View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Monetary Policy Going Forward
(Citing Bagehot, Bernanke and Babe Laufenberg)
Remarks before the Greater Houston Partnership

Richard W. Fisher
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Houston, Texas
September 1, 2010

The views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System.

Monetary Policy Going Forward
(Citing Bagehot, Bernanke and Babe Laufenberg)
Richard W. Fisher
Thank you, Jodie (Jiles). When I close my eyes and listen to you and that rich, resonant voice, I
hear the cadence and passion of a great preacher. When I open my eyes, I see Jodie Jiles the
accountant. Jodie, you may be the only “compassionate accountant” on the planet! I thank you
for being a man of exacting precision while still possessing a great big heart. I thank you for
serving the Houston Branch of the Dallas Fed with constant dedication in reminding us that we
serve all the people of Texas and America, regardless of their economic status. And I thank you
for that kind introduction.
I recently saw a sign in a shop window in West Texas that said “Lord, please give me just one
chance … to prove that money can’t buy happiness.” Well, we all know that money can’t buy
happiness, but it sure helps. (I think it was W. Somerset Maugham who said, “Money is like a
sixth sense without which you cannot make a complete use of the other five.”) Today, I would
like to talk about money from the perspective of monetary policy. What is the Federal Reserve’s
responsibility and what can the Fed do at this critical juncture to brighten the economic picture
and bring about a happier circumstance?
Everything I say today reflects my own views. I never attempt to speak for others at the Fed; I
always speak of my own volition. Given that I rotate into a formal voting member’s slot on the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) next year, I thought it might be of interest if I outlined
how I see things moving forward.
Financial Stability
For starters, I think it important to dispel the concept that the Fed has only a “dual” mandate.
To be sure, we are responsible under the Federal Reserve Act for creating the monetary
conditions that foster full employment and price stability; I will turn to that critical dual mission
in a minute. But we also have the responsibility to preserve financial stability. Delivering on our
obligation to ensure financial stability is an important prerequisite for executing our duties under
the Act. Thus, while it is not formally stated as such, ensuring financial stability is an assumed
mandate of the Fed. Understanding that this, too, is the purpose of a central bank will help you
understand why we acted as we did to address the Financial Panic of 2008 and what we might or
might not do as we seek now to harness monetary policy to restore economic growth.
I think most everyone is aware of the actions the Fed has undertaken since the trip-wire event of
Lehman’s failure. I do want to remind you, however, that what we faced then was a full-blown
liquidity crisis. No financial counterparty was willing to trust, or lend to, another. The interbank
lending, commercial paper and asset-backed securities markets ceased to function; money market
funds “broke the buck;” the stock and bond markets were in a tailspin; the mortgage markets
were in total disarray. In response, the Fed did what central bankers have done since the iconic

