View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11:00 a.m. EST
December 2, 2021

Between the Hither and the Farther Shore:
Thoughts on Unfinished Business

Remarks by
Randal K. Quarles
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
The American Enterprise Institute
Washington, D.C.

December 2, 2021

When I joined the Board of Governors as Vice Chair for Supervision in the fall of
2017, the Federal Reserve was in the latter stages of a decade-long effort to build a new
financial regulatory framework, responding to the financial crisis of 2008. Yet, although
the mortar was not yet dry on that construction project—based on the blueprint created by
Congress, central banks, and supervisors around the world—there was already broad
recognition across the political spectrum that the framework could be improved upon,
based on the experience of how it had worked over the decade of its implementation.
That was the judgement of the authors of the post-crisis blueprint, former Senator Chris
Dodd and former Congressman Barney Frank.1 It was also the recommendation of one
of my predecessors at the Fed, Dan Tarullo—a principal architect of this framework—
who, in his final speech as a Fed governor, proposed several significant changes.2
I came to the Fed in order to take on that task of making the system better: more
simple, more efficient, more transparent. Congress also took up this effort in the broadly
bipartisan Economic Growth, Regulatory Relief, and Consumer Protection Act, and we
adjusted our regulatory framework to better align our requirements with the risk posed by
firms to the financial system. We maintained and, in fact, raised regulatory standards for
the most systemically important firms and simplified regulatory requirements for smaller
firms without diminishing the resilience of the system as a whole.
In the midst of our work to improve our framework, we faced the unique
experience of the COVID event, which tested that resilience. This real-life stress test

Chris Dodd and Barney Frank, interview by David Brancaccio, Marketplace, September 12, 2018,
https://features.marketplace.org/politicsofcrisis/#transcript.

1

Daniel K. Tarullo, “Departing Thoughts” (speech at the Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton, NJ, April 4,
2017), https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/tarullo20170404a.htm.
2

-2demanded emergency action with respect to our regulatory framework and more broadly,
including through the establishment of 13 emergency lending facilities under our role as
the lender of last resort to help stabilize the financial system.
Now, as my tenure as a member of the Board comes to a close, I would like to use
this final speech to discuss issues that my successor, and his or her colleagues, will
confront—areas of unfinished business.3 In the near term, there will need to be further
refinements to the bank supervisory and regulatory framework, based on the
accumulating evidence and experience of how these ideas, rules, and procedures have
worked in practice. In the longer term, the Fed will at some point need to grapple with
the implications of some of the novel emergency lending facilities we established during
the onset of the COVID event. I supported these facilities in light of the specific
challenges the country faced that grueling spring, but I believe it is possible to draw some
lessons from the experience and set out some principles for the Fed’s emergency lending
to prevent this precedent – or some vision of what it represents—from exceeding
reasonable bounds in the future. Finally, in my capacity as the outgoing Chairman of the
Financial Stability Board (FSB), I have some reflections on the upcoming agenda for the
FSB.
Further Refinements to the Supervisory and Regulatory Framework
As I have noted previously, the post-crisis regulatory framework is strong, as
evidenced by how well it fared against a severe real-life stress test—the COVID event.4

The views expressed here are my own and not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Board of
Governors or members of the Federal Reserve staff.

3

Randal K. Quarles, “Jet Flight, Mail Bags, and Banking Regulation” (speech at the Prudential Regulation
Conference, Salt Lake City, UT, June 3, 2021),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20210603a.htm.

4

-3Banks entered the COVID event with high levels of capital and liquidity, and served as a
source of strength to the economy in a time of need. 5 Some have argued that the time of
COVID was not a true test of the system, because of the unprecedented level of fiscal and
other support provided to the real economy during that time, from which the financial
sector indirectly benefited. Such an argument ignores, however, that the Federal Reserve
did not take such support for granted during the throes of the crisis itself, and as a result
we ran multiple stress tests throughout the COVID event, with three separate and distinct
scenarios, along with a “sensitivity analysis,” which itself included three additional
hypothetical recessions.6 Each of these stress tests assumed no additional fiscal or other
measures to support the economy, and demonstrated that, even without such support, the
banking industry would have fared very well. In my view the resilience of banks during
the COVID event, coupled with the results of our stress tests, demonstrate that the overall
level of capital in the banking system is more than ample.
In addition to the demonstrated hardiness of our regulatory framework, I believe
our supervisory framework is also stronger now than it was four years ago. In January
2020, I spoke about the importance of transparency, accountability, and fairness in bank

While the passage of time blurs all memories, it is worth recalling that during the early days of the
COVID event, we did not know how bad the inevitable recession would be, or how long it would last. As I
have said before, the fact that the Treasury market—the lifeblood of our financial system—malfunctioned
underscores the peril at the time. The banking system’s ability to function as a source of strength during
that period of tremendous uncertainty is certainly a testament to its resilience.
6
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Federal Reserve Board releases results of annual
bank stress tests,” news release, June 24, 2021,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20210624a.htm. See also “Federal Reserve
Board releases second round of bank stress test results,” news release, December 18, 2020,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20201218b.htm and “Federal Reserve
Board releases results of stress tests for 2020 and additional sensitivity analyses conducted in light of the
coronavirus event,” news release, June 25, 2020,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20200625c.htm.
5

