View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Randall S. Kroszner

To the National Association for Business Economics 2007 Annual Washington Economic
Policy Conference, Arlington, Virginia
March 12, 2007

The Changing Dynamics of Inflation
I am pleased to be here today at this meeting of the National Association for Business Economics.
My subject this afternoon will be inflation dynamics. Since the mid-1980s, we have seen important
improvements in these dynamics--inflation is now much lower and more stable than it once was,
and it appears to be less closely correlated with movements in other economic factors than it was
during the 1960s and 1970s (see table). Moreover, we have seen these improvements not only in the
United States but in other countries as well. Questions of intense interest to many of you as well as
to us at the Federal Reserve are, What caused these changes in the inflation process? and What are
their implications for monetary policy?
Having spent many years as a University of Chicago professor, my first reaction to these changes is
to think “money.” As Milton Friedman famously said many years ago, “Inflation is always and
everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” Unfortunately, given the lack of a stable relationship
between money growth and inflation, the pure monetarist view has taken a beating since then.
However, Friedman was right that inflation is, ultimately, something that central banks determine, at
least on average, over time.
My second reaction is to think about another factor that Friedman emphasized--expectations. Views
about the inflation process vary, but expectations are at the heart of almost all of them. And in any
model in which expectations are important, monetary policy will also be important. So monetary
policy, if not money itself, remains a central determinant of inflation dynamics. Accordingly, one of
my principal themes today will be that expectations are important in the inflation process and that
the improved conduct of monetary policy, by influencing the formation of expectations in a
favorable manner, may account for many of the changes in inflation dynamics that we observe. At
the same time, I am wary of ascribing all of the changes in dynamics to monetary policy. We should
not place too much faith in any one framework, and so we need to keep an open mind about other
possible explanations for the recent changes in inflation dynamics.
Before proceeding further, let me say that the views I will express today are my own and are not
necessarily shared by the other members of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
or the Federal Open Market Committee.
The Expectational Approach to Thinking about Inflation
Now almost forty years old, the expectational approach to inflation dynamics--developed
simultaneously by Friedman and recent Nobel prize winner Edmund Phelps--is still the dominant
framework for thinking about inflation. Let me begin with a quick review of what Friedman and
Phelps said forty years ago and then discuss very briefly how it relates to current thinking about the
inflation process.
In Friedman’s framework as expressed in his 1967 presidential address to the American Economics
Association, inflation is related to inflation expectations as well as the level of resource utilization.
Friedman explained that for a variety of real-world reasons, wages and prices might not always
adjust immediately to changes in the money supply. If they did not so adjust, monetary policy could

