About one-fourth of the establishments had
some form of automatic wage progression in effect. The progression
was generally limited to an entrance rate followed by an automatic
increase to a job rate after a specified length of service of usually about
1 month in the Midwest and 2 or 3 weeks or 1 month in the Southeast.




27

EARNINGS

WAGES AND PRODUCTIVE LABOR COSTS6

Adequate wages for women workers were not necessarily accom­
panied by high productive labor costs, nor did low wages assure low
productive labor costs. The American Institute of Laundering, on the
basis of cost information supplied them by 409 member laundries,
reported average productive labor costs of 35 percent in 1944; that is,
35 percent of receipts was expended on productive labor costs.
A sufficient number of employers in six cities reported information
on productive labor costs for the year ended 1944 so that a comparison
could be made of one city with another. Average costs were not
identical in these cities, nor did all correspond to the 35-percent na­
tional average reported by the American Institute of Laundering.
More significant, however, is the relationship of productive labor costs
to the average hourly earnings of women productive workers in these
cities. Chicago showed the lowest costs. Here, productive labor
costs consumed an average of 30 percent of revenue, but average hourly
earnings were highest in this city. Comparing Chicago with Mem­
phis, we find that Memphis, where productive labor costs averaged
only slightly more than in Chicago, showed average earnings about
half those of Chicago. Comparisons of other cities point to the same
conclusion. Average productive labor costs in Indianapolis and
Kansas City were almost the same, 34 and 35 percent, respectively,
but average hourly earnings differed substantially, being almost 15
percent higher in Indianapolis than in Kansas City. The six-city
comparison can be seen in table 7 in which the cities are listed in the
order of average productive labor costs expressed as a percent of
revenue.
Table 7.—Earnings of Women Productive Workers and Productive Labor Costs in Six
Cities
Number of Average
plants re­ productive
porting in­ labor costs
formation (percent)

City

Chicago____________ _____ _______ ______
Memphis_____ ___________________ .
Kansas City____________ __________
Louisville________ _______________ ____
St. Louis__________ __________ _____________

17
9

v......................

9

30

Average
hourly
earnings 1
$0.61

.44

1 In plants reporting productive labor costs.

Narrowing the comparison to individual laundries within the same
city, one comes upon many illustrations, not only of laundries whose
women had low earnings compared to the average for the city yet
whose productive labor costs were comparatively high, but also" of
laundries showing comparatively high earnings and low costs. The
following illustrations are typical. Laundries designated as plant
“A” reported higher earnings and lower costs than those shown as
plant “B.”
6 Productive labor costs, expressed as a percent of revenue, represent the percent which laundry productive
labor costs consumed of total laundry receipts. Dry-cleaning costs and receipts were excluded. This
percent does not show actual dollar costs, nor should it be confused with unit labor costs.




28

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES
City

Chicago_______
Indianapolis
Louisville

Plant

_____ ________________

_________ ________________

__________

Macon.. _.

. ________________

______ ________________

Norfolk____ _____ __
St. Louis_____ _____

_

______________
_________ _____ _

A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B
A
B

Productive
labor costs
(percent)

30
39
27
34
30
43
29
35
34
41
34
40

Average
hourly
earnings

$0.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.

73
55
61
55
55
41
30
23
43
30
49
39

From the foregoing comparisons and from table 7 it can be seen
that productive labor costs are obviously influenced by factors other
than the wage level of productive workers, most of whom arc women.
A Virginia laundry owner whose 1944 productive labor-costs ratio
was lower than in 1941 attributed the reduction directly to the vastly
improved production methods and more modern equipment instituted
after a study revealed that many production bugs could be ironed out.
In 1944 the laundry did a substantially higher volume of business
with fewer employees than in 1941. Productivity increased substan­
tially as did employee’s earnings.
Laundry owners, expressing themselves through their own trade
journals, have similarly declared that good wage standards can stim­
ulate the attainment of efficiencies so necessary in the industry. An
editorial in the May 1945 issue of the American Laundry Digest stated
that—
“Laundry owners should remember that higher wages do not
necessarily mean higher labor costs. In well operated plants
higher wages have acted as a spur to management, and low*er
labor costs have resulted. This has meant that higher wages
have not come out of profits but out of increased production.”
LAUNDRY EARNINGS COMPARED WITH EARNINGS IN OTHER
INDUSTRIES

The 1945 wage level of women laundry workers in any one city did
not evolve in a vacuum. It has been influenced by a variety of forces
among which is the prevailing wage level for women in other industries
of the same city. Competition in a labor market area for the available
labor supply sets up a cross-current of influences affecting the wage
level of all industries in the area. Such competition is of more
limited effect in the South, however, because of the restricted employ­
ment opportunities of Negro women workers, hired readily for many
laundry jobs but only for a few jobs or not at all in other industries.
It is significant to see how women’s laundry earnings stack up
against earnings in other industries. Information on women’s earn­
ings is available for one or more other industries in 12 of the cities
visited during the laundry survey. As table 8 shows, women’s earn­
ings in laundries generally came closer to approximating those in
limited-price stores (5 anil 10’s) than these in any other industry.
Women workers in department stores and clothing stores usually
earned substantially more than in laundries. Manufacturing earnings
in industries important to women in each city were far and away
above those in laundries.




Table 8.—Comparison of Average Hourly Earnings of Women Production Workers in Power Laundries With Earnings in Other Industries in the Same City
Average hourly earnings of women
Retail trade 1

City

Power
Depart­
laundries Limitedprice
ment
stores
stores

July
1945

April
1945

Cloth­ Cotton Seam­ Wood Cotton Women’s Men’s
furniture work
and
and boys’
ing
less
(not up­ pants misses’
dress
stores textile hosiery holstered)
dresses
shirts
April
1945

$0, 30

$0.35

$0.63

$0. 57

.37
.39
.34
.50

.38
.34
.38
.41

.47
.52
.50

.50
.61

.34
.33
.26

.34

.36
.32
.32
.61

.35
.38
.32
.47

April
1946

.47
.58

.68

.83

1 Based on information obtained from employers by the Bureau of Labor Statistics,
U. S. Department of Labor,




October
1945

$0.69
$0. 72
.76
.70

.51
.54

Janu­
ary
1946

$0.57
.64
.54

April
1945

$0.50

April
1945

.45
.75

April
1945

1.06

.

$0.68 (cigarettes)

$0. 55
.53

(?)

$0.82 (cigars)

$0.72

.51

Other

.65

$0.79 (full-fashioned hosiery)
$0.58 (wood furniture, upholstered)

$0.55
$0.81
$0.80
$0.64
$0.82

EARNINGS

Alabama: Birmingham__
Florida:
Jacksonville______
__ ______
Tampa___ _____
Georgia: Atlanta
Kentucky: Louisville... _________
North Carolina:
Charlotte. . . _.
Winston-Salem_______________
South Carolina: Greenville____ .
Tennessee:
Knoxville ..............................
Memphis_______
Nashville . _____
Illinois: Chicago_____________ _____

April
1945

Manufacturing 1

(tobacco and snuff)
(radios and equipment)
(footwear)
(boxes, set-up)
(gloves)

1 Pay-roll dates as follows; January 1945—Radios and equipment; July 1945—Gloves;
August and October 1945—Footwear; October 1945—Wood furniture (upholstered),
Boxes (set-up); January 1946—Cigars, Cigarettes, Tobacco and snuff, Full-fashioned
hosiery.

to

CO

CHAPTER IV. PRICES
LAUNDRY SERVICES

Familiarity with the services offered by laundries is essential to an
understanding of their pricing practices. Most family laundries sell
several types of services, offered under a variety of names.
PRINCIPAL TYPES OF SERVICE

A bachelor bundle is usually composed of shirts and other items that
are completely finished and mended. All items are priced individually,
by the piece, rather than at pound rates as in most other services.
This type of service is also known as “custom work,” “piecework,”
“list price work,” or “bundle work.”
In a damp-wash service (often called “wet wash”), all items are
washed, extracted, and returned damp. The customer must iron the
laundry.
The several semi-finish services are known by various trade names,
such as, “fluff dry,” “rough dry,J’ and “soft dry.” In a semi-finish
service the flatwork is ironed, and the wearing apparel, after being
washed and dried, is returned to the customer for ironing. Another
type of semifinish service, generally known as “thrifty,” also calls for
ironed flatwork, but the wearing apparel is returned damp instead
of dry, as in the other types.
Tli c familyfinish service offers washing and ironing of all articles in
the bundle. In the less expensive type, everything is completely
machine-finished and ready for use, while the more expensive type (a
deluxe service) also includes hand touch-up (hand ironing) and some­
times mending.
A rate per pound is usually charged for the above services (except
bachelor bundle), and a bundle of a specified minimum size is generally
required. In each of the pound-price services, except frequently
family-finish, shirts are generally finished at an extra charge. Indi­
vidual laundries may offer one, more, or all the services and may or
may not offer delivery service. Some laundries are exclusively of the
“pick-up and deliver” type, whereas others are exclusively of the
“drive-in” or “walk-in” type offering all their services on a cashand-carry basis and may or may not have different sets of prices
for each.
WARTIME REGULATIONS ON SERVICE AND PRICES

In common with many other industries, power laundries experienced
shortages during the war, of labor, materials, and equipment, which
necessarily limited the quality and types of service that could be
provided the public. Government regulations on prices, transporta­
tion, and manpower also affected the services offered. Inasmuch as
30




PRICES

31

information was secured on conditions in effect in July 1945, a month
before VJ-day, the services then offered were influenced by wartime
controls.
The Office of Price Administration permitted the elimination of
many practices, called “frills,” without corresponding price decreases.
Among them were the discontinuance of hand finishing on machinepressed articles, the ironing of handerchiefs in the semifinish services,
mending, special starching, and the delivery of list-price bundles
priced under $1. Under OPA regulations, laundry prices were frozen
at the March 1942 level. Price relief was granted to individual laun­
dries when management return 1 fell below 8 percent of sales or in
other specified circumstances. In Chicago, area-price relief (applica­
ble to all laundries) was granted, but in the other cities visited only
individual establishments, upon application and approval, were
allowed to increase prices. Price relief, when granted, was generally
expressed as a percentage of existing prices. The approved increase
was added as a surcharge to each customer’s bill, first totaled accord­
ing to previous prices.
The industry was also affected by regulations of the War Manpower
Commission which set up requirements for laundries to meet before
they could be declared essential or “locally needed,” thereby assuring
themselves some measure of stability in retaining workers. Estab­
lishments wishing to be classified as “locally needed” were required,
among other things, to offer a maximum of three services—wet
wash, semifinish or rough dry, and press or family finish; to eliminate
hand ironing, retouching of flatwork and wearing apparel, and ironing
of articles already dry-tumbled; to do all starching in the wash wheel
(rather than as a process separate from washing) and to use only one
grade of starch; to discontinue the use of shirt boards and other
packaging frills; and to reduce labor requirements for pick-up and
delivery service by establishing nonoverlapping delivery zones and a
7-day delivery schedule for semifinish and family finish services, that
is, simultaneous pick-ups and deliveries once a week in any zone.
Regulations of the Office of Defense Transportation materially
affected the delivery service of laundries which, among other require­
ments, had to reduce mileage of their motor trucks; were not allowed
to make special deliveries, call-backs, or more than one delivery a
day at the same point of destination; and were required to eliminate
wasteful and duplicating delivery operations.
WARTIME CHANGES IN SERVICE

Among the establishments included in this survey, family finish
was the service most frequently eliminated during the war by laundries
reporting a change in basic services. Many discontinued it entirely,
and a few reported that they limited the amount of family-finish work
by discouraging customer requests for this service or by accepting
only, a certain amount. Laundering of curtains was quite generally
eliminated, and a few laundrymen also reported they had discon­
tinued laundering silks, rayons, rugs, blankets, spreads, pillows, and
handkerchiefs. Some laundries did not iron bath towels, fancy work,
overalls, or socks.
1 Defined as profit before provisions for executive salaries and Federal income taxes.