-4supervision. 7 Every agency of the federal government has a legal, constitutional, and, I
believe, moral responsibility to be accountable to the public we serve, and one of the
principal ways we do this is through transparency. The banking agencies (including the
Fed) have for decades not been transparent in the way that we have conducted
supervision—yet, especially since 2008, we had been accomplishing more and more of
our work through this opaque mechanism with limited accountability. In that light, I am
quite proud of the improvements we have made in increasing the transparency and public
accountability for our activities overseeing banks.
The Fed fostered the public conversation on transparency in supervision when we
organized a conference on supervision and actively participated in the discussion with
academics and other members of the public. An important part of monetary policy
transparency is the semiannual process where the Fed reports on its activities to Congress
and the Chair submits to questions from both houses of Congress. I am pleased to say
that there is now a similar twice-yearly process in which the Fed produces a public,
written report on supervision and regulation and then submits to questions from
lawmakers. Our Supervision and Regulation Report—instituted early in my term—
regularly provides the public with insights about our supervisory process, including
aggregate supervisory ratings trends and supervisory priorities for our different
portfolios—information that was previously hard to find, and sometimes not public at all.

Randal K. Quarles, “Spontaneity and Order: Transparency, Accountability, and Fairness in Bank
Supervision” (speech at the American Bar Association Banking Law Committee Meeting 2020,
Washington, DC, January 17, 2020),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20200117a.htm.
7

-5I believe one concrete and successful change to supervision was to our stress
testing process, where we have greatly increased transparency, and thus accountability.8
Transparency does not mean giving answers to tests in advance—an inapt analogy given
the structure of these tests—but is more akin to ensuring that students have been given
the textbook. It means balancing rigor and fairness, and ensuring that the Fed’s
intentions are understood well enough to advance our goal—and our goal is not to
develop the most recondite test, but rather for banks to improve their resilience to
extraordinary stress in the financial system. The evidence that we succeeded is how well
banks weathered the extraordinary stress that arrived in the spring of 2020, consistent
with the results of our stress tests.
Transparency, accountability, and the public legitimacy it confers have
empowered the Fed to meet the great challenges that our economy and financial system
have faced in recent years. If the Federal Reserve is to continue to play that vital role,
then it must also continue to extend transparency to all of its important responsibilities.
As I look ahead to the future of regulation and supervision at the Federal Reserve, I
believe that the Fed will be more effective in overseeing banks, and more effective in
promoting the stability of the financial system, if it maintains its commitment to be open
and transparent in how it conducts its work.
In the same spirit, while our regulatory and supervisory framework is strong, there
are further refinements that could be made to improve the framework. A number of them
were on my agenda when the COVID event shifted the Fed’s focus to deal with the

See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Federal Reserve Board finalizes set of changes
that will increase the transparency of its stress testing program for nation’s largest and most complex
banks,” news release, February 5, 2019,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20190205a.htm.

8

-6emergency. I am proud of what we accomplished in my time here, but there is certainly
more to be done.
Leverage Ratio Fundamentalism
One of the principal matters that the Fed will have to take up in the very near term
is the calibration of our leverage capital standards. Our capital framework includes two
types of requirements: risk-based and leverage capital requirements. Risk-based
requirements are risk-sensitive and change depending on the riskiness of an asset.
Leverage capital requirements set a minimum floor for required capital by disregarding
risk-sensitivity measures. Our capital framework includes two leverage requirements,
with increasingly strict requirements for the largest institutions.9
While a leverage ratio is an important backstop, it can result in perverse
incentives if it becomes the primary constraint on a bank’s investment decisions.
Because a leverage ratio is not sensitive to risk, a firm that is “bound” by such a ratio has
an incentive to avoid adding safe assets to its portfolio. During times of stress in the
financial system, when it is most important for banks to be able to continue serving
businesses and households, or intermediating transactions, a binding leverage
constraint—or even one that threatens to become binding—may discourage banks from
engaging in safe activities, such as those involving U.S. Treasury securities.10
The first is a 4 percent ratio that applies to all banking organizations and is based on the ratio of tier 1
capital to average total consolidated assets. In addition, the largest banking organizations are subject to a 3
percent supplementary leverage ratio requirement, based on a ratio of tier 1 capital to on-balance-sheet
assets and certain off-balance-sheet assets. This supplementary requirement is stricter for U.S. global
systemically important banks (U.S. G-SIBs). U.S. G-SIBs must maintain a supplementary leverage ratio of
3 percent plus an additional buffer of 2 percent to avoid limitations on capital distributions. Their
depository institution subsidiaries must maintain a 6 percent supplementary leverage ratio to be deemed
“well capitalized” under the prompt corrective action framework of each federal banking agency.
9