1

Walter Bagehot wrote the rule book for responding to financial panics of the 19th century. We
jumped into the breach as the lender of last resort.1
This was nervous-making for many. It required that we create and deploy programs totaling
trillions of dollars to restore stability to the key markets, providing liquidity to banks and
businesses. As it turned out, these emergency interventions by the Fed were effective. And, most
important, once they had done their job, we wound them down and closed them up. Let me
repeat that: All the emergency liquidity facilities that the Federal Reserve instituted were closed
down and did not cost the taxpayers of this great country a single dime. Indeed, last year, as we
finished up this work, the Federal Reserve paid $47.4 billion in profits to the Treasury. Imagine
that! A government agency that (a) created programs that actually worked as promised, (b) made
money for the taxpayers in the process and (c) undid the programs―all in the space of about 28
months—once they had done their job.
I mention this to illustrate a couple of points.
First, we take our job seriously. We are the central bank of the most powerful and important
economy in the world. We bear significant responsibility as the lender of last resort. We have the
power to create money. This is an awesome power. We are not afraid to use it. It requires that we
discharge our duties deliberately. If we fail to act when action is required, we might be the agent
of economic destruction. And if we overreact, we can be equally destructive. Which means we
must at all times carefully weigh the costs, as well as the benefits, of any and all actions we take.
And as the efficacy of our actions depends upon confidence in our integrity, we must always
bear in mind that our word is our bond. We cannot risk either overpromising or undercommitting
to executing the duties than have been assigned to us.
Second, I mention this responsibility by way of pointing out that the situation we face now is far
different from that which we faced in 2008. Then, banks were at risk of not having access to
capital; now they have over $1 trillion in excess reserves on deposit at the 12 Federal Reserve
banks. Then, nonfinancial businesses feared the capital markets would be closed to them; now,
the bond markets for publicly traded companies are significantly improved and quite robust
(IBM recently issued three-year paper with a 1 percent coupon and, just last week, Norfolk
Southern Corp. issued a 100-year bond with a 6 percent coupon); presently, significant amounts
of working capital are lying fallow on the balance sheets of the larger firms. Then, the S&P 500
index was cascading to close at 676 on March 9 of 2009; yesterday, despite recent retracement, it
closed 55 percent higher at 1,049. Then, small businesses faced being cut off from banks and
other forms of non-publicly issued sources of capital; this July, of small businesses seeking
credit, the National Federation of Independent Business reported that only 9 percent did not have
their credit needs met and only 4 percent mentioned the availability of credit as a significant
issue.2
I think one could reasonably state that when fear reached a feverish pitch and was crippling the
most basic financial markets, the Fed acted appropriately and effectively to restore them.
That said, we are not in the financial pink. Consumers are still under financial duress, and while
our most recent survey of senior loan officers indicates banks are beginning to ease credit
standards, they are not necessarily expanding credit. The bottom line is that what is restraining
2

the economy is not a shortage of current liquidity; rather, it is uncertainty, high household debt
burdens and a lack of confidence in future income growth.
Incomes plunged in 2008 and into early 2009. Since then, growth has resumed. But the gap
between where we are now and where we would have been had we cruised along at the longterm rate of nominal growth of 4 or 4.5 percent―consistent with 2.5 percent average real growth
and 1.5 to 2 percent inflation―is large and is not narrowing. By our calculation at the Dallas
Fed, nominal income is over 9 percent lower than where it would have been had we not been
blown off course by the Panic of 2008. With incomes falling short, households have found
themselves overburdened with debt. Compounding the problem, the Conference Board’s
consumer survey shows households expecting income increases over the next six months to be
outnumbered by those expecting decreases. This pessimism about income prospects has
continued, without interruption, since the collapse of Lehman Brothers. It is unprecedented in
depth and duration in the 44 years the survey has been conducted.
As Jodie mentioned, I was a midshipman at the U.S. Naval Academy. One of the basic lessons
learned in navigation courses at Annapolis is that if a storm has blown your ship off course, you
don’t simply resume your old compass heading. You make an adjustment to offset the effects of
the blow and you beat a course accordingly. We need monetary and fiscal policies that bring
economic growth back up to speed and, over the next few years, begin to close the income gap
that opened up during the storms of 2008 and early 2009. Without such policies, progress in
deleveraging the balance sheets of households and businesses will be painfully slow and our
nation’s recovery will be drawn out longer than necessary.
Price Stability
On the price front, I am known as an inflation hawk. I am comfortable with that description. As I
have pointed out many times, ornithologists classify doves as being from the pigeon family. I do
not wish to be anybody’s pigeon, and nothing I just said about desiring faster income growth
should lead you to think I have gone soft on inflation. Nor am I alone in my firm commitment to
keeping inflation under control: You may have noted Chairman Ben Bernanke’s unequivocal
statement last week in Jackson Hole, Wyo., that he sees “no support” within the FOMC for
increasing its medium-term inflation goals above levels consistent with price stability.3 But it is
clear that inflation is not the immediate problem facing the nation. As pointed out by the
chairman, inflation has declined to a level that is at the low end of the 1.5 to 2 percent range that
the participants in FOMC deliberations consider conducive for healthy economic growth over the
long run.
The Dallas Fed, which as might be expected, being Texan, has a separate and distinct way of
calculating inflation. We use a trimmed-mean analysis.4 In studying the entrails of the price
index for consumer expenditures (the PCE), at present we see neither an impulse toward inflation
nor, despite much talk among economists and political pundits, toward deflation. Trimmed mean
inflation rates recorded over the last three months have been slightly above the rates we saw in
early spring, and the index’s six- and 12-month inflation rates have been stable over the past
three months. Within the core PCE index, rates of price change for two of the largest
components―rent and owners’ equivalent rent―have lately turned from falling to rising. That
change of direction alone should, in the near term, provide some restraint against further
3

