View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Observations on the U.S. Economy:
Need the Fed Do More?
(With Reference to Elvis Costello, Clarence Day,
Narayana Kocherlakota and Bernard Baruch)
Remarks before the Vancouver Board of Trade

Richard W. Fisher
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada
October 1, 2010

The views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System.

Observations on the U.S. Economy: Need the Fed Do More?
(With Reference to Elvis Costello, Clarence Day, Narayana Kocherlakota
and Bernard Baruch)
Richard W. Fisher
On September 11, 2001, I was on a flight returning from the celebration of the opening of the
Jewish Museum in Berlin two days earlier. We were approaching New York City as the World
Trade Center was attacked and were rerouted to Toronto. As one of the first planes to land in
Canada, we were held on the tarmac for some time, having only been told we had been prevented
from landing in New York because of “severe headwinds.” After deplaning and going through an
extensive screening process, we were finally briefed on what little was known at the time of the
horrors of that day. We finally exited the airport to find hundreds of cars of private citizens who
had spontaneously massed and come to the airport to take any and all of their American brethren
into their homes and care for us while we waited anxiously to learn more of what had happened
and why.
That afternoon, I somehow managed to get through by phone to my wife, Nancy. She was hiding
in the basement of a home in Washington, D.C., with our two youngest children. With the
passage of time, it is easy to forget how chaotic and frightful that day was. Nancy was in
Georgetown, a stone’s throw from the Pentagon. It was unclear if all of Washington was under
attack; rumors abounded that the Capitol and the White House were targeted. I wanted to make
sure my wife and children were safe. She reported they were and then asked if I was. I remember
saying, “I am safe in the hands of our Canadian brothers and sisters.” This is the first time I have
had a formal chance to say it, so I am taking the liberty of doing so: Thank you for the
compassion and unconditional friendship you and your countrymen showed the United States on
that infamous day. For the rest of my life, Canada will hold a special place in my heart.
I am delighted to be in this magnificent, thriving city of Vancouver. My son Miles―the one who
was huddled in the basement with his mom and little sister on September 11―is filming his first
lead role in a movie here as we speak. It is a Warner Brothers film titled Final Destination 5, due
for release next summer. So, of course, I am hoping Vancouver will be the launching point for
my being able to retire in comfort. And this is the home of two of my favorite musicians, Diana
Krall and her husband, the eclectically talented Elvis Costello, who works closely with and is
highly regarded by the Dallas Symphony Orchestra. I am especially honored to speak to the
Vancouver Board of Trade and to have been introduced by Jason [McLean]. This body has long
been a forceful advocate for private enterprise and for limited and effective government
involvement in economic activity. The ethic here is very compatible with the successful
economic practices of my home state of Texas.
I have been asked to speak about the course of the U.S. economy. Before doing so, let me
provide some disclaimers.
First, as is the practice of all senior Federal Reserve officials, I speak only for myself as but one
of 18 who presently participate in Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) deliberations. I do
not speak for the others on the FOMC, and they do not speak for me.
1