As I mentioned previously, one of the primary strains in the financial markets during the onset of the
COVID event was in the Treasury market, where a wide range of investors sought to sell Treasuries to raise

10

-7That is not to say that a leverage requirement should never be the constraining
requirement for a firm. In times of stress, a leverage ratio can serve as a transparent
measure of capital when our risk weights may be called into question. In addition, it
guards against behavior by a supervised institution to game those risk weights. Finally, a
leverage ratio leans against the inherent tendency of bank leverage to increase in an
economic boom and fall during a recession.
What we are seeing today, however, is that supervised firms are increasingly
being constrained by the supplementary leverage ratio not for any of these valid reasons,
but simply because of a rise in the level of safe assets in the U.S. financial system. The
supplementary leverage ratio was originally calibrated for a financial system with a far
lower level of central bank reserves and a much smaller Treasury market.11 The current
environment is, of course, much different. Treasury issuance is at an all-time high and
the banking system is awash with central bank reserves. To provide some context to the
degree of this trend, for the largest banks, the amount of reserves they hold is $1.35
trillion and the amount of Treasury securities is $1.38 trillion, each roughly double the
amount they held when our supplementary leverage ratio rule was finalized. Even at
these lower levels of safe assets, some on the Board worried that the SLR might be too
tightly calibrated—but they took comfort from the staff’s projection that reserves in the
system were likely to fall, creating more elbow room within the envelope created by the

cash. Those selling pressures appear to have overwhelmed dealers’ capacity or willingness to absorb and
intermediate Treasury securities. Randal K. Quarles, “What Happened? What Have We Learned From It?
Lessons from COVID-19 Stress on the Financial System,” (speech at the Institute of International Finance,
Washington, DC, October 15, 2020),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20201015a.htm.
See “Agencies adopt enhanced supplementary leverage ratio final rule and issue supplementary leverage
ratio notice of proposed rulemaking,” news release, April 8, 2014,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20140408a.htm.

11

-8SLR. Indeed, when we finalized our leverage requirements for the largest banks, staff
projected the amount of reserves in the system would decline to $25 billion by year end
2021. 12 The current total of approximately $4.16 trillion in reserves is about 165 times
that amount.
During the onset of the COVID event, regulators took emergency action to
exclude U.S. Treasury securities and deposits at Federal Reserve Banks from the
supplementary leverage ratio to provide banks with additional flexibility to act as
financial intermediaries in that period of financial stress. 13 That exclusion expired as
scheduled on March 31, 2021. I supported that expiration, with the commitment that the
Fed develop a longer-term solution to the perverse implications of the current calibration
of the SLR.
With respect to the enhanced supplementary leverage ratio (eSLR) that applies to
U.S. global systemically important banks (G-SIBs), the best way to address this problem
is the approach endorsed by the Basel Committee: recalibrating the fixed 2-percent eSLR
buffer requirement to equal 50 percent of the applicable G-SIB capital surcharge, with
corresponding recalibration at the bank level.14 This is an approach previously proposed

Federal Reserve Board, Report to the FOMC on Economic Conditions and Monetary Policy, Book B at
49, fn.5 (March 13, 2014),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/FOMC20140319tealbookb20140313.pdf.
13
See “Regulators temporarily change the supplementary leverage ratio to increase banking organizations’
ability to support credit to households and businesses in light of the coronavirus response,” news release,
May 15, 2020, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20200515a.htm. See also
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Federal Reserve Board announces temporary change
to its supplementary leverage ratio rule to ease strains in the Treasury market resulting from the
coronavirus and increase banking organizations’ ability to provide credit to households and businesses,”
news release, April 1, 2020,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20200401a.htm.
12

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Leverage ratio requirements for global systemically
important banks (Basel: Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, January 2022),
https://www.bis.org/basel_framework/chapter/LEV/40.htm?inforce=20220101&published=20191215&exp
ort=pdf.
14

-9by the Board and the OCC. 15 This is preferable to other options, such as excluding
central bank reserves or U.S. Treasury securities, or both, from the ratio’s denominator.
Excluding only central bank reserves would exacerbate a structural preference for
reserves over Treasuries in bank portfolios, which could have perverse consequences for
the operation of the Treasury market (as we saw in September of 2019). Trying to reduce
this preference by excluding both reserves and Treasuries could result in a significant
lowering of capital levels and exacerbate the incentive for the banking system to prefer
funding the government to funding private enterprise. If we were to attempt to offset the
lowering of capital levels by increasing the leverage capital requirement on non-excluded
assets, this disincentive to fund private enterprise would only grow stronger. But
whatever the form of the adjustment, this issue needs to be addressed to ensure that our
capital framework does not lead to increased risk taking and reduced safe-asset
intermediation. As it stands, we are driving deposits out of the highly regulated banking
system and requiring that cash be held in other, less stable parts of the financial sector,
such as money market funds. If we enter another crisis with this issue unaddressed, the
leverage ratio fundamentalists will have much to answer for.
Basel III Reforms
International cooperation regarding our prudential requirements is critical to
promote global resilience in the banking sector, and I have been strongly committed since
my arrival at the Board to implementing the final phase of the Basel III capital reforms
here in the United States. I had hoped that the US would have led the world in setting out

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Rule proposed to tailor ‘enhanced supplementary
leverage ratio’ requirements,” news release, April 11, 2018,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20180411a.htm.