32

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

Changes reported in processing usually related to the starching
process—only one grade of starch, and starching done directly in the
“wheel.” A few also said they had increased the wash loads, cut
washing time, eliminated bleaching, and discontinued tumbling towels.
Wartime changes in packaging, corresponding to the standards set
up by the War Manpower Commission, were chiefly the elimination
of the use of shirt boards, boxes, tissue paper, and cellophane
wrappings. Some laundries were unable to get collar supports.
Delivery-service changes were reported by practically all the
laundries visited. Service was most often limited to once weekly in
any one zone, but in some laundries twice weekly was possible.
Routes were consolidated, and outlying deliveries were discontinued.
Many laundry owners hailed the changes resulting from Government
war controls on delivery service as a boon to the industry and, for the
most part, would like to continue, in peacetime, the delivery practices
adopted during the war. Some owners reported substantial cuts in
delivery costs because of the consequent reduction in force and
diminished consumption of gasoline and oil; others asserted that the
curtailed delivery service and regulated pick-ups had benefited their
establishments by stabilizing the flow of work during the course of
the week and by increasing operating efficiency.
Concerning the other services curtailed or discontinued during the
war, a few owners mentioned that complete services would be restored
after the war; others indicated the services would be resumed only in
response to community demand or on condition that the labor supply
would be adequate. Particular methods of packaging, providing
so-called “frills” (mending, special starching, folding, and laundering
of curtains),, and complete family-finish work were described, in some
laundries, as deficit-producing services not to be resumed in peacetime
SERVICES SELECTED FOR PRICE-ANALYSIS

Information was obtained from laundry owners on prices in effect
July k945, the same date as the pay-roll week used for the wage
information. Only three basic prices have been selected for analysis—the list price of men’s shirts, the pound price of damp-wash service,
and the pound price of family-finish service, of the “budget” or
“economy” type if more than one family-finish service was offered.
These prices have been chosen because they represent basic services
that are relatively comparable from one laundry or city to another,
though undoubtedly some differences exist between one laundry and
another in the quality of processing and service. Prices for semi­
finished work have been excluded because differences from plant to
plant may represent differences in type of service rather than price
differences for the same service.
Only prices quoted for service which includes pick-up and delivery
have been selected. Cash-and-carry prices have, therefore, been
excluded. This exclusion should not be interpreted, however, as an
attempt to minimize the noticeable development in the industry of
cash-and-carry trade. Some cash-and-carry business was done by
almost every laundry included in the survey, and a few laundries
operated on this basis exclusively.
Each of the three prices selected may not be equally significant in
every laundry. Obviously, a family-finish price is more important




PRICES

33

in a laundry specializing in this service than in one catering to dampwash business. Information was not collected on the distribution of
business among the various services in the laundries surveyed. This
would be influenced by such factors as the type of city in which the
laundry is located and the type of clientele served by the establish­
ment. The prices used, however, are sufficiently basic to be indicative
of price practices.
METHODS OF PRICING

There are two types of laundry prices—list prices and pound
prices. List prices are those charged for each individual item and
applied to articles in a bachelor bundle. A few laundries also use
this method of pricing for family-finish work. Most laundries charge
pound rates for family bundles, whether they are to be damp-washed,
semifinished, or completely finished. A minimum price is usually
quoted for each of these services, and the same minimum applies to a
bundle of a specified number of pounds or less. For each pound
above the minimum size, a flat, pound price is added. Generally the
additional pound price is lower than the pound rate in the minimumsize bundle, to induce the customer to send a large bundle.
In the damp-wash service, the pound price of flatwork is the
same as that of wearing apparel. In a semifinished bundle, flatwork,
which is finished, costs more per pound than does wearing apparel,
which is only washed and dried. In a completely finished bundle,
the pound price of wearing apparel is generally higher than that of
flatwork; and most laundries specify the maximum percentage of
wearing apparel that will be accepted in a family-finish bundle.
Methods of pricing shirts are somewhat complex. When shirts
are included in a list-price service, they are charged for at the list
price. However, when shirts are included in the damp-wash or semi­
finish services, the true total price of each shirt is composed of two
charges. Shirts accompanying several types of family bundles are
weighed with the bundle, and the applicable pound price of the
requested service is charged for the shirts as well as for all other
articles in the bundle. In addition, an extra charge (usually lower
than the list price) is made for each shirt. This additional charge
may be a fixed price applicable to all but list-price bundles. It is
thus evident that the true total price of shirts accompanying family
bundles varies according to the type of service requested for other
articles in the bundle. For example, pound prices for damp wash
are far lower than for semifinish. Shirts included in each of these
two services, though processed identically, will nevertheless usually
have a higher total price in a semifinish than in a damp-wash bundle.
This inconsistency in price setting is further complicated by the fact
that the total shirt price in one or more of the family bundles may not
be the same as the laundry’s list price of shirts. Moreover, laundries
in most cities do not make an additional charge for shirts accompany­
ing family-finish bundles. Instead, the applicable pound rate for
wearing apparel is often charged for shirts as well as for other items of
apparel. This creates another shirt price in the same laundry. Some
laundries have as many as four or five different prices for shirts,
although all are processed in exactly the same way.




34

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

It is evident that laundries offer several types"of service with a
variety of trade names and price-setting methods likely to be confusing
to the public. Aware of this situation, several industry spokesmen
are in agreement on the need for greater standardization of services
and simplification of pricing methods.
COMPUTATION OF PRICES

Because of the varieties of methods used by laundries in setting
prices, it was necessary to translate these prices into a unit which would
be comparable from one laundry to another. The prices selected for
analysis, as quoted for pick-up and delivery service, were computed as
follows:
Shirt price: represents the list price of laundering and finishing
one (man’s) shirt. The use of the list price has the disadvantage
of not being of equal significance in each laundry, because one
laundry may do a high volume of shirt business at list price,
whereas another may do its volume shirt business at any one of
the several types of family-bundle price. The list price has the
advantage, however, of being comparable from one laundry to
another.
Damp-wash price: represents the price of 1 pound of laundry
in a damp-wash (wet-wash) service, computed on the basis of
how much the customer would pay per pound if she were to send
a 20-pound bundle to the laundry. A 20-pound bundle was used
because this was the highest minimum-weight bundle specified
among the laundries surveyed.
Family-finish price: represents the price of 1 pound of laundry
in a regular family-finish service, computed on the basis of how
much the customer would pay per pound if she were to send a
16-pound bundle, consisting of 60 percent flatwork and 40 per­
cent wearing apparel, which represents the average family-finish
bundle, according to the American Institute of Laundering. To
make allowance for those establishments making an additional
charge for shirts, four shirts were included in the average bundle.
In laundries offering more than one type of family-finish service,
the price of the less expensive service was used.
OPA price relief: the prices used for each of the above items
take into account price increases, when granted by OPA, in effect
on the date for which pay-roll information was furnished.
Prevailing price: this term is used in this report to designate the
price most commonly charged in a city for any of the above
services.
ANALYSIS OF PRICE STRUCTURE

Aside from the complexities and inconsistencies in price-setting
methods, analysis of the actual prices in effect July 1945, yields some
fairly general observations applicable to almost all cities visited.
Prices for each service were relatively uniform among laundries in
any one city, a tendency only somewhat more pronounced in smaller
than in larger cities. The size of a laundry or the size of the city in
which a laundry was located, did not appear to affect prices. The




PRICES

35

geographic location of the city appeared to have no effect on the list
price of shirts, only slight effect on the pound price of damp wash,
but a somewhat greater effect on the pound price of family finish.
GENERAL PRICE UNIFORMITY WITHIN CITY

Due either to competition or to trade agreement, prices within a
city tended to be identical in all or most laundries. While there might
be considerable difference between the prices charged by the lowest
charging and the highest charging laundry, usually most establish­
ments within a city charged identical prices or prices only slightly
different from one another. This practice was not peculiar to the
Southeast or Midwest, nor to cities of any particular size. Rather, it
was characteristic of most cities. In Chicago, for example, the list
price of shirts varied from 16 to 25 cents, but 20 of 22 laundries all
^charged the same price—16 cents. Similarly, the pound price of
damp wash was identical in all but one laundry, and that of family
finish was identical in all offering this service. Price identity was
especially marked in 6 cities where not even 1 laundry deviated from
the city’s prevailing price for each of the three services analyzed.2
From this observation of price uniformity within a city, it is obvious
that the size of the establishment did not influence prices. In a city
as large as Memphis, for example, where establishments differed
greatly in size from one with a total of less than 50 to another with
almost 500 employees, all charged the same prices. Only a few cities
did not conform to this pattern of price standardization.
It would appear that price standardization within a city would
have been even more widespread than was found in effect were it not
for the fact that price relief, approved on the basis of profit, was
granted generally to individual laundries, rather than to groups of
laundries. Prices in establishments granted relief, previously per­
haps in line with others in the city, consequently varied from the city’s
prevailing price.
Comparison of price characteristics in 8 cities included among those
surveyed by the Women’s Bureau in 1934 and in 1945 demonstrates
that price standardization, already in evidence in 1934, has since
become more pronounced, particularly in Chicago and Memphis.
LIST PRICE OF SHIRTS

The list price of men’s shirts appeared to be particularly rigid, not
only within a city but also from city to city. The single price most
frequently charged was 15 cents—the prevailing price in over half the
cities visited. Almost two-thirds of all the laundries charged 15 to
16 cents for finishing a man’s shirt at list price. There was a group
of southern laundries, however, concentrated in Columbia, Jackson­
ville, and Macon, which charged only 12 cents, and in some scattered
cities 18 cents was the prevailing price.
Shirt prices apparently do not respond readily to changing economic
conditions. When the Women’s Bureau made its 1934 survey of
power laundries located throughout the country, it found that the
prevailing price was 15 cents in 13 of the 22 cities covered at that time.
A 15-cent price continued to be popular in 1945.3
2 The six cities are Evansville, Lafayette, Memphis, Springfield, Tampa, and Wilmington. In the city
of Columbia, too, all laundries charged the same price for shirts and for family finish; the pound price of
damp wash differed by only 2 mills.
3 It should be remembered that 1945 prices in most laundries represented prices frozen at 1942 levels.




Table 9.—Retail Prices of Selected Laundry Services, by City 1
List price of shirts
City

Range
of prices
(cents)

22

16-25

Prevail­
ing price
(cents)

Pound price of damp wash a
Number Number
of plants of
plants
charging
prevail­ report­
ing
ing price

Pound price oi family finish 3

Number
Prevail­ of plants Number
ing price charging of plants
(cents)
prevail­ report­
ing
ing price

Range
of prices
(cents)

Range
of prices
(cents)

Prevailing
price (cents)

Number
of plants
charging
prevail­
ing price

Middle West: .

South Bend___ ______ ____
Missouri:

16

5
8
2
2
4

15
14-15.3
15
18
15.9 & 16.2

15
14
15
18
15.9

4
10
4
14

15
13. 4-18.8
13.7-18
11. 4-20

15
14.6-15.5
18
12.5
15

20
6
2
3
4
6
8

27
7

5.6 & 5.7

5.6

5

2

5
5 & 5.7 l
6. 4 & 6. 5
l1

,

4 & 4.1

3
11
3

5 & 5! 6
4. 5-6. 3

8

5-7.8

5
6
5

26

5.7
6.4

1 }
1
3

4

2 I
2

4.1
5.6
4. 5-4.8

13

5
7

21

21

17.4
14.6-15.9
16

«

4
5
2

17. 2 & 17.3

2

12.5
12.5 & 13.6 lf
13.6
11. 5-20.2
14. 2-14. 4
12. 5-14.4
12. 5 & 13
14-21.3
(5)
14. 2
14.2

2
4
2

„

17.2 & 17.3
4

6

12

13

17.4
15. 4
16

2

Southeast:
Florida:
Georgia:

Brunswick.............. .................
Savannah.......................... ......




13

10-16.8

15-15.9

11
5

12 & 15
15

12
15

10

15 & 16. 4

15

2
2
4
5
7

15
15
12 & 15
15
12. 2-18. 9

15
15
12
15
15

10

5-5.3

8
5

6

12

12.8-J6. 6

6

12

11. 6-14. 2
12.8

10

14.4-15. 7

4& 5
2
5

4
7

5& 5.2 5 & 5.2
4&5
5
5-4. 8
4. 5-5.8 lf 4.
5. 5-5.8

2
3
3

0

f
l

12.2
12.8

5
4

14.4
15.4
15.7

4
3
3

11.6

5

w
<•)
11.6
7

13-19.1

(*)

W O M EN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

Number
of plants
report­
ing

CO

North Carolina:
Charlotte______ __________
Raleigh....................................
Wilmington---------------------Winston-Salem.................... .
South Carolina:
Charleston...............................
Columbia.................................
Greenville________________
Spartanburg______________
Tennessee:
Knoxville....... -.......................
Memphis..___ ___________
Nashville ------- ------- ------Virginia:
Newport News........................
Norfolk ________________
Portsmouth

8
7
6
3
6
11
7
4
7
9
6
2
10
4

15-16.1
15 & 16. 7
18
15 & 16

15
15
18
16

6
6
6
2

7

5-5.4

5

6
3

6
5

6
5

5
6
6
3

4
6
6
2

13-15.1
12. 8-14. 8
16
14 & 14.5

13-7 & 14
(6)
16
14 & 14. 5

6
2

‘15
12
15
10 & 15

15
12
15
15

6
11
7
3

6
5
3

4 & 4.2
5&6
5&6

4.2
5
5

4
4
2

5
11
5
4

12. 2 & 13
10
10.8 & 13
11.6 & 12.2

12.2
10
13
12.2

4
11
4
3

15
15
16-16.6

i
9
3

5
9

5&6
4.2
5-6

5
4.2
5-5.4

4
9

4
9
6

/ 13 * 13.6
13 -15. 7 1 15.1 & 15. 7
14.4
14.4
(5)
13. 9-16

2
2
9

18
16
15

2
8
4

2
8
4

5
5-6
4.8-7

(5)

2

2
10
4

13 & 16.8
14
14

2
10
3

15
15
16-18. 4
18
15 & 16
15




5

2

16 & 16. 8
14
14 & 15. 3

N. B. Prevailing price: designates that price most commonly charged in a city, gen­
erally by half or more of the plants. In cities in which there is no single prevailing price
and in which prices in at least half or more of the plants fall within a narrow range (of
less than $0,005 for damp wash and of less than $0.01 for shirts and for family finish), this
range is shown as the prevailing price. In those few cities in which two or three different
prices, rather than one price or one narrow range, are almost equally common, these
prices are shown.
.

