View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery

Statement of
William McChesney Martin, Jr.,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
before the
Subcommittee on National Security and International Operations




of the
Committee on Government Operations
United States Senate

August 30, 1965

A strong, healthy American economy is vital to our national
security—both because it provides the means with which we defend our¬
selves and because our influence in international affairs is inextricably
related to our own economic performance.
The Federal Reserve System has a host of duties and responsi¬
bilities related to the supervision of banks, the performance of fiscal
agency services for the Treasury, and the efficient functioning of the
payments mechanism in the United States, but far and away its major
responsibility is to encourage, as best it can with the tools at its
disposal, financial conditions which will, in turn, contribute to
vigorous, sustained growth in output and employment.

In other words,

our overriding objective is to strengthen the U. S. economy.
I have spoken thus far of the strength of the American economy
without making any special reference to the strength of the dollar as
an international currency or to our balance of payments.

As some of you

probably know, to me these are part of the same package.

We cannot have

a strong economy without a strong dollar.

In the long run, equilibrium

in our international accounts is just as essential to our domestic
prosperity as it is to the dollar's position in international commerce.
It would be utterly unrealistic to think that we could have lasting
prosperity in this country if we had a weak dollar, and consequently a
deteriorating confidence around the world in the United States and its
economic system.




-2Let me say just a few words about what the Federal Reserve System
can do and what it has been doing to help bring about the kind of financial
climate that is conducive "to maximum production, employment and purchasing
power"--the objectives of Government economic policy as set forth in the
Employment Act of 1946.
Basically, our influence on economic developments stems from our
authority to specify the amount of reserves that banks are required to hold
and our control over the supply of these reserves.

Because of short-term

fluctuations in factors beyond our control, we cannot determine precisely
the amount of reserves that are available to banks each day, or even each
week; but we can offset these fluctuations in the longer run, and it is
fair to say that from month to month and year to year the supply of reserves
is determined by the policies of the Federal Open Market Committee,
We could undertake to regulate the growth of reserves available
to banks in accordance with some set formula.

As a practical matter, how¬

ever, the Committee exercises its regulative influence by establishing and
maintaining conditions as to the cost and availability of reserves befitting
current economic needs.

With this approach, the growth of bank reserves

reflects in part market factors, which depend in turn on the strength of
credit demands within the economy.
Regulation of the supply of reserves available to commercial banks
has an influence on the cost and availability of credit and on the rate of
growth in money and credit, which affects in turn the aggregate demand for
goods and services.

But these variables are also influenced by many other

factors, and the impact of moderate changes in monetary policy is often
hard to identify, much less quantify.

Even fairly drastic changes in our

policies may at times be overshadowed by the sweep of other developments.




-3Let me digress here to say that our own staff and many other econ¬
omists working indeoendently are laboring continuously—aided considerably
by the advances in recent years in computer technology--to isolate and meas¬
ure more exactly the impact of changes in policy at various stages of this
process so that we may think and speak with more precision about the ulti¬
mate effects of policy changes.

In the meantime, the precise magnitude and

timing of these effects are not subject to exact scientific determination
and so remain a matter of judgment, and one on which judgments may differ,
I am stressing these limits of our knowledge in order to explain
why central banking remains an art rather than a science.
it is the art of moderation, or the middle way.

And as an art,

At all times, we must be

aware of the risk that the economy might be undermined by either defla-*
tion or inflation.
What the Federal Open Market Committee does in performing its
policy-making functions, can be described in infinite detail, but it can
also be summarized accurately, I think, in a very few words.

The Com¬

mittee issues directives to the Manager of the System's Open Market
Account as to the conditions of reserve availability which, in its best
judgment, will be most conducive to the sound, healthy growth of the
economy.

Most often, over the years, there has been a substantial

unanimity in the Committee as to the directive most likely to contribute
to this end.

Occasionally there have been sharp differences of view,

but these have usually come at times when the future course of economic
events was especially hard to divine, and our thinking has tended to
come together again as the situation clarified.