15

- 10 a concrete proposal to implement the Basel III endgame by the end of last year, but the
intervention of COVID set back that timetable, and although we are working hard with
the other banking agencies to iron out the last issues, our proposal will have to come after
my departure. A major issue that we are grappling with is how to implement these
reforms, which reduce the role of bank internal models on bank capital requirements,
while maintaining the overall level of aggregate capital requirements. As I noted earlier,
the experience of the COVID event has made clear that capital requirements in the United
States are ample—yet, other things being equal, implementing the remaining elements of
Basel III could result in a material increase in capital levels, perhaps up to 20 percent for
our largest holding companies. Endlessly increasing capital levels is not costless. In the
real world, as opposed to the world from which certain pundits and kibitzers make their
occasional visits to our planet, excessively high capital levels constrain the ability of the
banking system to provide credit to the real economy, and we pay the cost in jobs and
living standards. What policymakers will need to do as they implement the Basel III
reforms is determine whether adjustments to other parts of the capital framework are
necessary to ensure that we do not unduly increase the level of required capital in the
system.
The most logical place to make such an adjustment would be the G-SIB
surcharge. In the US, we have calibrated the G-SIB surcharge at twice the internationally
agreed level, and we did so expressly noting that we would revisit the surcharge
calibration periodically to reflect current conditions. We have not followed through on
our commitment to revisit the surcharge calibration, and once these last elements of the
Basel framework are implemented, there will be little justification for a super-calibrated

- 11 G-SIB surcharge. But many people have an emotional attachment to the G-SIB
surcharge, and if that emotion should overwhelm the logic of the case, there are other less
talismanic candidates for re-calibration in the existing capital framework that could
achieve the same purpose of keeping aggregate capital roughly constant while completing
Basel III.
Volatility in our Stress Tests
Our stress testing framework is a cornerstone of our prudential framework, and I
am proud of how well it performed during the COVID event, helping to ease stress in the
financial system by demonstrating the capital adequacy of banks. The stress testing
framework is used to set capital requirements for large firms, and the volatility of these
requirements from year to year indicates that we still do not have those requirements
quite right. As I have said previously, excessive volatility in a firm’s capital
requirements limits the firm’s ability to manage its capital effectively. 16 While some
measure of volatility is expected and desirable in a dynamic stress test, we must guard
against excess volatility when it has no particular relationship to changing risks at firms.
It is difficult to justify large year-over-year swings in capital requirements for individual
banking firms that are simply artifacts of the stress testing process rather than reflecting a
genuine change in a firm’s business.
I have wrestled for some time with the question of how best to address excessive
volatility. In the end, I think the simplest and most effective approach would be to

Randal K. Quarles, “A New Chapter in Stress Testing,” (speech at the Brookings Institution,
Washington, DC, November 9, 2018),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20181109a.htm. See also Randal K. Quarles,
“Stress Testing: A Decade of Continuity and Change,” (speech at the Brookings Institution, Washington,
DC, July 9, 2019), https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20190709a.htm.
16

- 12 average the results of the current year’s stress test with the corresponding stress test
results from the previous two years. This would not affect the overall stringency of the
tests but would mean that firms that hold the risk profile of their balance sheets relatively
constant would not see a large spike or plummet in their required capital from year-toyear based on changes in the Fed’s scenario choices.
Cross-Border Resolution and Market Fragmentation
In May 2018, I spoke about the vital importance of cross-border banking to global
financial stability and prosperity.17 The Fed’s work internationally on pre-positioning,
ring-fencing, and market fragmentation is still vital, and we should continue efforts to
find the right balance between flexibility for the parent bank and certainty for host
country authorities. Striking that balance properly is essential in order to encourage the
international cooperation that is so critical during times of global financial stress.
As I noted previously, while a home regulator will by nature prefer flexibility in
resolution, the host regulator will prefer certainty that local resources will be available in
stressful conditions. The host regulator, however, must recognize that flexibility in a
single point of entry resolution may further the success of the resolution of the entire
group, which will ultimately benefit the host regulator. Domestically, the United States
needs to do its part in its role as a host regulator by making sure that our U.S. prepositioning requirements for foreign banks with significant U.S. operations are
appropriately calibrated. U.S. intermediate holding companies of foreign-owned G-SIBs
are required to issue a minimum amount of loss-absorbing instruments to their foreign

Randal K. Quarles, “Trust Everyone—But Brand Your Cattle: Finding the Right Balance in CrossBorder Resolution” (speech at Harvard Law School, Cambridge, MA, May 16, 2018),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20180516a.htm.
17