affect resource utilization. The reason that Friedman’s work, and that of Phelps, was so
revolutionary was that it overturned the earlier belief that monetary policy could have a permanent
influence on resource utilization in favor of a new view that monetary policy could affect real
activity only temporarily.
In the early 1970s, Robert Lucas expanded on the ideas of Friedman and Phelps and noted that shifts
in the way a central bank conducts monetary policy imply changes in the way the public forms its
expectations.
Over the past thirty years, economists have taken these observations to heart in trying to explain the
behavior of overall inflation. One standard approach starts with the notion that many wages and
prices adjust only gradually to changes in costs and demand. That assumption about the
microeconomic behavior of price setters has recently been bolstered by some research that has
looked at the data underlying the consumer price index to assess how often prices change (Bils and
Klenow, 2004). The research finds that, indeed, prices for many goods and services appear to adjust
only gradually, with the typical firm changing the price of a typical item about once every four
months.
When wages and prices adjust only infrequently, expectations are important, because firms and
households must take into account the demand and supply conditions that will prevail until they
again reset their prices. All sorts of expectations will matter, but central among them are inflation
expectations: If wages and prices in general are rising over time, then when firms have a chance to
reset their prices, they will generally set them higher than they would if the overall price level was
holding steady.
Because the new approaches to understanding inflation are grounded in the behavior of individual
decisionmakers, they have the solid theoretical foundations that are valuable for policy analysis.1
Moreover, some evidence indicates that empirical models based on this research do fairly well at
forecasting. Of course, time will tell about their usefulness in the day-to-day operations of monetary
policy. But the new research does demonstrate the continuing value of the expectations-focused
approach that Friedman and Phelps championed forty years ago.
Changes in Inflation Dynamics
As I noted earlier, the inflation process seems to have changed in a number of ways in recent years,
both in the United States and in other countries. I would like to review these changes and then
consider what they may tell us about the underlying processes driving inflation.
One notable change is that movements in inflation now appear to tell us much less about future
inflation than was the case, say, thirty years ago. Here I am talking about predictions of inflation
using only information on past inflation, without taking into account any other information. The
evidence suggests that, at the peak of U.S. inflation in the late 1970s and early 1980s, the best such
“univariate” forecast of inflation--into the indefinite future--was a simple average of inflation over
the past few quarters (Stock and Watson, 2007; Cecchetti and others, 2007). In that period, sharp
increases in inflation were reversed only slowly. By contrast, shocks to inflation since roughly the
mid-1980s have tended to be short-lived, so that the best forecast of future inflation would be a very
long average of past inflation. Thus, when inflation moves above its recent long-run average, most
of the upswing will likely be quickly reversed, although this result is not guaranteed. That’s a
remarkable change in the behavior of inflation. The international evidence indicates that the
longevity of inflation shocks has been attenuated in many other countries as well (Cecchetti and
others, 2007). Moreover, the timing of the switch from largely permanent to mostly transitory
movements in inflation is remarkably similar across the United States and these other countries.
Another apparent change in the inflation process has been a reduction in the correlation between
inflation and unemployment (Atkeson and Ohanian, 2001; Roberts 2006). Now, this relationship
was always loose, as most of the historical variation in inflation has reflected influences aside from
movements in unemployment or other measures of resource utilization. Still, in the 1960s and
1970s, a reasonably strong empirical relationship between inflation and unemployment could be

found for the United States, with inflation tending to rise in periods when unemployment was low
and vice-versa. Starting in the 1980s, however, this correlation began to weaken noticeably. In fact,
some researchers now find no relationship at all, whereas others tend to find one that is of reduced
economic importance.2 Again, similar shifts have been observed in other countries, and these results
are not sensitive to whether we are looking at core inflation or total inflation (Borio and Filardo,
2006; Ihrig and others, forthcoming).
Next on the list of changes is the influence of energy prices. During the 1970s, fluctuations in
energy prices appear to have had a significant influence on core inflation--that is, on the growth rate
of consumer prices excluding food and energy. But since the early 1980s, the inflationary effect of
movements in prices for gasoline, natural gas, and other energy goods seems to have declined
considerably, even after allowance is made for a secular decline in the energy intensity of the U.S.
economy (Hooker, 1996). Indeed, some estimates even suggest that energy price shocks have no
effect whatsoever on core inflation. From a cost-accounting perspective, estimates of a zero effect
seem too improbable to be taken literally: Recent swings in energy input costs have been
sufficiently large that they should have had a noticeable effect on the prices of other goods and
services, even allowing for their relatively small share in overall costs. I will return later to possible
explanations for the sharp drop in the estimated effects of movements in energy prices.3
Finally, one of the most striking changes in the U.S. economy in recent decades has been the
reduction in the economy’s volatility. The standard deviation of quarterly growth of real (that is,
inflation adjusted) gross domestic product for the United States since the mid-1980s has been about
half that experienced during the 1960s and 1970s. The volatility of inflation has fallen to a similar
degree; moreover, the reduction in volatility for both output and inflation is widespread across
countries. Of course, a smaller volatility of real GDP is not a change in inflation dynamics. But if
monetary policy has been an important factor behind the drop in the economy’s volatility, then the
expectational mechanisms may be very similar to those affecting inflation dynamics.4
Expectations, Monetary Policy, and Changing Inflation Dynamics
As Lucas pointed out, because expectations matter for inflation, monetary policy matters for
inflation, too. And the historical record supports the notion that, starting with Chairman Paul
Volcker, U.S. monetary policy has been more focused on low and stable inflation than was the case
in the 1960s and 1970s (Romer and Romer, 2002). So it is natural to ask, can changes in the conduct
of monetary policy in the United States (and elsewhere) help to account for the changes we’ve seen
in inflation dynamics?
The strongest case for a link between monetary policy and changes in inflation dynamics is in the
greater stability of inflation. Inflation is clearly under the long-run control of the Fed, and the
relative stability of inflation clearly reflects the action of monetary policy. Thus, if the central bank
wants to keep inflation low on average over time, it can surely do so. The case for monetary policy
contributing to reduced volatility of inflation is also fairly straightforward: The central bank can
stabilize inflation by raising and lowering interest rates to lean against inflationary disturbances.
Once we take account of the role of expectations, the stabilizing effects of monetary policy become
even greater: If economic decision makers come to realize that the Fed is doing more to stabilize
inflation, then shocks that push up inflation will lead to smaller increases in inflation expectations
than in the past. Because current inflation is affected by inflation expectations, the smaller increase
in expected inflation will lead to a smaller increase in actual inflation as well. And because many
shocks that may lead to inflation, such as unexpected surges in spending, also cause movements in
output and employment in the same direction, the maintenance of price stability promotes the
stability of the real economy.
This experience of low and stable inflation, coupled with the Fed’s clear statements of commitment
to maintaining this performance, has no doubt contributed to the stability of long-run inflation
expectations in the past decade or so. This stability has been remarkable. By one measure--from the
Philadelphia Fed’s Survey of Professional Forecasters--long-run inflation expectations have barely

