View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on Delivery

12:00 Noon, Tokyo Time
May 7, 1985

Innovation and Deregulation in Financial Markets in the United States

Presentation by
Preston Martin
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Federation of Bankers Associations of Japan
Tokyo, Japan
May 7, 1985

Presentation by
Preston Martin
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Federation of Bankers Associations of Japan
Tokyo, Japan
May 7, 1985

Over the past five years or so, substantial progress has been
made in deregulating the financial system in the United States.

Many

of you presently are dealing with the effects of similar developments
in your own country.

It therefore seems appropriate to discuss some of

the lessons that can be learned frcm the deregulation in the United
States.

There are many aspects to this issue.

The Federal Reserve,

for example, has devoted considerable energy to dealing with the uncer­
tainties raised for monetary policy by the deregulation of deposit
instruments and interest rates.

However, today I plan to devote my

attention to an issue closer to your own particular interest— lessons
for depository institutions from the deregulation of a major financial
system.
Recent Derequlatory Actions
Deregulation in the U.S. was stimulated by a variety of mar­
ket developments that had caused problems for domestic finance.

These

developments included innovations in unregulated portions of the pri­
vate sector, and changes in the inflation and interest-rate environment
in the United States.

Artificial limits on deposit rates had disrupted

market processes as market interest rates rose and became more vola­
tile.

Furthermore, the combination of market interest rate develop­

ments and private market innovations had made life difficult for insti­
tutions that were limited to raising funds in regulated deposit mar­
kets.

2
A major thrust of the deregulatory process has been to remove
artificial constraints on both loan and deposit rates, to broaden the
asset powers of depository institutions that traditionally have spe­
cialized in mortgage investment, to remove barriers to investment in
mortgage instruments by private investors with diversified portfolios
(such as pension funds), and to widen and deepen secondary market chan­
nels that can carry loan instruments from traditional lenders to a
broad range of capital market investors.

These developments reflect

confidence by the regulatory authorities in the ability of a flexible
private market system to provide adequate credit, at all stages of the
business cycle, and at competitive market interest rates.
Fixed ceilings on deposit interest rates have been dismantled
in a series of steps since 1978 to permit depository institutions to
compete more effectively for funds against unregulated market instru­
ments, such as stockbrokers' money market mutual funds.

Only minor

remnants of deposit-rate ceilings exist at this time. State ceilings on
hone mortgage rates were preempted by federal law in 1980 as record
high market rates prevented mortgage borrowers from competing effec­
tively for funds in various geographic areas.

Maximum interest rates

on home loans insured by the Federal Housing Administration were elimi­
nated by federal law in 1983 in an environment of heightened interest
rate volatility.

Regulations governing investment by private pension

funds in mortgage-backed securities have been liberalized since 1981,
in order to remove various technical impediments to acquisitions of
mortgage-related instruments by fund managers.

3

In the United States, pricing of depository institutions'
deposit structure »as gradually changed from regulated pricing to a
market determined system, before very much consideration was given to
the deregulation of the asset side of institutions' balance sheets.
This affected the financial condition of many banks and savings and
loans, in seme instances producing a significant shrinkage in the
spread of asset yields over deposit rates, and in others produced a
negative interest-rate spread.

The combination of a fixed-rate loan

portfolio and a partially deregulated deposit base resulted in diffi­
culties for institutions for an extended period of adjustment.
tors have responded by permitting broader asset powers.

Regula­

Hcwever, many

savings and loans were not prepared to take advantage of these new
earnings opportunities. Time is required to fully use the opportuni­
ties afforded by deregulation.
Further, deregulation raises the question of hew high an
institution's capital must be to compensate for the new risks intro­
duced by deregulation.

While regulators liberalized rules regarding

intra- and interstate competition to enhance the consolidation of the
savings and loan industry, this liberalization was not enough to elimi­
nate financial institution needs to build up capital, and sinultaneously in seme cases, liquidity.

The consolidation of the banking and the

savings and loan industry in the United States is continuing.

Finan­

cial managers who choose not to be part of the deregulation process can
merge into institution's choosing to compete.
A major source of needed capital in the U.S. has been the
sale of common stock, including shares issued in the process of

4

converting from the mutual form of organization to the stockholder
form.

Of course institutions have subsequently augmented capital by

issuing large new blocs of equity securities, in both the stock and the
convertible debt form.

In addition, institutions have been set free to

acquire firms both directly as subsidiaries and via utilization of the
holding cortpany device, thus becoming affiliated with cctrpanies having
substantial capital resources.

With deregulation cones diversity of

activities, and with diversity ccanes risk.

Risk exposure in turn takes

on added dimensions when the economy is evolving into one characterized
by more volatile interest rates.
On the government side, deregulation demands more informed
and irore vigorous examination and supervision.