PRICES

1 Based on prices quoted for pick-up and delivery service. City and/or price not shown
where only 1 plant reported.
* Based on price per pound of a 20-pound bundle.
J Based on price per pound of a 16-pound bundle of 60 percent flatwork and 40 percent
wearing apparel including 4 shirts.
4 Only one plant reported.
1 Prices vary too much to report any as prevailing.

5

2

CO

38

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

POUND PRICE OF DAMP WASH

Almost tho same degree of uniformity within a city was found in
prices of damp-wash bundles as was found in shirt prices. On com
paring the price level itself in different cities, one finds that 5 cents a
pound is most popular in southeastern laundries, whereas a slightly
higher price, 5 to 6 cents, is characteristic of the Middle West.
This service was not offered in over a fifth of the laundries visited,
many of which had not offered it even before the war. Possibly the
increased use of washing machines in the home may reduce the demand
for this type of service from commercial laundries.
POUND PRICE OF FAMILY FINISH

This price, much more than either of the others, appeared to be
sensitive not only to the conditions within the establishment itself
but also to the characteristics of the city. Ability of the customer to
pay appeared to affect price, whereas the influence of this factor was
hardly noticeable in the price level of shirts and only slightly evident
in damp-wash prices.
In 30 cities where 2 or more laundries offered this service, 16 showed
price standardization, but in each of the other 14 cities prices among
competing laundries generally differed from one another. Many
more cities showed standardization on prices of shirts and of damp
wash.
Unlike prices of other services, there was no single family-finish
price that was charged by a large proportion of the laundries. Prices
in southeastern cities were generally lower than in the Middle West.
About three-fourths of the southeastern laundries charged less than
15 cents a pound, but some two-thirds of those in tho Middle West
quoted 15 cents or more. Prices as low as 10, 11, or 12 cents a pound
were quoted in several southern laundries but only rarely, if ever,
were found in the Middle West. Relatively popular prices in the
Southeast were about 12 or 14 cents, but in the Middle West they
were about 14, 15, or 17 cents. The prevailing price in Chicago was
21 cents, higher than in any other city surveyed.
Among the wartime effects on laundry service discussed earlier
was the elimination of family-finish service—in about one-sixth of the
establishments visited. Apparently the relatively high cost of
finishing wearing apparel, coupled with the shortage of labor, induced
some laundries to dispense with this service.
PRICE AND SIZE OF CITY

There were no consistent differences between prices charged in
larger cities and those in smaller cities of the same State. Prices in
the smaller cities were often as high as or higher than those in the
larger cities. Sometimes the situation was reversed. In Indiana the
prevailing prices of shirts and of family finish were higher in each of
the smaller cities than in Indianapolis. Similarly, in South Carolina,
prices in the smaller cities were higher than in Columbia. In Georgia,
however, Atlanta’s prices for shirts and for damp wash were about the
same as in the smaller cities, but prices for family finish were sub­
stantially higher in Atlanta than elsewhere in the State.
•
SUMMARY

Table 9 presents the price information supplied by employers
which formed the factual basis for the preceding analysis.




PRICES

39

PRICES AND EARNINGS
OVER-ALL RELATIONSHIP

In order to determine the exact relationship between prices charged
the customer and earnings received by employees, it would be neces­
sary to convert all prices in an establishment, on the basis of business
done at each price, into a single price unit comparable to what the
average hourly earnings figure represents for employees’ wages. To
secure this type of information would have required far more intense
study of each individual plant than was undertaken in this survey.
Some general and rather crucial conclusions can nevertheless be drawn
from the available information.
Although, on the whole, there was a slight tendency for higher
prices to accompany higher earnings, so many laundries deviated
from this tendency as to warrant the conclusion that higher prices
were not an inevitable concomitant of higher earnings.
DEVIATIONS FROM OVER-ALL RELATIONSHIP

One has only to compare the lack of wage standardization within
a city with the highly developed price standardization to realize that
many laundries paying lower wages than others capitalize on the ad­
vantage of charging the same prices. In practically every city largo
enough to support several laundries, some establishments paid higher
wages without charging higher prices than competitors in the same
city. To allow some employers to undercut wages while adhering to
the city’s standard prices constitutes unfair competition. Such prac­
tices are a constant threat not only to wage standards but also to the
industry’s stability.
Observations of the earnings and prices actually in existence among
competing laundries in the same city demonstrate that good wage
standards do not inevitably mean high prices. Efficiencies in man­
agement and operating methods and increased productivity can often
enable employers to pay adequate wages without proportionate in­
creases in prices. While sometimes higher earnings were reported in
laundries quoting higher prices, it was not uncommon to find that higher
earnings went hand in hand with lower prices.
In addition to the wage-price situation within a city, the relation­
ship between one city and another should be considered. Such a
city-to-city comparison lends supporting evidence to the observation
described previously-—that higher earnings do not necessarily cause
higher prices. Sometimes they went together, but practices in several
cities prove that they need not. For example, prevailing prices for
each of the three services studied were identical in two South Carolina
cities, but in one of them, Charleston, the 34-cent average earnings of
women workers were 7 cents higher than in the other, Spartanburg.
Even more conclusive is evidence provided by the cities in which prices
were lower but earnings higher than in the others. Prices in both
Springfield, Mo., and Portsmouth, Va., were substantially lower than




40

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

in Wilmington, N. C., but women’s earnings were considerably higher.
Similarly, Jacksonville, Fla., charged less and women earned more
than in Greenville, S. C.
EARNINGS IN SPECIFIC OCCUPATIONS RELATED TO PRICES

Further evidence that prices do not always reflect wages was found
in comparing prices for two services with earnings in two occupa­
tions-—earnings which might be expected to influence price. The
list price of shirts was compared with earnings of shirt operatives, and
the pound price of family finish was compared with earnings of ma­
chine pressers, who finish the wearing apparel in family-finish bundles.
It is recognized, of course, that even in plants or industries of rela­
tively well rationalized price structure unit labor costs of a specific
item are not necessarily covered by the price of that item but, instead,
may be defrayed, for a variety of reasons, by prices of other items.
Despite this accepted business practice, it is nonetheless striking to
observe the relatively minor influence earnings in these occupations
exercise on price.
Within each region earnings tended somewhat to be higher in
laundries quoting higher prices. More significant, however, are the
marked variations in earnings in laundries charging the same price.
Tables 10 and 11 group those laundries quoting the same price for
a service and show the differences in earnings in these same laundries.
For example, midwestern laundries charging a 15-cent list price for
shirts reported average hourly earnings of shirt operatives ranging
from a low of '34% cents in one laundry to a high of 57/ cents in
another. Compare this with the Southeast. Here, laundries charg­
ing the same price, 15 cents, showed shirt operatives’ earnings which
averaged only 19 cents in one plant but climbed all the way up to
68 cents in another. The variations in earnings among laundries
charging another popular price, 16 cents, were just as striking, if not
more so.
The same observation holds true when earnings of machine pressers
are examined in relation to the pound price of a family-finish bundle.
Admittedly, the entire problem of establishing a rational relation­
ship between prices and wages does not yield itself readily to quick
solution of a-b-c simplicity. Worthy of mention is the future course
suggested by one industry spokesman in a manual written to guide
war veterans interested in establishing a laundry. Glancing at the
industry’s postwar problems, this spokesman looks toward a period
of lower prices, a fair profit, and a 60-cent minimum wage for women
workers.4
4 See: Victor Kramer, Establishing and Operating a Laundry. U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau
of Foreign and Domestic Commerce. U. S. Government Printing Office, Washington, 1946. pp. 189,190.




Table 10.—Comparison of Average Hourly Earnings of Women Shirtline Operatives With List Price of Shirts, by Region

Average hourly earnings

Percent distribution...
Average hourly earn-

Middle West

Southeast

Number of plants in which list price of shirts was—
Num­
ber of
plants
25
12 H
16
18
19
20
14
15
13
report­ 11
ing
cents cents cents cents cents cents cents cents cents cents

Number of plants in which list price of shirts was—
Num­
ber of
plants
18
19
16
17
12
13
14
15
report­ 10
11
ing
cents cents cents cents cents cents cents cents cents cents

78
100

1
1

8
10

2
3

10
13

24
31

23
30

7
9

1
1

1
1

1
1

$0. 53 $0. 45 $0. 51 $0. 48 $0. 51 $0. 44 $0. 04 $0. 53 $0. 49 $0. 55 $0. 80

1

1
1
3

1

1
4
2
1 Based on prices quoted for pick-up and delivery service.

1
2
3
3
1

1
6
6
8
1
2

1
3
0
2
6
1
1
3
2
2

1
3
1
1
1

1

1

1

137
100

2
1

$0.36 $0. 23
1
15
20
45
24
9
5
9
5
1
2
1

2

10
7

1
1

$0. 33 $0.32 $0. 21 $0. 36 $0. 40 $0.31 $0. 33

$0.50

22
16

4
5
6
4
1
1
1

1
1

1
1

1
1

74
54

1
7
9
23
15
5
4
6
3
1

22
16

4
8
2
2
1
1
2
1
1

4
3

1
3

1
1
4
3
1
1

PRICES

1
9
12
18




1

Table 11.—Comparison of Average Hourly Earnings of Women Machine Pressers With Price per Pound of Family-Finish Service, by Region1

Average hourly earnings-

Southeast

Number of plants in which pound price of family-finish service
was—
Num­
ber of
plants 11,
20,
12,
13,
14,
15,
16,
17,
report­ under under
under under under under under 18 under 21
ing
18 cents 21 cents
12
10
13
14
15
17
cents
cents cents cents cents cents cents cents

Number of plants in which pound price of family-finish
service was—
Num­
ber of
plants 10,
10,
12,
14,
16,
11$
13,
15,
report­ under
under under under under under under 17 under
ing
12
13
14
15
16
17 cents 20
11
cents
cents cents cents cents cents cents cents

9
12
9
2
52
2
8
5
1
1
3
4
2
17
2
4
23
15
10
17
100
6
$0.49 $0.47 $0.36 $0.34 $0.43 $0.55 $0.46 $0.45 $0.58 $0.47 $0.64

2
7
10
17
3
3
4
2
1
2
1

3
1

1 Based on prices quoted for pick-up and delivery service.




1
1

1
5
6

1
1
1
2
1
1
1

1
4

1
3
4
1

1
1

1

1
2
3
1
1
1

12
1
9
7
23
17
37
13
120
19
14
31
10
1
7
6
11
100
$0.35 $0.28 $0.29 $0.32 $0.34 $0.39 $0.37 $0.35 $0.63
1
12
24
27
28
12
6
3
2
3
1
1

2
5
1
1

3
2
2

1
3
6
5
4
3
1

3
4
3
3
1
2
1

6
11
8
4
2
2
1
1
1
1

1
2
6
3
1

1
2
3
4
1
1

1
1
$0.45

1
1

W OM EN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

Average hourly earnings-------

Middle West

CHAPTER V. SHIRT PRODUCTIVITY
Production achieved on the shirtline often provides one of the
basic indexes of over-all plant efficiency. Shirt output also lends
itself readily to measurement. Laundry owners are more apt to be
familiar with the output of their shirt crews than of other groups of
workers, not only because the frequent use of incentive pay on this
operation requires that production records be kept, but also because
many owners watch shirt output closely to provide them with some
means of evaluating productivity. Information was therefore ob­
tained from employers on the number of shirts finished by the shirt
operatives. With relatively few exceptions, employers were able to
supply this information, most often by reference to actual production
records. In a few plants, authoritative estimates were accepted.
FACTORS INFLUENCING PRODUCTIVITY

Type of equipment appeared to be among the most important
determinants of productivity. Even skilled, competent operatives,
working under good conditions, cannot overcome the mechanical
limitations of the equipment itself. They cannot exceed the capacity
of the machines. Employers whose shirt operatives had achieved
relatively high output frequently attributed it to their modern equip­
ment, in a good state of repair, and of the type not requiring hand
finishing. The importance of equipment was corroborated also by
employers with low output who ascribed' their low output to equip­
ment that was old, or subject to break-downs, or of the type requiring
hand ironing. Important too are the steam pressure and air pressure
used in the machines. The steam pressure controls the degree of
heat in the presses, and the air pressure (on modern equipment)
controls the speed with which the head of the press is lowered and
raised. Equipment that eliminates the need for hand ironing was
often stressed as an essential to good production.
Good equipment, in itself, cannot guarantee good output. There
are other basic factors influencing productivity which, like equip­
ment, can be controlled by the employer. The volume and flow of
work have an appreciable effect on the output of the operatives. Too
many shirts one day and a prolonged lull the next do not assure sus­
tained, high output. Also, extreme fluctuations during the course of
a single day have an adverse effect on the work-rhythm of the shirt
crew. Employees who have to wait for varying lengths of time for
work to be brought to the unit cannot be expected to maintain con­
sistently good production. Another factor is the division of labor in
the unit and the definition of each employee’s job. Shirt operatives
work as a team on specialized presses; each member of the team per­
forms successive operations on the same shirt. An individual shirt
unit may consist of 2, 3, often 4, and up to as many as 8 operatives.