disinflation in core PCE. In short, I concur with Chairman Bernanke’s assessment that “the risk
of either an undesirable rise in inflation or of a significant further disinflation seems low.”5
Full Employment
With the efficacy of most financial markets reasonably restored and inflation subdued, the
question then is how the Federal Reserve might best do its part to restore employment growth.
Here’s the rub. Note that I say, “Do its part.” The Fed is not the end-all for curing every
economic pathology. To return to my naval analogy, we are not the only authority in the pilot
house. We play a crucial role in conditioning the economy, but we do not play the only role.
Fiscal and regulatory authorities share significant responsibility for incentivizing economic
behavior through taxes, spending and rulemaking.
With this in mind, I have been outspoken about what I refer to as “random refereeing,” by which
I mean the tendency for lawmakers and rule makers to create programs that hinder, rather than
advance, the incentive for the private sector to expand its payrolls. I spoke of this recently in San
Antonio, noting that among the CEOs I regularly survey before every FOMC meeting―leaders
of companies nationwide that vary in size from nine employees to over a million and represent a
broad cross section of goods and service companies―the prevailing sentiment is that politicians
and officials who craft and enforce taxes and rules have been doing so in a capricious manner
that makes long-term planning, including expanding payrolls, difficult, if not impossible.6
Just last week, I sat in on a financial planning and budgeting discussion with middle managers of
one of America’s leading consumer goods producers. Asked directly how they determine the allin cost of an employee, the CFO replied, “We can’t. We can’t because we don’t know what will
happen on the tax front or with social overhead.” So their current plan is to withhold payroll
expansion in the United States while investing their growing cash reserves in driving
productivity enhancement from their current crop of over 200,000 employees, of which about
70,000 are located in the United States. Meanwhile, they are searching to expand their operations
in other countries that “offer better incentives, stability and a more entrepreneurial environment.”
The sentiment expressed by this CFO is not atypical. A careful reader of the minutes of the last
FOMC meeting will note that several participants in the committee’s deliberations “reported that
business contacts again indicated that uncertainty about future taxes, regulations, and health-care
costs made them reluctant to expand their workforces. Instead, businesses had continued to meet
growth in demand for their products largely through productivity gains and by increasing
existing employees’ hours.” This does not bode well for job creation here at home.7
The retarding effect of heightened uncertainty over the fiscal and regulatory direction of the
country makes it difficult to kick-start the transmission mechanism of the economy. One might
reasonably posit that the gas tank of those who have the capacity to hire―the private-sector
businesses of America―is reasonably full. And one might conclude that the Fed, having cut the
cost of interbank overnight lending to near zero and used quantitative easing to coax the entire
yield curve downward, has driven the cost of gas to virtually nil for both the government and
those businesses that are creditworthy.
The issue now is how that fuel might be released so as to propel the engine of job creation and
drive a happier pace of economic growth.
4