- 13 parents. These requirements with respect to what is known as internal total loss
absorbing capacity include a separate minimum unsecured long-term debt requirement.
Our internal total loss-absorbing requirements for these firms are currently at the
top end of the scale set forth by the FSB and willingness by the United States to consider
adjusting that calibration to a lower level within the FSB-agreed range may prompt other
jurisdictions to do the same. Such a global recalibration, which would do nothing to
diminish the loss absorbency requirements that apply at a consolidated group level, could
better the prospects of successful resolution both for foreign G-SIBs operating in the
United States and for U.S. G-SIBs operating abroad in a future period of financial stress.
We also should consider further simplification of our regulatory framework by
streamlining our currently separate and somewhat redundant total loss-absorbing capacity
and long-term debt requirements. It is important that we do not create conditions that
will make any resolution more difficult in the future.
Supervision
I have already noted that transparency and accountability—and the legitimacy
they confer—have helped the Fed to meet the great challenges of recent years. As I look
ahead to the future of supervision at the Federal Reserve, I believe that if the Fed
maintains its commitment to openness and transparency in how it conducts supervision, it
will be more effective in overseeing banks and promoting the stability of the financial
system. Being open and transparent does not mean relaxing supervisory standards.
Greater transparency makes supervision more effective by ensuring that our expectations
are well understood. And by more clearly explaining and justifying those expectations,

- 14 we enhance the legitimacy of our standards and build respect for the rules, which is
critical to promoting and producing compliance in any legal regime.
We need to do more here, and while we have made many of the improvements to
transparency I discussed in my January 2020 speech, there is still unfinished work.18 The
greatest focus should be on improving our supervisory communications process. We can
do so in a few ways. First, we should restore the “supervisory observation” category for
less urgent items of concern, which could increase the quality of feedback provided to a
firm as it would allow an examiner to give notice about a supervisory concern even if that
concern has not risen to the level of a matter requiring attention, or MRA. We should be
vigilant that future MRAs are limited to violations of law, violations of regulation, and
material safety and soundness issues to improve the fairness of our supervisory process
given the weight MRAs carry with respect to a bank’s supervisory rating. We have
committed to this practice, but in the absence of a supervisory observations category it
remains too common that we issue MRAs for supervisory concerns that do not truly rise

Since January 2020, the Federal Reserve has taken a number of measures to improve its supervisory
framework. The Federal Reserve defined the financial institutions subject to the LISCC framework. See
SR 20-30: Financial Institutions Subject to the LISCC Supervisory Program at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/supervisionreg/srletters/sr2030.htm. The Federal Reserve also adopted a
final rule, codifying an interagency statement, which affirmed the principle that supervisory guidance does
not have the force and effect of law or regulation. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
“Federal Reserve Board adopts final rule outlining and confirming the use of supervisory guidance for
regulated institutions,” news release, March 31, 2021,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20210331a.htm. In addition, we have
released, in searchable form, scores of historical private legal interpretations of our significant rules. See
https://www.federalreserve.gov/supervisionreg/legalinterpretations/legalinterpretations.htm. The Federal
Reserve also finalized a rule that clarified revisions to the definition of confidential supervisory information
(CSI), which allows banks to share CSI with a broader range of parties and thereby better resolve
supervisory concerns. See “Federal Reserve Board finalizes a rule that implements technical clarifying
updates to Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) procedures and changes to rules for the disclosure of CSI,”
news release, July 24, 2020,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20200724a.htm. Finally, we adjusted the
scope of our capital planning guidance, SR Letters 15-18 and 15-19, to align with our tailoring framework.
18

- 15 to that level. We need a framework that allows us to communicate all our concerns,
while recognizing that “when everything’s urgent, nothing is.”
Finally, we should implement a routine practice of independent review of
important supervisory communications and guidance documents. We want to make sure
our supervisory communications focus on violations of law and material safety and
soundness issues. Together, these approaches will greatly improve our supervisory
communication and enhance our supervisory process.
Digital Assets
Finally, before turning to some longer-term issues, I would like to discuss digital
assets, which the banking agencies have all said will be an area of significant focus in the
coming year. 19 The Federal Reserve, and our fellow regulators, should welcome
responsible innovation, and we should create a regulatory environment that not only
allows for such innovation, but encourages it.
Digital assets, such as stablecoins, are just such an area of welcome innovation. It
is clear that there is a strong demand for these assets among bank customers, and wellregulated banks should be allowed to engage in activities regarding these assets. We do
have some legitimate concerns that must be addressed by any provider of these assets:
the structure of the asset must be stable (no fractional reserve; no liquidity mismatch;
limited currency volatility), the consumer must be protected (clear legal claims on asset
pools), and criminal activity must be deterred (transparency to law enforcement). But
once these concerns are addressed—and many of the companies active in this area are

See “Interagency Joint Statement on Crypto-Asset Policy Sprint Initiative and Next Steps,” news release,
November 23, 2021, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/files/bcreg20211123a1.pdf.