-4Thus far I have described our functions and their relation to
what I understand to be your interests in very general terms,

I surmise

from your initial memorandum and your previous hearings that it would be
appropriate for me to tell you about our activities in the international
field in a little more detail.
Let me say, first of all, that the Federal Reserve has neither
the authority nor the inclination to make foreign policy of any kind,
including foreign financial policy.

As a member of the National Advisory

Council on International Monetary and Financial Problems, I am called
upon to advise the President on those problems.
has, and can have, only one foreign policy.

But the United States

Any action the Federal Reserve

may take in matters connected with foreign relations, any negotiation or
discussion with foreign central bankers, any participation in international
activities, institutions, or meetings--in short, anything we do or say
in this area is carefully coordinated with those Government agencies to
which the President has delegated authority, and on occasion directly
with the White House.
But within the framework of U.S. foreign financial policy, and
with the full approval and indeed encouragement of the Administration,
the Federal Reserve has greatly expanded its international activities
in recent years.

These activities include three different, though

interconnected, categories:

first, participation in international

meetings, discussions, and negotiations in which representatives of
the Federal Reserve form part of a U.S. delegation; second, a wide range
of informational contacts, formal and informal, with foreign central banks;




-5-

and third, arrangements with foreign central banks on foreign exchange
operations.
Federal Reserve representatives, acting as members of a U.S.
delegation, have played important roles in meetings and negotiations
connected with the International Monetary Fund, with the so-called
Group of Ten, and with the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development.
Federal Reserve connection with the work of the IMF started
even before that organization was established:

members of the Board of

Governors and of its staff participated in the drafting of the proposals
that led to the Bretton Woods Conference of 1944, and in the work of the
Conference and the drafting of the IMF Agreement itself.

More recently,

they have regularly formed part of the U.S. delegation at the annual
meeting of the IMF, and of the group of officials that consults every
year with the IMF on economic and monetary developments and policies in
the United States.
Federal Reserve officials also play an important role as
members of the various U.S. delegations in the so-called Group of Ten,
which includes the ten leading member countries of the International
Monetary Fund.

This is the group of member countries that agreed in

December 1961 "to lend the Fund amounts of their currencies up to a
total of $6 billion, so as to reinforce the Fund's ability to grant
drawings to participants in the Arrangements in order to forestall or




-6-

cope with an impairment of the international monetary system. "ll/ By
Act of June 19, 1962, the Congress authorized the United States to
participate in an amount up to $2 billion in these Arrangements.
The Ministers and Central Bank Governors of these ten
countries, together with the Managing Director of the IMF, decided in
October 1963 to review the functioning of the international monetary
system and the probable future needs for international liquidity.

They

instructed their Deputies to examine these questions and to report on
the progress of their studies.

The Secretary of the Treasury, as the

U.S. member of the Ministerial group, appointed the Under Secretary of
the Treasury for Monetary Affairs and a member of the Board of Governors,
Mr. Daane, as his Deputies.

These U.S. Deputies, and their countetparts

from the central banks and finance ministries of the other countries of
the Group of Ten, have been responsible for constructive work on the
international payments problem, especially for important studies on
problems of reserve assets and other matters of vital importance for
any appraisal and reform of the international monetary system.

Staff

members of the Federal Reserve have participated, and still are partici¬
pating, in the studies undertaken by the working parties of the Deputies.
Further, Federal Reserve officials form part of the U.S. dele¬
gations to the meetings of the Economic Policy Committee of the OECD--the

1/ Annex to the Ministerial Statement of the Group of Ten of
August 10, 1964, section 16 (f).




-7successor to the organization set up to help implement the Marshall
Plan--and of its working parties.

From the point of view of the Federal

Reserve, the most important of these groups is Working Party 3, which
periodically discusses the balance-of-payments problems and policies
of the participating countries.
These discussions in WP-3 are valuable as means of conveying
information and fostering mutual understanding.