Second, I do so bearing in mind a lesson from a Canadian turned Harvard professor, John
Kenneth Galbraith, who taught me and his other students that “economic forecasting was
invented to make astrology look respectable.”
It is rare that economists’ precise forecasts ever prove accurate. As the iconic Bernard Baruch
said so well: “If [economists] knew so much, they would have all the money and we would have
none.” 1 Even with the advantages we at the Federal Reserve have, with our access to data and
battalions of brilliant economists on our staffs that model and analyze it, we are not prescient.
Making monetary policy as a central banker comes down to judgment, which must constantly be
recalibrated and refined as we contemplate and make decisions. Today, I can only offer my best
personal judgment as to where the U.S. economy is headed.
An analysis of the current predicament in the United States leads one to conclude that while the
risks of a double-dip recession are small, the pace of the recovery is subpar. Late last year and in
early 2010, we had a burst of growth led primarily by inventory adjustment. Real inventory
accumulation rose from a minus $162 billion in the second quarter of 2009 to a plus $63 billion
in the second quarter of 2010, a swing of $225 billion that accounted for approximately 60
percent of the 3 percent real GDP growth that we saw over that four-quarter period. With
inventories now better aligned with sales, it is doubtful this variable will provide much economic
propulsion in the coming quarters.
Turning to final demand, the weak pace of recovery in U.S. export markets and political and
budget realities mean that little near-term growth impetus can be expected from either net
exports or government purchases. Only consumption and nonresidential fixed investment are
likely to make positive contributions to expansion. Yet, in these sectors, there is no reason to
believe that growth will be notably strong. Residential investment, meanwhile, was an outright
drag on growth last quarter, reflecting the hangover from expiring tax incentives. It has since
shown signs of bottoming out but can hardly be expected to become a robust factor for the
foreseeable future. On net, then, I see only modest third-quarter growth, with an acceleration to
moderate growth after that.
The key point is that the pace of the economic recovery is insufficient to create the number of
jobs the United States needs to bring down unemployment.
If we cannot generate enough new jobs to absorb the labor force, we cannot expect to grow final
demand needed to achieve more rapid economic growth. In the summation of the deliberations of
the FOMC last week, it was crisply noted that “employers remain reluctant to add to payrolls.”
At the same time, the Committee reported it saw no prospect on the foreseeable horizon for
inflation―the bête noire of all central bankers—to raise its ugly head; neither was the bête rouge
of deflation highlighted. Instead, in more convoluted syntax, the majority view of the Committee
was summarized as follows: “Measures of underlying inflation are currently at levels somewhat
below those the Committee judges most consistent, over the longer run, with its mandate to
promote maximum employment and price stability.” The statement concluded by saying that the
FOMC was “prepared to provide additional accommodation if needed to support the economic
recovery and to return inflation, over time, to levels consistent with its mandate.” 2

2

I am afraid that despite recent speculation in the press and among market pundits, we did little to
settle the debate as to whether the Committee might actually engage in further monetary
accommodation, or what has become known in the parlance of Wall Street as “QE2,” a second
round of quantitative easing. It would be marked by an expansion of our balance sheet beyond its
current footings of $2.3 trillion through the purchase of additional Treasuries or other securities.
To be sure, some in the marketplace―including those with the most to gain financially―read
the tea leaves of the statement as indicating a bias toward further asset purchases, executed either
in small increments or in a “shock-and-awe” format entailing large buy-ins, leaving open only
the question of when. At least one renowned investor noted in a widely reported CNBC
interview that the FOMC’s release meant “we (the Fed) want economic growth, and we don’t
care if there’s inflation.” He asked pointedly: “Have they ever said that before?” 3 For many, the
FOMC’s pronouncement was interpreted as confirming the promise of a “Fed put,” implying that
the greater the economy’s weakness, the more easy money the Fed will provide.
And yet the efficacy of further accommodation at this point is not crystal clear. When the Federal
Reserve buys Treasuries to drive down yields, it adds money to the financial system. In sharp
contrast to the depths of the Panic of 2008, when liquidity had evaporated and we stepped into
the breach to revive it, today there is abundant liquidity in our economy. The excess reserves of
private banks sitting on the balance sheets of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks exceed $1 trillion.
Nonfinancial corporations have an aggregate liquid asset ratio running at a seven-year high; cash
flow from current production is running above total investment expenditure; and cash as a
percentage of market cap is extraordinarily high. Credit availability remains a challenge for small
businesses, but only 4 percent of small businesses surveyed by the National Federation of
Independent Business reported financing as their top business problem. 4 And reports of lagging
receivables or the stretching out of payment terms that were so prominent only one year ago in
the corporate supply chain have become as scarce as hens’ teeth.
However one may view the prominence of credit constraints for small businesses, it is unclear
whether broad monetary actions will alleviate them; it may be more appropriate for the Treasury
to undertake a targeted fiscal initiative to improve credit availability to small businesses. For
mid- and large-sized nonfinancial firms, capital is fairly abundant in America, and it is unclear
how much they would benefit from lowering Treasury interest rates.
The vexing question is: Why isn’t this liquidity being utilized to hire new workers and reduce
unemployment? If current dramatically high levels of liquidity and low interest rates are not
being harnessed to add to payrolls, would driving interest rates further down and adding further
liquidity to the system through Fed purchases of Treasury securities induce businesses and
consumers to get on with spending it?
The intrepid economist would argue in the affirmative, the logic being that there is a tipping
point at which the market becomes convinced that money held in reserve earning negligible
returns is at risk of being debased through some inflation and, thus, should be spent rather than
hoarded. Hence, the appeal of the Fed’s showing a little leg of inflationary permissiveness.
I am personally wary of this argument, despite its theoretical logic. My soundings among those
who actually do the work of creating sustainable jobs and making productive capital
investments―private businesses big and small―indicate that few are willing to commit to
expanding U.S. payrolls or to undertaking significant commitments to expand capital
3