43

44

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

A poor division of labor and a failure to determine specifically each
individual worker’s responsibility are obviously not conducive to
high output for the unit as a whole. The timing of the work-flow
through the unit should be such that each successive member of the
crew is ready to handle the shirt when the preceding operative has
finished her part of the processing. This calls for the elimination of
wasteful, unproductive, and duplicating motions and a clear-cut
understanding on each worker’s part of her specific contribution to
the work of the unit and to the standard of production she is expected
to meet.
Several other elements which affect productivity revolve around
the labor force itself—experience, teamwork, stability, regularity of
attendance, training, supervision, and employee interest. Employers
who expressed themselves on this subject attributed high production
to careful selection of workers, expert training, the use of skilled opera­
tors, good teamwork, adequate supervision, and low turn-over. On
the other side of the picture were the employers with low output
caused, they said, by the type of worker available to them, by the use
of inexperienced workers, and by high turn-over. There is no doubt
that the war years were not propitious for increasing or even maintain­
ing output. Experienced workers left for higher wages in other
industries, and employee turn-over increased alarmingly. The em­
ployer who said he could not get normal output because a learner was
frequently on one or more of his shirt units was not alone in that
predicament.
A few employers mentioned they stressed quality or hand finishing
(even when the equipment did not require it) rather than quantity
and were therefore not too much concerned about their relatively low
shirt production. Other employers (primarily in Chicago), desirous
of attaining good output, at the same time placed controls on maxi­
mum output. In contrast with so many of the southern laundry
owners who said their workers were not achieving the desired output,
many Chicago employers were confronted with the problem of
putting a brake on very high production in order to protect quality.
Inasmuch as shirts are dried as well as ironed by the presses, it is
necessary that the shirts remain on the heated presses long enough
to dry. An operator can, by removing the shirt from the press too
soon, reach an unusually high output, but the shirt, not thoroughly
dry, will soon look wilted. Employers, in explaining why deliberate
top limits were placed on production, generally referred to the need to
preserve quality, but it is undoubtedly also true that they wanted to
keep their wage bills in hand, because their shirt operatives were
often paid according to the number of shirts finished.
Several employers attributed good production on the shirtline to
their use of an incentive method of wage payment to the operatives,
but, as will be discussed later, incentive pay did not prove to be an
indispensable prerequisite to high output.
VARIATIONS IN SHIRT OUTPUT

From the information supplied by employers, shirt output per
operator-hour was calculated. For example, in a laundry with 3 shirt
units, each composed of 4 operators, and averaging a total of 240




SHIRT PRODUCTIVITY

45

shirts an hour, the hourly output of each unit would average 80 shirts,
and of each operator,' 20 shirts.
Productivity varied markedly from one laundry to another within
each of the cities surveyed. In many cities there were 1 or more
laundries with output as low as 10 or fewer shirts per operator-hour.
At the same time, most cities had substantially more productive
laundries where output reached 20 and sometimes as high as 30 or
more per operator-hour. In Chicago, for example, with its relatively
high production standing, the plant with the highest output achieved
30 shirts per operator-hour whereas another only 10. In Norfolk, the
spread from low to high was little different from Chicago. One
Norfolk laundry produced as few as 11 shirts an hour, in sharp con­
trast with another whose operators were turning out 34. Even in a
city like Birmingham, where the vast majority of the plants were able
to reach less than 14 shirts an hour, some laundries attained con­
siderably higher production. Extremes in production were common
to practically all the cities visited. Undoubtedly the conditions in
the war years, when the demand for laundry service exceeded the
supply, enabled many inefficient plants to remain in operation.
However, even if one were to remove from consideration the very
low-output establishments in each city, there would still be sub­
stantial differences in production in the remaining laundries in most
cities. Of only a very few cities can it be said that production in the
majority of the establishments was similar or only slightly different.
Memphis is one of them. Here most laundries reached a production
figure of 13 to 16 shirts per operator-hour. Indianapolis is another;
about half the laundries produced 17 to 20 an hour. But this relative
uniformity was not found in most of the other cities and, like the
striking differences in earnings, offers further evidence of the lack of
standardization within each city.
Differences in average output from city to city, though found, were
not as widespread as the differences within each city. The average
output1 for most localities was 15 to 18 shirts per operator-hour.
This average was substantially exceeded in St. Louis, Louisville, and
Chicago where average output topped the list at 24 in St. Louis and
in Louisville and at 21 in Chicago. At the other end of the scale are
Birmingham and three small cities of North Carolina where produc­
tion lagged behind at an average of 12 and 11, respectively. There­
fore, although the localities at the top of the list averaged twice as
high a production as those at the bottom, it is possible to refer to a
norm, or standard production, of 15 to 18 shirts which most localities
averaged.
.
.
These locality averages, useful as they are for an over-all view of
production, are of limited value because they are based on extremes
within each city and obscure significant differences between the mid­
western and southeastern regions. Of the 80 midwestern laundries
able to supply production data, over half (53 percent) reported out­
put of 20 or more shirts per operator-hour. This is better than twice
the achievement in southeastern laundries where only one-fourth
reached an output of at least 20. Laundries in southeastern cities
1 This average is based on a median average—half the laundries produced more; half, less. A median
average was used rather than a simple arithmetic average because of the extremes in output found in most
cities.




46

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

appear prominently at the low-production end of the scale—44 per­
cent of them reported production of less than 15 shirts and 7 percent,
less than 10 shirts. On the other hand, only 23 percent of the laun­
dries in midwestern cities produced under 15 shirts per operator-hour,
and those with production falling below 10 were very rare. Con­
spicuous as low-output midwestern cities are Terre Haute, Ind.,
and three small Missouri cities. Among the southeastern cities,
Louisville is outstanding for its high productivity. The Hampton
Roads area in Virginia also stands out as above average. But almost
all the other localities had relatively high proportions of their laun­
dries with particularly low'shirt output.
Some southern laundry owners blamed low output on the supposed
low productivity of Negro workers. The fact of the matter is (sur­
prising as it may be to some) that the 3 laundries with the highest
rates of shirt production of all those visited—one in Chicago with 30,
another in St. Louis with 33, the third in Norfolk with 34—were
staffed with Negro women who constituted 99; 95, and 85 percent,
respectively, of all their women production workers.
The information on shirt output in each locality is presented in
table 12.
Table 12.—Shirt Production per Operator-Hour, by Locality

Locality

Number
of plants
reporting

Shirt production
per operator-hour

Number of plants with average
shirt production per operatorhour of—

Rjange in Under
Aver­ plant
aver­
age i
15
ages

15,
under
20

20,
under
25

25,
and
over

All localities
Middle West___ ____________ ___
Illinois: Chicago___ _
Indiana:
Indianapolis. .......................... .
Other places (4) ___ _. _
Missouri:
Kansas City . ................. .
St. Louis_____ ____ _______
Other places (5) ........................

219
80
28

17
20
21

8-34
8-33
10-30

79
18
4

63
20
5

47
22
8

30
20
11

8
11

18
16

14-22
10-27

1
3

5
3

2
4

1

8
13
12

15
24
16

9-25
14-33
8-25

3
1
6

3
1
3

1
5
2

1
6
1

Southeast......... .................... ..................
Alabama: Birmingham_____ ____
Florida:
Jacksonville.. _______________
Tampa
Georgia:
Atlanta... ........................ ......
Savannah and other places (3)..
Kentucky: Louisville...... ...............
North Carolina:
Charlotte and Winston-Salem..
Other places (3)
South Carolina:
Charleston and Columbia....... .
Greenville and Spartanburg__
Tennessee:
Memphis............. ............... .
Nashville and Knoxville_____
Virginia: Hampton Rfoads area......

139
14

16
12

8-34
8-28

61
9

43
2

25
1

10
2

11
8

15
16

8-22
10-23

5
3

3

3

10
12
5

15
15
24

8-22
17-29

6

3

3

10
12

16
11

8-25
8-25

4
9

3
1

2
1

1
1

15
9

16
15

12-30
8-18

6
4

5
5

3

1

9
11
13

15
18
19

11-20
12-25
10-34

5
4
2

3
3
8

1
3
1

1
2

i This represents a median; half the plants were above; half, below.




SHIRT PRODUCTIVITY

47

EFFECT ON SHIRT OUTPUT OF HAND FINISHING AND SIZE OF
UNIT

Output appeared to be lower in plants doing hand finishing of shirts.
Most often the type of equipment required hand finishing, hut some­
times the owner preferred to offer this service. Several employers,
in attributing low or high production to the use or absence of hand
finishing, corroborated this finding. An Indianapolis laundry, for
example, had two types of shirt units—one turning out a completely
machine-finished shirt and the other doing some hand finishing. The
former unit had average production of 25 per operator-hour; the
latter, doing hand finishing, averaged only 12.
Seemingly, output was also affected by the size of the shirt unit.
For a group of laundries where information was available, it was
found that output per operator-hour was as high as 20 or more only
when 4 or fewer operatives worked in a unit. A few employers ex­
pressed a preference for smaller units, explaining that it is easier to
develop good teamwork on a small unit. On the other hand, a
few owners said they had deliberately added additional workers to
the unit and that though production per operator was lowered, they
thereby assured themselves a reserve of workers.
PRODUCTIVITY AND METHOD OF WAGE PAYMENT

Although it was generally true that laundries whose shirt opera­
tives were paid on the basis of an incentive wage achieved higher
productivity than laundries paying their operatives on a time method,
the existence of an incentive system, per se, did not inevitably assure
high output per operator-hour, nor did it provide a cure-all for elimi­
nating extremely low output.
Shirt production per operator-hour was less than' 20 in almost
two-thirds of the establishments. Only 14 percent attained a pro­
duction figure of 25 or more. When, from among the total group of
laundries, those which paid all members of their shirt crews on a
time-method were compared with those which paid all shirt opera­
tives on an incentive basis, sharp contrasts were found between the
time and the incentive shirtlines. Over four-fifths of the time plants,
compared to less than half the incentive plants, had production
falling below 20 shirts per operator-hour. Only 2 percent of the time
crews achieved production of 25 or more, compared to 26 percent of
the incentive crews reaching this output.
Other significant facts stand out, however, from this analysis.
Despite the use of an incentive wage method, almost half the incentive
plants could not reach production as high as 20 per operator-hour, and
in over a third of these production hit low points of less than 15 an
hour. In several localities, including Chicago, St. Louis, and Atlanta,
some laundries paying shirt crews on the time method exceeded the
operator-hour output of incentive plants. It is evident, therefore,
that an incentive system, in itself, did not automatically guarantee
high productivity.




48

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

Equally significant is the fact that southeastern laundries, even
when they used incentive methods of pay, did not equal the produc­
tion performance of laundries in midwestern cities. Among the south­
eastern laundries whose shirt operatives were paid exclusively under
an incentive system, almost three-fifths had production of under 20,
and almost a third of these, under 15. Midwestern laundries using
incentive pay did almost twice as well. Here, in almost three-fourths
of the incentive plants, production averaged 20 or more, and in the
majority of these plants production was substantially higher—25 or
more shirts per operator-hour. Obviously, factors other than method
of wage payment have influenced productivity in many southeastern
laundries.
Table 13 presents the picture.
Table 13.—Comparison of Shirf Production per Operator-Hour and Method of Wage
Payment, by Region
Both regions
Shirt production per
operator-hour

Middle West

Southesat

Number of Percent Number of Percent Number of Percent
plants
distribution
plants
distribution
plants
distribution
ALL PLANTS

All reporting plants
Under 20_________ _
20 and over.........................

219
142
77

100.0
64.9
35.1

80
38
42

100.0
47.5
52.5

139
104
35

100.0
74.8
25.2

PLANTS PAYING ALL SHIRTLINE OPERATIVES BY TIME METHOD
All reporting plants______
Under 20______ ______
20 and over...........