However, we all know

that the real burden of dealing with change and of seizing opportunity
lies with management. Interest rate fluctuations and increasing sophis­
tication among depositors inherently are part of the deregulated envir­
onment.

Where those forces are coupled with management's need to rely

upon short-term deposits, as in the United States, the presence of an
extensive secondary market and/or major institutions supporting that
market is a must.

When very substantial liquidity demands are made on

the larger thrift institutions, their very survival may depend upon the
ability to sell, swap, and borrow against a newly liquid asset from a
marketable mortgage portfolio.
U.S. monetary policy presently is designed to permit the
economy to expand toward a full-employment level without regenerating
inflationary pressures.

This eventually should lead to real interest

rates that are lower and more stable than at present, with attendant

5
benefits for other credit-dependent private sectors.

The chances of

this result being realized would be enhanced by a proper coordination
between monetary and fiscal policy.

But as you knew, the prospect of

continued large federal budget deficits in the U.S. still loans ahead.
That expectation is widely held in the U.S. financial markets and by
the public at large, and the prospect of public sector "crowding out"
of private demands for the available supply of credit appears at least
partly responsible for the stubbornly high "real" interest rates that
have prevailed on longer-term instruments.

There are fears in the mar­

ketplace that large deficits will not only place heavy demands on the
credit markets, but that they will thereby create pressures for exces­
sive monetary expansion, causing the battle to keep the inflation rate
under control to become considerably more difficult.

These imbalances,

occurring as they have during the period of deregulation, have not made
the adjustments of depository institutions any easier.
The Internationalization of Financial Markets
The internationalization of financial markets is one of the
most important trends that institutions mast learn to deal with, and
one that shews the high degree of innovation that currently is taking
place in financial institutions and markets.

Of course, capital has

been flowing across international borders for centuries.

The economic

development of the United States fran the colonial period through the
19th century, for exaitple, was financed in good part by capital pro­
vided by Great Britain and other European nations.

And throughout most

of the 20th century— indeed, generally until the current decade— the
United States has been a major source of net capital for many other

6
countries.

Of course more recently the U.S. has once again become a

net user of capital, and has received a substantial share from Japan.
However, during the past 20 years, financial markets in major
countries have becane increasingly more international in character and
increasingly more integrated.

Initially this process occurred primari­

ly in the more traditional types of banking activities.

Until the mid-

1960s, U.S. and foreign banks conducted the great bulk of their inter­
national banking transactions from offices in their heme countries.

At

that time, under the impetus provided by the United States program to
control capital outflows, banking transactions in dollars outside the
United States expanded rapidly.

U.S. banks developed foreign branch

networks to accept deposits from and extend credits to foreign custo­
mers.

Initially, the growth of this business occurred principally in

offices in Europe— hence, the name Eurodollar market.

But soon such

international banking activity developed in a wide range of other
financial centers, such as Singapore and Hong Kong, and also in newly
established offshore banking centers in the Caribbean and elsewhere.
And the number of participants grew to include major banks frcm all
countries.
The volume of deposits placed in offshore offices of U.S.
banks increased greatly in those days because they were not subject to
the U.S. interest rate ceilings or the reserve requirements that
applied to deposits in national markets.

Over the same time, the rapid

development of connunications technology helped to enlarge the competi­
tive environment for international financial services to a worldwide
basis.

In this environment, banks began to shave margins between rates

7
paid on deposits and rates charged on loans, to develop new types of
banking instruments, and (later, when U.S. banking supervisors began to
require banks to improve their capital positions) to seek income from
providing services outside the traditional banking role of intermedia­
tion.
U.S. banks have expanded their provision of financial ser­
vices internationally by playing an important role in the establishment
and development of the Eurobond market and by helping to link that mar­
ket with domestic securities markets.

Hie Eurobond market developed in

parallel with the Eurobanking market, although, until recently, at a
more moderate pace.

Prior to the development of this market, interna­

tional security issues took the form of bonds issued by nonresidents in
national markets and were subject to the regulations that applied in
that market.

By the mid-1960s, however, the "offshore" Eurobond market

had begun a period of concerted growth, as offerings by U.S. and Euro­
pean corporations and sovereign borrowers became more or less continu­
ous, supplementing the funds raised and loaned in the Eurobanking
markets.
Although the Eurobond market, whose market makers are located
in a nuntoer of financial centers, including the U.S. and Japan, is not
subject to national regulations, its investors, issuers and underwrit­
ers are frequently subject to regulation by their national authorities.
Nevertheless, the trend in recent years has clearly been to open up
national securities markets and thus to allow greater integration of
these markets and other national and international markets.

Recent

examples include the removal by Germany and Japan of important

8

restrictions on the use of their currencies in certain international
financial transactions.
The securities issued in the Eurobond market have continued
to be those of European governments, the most creditworthy of U.S. and
foreign corporations, and international organizations such as the World
Bank.