expenditures in the U.S. other than in areas that enhance productivity of the current workforce.
Without exception, all the business leaders I interview cite nonmonetary factors―fiscal policy
and regulatory constraints or, worse, uncertainty going forward―and better opportunities for
earning a return on investment elsewhere as inhibiting their willingness to commit to expansion
in the U.S. As the CEO of one medium-sized business put it to me shortly before the last FOMC
meeting, “Part of it is uncertainty: We just don’t know what the new reg[ulation]s [sic] like
health care are going to cost and what the new rules will be. Part of it is certainty: We know that
taxes are eventually going to have to increase to get us out of the fiscal hole Republicans and
Democrats alike have dug for us, and we know that regulatory intervention will be getting more
intense.” Small wonder that most business leaders I survey, including small businesses, remain
fixated on driving productivity and lowering costs, budgeting to “get less people to wear more
hats.” Tax and regulatory uncertainty―combined with a now well-inculcated culture of driving
all resources, including labor, to their most productive use at least cost―does not bode well for a
rapid diminution of unemployment and the concomitant expansion of demand.
The Fed operates under a dual mandate that charges us with both keeping prices stable and
maintaining maximum sustainable employment. Some economic theories would lead one to
believe we could shake job creation from the trees if we were to further expand our balance
sheet. Yet, to paraphrase the early 20th century progressive, Clarence Day―the once ubiquitous
contributor to my favorite magazine, The New Yorker, and author of one of my all-time favorite
films, Life with Father―“Too many [theorists] begin with a dislike of reality.” 5 The reality of
fiscal and regulatory policy inhibiting the transmission mechanism of monetary policy is vexing
to monetary theorists. And yet it seems to me to be a significant factor holding back economic
recovery.
One of my brightest and most intellectually credentialed colleagues, Narayana Kocherlakota,
president of the Minneapolis Fed, has noted that one of our deep-seated problems is structural
unemployment—that we do not have a workforce adequate to the needs of the high-value-added
businesses that define the U.S. “Firms have jobs but can’t find appropriate workers,” he says.
And he concludes, “It is hard to see how the Fed can do much to cure this problem.” 6 I would
add that if this is true, then the matching of job skills to needs is doubly complicated if
businesses feel handicapped by the current tax and regulatory regime or find other countries
better placed to expand in a globalized, cyber-ized economy that encourages investment to
gravitate to optimal locations for enhancing return on investment.
In my darkest moments, in fact, I wonder if the monetary accommodation we have engineered
might not be working in the wrong places. Far too many of the large corporations I survey report
that the most effective way to deploy cheap money raised in the current bond markets or in the
form of loans from banks, beyond buying in stock or expanding dividends, is to invest it abroad
where taxes are lower and governments are more eager to please. This would not be of concern if
foreign direct investment in the U.S. were offsetting this impulse. This year, net direct
investment in the U.S. has been running at a pace that would exceed minus $200 billion,
meaning outflows of foreign direct investment are exceeding inflows by a healthy margin. We
will have to watch the data as it unfolds to see if this is momentary fillip or evidence of a broader
trend. But I wonder: If others cotton to the view that “(the Fed) doesn’t care about inflation,” or
begin to question whether we at the FOMC can slice the apple so precisely as to maintain
inflation at a rate between what is now “somewhat below” that which is “most consistent with
[our] mandate”―say 1 percent―and a level that is more consistent with the mandate―say 2
4