But they have acquired

particular significance since WP-3 has been charged by the Ministers of
the Group of Ten with the task of providing "a basis for multilateral
surveillance of the various elements of liquidity creation, with a
view to avoiding excesses or shortages in the means of financing existing
or anticipated surpluses and deficits in the balance of payments, and to
discussing measures appropriate for each country in accordance with the
2/
general economic outlook.11—' WP-3 has also been charged by the Ministers
with the task of undertaking a thorough study of the measures

and instru¬

ments best suited for averting large and persistent payments imbalances.
Meetings of Federal Reserve officials with other central
bankers take place periodically within the framework of the Bank for
International Settlements and the Center for Latin American Monetary
Studies, which is known by the initials of its Spanish title as CEMLA.
The Federal Reserve, in accordance with then prevailing U.S. policies,
declined formal membership in the BIS when it was first established.
But it has more recently, in accordance with contemporary U.S. policies,

2/




Annex to the Ministerial Statement of August 10, 1964, section 37,

-8accepted the invitation of the BIS to send observers to the monthly
and annual meetings of the central bankers that form its Board of
Directors.

These meetings do not result in policy decisions but they

permit a frank exchange of information and opinions among central
banks which are useful in many ways. One of the members of the Board
regularly attends the annual meeting of the BIS members. At the monthly
meetings the Federal Reserve is usually represented by officials of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York--customarily Mr. Hayes, its President,
or Mr. Coombs, its Vice President in charge of the Foreign Department,
who also acts as Special Manager for System foreign-exchange operations.
Recently, the work of the BIS--like that of Working Party 3
of the OECD--has been integrated with that of the Group of Ten, since
the Ministers of the Group of Ten have asked the BIS to combine statis¬
tical data "bearing on the means utilized to finance surpluses or
deficits11 in the international accounts of the members of the Group,
and to supply them "confidentially to all participants and to Working
Party 3 of OECD."^
The Federal Reserve is closely associated with, and provides
technical and financial support to, CEMLA, which is a research organi¬
zation established by the central banks of the Western Hemisphere.
Again, our participation is mainly informational but we are also
assisting CEMLA in the important task of helping to train central bankers
for Latin American countries.
3/ Annex to Ministerial Statement, section 37.




-9-

In addition, the heads of the central banks of the Americas
are now meeting annually for the purpose of discussing common problems.
Participation of the Federal Reserve in these gatherings demonstrates
that the United States is interested in close financial collaboration
with its American sister republics just as it is interested in co¬
operating with countries in the Group of Ten.
The day-to-day activities of the Federal Reserve have been most
directly affected by its participation in foreign-exchange operations.
Between the early 'thirties and the early 'sixties, the Federal Reserve
did not operate in the foreign-exchange market for its own account,
although it continued to do so as fiscal agent for the Treasury and its
Stabilization Fund, and as banking correspondent of foreign central
banks.

After lengthy deliberation and full consultation with the

Treasury, the Federal Reserve decided in February 1562 to re-enter the
foreign-exchange field.

As set forth in the Authorization given by the

Federal Open Market Committee to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
the basic purposes of the operations are (1) to help safeguard the value
of the dollar, in international exchange markets; (2) to aid in making the
international payments system more effective; (3) to further monetary
cooperation with foreign central banks and the IMF; (4) to help moderate
temporary imbalances in international payments; and (5) in the long run,
to make possible growth in international liquidity in accordance with
the needs of an expanding world economy.




-10-

The Federal Reserve has conducted its foreign-exchange
operations mainly in the form of mutual arrangements with major foreign
central banks and the BIS.

It also purchases or sells convertible

foreign currencies outright, in the spot market, or engages in forward
operations in such currencies; but the total amount of spot currencies
the Special Manager is authorized to hold for System account and the
total amount of forward transactions as well as the purposes for which
he is permitted to engage in such transactions are strictly circumscribed
in the directives given him by the FOMC.

Holdings of foreign currencies

through outright spot purchases are limited to an aggregate of $150
million, and forward transactions--excepting forward transactions that
are merely designed to eliminate the exchange risk of spot holdings or
forward commitments--are limited to $275 million equivalent.
In contrast to the modest amounts of these market transactions,
the Federal Reserve has concluded with eleven foreign central banks and
the BIS mutual currency agreements, the so-called swap agreements, under
which the Federal Reserve could draw a total of $2.8 billion in foreign
exchange, and its partners a corresponding amount in dollars.