104
85
19

100.0
81.8
18.2

34
24
10

100.0
70.6
29.4

70
61
9

100.0
87.1
12.9

PLANTS PAYING ALL SHIRTLINE OPERATIVES BY INCENTIVE METHOD
All reporting plants.......... . .
Under 20......................
20 and over_______

81
38
43

100.0
46.9
53.1

31
9
22

100.0
29.0
71.0

50
29
21

100.0
58.0
42.0

PRODUCTIVITY AND EARNINGS

Contrary to what might have been expected, differences in produc­
tivity did not account for differences in earnings. Shirt operatives
have no assurance that their pay will be commensurate with their
output. Operatives with identical output, working in different cities,
and often in different laundries of the same city, received vastly dif­
ferent wages. lor example, in southeastern laundries which reported
shirt output of about 20 per operator-horn1, average hourly earnings
of the shirt operatives varied from a low of 30 cents in one of these
plants to a high of 59 cents in another. In midwestern laundries with
the same output'—20 per operator-hour—shirt operatives in one plant
averaged 40 cents an hour, in another 85 cents. That output bears
little relationship to earnings is also illustrated by the 10 southeastern
laundries whose shirt operatives averaged about 11 shirts an hour and
who received, on the average, 32 cents an hour. In another group of




49

SHIRT PRODUCTIVITY

southeastern laundries where the operatives produced more-—15
shirts an hour—they earned less, only 28 cents, on the average.
Even within the same city, earnings differed widely in laundries
with identical output per operator-hour. In Norfolk, two laundries,
both of whose shirt operatives were paid on an incentive basis, reported
the same output, 19 shirts per operator-hour, but the shirt operatives
averaged only 47 cents an hour in one laundry, compared to 72 cents
in the other—a difference of 53 percent. Four Chicago laundries,
paying all their shirt operatives under an incentive method', were able
to turn out 25 shirts per operator-hour, but earnings varied from 61
cents to 90 cents.
Operatives in one laundry sometimes earned less for a higher output
than operatives in another laundry in the same city. In a Tampa
laundry, for example, operatives averaged 52 cents an hour and pro­
duced an average of 16 shirts per operator-hour. In another Tampa
laundry, operatives produced 22 shirts an hour, but averaged only 39
cents an hour. This type of inequity was found in many cities.
As was noted previously, laundries in many of the midwestern cities
achieved substantially better production records than did those in
southeastern cities. But the differences in earnings of shirt opera­
tives, when compared to their output, was even more striking. Shirt
operatives in many southeastern laundries, for output only somewhat
lower than in the Midwest, nevertheless earned materially less-—an
earnings difference substantially greater than could be cohsidered
warranted by the difference in output. As table 14 shows, in south­
eastern laundries which paid all their shirt operatives on an incentive
basis, production, on the average, was 14 percent less than in mid­
western laundries using incentive pay, but earnings in the Southeast
were 36 percent lower than in the Midwest, a difference over two
and a half times the difference in output.
Table 14.

Comparison of Average Shirt Production per Operator-Hour and Average
Hourly Earnings of Shirtline Operatives, by R egion
Average
Average shirt
All report­ production hourly earn­
ing plants per operator- ings of shirt­
line opera­
hour
tives

Region

ALL PLANTS
Middle West_____ ____________________________
Southeast_____________________ _____ _________ "

79
129

20
16

$0. 56
.36

Percent by which Southeast is less than Middle West.

__

20

36

PLANTS PAYING ALL SHIRTLINE OPERATIVES BY TIME METHOD
Middle West..................................... ...... ......................
Southeast—......... ................................ ...........................

34
70

Percent by which Southeast is less than Middle West

16
13

.48
.32

19

33

PLANTS PAYING ALL SHIRTLINE OPERATIVES BY INCENTIVE METHOD
Middle West_________ ______________ ____t...........
Southeast___ _____________________ ____________
Percent by which Southeast is less than Middle West.




31
50

22
19

.64
.41

14

36

CHAPTER VI. HOURS
Low wages and long hours often go hand in hand. Management
inefficiencies resulting in low output tend to make the employer think
that only by operating under an unduly long workweek can the re­
quired work be produced. The effects of unreasonably long hours on
productivity per man-hour, on absenteeism, and on turn-over are
well recognized in present day principles of industrial efficiency.
During the war period, laundry employers may have either extended
the workweek or failed to reduce one already long in order to maximize
the use of available labor and existing machinery. On the other hand
many employers, in an effort to make laundry employment more
attractive, reduced hours of work. Such war conditions probably
influenced the hours schedules in effect in 1945.
Industry in normal years has been tending toward a 40-hour week,
a development stimulated by the provisions of the Federal Fair Labor
Standards Act which require the payment of time and one-half the
employee’s regular rate of pay for hours beyond 40 per week. Despite
the fact that women, often compelled by economic necessity to hold a
full-time job and to perform a variety of homemaking tasks in their
“leisure” hours, have a particular need for reasonable working hours,
many are denied the benefits of the Fair Labor Standards Act because
they are concentrated in intrastate trade and service industries.
Especially in an industry which leans heavily on women’s labor, the
hours of work bear directly on the problem of recruiting and retaining
a competent workforce. Among retail department stores there is a
noticeable trend toward the 5-day, 40-hour week for employees,
though the store itself may remain open to customers for longer hours.
Relatively few laundries have matched this standard.
Laundries have long been faced with the difficulty, stemming from
the traditional Monday washday, of regularizing the workweek.
Wartime regulations on delivery service have helped to overcome this
problem by regularizing the work load and consequently the workweek.
Employers hope to retain this advantage. When, instead of pick-ups
on Monday and deliveries on Thursday and Friday, regulated pick-ups
and deliveries are made on each day of the week, the volume and flow
of work in the plant can be kept at an even keel, making it possible
to establish a definite schedule of daily and weekly hours for employees.
Several employers reported that hours of work varied, depending
on the work load. In these plants the scheduled workweek generally
called for a full day on Saturday, but employees were allowed to leave
when the week’s work was completed. Sometimes this meant about
half a day’s work on Saturday and sometimes none at all.
SCHEDULED WEEKLY HOURS

The scheduled hours for women production employees sometimes
corresponded with the hours usually worked, but, as described above,
50




51

HOURS

they sometimes represented the maximum hours employees might be
called upon to work if the work load required it, exclusive of overtime
which might or might not be paid for.
A 40-hour week was virtually unknown except in some Chicago
laundries. The workweek in most laundries, about two-thirds of
them, called for 45 to 50 hours. Relatively few had less than 45 hours,
but one-fifth of the total 258 plants scheduled their women employees
to work more than 50 hours a week, sometimes as long as 54, 55, 56,
and even 57 hours. Hours were generally longer in the Southeast
than in the Middle West, but large proportions of the establishments
in both regions had unreasonably long workweeks; more than 48
hours a week were scheduled in 36 percent of the midwestern laundries
and 47 percent of those in the southeast.
That laundries can adhere to reasonable schedules is proved by the
practices of groups of employers in many cities. Table 15 shows the
workweek scheduled for women production workers in the laundries
surveyed. Relatively few laundries reported that employees in some
departments worked on a schedule different from that of the other
workers.
Table 1 5.—Weekly Hours of Work Scheduled by Plants for Women Production Workers,
by Locality
Number of plants reporting scheduled weekly hours of—
Locality

All laundries _
Percent distribution______
Middle West—All plants
Percent distribution__________
Illinois: Chicago
Indiana:
Other places (4)
Missouri:
Kansas City .............. ......
Southeast—All plants________ _
Percent distribution...
Florida:
Jacksonville__________ _
Georgia:
Savannah
Other places (3)............ .
North Carolina:
Raleigh
South Carolina:

Tennessee:

Virginia: Hampton Roads area..




num­
ber of
plants

40

258
100.0

13
5.0

92
100.0
30

Over
40, un­
der 45
18
7.0

Over
Over 54 and
48,
un­
through 50,
over
der 54
50

43
16.7

60
23.2

31
12.0

20
7.8

7

18

7

17

15

13

5

7.6
6

19.6
3

7.6
1

18.5
10

16.3

14.1

5.4

3
1.8

13
8
10
8
10

2

12
6
11
9
14
8
16

33
12.8

48

10

16
10
14

9
7
10

40
15.5

Over
45, un­
der 48

10.9
10

8
14

166
100.0
15

45

2
4

1

1

4

2

1

5
2
2

2
1
1

1
2
2

3
1
5

2

11
6.6
1

22
13.3
1

26
15.7
3

26
15.7
5

45
27.1

18
10.8

3

1
1

2

1
2

4

2

1

1
4
2

2
1

1

6
1
2

5

1
1

2
2
2

2
1
1

2

2

4
2
2

1
1

1
1

1
2

1
2
2

1

5
3

2
1

2
2
. 5

1
1

5
5
2

11

15
9.0

1

1
1

1
3

2
3

4

52

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

States, recognizing that women’s hours of work are of vital public
concern, have passed legislation to protect women workers. All but
five States fix maximum weekly and/or daily hours for women. The
existence of a law, however, does not necessarily mean that laundry
workers are covered, nor that the law itself, where it does apply to
laundries, actually protects women from excessively long hours. The
standards set in some laws have long since become outmoded.
The cities included in this survey were located in 11 States, 5 of
which do not regulate maximum hours of women laundry workers, and
4 fix a legal maximum as high as 54, 55, 57, or 60 hours a week. A 48hour maximum is in effect in only 2 of these States—Illinois and
Virginia. All the laundries visited in these 2 States were operating,
in line with the legal maximum, on no more than a 48-hour week for
women, demonstrating the ability of employers to adjust to reasonable
hours of work, if required to do so. The following tabulation shows
the legal maximum for women laundry workers in States included in
the survey.
Legal maximum
Daily
Weekly

State i

Illinois________
Virginia_______
Missouri______
North Carolina.
Tennessee_____
Kentucky_____

8
9
9
11
10 H
10

48
48
54
55
57
60

OTHER WORKING TIME CONDITIONS1
2
WORKDAY, LUNCH PERIODS, REST PERIODS

The workday in most laundries was long, burdensome, and unre­
lieved. A 9-hour day or longer was found in almost two-tliirds of the
establishments. Excluding Chicago, where the State law prohibits
more than 8 hours a day, one finds that the 8-hour day, so popular in
other industries, is a rarity indeed to women laundry workers. Here
and there, as in Columbia, S. C., and Jacksonville, Fla., some laundries
were using the 8-hour day, but by and large the 9-hour day was most
common. In several laundries, notably in the Southeast, women were
scheduled to work as long as 10 or 10‘Z hours daily.
These long days were usually interrupted by a 30-minute lunch
period. Kest periods, widely accepted by progressive employers as
good management, were rarely provided in the Southeast but were
substantially more prevalent in the Middle West. Laundries allowing
rest periods, all of which were paid for, provided one or two a day, each
usually of 10 or 15 minutes’ duration. In an industry such as this, in
which many employers have been slow to adopt modern labor stand­
ards, if at all, significant attention should be focused on those employers
who have found it possible to adjust to standards practiced with
matter-of-fact acceptance in other industries.
1 Alabama, Florida, and Indiana have no maximum-hour laws. The laws in Georgia and South Carolina
are not applicable to laundries.
2 Unfortunately the important problem of overtime and overtime pay is omitted from this discussion
because of inadequate information.




HOURS

53

HOLIDAYS

Although information on the observance of holidays and on holiday
pay was not obtained from every employer, enough detail was supplied
by many of them to indicate the types of practices in use.
To laundry workers a holiday often means forfeiting a day’s pay.
Many establishments did not pay for holidays, though observed by
the plant. Others limited pay to weekly workers, thus excluding
hourly and incentive workers from benefits allowed other workers in
the same plant. Payment for holidays not worked, when made, had
strings attached in several southeastern laundries which imposed
conditions of payment. Most frequently imposed was the require­
ment that employees must work all other workdays in the holiday
week. In other plants requirements were such that the holiday pay
was earned on other days of the week. For example, employees were
required to work longer horns or to complete the week’s work quota
on other workdays.
TREND IN HOURS CHANGES
COMPARISON OF 1945 AND 1927-28

Progress in approaching reasonable hour standards has been made,
however slow. Three southern cities covered in the present survey
were also included in a Women’s Bureau survey of 1927-28—Atlanta,
Birmingham, and Jacksonville. At that time almost two-fifths of
the hours schedules in laundries of these three cities called for more
than 54 hours a week, whereas only one laundry in these cities had a
similar schedule in 1945. On the other hand, schedules of 48 hours
or less were found in over half the laundries in 1945, whereas in 1927-28
not one laundry in either Birmingham or Jacksonville and only a few
in Atlanta had schedules of 48 hours or less.
CHANGES SINCE 1942

That war conditions accelerated this slow progress in reducing hours
is borne out by the reports from employers on changes made in hours
schedules since 1942. Two-fifths of the establishments had changed
the hours of women production workers. The predominant trend
was toward a decrease in hours, either by reducing hours on Saturday
to provide the women with necessary shopping time, or by cutting
the length of each workday by half an hour. Many laundry em­
ployers were forced by competition for labor to attempt to bring their
labor standards into line with those in other industries.
A few employers, primarily in Chicago, increased hours, for the
most part by raising them to 48. Some had instituted a night shift
during the war.