budged since 1998. Other measures have varied a bit more, but overall, the movements in the
expectational indicators have been quite small.
Better monetary policy may also help explain the apparent decline in the sensitivity of inflation to
resource utilization. We might interpret the reduced statistical correlation between unemployment
and inflation as evidence of a decline in the direct effect of resource utilization on inflation. But
given that the conduct of monetary policy was changing at the same time, it may be premature to
draw such a conclusion. Consider the following thought experiment. Suppose that the Federal
Reserve managed to stabilize inflation perfectly. That outcome would eliminate any empirical
correlation between inflation and unemployment even if there really was an underlying relationship
between inflation and resource utilization operating through the influence of the latter on, say,
marginal labor costs.5 As this example illustrates, the correlation between unemployment and
inflation may have no bearing on whether these variables are truly linked structurally.
I hasten to add that I am not advocating that the Fed stabilize inflation perfectly--this is simply an
illustrative example. So let’s consider another alternative: Suppose that the Fed is willing to accept
some temporary deviation of inflation from its desirable level to moderate an accompanying
weakness in real activity, as might occur in the face of an adverse productivity shock. In this
instance, the most likely correlation between inflation and unemployment would be positive--that is,
under these conditions the relationship between inflation and unemployment would be the exact
opposite of the predictions of the old-fashioned Phillips curve. And again, this result could arise
even though the structure of the economy was such that an increase in resource utilization would
tend to put upward pressure on production costs and thus prices.
From this perspective, the declining correlation of resource utilization with inflation may be an
indication of the success of monetary policy in pursuing its dual mandate of price stability and
maximum sustainable growth: Because the Fed is trying to stabilize both inflation and real activity,
then, when faced by shocks that push these variables in the same direction, the Fed will want to try
to offset both adverse developments to the extent that it can. Thus, I see the reduced correlation
between inflation and unemployment as an indication of the success of monetary policy in this
dimension.
Further evidence that better monetary policy and accompanying expectational effects have promoted
a more stable economy is provided by the rather muted inflationary effects of the recent sharp
increases in crude oil prices. In the 1970s, inflation moved up sharply with increases in crude oil
prices. Moreover, not only did overall inflation move up, but core inflation, wages increases, and
inflation expectations moved up as well. In response to the resulting high inflation, the Fed was
obliged to raise interest rates, and the economy weakened. The contrast with recent performance is
quite stark. True, overall inflation moved up with energy prices, and some of the pickup in core
inflation last year probably reflected the transitory effects of the pass-through of increased energy
costs. However, that pass-through was a mere ripple compared with the behavior of the 1970s.
Similarly, when gasoline prices surge, surveys of household inflation expectations still move up, but
not for long. By contrast, in the 1970s, survey expectations moved up sharply and remained elevated
in the wake of the two oil shocks. Indicators of long-term inflation expectations did not exist in the
1970s, but in the current period, the stability of these expectations has been remarkable. As I shall
discuss, other explanations for these changes exist, but in my view, the effects of monetary policy
are the most plausible.
What can the international experience tell us about the likely sources of the changes in inflation
dynamics? First, we need to acknowledge that many of the changes we have seen in U.S. inflation
dynamics have also occurred in other countries. That fact suggests that at least some of the
explanations of the change in inflation dynamics should be common across countries rather than
country-specific. If monetary policy is central to these changes, it must be the case that many
countries have made similar changes to monetary policy.
As I noted in a speech last fall, one possible reason for such common changes in monetary policy
may have been greater currency competition (Kroszner, 2006). In broad terms, the idea is that