Generally,

these agreements are on a stand-by basis; in other words, a participating
central bank draws on the arrangement only when, and to the extent that,
it needs an amount in foreign exchange or dollars, respectively.
Cumulatively, from the beginning of the operations to the end
of July 1965, drawings under the swap agreements reached the impressive
totals of $2.2 billion equivalent drawn by the Federal Reserve and $3.4




-11-

billion drawn by foreign central banks.

Of course the amounts out¬

standing at any one time have been much smaller.

At the end of 1964,

for instance, outstanding drawings by the System totalled less than
$300 million, and outstanding drawings by foreign central banks $200
million, leaving a net debtor position of the System of less than $100
million--which, incidentally, has since turned into a net creditor position.
Under the swap agreements, both the System and its partners
make drawings only for the purpose of counteracting the effects on ex¬
change markets and reserve positions of temporary or transitional
fluctuations in payments flows.

About half of the drawings ever made

by the System, and most of the drawings made by foreign central banks,
have been repaid within three months; nearly 90 per cent of the recent
drawings made by the System and 100 per cent of the drawings made by
foreign central banks have been repaid within six months.
In any event, no drawing is permitted to remain outstanding
for more than twelve months.

This policy ensures that drawings will be

made, either by the System or by a foreign central, bank, only for
temporary purposes and not for the purpose

of financing a persistent

payments deficit.
In all swap arrangements both parties are fully protected from
the danger of exchange-rate fluctuations.

If a foreign central bank

draws dollars, its obligation to repay dollars would not be altered if
in the meantime its currency were devalued.
exchanges of currencies rather than credits.

Moreover, the drawings are
For instance, if, say, the

National Bank of Belgium draws dollars, the System receives the equivalent




-12in Belgian francs; and since the National Bank of Belgium has to make
repayment in dollars, the System is at all times protected from any
possibility of loss. Obviously, the same protection is given to foreign
central banks whenever the System draws a foreign currency.
The interest rates for drawings are identical for both parties.
Hence, until one party disburses the currency drawn., there is no net
interest burden for either party. Amounts drawn and actually disbursed
incur an interest cost, needless to say; the interest charge is generally
close to the U.S. Treasury bill rate.
The advantages of these arrangements for the United States, and
for the free world in general, can best be explained by briefly discussing
two instances:

Federal Reserve actions on the tragic day of President

Kennedy's assassination, and at the time of the sterling crisis last
November.
The initial shock of the news of the assassination of the
President temporarily paralyzed the New York exchange market, and there
was imminent danger of panic selling of dollars here and abroad.

The

Special Manager of the System foreign-exchange account immediately offered
in the market sizable amounts of foreign currencies at the rates prevail¬
ing before the tragedy. As the market realized that the Federal Reserve,
with the cooperation of foreign central banks, was fully prepared to
defend existing exchange-rate levels, speculation subsided.

By the end

of the day, Federal Reserve intervention plus a parallel intervention of
the Bank of Canada together totalled less than $50 million in all




-13-

currencies.

No further Federal Reserve intervention was needed on the

following days.
In November 1964, sterling was hit by large waves of selling,
despite actions taken by the British authorities, including an increase
in Bank Rate to 7 per cent and the introduction of a 15 per cent import
surcharge.

On November 24, a massive credit package to back up sterling

began to take shape.

The Federal Open Market Committee approved a

$250 million increase in the swap arrangement with the Bank of England;
simultaneously, the Export-Import Bank granted Britain a $250 million
credit.

The Bank of England and Federal Reserve officials were in almost

continuous telephone communication with the other major central banks
which participate in the network of swap arrangements with the System,
and on the afternoon of November 25 a $3 billion package of credits
obtained from eleven countries and the BIS could be announced.
Federal Reserve drawings under the swap arrangements do not
necessarily reflect an international payments deficit of the United
States.

