View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on delivery
Expected 10:00 AM F.DT




Statement by

Preston Martin

Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Consumer Affairs and Coinage Subcommittee

of the

Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs

U.S. House of Representative»

JuljrlS, 1982

I appreciate the opportunity to testify today on a bill to reinstate
the Credit Control Act in a modified form.

As you know, under that Act, which

expired July 1, the President was empowered to authorize the Federal Reserve
to “regulate and control a n y !or all extensions of credit1' if he found such
action "necessary or appropriate to prevent or control inflation generated by
the extension of credit in an excessive volume".

The Act gave the Board broad

powers to regulate the terms under which credit is extended and the purposes
for which it can be granted, as well as to require reporting and record-keeping
of credit transactions, once the President has decided that these powers should
be exercised.

One of the proposed amendments would enlarge the circumstances

under which the President could invoke the Act to encompass recession and unem­
ployment as well as inflation.

Another proposed amendment would make explicit

the Board’s authority under the Act to limit credit granted for "nonproductive"
purposes and to ensure the availability of credit for other uses.
The Federal Reserve Board is sympathetic to the concerns about the
cost and availability of credit over recent years that apparently have prompted
proposals to retain credit control authority.

High interest rates have contri­

buted to the weakness of the economy and stresses on the financial condition of
entities operating within it, and have been a factor in the sharp rise in busi­
ness and personal bankruptcies over recent years.

However, we do not believe

that credit controls are an effective, efficient, or fair method to deal with
these problems or those of inflation when the more general instruments of mone­
tary and fiscal policy can be used.

Our experience with the administration of

controls for a brief period in 1980 amply demonstrated the difficulties
encountered in the application of credit controls.




-

2

-

Some have argued that direct government intervention in credit allo­
cation may be necessary under extraordinary circumstances, such as a national
emergency, and in the absence of standby authority problems might be encountered
in such circumstances if borrowers moved to obtain credit when enabling legisla­
tion was being considered.

The greater danger would be that distortions

in credit flows could occur on other occasions when circumstances seemed to
suggest controls might be activated, and the existence of credit control author­
ity might tend to encourage its use unnecessarily.

Accordingly, the Board feels

that the proposed legislation would do more harm than good.
The Effects of Credit Controls
The ability of credit controls applied in this country to achieve
their intended effects over any extended period is limited, and the costs to
borrowers, lenders, and society as a whole from attempts to use controls to
combat inflation or unemployment could become quite sizable.

These difficulties

stem in large measure from the availability to many U.S. borrowers of funds from
a number of different sources.

A large business, for example, may be able to

borrow from a bank, finance company or other financial intermediary, or it could
obtain funds directly in a variety of security markets ranging from very short­
term commercial paper through notes and bonds and including sales of equity.
These markets are mostly located in this country, but increasing numbers of cor­
porate borrowers are gaining access to a highly integrated worldwide dollar mar­
ket, over which it would be extremely difficult for U.S. authorities to exercise
effective control.
This sophisticated and decentralized financial system is a great
advantage to the U.S.

economy, since it gives savers a variety of instruments

to choose among and helps to channel these savings to investment uses in an effi­
cient manner.



However, the existence of these markets also means that control

-3-

of one particular type of credit, or of a narrow range of credit instruments,
is unlikely to be effective over an extended period.

Borrowers may have a

preference as to the terms on which they wish to fund a particular purchase,
but money is fungible-— that is, funds obtained from any source can be applied
for any purpose— and if the incentive and opportunities are present unregulated
credit will tend to be substituted for credit subject to controls.

As attempts

are made to maintain the effectiveness of controls in the face of continuing
substitutions by borrowers and lenders, regulations will tend to become increas­
ingly pervasive, complex, and burdensome.

Moreover, because controls are most

readily applied to domestic financial intermediaries, borrowers, such as house­
holds and small businesses, that depend on these institutions for credit may
tend to feel the major effects of controls even when this is contrary to the
intent of their designers.
The cost of credit controls, if maintained for any extended period,
would include most visibly the government bureaucracy and thè rule making and
enforcing machinery that would be needed.

Less obvious would be the costs

incurred by private businesses in increased reporting burden and the expendi­
ture of managerial ingenuity to conform with or, perhaps, get around the regu­
lations.

Least easy to ascertain would be the costs arising from distortions

in resource allocation and inefficiencies that inevitably result when regula­
tory mandate is substituted for market decisions.

Of course, the whole purpose

of controls is to change the allocation of credit and presumably of spending
from what would prevail in tha absence of interference.

There already exist a

number of governmental programs to influence the flow of funds to various sec­
tors— especially towards housing and agriculture.

However, the full effect of

these programs, for example on competing uses of credit, and the additional




-4-

costs of credit controls are difficult to determine.