CHAPTER VII. PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS1
Though difficult to measure, good working conditions enhance the
attractiveness of a job and augment the value of wages received.
But when low wages and long hours are combined with undesirable
working conditions, the result is a triple threat to decent standards.
Proper working conditions are important not only in stimulating
morale and effective production but also in promoting stability of the
work force, a problem of particular importance to laundries today.
During the year after the war employment in laundry plants climbed
steadily. Hiring was somewhat facilitated by the curtailment of war
production and the displacement of women in industrial employment.
Turn-over, however, serious during the war, continued to run high.
Many of the newly hired women, aside from having had received
adequate wages in wartime, had been working in plants where condi­
tions were attractive. They know, from their own experience, that
modern improvements can minimize, if not completely eliminate, the
unpleasant aspects of a job, and that facilities can be and are provided
elsewhere for the employee’s comfort. Coming to the laundry in­
dustry, they are confronted with a job in its very nature unpleasant
and sometimes intolerable. Employee-welfare facilities are often
lacking. Many workers complain of excessive heat. High humidity
caused by steam and water add to the discomfort. The noise of
machines, handling dirty, wet, or hot clothes, and the strenuous
nature of some tasks combine to make the jobs, already unattractive
because of low wages, far from appealing. Questioned by Women’s
Bureau agents on employee turn-over, laundry owners often admitted
freely that turn-over was highest on those jobs lowest paid, such as
flatwork, or on jobs at which excessive heat was generated, such as
shirt and garment pressing. Current reports from employment offices
throughout the country indicate that recruitment of workers is difficult.
Laundry work need not be undesirable. Progressive employers
have made great strides in reducing the severe discomforts of heat and
humidity by modern ventilation methods and exhaust systems. Some
have provided adequate facilities for the welfare of their employees
by furnishing seats, rest rooms, lunchrooms, and acceptable washing
and toilet facilities.
_
_
Women’s Bureau agents, in visiting the laundries included _ in
the present survey, observed work surroundings and recorded their im­
pressions by describing, as poor, fair, good, or very good, each of
various conditions, such as ventilation, layout, employee-welfare facili­
ties. Obviously, the subjective element entered the agents’ descrip­
tions, but in order to reduce its effect to a minimum a set of standards
had been previously agreed upon, based on standards set up by the
American Standard Association and by Federal and State govern­
1 Because information was not obtainable from 1 of the 258 plants surveyed, this chapter is based on con­
ditions in 257 plants.
54




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

55

ment agencies and on suggestions made by the American Institute
of Laundering.
Two types of working conditions were evaluated, (1) conditions in
the work area itself: ventilation, illumination, layout, equipment, and
housekeeping; and (2) employee-welfare facilities: drinking and wash­
ing facilities, toilets, seating, and other facilities such as lunchrooms,
rest rooms, and dressing rooms.
GENERAL OBSERVATIONS

Conditions in the work area itself were generally satisfactory
in the majority of the establishments, except for the fact that house­
keeping was often not up to par. Major items, however, such as
ventilation, illumination, layout, and equipment were considered
adequate more often than not.
Unfortunately adequate facilities for the welfare and personal
needs of employees were not common. Sanitary facilities, usually pro­
vided, were frequently inadequate. Other employee-welfare im­
provements such as seats, lunchrooms, dressing, and rest rooms were
often conspicuous by their total absence or were grossly unsatisfactory.
That employers were generally mindful of improvements in the
work area but neglected employee-welfare facilities can be traced to
the easily observable effect of poor work surroundings on production—
of vital importance to the employer. On the other hand, not only did
some employers fail to see the relationship between poor welfare
facilities and worker morale, but others were not even cognizant of
the inadequacy of such facilities. Laundry operators of plants with
poor facilities sometimes boasted to agents of the superior conditions
in their own plants, asserting they were the best in town or as good
as could be found anywhere. The unsatisfactory conditions observed
m these plants resulted perhaps from a failure to recognize short­
comings rather than an unwillingness to provide decent working
conditions.
It is recognized that at the time of this survey, shortly after VJ-day,
employers were not yet able to purchase equipment or materials
to install or construct improvements, despite an intention to do so.
Agents were told of plans to expand and improve working conditions.
It is hoped that this summary of conditions in 1945 will aid employers
m making these improvements, so necessary in the industry.
CONDITIONS IN WORK AREA
VENTILATION

Ventilation is a particularly serious problem in laundries because
the work processes generate heat and humidity. Employers’ recog­
nition of this fact is shown by the large number of them (58 percent)
who had achieved satisfactory ventilation.
Ventilation was judged on the basis of temperature and humidity
readings, taken with a sling psy chrome ter, and on observations of
natural and artificial ventdating systems. Agents noted whether
windows or artificial ventilation provided a cross flow and proper
movement of air, whether cedings were sufficiently high, and whether
specialized attention had been given to areas requiring it. They




56

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

observed, for example, whether fresh air was provided in areas where
soiled clothes were being handled, and whether local exhaust systems
were in use directly over machines generating steam, such as flatwork
ironers and shirt and garment presses.
Types of ventilation varied widely, ranging from a very poor
system in an Atlanta laundry where low ceilings, only few windows,
and no provision at all for artificial ventilation made the atmosphere
almost unbearable, to other plants with large window areas, high
ceilings, local exhausts, and extensive systems of general mechanical
ventilation.
The problem must be coped with differently in each plant. The
size and layout of the workroom as well as the construction of the
building itself are important considerations. The following illustra­
tions, offered to familiarize employers with conditions in other plants,
may suggest means of improvement to those who have not yet suc­
cessfully overcome the problem.
A Chicago laundry, faced with the problem of counteracting the heat of the
sun’s rays which came through the west windows and a skylight, tackled it
in the following manner. In the skylight was installed a type of glass which
permits light to enter but filters out the heat rays of the sun. _ The west
windows were fitted with copper screens (“cool shades”) with tiny curved
surfaces that deflect the light. Complete ventilation of the plant was assured
by cutting vents beneath the windows and installing exhaust fans in the
opposite wall to pull cool air from the outside across the room.
The workroom of an Indiana laundry was equipped with an extensive system
of ducts which carried fresh air from the outside. The conducted air was
poured down onto the workers, who, it was said, preferred this direct flow of
air to less immediate contact.
In a Chicago laundry, through iron grating beneath the windows, fans drew
air from the outside. Hoods had been installed over the shirtlines and the
flatwork ironers and were equipped with large exhaust fans. The plant
superintendent, emphasizing the importance of having the hoods close to
the presses, related that the hoods had been lowered recently, on the recom­
mendation of an engineer. Results were gratifying, he reported, in that the
summer just passed was the first during which women workers had not
fainted or been forced to leave for homo due to the heat.
The ventilating system in a Louisville plant included a row of exhaust fans
over the finishing department. To determine the effectiveness of the fans,
the plant superintendent suggested that temperature and humidity readings
be taken at the flatwork ironer while the fans were in motion and again a few
minutes later when the fans were turned off. The fans were turned off
without the knowledge of the workers who began to perspire and talk among
themselves about the suddenly uncomfortable atmosphere; readings showed
a difference of 8 degrees in temperature and 6 in humidity.
A well ventilated North Carolina plant had windows and doors on three
sides, skylights, five large exhaust fans, two upright fans, and other smaller
fans.
High-speed fans in a Virginia plant were placed 15 feet apart at floor level to
carry the air upward. The fans, it was said, changed the air every minute.
There were fans also over the flatwork ironers. High ceilings and skylights
complemented the picture, and tinted window glass was used to cut heat
radiation.
■

Local exhaust systems, either fans or hoods over a specific area, are
desirable in that they draw off steam immediately at the source and
prevent it from diffusing into the room. While the advantages of an
exhaust fan are obvious, there was some disagreement about hoods.
Some employers explained that hoods gathered dust and lint and hence




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

57

were not practicable. Hoods, used in some midwestern laundries,
were seldom found in the Southeast. Much more common were
exhausts in the ceiling over processing areas, especially flatwork
ironers. Asbestos cement covering on presses was another device
sometimes employed to control heat.
The existence of good ventilating systems in the majority of
laundries should not obscure the patently inadequate conditions in
many—over two-fifths of all those visited. Unsatisfactory conditions,
particularly common in Birmingham and in cities of Georgia and
South Carolina, were found in every locality.
Good laundry ventilation is aided by such devices as large window
areas that provide cross ventilation, high ceilings permitting steam to
rise, and intake and exhaust fans to insure a supply of fresh air and
removal of steam at the source.
ILLUMINATION

Good lighting promotes accuracy, cleanliness, and orderliness.
Laundries require primarily good general illumination and also special
local lighting for some operations, such as marking, sorting, and
mending. Illumination, to be considered good, should be sufficient,
evenly distributed, and without glare. The existence of window areas
and the provision of electric lights do not, in themselves, assure ade­
quate illumination. Preferred standards require that the windows
be arranged to admit a maximum of light with a minimum of glare.
They must be kept clean. Electric light bulbs should be above the
normal line of vision, well spaced, correctly shaded, and clean.
Women’s Bureau agents did not attempt to measure the quantity
of light. Rather they evaluated it on the basis of their observations.
They noted whether lighting appeared to be uniformly sufficient
throughout the plant, including all work areas, aisles, and stairways,
and whether local lighting was provided for jobs involving possible
eyestrain. The type of lighting fixtures was observed, as was the
existence of any unlighted areas, such as dark stairways.
Illumination was considered adequate in almost two-thirds of the
laundries, which unsually had large, clean window areas and fluores­
cent lighting or well shaded incandescent bulbs. In relatively few
plants was the lighting poor, but in some it was only fair.
A large Memphis laundry with unusually good illumination had
large casement windows on all sides fitted with heat-resistant glass
that reduced glare. Walls were of white tile. Electric light bulbs,
none of which was exposed, were covered with white, dome-shaped
globes. Fluorescent lights over the shirtline, marking, and sorting
units, and adjustable green-shaded lamps for the menders provided
the necessary special lighting. Other plants with particularly good
lighting had windows on four sides and skylights; white ceilings and
walls reflected the light.
In contrast, laundries with unsatisfactory illumination often had
dirty windows and light bulbs, unshaded or unreplaced broken bulbs,
and no special lighting on particular jobs requiring it. In some,
stairways and other places outside the work area, though used by
employees, were only dimly lit and hence a safety hazard. On the
whole, better maintenance—cleaning windows and light bulbs, shading




58

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

bulbs, replacing those worn out or broken—would have improved
the illumination in many laundries.
LAY-OUT

The lay-out of a plant directly affects production. Essential to
good lay-out is the proper location and spacing of departments and
equipment to assure a smooth flow of work from one department to
another, with a minimum of criss-crossing or unproductive motions,
a minimum of trucking of work and walking by operators, and a
maximum use of labor saving devices.
Agents judged lay-out on the basis of floor plan and the extent to
which labor saving devices were used, such as conveyor belts, rails,
elevators, and chutes. Agents observed whether aisles were suffi­
ciently wide and work areas uncrowded and whether soiled garments
were kept entirely separate from clean clothing.
By and large, the lay-out was found adequate, and the flow of work
was systematic. This was not always simple to accomplish, especially
when laundries were situated in buildings not originally constructed
for this purpose.
Some laundries had all departments on one floor except marking
which was on a mezzanine above the washroom. Laundry, after
being marked and classified, was dropped into chutes which emptied
into the wash wheels. In one Florida plant, however, though laundry
was marked on the balcony, it was carried up- and down-stairs—an
avoidable use of additional labor.
A one-story plant is considered more satisfactory than a multi­
story type. Some plants of the multistory type, however, had
minimized the amount of labor required to transfer laundry from one
floor to another by using such devices as conveyors, rails, chutes, or
elevators. Conveyors and rails were used also to move laundry from
one department to another on the same floor, although carts were
more commonly used for this purpose. The engineer in a North
Carolina laundry had designed a three-tiered cart with the advantage
of minimizing”the crushing or “pounding down” of laundry, a short­
coming of the more usual, deep cart.
Other practicable methods and devices found in use are worth
mentioning:
Incoming bundles in a Chicago plant were piled at one end of a conveyor
belt. Along the conveyor, classifiers and identifiers were stationed at tables
on the sides of which were racks designed to hold the nets open so that laundry
could be dropped into them easily.
After the bundles were broken and marked in the marking and identifying
department of a Missouri plant, the laundry was put into nets, and the nets
in turn loaded at waist level into canvas bags. Conveyors carried these
bags to the washroom and returned them empty to the marking room.
Handling and routing were facilitated in a Virginia laundry by hanging
wearing apparel on racks that were moved along a rail.
In a Louisville plant the classifier worked from a raised platform from which
she could, without raising her arms, toss the bags of laundry into their proper
carts.

Although, generally speaking, lay-out was satisfactory, the stand­
ards in some localities were not equal to those found elsewhere.