Regardless of our overall payments position, it is unavoidable

that from time to time the United States has a substantial deficit in
relation to one country, and a substantial surplus in relation to another.
If the foreign surplus country traditionally converts dollar accruals into
gold while the foreign deficit country holds most of its reserves in
dollars, the U.S. gold stock will be reduced even in the absence of an
overall payments deficit; this actually happened last quarter, when--as
you know--the United States had a payments surplus.




-14-

But insofar as the deficit in relation to the foreign surplus
country might be deemed temporary, the decline in the U.S. gold stock
could be avoided by means of a drawing on the swap arrangement with
that country.

Similarly, if the foreign deficit country is pressed for

reserves, it may also prefer to make a drawing on its swap arrangement
rather than reduce its reserves, provided that its deficit is considered
temporary and reversible.

Hence, swap drawings initiated by the System

on some central bank are usually outstanding side by side with swap
drawings initiated by some other central bank.
The concern of the Federal Reserve with international matters
is not restricted to the international activities of the System.

Our

concern is most directly connected with the main purpose of our monetary
policy:

in view of the inter-relations between our country's domestic

and international monetary equilibrium, domestic policy considerations
are sufficient reason for avoiding policies that would perpetuate or
aggravate a payments imbalance.
It is true that the recent U.S. payments deficit has been of a
character very different from that of payments difficulties of most
other countries.

In general, a country suffers from a payments deficit

when its imports of goods and services exceed its exports.

But the

United States does not spend more abroad on goods and services than it
earns.

On the contrary, it has had record export surpluses in recent

years, even after deducting all Government expenditures abroad from its
export receipts.

But U.S. investors have lent and invested funds overseas

that were larger than the export surplus.




Hence, although the international

-15-

wealth of the United States has increased, its international liquidity
has declined:

its gold reserves have dropped, and its short-term

liabilities have increased faster than its liquid claims on foreigners.
This difference between the U.S. position and the usual position
of a deficit country may be important from the point of view of needed
remedies; it does not alter the fact that a large and persistent de¬
cline in the international liquidity of the United States can no more
be permitted to go on unchecked than could a trade deficit.

There are,

in my judgment, three main reasons why a continuation of the decline in
our international liquidity would be extremely harmful for both the
United States and the rest of the free world.
First, a large part of the free world's trade and finance is
conducted in U.S. dollars.

But the dollar can continue in its inter¬

national role only as long as the world has full confidence in its stable
value.

And while the value of the dollar is ultimately based on the

prosperity and stability of the U.S. economy, confidence also is deeply
affected by changes in the relationship between our gold reserves and our
net short-term liabilities to foreigners, especially foreign monetary
authorities, which we are prepared to redeem in gold on demand.

Hence,

a persistent and large deterioration in that relationship--in other words,
a persistent and large decline in our international liquidity--tends to
undermine confidence in the dollar, and to threaten the vital role of the
dollar in international commerce.
More concretely, some foreign observers have contended that the
United States could have a persistent deficit in its payments only because




-16-

it could rely on the international role of the dollar.

Foreign merchants,

bankers, and investors have been willing to accumulate dollar balances,
and foreign central banks have been willing to accumulate dollar reserves
only because the dollar has been generally acceptable in settlement of
international transactions.

Otherwise, the United States would have had

to settle all payments deficits in gold, and would have had to take
drastic action long ago to keep its gold stock from being depleted.
There is only a short way from this line of argument to the
demand that in the future the United States be made to abide by inter¬
national payments discipline in exactly the same way as a country whose
currency does not circulate internationally; in other words, that all
settlements of international payments deficits be made exclusively in
gold, and that the dollar cease to function as a reserve currency, if
not also as a key currency in private international transactions.

Such

a change would not only wipe out U.S. gold reserves, as foreigners would
convert their dollar balances into gold.

It would also greatly reduce

the international liquidity of the free world as a whole, and hence pose
a serious threat to any further expansion of international commerce, or
even to the maintenance of its present volume.
Second, indefinite continuation of a payments deficit would
increasingly impede the conduct of U.S. monetary policy. In the long run,
domestic and international goals of monetary policy are, in my judgment,
identical; but in an emergency situation circumstances could arise in
which a sudden elimination of a payments deficit would require monetary




-17-

measures of such severity that they would not be appropriate from the
point of view of domestic policy goals.