Breaking into the complex

web of private decisions about lending and borrowing, spending and saving, may
involve considerable unintended indirect consequences from distorting the price
and interest rate signals given to market participants.
The 1980 Experience
In many respects, the problems and pitfalls of utilizing credit con­
trols were illustrated by our experience in the spring of 1980, when, as consis­
tent with the order of President Carter, the Board took a series of actions
designed to curb inflationary pressures by slowing the overall growth of cred­
it, while directing it to uses considered most beneficial to the economy.

The

components of the program, not all of which required the authority of the Cred­
it Control Act, included:

a voluntary Special Credit Restraint Program intended

to reduce the expansion of short-term credit, primarily by holding the growth
of bank loans below 9 percent for the year, with restraint to be applied mainly
to loans for speculative purposes or for effecting takeovers or stock repurchases,
rather than to loans to small businesses, farmers, and purchasers of homes and
autos; special deposit requirements on increases in certain types of consumer
loans; an increase in the reserve requirement on growth in managed liabilities
of member banks and extension of the marginal reserve requirement to nonmembers
to further discourage the expansion of bank credit; a special deposit requirement
on increases in money market fund assets, in the expectation that lower yields
on these intermediaries would slow the diversion of deposits from local insti­
tutions; and a surcharge on frequent borrowing from the Federal Reserve discount
window by large banks.
When the President authorized the imposition of credit controls in
March of 1^80, conditions in credit markets had been deteriorating in many



respects.

Interest rat*« were rising, with concern about impending federal

government deficits and a pickup in inflation driving bond yields to record
levels, and bank credit growth was running well above the range considered
appropriate by the Federal Open Market Committee.

It appeared that the public

had little confidence that the usual fiscal and monetary policy instruments
would be used to effect a lasting reduction in inflation.

Under these circum­

stances, it seemed appropriate to supplement the«e techniques temporarily with
the special measures of the credit restraint program; it was hoped that these
actions would speed the response of the economy to the more general policies
already in place.
The program did contribute to a sharp reduction in interest rates,
but this downward movement in rates accompanied a steep decline in economic
activity.

One reason for this was the great amount of uncertainty and confusion

that accompanied the onset of controls.

Borrowers reduced their use of all

types of credit, including those tha credit restraint program was not intended
to curtail, and with this reduction went a sharp drop in credit-financed pur­
chases.

Some lenders, fearful of violating Board guidelines, drew back from

the credit markets, cutting sharply their credit extensions; others used the
credit restraint program as the occasion for accelerating a tightening of loan
terms that had been in train for some time.

In response to incoming information

about the economy and credit markets, the Federal Reserve quickly took steps to
ease the credit restrictions.

With the credit restraints off, interest rates

lower, and underlying demands for goods and services still strong, the economy
rebounded rapidly in the third and fourth quarters of 1980, carrying interest
rates to even higher levels.

In the end the credit controls appeared to add to

the volatility in financial markets and the econotcy in 1980 and, in some ways,




-6-

by distorting underlying economic and financial conditions, made sound fiscal
and monetary policies more difficult to formulate.
In addition, the numerous practical problems encountered in imple­
menting the program tended to demonstrate the essentially arbitrary nature of
governmental direction of credit decisions and the burdens imposed by controls.
The general principles guiding the credit restraint program seemed reasonably
straightforward, but constant modification, interpretation, and clarification
were needed as these general principles were applied to the complex financial
relationships that characterize our economy.

In the few months they were in

effect, the consumer credit regulations, by themselves, required 31 pages of
answers to common questions in addition to innumerable responses to inquiries
specific to individual institutions, even though they were aimed at a quite
limited sector of the consumer credit market.

The voluntary credit restraint

program for banks and other lenders necessitated numerous judgments by the
Federal Reserve and the lenders as to whether individual loans for takeover,
purely financial, or speculative purposes were justified under the guidelines.
Lenders and borrowers rarely enter loan contracts that they do not feel will
produce some economic benefits, and we found that the longer the program was
in effect, the more numerous and difficult became the issues of this sort that
had to be confronted.

Problems also were encountered in verifying whether cred­

it had continued to be made available to borrowers, such as farmers and small
businesses, who were supposed to receive favored treatment under the regulations.
Recognizing that larger corporations might be unfairly advantaged by
access to a variety of credit markets, the Board required these corporations
to report directly to us so we could monitor their total use of credit.

There

was great difficulty in standardizing and interpreting these reports, however,




-7-

especially the information dealing with transactions with foreign subsidiaries.
Moreover, the regulations and accompanying reports placed a substantial burden
on corporations and lenders, who often were asked to develop and report data
in unfamiliar and difficult categories.

The Federal Reserve Banks and Board

also found that considerable resources had to be diverted from regular duties
to interpret and monitor compliance with the regulations, answer questions, and
analyze incoming reports.
Credit Controls to Combat Inflation or Recession
As in 1980, the usual reason for imposing credit controls has been to
combat inflation, or prevent its outbreak.