increased globalization, deregulation, and innovation raised the returns to low inflation--and
increased the penalties for high inflation--relative to results obtained twenty or thirty years ago. For
example, deregulation has led to an opening of capital markets, and hence financial globalization,
which has in turn boosted innovation and helped to increase global competition by shrinking
barriers of time and distance. Accordingly, trade and financial linkages between countries have
tightened tremendously in recent years.
Meanwhile, substantial financial innovations--including advances in electronic payment systems and
trading systems as well as more widespread credit card networks and increased use of mutual funds-have facilitated the movement of wealth around the globe. As a result, deregulation, globalization,
and innovation have made it easier for citizens to move their wealth out of nominal assets in their
local currency and thereby avoid any inflation tax should their government show signs that it might
resort to inflationary tactics to finance spending.6 At the same time, the public’s understanding of
the costs of inflation has increased, in part because of experiences of high inflation in many
countries in the 1980s. Almost everywhere, public opinion eventually turned against allowing
inflation to continue. This public pressure has reinforced the trend against inflationary policies.
Increased competition among currencies, driven by the confluence of factors that I just described,
has limited the ability of governments and central banks to pursue high-inflation policies. Moreover,
currency competition has raised the costs of poor policy and thus increased the incentives of the
monetary authorities to maintain low inflation.
Many of these arguments will apply with greater force in developing economies, where the costs of
poor policies have been demonstrated quite clearly. Nonetheless, I think that currency competition
has played at least some role in disciplining policy in the United States and other developed
countries.
Other Explanations for the Change in Inflation Dynamics
Of course, monetary policy may not be the whole story, and we need to resist embracing any single
explanation too wholeheartedly. There may be other reasons for the changes in inflation dynamics.
For example, the reduced sensitivity of core inflation to oil and natural gas prices likely also reflects
both the increased energy efficiency of the economy and the fact that shocks to the prices of these
goods since the mid-1980s have, at least until the latest episode, been viewed as mostly temporary.
In contrast, the rise in oil prices during the 1970s was probably seen at the time as largely reflecting
a permanent shift in global demand/supply balances.
Another factor that might help to account for some of the changes in inflation dynamics is
globalization. Because national markets have become more open to international trade, domestic
firms and workers face more competition and have less market power than in the past. This
development could help to account for any reduced sensitivity of U.S. inflation to domestic resource
utilization. In fact, one recent study even purports to show that foreign output gaps are more
important in explaining domestic inflation in industrialized countries than domestic factors (Borio
and Filardo, 2006). However, this result has been challenged by the Federal Reserve staffers, who
find that estimates to this effect are fragile.7 That said, this is an issue that merits close monitoring
as globalization continues.
Other factors may also be at work, such as the deregulation of the 1980s and the faster productivity
growth we have seen over the past decade. But I think that even after we have given these factors
their appropriate due, the evidence still suggests that better monetary policy explains much (albeit
not all) of the changes in inflation dynamics that have occurred. In fact, it is interesting to speculate
on the degree to which better monetary policy might account for some of the structural factors I
have listed. Consider faster productivity growth. High and variable inflation likely creates a
distraction for firms--managers must pay attention to the damage that inflation can do to their
balance sheets. They thus divert their attention from improving products and services to financial
management. Such distraction likely hurts the productivity of firms. Although I don’t think low
inflation is the only factor behind the rebound in productivity growth in the United States--after all,
other countries did not see such an acceleration in output per hour as inflation came down--I think it