19

- 16 eager and able to address them—we should let the ingenious and inventive private sector
move rapidly.
I am concerned, however, that regulators are contemplating steps that could
hamper these innovations unnecessarily. For example, the President’s Working Group on
Financial Markets recently issued its report on stablecoins and, while the report sensibly
discusses the risks associated with stablecoins, it contemplates approaches that I don’t
believe are warranted, such as limiting wallet providers’ affiliation with commercial
entities. 20 It is one thing to say that a stablecoin issuer itself must be a regulated bank—I
think that is probably overkill, as there are perfectly effective ways for nonbanks to meet
our legitimate regulatory concerns, but there is at least a clear relation between the
existing framework of bank regulation and the specific measures that stablecoin issuers
must address to operate safely. It is, however, quite another thing to contemplate that
wallet providers may need to be completely separated from commercial firms. It is not at
all clear what regulatory interest would be furthered by such a limitation, which is much
more restrictive than we require for nondigital assets.
While digital asset-related activities may be novel, regulators need not treat these
activities differently simply because of the nature of the technology. We must focus with
care on the unique risks posed by these activities and avoid unnecessarily impeding their
promise. For that reason, I am hopeful that regulators will show reasoned constraint in
the regulation of digital assets.

President’s Working Group on Financial Markets, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and the
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Report on Stablecoins (Washington: U.S. Treasury, November
2021), https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/StableCoinReport_Nov1_508.pdf.

20

- 17 Lessons Learned from the Emergency Lending Facilities
To this point, I have been addressing issues that the Fed will have to deal with in
the near term. Let me now turn to a longer-term challenge: the implications of our
emergency actions in the recent crisis. The COVID event caused an unprecedented—
indeed, unimagined—shutdown of economic activity in the United States and much of
the world. The Federal Reserve responded to the COVID event with the same vigor it
showed when the Great Financial Crisis threatened a worldwide Depression, employing
our ample emergency power under Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act to stabilize
the economy and financial system. In this case, we reactivated forms of the lending
facilities employed during the Great Financial Crisis, and then went farther to create new
lending facilities to support households, businesses, and state and local government
entities that, it was feared, would be frozen out of credit markets. In all, the Federal
Reserve created 13 lending facilities with the statutorily required approval of the
Secretary of the Treasury. I supported these actions, and still do, as the right response
when faced with the specific challenges we faced in the spring of 2020.
But I did at the time, and still do, have concerns about the possible precedents that
have been created by the novel facilities that we created. It starts with a distinction
between liquidity facilities 21 designed to bolster market functioning by providing shortterm loans to financial firms when such credit is suddenly not available, and what I would

I view the liquidity facilities as the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), the Primary Dealer
Credit Facility (PDCF), the Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (MMLF), the Term AssetBacked Securities Loan Facility (TALF), and the Paycheck Protection Program Liquidity Facility (PPPLF).
But there is room for adjustment of this typology: certain features of both the TALF and PPPLF programs
might indicate that they should fall in the credit facility category.

21

- 18 call credit facilities 22, which support the extension of long-term credit to the real
economy—households, businesses, and governments.
The two different types of facilities have materially different characteristics. The
liquidity facilities are largely “wholesale”23; the term of the funding they offer is
generally quite short; operating them calls on expertise that Fed staff either have or that is
quite similar to existing expertise; the risk of loss is minimal, given the nature of the
facilities; and withdrawing from them is relatively straightforward, either selling the
assets or letting them mature, which happens quickly given the short term and penalty
rate of the funding.
The credit facilities, by contrast, are largely “retail” 24; the end-users of the credit
support are households, businesses, and governments that attract significant political
interest, meaning pressure for continued expansion of credit will be great; the credit
facilities involve longer-term lending; operating the credit facilities requires expertise that
the Fed does not have and that is not highly analogous to existing Fed expertise; the
potential for troubled loans (and thus potential loss) is material, which will also require
expertise and administrative attention that the Fed is ill suited to provide; the penalty rate
needed for 13(3) lending can reduce the effectiveness of the facilities (and encounter

I view the credit facilities as the Primary Market Corporate Credit Facility (PMCCF), the Secondary
Market Corporate Credit Facility (SMCCF), the Main Street Lending Program (Main Street), and the
Municipal Liquidity Facility (MLF). Again, some might argue that TALF and PPPLF also belong here.

22

By “wholesale,” I mean that the liquidity facilities are aimed at improving the operation of wholesale
financial markets, rather than providing longer term funds for households and businesses in the real
economy. They are thus generally quite removed from politically appealing groups of beneficiaries.

23

By “retail,” I mean that the credit facilities provide longer-term credit either directly to nonfinancial
actors, or to financial firms for the sole purpose of on-lending to defined classes of nonfinancial actors, all
in support of the real economy rather than the operation of financial markets.