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

59

Falling short of achievement in other cities were many laundries in
Atlanta, Jacksonville, and small North Carolina cities.
EQUIPMENT

Equipment, like lay-out, affects directly the rate of production.
Equipment that is outmoded or subject to frequent break-down places
the employer at a competitive disadvantage in relation to others
operating with modern machinery, and it makes it impossible for the
worker to match the production standard achieved in other plants.
Factors used in evaluating equipment were typo and condition of
equipment and of guarding on machines. Agents also took note of the
use of specialized equipment adapted to particular needs. Agents
observed, for example, whether washers were of wooden or metal
construction; whether presses were of the air-compression or older,
foot-treadle type; whether flatwork ironers were guarded; and whether
the covers of washers and extractors were equipped with an inter­
locking device to prevent operation of the machine with the cover
open.
On the basis of these criteria, equipment was considered good or
very good in three-fifths of the 257 plants. A negligible number of
plants were rated poor, and somewhat over a third were judged fair.
In four localities, however, equipment did not equal the standards
found elsewhere—Atlanta, Birmingham, Tampa, and small North
Carolina cities.
Washers.—In laundries with good equipment, washers were fre­
quently of metal construction. Many were automatic to some extent
and had interlocking devices on the covers. On the “automatic washman,” the most modern washer, the washing cycle, initiated by press­
ing a button, is automatically completed without further handling.
In one laundry pipes connected the washer with a container of washing
solution, admitted into the machine by opening a valve. On the other
hand, the older type of wooden wheel, still found in some laundries,
was frequently operated with open covers so that the water sloshed
out of the rapidly revolving cylinders onto the floor.
Extractors. —These machines should be equipped with metal covers
and interlocking devices. Lack of such devices, as well as broken
covers, or occasionally the complete absence of a cover, constituted
the most common faults of equipment observed during the survey.
Flatwork ironers.— Some type of guard was almost invariably found
on these machines, affording protection against injury to almost all
flatworkers. The guarding usually consisted either of a shield extend­
ing across the ironer or of one or more small, light rolls in front of the
heavy cylinders.
Ironers in some plants were equipped with special features. Some
had conveyors or baskets that could be swung from one end of the ironer
to the other to carry damp or imperfectly ironed pieces from the
folders to the feeders for re-honing. A few laundries had cooling de­
vices on the ironers which cooled the pieces as they left the machine.
The flatwork emerged warm, and not hot as is general elsewhere, and
hence was easier and more comfortable for the folders to handle. An
unusual electrical device on the ironer in one plant operated in such a




60

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

way that large pieces of flatwork emerged from the ironer completely
folded.
Presses.—The majority of presses, of all types, were adequately
guarded. Most of the presses were of the air-compression type, oper­
ated by pressing two buttons simultaneously, one with each hand.
Because both hands are occupied, they cannot be caught as the head
of the press is lowered. Sometimes it was possible for the worker, by
tampering with the buttons, to use only one hand to operate the press.
To prevent this, some plants had set the button controls in close-fitting
rings. While the two-button-control, air-compression presses were
most common, a number of plants still had some of the old foottreadle type. For the most part, however, they were being replaced.
Time-adjusted shirtline presses were also seen in use. The operator
has only to lower the head (the upper of the two pressing surfaces)
which is automatically raised when the shirt has been on the press
long enough.
Special equipment. —Some laundries had installed specialized equip­
ment to answer particular needs. For example, in one plant finished
laundry was sent to a semicircular table, rather than to a more com­
mon long type, where bundle wrappers assorted the pieces into bundles.
At a semicircular table the workers have only to turn to pick up the
pieces, whereas at a long table they must walk from one part to
another. This plant was also equipped with a large tumbler which
gently tumbled laundry to loosen it after it came out of the extractors
tightly wound. This saved the time of finishing operators who did
not have to loosen the pieces by hand.
Postwar Plans
That modern equipment was not more widely used was undoubtedly
due to employers’ inability to buy new equipment during the war.
Some laundry owners said they had already ordered or intended to
buy new equipment, such as automatic metal wash wheels, modern
extractors with conveyor rails, shirtline presses, apparel presses, flatwork ironei'S, and conveyors.
HOUSEKEEPING

Individuals are more or less sensitive to their surroundings. Clean,
orderly surroundings are conducive to clean, orderly work habits.
Agents, in judging housekeeping, noted whether washroom floors
were of relatively impervious material, well drained, and without a
measurable depth of water; whether floors were in good repair and
without obstructions which might cause falls; whether windows, light
bulbs, floors, and stairs were clean; and whether aisles were kept open
and free of obstruction.
In contrast with each of the other items used in judging work-area
conditions, housekeeping was often found to be unsatisfactory.
Housekeeping was definitely considered poor in 39 of the 257 laundries,
several of which were in Georgia or South Carolina, and it was rated
only fair in 97 other laundries. In less than half the establishments was
housekeeping considered good or very good. Because of the difficulty
in hiring porters during the war, plants were not cleaned so frequently
or thoroughly as necessary. At the time of the survey some plants




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

61

were getting a postwar housecleaning. Light fixtures, floors, and all
areas in the plant were being thoroughly cleaned for the first time in
many months.
Laundries where housekeeping was considered good or very good
were characterized by wide, uncluttered aisles, by clean floors, windows,
and light fixtures, and by well-drained concrete floors in the washroom,
which, though often wet, had no measurable depth of water.
While concrete or other relatively impervious material is desirable
for the washroom, a more resilient material is preferable in other
work areas to relieve the strain caused by standing constantly on a
hard surface. To counteract this strain, some laundries which had
concrete floors provided their employees with mats. In a clean,
spacious Jacksonville laundry employees .were given a choice of mats
or wooden platforms on which to stand. Other plants had laid special
floor surfaces of composition or asphalt which were smooth, even, and
less fatiguing than a harder surface.
Agents found that white interiors were used advantageously to
achieve a cheerful appearance. A Missouri laundry, where house­
keeping was excellent, was described as having spotlessly white paint­
ing throughout; clean, smooth, unobstructed floors; and compositioncovered work tables. White brick walls, wooden floors (except in
the washroom), wide, clear aisles, and spacious work areas were
observed in a North Carolina plant.
Many plants, however, were far from satisfactory. In an Indiana
laundry were observed crowded, cluttered aisles, dirty light bulbs,
floors dirty and rutted, and very wet washroom floors caused by non­
functioning drains. A Florida laundry was housed in a very old
building once used as a store. The ceiling, made of fiberboard,
much of it loose, was covered with dust and cobwebs. In addition to
cluttered aisles, unduly wet washroom floors, and a generally dirty
appearance, undesirable features observed in some laundries included
pipe-obstructed floors; narrow or broken stairs, sometimes without
handrails; no provision of mats on hard-surfaced floors; soiled cloth­
ing scattered around marking room; and haphazard storage of com­
pleted bundles. The call office of a Virginia laundry, for example,
was practically littered with bundles—on desks, floors, and chairs.
Contrast this with the simple system found in other laundries where
rows of shelves had been constructed, each designated with a letter
of the alphabet; on these shelves bundles were neatly “filed” according
to the first initial of the customer’s name.
EMPLOYEE-WELFARE FACILITIES

Although employers would unquestionably be aghast at the very
thought of using in their own homes the types of facilities they pro­
vided their employees, many showed little concern or awareness of the
flagrant inadequacies in plant facilities. Not that luxurious appoint­
ments are necessary. But certainly facilities which recognize the
simple decencies of living are essential in a place where human beings
spend a substantial part of their waking hours.
In contrast with conditions in the work area, satisfactory on the
whole, facilities for the health and comfort of employees were often
wholly lacking or inadequate.




62

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

DRINKING FACILITIES

Adequate, pure drinking water, dispensed by sanitary means, is
essential in laundries where the temperature is relatively high, and
the work involves almost constant movement. Drinking water
facilities were judged on the basis of adequacy (1 facility for every 30
persons was considered adequate), type, location, and state of repair,
particularly of guards against contact by mouth and nose. Essenti­
ally, the water should be somewhat cooled, but not by direct contact
with ice, and so dispensed as not to transmit disease. Any one of
several types of dispensers is adequate. Satisfactory types include:
(1) Water coolers provided with suitable dispensers for individual
paper cups and containers for disposal of used cups; and (2) drinking
fountains, of impervious material; equipped with angle-jets, which
prevent the water from falling back on the opening, and with guards
to prevent the drinker’s mouth and nose from coming in contact with
the nozzle; the inclined jet of water not touching the guard, to avoid
spattering.
_
Drinking facilities were poor in fully one-fourth of the 257 laundries.
Almost every laundry in Memphis was described as poor. Only
somewhat over one-third of all laundries were reported to have good or
very good facilities, but not even one laundry was so described in
several cities—some cities in Georgia and in South Carolina.
Laundries with satisfactory facilities had modern dispensers supply­
ing cool water, often electrically refrigerated. The dispensers were
either fountains with a well-guarded, slanting jet or water coolers and
disposable cups.
Laundries with unsatisfactory facilities sometimes had one waterfilled wooden barrel, from which workers drew water into their own
glasses or milk bottles. In other plants the only source of drinking
water was a washtub faucet in the washrooms.
WASHING FACILITIES

W ashing facilities were evaluated on the basis of adequacy and
cleanliness. They were considered adequate when one washbasin was
provided for every 10-100 employees and one additional basin for
every 15 additional persons; when basins were of vitreous, glazed,
enameled-ware, or similar material; and when hot and cold water,
soap, towels, and towel-disposal facilities were provided. The facili­
ties should be located in or near the toilet rooms.
In nearly half the laundries washing facilities were highly unsatis­
factory; in 4 plants they were not provided at all. Only 16 percent
of all laundries visited provided good or very good facilities.
The best of the washing facilities consisted of an adequate number
of clean washbasins with hot and cold water, soap (liquid, powder,
or bar), and sanitary towels—roller towels, paper towels, or indi­
vidual cloth towels. Showers were provided in a few laundries.
Laundries described as having poor facilities often provided only
cold water and neither soap nor towels. A single faucet, intended to
accommodate all employees, might be the only source of water for
washing. The only washing facility in a small city, Missouri laundry
consisted of a long, cold-water pipe in the laundry washroom to which
had been attached a faucet. Water, when drawn, poured directly
onto the floor. Neither towels nor soap were provided, In a Kansas




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

63

City plant towels were used in common. Negro women in a Jack­
sonville laundry, comprising 60 percent of all the plants’ women pro­
duction workers, liad no place to wash except at a workroom washtub. In many plants the washbowls, inadequate in number, were
dirty. Soap was frequently lacking. The majority of laundries
provided either unsanitary common towels or none at all.
TOILETS

Good toilet facilities, essential in all industrial establishments,
safeguard workers’ health. Inadequate, unsanitary facilities are
likely to spread disease.
.
Adequate standards require that one toilet be provided for every
15 women employed, that separate rooms, clearly distinguished, be
available for men and for women, and that each toilet be enclosed in
an individual compartment closed by a door which can be fastened
to insure privacy. Toilet facilities should be conveniently located
near the workroom. Toilet paper and, in women’s facilities, covered
receptacles for sanitary napkins are essential. Washing facilities
should be available in or near the toilet rooms. The facilities must
be kept clean, sanitary, and in a good state of repair.
That laundries did not always meet these standards may be seen
from the fact that in 33 percent of them toilet facilities were described
as poor; and in 43 percent, only fair. Only one-fourth of the 257
plants were described as good or very good. In the large southern
city of Memphis there was not even one laundry where facilities were
considered good—the majority were poor. On the other hand, not
one Louisville laundry was considered poor.
Toilet facilities judged good or very good were of the type previously
described as being adequate, located in rooms satisfactorily lighted
and ventilated. In a few laundries clean, modern toilets were" enclosed
in individual steel booths which could be closed by a door equipped
with a fastener.
Eye-witness comments by agents on the poor facilities describe
shocking conditions. Laundry owners who accompanied agents in
touring the plant sometimes claimed they themselves were seeing the
women’s personal service facilities for the first time. Agents’ observa­
tions of poor facilities showed the number of toilets was inadequate.
Almost invariably the toilets, as well as the toilet rooms, were dirty,
often with heavily accumulated dirt testifying to infrequent and
haphazard cleaning. Some of the most serious deficiencies indicated
a disregard for simple, basic decency. The following observations were
among those made: no toilet paper provided (one plant had supplied
a mail-order catalogue (!) as a substitute); two or more toilets, without
separating partitions, located in a dressing room and unscreened from
the rest of the room; broken seats or none at all; leaking, out-of-order
toilets; common toilets for men and women; inadequate lighting and
ventilation in toilet room. Among the worst facility encountered
were outside toilets. Such a facility in a Virginia laundry consisted
of a small, dilapidated shack located in an outside alley. Only a thin
wall separated two, filthy toilets, one for each sex. When not in use,
the toilet-doors were open.
Additional and/or modern facilities were sometimes needed, but
very often necessary improvements could have been made by better




64

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

maintenance of existing facilities. Particularly needed were cleanli­
ness and prompt repair. Frequently lacking were such essentials as
toilet paper, sanitary-napkin dispensers, covered receptacles, and
door-fasteners. Frequently the facilities for Negro women were
inferior to those available to white women. Sometimes, though
Negro women outnumbered white, fewer toilets were provided for
the Negroes.
SEATING

Most laundry production jobs require the worker to stand while
working. However, women menders are seated, and occasionally
women who operate handkerchief ironers or fold small pieces of flatwork are provided with seats. While it may not be feasible to seat
workers at most laundry jobs, seats are essential for use during lunch,
rest, or enforced waiting periods. From a North Carolina laundry
came the report that shirtline operatives, who had almost daily
waiting periods, sometimes had to wait more than an hour at a time
for shirts to be brought to them. Although this may be an extreme
illustration, it was not unusual to find that workers had several short
waiting periods daily. Aside from the fact that such unproductive
waiting time is a loss both to the employer and the employee, it
would seem only reasonable to expect to have a seat during enforced
idle time.
Authoritative experts agree that alternate sitting and standing
positions are more healthful and more conducive to efficiency than
are either constant standing or constant sitting. Constant standing is
fatiguing. Every State in the country except Mississippi and Illinois 2
now has legislation requiring that seats be provided for women
employees. Many of the seating laws, however, cannot be satisfac­
torily enforced because they do not define what is meant by “adequate
seats.”
.
Two types of seating were investigated—seats for use, when possi­
ble, at or near work stations, and seats for use during lunch and rest
periods. Almost a fourth (59) of all the laundries visited provided no
seats whatsoever for plant workers—a deficiency especially prevalent
in small cities of Georgia, North and South Carolina. Workers in
100 other laundries, where seating was poor, were not much better off.
Frequently, a couple of chairs, without backrests at that, were pro­
vided only for the menders. In one laundry, typical of others, women
workers had no alternative but to eat their lunch while sitting on
window sills or work tables.
.
In only 35 laundries, most of them in the Middle West, was seating
described as good or very good. Here, a sufficient number of seats
was provided for use during lunch and rest periods. Sometimes seats
were available at work stations. In one plant flatwork folders sat
while folding small or medium-sized pieces, alternating jobs every day
or half-day with feeders, to give all flatworkers an opportunity to sit
part of the time.
2 Illinois had a seating law, but it is no longer in effect.