has played a role.
Policy Implications
A review of the possible causes of the changes in inflation dynamics naturally leads to the question
of their implications for the conduct of monetary policy. In today’s economy, it is very difficult to
know whether any given change in output or employment will have inflationary consequences. One
lesson that is fair to draw, however, is that resource utilization generally does not tell us much about
the future course of inflation over the next year or two. Rather, the near-term inflation outlook is
more likely to be dominated by cost factors, such as productivity growth and the price of raw
materials, than by the tightness of labor and product markets. Furthermore, the weak relationship
between inflation and the unemployment rate means that it is probably more difficult than ever to
gauge the economy’s productive potential--and hence estimate so-called output gaps--especially in
real time. In light of these uncertainties, prudent policymakers should take an eclectic approach and
base their policy decisions on both a wide variety of indicators and views about how the economy
may work and avoid a narrow focus on economic slack.
My earlier comments also underscored the central importance of expectations to the successful
conduct of monetary policy. In particular, the Federal Reserve and many other central banks appear
to have succeeded in anchoring long-run inflation expectations--an achievement that has contributed
to macroeconomic stability and eased the task of monetary policy. However, bad luck or other
factors could cause expectations to begin to drift again. If so, the Federal Reserve will need to
respond appropriately. A problem of this sort is probably fixed most easily if it is detected early, and
thus policymakers should closely monitor the available indicators of expectations to head off any
trouble as soon as possible.
The final lesson I draw is a cautionary note: The stability of inflation could lead to complacency. As
long as inflation expectations are well anchored, actual inflation will have a natural tendency to
revert to the anchor of long-run inflation expectations. Under such circumstances, policymakers may
be tempted to relax their resolve in responding to potentially inflationary developments. Such
relaxation could be costly, however. Inflation expectations have become well-anchored because the
public has become confident that the Federal Reserve will do the right thing. But this belief will
persist only as long as we on the Federal Open Market Committee continue to ratify the public’s
expectations that inflation will remain low and stable. Thus, complacency would be a threat to the
credibility that the Federal Reserve has worked so hard to acquire, and its loss would likely mean
the reversal of many of the favorable inflation developments seen over the past two decades.
One message that I hope has been clear is that there is much we don’t know about the inflation
process. Policymakers would of course like to be 100 percent confident that they have the right way
of looking at the world. But I think we always need to be open to the possibility that other forces
may be at work or that other interpretations better explain what we’ve observed. We need to
approach our task with a certain degree of humility and an open mind.
Still, I think we can be fairly certain that low and stable inflation has been brought about by
guarding against looming inflation risks, and continuing in this vein seems sensible to me. Above
all, we must continue to conduct policy in such a way as to keep inflation low and stable--an
approach that also promotes full employment and maximum sustainable real growth of the
economy.

References
Atkeson, Andrew, and Lee H. Ohanian (2001). “Are Phillips Curves Useful for Forecasting
Inflation?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, vol. 25 (Winter), pp. 2-11.
Bernanke, Ben S. (2007). “Globalization and Monetary Policy,” speech delivered at the Fourth
Economic Summit, Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, March 2.