24

- 19 significant political opposition), given the purpose of the credit support and the nature of
the beneficiaries; and withdrawing from the facilities will involve telling specific
beneficiaries that their funding will not be extended (another politically fraught event).
Equally important, from outside the technocratic halls of the Fed there will
emerge, from many directions, persistent political pressure to pursue, through the
ostensibly monetary mechanism of central bank emergency lending, fiscal policy
objectives that ought—as a matter of fundamental economics and fundamental
governance—to be decided upon by elected representatives operating within the
budgetary constraints of the appropriations process. As a prospective shortcut around
those constraints, extended provision of credit to broad sections of the economy through
the mechanism of 13(3) without either a required appropriation or effective limit could
easily prove an impossible lure for future Congresses to resist, under the guise of one
“emergency” or another: having established the precedent that the Fed can lend to
businesses and municipalities for the COVID event, there will inevitably be those whose
plans are grand and whose patience with democratic accountability low who will begin to
ask why the Fed can’t fund repairs of the country’s aging infrastructure, or finance the
building of a border wall, or purchase trillions of dollars of green energy bonds, or
underwrite the colonization of Mars. An entity that can do that without any need for
Congressional appropriations, would have the vastest political consequence and political
control of it would be a great prize. It would encourage dangerous fiscal irresponsibility,
and the attendant pressures would turn us from a technocratic, nonpolitical institution
with a crucial but focused mandate and great autonomy in the pursuit of that mandate,

- 20 into the most politically entangled organization in the country—and the damage to our
core monetary policy and financial regulatory mission would be great.
Fortunately, there were no major problems with the COVID credit facilities.
While political pressure related to the credit facilities waxed and waned, the economy
recovered quickly enough that the facilities could be wound down within several months
with relatively little opera. However, these good outcomes had more to do with good
luck than good structure. While the economy and financial system were under intense
stress for several months in spring of 2020, the reopening of the economy and rapid
recovery that began in May of that year was a major reason that material losses, political
pressures, and operational problems were avoided. To cite one example, the crisis in the
municipal bond market, which seemed possible that spring, never materialized.25
We cannot undo the precedent we have established (nor should we—if we face a
similar challenge in the future, the Fed should respond forcefully), but in breaching the
long unbreachable firewall of offering direct lending to non-financial businesses, both
large and small—as well as a wide range of state and municipal governments—we face a
fundamental problem: the extension of funds to these borrowers, and management of
these loans, inherently involve the allocation of credit, which is both a fiscal and a
political action that is being made primarily by an unelected body.

While it was feared that plunging tax revenue would cause widespread fiscal problems for state and local
governments that could freeze municipal bond markets, tax revenue did not fall significantly because
employment losses were concentrated in low wage jobs, incomes were supported by generous
unemployment compensation payments, the decline in consumption was concentrated in services which
have lower sales tax burdens, and property taxes continued to rise in the booming housing market. While
the creation of the MLF helped settle markets and obviate the need for the emergency facility, and aid to
states and localities from Congress was significant, it is hard to know how much intervention would have
been needed, and how this episode would have played out, if states and localities had faced big financial
problems.

25

- 21 For all these reasons, I believe we should establish a clear understanding that,
should the Fed ever again use its 13(3) authority to establish credit facilities similar to
those of the COVID event, Congress will without delay create a structure to transfer the
ongoing funding and governance of the credit facilities into a non-Fed vehicle that will
fund, manage, and eventually wind down the extraordinary credit support. 26
Section 13(3) creates a standing power of the Fed to act rapidly and forcefully to
address a crisis. 13(3) allows the nature of that response to be flexible depending on the
nature of the crisis. Financial market dysfunction can be addressed through 13(3)
liquidity facilities that fit comfortably within the Fed’s operations and expertise, and in
many cases might not require any use of Treasury equity or other Congressionally
appropriated funds.
But if the shock is one—like the COVID event—that requires real economy credit
support to address its root causes, the Fed can use 13(3) to provide the same rapid and
forceful response (with appropriate Treasury equity for credit protection), but we should
establish the expectation that this credit support will be moved into a separate, non-Fed
structure as quickly as Congress can manage. In the same way that the 13(3) facilities
developed in 2008 served as templates in 2020, greatly increasing the speed of our
response, the template outlined here that we create for the future here should ideally
become the default expectation of Congress, markets, and the public should the Fed ever
again be called upon to provide credit facilities under section 13(3).
There are many precedents for such an approach. During the Great Depression,
for example, Congress created the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) to provide
I should stress that these measures would be necessary only for credit facilities. The Fed’s liquidity
facilities can be created and managed by the Fed without the need for such measures.