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

65

DRESSING, REST, AND LUNCH ROOM FACILITIES

Facilities outside the work area where women could eat lunch, rest
when necessary, and change clothing were not too common. In
small plants one adequately equipped room may suffice, while larger
plants may require three separate rooms—a lunch room, a rest room,
and a dressing room.
Dressing Booms
Almost half the laundries had no such facility, a more common
failure in the Southeast than in the Middle "West. When provided,
the dressing rooms were of various types. Sometimes the facility
consisted only of a narrow partitioned aisle where coats were hung, but
in a few places large rooms were available, equipped with benches,
metal lockers, and possibly showers. By and large the dressing facil­
ity, when available, provided hooks or hangers for coats, a bench or
two, and perhaps a mirror. Most of the dressing rooms were consid.... !

'

NOTE LOCKERS AND SHOWERS IN THIS REST ROOM FOR WOMEN LAUNDRY
WORKERS




66

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

ered unsatisfactory because crowded, improperly lighted and ventil­
ated, and inadequately equipped.
Two of the best dressing rooms observed were in relatively large
laundries. A Chicago laundry provided a large room, equipped with
individual metal lockers and benches. Adjacent to it was a first aid
room, with cot and equipment. A North Carolina laundry provided
dressing rooms for both white and Negro women, both rooms large,
adequately furnished, and equipped with showers.
Rest Rooms
These are practically an unknown luxury to laundry workers, even
to those employed in large plants. Only 15 of 91 midwestern laund­
ries provided rest rooms, much more scarce in the Southeast where
only 7 were found among 166 plants. Many of the few rest rooms
observed were unsatisfactory.
Lunch Rooms
Only about 1 of every 10 laundries provided a lunch room, although
it would appear that such a facility is necessary in an industry where
most employees are allowed only half an hour for lunch, hardly enough
time to leave the building, eat at a nearby restaurant, and return.
In many laundries women ate their lunch in the work area.
Some of the relatively few lunch rooms were of a desirable type.
Most were separate rooms, used only as eating places. Sometimes
low-cost, hot food was served, cafeteria style. Others had facilities

A MODEST EMPLOYEE CAFETERIA IN A LAUNDRY. FREE COFFEE IS
FEATURED.




PHYSICAL WORKING CONDITIONS

67

for food-preparation or refrigeration. Chairs and tables were pro­
vided. In some plants, vending machines dispensed candy, cookies,
and soft drinks, or a snack bar might be provided where workers
could buy milk, coffee, sandwiches, candy, and the like.
In a few laundries which had no eating facilities on the premises,
management had made provision for an adequate noonday meal for
the employees. Arrangements had been made to have a neighbor­
hood woman prepare lunch and serve it in her home to workers of a
North Carolina laundry. A similar provision had been made in
another plant, where a woman prepared lunch and brought it to the
laundry.
No Facilities
Almost half the laundries had no dressing, rest, or lunch rooms.
Here, coats were usually hung on nails or hooks in the workroom;
lunch, if taken at the plant, was eaten in the workroom; and quiet,
comfortable rest facilities were not available. Plants entirely lacking
in service facilities were substantially more prevalent in the Southeast,
where they constituted three-fifths of the 166 southeastern plants.
Several were large plants, employing more than 100 women, where
the provision of minimum adequate facilities would not be an unreason­
able requirement.




PUBLICATIONS OF THE WOMEN'S BUREAU
For complete list of publications, write the Women’s Bureau.
Single copies of these publications—Or a small supply for special
educational purposes—may be secured through the Women’s Bureau
without charge, as long as the free supply lasts. These bulletins may
be ■purchased direct from the Superintendent of Documents, Wash­
ington 25, D. C., at prices listed. A discount of 25 percent on orders
of 100 or more copies is allowed. Leaflets may be secured from the
Women’s Bureau.
Bulletins available for distribution, published since 1940
No. 157. The Legal Status of Women in the United States of America,
January 1938, United States Summary. 1941. 89 pp.
150. No. 157-A. Cumulative Supplement, 1938-1945.
31 pp. 1946 100. Leaflet—Women’s Eligibility for
Jury Duty. June 1, 1947.
175. Earnings in the Women’s and Children’s Apparel Industry
in the Spring of 1939. 91 pp. 1940. 150.
176. Application of Labor Legislation to the Fruit and Vegetable
Canning and Preserving Industries. 162 pp. 1940. 200.
177. Earnings and Hours in Hawaii Woman-Employing Indus­
tries. 53 pp. 1940. 100.
178. Women’s Wages and Hours in Nebraska. 51 pp. 1940.
100.

...

180. Employment in Service and Trade Industries in Maine.
30 pp. 1940. 100.
182. Employment of Women in the Federal Government, 1923
to 1939. 60-pp. 1941. 100.
183. Women Workers in Their Family Environment. (City of
Cleveland, State of Utah) 82 pp. 1941. 15^.
185. The Migratory Labor Problem in Delaware. 24 pp. 1941.
100.

'

...

.

.

186. Earnings and Hours in Pacific Coast Fish Canneries. 30
pp. 1941. 100.
187. Labor Standards and Competitive Market Conditions in
the Canned-Goods Industry. 34 pp. 1941. 100.
188. Office Work in 5 Cities in 1940:
1, Houston (100); 2, Los Angeles (100); 3, Kansas
City (150); 4, Richmond (150); 5, Philadelphia(150);
Chart, Salary Rates in 5 Cities.
189. Part 1. Women’s Factory Employment in an Expanding
Aircraft Production Program. 12 pp. 1942. 50. (See
Bull. 192-1.)
Part 4. Employment of and Demand for Women WTorkers
in the Manufacture of Instruments—Aircraft, Optical
68




PUBLICATIONS OP WOMEN S BUREAU

190.
191.

.192.

195.
196.
197.
198.
199.
200.
201.
202.

203.

69

and Fire-Control, and Surgical and Dental. 20 pp.
1942. 5*5.
Recreation and Housing for Women War Workers: A Hand­
book on Standards.t 40 pp.V 1942. 10*5.
State Minimum-Wage Laws and Orders, 1942: An Analysis.
52 pp. and 6 folders. 1942. 20*5. Supplements through
1946. Mimeo. Progress of Minimum-Wage Legislation,
1943-1945.
Reports on employment of women in wartime industries:
1, Aircraft Assembly Plants (10*5); 2, Artillery Ammuni­
tion Plants (5*5); 3, Manufacture of Cannon' and Small
Arms (10*5); 4, Machine Tool Industry (10*5); 5, Steel
(10*5); 6, Shipyards (20*5); 7, Foundries (10*5); 8, Army
Supply Depots (10*5); 9, Cane-Sugar Refineries (10*5).
Women Workers in Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay. 15 pp.
1942. 5*5.
“Equal Pay” for Women in War Industries. 26 pp. 1942.
100.
Women Workers in Some Expanding Wartime Industries—
New Jersey, 1942. 44 pp. 1943. 10*5.
Employment and Housing Problems of Migratory Workers
in New York and New Jersey Canning Industries, 1943.
35 pp. 1944. 10*5.
Successful Practices in the Employment of Nonfarm Women
on Farms in the Northeastern States. 44 pp. 1944.
10*5.
.
British Policies and Methods in Employing Women in War­
time. 44 pp. 1944. 10*5.
Employment Opportunities in Characteristic Industrial Oc­
cupations of Women. 50 pp. 1944. 10*5.
State Labor Laws for Women with Wartime Modifications,
Dec. 15, 1944.
.
Parti. Analysis of Hour Laws. 110 pp. 1945. 15*5.
Part II. Analysis of Plant Facilities Laws. 43 pp.
1945. 10*5.
PartHI. Analysis of Regulatory Laws. Prohibitory
Laws, Maternity Laws. 12 pp. 1945. 5p.
Part IV. Analysis of Industrial Home-Work Laws. 26
pp. 1945. 10*5.
Part V. Explanation and Appraisal. 66 pp. 1946.
15*5.
The Outlook for Women in Occupations in the Medical and
Other Health Services.
No. 1—Physical Therapists. 14 pp. 1945. 10*!.
No. 2—Occuptaional Therapists. 15 pp. 1945. lOp.
No. 3—Professional Nurses, 66 pp. 1946. 15*!.
No. 4—Medical Laboratory Technicians. 10 pp.
1945. 10*!.
No. 5—Practical Nurses and Hospital Attendants.
20 pp. 1945. 10*!.
No. 6—Medical Record Librarians. 9 pp. 1945. 10c!,
No. 7■—Women Physicians. 28 pp. 1945. 10c.




70

WOMEN WORKERS IN POWER LAUNDRIES

No.
No.
No.
No.

8—X-Ray Technicians. 14 pp. 1945. 10c.
9—Women Dentists. 21 pp. 1945. 10*4.
10—Dental Hygienists. 17 pp. 1945. 10*4.
11—Physicians’ and Dentists’ Assistants. 15 pp.
1946. 10*4.
No. 12—Trends and Their Effect Upon the Demand
for Women Workers. 55 pp. 1946. 15*4.
204. Women’s Emergency Farm Service on the Pacific Coast in
1943. 36 pp. 1945. 10*4.
205. Negro Women War Worker. 23 pp. 1945. 10*4.
206. Women Workers in Brazil. 42 pp. 1946. 100.
207. The Woman Telephone Worker. 38 pp. 1946. 10*4.
207-A. Typical Women’s Jobs in the Telephone Industry. (In
press.)
208. Women’s Wartime Hours of Work—The Effect on Their
Factory Performance and Home Life. 187 pp. 1947.
35*4.
209. Women Workers in Ten War Production Areas and Their
Postwar Employment Plans. (Springfield-Holyoke,
Baltimore, Dayton-Springfield, Detroit-Willow Run, Ke­
nosha, Wichita, Mobile, Seattle-Tacoma, San FranciscoOakland, and Erie County, N. Y.) 56 pp. 1946. 15*4.
210. Women Workers in Paraguay. 16 pp. 1946. 10*4.
211. Employment of Women in the Early Postwar Period, With
Background of Prewar and War Data. 14 pp. 1946.
10*4.
212. Industrial Injuries to Women. (In press.)
213. Women Workers in Peru. (In press.)
214. Maternity-Benefits Under Union-Contract Health Insur­
ance Plans. (In press.)
215. Women Workers in Power Laundries. (Instant publication.)
216. Women Workers After VJ-Day in One Community—Bridge­
port, Conn. (In press.)
217. International Work for Status of Women. (In press.)
218. Women’s Occupations Through Seven Decades. (In press.)
219. Earnings of Women Factory Workers, 1946. (In press.)
Special bulletins
No. 2. Lifting and Carrying Weights by Women in Industry. Rev.
1Q46.

12 pp.

50.

3. Safety Clothing for Women in Industry. 11 pp. 1941. 100.
Supplements: Safety Caps for Women Machine Operators.
4 pp. 1944. 50. Safety Shoes for Women War Workers.
4 pp. 1944. 50.
.
4. Washing and Toilet Facilities for Women War Workers.
11 pp. 1942. 50.
1
10. Women’s Effective War Work Requires Good Posture. 6 pp.
1943. 50.
13. Part-Time Employment of Women in Wartime. 17 pp.
1943. 100.
14. When You Hire Women. 16 pp. 1944. 100.
15. Community Services for Women War Workers. 11 pp.
1944. 50.




PUBLICATIONS OF WOMEN’S BUREAU

71

19. The Industrial Nurse and the Woman Worker. 47 pp.
1944. 100.
20. Changes in Women’s Employment During the War. 29 pp.
1944. 100. (Chart based on statistical data also avail a­
ble.)
Bibliography on Night Work for Women. 1946. Multilith.
Leaflets
Standards for Employment of Women. Leaflet No. 1, 1946.
Training for Jobs—For Women and Girls. Leaflet No. 1, 1947.
Equal'Pay for Women. Leaflet No. 2, 1947.
Women White-Collar Workers, “Re-Tool Your Thinking for Your
Job Tomorrow.” 1945.
Protect Future Wage Levels Now (on minimum-wage legislation).
1946.
■
Unemployment Compensation—How it Works for Working
Women. 1945.
Why Women Work. 1946. Multilith.
The Women's Bureau—Its Purpose and Functions. 1946.
Your Job Future After College. 1947.




o