percent―might this not add to the uncertainty already created by the fiscal incontinence of
Congress and the regulatory and rule-making “excesses” about which businesses now complain?
In his much-noted speech at Jackson Hole in August, Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke
spoke of the need to evaluate the costs as well as the benefits of further monetary
accommodation.
In performing a cost/benefit analysis of a possible QE2, we will need to bear in mind that one
cost that has already been incurred in the process of running an easy money policy has been to
drive down the returns earned by savers, especially those who do not have the means or
sophistication or the demographic profile to place their money at risk further out in the yield
curve or who are wary of the inherent risk of stocks. A great many baby boomers or older
cohorts who played by the rules, saved their money and have migrated over time, as prudent
investment counselors advise, to short- to intermediate-dated, fixed-income instruments, are
earning extremely low nominal and real returns on their savings. Further reductions in rates
earned on savings will hardly endear the Fed to this portion of the population. Moreover, driving
down bond yields might force increased pension contributions from corporations and state and
local governments, decreasing the deployment of monies toward job maintenance in the public
sector. Debasing those savings with even a little more inflation than what is above minimal
levels acceptable to the FOMC is unlikely to endear the Fed to these citizens. And if―and here I
especially stress the word if because the evidence is thus far only anecdotal and has yet to be
confirmed by longer-term data―if it were to prove out that the reduction of long-term rates
engendered by Fed policy had been used to unwittingly underwrite investment and job creation
abroad, particularly in countries where exchange-rate adjustment is inhibited, then the potential
political costs relative to the benefit of further accommodation will have increased.
Another issue to be considered before embarking on a program to purchase additional long-term
assets is whether such programs violate the basic tenets of the bedrock Bagehot principle, named
for the 19th century British leader who “wrote the playbook” for central banking. Walter
Bagehot advocated that when responding to a financial crisis, a central bank should lend freely at
a penalty rate to anybody and everybody on good collateral. This was the principle we followed
in addressing the Panic of 2008, and it was the right thing to do. While none of us are satisfied
with the current pace of economic expansion and job creation, presently it is not clear that
conditions warrant further crisis-like deployment of the Fed’s arsenal. Besides, it would be
difficult to build a case that the main recipient of further credit extensions, namely the U.S.
Treasury, or borrowers whose rates are based on historically low spreads over Treasuries, have
difficulty accessing the capital markets.
So I confess that, at least in my mind, it is not clear that the benefits of further quantitative easing
outweigh the costs, especially if the economic scenario I outlined at the beginning of these
comments obtains.
What I envision from the current vantage point is an anemic recovery, but not one that slips into
reverse gear. Thus, barring an unforeseen shock, I have concerns about the efficacy of further
expanding the Fed’s balance sheet until our political authorities better align fiscal and regulatory
initiatives with the needs of job creators. Otherwise, further quantitative easing might be pushing
on a string. In the worst case, it could flood the engine of the economy with gas that might later
ignite inflation.
5

Of course, if the fiscal and regulatory authorities are able to dispel the angst that businesses are
reporting, further accommodation might not even be needed. If job-creating businesses are more
certain about future policy and are satisfactorily incentivized, they are more likely to take
advantage of low interest rates, release the liquidity they are hoarding and invest it robustly in
hiring and training a workforce that will propel the American economy to new levels of
prosperity, rendering moot the argument for QE2. The key is to first remove or reduce the tax
and regulatory uncertainties that act as an impediment to businesses responding to an increase in
final demand. I consider this to be a far more desirable outcome than being saddled with a
bloated Fed balance sheet.
That is the view from the Dallas Fed.
Thank you, Peter [Brown], for inviting me to be one of the Board of Trade’s “Distinguished
Speakers.” I should tell you that last night I turned to my wife and asked, “In your wildest
dreams did you ever envision my being a Distinguished Speaker for a forum as prestigious as the
Vancouver Board of Trade, following in the footsteps of Prime Minister Goh, Prince Philip,
President Zedillo and President Clinton?” This was her reply: “I hate to let you down, Richard,
but after 37 years of marriage, you rarely appear in my wildest dreams.”
Thank you all.

1

See Bernard M. Baruch: The Adventures of a Wall Street Legend, by James Grant, New York: John Wiley and
Sons, 1997, p. 310.

2

See Federal Open Market Committee Press Release, Sept. 21, 2010,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20100921a.htm.

3

See “Hedge Fund Titan David Tepper,” interview, CNBC, Sept. 24, 2010,
www.cnbc.com/id/15840232?play=1&video=1598887347.

4

See “NFIB Small Business Economic Trends,” by William C. Dunkelberg and Holly Wade, National Federation of
Independent Business, September 2010, www.nfib.com/Portals/0/PDF/sbet/sbet201009.pdf.

5

See This Simian World, by Clarence Day, New York: Alfred Knopf, 1920, p. 67.

6

See “Inside the FOMC,” speech by Narayana Kocherlakota, Marquette, Mich., Aug. 17, 2010,
www.minneapolisfed.org/news_events/pres/speech_display.cfm?id=4525.

6