26

- 22 emergency credit to the real economy, expressly steering clear of the problems that would
naturally have been associated with using the Federal Reserve for such a purpose. 27 The
RFC had a limited life, separately appropriated capitalization, and separate borrowing
authority in order to fund direct lending to borrowers. More recently, during the 1990s
financial and economic crisis in Sweden, Norway, and Finland, after initial stabilizing
responses from their central banks, these countries established new governmental
agencies outside their central banks to manage the broader, continuing support programs.
Measures such as these have a number of advantages:
1. A separate entity can be expressly stated to be an emergency vehicle with a
limited life. It can be legally required to extend credit for a short, specified period
and then be wound down.
2. Providing credit support through a separate vehicle establishes a clear division
between fiscal measures and monetary policy.
3. Lending through a separate organization allows more flexibility on the interest
rate and other terms of government-sponsored credit support. While we were
lucky in the COVID event, one could easily have imagined the economic crisis
deepening to the point where achieving the purposes of widespread credit support
would have called for lending at a market or even subsidized rate, rather than the
penalty rate required for central bank lending. Doing so is a decision that should
be made by Congress, rather than the Fed.
4. The separate incorporation and funding of a separate vehicle would give
transparency and clear boundaries to the degree of government financial support
being provided to the economy.
5. Placing the inherently political decisions around the allocation of credit in a
separately governed entity will keep the Fed from being fundamentally
transformed by efforts to politicize the credit-granting mechanism.
6. Finally, having a separate entity will facilitate hiring the necessary people with
the necessary expertise, which will likely be quite different from the expertise
usually found in either the Treasury or the Federal Reserve.

Parinitha Sastry, “The Political Origins of Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act,” FRBNY Economic
Policy Review (New York: Federal Reserve Board of New York, September 2018),
https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/research/epr/2018/epr_2018_political-origins_sastry.pdf.
27

- 23 a. In particular, the types of personnel and expertise required to work out
troubled loans made with government credit support are very different
from the personnel and expertise widely available in either the Fed or the
Treasury.
This would not be a U-turn from our decisive response to the COVID event, but
rather simply the logical next step. In addition to providing clarity for the public as to
what to expect in future crises, adopting this model going forward could reduce concerns
a future Fed might have that a forceful response could entangle it in difficult political
problems. This could help give a future Fed the freedom to determine what it believes is
truly the right technocratic response to a particular future shock. Adoption of such a
framework would also reduce the attraction of the Fed as a general purpose funder of
credit-intensive political projects—we would have established that the piper will not only
always have to be paid, but paid promptly. This framework also gives an appropriate role
to 13(3), consistent with the clear authority granted to us, but also consistent with what
we have learned about the entanglement of central banks with fiscal policy and politics in
the years since 13(3)'s enactment. We would not be ignoring the credit support authority
13(3) gives us, rather we would be anchoring it in its appropriate emergency context.
The Future of the Financial Stability Board
As we continue to grapple with a future framework for emergency lending, the
United States is not alone. Around the world, financial authorities are reflecting on the
lessons from the COVID event while exchanging experiences and views at the FSB,
which I have chaired for the past three years. My FSB term ended just yesterday, but
there remains much to be done at the FSB.

- 24 One of the most important tasks is addressing vulnerabilities related to non-bank
financial intermediation, or NBFI.
This has been a critical focus of my chairmanship and is reflected in the FSB’s
ambitious multiyear workplan to enhance NBFI resilience. One set of initiatives under
the workplan focuses on specific risk factors that appear to have propagated stress,
including liquidity strains during the COVID event. The FSB has made considerable
progress in the NBFI space in a short amount of time. As a first major deliverable under
the NBFI work program, the FSB recently published policy proposals to address
structural vulnerabilities in money market mutual funds (MMFs).
Although we’ve made good progress, we cannot lose momentum. It is critical
that jurisdictions make meaningful progress in MMF reforms, building on the FSB’s
policy proposals. FSB members have clearly noted the importance of this task by
committing to reviewing the progress made by members in two- and five-years’ time.
The FSB and international standard-setting bodies must also advance policy work on
specific risk areas, such as open-ended funds and margining practices, that appear to have
contributed to stress during the COVID event. We also need to develop a shared
understanding of how vulnerabilities in the NBFI sector may cause spillover effects or
impact broader market functioning in the future. To achieve this aim, the FSB will
continue to examine the structure and drivers of liquidity in government and corporate
bond markets during stress and develop a broad, systemic risk perspective on NBFI as
well as policies to address such risks.
As chair of the FSB, I have had the opportunity to work with brilliant and
dedicated colleagues around the world. Under pressure from the severe tests of the

- 25 COVID event, together we delivered—true to our mandate—through cooperation,
analytical rigor, and broad engagement. I depart the Financial Stability Board knowing it
is well-prepared to complete the tasks at hand and face the challenges of the future.
Conclusion
I am told that Dan Tarullo’s final speech as a Fed Governor was 26 pages long,
and this one is only 25—consistent with my relentless quest to improve the Fed’s
efficiency and simplicity. Yet even at this Mahabharatan length, I have only hit the
highlights of what my successor will need to address. Fortunately, he (or she) will
benefit from the same principal advantages I have had over the last four years: the
intellectual horsepower, analytical rigor, and disciplined expertise of the Federal
Reserve’s staff. These are powerful advantages indeed, even with so complex and
sustained an agenda. I wish her (or him) well.