The longer the payments deficit

remains unchecked, the greater the possibility or even probability of a
sudden emergency of that kind.
Third, while the present international payments system has, in
my judgment, functioned extremely well, it is--like all human institu¬
tions-- in need of further improvement.

The United States has the

greatest interest not only in bringing about that improvement but also
in seeing to it that the necessary improvement does not impair the inter¬
national function of the U.S. dollar.

But as long as our payments balance

continues in deficit, all suggestions made by U.S. representatives will
be subject to a suspicion that they aim not at improving the system but
at finding new and painless ways to finance the U.S. deficit and thus
to permit the United States to continue to run a deficit.

This suspicion,

unfounded though it is, needs to be allayed if we are to attain consensus
on the problem of international payments reform; it will not be finally
allayed until our payments position returns to lasting equilibrium.
The Federal Reserve is contributing to the elimination of the
payments deficit primarily by a monetary policy designed to provide member
banks with reserves large enough to permit them to continue to finance our
present prosperity and to attain even better utilization of our manpower
and capital resources but not so large as to permit either domestic in¬
flationary pressures to develop or an excessive amount of funds to flow
abroad.

In accordance with the President's balance of payments message

of February 10, 1965, this general policy is being supplemented by the




-18-

participation of the Federal Reserve in the voluntary efforts of
commercial banks and other financial institutions to restrain the
expansion of credits to foreigners.

As you know, these efforts have

been successful almost beyond expectation; but they clearly are a
temporary remedy, and cannot be relied upon to bring about lasting
equilibrium.
The Federal Reserve will continue to do its part not only in
the attempts at eliminating our payments deficit for good but also in
the work that will lead, I hope, to a better international monetary
system.

Such a system will, in my judgment, need to be based on existing

institutions which have provided a framework for unprecedented economic
progress at home and abroad;

on expanded functions of the International

Monetary Fund; on financial cooperation of the sort pioneered through
our swap arrangements; and on the continued use of reserve currencies
as a means of settling international transactions and as international
reserves side by side with gold.
Whatever the differing attitudes of countries regarding the
composition of their reserves between gold and foreign exchange, it is
a fact of financial life that all countries use reserve currencies-especially the dollar--in their exchange markets.

Thus countries in

balance of payments surplus inevitably find their dollar balances in¬
creasing; the more tary authorities of countries in deficit must sell
dollars in their exchange markets to support their exchange rates.

This

almost universal use of dollars by monetary authorities is a reflection
of the widespread employment of the dollar by private traders and financial




-19institutions, even in transactions that do not involve the United States,
The use of the dollar as a reserve is closely related to its function
as a medium of exchange, and reflects as well the predominant position
of the U.S. economy and the ready convertibility of dollars into gold
at the established price of $35 per ounce.

Certainly any proposal for

changing the international monetary system must respect these functions
performed by dollars and must avoid the introduction of incentives to
convert dollar holdings into gold.
Whether other countries do or do not wish to continue to use
the dollar as a reserve currency is of course up to them.

The United

States does not insist that other nations accumulate dollars to meet
their reserve needs. Nor does the United States claim that the amount
of dollars that flow abroad as a result of our balance of payments
position necessarily or automatically corresponds to the needs of the
rest of the world for currency reserves.

In this connection we at the

Federal Reserve can well understand those who say in effect that inter¬
national money will not manage itself.
The international monetary system must be flexible rather than
rigid.

It must be adaptable to the differing and, over time, changing

needs of the various countries.

It would be a great mistake to act as

if all countries were alike in their size, structures, policies, and
values. Any change in the monetary system must recognize the great
diversity that exists among countries, even among the major industrial
countries. And any such change must be an evolutionary one, preserving
and building upon the valuable elements of the existing system.




-20-

If interactional agreement can be reached on such a basis, the
reform of our international monetary system may be expected to contribute
to world prosperity without disturbing market processes, without violating
national monetary sovereignty, and without disrupting international co¬
operation.