One reason U.S. corporate borrowers have continued to be

attracted to this market is that in recent years they have been able to
borrow at cheaper rates than in the United States.

In part, this is

possible because securities are offered in bearer form, giving a guar­
antee of anonymity to the investor.

Most of the investors in this mar­

ket have been and continue to be foreign financial institutions and
foreign residents.
Thus, the Eurobond market in its maturity is an effective
alternative to national debt markets.

As such, it provides an impor­

tant means by which capital can flow between countries internationally,
helping to promote its efficient allocation on a worldwide basis.

During the 1980s, for example, the market has served as an important
source of net capital inflow into the United States, a development
which is a counterpart of the large trade deficit this country has been
running over this period.
U.S. banks have been able to participate in the development
and operations of international capital markets through foreign subsid­
iaries by reason of the broad statutory authority contained in the Edge
Act (a section of the Federal Reserve Act). A principal purpose of
that act, which was enacted in 1919, was to facilitate the internation­
al and foreign banking and financial operations of U.S. banks and to

9

promote, thereby, the foreign trade and ccnmerce of the United States.
Through the creation of subsidiary corporations endowed with greater
banking and financing powers than those possessed by domestic banks, it
was intended by the U.S. Congress that U.S. banks should be able to
compete more effectively with foreign banking institutions in U.S.
trade financing and in international and foreign banking.

The Federal

Reserve Board has determined, through its regulations and orders in
individual cases, which activities abroad are appropriate for U.S.
banking organizations in the light of the purposes of the Edge Act and
related statutes.
In the mid-1960s, as U.S. companies sought ways to raise
medium- and long-term funds offshore to finance their direct invest­
ments and operations overseas, U.S. banks asked for authority to under­
write and deal in securities abroad through merchant banking subsidi­
aries.

In this context, the Federal Reserve Board gave that permission

to a number of subsidiaries, at first mainly in London but subsequently
in other banking centers.

Although the primary interest at that time

was in underwriting and dealing in debt securities, authorizations were
extended to equity securities and other securities containing equity
elements.

Subsequently, in the 1979 revision of its regulations

regarding international banking, the Board placed underwriting, dis­
tributing, and dealing in debt and equity securities outside the United
States on the list of permissible activities.
The Reserve Board's regulation admonishes the U.S. banking
organizations that their underwriting and other activities abroad are
to be carried out at all times with high standards of banking or

10

financial prudence, having due regard for diversification of risks,
suitable liquidity, and adequacy of capital.

The Board monitors these

activities through regular reporting requirements and the examination
process.
U.S. ccmnercial banks, as well as U.S. investment banks, have
only become important underwriters in the Eurobond market in the 1980s.
In significant part this prominence is attributable to the development
of various innovative financial arrangements, most importantly currency
and interest rate swaps.

In its simple form, an interest rate swap,

for example, involves two parties, one with a fixed interest payment
debt, the other with a floating rate debt.
their interest payment obligation.

These parties agree to swap

One or both parties enter these

agreements to obtain a preferred interest payment stream and/or to
lower borrowing costs.

Because of the rapid growth of financial swaps

and other innovative financial arrangements and the major involvement
or international banks in their employment, the Federal Reserve is
cooperating with other central banks in assembling information on these
arrangements and to analyze their market implications and policy sig­
nificance.
Future Prospects
Following this review of financial innovation and deregula­
tion in the U.S., may I suggest a few lessons from our experience?
not resist the deregulation of your institutions.

Do

The opening up of

your financial markets to more domestic and foreign competition
(including U.S. institutions) will be to the benefit of financial par­
ticipants in Japan, the U.S., and the rest of world, as well as these

11

economies in general.

First, the consumer is better served by a market

rate on his deposits and loans tailored to his changing needs.
ness firms will be similarly benefited.

Busi­

Your management will benefit

from the "on your toes" feeling which comes with heightened competition
— your recruitment of bright young people will be greatly aided, and
thus the long range future of the institution into which you have
poured so many years will be enhanced.

In the process of transition,

some institutions will fall by the wayside, but without deregulation,
firms outside your industry will find the legal loopholes and force a
direction of change which may be contrary to the public interest, as
they have in some cases in the United States.
Secure from your legislative bodies an adequate time frame in
which you can transform your asset structure conterminously with free­
ing the liability side of your balance sheets.

The U.S. transition was

not balanced and the time to adjust was too brief.

Test your strategic

planning as to the best market niche or combination of services which
will enhance your market share.

No management can adequately achieve

high performance in every field of activity the regulators may permit.
Remember that the consumer may tend to single you out for those things
you do best, and still go down the street for the other fellow's spe­
cialty.

Note that the new services you render likely will serve better

to expand your market share rather than become rich profit centers on
their own.

Your satisfaction and that of your customers will be

derived from the superior service rendered by the best institution in
the market.