This does not mean that the actions of the Fed going forward are unimportant or that our job is
ever done. At the last meeting of the FOMC, we collectively decided to reinvest the proceeds of
payments from our portfolio of mortgage-backed securities into longer-term Treasury securities,
thus keeping constant the size of our portfolio and avoiding a possible passive reduction in
monetary accommodation. In part, this represents a recognition that the performance of the
economy is sub-par and we wish to “do no harm” to the process of repair.
The former NFL quarterback and present sports anchor for the CBS affiliate in Dallas–Fort
Worth, Babe Laufenberg, recently reminded me that in football, “momentum is not a light
switch.” It cannot be turned on in an instant; it needs to build throughout the season. At a
minimum, we need to let the slight momentum of the current economic recovery build and do
nothing to disrupt it.
As for doing more than avoiding passive tightening in an attempt to goose up that momentum,
much will depend on the cost–benefit trade-off of utilizing any of the additional tools in our kit. I
think it is abundantly clear to the market that regardless of the language the FOMC employs to
describe its deliberations and intentions, the consensus of the committee is to keep the price of
money—the cost of the gas needed for our nation’s economic engine—low until the committee is
confident that the gears of the economy have begun to mesh more robustly.
Which focuses attention on the size of our balance sheet and whether we will expand it.
Personally, I would be reluctant to do so unless or until fiscal and regulatory initiatives are
aligned with the needs of job creators. Otherwise, further accommodation might be pushing on a
string. In the worst case, it could flood the engine of the economy with gas that might later ignite
inflation. Of course, if the fiscal and regulatory authorities are able to dispel the angst that they
are reportedly causing, further accommodation may not be needed because the liquidity that has
been built up on corporate balance sheets and in the excess reserves of banks might then be
released into the economy and spur job creation.
For me, the ball is in the fiscal court for now. Any further action by the Fed must be subject to
the kind of rigorous cost–benefit analysis that Ben Bernanke cited in Jackson Hole. One of the
variables that must be taken into account is whether fiscal and regulatory policies are conducive
to growth.
Returning to the sign in that West Texas shop, I believe that monetary accommodation alone
cannot buy happiness. I am as keen as anyone on providing the monetary means to make the
engine of the American economy hum once again. We need to get back on the path of narrowing
the gap between income growth and what the American people hoped and planned for when they
charted the course of future income streams needed to meet their financial obligations, conduct
their businesses and care for their families.
As with individuals, for the economy to be truly content, it must have confidence in itself and in
the future. I believe the Fed should employ every tool it has available to make that possible. But
it is important to recognize that we cannot do it alone. The best way to leverage the influence of
monetary policy is to have fiscal and regulatory policy that complements, rather than counters,
the impact we might have in helping the economy get back on the course of sustained,
noninflationary growth.
5

Notes
1

Richard W. Fisher, “Albert H. Gordon Lecture: Comments on the Current Financial Crisis” (Speech at
Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass., Feb. 23, 2009),
www.dallasfed.org/news/speeches/fisher/2009/fs090223.cfm.
2
See “NFIB Small Business Economic Trends,” by William C. Dunkelberg and Holly Wade, National Federation of
Independent Business, August 2010, www.nfib.com/Portals/0/PDF/sbet/SBET201008.pdf.
3
Ben S. Bernanke, “The Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy” (Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyo., Aug. 27, 2010),
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100827a.htm.
4
See Trimmed Mean PCE Inflation Rate report, July 2010, www.dallasfed.org/data/pce/index.html, and “Behind
the Numbers: PCE Inflation Update, July 2010,” by Jim Dolmas, http://dallasfed.org/data/pce/2010/pce1007.cfm.
5
See note 3.
6
See Richard W. Fisher, “Random Refereeing: How Uncertainty Hinders Economic Growth” (Speech before the San
Antonio Chamber of Commerce, San Antonio, Texas, July 29, 2010),
www.dallasfed.org/news/speeches/fisher/2010/fs100729.cfm.
7
See Federal Open Market Committee meeting minutes, Aug. 10, 2010,
www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomcminutes20100810.htm.

6