In the past this has primarily

occurred during war when resources were being diverted from the production of
consumer goods, and the exigencies of war finance were thought to constrain the
degree to which monetary and fiscal policies could be used to hold down overall
demand pressures.

In this context the terms or availability of credit to finance

consumer purchases were controlled in order to discourage consumer spending.
Such a policy might be successful in a national emergency when a public consensus
existed that would discourage finding ways to reduce the effect of the controls,
but even in these circumstances, avoiding an eventual upward movement in prices
requires policies that bring aggregate supply and demand into more lasting bal­
ance.

The use of credit controls— with the attendant costs, distortions, and

possibilities for evasion— is unlikely to produce a permanent reduction in
inflationary pressures, unless it is also accompanied by limitations on the
overall growth of money and credit.
In the proposed bill, credit controls may also be authorized by the
President to combat unemployment and recession.

The success of credit alloca­

tion for this purpose is likely to be even less than for holding down inflation.




-8-

Regulations to prevent or limit a proposed extension of credit or to raise its
cost would have a far better chance of being effective than would regulations
to induce credit extensions that do not appear beneficial to the lender or
borrower.

Lenders require a fair return on their investments; for financial

institutions this implies a reasonable margin over the cost of obtaining funds.
To encourage borrowing and spending as a method of boosting economic activity,
credit controls would have to result in greater volumes of credit at lower
interest rates.

It is difficult to see how this would ever work.

Controls also can be used in an attempt to effect a redistribution
of credit, perhaps to rechannel spending in directions considered more socially
desirable or to reduce unemployment in particular sectors.

They may be success­

ful in this, but only at the expense of increasing unemployment or reducing
spending in other sectors, and the effectiveness of controls even for this pur­
pose may be limited over time if constrained borrowers can substitute credit
from noncontrolled sources.
There has been wide discussion of credit availability differences
between productive and nonproductive (usually takeover credit) uses.

In that

connection I should note that borrowing to finance takeovers does not draw signif­
icantly on the Nation’s total volume of savings— our ultimate source of credit.
These transactions involve an exchange of financial assets, and, while the pur­
chaser of stock may borrow to obtain the necessary funds, those selling the stock
generally will recycle the proceeds back into financial markets through deposit
in a bank or other financial institution or purchase of another security.
Although the overall balance of credit supplies and demands will not
be greatly affected by such tram
distribution of credit and the s




>ns^ there may be some distortions in the
tóf rates in different markets.

In

-9-

addition, the tendency for banks to take on large obligations to individual
firms in very short periods in conjunction with takeover financing may have
implications in the context of the Federal Reserve’s supervisory responsibil­
ities,

For these reasons, we monitor the volume and terms of this activity

carefully.

When there are firm constraints on bank credit growth, loans for

one use would reduce funds from banks available for other purposes, with
potentially adverse consequences for those borrowers without access to other
credit sources.
The most recent example of our asking banks to limit takeover loans
was during the credit restraint period in the spring of 1980, when, as I noted
above, we asked the banks not only to curb lending for nonproductive purposes
but to maintain the flow of credit to homebuyers, small businesses and others
whose credit needs seemed important to satisfy.

The problems we encountered

then— for example, determining which takeovers were justified and monitoring
the use of foreign credit to finance mergers— highlighted the difficulties of
enforcing such restrictions in an equitable manner without impairing the effi­
cient funding in our financial markets of necessary and legitimate changes in
business ownership.

In this area, as in others, problems of anticipations also

complicate administering controls.
It seems to me that the problems facing borrowers today do not stem
from a lack of availability of funds from certain lenders that might be rem­
edied by redirecting credit flows, but rather from the generally high level of
interest rates.

Liquidity pressures and balance sheet imbalances of many years

standing are prevailing throughout our credit markets.

Of particular concern is

the elevated level of long-term rates, which has depressed our housing markets
and discouraged businesses from undertaking the capital investment and balance




-10-

sheet restructuring so urgently needed.

One factor keeping those rates so

high is investor fears of a reemergence of inflation at even higher levels as
the economy recovers— repeating the pattern of recent decades; another is the
prospect of the crowding out of private borrowers due to the financing of
massive and growing federal budget deficits in the midst of economic expansion.
Unless the Congress and Administration structure a federal budget that will
move toward balance instead of toward greater deficits at higher levels of
employment and output, the federal government will continue to use an outsized
share of our Nation’s savings.

Private borrowers, under these circumstances,

will continue to face high interest rates, and the credit sensitive sectors of
our economy will not regain their former vigor.

Stimulus to private activity

cannot be obtained by promulgating rules favoring one sector over another.
Instead we must work to increase the flow of credit to all private borrowers
and to assure that this credit will be available at reasonable rates by pursuing
monetary and fiscal policies that promise a lasting abatement of inflationary
pressures.