Bils, Mark, and Peter J. Klenow (2004). “Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices,”
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 112 (October), pp. 947-85.
Borio, Claudio, and Andrew Filardo (2006). “Globalization and Inflation: New Cross-Country
Evidence on the Global Determinants of Domestic Inflation,” unpublished paper, Bank for
International Settlements, March.
Cecchetti, Stephen G., Peter Hooper, Bruce C. Kasman, Kermit L. Schoenholtz, and Mark W.
Watson (2007). “Understanding the Evolving Inflation Process,” paper prepared for the U.S.
Monetary Policy Forum 2007 (February),
http://research.chicagogsb.edu/gfm/events/conferences/index.aspx.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans (2005). “Nominal Rigidities and
the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 113
(February), pp. 1-45.
Hooker, Mark A. (1996). “What Happened to the Oil Price-Macroeconomy Relationship?” Journal
of Monetary Economics, vol. 38, pp. 195-213.
Ihrig, Jane E., Steven B. Kamin, Deborah Lindner, and Jaime Marquez (forthcoming). “Some
Simple Tests of the Globalization and Inflation Hypothesis,” International Finance Discussion
Papers. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Ihrig, Jane E., Mario Marazzi, and Alexander D. Rothenberg (2006). “Exchange-Rate Pass-Through
in the G-7 Countries,” International Finance Discussion Papers 851. Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January.
Kroszner, Randall S. (2006). “The Conquest of Worldwide Inflation: Currency Competition and Its
Implications for Interest Rates and the Yield Curve,” speech delivered at the Cato Institute
Monetary Policy Conference, Nov. 16,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kroszner20061116a.htm.
Roberts, John M. (2006). “Monetary Policy and Inflation Dynamics,” International Journal of
Central Banking, vol. 2 (September), pp. 193-230.
Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer (2002). “The Evolution of Economic Understanding and
Postwar Stabilization Policy,” (439 KB PDF) in Rethinking Stabilization Policy, symposium
sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, August 29-31. Kansas City: the Reserve
Bank, pp. 11-78.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson (2007). "Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to
Forecast?" Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, supplement to vol. 39 (February), pp. 3-33.
Thomas, Charles P., and Jaime Marquez (2006). “Measurement Matters for Modeling U.S. Import
Prices,” International Finance Discussion Papers 883. Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, December.
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and U.S.
Secret Service (2006). The Use and Counterfeiting of United States Currency Abroad, Part 3.
Washington: Department of the Treasury, September,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/other/20061025a.htm.
Woodford, Michael (2003). Interest and Prices. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Footnotes

1. The academic literature refers to this new generation of macroeconomic models as dynamic
stochastic general equilibrium models. Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005) is one of the most
prominent examples of this new approach. Return to text
2. Atkeson and Ohanian (2001) argue that the unemployment rate no longer has any ability to
forecast inflation, while Roberts (2006) argues that the correlation has fallen but is still nonzero.
Return to text
3. One area in which the pattern of smaller correlations with inflation does not hold is import prices.
After adjusting for the rising share of imports in domestic price increases, we see little indication of
a reduction in the effect of import prices on U.S. inflation. We have some evidence, however, of a
reduced effect of exchange rates on import prices (Ihrig, Marazzi, and Rothenberg, 2006), although
this result may be sensitive to specification (Thomas and Marquez, 2006). Return to text
4. One key element of the inflation process that I have not yet mentioned is labor costs. Recent
developments in labor markets make it difficult to assess changes in the role of labor costs in the
inflation process. For example, since the mid-1990s, incentive-based employee stock options have
become an important form of compensation. This development has created measurement
difficulties: The government’s principle measure of labor compensation accounts for such options at
the time they are exercised (thereby conflating them with capital gains), rather than recording them
at their expected value at the time of issuance. As a result, the published compensation data provide
a distorted picture of labor costs. Return to text
5. Woodford (2003) includes results of this sort. Return to text
6. For emerging-market countries that had experienced high inflation, another aspect of
globalization fostering currency competition is the large amount of physical dollars now present in
these countries, which allows citizens to conduct transactions and store liquid wealth without
holding the local currency. Over one recent period, the fraction of U.S. currency estimated to be
held in foreign countries rose dramatically, from less than one-fifth in 1980 to as much as two-thirds
in the late 1990s, and today the total nominal amount is in the neighborhood of $400 billion, or
somewhat more than one-half (U.S. Department of the Treasury and others, 2006). Return to text
7. As noted in Bernanke (2007), Ihrig and others (forthcoming) find that these results are sensitive
to details of specification. Return to text

The Changing Dynamics of Inflation:
Prominent Features Before and After the Mid-1980s
Feature

1960s to mid-1980s

Mid-1980s to present

Inflation

High and variable

Low and stable

Inflation expectations

High and variable

Low and stable

Inflation persistence

Inflation shocks long-lived

Inflation shocks transitory

Substantial

Modest

Sensitivity of core inflation
to selected factors
Unemployment rate

Exchange rate movements
Energy price movements
Return to text
Return to top

Modest

Diminished

Substantial

Small